Module 2-3
Module 2-3
pens, razors and lighters can share much of its competences in making
and selling light, cheap, disposable consumer products across these
different product lines. We shall look at the potential gains from sharing
resources between value chains further in Module 5.
Timing. Being first-in to the market can give the entrant or innovator
certain cost advantages. For example, there may be network effects that
lead to decreased cost per user as the system grows and it may be
difficult or impractical for an entrant to duplicate or replicate (e.g.
railways). At the same time, there may be second-in benefits from
waiting and learning from others’ costly mistakes. We shall look at these
issues further in the context of innovation in Module 3.
Location. Different locations may have different resource costs. Land,
labour and capital costs may differ from region to region and country
to country. There may be advantages in locating all or part of the value
chain in areas where a major resource is relatively cheap (e.g. labour-
intensive processes to low-wage countries). The danger is that this may
geographically fragment the value chain and make it difficult to co-
ordinate its various pieces.
Institutional factors such as government regulation, taxation and
subsidies. Background institutional factors may also affect the cost
base of the firm; for example, many governments provide attractive
fiscal packages to attract inward investment. Conversely, other policies
may have an adverse effect on the cost base of the firm; for example,
the UK government’s decision to tax fuel heavily for environmental
reasons in the late-nineties had an adverse effect on many UK firms’
distribution costs.
Discretionary policies. This is really a catch-all category reflecting the
firm’s choice of strategy and how it may impact on its costs. For
example, some PC manufacturers such as Dell sell computers direct
rather than go through retailers and so cut out the middle man (see
3 Competitive Strategy Edinburgh Business School
Study by Lamyaa
Competitive Strategy Professor Neil Kay
low, the other firm would be best leaving this segment of the market to
the cost leader and pricing high (50 pay-off for the other firm versus 30 if
it tried to match the cost leader’s low price).
However, look at the pay-offs for the cost leader. If the other firm priced
low, the cost leader would be better off matching this strategy (pay-off 120
versus 80 if it raised price). But if the other firm priced high, the cost leader
would still be better off setting a low price (pay-off 140 versus 100). The
crucial thing here is that the cost leader’s best strategy is to keep price low
whatever the other firm does. As we saw in Module 1, this can be termed a
dominant strategy for the cost leader, that is it represents the best choice for
the firm no matter what the competing firm does.
The important consideration for the other firm is that no matter what it
does, its rival (the cost leader) will keep prices low. So that means that the
bottom row of pay-offs (associated with the high price option for the cost
leader) is irrelevant in its calculation. This leaves the top row in which the
other firm can choose to match the cost leader’s low price (pay-off of 30),
or go upmarket (and achieve a pay-off of 50). Clearly the other firm would
be better off going upmarket and pricing accordingly, leaving the cost
leader with the larger share of the pay-offs.
However, it is critical here that not only does the cost leader know that
its dominant strategy is to price low, the other firm must be fully aware
that this is the cost leader’s dominant strategy. If the other firm
(mistakenly) suspected that it could somehow squeeze the cost leader out
of this strategy and undercut it, then a costly price war could ensue with
both firms finishing worse off than would have been the case had the
other firm read the situation correctly. Ways that the cost leader may be
able to persuade the other firm that it would be a tactical mistake for it to
try to achieve cost leadership would be through credible commitments that
show it is irrevocably committed to this low-price strategy, irrespective of
what the other firm does. For example, it could close down its R&D team
except for those researchers working on process improvements, it could
6 Competitive Strategy Edinburgh Business School
Study by Lamyaa
Competitive Strategy Professor Neil Kay
standardise its production around one or two basic lines, it could move all
its production to a cheap low-cost location, and so on.
As we saw in Module 1, the ironic thing is that strategies that
demonstrably tie the firm’s hands and lock it into its preferred strategy
may help to reduce the chances of retaliation from competitors. These
rivals will perceive they have little or no chance of shifting the firm from
its strategy, and so they will have to plan around it. Just as an army may
credibly threaten its enemy that it intends to stand and fight by burning its
bridges (and destroying its escape route) behind it, so a firm may credibly
demonstrate its commitment to a cost strategy by eliminating the
alternatives to it. The important thing, of course, is not only to burn the
bridges but to make sure that the enemy can see them burning as well.
Similarly, if you have no choice but to fight your low-cost corner, it is
important that your rivals know this as well in case they indulge in a futile
price war.
Porter (1985, p. 118) summarises the major steps to be taken in undertaking
a strategic cost analysis of the value chain as follows:
1. Identify the value chain, and separate out and assign costs and assets
attributable to it.
2. Identify the relevant cost drivers and how they interact with each other.
3. Identify competitor value chains, costs, and sources of cost advantage. (This
should help test whether cost leadership is a viable strategy, or at least
whether there are further cost gains that the firm could seek out.)
4. Develop a strategy to reduce costs through cost drivers or by reconfiguring
value chain.
5. Guard against eroding differentiation.
6. Test for sustainability. (Can competitors replicate what you have done?)
A difficulty in carrying out the third step of the process is that rivals are
unlikely to open their books to you to help you work out their cost structure.
Further, even if you can observe that your competitors appear to be pushing
down their costs and prices, it may be difficult to identify the sources of these
7 Competitive Strategy Edinburgh Business School
Study by Lamyaa
Competitive Strategy Professor Neil Kay
cost gains. Many cost drivers, some of which are illustrated in Figure 2.7, tend
to be achieved over time and may be mutually reinforcing (X-efficiency in the
diagram below refers to the elimination of inefficient high-cost practices in the
firm). If cost per unit for a competitor falls, is it because of internal or external
economies, innovative improvements, learning curve gains or simply the
elimination of waste?
In practice, the firm may be able to find indirect methods of assessing its
competitors’ cost levels, e.g. market share, the size of its sales team, information
on the costs of publicly available inputs, and so on. At best, the firm may only
be able to get rough guides as to its competitors’ cost positions and how various
cost drivers contribute to the relative positioning of it and its rivals.
* External
* Economies economies
of scale £
£ * Innovation
AC ACx
1
AC
Q Q
ACx
AC/unit
AC
Q Q