CH 9 Part 2 Notes EC 113
CH 9 Part 2 Notes EC 113
How a Capital Crunch in the U.S. Caused a Credit Crunch in 2008 and 2009
It appears that the 2008-2009 credit crunch (a time when credit was hard to get) in the U.S.
was caused in part by a capital crunch, in which shortfalls of bank capital led to slower growth in
the U.S. economy. At the time, a major boom and bust in the U.S. housing market led to huge
losses for banks from their holdings of securities backed by residential mortgages.
These losses reduced bank capital and led to capital shortfalls: Banks had to either raise new
capital or restrict asset growth by cutting back on lending. Banks did try to raise new capital but
with the growing weakness of the economy, raising new capital was very hard so banks also
chose to tighten their lending standards and reduce lending. Both of these produced a weak U.S.
economy in 2008 and 2009.
2
The attempts of financial institutions to overcome adverse selection and moral hazard
problems help explain a number of principles for managing credit risk: (i) screening and
monitoring, (ii) establishment of long-term customer relationships, (iii) loan commitments, (iv)
collateral and compensating balance requirements, and (v) credit rationing.
Screening
Adverse selection in loan markets requires banks or lenders to screen out bad credit risks from
the good ones so that loans are profitable to them. To do this effectively, lenders must collect
reliable information from prospective borrowers. Effective screening and information collection
together from an important principle of credit risk management.
When you take out a car loan or a mortgage for a home, you will be asked to fill out forms
requiring you to spill out a lot of your private information to the bank or the lender.
You will be asked about your salary, bank accounts, assets (such as cars, stocks or insurance
policies), outstanding loans, credit card, loan or credit card record (payment histories,
bankruptcies, of any), work history and who your employers have been, criminal record, health
record, military service record. You will also likely to be asked about your age, marital status,
and number of children or dependents.
All of these information will be utilized by the lender to evaluate how good a credit risk you
are by calculating (in the U.S.) your credit score, a statistical measure derived from your answers
that predicts whether you are more or less likely to have problems paying your loan payments.
Deciding on whether you are a good or bad credit risk is not entirely scientific. Sometimes a
lender must also use judgment. E.g., the loan officer who decides on whether to grant you a loan
or not might talk to your employer(s) or the references you supplied. Or the loan officer could
also size you up by your looks (appearance) or demeanor.
The same process of screening and collecting information applies when it comes for the bank
to decide whether or not to grant a business loan (to a company or business). The lender collects
information about the company’s profits and losses (income), and about its assets and liabilities,
its likely future success or future plans, purpose of the loan, and the competition in the industry.
The loan officer might also visit the factory of the company to get a firsthand look at its
3
operations (or if it even has one). In short, whether it’s a personal or business loan, bankers or
lenders have to be nosy.
Specialization in Lending
Although puzzling, the fact is banks often specialize in lending to local firms or firms in
particular industries, such as energy or construction or mining (puzzling because this means
banks are not diversifying their loan portfolio, exposing themselves to more risk).
But in another sense, it also makes sense. By lending to local firms instead of faraway firms,
bank are better able (easier) to collect information, hence, better able to screen out bad credit
risks. Also, by concentrating their lending on firms in specific industries, banks become more
knowledgeable about these industries and are better able to predict which firms will make timely
payments on their loans.
In addition, provisions in the loan commitment agreement require that the firm continually
supply the bank with information about the firm’s income, asset and liability position, business
activities, and so on. A loan commitment arrangement is a powerful method for reducing the
bank’s costs for screening and information collection.
Credit Rationing
Credit rationing is another way for banks to deal with adverse selection and moral hazard.
Credit rationing is refusing to make loans even though borrowers are willing to pay the stated
interest rate or even a higher rate. Two forms of credit rationing: (i) when a lender refuses to
make a loan of any amount to the borrower even if the borrower is willing to pay a higher
interest rate; (ii) when a lender is willing to make a loan but restricts the size of the loan to less
than the borrower would like.
In the case of the first type of credit rationing or (i), why doesn’t the lender just make the loan
at a higher interest rate even if the potential borrower is a credit risk?
The answer is that adverse selection prevents this solution because it is precisely those firms
and individuals with the riskiest investment projects who would be applying and be willing to
pay the higher interest rate. The more likely outcome is that the borrower would not succeed and
the loan not repaid.
So charging a higher interest rate just makes adverse selection worse for the lender⎯that is, it
increases the likelihood that the lender is lending to a bad credit risk. The lender would therefore
not make any loans at a higher interest rate. Instead, it would engage in the first type of credit
rationing ((i) above) and would turn down loans.
When banks and other lending institutions grant loans to borrowers but not in amounts as large
as borrowers would want, banks may be said to engage in the second type of credit rationing ((ii)
above) to guard against moral hazard. If banks find it necessary to do this sometimes, it’s
because the larger the loan, the greater is the incentive of a borrower to engage in risky activities
that make it less likely for the loan to be repaid.
5
More borrowers are able to repay loans that are smaller in amounts than when they are larger.
Thus, it is no wonder that banks/lenders ration credit by providing borrowers with smaller loans
than they seek.
A total of $20M of the bank’s assets are rate-sensitive, with interest rates that change
frequently or at least once a year, while $80M of its assets are fixed-rate, with interest rates that
remain unchanged for a long period (over a year).
On the liabilities side, the bank has $50M of rate-sensitive liabilities and $50M of fixed-rate
liabilities.
Suppose that interest rates rise by 5 percentage points on average from $10 % to 15 %. The
income (cash inflow) on the assets increases by $1M (= 0.05 x $20M) while the payments on the
liabilities (cash outflow) increase by $2.5M (= 0.05 x $50M). Thus, the bank’s profits decline by
$1.5M (= $1M − $2.5M).
Conversely, if interest rates fall by 5 percentage points, the bank’s profits increase by $1.5M
(prove this to yourself). Conclusion: If a bank has more rate-sensitive liabilities than assets, a
rise in interest rates will reduce bank profits and a decline in interest rates will raise bank profits.
By multiplying the gap times the change in the interest rates, we can immediately obtain the
effect on bank profits. For example, when interest rates rise by 5 percentage points,
Clearly not all assets and liabilities in the fixed-rate category have the same maturity. One
refinement, the maturity bucket approach, is to measure the gap for several maturity subintervals
(called maturity buckets) so that effects of interest rate changes over a multiyear period can be
calculated. The second refinement, the
standardized gap analysis, accounts for the differing degrees of rate sensitivity for different rate-
sensitive assets and liabilities.
An alternative method for measuring interest-rate risk, called duration analysis, examines the
sensitivity of the market value of the banks total assets and liabilities to changes in interest rates.
It uses the weighted average duration of a financial institution’s assets and of its liabilities to see
how net worth responds to a change in interest rates. (Duration measures the average lifetime of
a security’s stream of payments (how long before the loans are paid off entirely.)
Suppose the average duration of a bank’s assets is 3 years (i.e., the average lifetime of the
stream of payments is 3 years), whereas the average duration of its liabilities is 2 years. Assume
that a bank has $100M of assets and, say, $90M of liabilities, so its bank capital is 10% of assets
(or 10M). With a 5-percentage point increase in interest rates, the market value of the bank’s
assets falls by 15% (= − 5% x 3 years) (the loans become less valuable if sold in the market after
the drop in interest rates). That is a decline of $15M on assets of $100M. However, the market
value of liabilities falls by 10% (= − 5% x 2 years), a decline of $9M on the $90M of liabilities
(securities like bonds drop in price with a rise in interest rates).
The net result is that the net worth (the market value of assets minus the liabilities) has
decreased by $6M, or 6% of the total original asset. Similarly, a 5-percentage point decline in
interest rates increases the net worth by 6% of the total value.
Both duration analysis and gap analysis indicate that the bank will suffer if interest rates rise
but will gain if interest rates fall. To lower interest rate risk, (i) shorten the duration of assets,
and (ii) shorten the duration of liabilities. Thus, duration analysis and gap analysis are useful
tools for informing a bank manager of the institution’s degree of exposure to interest-rate risk.