Classical Theory of Income and Employment
Classical Theory of Income and Employment
Classical Theory of Income and Employment
The lower the wage rate, the more the workers will be employed. This is
why it is downward sloping. The supply curve of labour is upward sloping
for obvious reasons. The higher the wage rate, the greater the supply of
labour.
Model
Fig. 1 shows the labour market situation. The equilibrium wage rate (W0) is
determined by the demand for and the supply of labour. The level of employ-
ment is OL0. The lower graph shows the relation between total output and the
quantity of the variable factor (labour).
The graph actually shows the short-run production function which may be ex-
pressed as Q =f (KL), where Q is output, K is the fixed quantity of capital and L
is the variable factor labour. Total output is OQ0 when OL0 units of labour are
employed.
According to classical economists this equilibrium level of employment is the
‘full employment’ level. So, the existence of unemployed workers was a logical
impossibility. Any unemployment which existed at the equilibrium wage rate
(OW0) was attributable to frictions or restrictive practices in the economy or
was voluntary in nature.
The classical economists assumed flexibility of wages and prices (or of real
wages). They believed that if the wage rate was flexible a competitive economy
would always be able to maintain full employment. In other words, aggregate
demand would be sufficient to absorb the full capacity output OQ1.
In fact, “whatever the full employment level of output, the income created in
producing it will necessarily lead to spending which will be sufficient to
purchase the goods produced”. In other words, the classical economists denied
the possibility of under-spending or overproduction. True enough, the classicists
had faith in Say’s Law, named after the French economist J. B. Say (1767-
1832).
Say’s Law. Say’s Law is the simple notion that the supply of goods and services
creates its own demand, i.e., the very act of producing goods and services
generates an amount of income equal to the value of the goods produced. That
is, the production of any good would automatically provide the wherewithal to
take the output off the market.
The essence of the Law—that supply creates its own demand—can be
envisaged most easily in terms of a simple barter economy. A farmer, for
example, produces or supplies wheat as a means of buying (or demanding) the
shoes, shirts and other things produced by shoe-makers and craftsmen. The
farmer’s supply of wheat is equivalent to his demand for other goods.
This is true for other producers and for the whole economy. Demand must be
the same as supply. In fact, the circular flow model of the economy and national
accounting both suggest this sort of relationship. For instance, “the income
generated from the production of any level of total output would, when spent,
be just sufficient to provide a matching demand”.
Say’s Law is equally applicable in a modern economy which uses money as a
medium of exchange and store of value. Here any excess supply of money
possessed by an individual implies excess demand for goods and vice versa. So,
for the economy to be in equilibrium the sum of the excess supply functions
must be zero.
If the composition of output is in accord with the tastes and preferences of
consumers, all markets would be cleared of their outputs. Thus all that
businessmen need to do to sell a full-employment output is to produce that
output; “Say’s Law guarantees that there will be sufficient consumption
spending for its successful disposal”.
Saving, Investment and the Rate of Interest:
There is, of course, a serious omission in Say’s Law. If the recipients of income
in this simple model save a portion of their income, consumption expenditure
will fall short of total output and supply would no longer create its own demand.
Consequently, there would be unsold goods, falling prices, cutbacks in produc-
tion, unemployment and falling incomes.
However, the classical economists ruled out this possibility by suggesting that
saving would not really in a deficiency of total demand, because each and every
rupee saved would be automatically invested by business firms. That is,
investment would occur to fill any consumption ‘gap’ caused by saving leakage.
In fact, businessmen produce not only consumption goods for sale to
households but investment (capital) goods for sale to other firms (or to one
another). The latter constitute a considerable portion of society’s total output. In
other words, investment spending by business will add to the income-
expenditure stream.
This may fill any consumption gap arising from saving. Thus, if private
business firms as a group intend to invest as much as households want to save,
Say’s Law will hold and the levels of national income and employment will
remain constant.
To illustrate Say’s law consider Fig. 2. It shows a simplified version of the
circular flow of income diagram. There are only two sectors—households and
private business firms. Households receive income exactly equal to the value of
goods and services produced.
Part of this income is spent on consumption goods, the balance is saved. Thus
consumption demand falls short of the total value of production (GNP) by the
amount of saving, which is made up by demand for capital goods (i.e.,
investment demand). Thus so long as investment and saving are equal,
aggregate demand (i.e., consumption demand plus investment demand) will
always be equal to the total value of production.
Thus, “weather or not the economy could achieve and sustain a level of
spending sufficient to provide a full-employment level of output and income
therefore would depend upon whether businesses were willing to invest enough
to offset the amount households want to save”.
According to Keynes’ own theory of income and employment: "In the short
period, level of national income and so of employment is determined by
aggregate demand and aggregate supply in the country. The equilibrium of
national income occurs where aggregate demand is equal to aggregate supply.
This equilibrium is also called effective demand point".
Effective demand
Effective demand represents that aggregate demand or total spending
(consumption expenditure and investment expenditure) which matches with
aggregate supply (national income at factor cost).
Effective demand is the equilibrium between aggregate demand (C+I) and
aggregate supply (C+S).
This equilibrium position (effective demand) indicates that the entrepreneurs
neither have a tendency to increase production nor a tendency to decrease
production.
It implies that the national income and employment which correspond to the
effective demand are equilibrium levels of national income and employment.
Unlike classical theory of income and employment, Keynesian theory of income
and employment emphasizes that the equilibrium level of employment would
not necessarily be full employment. It can be below or above the level of full
employment.
Determinants of Income:
The determinants of effective demand and so of equilibrium level of national
income and employment are the aggregate demand and aggregate supply.
(1) Aggregate Demand (C+l):
Aggregate demand refers to the sum of expenditure households, firms
and the government is undertaking on consumption and investment in an
economy.
The aggregate demand price is the amount of money which the
entrepreneurs actually expect to receive as a result of the sale of output
produced by the employment of certain number of workers.
Determinants of Income:
In other words, the aggregate supply is the value of final output valued at
factor cost.
The aggregate supply price is the minimum amount of money which the
entrepreneurs must expect to receive to cover the costs of output
produced by the employment of certain number of workers.
Determinants of Income:
Explanation
In the above figure , the aggregate demand curve (C+l), intersects the
aggregate supply curve (OS) at point E1 which is an effective demand
point. At point E1 , the equilibrium of national income is OY1 .
Let us assume that in the generation of OY1 level of income, some of the
workers willing to work have not been absorbed. It means that E1
(effective demand point) is an under employment equilibrium and OY1 is
under employment level of income.