Inflation, Financial Markets and Long-Run Real Activity: Elisabeth Huybens, Bruce D. Smith
Inflation, Financial Markets and Long-Run Real Activity: Elisabeth Huybens, Bruce D. Smith
Inflation, Financial Markets and Long-Run Real Activity: Elisabeth Huybens, Bruce D. Smith
Received 25 August 1997; received in revised form 5 March 1998; accepted 6 May 1998
Abstract
Empirical evidence suggests that real activity, the volume of bank lending activity, and
the volume of trading in equity markets are strongly positively correlated. At the same
time, inflation and financial market activity are strongly negatively correlated (in the long
run), as are inflation and the real rate of return on equity. Inflation and real activity are
also negatively correlated in the long run, particularly for economies with relatively high
rates of inflation. We present a monetary growth model in which banks and secondary
capital markets play a crucial allocative function. We show that — at least under certain
configurations of parameters — the predictions of the model are consistent with these and
several other observations about inflation, finance and long-run real activity. 1999
Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
Extensive empirical investigation has established the following facts about the
long-run relationships between inflation, financial market conditions, and real
activity.
0304-3932/99/$ — see front matter 1999 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 3 0 4 - 3 9 3 2 ( 9 8 ) 0 0 0 6 0 - 9
284 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
Barro (1995) asserts that there is evidence of a negative relationship at all rates of inflation.
Bruno and Easterly (1998) and Bullard and Keating (1995) find support for the notion that this
negative relationship emerges only when rates of inflation exceed some threshold. Levine and Renelt
(1992) and Clark (1997) also question whether there is a uniformly negative relationship between
inflation and real activity independently of the prevailing rate of inflation.
The importance of long gestation periods in capital production has been emphasized by authors
from Bohm-Bawerk (1891) to Kydland and Prescott (1982). The specific model we adopt resembles
Bencivenga et al. (1995, 1996) in the nature of the gestation lags in capital production.
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 285
Hicks (1969) identifies the central feature of the industrial revolution to be the employment of
large scale technologies requiring the provision of external finance for their operation.
286 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
or more steady state equilibria. These steady states are differentiated by their
capital stocks and levels of real activity, as well as by the level of activity in their
financial markets. In the low-capital-stock steady state agents will utilize either
the commonly available or the long-gestation capital production technology. In
the former case clearly no financial market activity is necessary. In the high-
capital-stock steady state, on the other hand, production of capital will occur
using the long-gestation technology; hence both intermediaries and equity
markets will be active. For this steady state, we are able to state conditions
under which higher steady state levels of real activity are associated with higher
volumes of both bank lending and equity market activity. We also state condi-
tions under which equity market activity rises relative to bank lending activity
as the steady state capital stock rises.
With respect to inflation, we show that higher rates of money creation (steady
state inflation) lead to lower levels of real activity, in the high-capital-stock
steady state. They also reduce the real return on all assets, including equity, and
higher money growth is (under conditions we state) detrimental both to bank
lending activity and to the volume of trading in equity markets. Moreover, it is
also possible to state conditions under which the negative relationship between
inflation and long-run real activity becomes more pronounced at higher rates of
inflation, as many have argued is true empirically.
Finally we spend some time analyzing the properties of equilibrium dynamics,
in a neighborhood of each steady state. We are able to show that the low-
capital-stock steady state is a saddle; hence there are always equilibrium paths
that approach it. In addition, we illustrate by example that the high-capital-
stock steady state may be either a source or a saddle. If it is a saddle, it too can
potentially be approached from some combination of initial conditions. Our
examples further demonstrate the possibility that the stability properties of the
high-capital-stock steady state depend upon the rate of money growth. As the
rate of money creation rises, it can transpire that the high activity steady state is
transformed from a saddle to a source. Hence it can no longer be approached,
and if the economy converges to a steady state, it must converge to the low
activity steady state. Consequently, for economies whose inflation rate exceeds
some critical level, the only ‘relevant’ steady state may be the low activity one.
Thus economies with high enough rates of inflation can display discretely lower
long-run levels of real and financial market activity than their low inflation
counterparts. Moreover, economies in low activity steady states (those with high
rates of inflation) will display a much different correlation pattern between
inflation and financial market conditions than will economies in high activity
steady states (those with lower rates of inflation).
Boyd and Smith (1998) and Huybens and Smith (1998) obtain some analytical results on this
point in much simpler, but related models.
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 287
What accounts for the existence of multiple steady states, and for the other
findings we have described? In this economy, a steady state equilibrium has the
property that the return on loans and the return on equity must equal the
prevailing real rate of return on money. This is given, in a steady state, by the
exogenously determined rate of money growth. In the presence of the CSV
problem, the return on loans depends on two factors: the marginal product of
capital, and the quantity of internal finance provided. Thus the required rate
of return on loans can be obtained either by having a relatively low stock of
capital, along with a relatively high marginal product of capital, a low level
of income, and a low level of internal finance; or by having a relatively high stock
of capital, a correspondingly high level of internal finance, but a low marginal
product of capital. These two methods of delivering a particular rate of return
typically yield two steady state equilibria. The high activity steady state will also
have a high level of internal finance, and the higher the steady state capital stock,
the higher will be the amount of internal finance provided.
If the steady state real return is lowered by an increase in the steady state rate
of inflation, in the high activity steady state the result is a decline in the quantity
of internal finance provided. This produces the required decline in the real
return on loans. It also exacerbates the severity of the CSV problem and leads to
more extensive rationing of credit. As a result, the capital stock falls. And, under
the conditions we describe, so does the volume of financial market activity. Thus
this model can potentially account for all of the observations cited above.
The paper proceeds as follows. Sections 1 and 2 describe the environment and
the nature of trade in the model. Section 3 analyzes steady state equilibria.
Section 4 discusses steady state financial market activity and its relation to
inflation. Section 5 briefly discusses local dynamics, while Section 6 concludes.
2. The model
Again we emphasize that this feature of the economy is not essential to our results. What is
necessary is that higher inflation lowers long-run real returns. Negative associations between
inflation and real returns on a variety of savings instruments are well-documented empirically.
The latter point was first made by Bernanke and Gertler (1989).
Hamid and Singh (1992) document that, as an empirical matter, countries with high income
levels also — on average — have high fractions of capital investments that are financed internally.
288 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
input, and ¸ denote the time t labor input of a representative firm. Then its final
R
output is F(K , ¸ ). We will assume that F is a CES production function with
R R
elasticity of substitution greater than 1, that is F(K, ¸),[aKM#b¸M]M, with
0(o(1. Thus F is increasing in each argument and strictly concave. In
addition, if k,K/¸ is the capital—labor ratio, and if f (k),F(k, 1)"
[akM#b]M is the intensive production function, then f '0'f holds ∀k, and
in addition lim f (k)"R.
I
Agents are assumed to care only about old age consumption and, in addition,
all agents are risk neutral. Thus all young period income is saved.
There are potentially three assets in our economy, money and investments in
the two different technologies for converting final goods into capital. The two
capital production technologies are indexed by j"1,2. Technology j"1 is
a simple capital production technology: one unit of the final good invested at
t returns R '0 units of capital at t#1. Technology j"2 is a more complic-
ated capital production technology, which has the following properties. First,
only a fraction d3(0, 1) of the population — which we will call potential
borrowers — has access to this technology. The remaining fraction (1!d) of the
population — which we will call lenders — does not have access to the complic-
ated capital production technology. Second, the technology is indivisible: each
potential borrower has one investment project which can only be operated at
the scale q. Third, when this technology is utilized, two periods are needed to
obtain mature capital. Fourth, the return on investments in technology 2 is
random. More specifically, then, q'0 units of the final good invested in
technology 2 at t yield zq units of capital in progress (CIP) at t#1, and R zq
units of capital at t#2. The random variable z is iid (across borrowers and
periods), and is realized at t#1. We let G denote the probability distribution of
z, and assume that G has a differentiable density function g with support [0,zN ].
Let zL be the expected value of z. Finally, we assume that this technology is
subject to a standard CSV problem of the type introduced by Townsend (1979):
only the project owner can costlessly observe z, while any agent other than the
project owner can observe z only by bearing a fixed cost of c'0 units of capital
in progress (CIP).
Capital produced by the simple investment technology is a perfect substitute
for capital produced in the alternative fashion. Moreover, we assume that the
capital stock depreciates completely after being used in production.
With respect to endowments, all young agents are endowed with one unit of
labor, which is supplied inelastically, and agents are retired when old. Indi-
viduals other than the old of period zero have no endowment of capital or final
That is, in verifying the project return, c units of CIP are used up. This assumption is responsible
for the simple form assumed by the expected return to lenders under credit rationing (see
Eq. (15)).
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 289
goods, while the initial old agents have an aggregate capital endowment of
K '0, and an aggregate endowment of capital in progress, CIP '0.
3. Trade
We assume that capital and labor are traded in competitive markets at each
date. Then, letting w denote the time t real wage rate and o the time t capital
R R
rental rate, the standard factor pricing relationships obtain:
o "f (k ), (1)
R R
w "f (k )!k f (k ),w(k ). (2)
R R R R R
Clearly w(k)'0 holds.
All young agents at t supply one unit of labor inelastically, earning the real
wage rate w . However, we will assume that this young period income does not
R
suffice to run a capital production project of type j"2.
We thus abstract from stochastic state verification. In a similar context, Boyd and Smith (1994)
show that the welfare gains from stochastic monitoring are trivial when realistic parameter values
are assumed.
290 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
R
[R (z)b !u c]g(z)dz#x b g(z)dz5r b .
R R R> R R
R
R R
(4)
u
R>
c
R
g(z)dz.
As a result, intermediaries need not be monitored by their depositors. See Krasa and Villamil
(1992) for a consideration of intermediaries that cannot perfectly diversify risk.
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 291
u zq
x 4inf R> . (7)
R b
X R
o
R
Eqs. (6) and (7) state that repayments never exceed the real value of the CIP
yielded by an investment project, which in state z is u zq at t#1.
R>
Borrowers announce contract terms in order to maximize their own expected
utility subject to the constraints (4)-(7). Therefore, announced loan contracts at
date t will be selected to maximize
u
R>
zL q!b
R
R
R (z)g(z)dz!x b
R R R g(z)dz
R
Proposition 1. Suppose q'b . ¹hen the optimal contractual loan terms satisfy
R
u zq
R (z)" R> , z3A , (8)
R b R
R
xb
A " 0, R R , (9)
R (u q)
R>
u c
r" R (z)! R> g(z)dz#x g(z)dz. (10)
R R b R
R R R
For future reference, substituting Eqs. (8) and (9) into Eq. (10) yields
u c
R (z)! R> g(z)dz#x g(z)dz
R b R
R R R
u c xb u q VR@RSR>O
"x ! R> G R R ! R> G(z)dz
R b (u q) b
R R> R
b
,n x ; R "r . (11)
R u R
R>
The function n gives the expected return to a lender as a function of the gross
loan rate, x , the amount of external finance required, b , and the future relative
R R
price of CIP, u .
R>
It will be useful in what follows to put some additional structure on the
function n. In particular, we will assume the following.
b
Assumption 3. n 0, R '0.
u
R>
Assumption 2 implies that n (0. Assumptions 2 and 3 imply that the
function n has the configuration depicted in Fig. 1. Evidently, given b /u ,
R R>
there is a unique value of x which maximizes the expected return that can be
R
offered. We denote this value by xL (b /u ), where the function xL is defined
R R>
implicitly by
b b c b b b b
n xL R ; R ,1! g xL R R !G xL R R
u u q u (u q) u (u q)
R> R> R> R> R> R>
,0. (12)
b b
xL R R ,g, (13)
u (u q)
R> R>
where g'0 is a constant satisfying 1!(c/q)g(g)!G(g),0. When all potential
borrowers offer the interest rate xL (b /u ), project return verification occurs iff
R R>
z3[0,g).
A well known feature of the environment just described — which was originally
noted by Gale and Hellwig (1985) and Williamson (1986, 1987) — is that it
permits the existence of unfulfilled demand for credit. In particular, if all
borrowers desire to operate their projects at date t, the total (per capita) demand
for funds is dq. The total per capita supply of saving is w(k ) at t. Therefore credit
R
demand must exceed credit supply, and hence credit must be rationed, if the
following assumption holds for all t50.
Assumption 4. dq'w(k ).
R
When credit rationing exists, however, it also must be the case that
b
x "xL R . (14)
R u
R>
Eq. (14) asserts that all potential borrowers are offering the interest rate that
maximizes a prospective lender’s expected rate of return. As a result, rationed
(unfunded) potential borrowers cannot obtain credit simply by offering an
alternative set of loan contract terms, since doing so reduces the expected return
perceived by (all) lenders. Thus if assumption 4 and Eq. (14) hold at date t, credit
rationing is an equilibrium outcome. We focus here on economies where credit is
rationed at all dates.
When credit is rationed, the probability that any project will have to be monitored, ex post, is
simply G(g). Thus the monitoring probability — and, by implication, the probability of bankruptcy
— is independent of any endogenous variables. The result is a substantial technical simplification, as
is illustrated by the relatively simple expression in Eq. (15) describing the expected return received by
a lender.
Of course credit rationing is clearly a widespread phenomenon in developing countries (Mc-
Kinnon, 1973), and there is substantial evidence of significant rationing of credit even in the
United States (Japelli, 1990). Therefore this does not seem to be an empirically unreasonable
assumption.
294 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
b b
r "n xL R ; R
R u u
R> R>
u q b b c b b
, R> xL R R ! G xL R R
b u (u q) q u (u q)
R R> R> R> R>
VL @RSR>O u q c E
! G(z)dz , R> g! G(g)! G(z)dz . (15)
b q
R
In particular, the return on savings between t and t#1 is proportional to the
ratio u /b when credit rationing obtains.
R> R
It is also possible to show that the expected utility of a funded borrower at
t under credit rationing is given by
b b
u zL q!r b !u cG xL R R
R> R R R> u (u q)
R> R>
c
,u q zL ! G(g) !r b .
R> q R R
Since any potential borrower could always forego investing in his project and
deposit his income in a bank instead, all potential borrowers can guarantee
themselves the utility level r w . Thus (potential) borrowers wish to operate their
R R
projects (under credit rationing) iff
c
u q zL ! G(g) !r b 5r w . (16)
R> q R R R R
We now define
c
,zL ! G(g),
q
(17)
c E
t,q g! G(g)! G(z)dz .
q
The parameter
is the expected project yield per unit invested, net of CIP
consumed by monitoring, under credit rationing. The parameter t determines
the expected return on deposits under credit rationing, since
u u
r "t R>,t R> . (18)
R b [q!w(k )]
R R
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 295
3.4. Money
The initial old at time zero are endowed with the initial per capita money
supply M 50. Thereafter, the money supply grows at the constant (gross)
\
rate p51, which the government selects once and for all at t"0. Therefore
M "pM , t5!1. (22)
R> R
We let the government have an endogenous real expenditure level of g (per
R
capita) at time t. The government budget constraint implies that
M !M
g" R R\. (23)
R p
R
Letting m ,M /p denote the per capita stock of real balances, Eqs. (22) and
R R R
(23) imply that
p!1
g" m.
R p R
The analysis would be unaltered if monetary injections ocurred via lump-sum transfers to old
lenders.
296 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
4.1. Steady state equilibria when the production technology j"1 is utilized
When the economy produces only type j"1 capital, an equilibrium in which
capital investments coexist with money at all dates must satisfy the no-arbitrage
condition
p
R f (k )" R , t50. (24)
R> p
R>
By definition,
p m M m
R , R> R , R>, (25)
p m M pm
R> R R> R
so that Eq. (24) can be rewritten to yield
m
R f (k )" R> , t50. (26)
R> (pm )
R
In addition, ‘sources’ and ‘uses’ of funds must be equal in equilibrium. If we let
i denote the per capita quantity of resources invested in capital production at t,
R
then an equality between sources and uses of funds requires that
w(k )"i #m , t50,
R R R
since young agents save all of their wage income. Of course,
k "R i , t50,
R> R
and therefore
k
m "w(k )! R>, t50. (27)
R R R
In steady state, Eqs. (26) and (27) reduce to
1
R f (k)" , (28)
p
k
m"w(k)! . (29)
R
Given our assumptions on the production technology f, it is clear that a unique
monetary steady state k exists when the economy produces only type j"1
Q
capital.
4.2. Steady state equilibria when the production technology j"2 is utilized
When the economy produces only type j"2 capital, an equilibrium in which
money is valued, and in which loans to capital producers are made at all dates
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 297
m k
m "w(k )!k pf (k ) R ! R>, t50. (36)
R R R> R> m R
R>
For an economy which produces only type j"2 capital, Eqs. (33) and (36)
describe the evolution of any equilibrium sequences +k , m , when credit is
R R
298 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
R tf (k) 1
" "r, (37)
[q!w(k)] p
k
m"w(k)!kpf (k)! . (38)
R
We now define the function H(k) by
f (k)
H(k), . (39)
[q!w(k)]
Then, in a steady state equilibrium where only type j"2 capital is produced, the
per capita capital stock satisfies the following condition:
1
H(k)" . (40)
R tp
It will clearly be necessary to establish some properties of the function H.
These are stated in Lemma 1.
Lemma 1 implies that the function H has the configuration depicted in Fig. 2,
and it is clear from this picture and Eq. (40) that there are potentially two steady
states, k and k , when the economy produces only type j"2 capital.
A A
Fig. 2. The steady state capital stock with long gestation investments.
Proposition 2. In a steady state equilibrium, type j"2 capital will be produced iff
R t
f (k)[q!w(k)]( .
(R )
The proof of Proposition 2 is presented in Appendix B.
Case 1. k(f \(q). This is the situation depicted in Fig. 3. For case 1, the
following proposition is immediate from an examination of Fig. 3.
300 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
Proposition 3. (a) Suppose that (R tp)\'H[ f \(q)]. ¹hen there are exactly
two steady state values of k, denoted by k and k in Fig. 3. If R f (k)41/p, then
solution to
k satisfies Eq. (28). If R f (k)'1/p, then k is given by the smallest
Eq. (40). In each case k is the largest solution to Eq. (40). (b) Suppose that
(R tp)\(H[ f\(q)]. ¹hen there is no monetary steady state with credit
rationing.
Fig. 4 depicts the consequences (for the steady state capital stock) of an
increase in the rate of money creation, when case 1 obtains. As is apparent from
the figure, an increase in the money growth rate (the steady state inflation rate),
increases the steady state capital stock in the low-capital stock steady state, but
decreases the steady state capital stock in the high-capital-stock steady state.
The relationship between the rate of money creation and the steady state capital
stock for case 1 is presented in Fig. 5.
Case 2. k'f \(q). This is the situation depicted in Fig. 6. For case 2, the
following proposition can be deduced from that figure.
Proposition 4. (a) Suppose that 1/p'R f ( k). ¹hen there are exactly two steady
state values of k, denoted by k and k in Fig. 6. ¹he value k satisfies Eq. (28)
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 301
while k is the largest solution of Eq. (40). (b) Suppose that 1/p(R f (k). ¹hen
there is no monetary steady state with credit rationing.
The result of increasing the money growth rate (the steady state inflation rate)
is depicted in Fig. 7. As in case 1, an increase in the rate of money creation
increases the steady state capital stock in the low-capital stock steady state, but
decreases the steady state capital stock in the high-capital-stock steady state.
The relationship between the rate of money creation and the steady state capital
stock for case 2 is presented in Fig. 8.
It remains to state conditions under which the steady state level of real
balances is positive. For steady states with the type 1 capital production
technology in use, our assumptions on f (k) imply that real balances are necessar-
ily positive - in the steady state — if R w(k)'k is satisfied. For steady state
technology is utilized, real
equilibria where the type 2 capital production
balances will be positive necessarily if w(k )!pk f (k )'k /(
R ) holds.
Moreover, for steady states determined by Eq. (40) it is necessary to verify that
(i) credit is rationed, and (ii) borrowers prefer to borrow rather than lend. The
former condition will be satisfied if k (
R dq holds, while the latter will be
satisfied if
[q!w(k )]5t obtains.
302 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
Fig. 5. The relationship between the money growth rate and the steady state capital stock — Case 1.
From this initial analysis it is clear that our economy is capable of reproduc-
ing several of the empirical facts laid out in the introduction. First, the high-
capital-stock steady state displays a negative relationship between inflation and
real activity (see point 1 of the introduction). Moreover, in case 1 it is easy to
verify that this relationship becomes more pronounced at high rates of inflation.
Second, as is apparent from Eq. (37), the real return on equity holdings, r, is
negatively related to inflation (see point 4 of the introduction). Indeed, the real
return on equity falls one-for-one with increases in the inflation rate. This is
consistent with the large empirical literature that finds an essentially zero
correlation between inflation and nominal equity returns (Nelson, 1976; Fama
and Schwert, 1977; Gultekin, 1983; Boyd et al., 1996). And finally, a high level of
real activity is associated with a high level of internal project finance, as is true
empirically (Hamid and Singh, 1992).
What is the economic intuition behind these results? An increase in the money
growth rate, ceteris paribus, reduces the steady state return on money. Hence,
for money and other assets to be held simultaneously, the return on these assets
has to decrease as well. For steady states in which all capital is produced using
technology 1, and which therefore satisfy Eq. (28), this implies an increase in the
steady state capital stock. For steady states in which all capital is produced
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 303
using technology 2, and which thus satisfy Eq. (40), the decrease in the return on
money likewise has to be accompanied by a decrease in the return on loans, as
well as a decrease in the return to equity holdings. Given the presence of the
CSV problem, the consequences of this observation depend on the nature of the
steady state equilibrium that obtains. In the low-capital-stock steady state,
a decrease in the rate of return on money implies an increase in the steady state
capital stock. When the capital stock increases, the level of internal finance of
investment projects rises as well, which by itself tends to mitigate the CSV
problem and increase the return on loans. However, on the downward sloping
portion of the function H(k), the higher level of internal finance fails to compen-
sate for the reduction in the marginal product of capital. Hence an increase in
the per capita capital stock leads to the required fall in the rates of return on
loans and equity holdings. In the high-capital-stock steady state the same two
effects are at work. However, on the upward sloping portion of H(k), the
consequences of a change in the level of internal finance dominate the conse-
quences of a change in the marginal product of capital. Therefore a higher
steady state rate of inflation leads to a fall in the steady state capital stock. The
implied reduction in the provision of internal finance more than offsets the effect
of the increase in the marginal product of capital, and again the rate of return on
loans and equity falls in the necessary way.
304 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
Fig. 8. The relationship between the money growth rate and the steady state capital stock — Case 2.
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 305
represents the real value of CIP sold in secondary capital markets relative to the
size of the economy, that is
dkqu
E(k), .
f (k)
In effect, then, the function E(k) represents the ratio of the total value of trading
in secondary capital markets to GDP, for each possible value of the capital
stock consistent with technology 2 being in use. Since in steady state,
kf (k) 1
E(k)" (k). (41)
f (k) R t
In addition, we introduce a measure of bank lending activity, B, which repres-
ents the real value of intermediated lending relative to the size of the economy for
each value of the capital stock consistent with technology 2 being in use. B is
given by
dk[q!w(k)]
B(k), .
f(k)
Of course d is the fraction of potential borrowers in the population, of whom
a fraction k actually receive credit, while each funded borrower receives a loan of
q!w(k). Hence per capita bank lending is given by dk[q!w(k)], and B(k)
expresses the volume of bank lending to the private sector relative to GDP. An
alternative expression for B(k) is obtained by noting that dk"k/(R
q), so that
kf (k) 1
B(k)" . (42)
R
qf(k) H(k)
Finally, we introduce a measure of the relative importance of equity market
versus banking activity,
E(k) R H(k)
EB(k)" "
q . (43)
B(k) t
We can now state the following proposition.
We now present some examples which illustrate the effect of an increase in the
steady state rate of inflation on the steady state levels of output, equity market
activity, bank lending activity and on the relative importance of equity markets
versus intermediated lending. Our examples set f (k)"(0.1025k
#1.5),
q"3, g(z)"1/zN with zN "33.33, c"75.49, R "10, R "1, and in addition
d'0.99 holds. For these parameter values,
"10.5 and t"3. Moreover,
k"5.42, while f \(q)"5.12, so that case 2 obtains.
Example 1. For p"1.25, the low-capital-stock steady state is k "4.89 and the
high-capital-stock steady state is k "8.94. For the high-capital-stock steady state,
E"0.212, B"0.02525, and EB"8.4.
Example 2. For p"1.26, the low-capital-stock steady state is k "4.99 and the
high-capital-stock steady state is k "8.55. For the high-capital-stock steady state,
E"0.209, B"0.02517, and EB"8.3.
So, as the rate of money creation and the steady state rate of inflation increase
from 25% to 26%, real activity in the low-capital-stock steady state increases,
while output in the high-capital-stock steady state decreases. As real activity in
the high-capital-stock steady state decreases, so does the level of equity market
and bank lending activity. At the same time, the importance of equity market
activity relative to bank lending activity decreases as well.
6. Local dynamics
k "y , (44)
R> R
308 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
and
m "z . (45)
R> R
Then Eq. (36) can be written as
m
y "R
w(k )!y Rpf (y )!m , (46)
R> R Rz R R
R
while Eq. (33) becomes
m
f R
w(k )!y Rpf (y )!m
R Rz R R
z "R tpm R , t50. (47)
R> R [q!w(k )]
R
We now linearize the dynamical system consisting of Eqs. (44)—(47) in a neigh-
borhood of (any) steady state equilibrium (k, m, y, z). Then we have
(k !k, m !m, y !y, z !z)
R> R> R> R>
"J(k !k, m !m, y !y, z !z),
R R R R
where J is the Jacobian matrix
*k *k *k *k
R> R> R> R>
*k *m *y *z
R R R R
*m *m *m *m
R> R> R> R>
*k *m *y *z
J" R R R R ,
*y *y *y *y
R> R> R> R>
*k *m *y *z
R R R R
*z *z *z *z
R> R> R> R>
*k *m *y *z
R R R R
with all partial derivatives evaluated at the appropriate steady state. Expres-
sions for these derivatives are given in Appendix D.
The characteristic equation for J takes the form
*y *z *z *y
j R>!j R>!j ! R> R>
*y *z *y *z
R R R R
*y *z *z *y
!j R> R>! R> R>!j
*m *y *m *y
R R R R
*y *z *z *y
#j R> R>!j ! R> R>
*k *z *k *z
R R R R
*y *z *z *y
# R> R>! R> R>"0. (48)
*k *m *k *m
R R R R
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 309
Example 4. For p"1.30, the low-capital-stock steady state has k "5.36 and the
high-capital-stock steady state has k "6.34. For the high-capital-stock steady
state, E"0.19, B"0.02363, and EB"8.07. Moreover, at the high-capital-stock
steady state, j "!1.81, j "!1.14, and mod(j )"mod(j )"1.01, so the
steady state is a source.
Thus, for this set of examples, low rates of money growth result in a deter-
minate steady state. In particular, there exists a unique dynamical equilib-
rium path that approaches the high activity steady state. However, as the
money growth rate (and the steady state rate of inflation) increase, the economy
crosses a ‘threshold’ and the high-capital-stock steady state becomes a
source. The equilibrium behavior of the economy must change dramatically,
and if the economy approaches any steady state, that must obviously be
the low-capital-stock steady state. Then not only will real activity be low,
but so will financial market activity. Moreover, further increases in inflation —
at least in a case 2 economy — can have no incremental effects on the
volume of financial market activity. These predictions of the model are
quite consistent with a number of the empirical findings noted in the
introduction.
In addition, as Example 3 illustrates, dynamical equilibrium paths approach-
ing the high activity steady state can easily display endogenously arising volatil-
ity that dampens only very slowly. This is not possible here unless banks and
secondary capital markets are active. Thus, as argued by Keynes (1936) and
Friedman (1960) — and many others — the operation of the financial system can
readily give rise to endogenous fluctuations along perfect foresight equilibrium
paths.
310 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
7. Conclusions
Type j"2 capital will be produced in steady state iff the internal rate of
return on investments in technology 2 exceeds that on investments in technology
1. From Eqs. (28) and (37), this condition obtains iff
f (k)
R t 'R f (k). (B.1)
[q!w(k)]
Rearranging terms in Eq. (B.1) establishes the result.
312 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
The elements of the Jacobian matrix are given by the following expressions:
*k
R>"0, (D.1)
*k
R
*k
R>"0, (D.2)
*m
R
*k
R>"1, (D.3)
*y
R
*k
R>"0, (D.4)
*z
R
*m
R>"0, (D.5)
*k
R
*m
R>"0, (D.6)
*m
R
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 313
*m
R>"0, (D.7)
*y
R
*m
R>"1, (D.8)
*z
R
*y
R>"R
w(k), (D.9)
*k
R
*y kf (k)
R>"!R
1#p , (D.10)
*m m
R
*y
R>"R
p[w(k)!f (k)], (D.11)
*y
R
*y kf (k)
R>"R
p , (D.12)
*z m
R
*z w(k) 1
R>"m #R
f (k) , (D.13)
*k f (k) R tp
R
*z w(k) kf (k)
R>"1#R
m 1#p , (D.14)
*m kf (k) m
R
*z w(k)
R>"!R
pmf (k) 1! , (D.15)
*y f (k)
R
*z
R>"!R
pw(k). (D.16)
*z
R
References
Atje, R., Jovanovic, B., 1993. Stock markets and development. European Economic Review 37,
632—640.
Azariadis, C., 1993. Intertemporal Macroeconomics. Blackwell, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Barro, R.J., 1995. Inflation and economic growth. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 35, 166—176.
Bencivenga, V., Smith, B.D., Starr, R., 1995. Transactions costs, technological choice, and endogen-
ous growth. Journal of Economic Theory 67, 153—177.
Bencivenga, V., Smith, B.D., Starr, R., 1996. Liquidity of secondary capital markets, allocative
efficiency, and the maturity composition of the capital stock. Economic Theory 7, 19—50.
Bernanke, B.S., Gertler, M., 1989. Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations. American
Economic Review 79, 14—31.
Bohm-Bawerk, E., 1891. A Positive Theory of Capital. MacMillan, London.
Boyd, J.H., Levine, R., Smith, B.D., 1996. Inflation and financial market performance. Manuscript,
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
Boyd, J.H., Smith, B.D., 1994. How good are standard debt contracts?: Stochastic versus non-
stochastic monitoring in a costly state verification environment. Journal of Business 67, 539—561.
314 E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315
Boyd, J.H., Smith, B.D., 1998. Capital market imperfections in a monetary growth model. Economic
Theory 11, 241—273.
Bruno, M., Easterly, W., 1998. Inflation crises and long-run growth. Journal of Monetary Econ-
omics, forthcoming.
Bullard, J., Keating, J., 1995. The long-run relationship between inflation and output in post-war
economies. Journal of Monetary Economics 36, 477—496.
Champ, B., Smith, B.D., Williamson, S.D., 1996. Currency elasticity and banking panics: Theory and
evidence. Canadian Journal of Economics 29, 828—864.
Clark, T.E., 1997. Cross-country evidence on long-run growth and inflation. Economic Inquiry 35,
70—81.
Diamond, D., 1984. Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Economic
Studies 51, 393—414.
Diamond, P.A., 1965. National debt in a neoclassical growth model. American Economic Review 55,
1126—1150.
Fama, E., Schwert, G., 1977. Asset returns and inflation. Journal of Financial Economics 5,
115—146.
Friedman, M., 1960. A Program for Monetary Stability. Fordham University Press, New York.
Gale, D., Hellwig, M., 1985. Incentive-compatible debt contracts: The one-period problem. Review
of Economic Studies 52, 647—663.
Gurley, J.G., Shaw, E., 1960. Money in a Theory of Finance. The Brookings Institution, Washing-
ton, DC.
Gultekin, N., 1983. Stock market returns and inflation: Evidence from other countries. Journal of
Finance 38, 49-65.
Hamid, J., Singh, A., 1992. Corporate financial structures in developing countries. International
Finance Corporation, Technical Paper 1.
Hicks, J., 1969. A Theory of Economic History. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Huybens, E., Smith, B.D., 1998. Financial market frictions, monetary policy and capital accumula-
tion in a small open economy. Journal of Economic Theory 81, 353—400.
Japelli, T., 1990. Who is credit-constrained in the US economy?. Quarterly Journal of Economics
105, 219—234.
Keynes, J.M., 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. MacMillan, London.
Krasa, S., Villamil, A.P., 1992. Monitoring the monitor: an incentive structure for a financial
intermediary. Journal of Economic Theory 57, 197—221.
King, R.G., Levine, R., 1993a. Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 108, 717-738.
King, R.G., Levine, R., 1993b. Finance, entrepreneurship and growth: Theory and evidence. Journal
of Monetary Economics 32, 513-542.
Kydland, F., Prescott, E., 1982. Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50,
1345—1370.
Levine, R., 1997. Financial development and economic growth: Views and agenda. Journal of
Economic Literature 35, 688—726.
Levine, R., Renelt, D., 1992. A sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth regessions. American
Economic Review, 82, 942—963.
Levine, R., Zervos, S., 1998 Stock markets, banks and economic growth. American Economic
Review, forthcoming.
McKinnon, R.I., 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development. The Brookings Institution,
Washington, DC.
Nelson, C., 1976. Inflation and rates of return on common stocks. Journal of Finance 31, 471-483.
Schreft, S.L., Smith, B.D., 1997. Money, banking, and capital formation. Journal of Economic
Theory 73, 157—182.
Tirole, J., 1985. Asset bubbles and overlapping generations. Econometrica 53, 1071—1100.
E. Huybens, B.D. Smith / Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1999) 283–315 315
Townsend, R.M., 1979. Optimal contracts and competitive markets with costly state verification.
Journal of Economic Theory 21, 265—293.
Williamson, S.D., 1986. Costly monitoring, financial intermediation, and equilibrium credit
rationing. Journal of Monetary Economics 18, 159—179.
Williamson, S.D., 1987. Costly monitoring, loan contracts, and equilibrium credit rationing. Quar-
terly Journal of Economics 102, 135—145.