Dual Labour Market
Dual Labour Market
Dual Labour Market
Jeremy I. Bulow
Lawrence H. Summers
ABSTRACT
This paper develops a model of dual labor markets based on employers' need
may find it optimal to pay more than the going wage. This changes fundamentally
the character of labor markets. The model is applied to a wide range of labor
forces. Finally, the model provides the basis for a theory of involuntary
unemployment.
Jerenr I. Bulow
Lawrence H. Sumniers
Center for the Study of
the Econonnj and the State Department of Economics
Harvard University
University of Chicago Cambridge, MA 02138
1101 East 58th Street (617) 495—2l4iL7
Chicago, IL 60637
(312) 962—8779
—1—
Marginal workers would be indifferent to losing their jobs since wages would
just equal the amount they could earn pursuing alternative opportunities. With
welfare.
appears to hold in practice. Wages differ across workers in ways that are
consistently suggest that factors such as occupation, firm size, race, sex, age
found to. rise at times when productivity and real wages fall. Workers value
industries, and interferences with free trade are pervasive around the world.
This paper examines one theory of dual labor markets which can account for
these phenomena.1 The deviation from the standard competitive model which
drives our analysis is the inability of firms to costlessly determine how much
effort their workers are putting forth. Firms can elicit more effort from their
1Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984) analyze some related issues with a model which
is formally very similar to the model presented in the first section of this
paper. Yellen (1984) provides an informal discussion of dual labor markets
paralleling parts of the formal discussion presented here. Our initial analysis
was developed before we became aware of these contributions. The idea that
—2—
raising the cost to them of being caught shirking. The latter objective may
require that firms pay workers more than their opportunity cost. A worker who
is paid only his opportunity cost has little incentive to avoid shirking. Firms
have a strong incentive to make workers value their jobs. They can only do this
by paying more than the "going wage." It is the deviation of workers' wages
from their opportunity costs that gives rise to our model's imperfectly
competitive features.
The potential importance of the linkages between the level of wages and
worker productivity which form the basis of our analysis is well illustrated by
relations. This episode also serves to highlight the importance of the effort
the Ford Motor company introduced the five dollar day for industrial workers.
At the time prevailThg wages at Ford and other companies were between $2.00 and
$3.00 a day. Immediately following the announcement, more than ten thousand
persons gathered outside the Ford plant gates looking for jobs. Ford declared
that the motive for the wage increase was "profit sharing and efficiency
firms need to elicit effort from workers can give rise to a labor market with
imperfectly competitive features has recently been explored in Calvo (1979),
Ishikawa (1984), and Bowles (1984). A particularly clear statement of the role
of non-competitive wages in eliciting effort may be found in Becker and Stigler
(1974). It dates back at least to Marx's "reserve army of the unemployed."
The Ford high wage does away with all of the inertia and living
force resistance... The workingmen are absolutely docile, and it
is safe to say that since the last day of 1913, every single day
has seen major reductions in Ford shops labor costs.
Alan Nevins (1954) in his history of the early Ford Motor Company concluded
that:
The only available quantitative estimate of the effects of Ford's high wage
introduction of the high wage policy. One estimate, Levin (1927) suggests that
the high wage policy halved absenteeism. And Nevins reports that discharges
for cause declined very sharply because of the "instant and unquestioning
increases in worker effort. Nevins (1954) after reviewing the Ford archives
concluded that:
goods and services, and the maintaenance of worker morale is a major priority
for most firms. Productivity varies widely across time and space in ways which
defined.6 An HEW task force on Work in America (1973) after reviewing hundreds
Many economists take the position that markets will tend to make efficient
means by which it is produced but that stabilization policies of some sort are
alternative view is that recessions are just the most obvious symptom of market
presented here provides a justification for this alternative view. It shows how
involuntary unemployment can result from sources which also badly distort
The paper is organized as follows. Section I lays out our basic model of a
dual labor market. It shows how equally productive workers can in equilibrium
These sectors parallel institutional descriptions of the dual labor market such
high wages and responsible career jobs, while the secondary sector has menial
jobs, low wages and no job ladders. Although workers in the secondary sector
envy those in the primary sector, and are equally productive there is no
equilibrating market force which can erode wage differentials. The model also
Section II shows that our dual labor market model provides a formal
advocates that the high wage/high value added sectors of an economy should be
subsidized and protected from foreign competition. Unlike most of the arguments
in the industrial policy debate, ours explains why workers and not just
eliminate it. Our theory of discrimination also provides an explanation for the
total welfare.
primary sector jobs for incentive reasons. By postulatinf that the primary
sector does not hire workers who are employed but only those who are out of
work,we are able to show that involuntary unemployment with Keynesian features
will result. The model also provides the basis for theories of the cyclical
Doeringer and Piore (1971) have described the American economy as having a
dual labor market. Jobs fall into either the primary or secondary sector. Jobs
in the primary sector are "good jobs" characterized by high wages, job security,
Jobs in the secondary sector are characterized by low wages, casual attachments
between workers and firms, and are menial. Workers in the secondary sector envy
those in the primary sector who have both better jobs and higher wages. A
establishment, while small service firms such as fast food outlets typify the
secondary sector.
accurately capture many aspects of the labor market. Yet they raise an obvious
question. If workers in the secondary sector envy those in the primary sector,
why are not wages in the primary sector bid down? The logic of competitive
wages in different jobs. The model in this section provides an explanation for
the existence of dual labor markets. The central idea is that primary sector
firms may find it advantageous to pay more than the "going wage" it helps them
of involuntary unemployment.7
The Model
agents. Each can supply one unit of labor and produce w units of output in
(1.1) U = —r(v—t) dv
JtU(xiix2_as)e
where x. is the number of Units of sector i
output consumed in period t, r is
the discount rate, and s is an indicator variable equalling zero when the worker
works, and one when he shirks. Thus it is assumed that only two levels of
worker effort are possible. Shirking workers are assumed to produce no output.
Note that we have assumed that shirking and consuming extra units of x2 are
U(Ax1,Ax2) = AU(x1,x2). Note also that our assumptions imply that all consumers
will consume the economy's two goods in the same proportion. We ssume that
consumers can neither borrow nor lend. As we discuss below, this assumption
restricts workers from posting bonds against the possibility of their shirking.
the hometheticity of the utility function and production assumptions noted above
we can write:
x E E
(1.2) p1 = f() 2
=
2
=
1
i
g(E1); g < 0
Competition will insure that secondary sector workers receive a wage equal
assume that secondary sector workers are monitored perfectly and thus have no
possibility of shirking. This reflects the idea that secondary sector jobs are
menial.
The key aspect of our model is that detection of shirkers in the primary
of primary sector jobs. Both false positives and false negatives may result as
firms try to detect shirkers. We assume that a worker who is not shirking has
a shirker over an increment of time is (d2-d1)dt greater for those who are not
shirking than it is for those who are shirking. It is also assumed that all
either due to worker quits in order to relocate of withdraw from the labor force
demand.
We assume in the discussion below that firms are restricted to paying all
discussed. Firms in the primary sector need to induce their workers not to
shirk. The only penalty that they have at their disposal is the threat to fire
will become apparent that it is never desirable to fire workers not caught
shirking. Denoting the present value of lifetime utility for workers in the
primary and secondary sectors respectively by PV1 and PV2, workers will shirk at
(1.3) a
(d2—d1)(PV1—Pv2)
is satisfied. The left hand side is the instantaneous gain in utility from
shirking while the right hand side is the product of incremental probability of
being dismissed if a worker shirks and the loss in lifetime utility from being
dismissed. The values of PV1 and PV2 may be calculated from the recursive
equations:
— -
—(r+q+d 1 )t -(r+q+e 1 )t
(1.4) PV1 - = (w1-) fe dt +
(q+d1)(Pv2—)70e dt
E
— E —(r +
2
(1.5) PV2 — = 1(q+d1)(PV1-) fe dt
Equation (1.4) holds that the present value of the surplus from a primary sector
job is the sum of the discounted surplus from the current job and the present
the time until the secondary sector will next be entered. Since workers in the
secondary sector get a wage w, equation (1.5) is simply the present value of the
future surplus if in the primary sector discounted to reflect the time until the
primary sector is next entered. In forming equation (1.5) we have made use of
the steady state assumption that the flow of workers into and out of the primary
sector is equal, so that the flow rate out of the secondary sector is
2
Solving equations (1.3) through (1.5) yields the no shirk condition on
w -w=
- ar a(d1+q)N
(1.6) — + - -E
shirking, a, increases, firms must pay more to induce their workers not to
firms must also pay higher wages. Likewise, if the rate of turnover among
non-shirkers, d1 + q increases firms must pay higher wages. This is because the
greater the number of primary sector jobs, E1, the higher wages must be to
maintain the opportunity cost of losing a job, because the time a worker must
increases in r raise required wages because they reduce the present value of the
wages will exceed wages in the secondary sector even though all workers are
identical. Workers in the secondary sector will envy those •in the primary
sector, but it will not be possible for them to bid f or primary sector jobs by
being willing to accept lower wages. For if they accepted lower wages, they
would have an ircentive to shirk. Hence firms will not offer lower wages.
The model here implies that firms will be extremely conscious of relative
only observe their own labor supply curves and have no need to learn about
either wage or employment levels at other firms. Indeed, one of the major
the costs of information acquisition because each agent can act knowing only the
prices it faces.
In fact, firms are extremely concerned with assessing where they stand in
the wage distribution. The Handbook of Wage and Salary Administration (1984)
almost 50 surveys with salary data on the Chicago metropolitan area and 9
capital arguments for the existence of enduring attachments between workers and
firms, which does not rely on the productivity enhancing effects of experience.
Reductions in the exogenous seperation rate q, reduce the wage which primary
sector firms pay in order to insure that workers will not shirk. Firms
this means that they will not replace workers not determined to be shirking.
Firms also have an incentive to give laid off workers first priority for new
jobs, and to provide alternative jobs within the firm for poorly matched
workers.
Equation (1.6) provides one relation between primary sector employntent and
This relation (5) results from the requirement that workers in the primary
E
= =
(1.7) w = p1 wf(j1) wg(E1)
2
different wages. We defer until the next section an analysis of the efficiency
Wages
Wi
I
I
I
I
W -J
I
E1
Employment
Figure 1
workers, the interest rate and the utility workers get from shirking. In
The analysis so far has assumed that the only sanction available to firms
when workers are suspected of shirking is dismissal. One can imagine firms
developing various other means for inducing workers not to shirk. For example,
workers in primary sector jobs might be asked to post bonds which would be
forfeited in the event they were detected shirking. Since the probability of
detection is less than one, these bonds would have to exceed the value of the
output foregone because of worker shirking. Bonds of this type are not observed
in practice for two reasons. First, workers simply do not have the requisite
liquidity to post bonds. Second, and probably more important, third party
firms did not do this there would remain the problem of determining in which
number of the features of actual primary sector firms may perform some of the
same economic functions that bonding might perform. In particular, these firms
are characterized by job ladders and rising age-wage profiles, while similar
(1981) a rising age/wage profile can maintain the present value of a job as a
worker's years tonormal retirement diminish. As Medoff and Abraham (1981) have
productivity.10 Rising age-wage profiles are of course subject to the same sort
profiles unlike posted bonds will encourage workers to stay with firms even when
easily monitored. Thus John Dunlop (1985) writes "Capital intensive production
associated with.. .lengthy promotion ladders and elongated pyramids, while more
labor intensive operations as in light assembly, grocery stores and sewing have
few promotion ladders and flat pyramids." As Doeringer and Piore (1971)
We have already shown how taking account of the effort elicitation problem
can potentially explain two features of observed labor markets: the fact that
there are good and bad jobs held by equivalent workers, and the existence of
rising age-wage profiles in primary sector jobs. How important are these
phenomena empirically? One way of thinking about the question is the following:
How indifferent, even in good times, would the typical manufacturing worker be
to the loss of his job? In a competitive market, firms would pay workers no
more than their opportunity cost of working. Hence workers would be indifferent
to losing their job. This is not true in the environment described here where
and inter-occupation wage differences even for equally skilled workers. This
even after controlling for many measures of worker quality. It is also relevant
to the dualism that 'is said to characterize the labor market. Yet, a second
type of anomaly in the wage structure also stands out. There appear to be
literatures document the correlation of wage rates with unionism (e.g., Freeman
and Medoff (1984)), and firm size (e.g., Brown and Medoff (1985))and there is
differentials poses a difficult issue. Leaving aside the question of why firms
choose to pay different wages, how do high wage firms remain viable in the
market place? The question is a critical one. For typical firms the wage bill
is 4 times profits. If a firm paid even 10 percent above the going wage its
simple extension of our model can provide a further part of the explanation.
These resources are consumed according to a function $(d2), where 4 > 0. Then
order conditions for the solution of (1.8) that first order changes in wages
—16—
will have no effect on labor costs.11 This is dramatically different from the
standard model where wage changes translate directly into cost chaflges. It
follows that discrete changes in wages will give rise to much less than
proportional changes in labor costs. This helps to explain how high wage firms
endure. From the perspective of this model, the observation that firms in the
same industry pay different wages is no more mysterious than the obser ation
that their factor proportions differ. Wage premia in this model contribute
union productivity effect discussed by Freeman and Medoff (1984). When wages
argument, Brown and Medoff (1978) report some evidence suggesting that the
nonunionized sector.
Equation (1.8) also provides a basis for a theory of the firm size effect.
Large firms enjoy economies of scale and are able to get reduced prices from
suppliers but because of their size have less favorable 4(d2) functions. They
therefore substitute high wages for supervision. These ideas comport well with
a number of Brown and Medoff's (1985) empirical findings: (i) quit rates are
lower in large and unionized establishments; (ii) large employers have more
pronounced job ladders than do smaller firms and steeper age-wage profiles;
(iii) the wage differential between large and small firms decreases with skill
11The argument here is similar to but different from that of Akerlof and
Yellen (1984). They emphasize that inertia may not be very costly for firms.
Our point is that a variety of compensation-monitoring strategies will be about
equally attractive to firms. The argument here is more general than our model.
It will be valid in any setting where firms choose wages. Models based on
—17—
Wage Dynamics
the model presented here can contribute to the explanation of aspects of the
increased substantially at the same time that the market conditions facing the
relative wages in the face of declining product demand.12 One would expect
reductions in labor demand to lead to both lower employment and lower wages.
in the probability that the employer will initiate a separation will necessitate
the granting of a wage increase in order to insure that the no-shirk condition
function in (1.6) as a higher quit rate. Thus failing firms will find
This may also partially explain why firms tend to give relatively little notice
Summary
The analysis in this section suggests that in any economy where firms
cannot monitor workers perfectly, they will pursue policies which will cause
together can explain only a very small part of the inequality 'in wages.14 As
Jencks (1972) and Thurow (1976) argue this suggests the possible importance of
luck in wage determination. The formulation presented here shows how luck can
market. In the next section we explore the normative properties of our model.
The previous Section provided a model that was consistent with the
that are not readily explicable in terms of differences in labor qi.ality. The
differentials.
American industrial policy advocates such as Robert Reich and Lester Thurow
take the position that nations should try to focus economic policies on
encouraging high value added sectors. These sectors, it is argued provide "good
high wage jobs," in contrast to the low wage jobs found in other sectors of the
Japan over the last 20 years to their successful encouragement of high value
added production. They are alarmed by what they see as the de-industrialization
of America and the consequent loss of high value added employment. While
nation must have a comparative advantage in something, they find little solace
assumption that competition equalizes wages across sectors. We shall see that
-20-
first-best outcome in a model like ours. The deadweight loss relative to the
first best is equal to the shaded area in the figure. A subsidy to primary
sector production, wh-:h had the effect of shifting the PMC locus to the right
would increase total economic welfare. Indeed, a subsidy large enough to shift
the PMC locus out sufficiently to cause primary sector employment to rise to X.,
would achieve the same pareto-optimal outcome that would be achieved under
which was financed by a lump sum tax would represent a pareto improvement.
primary sector who were already better off than they were. Nonetheless, it
turns out that such a subsidy would represent a pareto improvement. This may be
dPV1 - dPV2
(2.1) ds ds =0
where s is the rate of subsidy. A change in the subsidy rate must have an equal
impact on the present value of lifetime welfare for workers in both the
• secondary and the primary sector. Equating the present value of the gain in
economic welfare from a change in the subsidy, to the sum of the present value
gains for workers currently in the primary and secondary sectors workers we have:
(2.2)
w- dE1 = dPV1
+ dPV2
+ dE1
r E1 ds E2 ds (PV1-PV2)—-—
'4-
Wages
Wi
E1 E2
Employment
Figure2
Subsidies and Economic Efficieçy
—21—
dE
dE1
where we have used the -fact that — =-—
ds ds
Since we know that w1-w > -
-
r PV1 PV2 starting at a zero subsidy rate, it
follows that dPV1/ds =
dPV2/ds
> 0. A small subsidy will represent a pareto-
to increase employment to its socially optimal level would reduce the present
order effect on social welfare but the transfer effect is first order; thus
Bhagwati and Srinavasan (1983) suggesting that if wages are artificially high in
the distortion. There are three important differences. First the wage
but instead are determined endogenously and depend on the relative sizes of the
two sectors. Increases in the subsidy raise wage differentials but are
cause for concern that subsidizing the high wage sector will lead to greater
subsidy on the lifetime welfare of workers in the primary and secondary sector,
15These results have implications for the effects of other labor market
policies. A proportional or progressive income tax reduces the utility gain
from holding a primary rather than a secondary sector job, thus shiftirj the NSC
to the left and reducing economic welfare. Note that this effect is first order
—22-
the case of an open economy, the differences between our formulation and the
heuristically in Figure 3•16 Imagine that the domestic economy is small and
the world price of the primary sector good, p. is less than the domestic price.
This may occur for any of the conventional "natural" reasons why foreigners
might have a comparative advantage in the primary sector, if foreign workers are
foreign firms have found better contracting devices for inducing workers not to
shirk. Each of these possibilities has some relevance to the current U.S.
policy debate. The region ABDE represents the welfare loss to the economy due
The angular area ABC represents the gain from free trade, as the price of
economic welfare. The lost rents as primary sector employment contracts from OF
to 00 represent a greater loss than the second order to gain to consumers from
There is a simple intuition for this result. The gains to consumers from
unlike the second order welfare costs normally associated with labor income
taxes. The difference arises because of the pre-existing distortions present in
our model. Similarly, policies directed at compressing wage differentials will
in a model like this one have unfortunate consequences. If primary sector
workers cannot be bonded to work hard by high wages, the market equilibrium will
of necessity involve a large threat of being confined to the secondary sector.
This in turn requires an expansion in the secondary sector at the expense of the
primary sector.
Wages
I
I
I
I
p1 B C
I
I
w _____________
0 G F N
Employment
Figure 3
1/1/,,,
—23—
allowing free trade are of second order in the change in the relative price of
primary sector output. On the other hand, the gains in primary sector
employment from restricting trade represent a first order welfare gain because
environment the no shirk condition (1.4) must still be met, but that product
(2.3) w1 =
where p1 is the world relative price of the primary good. Other conditions for
(2.5) =
g()
which is a result of our assumption of hornothetic tastes.
With the system of equations (1.6) and (2.3) to (2.5), we can solve for
dE
[(w1 -) + (wE -x
dp1
1 1
(26) r
dp
two effects. The first term on the right side of (2.6) arises because primary
—24--
sector size is constrained by a combination of the NSC and world prices; a lower
reflects the welfare gain from the lower foreign prices. It is equal to net
imports, (x1—wE1) times the price drop. It is clear that if the world price is
below but sufficiently close to the autarky price so that net imports are small,
the loss of primary job3 and their attached rents implies that welfare is
that of (2.1) and (2.2) shows that if world primary sector prices are below but
domestic workers; the gain to secondary workers in lower primary sector prices
follows from comparing Figures 4a and 4b. The welfare gains per dollar of
revenue cost from a subsidy to the primary sector are greater in an open economy
that would have had an autarky price less than or equal to the free trade price
than they would be in a closed economy. This is because the demand for primary
Therefore, for any subsidy per primary sector employee more people will switch
to the primary sector, and marginal worker shifts will provide as much of an
less and less. In the open economy, when primary sector output can be exported,
there s no similar factor limiting the gains from subsidizing primary sector
output. 17
17Thjs proposition and the one in the next paragraph may be verified by
/
PMC
s/
/
NSC
/ /
Wages
Wi
W -_
Einploynient
Figure 4
a) autarky
PMC NSC
/
Wages
Employment
b) free trade
—25-
where they have a comparative advantage. The greater is the world price
of primary sector output, the greater is the gain from increasing primary
primary sector employment if the world price of primary sector output is close
to the secondary sector wage w. In that case, there is little loss from letting
primary sector good from abroad. Where the world price is high, and the home
benefit.
The model presented here captures many of the prominent themes in the
industrial policy debate. There are good jobs and bad jobs even in equilibrium.
Good jobs have higher wages and higher average productivity. Value-added per
worker is higher in these jobs. Protecting sectors with good jobs can raise
firms. These seem less relevant to the issues debated than does our model which
calculating dE1/ds explicitly from equations (1.6) and (1.7) for the closed
economy and (1.6) and (2.3) for the open economy.
-26-
rationale for these actions. Obviously, an analysis of this kind taken alone
basis for thinking about many of the issues raised by the industrial policy
debate.
competition. Firms that did not discriminate would have lower costs than firms
which did and would therefore grow tending to eliminate discrimination. With
perfect capital markets, capital would be put to its most profitable use by
tastes, since firms comprised only of minority group members would have lower
costs than other firms. Furthermore, some evidence, Blau (1982) suggests that
18The formal model that we have presented here does not include capital as a
factor of production. Adding capital as a factor does not change the
conclusions reached so far, but leads to another conclusion. Traditional
competitive models suggest that it is in the national interest to allow capital
to seek the highest return available either at home or abroad. Once wage
—27—
ceteris paribus.19
discrimination find that much of the discrimination takes the form of equal pay
for equal work but unequal work (e.g. Lloyd and Niemi (1979)). Doeringer and
Piore (1971) in their discussion of the dual labor market emphasize that members
of disadvantaged groups are confined to the secondary sector. Even granting the
The dual labor market model developed here has as its central element wage
one considered here employers can costlessly discriminate since there is excess
demand for primary sector jobs. This is not correct. If the equilibrium
firms can lower the wage offered to disadvantaged workers without fear that they
confined to the secondary sector reduces the wage that must be paid to satisfy
is assumed that there are group differences that are unrelated to productivity.
After showing how these differences can lead to occupational segregation and
policies.
market is that they have very high separation rate. For example, Poterba and
Summers (1984) estimate that the rate of labor force withdrawal is about 1
percent per year for males 25-59 but about 19 percent per year for women in the
same age bracket.2° Data in Marston (1976) suggest large age and race
and Startz (1982). This seems a rather weak reed on which to base a theory of
discrimination.
20Some empirical studies suggest that turnover rates do not differ across
groups after controlling for job characteristics. These findings are not
inconsistent with the analysis presented here. If as implied by our model, high
turnover workers are assigned by the market to certain types of jobs, then
-29-
Taking account of the fact that there are two identifiable groups in the
population the basic equilibrium conditions require that workers be paid their
marginal products and that both men and women in the primary sector be induced
(3.1) w = W9(Elm+Eif) =
Pl(Elm4Elf)
- ar +
ar(d1+q )Nm
(3.2) (w1-w) = d -d
2 1 'd2 -d1''E2m
'
-
(w1—w) =
ar +
ar(d1+qf)Nf
(3.2)
2
where the subscripts m and f are used to denote males and females, for
sector men and women receive the same wages. However, comparing equations (3.2)
and (3.3) it is clear that a higher proportion of women will be confined to the
primary sector jobs, they must receive a greater inducement if they are not to
shirk. With equal wages, this can only occur if secondary sector women have a
smaller chance of moving to the primary sector than do secondary sector men.
These points are illustrated in Figure 5. As long as the NSC for women lies
above the NSC for men, there will be partial occupational segregation.
NS Cf I
I
I
I
I
I
Wages I II
I
I
V — —J — —I — ———
I I ii
I I
I I
N E+E N+N
m mf
Nf
E
in
Employment
Figure 5
(drawn assuming Nf = N)
-30-
groups differ in the utility they get from being in the secondary sector,
result. The model captures a commonly observed aspect of firm behavior. Firms
prefer to give jobs to workers who "really need them" than to workers who gain
raises the wages of men but reduces or has no effect on the earnings of women.
the cost to men of losing a desirable job, but reduces the costs to women for
employer prejudice.
are considered. Before turning to this analysis it should be noted that our
into efficient labor contracts in the primary sector. Population groups that
are liquidity constrained and therefore unable to accept low starting wages and
rising age-wage profiles will not be able to get primary sector jobs. The wage
they must be paid in order to get them not to shirk may well exceed the going
• primary sector wage. For example, historically some workers may not have been
primary sector jobs at low wages reflecting their low expected productivity, and
would be no incentive for a firm to make such an offer since at low wages all
Anti-Discrimination policies
Equivalently, what are the normative properties of policies which require that
in the primary sector? We examine these questions in the context of the model
least a small tax is desirable, we proceed as follows. Since men and women have
the same utility function, a tax increase will be desirable if d(EIM+EIF)/dt > 0.
Substituting equation (3.1) into (3.2) and (3.3) and introducing the tax
into the latter two equations allows us to implictly differentiate (3.2) and
large enough subsidy to drive the female primary sector participation rate up to
ar Nf t(E1M+Elf)
d -d
•
2
(-f) - 2
ii
2 1
(3.6) d(E1M+Eif) -
— (Nf_E1f) E1f
dt
positive to the point where the sectoral composition of employment is the same
for men and women, a reduction in the subsidy to the hiring of women will raise
welfare. A policy intermediate between the laissez faire outcome and the
sum of utilities.
in the absence of any subsidy the NSC for women is less steep than the NSC for
men. Hence a policy of taxing each man in the primary sector $1 and subsidizing
each woman in the primary sector by $E/Ef will bea net revenue raiser and will
increase total employment. If no revenues were raised, but all the proceeds were
used to subsidize the employment of women, the employment gains would be even
greater. On the other hand, if the share of men and women in the primary sector
is equalized, equations (3.2) and (3.3) imply that the NSC is flatter for men
thn for women. This is because a small increase in wages raises the present
value of a job by more for men than for women because of their longer horizon.
In this case, reducing the tax on men and the subsidy to women raises total
employment.
carried on through such quotas, the wages of women will rise above average
primary sector wages, and male wages will fall. A quota policy which reduces
artificially compress the wage differential between the primary and secondary
sectors. This would be disastrous for both men and women. With. a compressed
wage differential between the two sectors, the no shirk condition would require
-34-
the case where discimination results from one group getting more utility from a
secondary sector job than the other. In this case, the effect of a subsidy on
substitution of women for men in primary sector jobs. This reduces welfare
under the maintained assumption that women value primary sector jobs less than
men. We have not yet considered the welfare effects of affirmative action
Although primary sector jobs are rationed in our model, we have so far
assumed that no rent seeking behavior takes place. In a sense therefore the
who would like to work at the going wage are unable to find work. Yet as many
employers only hire Workers directly from the pool of unemployed workers. This
Imposing the requirement that workers must be unemployed before they can
(4.1) w1 = wg1(E1/E2)
(4.2) a = (p1)(d2d1)
d1
+ q + r
(d1+q)E1 (p1—1)
(4.3) w
N-E1—E2
recalling from before that the utility from being unemployed (having no income)
Equation (4.1) simply determines the relative price of primary sector output.
Note that we can no longer write it as g(E1) because now some workers are
unemployed. Equation (4.2) holds that the utility gain from shirking in the
primary sector must equal the present value of holding a job in the primary
permanently confined to the secondary sector. Equation (4.3) holds that the
sector job times the present value of such a job. This formulation differs
—36-
somewhat from that of Harris and Todaro (1970) who assume that workers must be
equilibrium requires both that the PMC and NSC cross and that secondary sector
involuntary as workers are queuing for primary sector jobs, and are identical to
primary sector job holders but cannot bid down wages and get primary sector
Second, relative to the first best the level of unemployment is too high
and the level of primary sector employment is too low. As we discuss more
welfare.
consumption will all move pro-cyclically as long as product demand is not too
elastic and/or the primary sector is not too small. This proposition may be
(d1+q)E1E
I
Wi
I
Wages
N
N-E1—E2U E2
Employment
Figure 6
prices will imply the same ratio of N-E1-E2/E1 as before the shock also
If the primary sector already dominates the economy (E11E2 large) then an
raise total employment. If, however, the economy is dominated by the secondary
sector, the principle effect of a shock will be to move workers into the primary
in Okun (1982). First, Okun noted that quits are pro-cyclical while employer
sector, while negative shocks lead to job loss as the primary sector contracts.
peaks. In the model here, positive productivity shocks lead to equal absoi
-38-
formulation provides an explanation for firms use of temporary layoffs and for
labor hoarding. Both serve to increase workers' horizon and therefore limit the
wage that must be paid to insure that workers do not shirk. A fourth
observation most sharply distinguishes our model firms from alternative accounts
of employment fluctuations.
rather than the number of hours worked per person. Worksharing arrangements in
the face of downturns in demand are a rarity in the American economy. While it
a worksharing device, it is hard to see why employers who must reduce the size
As Okun observes, the absence of worksharing antedates any incentives for full
unionization.
considered here. Assume that a worker holding a fraction (1-z) of his time to
searching for a full time job, and assume that his search efficiency is 1-z
times that of a full time worker. Available evidence on job search, Clark and
Summers (1979), suggests that in fact part time primary sector workers could
probably search about as efficiently as the full time employed. Assuming that
dismissal rates are proportional to hours on the job (so that a nor-shirking
full timer) but that quit rates are related to calendar time on the job, the
no-shirk wage per unit of time worked for a z-time employee, w, in an economy
(1—z)E1 (1—z)E1
+ +
r + e (z N-E N-E
-
(4.5) w — w = [
(w1—w)
z(r+d1q)
The crucial insight is that both a full—timer and a part—time worker get
the same benefit from shirking for an hour, and each is as likely to be caught.
Therefore, to prevent the part-timer from shirking the employer must offer him a
job which is equally valued (has the same present value) as a full-time job.
Such a constraint necessarily implies that the part-time employees will require
correlated. While we have not completed a full dynamic analysis of our model,
normal level, the instantaneous separation rate would be arbitrarily high and so
workers would shirk unless wages were infinite. It follows that a temporary
employment followed by a slow decline. Notice that primary sector wages would
rise more and employment less for a temporary productivity shock than for a
permanent productivity shock. This is because the knowledge that the shock was
Stuctural Unemployment
real model like ours with competitive product markets, seems to matter in
secondary sector output leads to a reduced relative price for primary sector
output and lower primary sector wages. This in turn causes primary sector
occurs despite the maintained assumption that it does not affect workers' search
decisions and that its financing does not affect employers' decisions about
layoffs. Rather, its effect occurs primarily through firms' wage setting
behavior. This model provides a possible basis for suspicions about the adverse
studies.
and reduce
increasing job security may substantially increase unemployment
primary sector employment. Such policies may be thought of as reducing d2, the
likelihood that a shirking worker will be detected and laid off. As we have
• wages, primary sector employment will decrease and unemployment will rise.
the No Shirk condition, pins down the relationship between primary and secondary
—42—
sector wages which must exist if primary workers are not to'shirk, as long as
reduced, primary sector firms will not be able to operate because the No Shirk
V. Conclusions
They can contribute to the understanding of many phenomena that are difficult to
acount for in other ways. And they have very different normative implications
than do other labor market models. Taking account of the effort elicitation
problem calls into question the general proposition that private labor market
market policies.
effort elicitation problem introduces several new elements into the analysis of
minimum wages. First, minimum wages may interfere with efficient contracting
constrain firms so that they cannot offer age-wage profiles which are as steep
as they would like, they will have to raise the total level of compensation in
order to insure that workers do not shirk. Second, minimum wage laws have a
they create. Because they will in general create some unemployment they raise
the cost to being laid off from the primary sector. This will permit lower
primary sector wages and greater primary sector employment. Third, minimum wage
-43-
firms affected by the minimum. Such firms will be able to reduce.the resources
Beyond their application to various labor market issues, there are a number
efficiency wages have made strong assumptions about the nature of compensation
be devised which obviate the need for firms to offer more than the going wage in
worker liquidity, moral hazard on the part of firms, risk aversion on the part
The observation that many workers are paid more than their opportunity cost
requires rationalization.
firms'
A related question emphasized by Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984) concerns
will be flawed. There will be " too many chiefs and too few indians". Firms
reducing workers' incentive to shirk. Extra wages benefit workers but extra
and to raise their wages will increase social welfare. Of Course_they may
reduce the welfare of those with human capital which is specialized towards
supervisory ability.
A second direction for future research concerns the sources of the linkages
between wages and productivity. In keeping with the work of others, we have
emphasized the effects of increases in the wages firms pay on the level of
effort that they are able to elicit from their workers. The mechanism we have
stressed is the role of the fear of job loss in inducing workers not to shirk.
personnel management, businessmen and union leaders all stress that equitable
and fair wage policies are critical to motivating workers. While standard
neoclassical economics has no role for income effects in the theory of the firm,
the question of how much firms can "afford to pay" plays a prominent role in
Workers effort level may depend more on whether they feel their wage is
just than on its absolute level. Depending on how "justice norms" are formed,
results similar to those produced by our formulation may result. Even in the
firms will be reluctant to cut wages for fear of alienating current employees.
established, and the costs of changing them for any one firm may exceed the
benefits. It is also clear that justice norms may influence the type of workers
-45-
hired by firms.
One promising avenue towards this objective involves the "menu costs" arguments
of Mankiw (1985) and Akerlof and Yellen (1985). These authors show that if
there is any cost to changing prices and if as in our model, the economy does
not attain the first best level of employment, expansionary policies will have
real effects and may raise welfare. Small nominal shocks will have real effects
analysis of the primary sector along the lines of Kiyotaki (1985). In such a
model, increases in current aggregate demand will have real effects, similar to
those of a productivity shock. The demand for primary sector output will
sector will reduce unemployment, the size of the secondary sector or both.
can influence real output. If monetary policy can affect the interest rate, it
I
will effect the wages firms must pay in order to insure that their workers do
not shirk. Increases in real interest rates reduce the discounted value of
higher wages which in turn reduce primary sector employment. Thus purely
monetary changes can affect the level of unemployment as long as they affect
Probably the most important direction for future research in this area
strong presumption that many firms are or could profit from offering their
final direction for empirical tests of these ideas would involve examining the
their jobs.
can be adduced for most any labor market outcome without resorting to models of
the type considered here. Ultimately the case for the utility of models based
on the effort elicitation problem, must rest on the common explanation they
provide for a very wide range of phenomena. Our investigation convinces us that
models based on the incentive effects of non-competitive wages provide the best
References
Arnold, H. L. and F.L. Favarote, FORD METHODS AND THE FORD SHOPS (New York)
1915.
Becker, 0., "Human Capital, Effort and the Sexual Division of Labor," Journal
of Labor Economics, January 1985.
Doeringer, P.B. and M.J. Piore, INTERNAL LABOR MARKETS AND MANPOWER ANALYSIS
(Lexington, Mass.: D. C. Heath and Co.) 1971.
Freeman, R. and J. Medoff, WHAT DO UNIONS DO? (New York: Basic Books) 1984.
Lee, J.R., "So Called Profit Sharing System in the Ford Plant," Annals of
the American Academy of Political and Social Science, May 1916,
pp. 297—310.
Lloyd, C. and B. Niemi, THE ECONOMICS OF SEX DIFFERENTIALS (New York: Columbia
University Press, 1979.
Medoff, J.L. and K.G. Abraham, "Are Those Paid More Really More Productive?
The Case of Experience," Journal of Human Resources 16, 2
(Spring 1981), 186-216.
Nevins, Alan, FORD, THE TIMES, THE MAN, THE COMPANY (New York: Charles
Scribner Sons) 1984.
Weitzmari, M., THE SHARE ECONOMY (Boston: Harvard University Press) 1984.