2) Lecture - Predictability - Fall - 2022
2) Lecture - Predictability - Fall - 2022
Giacomo Morelli
Sapienza University
[email protected]
We know from Asset Pricing that if expected returns are constant, then the EMH
implies that actual returns (net of transaction costs) should be unpredictable.
Empirical studies of predictability:
1 Seasonal patterns in returns
2 Autocorrelation in short-horizon (daily, weekly, monthly) returns:
Q-statistics, ARMA models
3 Autocorrelation in long-horizon (multi-year) returns:
AR models, variance ratio tests
4 Predictability based on valuation ratios (dividend yield, price-earnings ratio)
and firm characteristics (size, book-to-market ratio)
5 Predictability based on macroeconomic variables (consumption, GDP, interest
rates)
And if you incorporate transactions costs, there are no real gains left.
We often use the modified Box-Pierce statistic (Ljung-Box) due to better finite
sample properties:
s
X ρ̂(i)2 d 2
Q̃m = T (T + 2) → χ (s) (1)
T −i
i=1
How about decile 10 (big stocks)? After some specification search based on
information criteria things look quite different there
→ Model with lowest AIC just contains a constant, January dummy is insignificant
Giacomo Morelli Financial Risk Management Financial Risk Management 9 / 25
Autocorrelation in long-horizon returns
If log returns are iid distributed with zero mean and constant variance, σ 2 , we
have the following relationship
ρ(1) = 0, VR2 = 1, ρ(1) > 0, VR2 > 1 , ρ(1) < 0, VR2 < 1
| {z } | {z } | {z }
No Autocorrelation Pos. Autocorrelation Neg. Autocorrelation
General case:
iid log returns: Var(rt→t+k ) = k × Var(rt+1 )
Positive autocorrelation: Var(rt→t+k ) > k × Var(rt+1 )
Negative autocorrelation: Var(rt→t+k ) < k × Var(rt+1 )
1 Var(rt→t+k )
VRk ≡ (5)
k Var(rt+1 )
VRk < 1 : mean reverting
VRk = 1 : iid log returns
VRk > 1 : mean averting
ˆ k is distributed as
Under the iid null hypothesis, VR
√
ˆ d 2(2k − 1)(k − 1)
Tk(VR k − 1) → N 0,
3k
r
ˆ k) = 2(2k − 1)(k − 1)
SE(VR
3Tk 2
k Var(rt→t+k ) k Var(rt+1 ) ˆ k
VR Std. Error VR-stat.
1 0.0041 0.0041 1.00
12 0.0628 0.0492 1.28 0.048 5.75
24 0.1155 0.0984 1.17 0.050 3.48
36 0.1601 0.1476 1.08 0.050 1.68
48 0.2202 0.1968 1.12 0.051 2.35
Figure: Multi-period excess return prediction. Cochrane (2008): Financial Markets and
the Real Economy, In: HANDBOOK OF THE EQUITY RISK PREMIUM, Elsevier BV.
(Table 1)
t+k ∼ MA(k − 1)
⇒ OLS estimate of b consistent, but SE(b) inconsistent
⇒ use Newey-West (HAC-SE) robust standard errors
Empirical studies show:
b̂ ≈ 0 and R 2 ≈ 0 for small k
b̂ 6= 0 and R 2 very high for large k
A high (low) price, relative to dividends or earnings, signals lower (higher)
future long-term stock returns
We return to multi-period forecasting regressions later in the course
Figure: Recursive estimates of b of log excess return prediction with log dividend-to-price
ratio. Goyal & Welch (2003): Predicting the Equity Premium With Dividend Ratios,
Management Science 49 (5), pp. 639-654 (Figure 2)
etc
Figure: Recursive estimates of b of log excess return prediction with log dividend-to-price
ratio. Goyal & Welch (2003): Predicting the Equity Premium With Dividend Ratios,
Management Science 49 (5), pp. 639-654 (Figure 2)
Figure: CAY. Lettau & Ludvigson (2001): Consumption, Aggregate Wealth, and
Expected Stock Returns, Journal of Finance 56 (3), pp. 815-849 (Table III)