Elizabeth Cooke - Modern Studies in Property Law-Hart Publishing (2003)
Elizabeth Cooke - Modern Studies in Property Law-Hart Publishing (2003)
Elizabeth Cooke - Modern Studies in Property Law-Hart Publishing (2003)
Patron
Lord Nicholls of Birkenhead
Board of Advisers
Lord Millett
Mr Justice Neuberger
Judge Paul Baker, QC
G Abbott (Clifford Chance)
Professor W Cornish
Dr S Cretney
S Fogel (Dechert)
Professor M Grant
C Harpum
PD Orchard Lisle, CBE TD
T Symes (Mills Group)
CJ West (The Solicitor to HM Land Registry)
D Wright (Nabarro Nathanson)
Emeritus Director
Professor Paul Jackson
Executive Committee
Mrs EJ Cooke (Director)
Ms BSL Crabb
Mrs SE Murdoch
Modern Studies in Property Law
Volume II
Property 2002
Edited by
ELIZABETH COOKE
Reader in Law
University of Reading
The contributors severally have asserted their rights under the Copyright,
Designs and Patents Act 1988, to be identified as the authors of this work
I. International developments
1. The Diversification of Land Rights and its Implications for a
New Land Law in South Africa 3
Hanri Mostert
2. Protecting Social Participation Rights Within The
Property Paradigm: A Critical Reappraisal 27
Andre Van der Walt
3. Fiducia in an Emerging Economy 43
Piotr Stec
4. The Autonomous Meaning of ‘Possessions’ under the European
Convention on Human Rights 57
Tom Allen
III. Equity
7. Mortgages and Undue Influence 123
Mark Thompson
8. Estoppel and Restitution: Drawing a Divide 145
Nicholas Hopkins
9. Proprietary Estoppel and Formalities in Land Law and the Land
Registration Act 2002 165
Martin Dixon
viii Contents
GERMANY
HONG KONG
INDIA
IRELAND
MALAYSIA
Adorna Properties Sdn Bhd v Boonsom Boonyanit @Sun Yon Eng [2001]
1 MLJ 241................................................................................................92
Bhagwan Singh & Co Sdn Bhd v Hock Hin Bros Sdn Bhd [1987]
1 MLJ 324................................................................................................83
NEW ZEALAND
POLAND
SOUTH AFRICA
SWITZERLAND
UNITED KINGDOM
ZIMBABWE
Pt IV ..........................................................................................................241
Agricultural Holdings Act 1996 ..................................................................169
Agricultural Tenancies Act 1995..........................................................238, 245
s 1(4) ......................................................................................................238
s 3 ..........................................................................................................238
s 4(1)(f) ..................................................................................................245
Agriculture Act 1947 ..................................................................................319
Agriculture Act 1986 .................................................................................3171
Charter of the Forest 1217 ..........................................................................294
Charter of the Forest 1225 ..........................................................................294
Children Act 1989..........................................................................249, 251–52
s 1(3)(a) ..................................................................................................249
s 17 ........................................................................................................252
(1).....................................................................................................251
(10)...................................................................................................251
(a)–(c).........................................................................................251
s 20(1) ....................................................................................................251
(3) ....................................................................................................251
s 23B(8)(b)..............................................................................................252
s 27 ...................................................................................................251–52
Sched 1, para 1 .......................................................................................251
Children (Leaving Care) Act 2000 .........................................................251–52
Commonhold and Leasehold Reform Act 2002
(CLRA).........................................................268, 275–76, 278–79, 281–83
s 121.......................................................................................................280
s 138 .................................................................................................275–76
s 151 .................................................................................................278–79
s 155.......................................................................................................279
ss 159–60 ................................................................................................279
s 169.......................................................................................................279
Pt 2 ........................................................................................................268
Commons Agreement 1964.........................................................................290
Companies Act 1985 ..................................................................................184
s 182(1) ..................................................................................................183
s 183(1) ..................................................................................................183
s 184.......................................................................................................185
s 185(1) ..................................................................................................184
s 186(1)(a) ..............................................................................................184
s 188(1)–(2).............................................................................................183
s 212.......................................................................................................184
Companies Act 1989
s 207 .................................................................................................183–84
Compulsory Purchase Act 1965 ..................................................................342
Contract (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999 ................................................233
Table of Statutes xxvii
s 1 ..........................................................................................................234
Countryside Act 1968.................................................................................314
s 13 ........................................................................................................314
s 23 ........................................................................................................303
s 28 ........................................................................................................299
s 37 ........................................................................................................314
s 38 ........................................................................................................314
Countryside and Rights of Way Act 2000....................................................315
Crown Estate Act 1961
s 1(3) ......................................................................................................323
Dartmoor Commons Act 1986....................................................................324
Deer Removal Act 1851.......................................................................289, 296
Electronic Communications Act 2000 .........................................................169
s 8 ..........................................................................................................169
Environment Act 1995 ................................................................312, 314, 3172
s 5 ..........................................................................................................313
s 62 ..........................................................................................312, 318, 321
ss 63–64..................................................................................................312
s 66 ........................................................................................................314
s 69(2)(a) ................................................................................................317
Pt III.......................................................................................................315
Sched 9...................................................................................................315
Factors Act 1889
s 2 ............................................................................................................86
Family Law Reform Act 1969
s 1 ..........................................................................................................249
Family Law (Scotland) Act 1985
s 9(1)(b)..................................................................................................390
Fatal Accidents Act 1976
s 1(3) ......................................................................................................220
Finance Act 1985..........................................................................................64
Finance Act 1991 ....................................................................................64–65
Finance Act (No 2) Act 1992 ........................................................................64
Forestry Act 1945
s 4(5) ......................................................................................................288
Forestry Act 1967
s 1(2) ......................................................................................................325
(3A) .......................................................................................................325
s 47(3) ....................................................................................................304
Forestry (Transfer of Woods) Act 1923.......................................................288
Homelessness Act 2002 ..................................................................251, 253–54
Housing Act 1974.......................................................................................270
s 118(2) ..................................................................................................270
Housing Act 1985 ........................................................................256, 261, 272
xxviii Table of Statutes
Ground 16 .................................................................................................261
s 79 ........................................................................................................261
s 81 .................................................................................................256, 262
s 83 ........................................................................................................261
s 87 ........................................................................................................256
s 89 ........................................................................................................261
(2) ....................................................................................................256
s 91 .................................................................................................251, 262
ss 92–93..................................................................................................262
ss 102–3..................................................................................................261
s 105.......................................................................................................263
s 106A ....................................................................................................263
ss 118–19 ................................................................................................262
s 136.......................................................................................................262
s 157(1) ..................................................................................................315
Sched 2...................................................................................................261
Housing Act 1988.......................................................................................261
s 34(1) ....................................................................................................240
s 36 ........................................................................................................240
(2) ....................................................................................................240
(b) ................................................................................................240
(3) ....................................................................................................240
Housing Act 1996 (HA 1996) ..................................................252–53, 267, 271
s 83 ........................................................................................................278
s 106.......................................................................................................271
s 124.......................................................................................................260
s 125(2) ..................................................................................................260
s 128.......................................................................................................260
s 161.......................................................................................................253
s 182(1) ..................................................................................................253
s 184.......................................................................................................254
s 189(1) ..................................................................................................254
Pt VI .................................................................................................251–52
Pt VII ..............................................................................................251, 254
Housing Grants, Construction and Regeneration Act 1996
s 107.......................................................................................................168
Housing (Scotland) Act 1987 ......................................................................255
s 19(1) ....................................................................................................254
Housing (Scotland) Act 2001 ......................................................................254
s 9 ..........................................................................................................254
Human Fertilisation and Embryology Act 1990
ss 27–28..................................................................................................221
Human Rights Act 1998 ......................................................................263, 340
s 6(1) ......................................................................................................263
Table of Statutes xxix
(3) ...................................................................................................263
Inclosure Act 1808......................................................................................295
Inheritance (Family Provision) Act 1938 .....................................................204
Inheritance (Family Provision) Act (NI) 1960 ..............................................204
Inheritance (Provision for Family and Dependants) Act 1975
s 1(ba) ....................................................................................................220
(1A) ...................................................................................................220
Inheritance (Provision for Family and Dependants) Act (NI) 1979 ...............225
Insolvency Act 1986
s 239.......................................................................................................194
(4)(b) ..............................................................................................195
s 284.......................................................................................................115
(1)...................................................................................................115
Judicature Act 1873....................................................................................230
Land Charges Act 1972 .........................................................................87, 115
Land Clauses Consolidation Act 1845.........................................................331
ss 127–32 ................................................................................................331
Land Compensation Act 1961.....................................................................342
Land Compensation Act 1973.....................................................................342
Land Registration Act 1925 (LRA 1925)..................................81–82, 88, 90, 95
s 20(1).................................................................................................88, 90
(4) ......................................................................................................90
s 23(1).................................................................................................88, 90
(5) ......................................................................................................90
s 54(1) ......................................................................................................94
s 56(4) ......................................................................................................95
s 70(1)(f) ..................................................................................................89
(g) .......................................................................89, 99, 165, 171, 249
s 82(3)(a) ............................................................................................93, 99
(b)..................................................................................................99
s 102(2) ....................................................................................................95
s 144A .............................................................................................169, 172
Land Registration Act 2002 (LRA 2002).......................vi, 81, 89, 96, 98, 101–2,
106–7, 110, 112–17, 165–67, 169, 171, 174, 180–81
ss 11–12 ...................................................................................................88
s 23............................................................................103–4, 106, 108–9, 113
(1) ....................................................................................................103
(a) ................................................................................................103
(b) ................................................................................................104
(2) ....................................................................................................104
(a)–(b) ..........................................................................................104
(3) ....................................................................................................104
(a)–(b) ..........................................................................................104
s 24 ..........................................................................................103–4, 108–9
xxx Table of Statutes
(1) ....................................................................................................104
(a)–(b) ..........................................................................................104
s 25..............................................................................................103–4, 114
(1)–(2) ..............................................................................................104
s 26...................................................................................90, 101–8, 110–18
(1)........................................................................................103, 107–19
(2)........................................................................103, 105, 107, 113, 115
(a) ................................................................................................113
(b) ...................................................................................104, 114–15
(3) ................................................................103, 107–8, 110–11, 115–19
s 27 ......................................................................................94, 115–16, 118
(1) .............................................................................................114, 169
(2) ....................................................................................................114
(5) ....................................................................................................116
s 28 .................................................................................88, 90, 96, 105, 118
s 29 ....................................................................88, 90, 105, 114–15, 117–18
(1) ....................................................................................................116
(2)(a)(i) .......................................................................................96, 114
(iii)...........................................................................................106
(4) .............................................................................................114, 116
s 30..........................................................................88, 90, 105, 114–15, 118
(1) ....................................................................................................116
(2)(a)(i)...............................................................................................96
s 31 .................................................................................................105, 118
s 32 ........................................................................................................114
(3) ......................................................................................................96
s 38 ........................................................................................................116
s 40 ..........................................................................................................94
s 41 ...................................................................................................94, 114
s 42 ..........................................................................................................94
(1)(a) ................................................................................................114
(b) ................................................................................................106
s 43 ..........................................................................................................94
(1) ....................................................................................................114
(3)(c) ................................................................................................114
s 44 ..........................................................................................................94
s 45 ..........................................................................................................94
(3) ....................................................................................................114
(c) ................................................................................................114
s 46 ..........................................................................................................94
s 52..........................................................................103–4, 106, 108, 117–18
(1)–(2) ..............................................................................................103
s 58 ...................................................................................................88, 118
(2) ....................................................................................................116
Table of Statutes xxxi
s 71(b) ....................................................................................................116
s 86 ........................................................................................................115
(4) ....................................................................................................115
(5) ...............................................................................................115–16
(a)–(b) ..........................................................................................115
(c) ................................................................................................115
(i)–(ii) .......................................................................................115
(7) ....................................................................................................116
s 91............................................................................................169, 171–75
(3) ....................................................................................................169
s 93...........................................................................................114, 169–753
(2) ....................................................................................................169
s 96(3) ....................................................................................................116
s 103 ........................................................................................................92
s 106(3)(a) ..............................................................................................116
s 116 ..........................................................................106, 165, 171, 174, 383
s 129 .................................................................................................115–17
(1)...................................................................................................116
s 131 ........................................................................................................92
(2)(b) ................................................................................................92
Pt 3 .................................................................................................103, 105
Pt 4 ...................................................................................................113–14
Sched 1 ........................................................................................88, 170–71
Sched 2...................................................................................................116
Sched 3 ........................................................................................88, 170–71
cl 2...........................................................................................................89
para 2 .................................................................................................105–7
Sched 4
cl 2 .......................................................................................................92
cl 3 .......................................................................................................92
(2)(a) ..............................................................................................93
Sched 8
cl 1(a) ...................................................................................................92
Sched 12
para 7 ...................................................................................................89
para 11 .................................................................................................89
Land Registration Act (NI) Act 1970
s 47 ........................................................................................................207
Sched 5, Pt 1, para 15 ...................................................................................89
Land Registry Act 1862 ................................................................................84
Preamble .....................................................................................................84
Landlord and Tenant Act 1927 ...................................................................268
s 19(1)(a) ................................................................................................241
Landlord and Tenant Act 1954 ...................................................................245
xxxii Table of Statutes
s 38(1) ....................................................................................................245
Pt I .........................................................................................................268
Pt II........................................................................................................245
Landlord and Tenant Act 1985 (LTA 1985)....................................267, 277–78
s 11 ........................................................................................................263
s 18 ........................................................................................................268
s 19............................................................................................268, 277–79
(2B) ..................................................................................................278
s 20............................................................................................268, 278–79
(1)(b)................................................................................................278
ss 21–24 ..........................................................................................268, 277
ss 25–27..................................................................................................268
s 27A......................................................................................................279
(1)–(2) ............................................................................................279
ss 28–30..................................................................................................268
s 31C......................................................................................................278
Landlord and Tenant Act 1987 (LTA 1987) ................................................267
s 42 ........................................................................................................267
Pt II........................................................................................................279
Pts III–IV................................................................................................267
Pt VI ......................................................................................................267
Landlord and Tenant (Covenants) Act 1995 ...................................244–45, 268
s 3 ..........................................................................................................245
s 5 ..........................................................................................................245
s 16 ........................................................................................................245
Law of Property Act 1925 (LPA)..........................................................116, 256
s 1(6) ......................................................................................................256
s 2 ...................................................................................................106, 117
(1)(iii) ................................................................................................111
s 27 ........................................................................................................106
s 52 ........................................................................................................170
(1) ....................................................................................................257
s 53 ..........................................................................................168, 172, 175
(2) ....................................................................................................172
s 54(2) .............................................................................................170, 257
s 104(2) ..................................................................................................118
s 205(1)(ii) ..............................................................................................116
Law of Property (Miscellaneous Provisions) Act 1989
(LPA 1989) ......................................................................166, 168, 174–75
s 1 ..........................................................................................................168
s 2 ...............................................................................166, 168, 171–75, 179
(5) ..............................................................................................172, 174
s 2A ...........................................................................................169, 171–73
Law Reform (Succession) Act 1995 .............................................................204
Table of Statutes xxxiii
s 16 ........................................................................................................317
s 39 ........................................................................................................317
s 64 ........................................................................................................317
ss 76–77..................................................................................................320
s 101 ...............................................................................................318, 323
(3)...................................................................................................323
s 103.......................................................................................................320
National Parks (Scotland) Act 2000 ............................................................312
s 1 ..........................................................................................................313
ss 9–10 ...................................................................................................312
s 11 ........................................................................................................314
s 14 ........................................................................................................318
s 15 ........................................................................................................317
Scheds 2–3..............................................................................................312
National Trust Act 1907
s 4(1) ......................................................................................................320
(2) ......................................................................................................321
Negotiable Instruments Act 1881..................................................................86
New Forest Act 1877 ..........................................287, 290, 293, 296, 301, 303–4
s 1 ..........................................................................................................297
(2) ......................................................................................................304
ss 2–3 .....................................................................................................297
ss 5–7 .....................................................................................................296
s 8 ..........................................................................................................297
s 9..............................................................................................290, 297–98
s 10(3) ....................................................................................................298
s 13 ........................................................................................................298
s 14 ........................................................................................................297
s 15 .................................................................................................297, 301
s 16 ...................................................................................................297–98
s 17 .................................................................................................297, 301
s 18 ...................................................................................................297–98
ss 19–22..................................................................................................297
s 23 .................................................................................................297, 302
(4)–(5) ..............................................................................................304
s 24 ........................................................................................................297
s 25 .................................................................................................297, 302
ss 33–36..................................................................................................304
New Forest Act 1879 ..................................................................................287
s 2 ..........................................................................................................289
New Forest Act 1949 ..........................................287, 289–90, 297–99, 301, 304
ss 1–3 .....................................................................................................301
s 4 ..........................................................................................................289
s 5 ..........................................................................................................301
Table of Statutes xxxv
s 7 ..........................................................................................................301
s 8 ..........................................................................................................304
s 9(1)(b)..................................................................................................290
(3)–(4)................................................................................................290
s 11 ........................................................................................................303
s 13 ........................................................................................................303
ss 14–15..................................................................................................302
ss 16–18..................................................................................................303
s 29 ........................................................................................................302
s 33(1) ....................................................................................................301
New Forest Act 1964 ..............................................................287–88, 290, 298
s 1 ..........................................................................................................288
s 2 ..........................................................................................................289
s 3 ..........................................................................................................288
s 5 ..........................................................................................................288
s 6 ...................................................................................................298, 303
s 7 ..........................................................................................................291
s 8 ..........................................................................................................302
s 10 ........................................................................................................303
s 15 ........................................................................................................303
s 19 ........................................................................................................303
New Forest Act 1970 ..............................................................287, 298–99, 303
s 1 ..........................................................................................................299
s 3 ..........................................................................................................302
s 11 ........................................................................................................298
s 14 ........................................................................................................298
New Forest (Sale of Land and Public Purposes) Act 1902 ............................303
Norfolk and Suffolk Broads Act 1988 .........................................................312
Northern Ireland Act 1998
s 75 .................................................................................................220, 223
Ordinance of 1305......................................................................................294
Ordinance of 1306......................................................................................294
Planning and Compensation Act 1991 ........................................................342
s 66 ........................................................................................................348
Rent Act 1968
s 18(5) ....................................................................................................102
Rent Act 1977 ............................................................................................240
Rent Acts............................................................................................240, 261
Rentcharges Act 1977 ...........................................................................273–74
s 2 ..........................................................................................................279
(4).................................................................................................273–74
(a)–(b) ............................................................................................273
(5) ......................................................................................................273
Sale of Goods Act 1979...........................................................86, 188, 193, 200
xxxvi Table of Statutes
s 3(3) ......................................................................................................259
s 16 .................................................................................................190, 195
s 18 rule 5 ...............................................................................................195
s 61(1) ....................................................................................................193
Sale of Goods (Amendment) Act 1995 ..........................................194–195, 200
Settled Land Acts 1882–1890 ......................................................................207
Settled Land Act 1925.................................................................................207
s 27 ........................................................................................................257
(1) ....................................................................................................256
Statute of 1293 ...........................................................................................294
Statute of 1327 ...........................................................................................294
Statute of 1383 ...........................................................................................294
Statute of Purveyors 1350 ...........................................................................294
Stock Transfer Act 1963........................................................................183–84
s 1(1) ......................................................................................................183
Sched 1...................................................................................................183
Stock Transfer Act 1982 .............................................................................183
Telecommunications Act 1984....................................................................316
Town and Country Planning Act 1947.................................................316, 326
Town and Country Planning Act 1990........................................................334
Trustee Act 2000 (TA 2000) .........................................................101, 110, 113
s 8 ..........................................................................................................109
Trusts of Land and Appointment of Trustees Act 1996
(TLATA/TOLATA)......................101, 109–11, 113, 123, 207, 256–58, 385
s 8 ..........................................................................................................111
ss 9–11 ...................................................................................................258
s 14 ........................................................................................................258
s 15(1) ....................................................................................................258
s 16 .................................................................................................101, 118
ss 19–20..................................................................................................258
Wild Creatures and Forest Laws Act 1971 ....................................290, 294, 304
s 1(2) ......................................................................................................301
(3)......................................................................................................290
Wildlife and Countryside Act 1981 (WLCA 1981) .......................................287
s 42 ........................................................................................................315
s 43 ........................................................................................................314
Wildlife and Countryside Act 1985 .............................................................287
Wildlife and Countryside (Amendment) Act 19854
s 4 ..........................................................................................................325
Wills Act 1837 ....................................................................................168, 173
Table of Statutes xxxvii
STATUTORY INSTRUMENTS
AUSTRIA
CANADA
EUROPEAN COMMUNITY
GERMANY
Basic Law...............................................................................................29, 72
Art 14 .................................................................................................71–73
Table of Foreign Enactments xli
(1)–(3) ............................................................................................71
(I)(1) ..............................................................................................71
(2) ..................................................................................................71
Civil Code..............................................................................................45, 73
s 905 ...................................................................................................72–73
Constitution ................................................................................................72
Federal Water Resources Act .......................................................................72
IRELAND
ITALY
NEW ZEALAND
POLAND
SOUTH AFRICA
Act 26 of 1998................................................................................................9
Black Administration Act 38 of 1927 ..............................................................6
Communal Property Associations Act 28 of 1996 (CPA).................9, 13, 15, 17
s 2..............................................................................................................9
ss 10–13 ...................................................................................................16
Constitution 1996 ........................................................................................10
s 25 ............................................................................................................7
(5)–(7)..................................................................................................7
s 26.....................................................................................................11, 36
s 28 ............................................................................................................7
s 33 ..........................................................................................................34
Conversion of Certain Rights into Leasehold or Ownership Act 81 of 1988
(CLOA)................................................................................................13
Deeds Registries Act 47 of 1937 (DRA) ............................................4–6, 14, 20
reg 44A ....................................................................................................20
s 3(1)(b) ...................................................................................................20
(o) .....................................................................................................5
(r)......................................................................................................5
s 4 ............................................................................................................20
s 6 ............................................................................................................14
s 13(1) ......................................................................................................20
s 14 ..........................................................................................................20
s 15A........................................................................................................20
s 16 ............................................................................................................4
s 18(1) ......................................................................................................20
s 63(1)........................................................................................................5
s 70(4) ......................................................................................................19
s 102 ........................................................................................................14
Development Facilitation Act 67 of 1995 (DFA) ........................9–10, 13–14, 18
s 1 ............................................................................................................14
s 2 ............................................................................................................10
s 3 ............................................................................................................10
(c)(viii) ................................................................................................10
Table of Foreign Enactments xliii
(g)(iv) ..................................................................................................10
ss 4–37 .....................................................................................................10
s 38.....................................................................................................10, 14
ss 39–60 ...................................................................................................10
s 61 ..........................................................................................................10
(7) ......................................................................................................14
s 62.....................................................................................................10, 14
(4) ......................................................................................................14
(5)(b)..................................................................................................14
(7) ......................................................................................................14
ss 63–66 ...................................................................................................10
s 68 ..........................................................................................................10
Chs I–VII .................................................................................................10
Extension of Security of Tenure Act 62 of 1997 (ESTA) ............9, 11, 13, 16–18
s 2 ............................................................................................................16
s 4(1)–(2)..................................................................................................16
Ch II............................................................................................................16
Group Areas Act 36 of 1966 ...........................................................................6
Housing Act 107 of 1997 (HA) .......................................................9–10, 17–18
s 2(1)(c)(i) ................................................................................................10
(d)....................................................................................................11
Interim Constitution 1994..............................................................................7
s 121–3.......................................................................................................7
Interim Protection of Informal Land Rights Act 31 of 1996 (IPILRA).......13, 16
Preamble .....................................................................................................16
Land Reform (Labour Tenants) Act 3 of 1996 (LTA) ................9, 11–13, 15–16
s 3(2)(a)–(d) .............................................................................................15
ss 5–8 .......................................................................................................15
s 9 ............................................................................................................15
(1)........................................................................................................15
ss 10–15 ...................................................................................................15
s 16 ..........................................................................................................12
(1)(a)–(d)............................................................................................12
ss 18–21 ...................................................................................................12
s 22 ..........................................................................................................12
(5) ......................................................................................................12
ss 23–24 ...................................................................................................12
Chs 2–3....................................................................................................15
Land Rights Act...........................................................................................21
Less Formal Township Establishment Act 112 of 1991 (LFTEA) .....................9
Chs 1–3......................................................................................................9
Prevention of Illegal Eviction from and Unlawful Occupation of Land
Act 19 of 1998 (PIE).........................................................................13, 16
s 4 ............................................................................................................16
xliv Table of Foreign Enactments
s 6 ............................................................................................................17
Proclamation succeeding the Regulations for the Administration and
Control of Townships in Black Areas R293 Government Gazette 373
of 1962–11–16 ........................................................................................6
Promotion of Administrative Justice Act 3 of 2000
s 1 ............................................................................................................34
s 3 ............................................................................................................34
(1)........................................................................................................34
Provision of Certain Land and Assistance Act 126 of 1993 (PCLAA)..........9–10
s 2 ............................................................................................................10
Restitution of Land Rights Act 22 of 1994 (RLRA) .....................................7–9
Preamble .......................................................................................................7
s 1..............................................................................................................8
s 35(2)(c)....................................................................................................8
(3)–(4) ..................................................................................................8
Share Blocks Control Act 59 of 1980 (SBCA) ...........................................23–24
s 7(1)–(2)..................................................................................................23
s 9(1)........................................................................................................23
Transformation of Certain Rural Areas Act (House of Representatives)
9 of 1987 (TCRAA)....................................................................11, 13, 18
s 1 ............................................................................................................11
s 3(4)(b) ...................................................................................................11
(5)–(7)..................................................................................................11
s 4(1)(a)–(g)..............................................................................................11
(2)........................................................................................................11
s 9(1)(a)....................................................................................................11
Upgrading of Land Tenure Rights Act 112 of 1991 (ULTRA)........................13
s 3 ............................................................................................................13
SWITZERLAND
Bill of Rights................................................................................................32
Constitution ................................................................................................30
Art IV, §3, cl 2 ........................................................................................326
Fifth Amendment ...................................................................................31–33
Fourteenth Amendment..........................................................................31–33
Due Process Clause ......................................................................................29
Immigration and Nationality Act .................................................................29
Table of Foreign Enactments xlv
HANRI MOSTERT*
INTRODUCTION
* BA LLB LLM LLD (University of Stellenbosch). Paper presented at the Fourth Biennial
Conference of the Centre for Property Law at the University of Reading, 25–6 March 2002. The
financial assistance of the National Research Foundation at the University of Stellenbosch is hereby
gratefully acknowledged. The opinions expressed in this paper should, however, not be attributed
to either of these institutions. Thank you to Juanita Pienaar, André van der Walt, Gerrit Pienaar,
Anne Pope and David Butler for discussing and criticising the ideas expressed here, and Melanie
Fourie, Chantal Steenkamp and Agatha Atkins for excellent research and technical assistance.
1 Cf Daily Mail & Guardian, eg samaYende, and Arenstein, ‘Rural Revolt Threat’ (15.02.2002);
Moore, ‘Space for Rural Development’ (08.02.2002); TAC Model for Land Campaign (14.12.2001);
Forrest, ‘Conflicts Triggered by Land Transfer to Chiefs’ (23.11.2001).
4 Hanri Mostert
The records of the South African deeds registry are renowned for their accuracy,
but are not regarded as absolutely correct or comprehensive. As such, South
African land registration can be classified neither as an out-and-out system of
title registration nor as an out-an-out system of deeds registration. Certain real
rights in land can come about without registration. For present purposes, the
important point is that registration brings to fruition the principle of publicity
underlying the law of property by providing some holders of land rights with the
necessary security of title to enable them to enforce and protect their rights
against the public at large. In South Africa, registration serves a dual function:
(i) it indicates the act of delivery in respect of derivative acquisition of immov-
ables; and (ii) it provides a public record of real rights in land.
Conveyancing embodies the legal-procedural aspect of registration and is
probably one of the most technical fields of law. This practical side of registra-
tion overshadows the policy choices underlying the existing system to such an
extent that the latter do not enjoy much attention in legal literature. However,
these policy choices are important for establishing a just land regime, and for
delivering upon political promises. The following paragraphs indicate the
importance of choices concerning models of property rights within which the
registration system functions. The need for reform, and the possible directions
of land law development will become apparent from the discussion.
Rights to immovable property are usually divided into registrable real rights, on
the one hand, and non-registrable forms of land tenure, such as personal rights
or statutory grants, on the other. Real rights in land comprise two broad
categories in traditional private law theory in South Africa, namely ownership and
limited real rights. Other forms of land tenure include rights based on contract or
tribal affiliations and rights emanating from statutory concessions or permits
granted by the state. The law secures the different land rights to varying extents.
Traditionally, ownership is described as the most complete right, and the
only real right that a person can hold with regard to her own property.1a Other
rights in property are usually limited in scope and/or time. The South African
system of registration endorses this categorisation. The Deeds Registries Act
provides that ownership in land must be conveyed from one person to another
by a process of publicising and recording the transfer at the deeds registry.2 The
most commonly used method of conveyancing is the execution of a deed of
1a
Van der Merwe, Sakereg (Butterworths, Durban, 1989) at 170–73.
2
Deeds Registries Act 47 of 1937 (abbreviated: DRA), s 16.
Diversification of Land Rights 5
transfer and attestation thereof by the registrar of deeds.3 The few existing alter-
natives4 to this method serve a whole range of exceptions to the norm, but are,
nevertheless, based on the idea that landownership, and some of the rights
deduced from it, deserve special protection in terms of the publicity principle
underlying property law.
Limited real rights are defined as rights to specified uses of property belong-
ing to another,5 which restrict the exercise of the ownership entitlements by the
owner thereof. These rights are, in terms of the existing system, the only other
kinds of rights capable of being registered. In very broad terms, the courts
interpret the statutory criteria6 for the registrability of rights as permitting reg-
istration if the right at stake constitutes a ‘subtraction from the dominium,’ in
the sense that the obligation correlative to the right binds not only the present
landowner, but also all her successors-in-title.7 Rights other than ownership are
not registrable if they merely place an obligation on a specific person,8 without
burdening the landowner in her capacity as landowner.9
The Deeds Registries Act’s registrability and transfer requirements clearly
support a so-called ‘hierarchy of rights’ within the South African legal frame-
work for land. The registrar of deeds is statutorily required to register servitudes
and real rights,10 but restrained from registering any personal right in respect of
immovable property or any condition that does not restrict the exercise of a
right of ownership.11 This exclusionary approach indicates support for the
notion that ownership is the pinnacle of—or the most important right within—
a hierarchy of rights. Other rights are understood as being in stages of inferior-
ity to ownership.12
For purposes of publicity of land use and control, ownership and limited real
rights rank higher than other rights, because they are registrable. Therefore,
they represent better, more secure forms of title, because they can be protected
by real remedies. Moreover, because of their publication through registration,
they are enforceable in many situations, against a multitude of persons. Within
3 Jones, Conveyancing in South Africa 4th ed by Nel (Juta, Kenwyn, 1991) at 91.
4 Eg transfer by operation of law, endorsement of the existing title deed, issuing of a substituted
deed of grant, or revival of an earlier deed. Jones, ibid at 92–4.
5 Van der Walt & Pienaar, Inleiding tot die Sakereg (Juta, Kenwyn, 1996) at 29.
6 See n 8 and 10 below.
7 Eg Odendaalsrus Gold, General Investments & Extensions Ltd v Registrar of Deeds 1953 (1)
SA 600 (O) at 609H–612A; Pearly Beach Trust v Registrar of Deeds 1990 (4) SA 614 (C) at
616A–618E.
8 DRA, s 63(1) does, however, provide for the registration of personal rights that are incidental
to real rights to be registered against the same title deed. Ex Parte Geldenhuys 1926 OPD 155 at
163–4.
9 The exact meaning of ‘subtraction from the dominium’ is still contentious in South African
law. See Lorentz v Melle 1978 (3) SA 1044 (T); Pearly Beach Trust v Registrar of Deeds, above n 7;
Van der Walt & Pienaar, above n 5, at 36–9.
10 DRA, ss 3(1)(o), (r).
11 DRA, s 63(1). See, however, n 8 above.
12 Pienaar, ‘The Registration of Fragmented Use—Rights as a Development Tool in Rural Areas’
Seminar Report 6 (2001) Constitution and Law IV (Konrad Adenauer Stiftung, Johannesburg, 2001)
at 109.
6 Hanri Mostert
this hierarchy model of landownership, rights other than ownership and regis-
trable limited real rights rank low, and accordingly do not enjoy the same kind
of publicity or protection.
The disadvantages of the hierarchy approach were aggravated by the land
control system under Apartheid. Black South Africans were precluded from
obtaining and holding rights in land, which were protected by the acclaimed
common law system of property and backed by the sophisticated and effective
registration system. Instead, a host of legislative and administrative measures
forced blacks to resort to forms of land control that were not recognised or
effectively protected. These included tribal land rights13 and statutory land
rights based on a variety of permits.14 The lack of effective protection and pub-
licity of these ‘lesser’ rights had some serious consequences: when placed in
opposition to the secure rights within the protective ambit of property law, these
insecure rights were not competitive and did not provide their holders with any
significant benefits. Even more importantly, these insecure rights could not be
used as collateral security to procure bonds or loans. In effect, these so-called
‘black’ land rights were ostracised from the markets and invisible within the
economic infrastructure.15
The Deeds Registries Act’s support of the supremacy of ownership within a
system of land rights (wittingly or unwittingly) perpetuated the differentiation
between ‘black’ and ‘white’ land control mechanisms. Moreover, structural
inequalities inherent in the hierarchical system of land rights were strengthened.
This renders a reconsideration of the policy choices underlying reform initia-
tives all the more urgent. The following section entails an analysis of the land
reform aspects influencing the significance of the existing registration system.
The legacy of the hierarchy model of property under apartheid leaves a number
of problems to be resolved. These include: (i) vulnerability to interference with
or confiscation of rights; (ii) difficulty in securing housing subsidies and
development finance; (iii) lack of administrative support for the operating
system of land rights in practice; and (iv) unscrupulous individuals exploiting
the lack of enforceable rights to bring others on land in exchange for money,
thereby bolstering their own personal and economic power.16 Summarised,
these issues all result from a lack of legal enforceability of certain land rights.
13 Van der Walt, ‘Property Rights and Hierarchies of Power: A Critical Evaluation of Land-
Reform Policy in South Africa’ Koers (Vol. 64, No. 2 & 3, 1999) 259 at 262.
14 Eg Group Areas Act 36 of 1966; Black Administration Act 38 of 1927; Proclamation succeed-
ing the Regulations for the Administration and Control of Townships in Black Areas R293
Government Gazette 373 of 1962–11–16.
15 Van der Walt, above n 13 at 262–3.
16 Pienaar, above n 12 at 108.
Diversification of Land Rights 7
Section 25 of the 1996 Constitution provides the mandate for reform. The
constitutional property clause protects not only landownership, but also other
rights in property. The state is furthermore obliged to secure other forms of land
tenure. Section 25 of the 1996 Constitution thus gives new momentum to the
land reform programme, which was launched even before the coming into
force of the Interim Constitution17 in 1994. Sections 25(5)–(7) of the 1996
Constitution oblige the national legislature to provide redress through legisla-
tive means for the discrimination of the past and to transform insecure tenure
into legally protected tenure. As such, the constitutional property guarantee
embodies an attempt to reverse the systematic process of erosion to which most
‘black’ land rights were subject during apartheid.18
In addition, the Department of Land Affairs, whose policy is set out in the
White Paper of 1997,19 has made the eradication of the distinction between
‘black’ and ‘white’ land rights one of their main objectives. The land reform
programme consists of three separate, but interconnected elements: (i) land
restitution; (ii) redistribution of land; and (iii) tenure reform. Each of these ele-
ments influences the development of South African property law, but for present
purposes the redistribution and tenure reform aspects are most important. By
enabling the provision of land on the one hand, and the upgrading of existing,
but insecure land rights on the other, these two elements will determine the
state’s ability to deliver on promises of access to land. The success of the land
reform programme will depend on the extent to which a departure from the
hierarchy-of-rights model of landownership can be effected. It is already clear
that a break with the hierarchy model is more easily achieved in some parts of
the reform programme than in others.20 The continued hegemony of the hierar-
chy model must be evaluated according to the three main elements of the land
reform programme. This is the purpose of the following paragraphs.
Land Restitution
The restitution part of the programme aims at redressing the wrongs caused by
forced removals, which occurred after 1913. It is therefore restricted in scope21
and duration.22 The Restitution of Land Rights Act23 is the legislative centre-
piece of the process. The Land Claims Court and Commission on the
Restitution of Land Rights operate to give effect to the provisions of this act.
The preamble of the act confirms the legislative aim to promote and protect the
Van der Merwe/Pienaar ‘Land Reform in South Africa’ in Jackson/Wilde (eds), Reform of Property
Law (Ashgate-Dartmouth, Hants, 1997) at 359.
20 Van der Walt, above n 13 at 259–94.
21 See Carey-Miller & Pope, Land Title in South Africa (Juta & Co, Kenwyn, 2000) at 320–6.
22 See Van der Walt, above n 13 at 270–1 n 16.
23 Act 22 of 1994 (abbreviated: RLRA).
8 Hanri Mostert
24
RLRA, s 1.
25
Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21 at 320.
26
Dulabh and Another v Department of Land Affairs 1997 (4) SA 1108 (LCC) par 25–31.
27
Chief Nchabeleng v Chief Phasha 1998 (3) SA 578 (LLC), par 27.
28
Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21 at 323.
29
Ibid at 323–5.
30
RLRA, s 35(4).
31
Van der Walt, above n 13 at 273.
32
RLRA, s 35(2)(c) read with s 35(3).
Diversification of Land Rights 9
new rights to be awarded, and ways in which to ensure that new rights form the
basis of legally protected access to and enjoyment of land. These issues are left
to the wider processes of redistribution and tenure reform.33 Moreover, the con-
ventional method of registration still represents the only34 manner in which
rights may be transferred back to successful claimants. Awards of rights not
qualifying for transfer by registration remain problematic. The Restitution Act
therefore does not explicitly break with the hierarchy model of rights and it is
difficult to envisage a system developing from the act that would place the rights
encompassed by it on equal footing with ownership. The negative implications
for security of title arising as a result are not always satisfactorily equalled out
by the other two elements of the reform programme.
Land Redistribution
Land redistribution is aimed at the needs of the poorest urban and rural
residents, labour tenants, farm workers as well as new entrants to agriculture,
by providing access to land for residential and agricultural purposes,35 thereby
rectifying some of the inequalities in the existing land distribution patterns.36
Legislative measures falling within the purview of land redistribution37 are pre-
sent in the Less Formal Township Establishment Act,38 the Provision of Certain
Land and Assistance Act,39 the Development Facilitation Act,40 the Housing
Act,41 the Land Reform (Labour Tenants) Act,42 and the Extension of Security
of Tenure Act.43 This aspect of the reform programme involves both agricul-
tural and urban residential land.
The Less Formal Township Establishment Act was introduced in 1991 to alle-
viate the housing shortage by expediting settlement in and establishment of ‘less
formal’ urban settlements,44 and by providing for settlement of ‘indigenous
tribes’ in ‘less formal’ rural settlements.45 ‘Less formal’ settlements are supposed
to be somewhat more formalised than ‘squatter camps’, without complying
with normal development requirements and building regulations. The act dealt
with land and land rights in ‘less formal settlements’ on the basis of the existing
33 Confirmed by Communal Property Associations Act, s 2. Van der Walt, above n 13 at 274.
34 See, however, mechanisms for dealing with community awards in terms of the Community
Property Associations Act.
35 Pienaar, ‘Land Reform’ in Badenhorst, Pienaar et. al. Silberberg & Schoeman’s Law of
private law of landownership.46 Litigation that ensued soon after its enactment
indicated the problems contained in attempting to pursue policies of land law
reform from within the existing land law framework, where the hegemony of
landownership continued to exist, uncontested.47
The Provision of Land and Assistance Act48 provides for the settlement of
people on land designated, developed and subdivided for that purpose. Read in
conjunction with the Development Facilitation Act,49 the Provision of Land Act
makes radical provision for registration, and eliminates most of the usual controls
over subdivision and planning.50 In principle, therefore, the act is aimed at bring-
ing landownership within the reach of a wider part of the general public,51 and
perpetuates the existing hierarchy model of land control as espoused by private
law. It nevertheless indicates that the existing framework can be adapted to some
extent, especially as far as registration is concerned, to expedite access to land.
The Development Facilitation Act is, inter alia, aimed at facilitating, simpli-
fying and expediting the delivery of housing to the rural and urban poor.52 The
act aims to integrate all development planning approaches and physical plan-
ning and to adopt a policy-driven approach, supported by the implementation
of procedural measures, to decision-making in the context of land reform and
development.53 Therefore, the act is described as a ‘uniform template’ designed
to achieve the constitutional objective of expediting delivery of land rights.54
Provisions relating to the act’s general principles and objectives indicate that it
does not promote alternative land rights, although much more infringements—
and also more severe infringements—on landownership are envisaged. The act
relies heavily on the process of registration to realise its objectives.
The Housing Act55 supports a wide choice of housing and tenure options. In
this context, security of tenure is important in view of the fundamental right to
46
Van der Walt, above n 13 at 276.
47 See Van der Walt, ‘Marginal Notes on Powerful(l) Legends: Critical Perspectives on Property
Theory’ (1995) THRHR 396 for a discussion of Diepsloot Residents’ and Landowners’ Association
v Administrator, Transvaal (1993) 1 SA 577 (T) per De Villiers J; (1993) 3 SA 49 (T) per McCreath
J; (1994) 3 SA 366 (A) per Smalberger JA.
48 PLAA, s 2.
49 DFA, s 68.
50 Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21 at 408.
51 Ibid at 405–11 and Van der Walt, above n 13 at 276–7.
52 DFA, ch IV. Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21 at 411–49 and Van der Walt, above n 13 at
277–8; Latsky ‘Development and Facilitation Act’ in Budlender, Latsky & Roux (eds) New Land
Law (Juta, Kenwyn, 1996), ch 2A.
53 Latsky, ibid at 2A–3. The DFA deals with the general principles relating to all land develop-
ment (ch I, ss 2–4) and land development objectives (ch IV, ss 27–9). It also provides for the estab-
lishment of a new infrastructure in the form of a commission (ch II, ss 5–14) and certain tribunals
(ch III, ss 15–26). It deals with land development procedures, sometimes excluding (ch V, ss 30–47)
and sometimes including, small-scale farming (ch V, ss 30–47; ch VI, ss 48–60) and land tenure mat-
ters (ch VII, ss 61–6). It contains conservation measures (s 3(c)(viii)) and a commitment to the fun-
damental rights set out in the Constitution (s 3 (g)(iv)). The continued operation of this act is
currently uncertain.
54 Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21 at 413.
55 HA, s 2(1)(c)(i).
Diversification of Land Rights 11
56 HA, s 2(1)(d).
57 Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21 at 449.
58 Rural Areas Act (House of Representatives) 9 of 1987.
59 TCRAA, s 9(1)(a).
60 TCRAA, s 3(4)(b) read with TCRAA, ss 1, 3(5), 3(6) and 3(7).
61 TCRAA, s 4(1)(a)–(g).
62 TCRAA, s 4(2).
63 See differing classifications of Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21 at 525; Van der Walt, above
land of which they are not the registered owners. The latter will be discussed
under the heading of tenure reform.
The redistributory aspect of the Labour Tenants Act appears mainly from the
provisions for acquisition of landownership64 or other rights in land65 by labour
tenants, and for financial assistance in this regard.66 It enables labour tenants to
purchase land, with the subsidy of the state,67 from the landowners for whom
they work, and extensively regulates the conditions in terms of which such a
forced sale by the landowner will be necessary,68 and the circumstances under
which the Land Claims Court may be requested to interfere in negotiations
between the parties.69
In the final analysis, most of the redistribution laws aim to expedite delivery
of land and access to land in residential and agricultural sectors, whilst keeping
the costs involved as low as possible. State intervention in the market process is
meant to alter the unequal distribution of land,70 and to introduce a flexible sys-
tem of land rights. In reality, however, most of the redistribution laws still ulti-
mately aim at providing new entrants into the land market with common-law
landownership, and at promoting the aspiration of these people to acquire
landownership as opposed to other secure rights in land.71 In as far as these laws
enable delivery on promises of access to land, they tend to maintain existing
hierarchies and structures of private law. Even in cases where ‘other’ rights in
land are mentioned (eg in the Labour Tenants Act), there is no real departure
from the classifications of private law. In spite of policies stated to the contrary,
the hierarchy model of land control is perpetuated. As far as publicity is con-
cerned, registration is still the most important method of obtaining land and
enforcing land rights. Protection of land rights still relies on the existence of a
trustworthy and accurate record of such rights in the deeds registry. Ultimately,
the publicising and recording of rights in this manner still ensure that they can
be used as security to obtain financial assistance, thus fully exploiting the eco-
nomic value of the land to generate more wealth. This inability to break with
the hierarchy model of land control, as supported by the existing registration
system, in effect stunts the successful implementation of the redistribution pro-
gramme.72
64
LTA, s 16(1)(a) and (b).
65
Eg servitudes of water, way or any other servitude reasonably necessary or reasonably consis-
tent with the rights previously enjoyed by the labour tenant. LTA, s 16(1)(c) and (d).
66 LTA, s 16. Advances and subsidies are made available under LTA, s 26.
67 White Paper above n 19 at par 4.5.9 and 4.7.
68 LTA, ss 18–24.
69 LTA, s 22(5).
70 Van der Walt, above n 13 at 281.
71 Ibid.
72 See Daily Mail & Guardian, Majola, ‘Highs and Lows of States Delivery’ (08.02.2002); Smith,
‘Civil Resistance is Building Again in South Africa’ (01.02.2002); Cousins, ‘A Return to the
Apartheid Era?’ (23.11.2001).
Diversification of Land Rights 13
Tenure Reform
Many forms of tenure do not provide sufficient security of title or are unsuitable
for the purpose they are supposed to serve because they do not provide access to
financing, or because they feature within a problematic tribal or group struc-
tures, possibly disadvantaging women or other land users.73 Land tenure reform
represents that particularly complex part of the reform process by which these
insecure tenure forms are strengthened and secured. It also concerns the pro-
curement of loans upon secure land rights, or any aspect of the tenure under
which land rights are held or exercised. In the context of tenure reform, the
Department of Land Affairs aims74 to move away from a permits-based system
to a rights-oriented system, to develop a unitary, non-racial system of land
rights, to accommodate individuals in tenure systems according to their cir-
cumstances and preferences, to adhere to the constitutional commitment to
human rights and equality, to adopt a rights-based approach to deliver security
of tenure, and to upgrade the land registration system to facilitate new forms of
tenure. Legislative measures falling within the purview of land tenure reform are
found in the Conversion of Certain Rights into Leasehold or Ownership Act,75
the Upgrading of Land Tenure Rights Act,76 the Development Facilitation Act,
the Land Reform (Labour Tenants) Act, the Extension of Security of Tenure
Act, the Communal Property Associations Act,77 the Interim Protection of
Informal Land Rights Act78 and the Prevention of Illegal Eviction from and
Unlawful Occupation of Land Act.79
The outgoing National Party government promulgated laws serving a tenure-
reform purpose by increasing the security of certain tenure arrangements
through a process of ‘upgrading’ insecure rights. The Conversion of Certain
Rights into Leasehold or Ownership Act provided for conversion of land per-
mits into leasehold and for the conversion of leasehold into ownership.80
Likewise, the Upgrading of Land Tenure Rights Act provided for the upgrading
of precarious rights (granted to non-whites during the apartheid regime)81 to
ownership.82 The policy behind these early tenure-reform laws still supports the
idea that accessing landownership is the ultimate goal of reform.
73
Van der Walt, above n 13 at 281–2.
74
White Paper above n 19, par 4.16.
75
Act 81 of 1988 (abbreviated: CLOA).
76
Act 112 of 1991 (abbreviated: ULTRA).
77
Act 28 of 1996 (abbreviated: CPA).
78
Act 31 of 1996 (abbreviated: IPILRA).
79
Act 19 of 1998 (abbreviated: PIE).
80
Du Plessis, Olivier & Pienaar ‘Land Reform Continues during 1997’ (1997) SAPR/PL 263; Van
der Walt, above n 13 at 282.
81
Eg permission to occupy and the right of occupation in terms of the Rural Areas Act 9 of 1987
(House of Representatives); ULTRA, s 3.
82
Mnisi v Chauke (1994) (4) SA 715 (T).
14 Hanri Mostert
and use land as owner; to acquire landownership under the Act; to encumber the initial ownership
by means of a mortgage or a personal servitude (but not the right otherwise to encumber or deal with
the initial ownership); and to sell the right of initial ownership.
87 DFA, s 38.
88 DFA, s 62(7).
89 DRA, s 102.
90 Van der Merwe & Pienaar, above n 19 at 370.
91 Contra Carey-Miller, ‘A New Property?’ (1999) SALJ 749 at 754.
92 All other real rights except mortgage bonds must be cancelled by a court order. DRA, s 6.
93 DFA, s 62(5)(b).
94 See Van der Walt, above n 13 at 283.
95 Ie peaceful and undisturbed occupation of land for a continuous period of not less than five
years. DFA, s 1.
Diversification of Land Rights 15
96
Carey-Miller, above n 91 at 757.
97
LTA mentions four possible circumstances under which the right of use and occupation is ter-
minated: (i) waiver, s 3(2)(a); (ii) death, s 3(2)(b); (iii) eviction in accordance with the act, s 3(2)(c);
or (iv) acquisition of ownership or compensation, s 3(2)(d). Eviction may only take place according
to the provisions of the act.
98
LTA, ss 5–15. Sometimes eviction is not possible at all. See LTA, s 9(1).
99
LTA, s 12.
100
LTA, s 8.
101
Van der Walt, above n 13 at 284.
16 Hanri Mostert
does not relate to agricultural land only. Pienaar, above n 35 at 22; Carey-Miller & Pope, above
n 21 at 493–5.
107 Van der Walt, above n 13 at 286.
108 Pienaar, above n 35 at 23.
109 ESTA, s 4(1) and (2).
110 Van der Walt, above n 13 at 287.
111 Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21 at 516 ff discuss the relationship between the Prevention of
and state organs.113 The intention of the act is apparently not to create any new
land rights. It simply provides fair procedures for the eviction of unlawful occu-
pants.114 However, a court order in terms of the act that entrenches the position
of unlawful occupiers of land indirectly creates new, enforceable rights. It is
problematic that unlawful occupation of the land can become lawful through a
court order protecting unlawful occupiers against eviction, and the status of
unlawful occupiers protected in this manner will have to be clarified by the leg-
islature and/or the judiciary.
In conclusion, tenure reform is probably the most interesting aspect of land
reform as far as the establishment of more secure forms of tenure and the trans-
formation of land control framework are concerned. The most recent legislative
measures (i.e. the Extension of Security of Tenure Act and Communal Property
Associations Act) contain strong indications of a policy break with the hierar-
chy model of land control.115 These laws establish security of tenure where
rights or interests were precarious, by providing a minimum level of protection
through statutory anti-eviction, due-process and accountability provisions. Of
necessity, rights that ranked high in protection in terms of the hierarchy model
thereby are now more restricted than in the past, whilst ‘lesser’ rights and/or
interests are now better protected. Van der Walt116 indicates that laws provid-
ing substantive protection for the occupation rights of children, elderly persons
and weaker members of society bring about the most significant changes in this
regard.
The development of a new model of land use and control through reform legis-
lation is apparent to varying extents in different laws. Some (like the Housing
113
PIE, s 6.
114
Van der Walt, above n 13 at 288.
115 Ibid.
116 Ibid.
117 Ibid at 289.
18 Hanri Mostert
Act) contain policy statements for promotion of greater varieties of land rights,
without actual implementation thereof. Other laws create alternative frame-
works for land control, like where restitution of land rights were coupled with
the creation of communal property associations, or the new form of land con-
trol espoused by the Transformation of Certain Rural Areas Act. Further, some
laws create altogether new land rights or provide new kinds of protection for
existing, precarious ‘rights’, with the aim of addressing reform-driven needs not
fitting into the classical hierarchy model of land control. The Development
Facilitation Act’s mechanism of ‘initial ownership’, and the statutory protection
of insecure rights in the Extension Act are examples. The emerging model of
land control may be categorised as a more open approach to diversification of
control and use relations (fragmented use)118 with regard to land. The imminent
question now is whether the current registration system can cater effectively for
the variety of needs addressed in the emerging framework of land law.
The new model of diversified land use assumes that land-use rights deserve
strong protection because they address real needs, not because they happen to
be in privileged positions within a hierarchy of rights.119 Van der Walt,120
whose contribution to the coining of the emerging fragmented land rights model
cannot pass unnoticed, explains that the ideal land regime would satisfy both a
threshold and a ceiling requirement in securing tenure and providing access to
land. The threshold represents the minimum level of protection for any use-
right, through statutory recognition and provision of security, which need not
be registered title. The ceiling entails acceptance of the inherent restriction of all
rights in land by existing social structures and responsibilities, eg the public
interest. Hence, the diversified–rights model supports separation of land use and
title; and security of title established mainly by legislation, which will further-
more absorb regulation and restrictions imposed by the public interest.121
The hierarchy model might be more easily eradicated from the legal landscape
than from the societal structures within which development and creation of
wealth must take place. The state cannot fund development initiatives all by
itself. The beneficiaries of the development process themselves must ensure the
success of development endeavours by their co-operation. However, in order to
incorporate these beneficiaries, they need to be placed in a position from which
they can procure funds against security of their land rights. Inability to procure
118
This characterisation is used by Pienaar, above n 12 at 110 ff., in reliance on Van der Walt,
‘The Fragmentation of Land Rights’ (1992) SAJHR 431 and Van der Walt, above n 13.
119
Pienaar, above n 12 at 110.
120
Van der Walt, above n 118 at 431–50; Van der Walt, ‘Unity & Pluralism in Property Theory’,
(1995) TSAR 15–42; Van der Walt, above n 13 at 266; Cowen, ‘New Patterns of Landownership:
The Transformation of the Concept of Ownership as Plena in re Potestas’ Trust Bank Series of
Continuing Legal Education Lectures, WITS (Unpublished 1984).
121
Pienaar, above n 12 at 110.
Diversification of Land Rights 19
such funds, would mean that their rights de facto remain second-class. The
biggest possible drawback of the apparent lack of proper publicity in the
diversified-rights model therefore lies in probable reluctance of financial institu-
tions and private development agencies to advance loans against legislatively
secured rights.
The main criticism against diversification of land rights is rooted in the prin-
ciple of publicity: If security of tenure is to be afforded merely by legislation, it
can only be protected by means of a court order, arbitration or mediation. Thus,
legislative security of tenure would only be effective once a possible dispute has
been resolved. Hence, the principle of publicity is served only once the rights
conferred in terms of legislation are confirmed by court order, arbitration, medi-
ation or agreement. Security of use or occupation therefore needs further
individualisation, in order to make rights a practical reality.122
Continued reliance on registration in a new land regime is one possible way
to ensure security of title in protecting rights, generating wealth and supporting
development. Another possibility is extensive legislative regulation of new
rights, coupled with the creation of structures outside the registration system,
ensuring sufficient publicity.
122
Ibid.
123
Ibid.
124 Ibid at 111, in reliance on Van der Walt, above n 118; Van der Walt, above n 120; Cowen,
above n 120. Mineral rights can for instance be permanently separated from ownership of the land,
and that the holder of mineral rights enjoys preferential protection in the event of an irreconcilable
clash of interests with the owner. Badenhorst, ‘The revesting of state-held entitlements to exploit
minerals in South Africa’, (1991) TSAR 124. DRA, s 70(4). Thus, in cases where more than one title
exist simultaneously over the same land, ownership does not always confer preferential title. See
Van der Merwe, Sakereg, 2nd edn, (Butterworths, Durban, 1989) at 562–4; Kleyn, Boraine & Du
Plessis, Silberberg & Schoeman’s Law of Property, 3rd edn, (Butterworths, Durban, 1992) at
412–15.
125
Pienaar, above n 12 at 110.
126
Ie transfer is effected by registration plus the subjective intention of the transferor embodied in
the real agreement, whilst the underlying causa as such is irrelevant. Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21
at 51. Commissioner of Customs & Excise v Randles Brothers & Hudson Ltd (1941) AD 369 at 411.
127
Ie passing of rights to one party without the co-operation of the other party. Registration is
not compulsory, and the register is not always rectified immediately. Kleyn, Boraine & Du Plessis,
20 Hanri Mostert
inaccuracies in the system, for which the deeds registry personnel are not liable.
Nevertheless, the Deeds Registries Act contains several requirements ensuring
the reliability of information recorded in the register,128 and the responsibility
of private conveyancers for the correctness of the information in the register.129
It is still easy to maintain a registration system based on thorough examination
of documents, thereby maintaining the system’s accuracy and reliability,130
because so many rights are still excluded from the system. At present, a large
part of the population is excluded from the deeds registry system either because
the land in respect of which they hold rights has not been surveyed, or because
individualisation of the land-use rights in communal property is still impossible.
In order for registration to be of continued significance in the emerging land law
landscape, the protection under the publicity principle should be extended to
other forms of land use and control. The White Paper of 1997 already contained
some suggestions in this regard.131
With the law as it stands now, security of tenure in urban areas can only be
effected by way of a form of registered title, even within the ambit of reform
laws. The best example is the mechanism of ‘initial ownership’ of land capable
of being developed, but not yet complying with the deeds registry’s require-
ments for development. However, many urban settlements are on land inca-
pable of being developed to comply with requirements for incorporation in the
deeds registry. In these cases, existing legislation by itself does not provide
adequate protection or security of tenure. Individualisation through registration
in urban areas therefore requires an expansion of the registration system to
record and publicise more ‘informal’ land use relations. Suggestions to this
effect include (i) the recording of land use relations by local government or even
on municipal level;132 (ii) more innovative applications of the communal prop-
erty association system;133 or (iii) relocation of people, whose land use is unpro-
tected and insecure, to areas where it is possible to effect security of tenure
through recording and publicising their land use relations.134 However, at pre-
sent it is still unlikely that adaptations of this kind will be made to the registra-
the DRA (DRA, s 3(1)(b)); passing of ownership on compliance with the statutory requirements
(DRA, s 4); cadastral requirements (DRA, s 18(1)); the principle of sequence of transactions (DRA,
s 14); and the principle of linking and simultaneous registration of related transactions (DRA,
s 13(1)).
129 DRA, s 15A and reg 44A.
130 Pienaar, above n 12 at 111.
131
White Paper, above n 19, par 6.15.
132
Barry, ‘Secure Land Tenure for Informal Settlement Communities: The effectiveness of the
Cadastral System in Cape Town’; Fourie, ‘Property in Post-Apartheid South Africa’, Proceedings of
Conference on Land Tenure Issues (27–29 January 1998, UCT, Cape Town), online at http://www.
gtz.de/ [2002.03.06].
133
Pienaar, above n 12 at 114.
134
Ibid at 115.
Diversification of Land Rights 21
tion system, even though it could resolve issues of insecure tenure in urban
areas.135 Moreover, mere adaptations of this kind would probably not address
the existing inadequacies of the registration system.
Successful expansion and adaptation of the registration system to incorporate
land use relations will be more probable pertaining to rural areas. Most of the
informal rural land rights are still insecure because of the apartheid legacy con-
cerning land policy and administration, coupled with the vast array of legisla-
tive reform measures lacking an express policy break with the underlying
structure of apartheid land law.136 The unclear status of these rights inhibits
development of and investment in land. The task of undertaking full audits of
all existing land use relations, negotiating settlements and incorporating these
rights in the existing registration system is daunting. The New Communal Land
Rights Bill (GN 1453 in GG 23740, 14-08-2002) which was published for com-
ments during the second part of 2002, is expected to bring some relief in this
regard, although the Department of Land Affairs remains evasive about its
eagerly awaited date of promulgation.137
Some of the use-rights created under the diversified-rights model can already
be incorporated into the registration system.138 Labour tenants’ use rights can,
for example, be registered as real rights, even though it may be too expensive, or
the landowner could refuse to co-operate. Amended legislation could, however,
enable the court to compel a difficult landowner to co-operate; and the mainte-
nance of a separate register of these rights within the central deeds registry
system could enable issuance of a one-page certificate of title instead of a deed
of transfer. The land-information system could also incorporate a separate com-
puterised and comprehensive record of communal land rights accessible within
the central registration system.
An affordable, accessible register of statutorily diversified use rights would
require: (i) computerised recording of persons and rights within cadastrally
defined areas; (ii) registration of these rights only on demand; (iii) brevity of
documents, containing only relevant information; (iv) extensive recording of
information about the duration, conditions for use and transferability of land
rights, and about the right holders themselves; (v) incorporation of the land
information system into the central registration system, although maintenance
thereof could take place outside the deeds registry; (vi) clear definition of partial
land rights with reference to natural beacons or features; (vii) inclusion of infor-
mation about limitations on communal rights by group members or the admin-
istrative system wherein they are exercised, and about secondary or more
distant holders of rights; (viii) availability of information about encumbrances
by real security rights; (ix) accessibility of the information system as part of the
135 Ibid.
136 Ibid at 115–18.
137 See Daily Mail & Guardian, Forrest, ‘Uproar over Land Bill’ (23.11.2001); Cousins, ‘New
each part of the property linked to a particular block of shares. Upon purchas-
ing the shares, the purchaser acquires the rights and duties to a specific share
block in terms of the use agreement. The purchaser thus acquires the right to use
and occupy a specific part of the building and land in her capacity as shareholder
in the company.
Of particular interest for present purposes is the manner in which title in
terms of share blocks is protected and publicised. After the property has been
registered in the name of the company, no further action in the deeds registry is
necessary. The Share Blocks Control Act142 sets certain requirements to ensure
security of title to the land and/or buildings comprised in the scheme.143 The
main object and business of the share block company must be the operation of
a share block scheme.144 The company’s memorandum and articles of associa-
tion must be lodged with the Registrar of Companies.145 The name of the com-
pany must advertise the fact that it is a share block company.146 The
articles of association must provide for the right of occupation and use of a
specified part of the company’s immovable property in accordance with the use
agreement.147
Block shareholders are therefore placed in the virtual position of owners.148
Even though common-law ownership of part of the building is impossible,
tenure of block shareholders is secure enough to enable them to gain access to
loans and private development funds. The rights in terms of the use agree-
ment,149 the shares150 and the rights to the paid-up portion of the allocated loan
can be employed as collateral security.151
142
Act 59 of 1980 (abbreviated: SBCA).
143
Kleyn, Boraine & Du Plessis, above n 124 at 356.
144
SBCA, s 7(1).
145
Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21 at 230.
146
SBCA, s 9(1).
147
SBCA, s 7(2).
148
Carey-Miller & Pope, above n 21 at 225.
149
The ability of a member of a share block company to cede her rights under the use agreement
as security is subject to restrictions on cession in the use agreement. Usually the rights may only be
ceded either if the shares are transferred simultaneously, or if they are transferred separately from
the shares as security. In both instances, the company’s consent is necessary. However, such a
cession would imply that the member would be unable to exercise occupation of the land and/or
buildings. Therefore, this kind of cession is usually made subject to a suspensive condition in terms
of which the cession takes effect only once the debtor fails to perform in terms of the loan or
credit agreement. Butler ‘Shareblocks’ in LAWSA Vol. 25 Part 1, Joubert, Faris, Harms (eds)
(Butterworths, Durban, 2001) at par 35.
150
The legal position regarding the effect of a cession of shares as security is uncertain to some
extent. The consent of the directors may be required in terms of the company’s articles for a valid
cession or pledge of shares. See Britz v Sniegocki 1989 (4) SA 372 (D) at 380I. The cession of the
shares in securitatem debiti will not affect the cedent’s status as a member between her and the share
block company, as she remains the registered holder of the shares. See Standard Bank of SA Ltd v
Ocean Commodities Inc 1983 (1) SA 276 (A) 289A–B. A shareholder’s ability to procure credit upon
the strength of her shares is subject to any lien, which the company may have over the shares.
Barnard v Liquidators of S Seligmann & Co (Pty) Ltd 1964 (3) SA 692 (E) at 697. It may, however,
be determined in the company’s articles that the company’s lien will rank below a cession or pledge
to secure the purchase price of the shares. Butler, above n 149 at par 34.
151 Butler, ibid at par 33.
24 Hanri Mostert
The promulgation of the Share Blocks Control Act resolved many of the
problems surrounding the relative ‘insecurity’ of the personal rights conferred in
terms of share blocks when compared with traditional forms of registrable title
like ownership or limited real rights. The introduction of the sectional title
concept into South African law, which enabled acquisition of real rights to parts
of buildings, did not detract from the significance of share block schemes.152
These two mechanisms now co-exist in South African law, and can even
supplement each other.
Regardless of how many assets people accumulate or how hard they work, most
will not be able to prosper in economic terms if their property relations are not
formalised to some extent.153 Property relations remaining out of reach of
official records and outside the scope of policy-makers are economically invisi-
ble. Access and secure title to land are only meaningful if they receive sufficient
publicity so as to render full exploitation of the land and title thereto possible
and sensible for economic purposes.
Secure forms of land tenure are important because they may function as
collateral security to obtain private development funds and loans, with which
wealth can be generated. In this context, the publicity espoused by the system of
registration seems to be the most basic principle underlying a successful regime
of land use and control. Some authors have already pointed out that the regis-
tration will be of increased importance for the South African land regime in the
transition period, because of the policy in emerging land law to move away from
a system dominated by a hierarchy of rights to a much greater incidence of var-
ious forms of land title.154
The South African registration system is generally perceived as an accurate
and reliable guarantee of security of title.155 However, the registration process
is at present slow, cumbersome, expensive156 and exclusionary, because it does
not provide for the registration of all rights of land tenure recognised by statute
or envisaged within the land reform programme. Currently, the registration sys-
tem still perpetuates the outdated hierarchical approach to rights. The increas-
ing diversification of land rights because of reform legislation necessitates a
reconsideration of the operation of the existing system in an improved land
regime.
It has therefore become necessary either to reconcile new theoretical perspec-
tives with existing registration practices, or to redefine the significance of
157 The eminent example of such an adaptation is the introduction of a sophisticated system of
sectional title into South African law from 1971 onwards. This entailed a reform and adaptation not
only of some of the basic principles of South African property law (eg the superficies solo cedit rule),
but also of the registration system itself, to render it capable to cater for the specific needs of
sectional ownership.
2
Protecting Social Participation Rights
Within The Property Paradigm:
A Critical Reappraisal
AJ VAN DER WALT
In The New Property,2 Charles Reich famously argued that claims to participate
in state wealth (the ‘new property’)3 have come to serve the same social purpose
in postwar American society that was traditionally served by property owner-
ship, namely to secure individual autonomy against state interference.
1
This essay is based upon work supported by the National Research Foundation under Grant
number GUN 2050532. Any opinion, findings and conclusions or recommendations expressed are
those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the NRF.This section is based on part
of the author’s inaugural lecture, University of Stellenbosch, 8 May 2001, ‘Sosiale Geregtigheid,
Prosedurele Billikheid, en Eiendom: Alternatiewe Perspektiewe op Grondwetlike Waarborge’
(Social Justice, Procedural Fairness, and Property: Alternative Perspectives on Constitutional
Guarantees), (2002) 13 Stellenbosch LR59–82, 206–29.
2 Reich ‘The New Property’ (1964) 73 Yale LJ 733–87; see also Reich ‘Individual Rights and Social
Welfare: The Emerging Legal Issues’ (1965) 74 Yale LJ 1245–57; Reich ‘Beyond the New Property: An
Ecological View of Due Process’ (1990) 56 Brooklyn LR 731–45. Reich was not the first person to use
the notion of ‘new property’ with reference to social welfare rights; see Lynn ‘Legal and Economic
Implications of the Emergence of Quasi-Public Wealth’ (1956) 65 Yale LJ 786–805. For commentaries
on Reich’s article see Van Alstyne ‘Cracks in ‘The New Property’: Adjudicative Due Process in the
Administrative State’ (1977) 62 Cornell LR 445–93; Sackville ‘Property, Rights and Social Security’
(1978) 2 Univ NSW LJ 246–66; Williams ‘Liberty and Property: The Problem of Government Benefits’
(1983) 12 J Leg Studies 3–40; Epstein ‘No New Property’ (1990) 56 Brooklyn LR 747–5; Verkuil
‘Revisiting the New Property after Twenty-Five Years’ (1990) 31 William & Mary LR 365–73.
3 Reich discussed the following claims on state wealth (734–7): direct income and benefits (social
security benefits, unemployment compensation, aid to dependent children, veteran benefits, welfare
benefits), state jobs; occupational licences administered by the state; state grants and concessions
(taxi and other licences, television and radio frequencies, public transport permits, air transport
routes, liquor licences); state contracts; state subsidies; access to and use of state resources (airports
and harbours, public land, and other resources used free of charge); use of state facilities and ser-
vices (postal services, insurance, state subsidised research information). Reich’s notion of new prop-
erty includes but extends beyond what is commonly referred to as socio-economic rights; see the
discussion in s 2 below. In this paper, I refer to ‘social rights’ when discussing the more restricted
category of social support and assistance benefits associated with state welfare, pension, medical aid
and housing schemes, and to ‘commercial benefits’ when discussing state-granted licences, quotas
and similar benefits associated with commercial exploitation.
28 AJ van der Walt
Accordingly, Reich proposed that these participation claims should enjoy the
same strong constitutional protection traditionally granted to property owners4
to secure an enclave of individual independence against state regulation.5
Traditionally, claims to participate in state wealth6 are regarded as conditional
gratuities that can be withheld or revoked in the public interest,7 and Reich
argued that increasing dependence on the public interest state8 therefore creates
a new feudalism:9 participants depend on the state for their survival, but enjoy
no security because the state can unilaterally terminate their participation.10
Reich’s aim was to create a new zone of privacy,11 where the individual is free
from state regulation,12 by erecting a barrier of new property guarantees that
secures the individual’s status as participant in state wealth, just like the tradi-
tional barrier of property ownership used to protect personal freedom.13 For
that purpose it is necessary that new property interests should not be treated as
conditional gratuities, but as vested rights similar to traditional property own-
ership, which enjoys constitutional protection against state regulation.14
Reich stated the following principles upon which the protection of new prop-
erty interests should depend.15 Firstly, the state should not be allowed to abuse
4
Reich does not simply classify participation claims as property, but proposes equal protection
for claims that serve the same social purpose as property. The effect is accurately described as ‘prop-
ertizing welfare benefits’: Alexander Commodity & Propriety: Competing Visions of Property in
American Legal Thought 1776–1970 (1997) 363.
5
Reich 733: ‘The institution called property guards the troubled boundary between individual
man and the state. It is not the only guardian; many other institutions, laws, and practices serve as
well. But in a society that chiefly values material well-being, the power to control a particular por-
tion of that well-being is the very foundation of individuality’.
6
Reich 733: ‘One of the most important developments in the United States during the past
decade has been the emergence of government as a major source of wealth. . . . Government has
always had this function. But while in early times it was minor, today’s distribution of largess is on
a vast, imperial scale. . . . The valuables dispensed by government take many forms, but they all
share one characteristic: They are steadily taking the place of traditional forms of wealth—forms
which are held as private property. . . . The wealth of more and more Americans depends on a rela-
tionship to government’.
7
Reich 774.
8
Reich 778.
9
Reich 768.
10
Reich 733.
11 Reich 778.
12 Reich 785.
13 Reich 785.
14 Reich points out that property ownership was also initially granted conditionally and subject
to state cancellation and regulation, only sedimenting into the secure and constitutionally protected
rights they are over time—the fact that new property interests in state wealth are granted condi-
tionally and subject to regulation does not prevent these rights from also developing into strong,
secure rights. The current strong guarantee enjoyed by property ownership is based on the social
and political value of private ownership and not on the inherent value of the property involved, and
since participation claims in state wealth are also social constructs that fulfill a similar function, the
acceptability and scope of state regulation of these claims should also be determined with reference
to their function rather than their origin. Participation claims that serve important social and polit-
ical functions such as personal independence should consequently enjoy strong constitutional
protection.
15 Reich 779–86.
Protecting Social Participation Rights Within The Property Paradigm 29
its control over participation in state wealth to ‘buy out’ other constitutional
rights or claims by way of trade-offs or sacrifices.16 Secondly, legislative powers
to interfere with new property rights should be restricted substantively17 and
state regulation of new property should increasingly be subjected to procedural
controls.18 Finally, at least some participation claims19 that are currently
regarded as unenforceable gratuities should be transformed into vested or
acquired (and therefore constitutionally protected) rights so that the new prop-
erty can indeed safeguard personal independence.20
16 Reich 779. When the claims of an individual participant and the public interest are weighed
against each other in court, no weight should attach to the perception that claims for state support
are mere gratuities: Reich 781.
17 Reich 782–3 mentions three examples: a sensible notion of relevance to prevent all kinds of
other matters from being regulated through the regulation of new property; restriction of discretions
in the granting, withdrawal and cancellation of welfare support; and a complete ban on privatisa-
tion of the power to formulate policy regarding welfare rights.
18 Reich 783.
19 Namely the rights directly relating to individual autonomy and independence.
20 Reich 785.
21 363 US 603 (1960). Nestor immigrated to the US in 1913 and qualified for a pension in 1955.
He was deported in 1956 and further payment of his pension was terminated shortly thereafter,
because of his membership of the Communist Party between 1933 and 1939. The Immigration and
Nationality Act was adopted after 1939 and rendered membership of the Party illegal with retro-
spective effect (Flemming v Nestor at 613). Qualification for pension payments under the Act was
not based on contributions to the fund but on the recipient’s record as earner of an income over a
specified period (at 608–9). The pension fund was financed through a tax on earners who qualified
for the programme and their employers. The Court described the programme as a social insurance
(at 609), which is distinguished from an annuity by the fact that the recipient’s claim is eventually
not determined by contributions (at 610).
22 Flemming v Nestor 611: ‘Particularly when we deal with a withholding of a noncontractual
benefit under a social welfare program such as this, we must recognize that the Due Process Clause
can be thought to interpose a bar only if the statute manifests a patently arbitrary classification,
utterly lacking in rational justification’.
23
Flemming v Nestor 608, 610, 611. Pension benefits proper will probably qualify as property
rights. This distinction is not unique to US law; compare in German law BVerfGE 28, 119 (1970);
BVerfGE 45, 142 (1977); BGHZ 83, 1 (1982) (only vested rights are protected by the property guar-
antee in the German Basic Law); Van der Walt Constitutional Property Clauses: A Comparative
Analysis (1999) 173; BVerfGE 69, 272 (Eigenleistung) (1985) 300 (public-law interests in state-
controlled benefits are only protected if they have vested in the recipient and if they are based on sub-
stantial own effort and does not amount to a mere gratuity); Van der Walt (1999) 156–7. Compare
in Swiss law BGE 106 Ia 163 (Graf ) (1980); Van der Walt (1999) 373 (only vested rights are
protected). A similar principle applies in the case law of the European Court of Human Rights
30 AJ van der Walt
decision because no effort was made to balance the conflicting interests—on the
basis of the Court’s conception of a social security interest as a gratuity, public
interest and public policy automatically trumped an individual interest that
deserved better protection.24 However, the Court’s decision reflected the estab-
lished position, according to which interests that are recognised as rights by the
common law are protected by due process principles, while gratuitous benefits
granted by the state are not.25 What Reich proposed was an amendment of the
traditional position, arguing that benefits granted by the state should be recog-
nised and protected as vested rights because of their social function of securing
individual autonomy. The impact of this proposal on US law was mixed.
In Goldberg v Kelly26 the Supreme Court adopted Reich’s argument that
recipients of statutory welfare benefits have a right to receive those benefits and
not a mere privilege or gratuity,27 and that they accordingly have a right to be
regarding the First Protocol to the European Convention: X v United Kingdom [1970] YB 13 892; X
v The Netherlands [1971] YB 14 224; Müller v Austria [1976] 3 DR 25; X v Italy [1977] 11 DR 114
(a pension claim can be protected property under the property guarantee if there is a direct link
between the compulsory payment of contributions and the pension); Van der Walt (1999) 117. A
similar position has been adopted in India regarding a pension claim (Deokinandan Prasad v The
State of Bihar and Others AIR (58) 1971 SC 1409; Van der Walt (1999) 225) and a public service
bonus (Madan Mohan Patak and Another v Union of India and Others AIR (65) 1978 SC 803; Van
der Walt (1999) 226); compare for Zimbabwe Chairman, Public Service Commission, and Others v
Zimbabwe Teachers’ Association and Others 1997 1 SA 209 (ZSC) (public service bonus; Van der
Walt (1999) 494). See regarding licences Tre Traktörer AB v Sweden [1989] ECHR Ser A vol 159
(European Court); Hand and Others v City of Dublin and Others [1991] 1 IR 409 (Ireland); Bahadur
v Attorney General [1989] LRC (Const) 632 (CA) (Trinidad & Tobago); Lawlor v Minister of
Agriculture and Others [1988] ILRM 400 [1990] 1 IR 356 (Ireland); Hempenstall and Others v
Minister for the Environment [1994] 2 IR 20 (Ireland); as well as Van der Walt ‘The Constitutional
Property Clause and Police Power Regulation of Intangible Commercial Property—A Comparative
Analysis of Case Law’ in Jackson & Wilde (eds) Property Law: Current Issues and Debates (1999)
208–80.
24
Reich 769: participation in state wealth is important in the case of old age pensions, because
recipients of these pensions are usually vulnerable and dependent on payments for their survival.
Secondly, contributions to the fund are compulsory, and therefore recipients who have contributed
for years regard the pensions as their property, which is not reflected by the legal position. Thirdly,
recipients who lose their pension lose much more than just their contributions, because if they had
not been forced to make the contributions they could have invested their money in property that
could not be taken away from them so easily.
25 Compare Massey ‘Justice Rehnquist’s Theory of Property’ (1984) 93 Yale LJ 541–60, 543
(expectations are not recognised or protected as property by US courts, and are therefore subject to
(especially economic) regulation without a right to compensation); Anderson ‘Takings and
Expectations: Toward a ‘Broader Vision’ of Property Rights’ (1989) 37 Kansas LR 529–62, 529
(referring to Penn Central Transportation Co v City of New York 438 US 104 (1978) 124). The same
applies to regulation of new property: Anderson, 549.
26 397 US 254 (1970). Provision was made for a fair hearing where the beneficiary could appear
in person to hear and cross-examine witnesses, as well as for judicial review, but in both cases this
was restricted to the period after cancellation: 259–60. See Alexander ‘The Concept of Property in
Private and Constitutional Law: The Ideology of the Scientific Turn in Legal Analysis’ (1982) 82 Col
LR 1545–99; Epstein (1990) 56 Brooklyn LR 747–75; compare Barrie ‘Administrative Due Process
and the United States Supreme Court’ (1996) TSAR 133–44.
27 Goldberg v Kelly 261–2. The Constitution does not grant the right—it is granted by an inde-
pendent source such as legislation or the common law; compare Barrie (1996) TSAR 133, 139.
Protecting Social Participation Rights Within The Property Paradigm 31
heard before those benefits are cancelled,28 especially when cancellation would
have a disastrous effect for economically vulnerable recipients.29 Welfare assis-
tance limits financial dependency and uncertainty to help people maintain their
dignity,30 and therefore it is not just a gratuity or charity, but a contribution to
individual independence and social welfare, which in turn requires that payment
of state welfare benefits should proceed without interruption as far as possible.
To ensure that benefits are not cancelled by mistake, it is preferable to grant the
beneficiaries a right to be heard prior to cancellation.31 The decision in
Goldberg v Kelly made arbitrary cancellations of benefits more unlikely, and the
Supreme Court also adopted Reich’s argument that nobody should be prevented
or discouraged indirectly—through the granting or cancellation of state-granted
benefits32—from exercising their other fundamental rights.
However, the change of direction initiated in Goldberg v Kelly was short-
lived, and in later decisions the protection that was given to recipients of state
benefits was eroded.33 In Mathews v Eldridge34 it was decided that a full
28 Goldberg v Kelly 261. The exact form that procedural justice should assume in a particular
case depends on an investigation of the nature of the state function involved and the private interest
at stake: Goldberg v Kelly 262–3.
29 Possibilities for appeal and review subsequent to cancellation are described as insufficient con-
sidering the precarious situation of the recipients of state welfare payments. Summary cancellation
of payments can deprive recipients of vital support while they wait for the position to be rectified.
They receive support because they have no independent means, and therefore their position becomes
desperate immediately upon cancellation: Goldberg v Kelly 264.
30
A similar view of welfare benefits appears in the case law of the German Federal Constitutional
Court: the purpose of constitutional protection of property (including public-law property interests
in certain social security benefits) is to create and secure a protected sphere of independence for the
individual where he or she can take responsibility for the development of his or her own life, in order
to make an independent contribution to society: see Van der Walt (1999) above n 23 151, 156–7,
compare BVerfGE 69, 272 (Eigenleistung) (1985) 300.
31
Goldberg v Kelly 265. The decision in Goldberg v Kelly resulted in new property decisions in
various other fields: see Rendleman ‘The New Due Process: Rights and Remedies’ (1974–1975) 63
Kentucky LJ 531–674. An important example is the position of employees with vested rights in state
jobs: Board of Regents of State Colleges v Roth 408 US 564 (1972); Cleveland Board of Education v
Loudermill 470 US 532 (1985).
32 In Keyishan v Board of Regents 385 US 589 (1967); Perry v Sindermann 408 US 593 (1972);
Elrod v Burns 427 US 347 (1976) it was decided that continuation or cancellation of non-tenured
state jobs could not depend on the employee’s exercise of fundamental rights such as freedom of
speech, even though the employee did not have any vested right in re-employment.
33 As indicated by Reich himself in a later publication: (1990) 56 Brooklyn LR 731–45 731:
‘Twenty years later, we must confront the fact that the road opened by Goldberg v Kelly has not
been taken. Instead there has been retreat’. At 733 Reich criticises the watered-down application of
his theory since Goldberg v Kelly, and defends the even stronger claim that the right to procedural
due process in the Fifth and Fourteenth Amendments provides every citizen with a constitutional
right to minimum provision of life support, housing, child care, education, job opportunities, med-
ical insurance, a pension and a clean and healthy natural environment. This claim is in conflict with
the established tradition, confirmed shortly before Reich’s 1990 article by the Supreme Court in
DeShaney v Winnebago County Department of Social Services 489 US 189 (1989) (the due process
provision does not support positive claims against the state).
34 424 US 319 (1976) 335. The test formulated in this case for the regulation of welfare and simi-
lar benefits is still the standard: in every case it must be decided which procedure would be suitable
for the specific situation, with reference to three factors, namely the private interest affected by the
action, the risk that the holder would be deprived of this interest erroneously because of an improper
procedure, and the state’s interest in cheap and effective administration of the system.
32 AJ van der Walt
evidentiary hearing was not required before disability benefits are terminated,
and in later decisions it was suggested that the right to procedural fairness might
be subject to statutory conditions under which the benefit was granted.35 By
giving the legislature the opportunity to avoid administrative review procedures
by subjecting the grant of welfare benefits to statutory conditions and
qualifications, the courts effectively turned the clock back to the position prior
to Goldberg v Kelly.36
Reich’s impact was also limited in the sense that welfare claims were never
treated as property in the context of the takings clause. Reich’s theory goes
much further than prevention of gross unreasonableness and arbitrary state
action, as he construed a strong theoretical link between the protection of state
grants, procedural fairness, and property—Alexander describes the theoretical
rhetoric used by Reich as ‘propertizing welfare benefits’37 to underline the fact
35 Arnett v Kennedy 416 US 134 (1974); Bishop v Wood 426 US 341 (1976).
36 The US Bill of Rights does not protect socio-economic rights or procedural fairness directly—
the due process provision in the Fifth and Fourteenth Amendments protects specific rights (‘No state
shall deprive any person of life, liberty, or property without due process of law . . .’) and not due
process in general (Board of Regents of State Colleges v Roth 408 US 564 (1972) 569–71; Van Alstyne
(1977) 62 Cornell LR 445–93 451–2). State interference with political and personal liberties is tradi-
tionally subjected to a stricter procedural due process test. The distinction originated in the famous
Footnote 4 in Stone J’s opinion for the Supreme Court in United States v Carolene Products Co 304
US 144 (1938) 152 n 4: alleged interferences with economic rights are subjected to minimal scrutiny,
but state action that interferes with individual or political liberties is subjected to strict scrutiny.
State regulation of economic and commercial interests is therefore largely left in the discretion of the
legislature. The Supreme Court never explicitly subscribed to this dichotomy, but it did influence
subsequent decisions. See Funston ‘The Double Standard of Constitutional Protection in the Era of
the Welfare State’ (1975) Pol Science Q 261–87. The double standard of review was criticised in
Lynch v Household Finance Corp 405 US 538 (1972). The tendency to leave state regulation of eco-
nomic and commercial interests in the discretion of the legislature results from reaction against the
anti-regulation effect of laissez faire economic policy in the substantive due process decisions dating
from the Lochner court of the 1930s—see Tribe American Constitutional Law 2nd ed (1988) 567–86,
685–753, 769–84; Alexander (1997) 264ff, 275, 311ff, 315, 317, 331–4, 340–9 for an overview;
Lochner v New York 198 US 45 (1905); Coppage v Kansas 236 US 1 (1915). During the Lochner era
the Supreme Court subjected the Roosevelt government’s New Deal legislation to substantive
review and declared a whole range of social welfare legislation invalid, resulting in serious questions
about judicial activism and the separation of powers (the countermajoritarian difficulty; see Botha
‘Democracy and Rights: Constitutional Interpretation in a Postrealist World’ (2000) 63 THRHR
561–81). In the 1930s the Supreme Court abandoned the substantive due process approach in West
Coast Hotel Co v Parrish 300 US 379 (1937) and switched to a so-called ‘objective approach’, in
terms of which the courts would not interfere with statutory regulation of economic interests unless
other fundamental rights were interfered with in the process. Since then the procedural due process
guarantee has been interpreted as a formal guarantee that leaves the regulation of economic matters
to the legislative and administrative branches of government (deference). The courts’ lack of enthu-
siasm for the development in Goldberg v Kelly should probably be seen as fear for the impression of
a return to the substantive due process review of the Lochner era. Funston (1975) Pol Science Q 261
266: ‘. . . the Court more than lowered its sights; it gave up the hunt altogether’. Funston 270 refers
to a case decided only 14 days after Kelly and that already reverted to deference: Dandridge v
Williams 397 US 471 (1970) 485; see further James v Valtierra 402 US 137 (1971); San Antonio
Independent School District v Rodriquez 411 US 1 (1973).
37
Alexander (1997) 363. Commentators objected against the notion that state employees could
have property interests in their jobs, while the real purpose was simply to protect them against arbi-
trary regulation: Van Alstyne (1977) 62 Cornell LR 445–93, 484; Chandler ‘A Reconsideration of the
Protecting Social Participation Rights Within The Property Paradigm 33
The result Reich was aiming for, namely to restrict the insecurity of state-
granted benefits by subjecting their regulation to some sort of procedural con-
trol, was obtained in South African law and elsewhere by way of the doctrine of
legitimate expectation,41 which relies on an extensive interpretation of the
Concept of Property’ 1977 Archiv für Rechts- und Sozialphilosophie (Beihefte Neue Folge 10)
147–61, 160; Sackville (1978) 2 Univ NSW LJ 246–66; Epstein (1990) 56 Brooklyn LR 747, 769–75;
but compare Tushnet ‘The Newer Property: Suggestion for the Revival of Substantive Due Process’
(1975) Sup Ct Rev 261–88 (argues in favour of an extension of Reich’s theory on the basis of a revised
doctrine of substantive due process which will result in providing public sector jobs with constitu-
tional protection.)
38
Traditionally the protection of property in terms of the Fifth and Fourteenth Amendments to
the US Constitution includes two aspects, i e procedural fairness protection or due process and com-
pensation for takings; see Van der Walt (1999) 398–9. Compare Epstein (1990) 56 Brooklyn LR 747,
761. Massey (1984) 93 Yale LJ 541–60, 544 refers to the interest in participation cases as due process
property because they are not protected in terms of the takings guarantee. Massey (541 n 5) argues
that the distinction was never clarified, but apparently the Supreme Courts accepts (Massey 544
n 20) that property created by legislation (and not recognised in common law) cannot be taken away
without due process.
39
It may appear senseless to allow a compensation claim for expropriation of benefits sounding
in money, but in fact the value of such a claim is that it presents a basis for having the action declared
invalid rather than actually obtaining compensation: Van der Walt ‘Compensation for Excessive or
Unfair Regulation: A Comparative Overview of Constitutional Practice Relating to Regulatory
Takings’ (1999) 14 SAPL 273–331, 289.
40
The potential threat of an expanded application of this protection on the basis of a theory of
regulatory takings or inverse condemnation is particularly effective; see Van der Walt (1999) 14
SAPL 273–331.
41
This doctrine originated in the UK in the decision of Schmidt and another v Secretary of State
for Home Affairs [1969] 2 Ch 149, [1969] 1 All ER 904. This development was followed in
34 AJ van der Walt
notion of ‘vested rights’ to ensure that certain claims or benefits that do not
qualify as vested or acquired rights in terms of normal rights theory can never-
theless enjoy the protection of due process or procedural fairness principles.42
Stated simply, the doctrine of legitimate expectation amounts to expansion of
the normal reach of the due process principle—a solution that would have been
problematic in US law because of negative sentiment towards the notion of sub-
stantive due process.43 Reich’s solution was to redefine new property benefits in
such a way that they qualify as vested or acquired (and therefore protected)
rights that can benefit from due process control over state regulation—at the
risk of oversimplification one can say that Reich approached the matter from
the direction of an expansion of the property guarantee (which includes the kind
of due process protection he was looking for) rather than from an expansion of
the due process principle (which would have looked like a revival of substantive
due process and met with considerable resistance). In this sense, Reich’s choice
of the property paradigm as a theoretical framework was strategic rather than
purely philosophical.44
If one accepts, for the sake of argument, that Reich was not necessarily set
on devising a theory of property rights as such, and that he settled on the
property paradigm more or less by default or largely for strategic reasons, the
question is whether the theory of new property has any intrinsic value or
interest as a theory of social participation rights. Reich did not intend
specifically to promote the protection of socio-economic rights—the new
property includes but extends beyond the range of socio-economic rights as it
is usually understood.45 In effect Reich’s theory combines two groups of par-
ticipation claims, namely social or welfare benefits46 and state-granted com-
Commonwealth countries, see e g the recent Australian decision in Attorney-General (NSW) v Quin
(1990) 170 CLR 1 (FC) for a discussion of the doctrine of legitimate expectation and criticism against
it. In South Africa the doctrine was adopted in Administrator, Transvaal and others v Traub and
others 1989 4 SA 731 (A) and followed in a number of later cases. However, the extending effect of
the doctrine in common law review is uncertain in the new constitutional context; see n 42 below.
42
In current South African law, both s 33 of the 1996 Constitution and the definition clause in
s 1 of the Promotion of Administrative Justice Act 3 of 2000 refer simply to ‘rights’, but s 3 of the
Act (entitled ‘Procedurally fair administrative action affecting any person’) provides that ‘(1) admin-
istrative action which materially and adversely affects the rights or legitimate expectations of any
person must be procedurally fair’, thereby incorporating the effect of the doctrine of legitimate
expectation in the new statutory framework. For commentary on the similarities and differences
between the common law doctrine and the statutory provision see Cora Hoexter (with Rosemary
Lyster) The New Constitutional and Administrative Law (ed I Currie) vol II: Administrative Law
(2002) 215, 236.
43 See nn 36–7 above and surrounding text.
44
Although he offered a philosophical argument in support of his theoretical explanation—the
philosophical argument is that the new property safeguards personal independence and autonomy,
which is an important social value that deserves strong constitutional protection.
45
Eg the commercial participation rights (licences, quotas, etc) discussed by Reich are not usu-
ally regarded as socio-economic rights, while the welfare rights he mentions (medical aid, pension
funds etc) are. Other socio-economic rights such as housing and education can be classified under
Reich’s categories of new property rights, but are not discussed by name.
46
Old-age pensions, medical aid, welfare assistance proper, unemployment assistance, etc. This
category may also include state housing.
Protecting Social Participation Rights Within The Property Paradigm 35
mercial benefits.47 The common denominator between these two groups is that
both originate in state grants, as a consequence of which neither is recognised as
vested or acquired rights, and both are vulnerable to state regulation. In this
sense, the only link between the two groups is the common threat of uncon-
trolled state regulation and the common quest for procedural safeguards.
The differences between the two groups of state-granted benefits included in
Reich’s theory are significant: welfare benefits are typically needs-based and
aimed at the eradication or alleviation of poverty, whereas commercial benefits
are very often rights-based in principle48 and aimed at development and accu-
mulation of wealth. Even though the due process concern in both cases is to
escape the uncertainty of uncontrolled state regulation, the consequences of
regulation are very different in these two situations—in commercial situations,
cancellation of a trading licence or production quota might cause financial loss
and even ruin, but the cancellation of a state pension affects a socially and eco-
nomically vulnerable person’s very livelihood and security on a directly personal
level. Similarly, the purpose of protecting a commercial state-granted benefit
against arbitrary regulation is to ensure and promote commercial stability and
growth, to stabilise and protect existing wealth in a forward-looking frame of
mind; whereas the purpose of protecting a state-granted welfare benefit is to
prevent personal suffering and destitution and to alleviate poverty on a very per-
sonal, non-commercial level and with a specifically present-time purpose. At
least in the conceptual and logical framework of Reich’s own theory it seems
unjustified to ignore these differences, as it is unlikely that the protection of both
categories would serve personal independence and autonomy in exactly the
same manner and to the same degree.49
Theoretical discourse also reveals a quest for a theory of social and welfare
rights that reflects the difference in focus appearing from the discussion above.
Frank Michelman developed a theory of constitutional minimum welfare enti-
tlements,50 based on the liberal and republican pillars of his vision of society, in
47 State jobs, licences, quotas, radio frequencies, road and air traffic permissions and other per-
missions or grants that enable one to practice a trade or sell goods or services commercially.
48 In the sense that the acquisition of a vested right in the benefit is often possible and preferable.
Once they are recognised and protected as vested rights, these commercial benefits often become
commercially valuable and commodified. See n 23 above for comparative examples.
49 See Margaret Jane Radin ‘Property and Personhood’ (1982) 34 Stan LR 957–1015; ‘Market-
inalienability’ (1987) 100 Harv LR 1849–1937 for a similar distinction between ‘fungible’ and ‘per-
sonal’ property, based on the question whether the property in question is directly important for
personhood and therefore market-inalienable or imperfectly commodifiable, i e whether the protec-
tion of property interests in the property is premised on considerations of personal autonomy and
independence or on commercial interests.
50 Worked out in a series of law review articles, see Michelman FI ‘The Supreme Court 1968
Term—Foreword: On Protecting the Poor through the Fourteenth Amendment’ (1969) 83 Harv LR
7–59; ‘In Pursuit of Constitutional Welfare Rights: One View of Rawls’ Theory of Justice’ (1973)
121 Univ Penn LR 962–1019; ‘Formal and Associational Aims in Procedural Due Process’ in Pennock
J (ed) Due Process (Nomos XVIII) (1977) 126–71; ‘Welfare Rights in a Constitutional Democracy’
(1979) 3 Wash Univ LQ 659–93; Michelman FI ‘Human Rights and the Limits of Constitutional
Theory’ (2000) 13 Ratio Juris 63–76.
36 AJ van der Walt
which he set out a strong and eloquent argument for distinguishing between
rights-based and needs-based models of constitutional welfare rights. The heart
of the Michelman welfare thesis is that a minimum of welfare benefits have to
be provided to needy persons by the state, as a constitutional right, and on the
basis of extreme need, and that claims to this minimum welfare benefit are not
and need not be justified by any traditional notion of desert or vested rights.
Instead, the constitutional recognition of these benefits as rights is based on a
strong notion of self-government, political participation and civic responsibil-
ity. In the same vein, William Simon argued that social security and welfare
practice around the middle of the twentieth century favoured participatory over
exclusionary arguments in favour of the protection of welfare benefits against
state regulation.51 On the basis of these indications from social welfare theory it
seems justified to argue that at least some welfare participation benefits are not
adequately explained by exclusionary and desert-based theories (like Reich’s
new property theory) that rely on the traditional property paradigm. Of course
some state-granted participation benefits—such as the commercial benefits, and
perhaps even some of the welfare benefits—could and should be protected
against state regulation in a way that can be explained in a desert-based, exclu-
sionary, property paradigm,52 but at the same time an important category of
welfare benefits seems to be more closely related to notions of need, participa-
tion and civic responsibility. At least in this sense, Reich’s theory of new prop-
erty falls short of a fully satisfactory explanation of social participation rights.
This shortfall in the theoretical value of the theory of new property highlights
an important theoretical limitation in the property paradigm as such.
51 Simon WH ‘The Invention and Reinvention of Welfare Rights’ (1985) 44 Maryland LR 1–37;
‘Rights and Redistribution in the Welfare System’ (1986) 38 Stanford LR 1431–516; ‘Social-
Republican Property’ (1991) 38 UCLA LR 1335–413.
52 Because the nature of the entitlement created by the benefit and the relationship between the
beneficiary and the benefit resemble property rights closely. This is probably true of most of the
commercial benefits such as licences and quotas once awarded, and it may apply to some welfare
benefits in a developmental setting, eg state-granted land or housing for the poorest of the poor. See
in this regard the South African example in the decision of Government of the Republic of South
Africa v Grootboom 2001 1 SA 46 (CC) and Minister of Public Works and others v Kyalami Ridge
Environmental Association and others 2001 7 BCLR 652 (CC) (emergency housing for individuals
and communities in extreme need, in terms of s 26 of the 1996 Constitution).
53 This criticism against Reich’s theory was worked out by Verkuil PR ‘Revisiting the New
Property after Twenty-Five Years’ (1990) 31 William & Mary LR 365–73 at 365–7, 369.
Protecting Social Participation Rights Within The Property Paradigm 37
ally exacerbates the situation, because it reduces the debate about wealth and
poverty in a constitutional democracy to a mechanical process in which every-
thing depends on the classification of recognised and protected versus unrecog-
nised and unprotected interests, inside versus outside the circle of advantage,
while more difficult questions about the reasons and motivation for inclusion and
exclusion remain unasked and unanswered. This criticism against Reich’s theory
echoes similar concerns that have been voiced with regard to property theory and
the traditional property paradigm in general. The distinction between propriety
and participation or between entitlement and rights has been illuminated and
debated over the last decades in the property theories of authors such as Frank
Michelman,54 Margaret Jane Radin,55 Gregory Alexander56 and Joseph William
Singer.57 In fact, quite a number of property theorists have recently questioned
the strong exclusionary assumptions in the traditional model of property and
suggested participatory or relational qualifications.58
Concerns about the traditional property paradigm address at least two prob-
lems that can be described as the threshold and the ceiling issue respectively.
The ceiling issue concerns the traditional notion that property rights are unlim-
ited, and are mostly aimed at establishing or explaining the point—which is
more or less universally accepted nowadays—that the imposition of regulatory
ceilings on the rights or entitlements of property owners is theoretically accept-
able.59 The traditional assumption that property ownership is characteristically
exclusive, and therefore fundamentally protected against state interference and
regulation, has to be qualified in view of the ceiling debate. The threshold issue
concerns the problem of property maldistribution and focuses on redistributive
efforts, including efforts to safeguard certain minimum property entitlements,
in an effort to improve the balance of distribution. Even theorists who accept
exclusivity assumptions in the traditional property paradigm nowadays qualify
those assumptions with reference to various aspects of both ceiling and thresh-
old issues.60 However, the more radical theorists, especially those who work in
54 ‘Possession vs. Distribution in the Constitutional Idea of Property’ (1987) 72 Iowa LR 1319–50.
55 ‘The Liberal Conception of Property: Cross Currents in the Jurisprudence of Takings’ (1988)
88 Col LR 1667–96.
56 (1982) 82 Col LR 1545–99; Commodity and Propriety: Competing Visions of Property in
345–8, where Rose discusses the role of property in supporting and protecting independence);
Martha Minow ‘Interpreting Rights: An Essay for Robert Cover’ (1987) 96 Yale LJ 1860–915;
Jennifer Nedelsky ‘Reconceiving Rights as Relationship’ (1993) Rev Const Studies 1–26.
59
Much of US regulatory takings doctrine is concerned with the distinction between situations
where such regulation is justified per se and situations where it is justified only when accompanied
by compensation; see Van der Walt AJ ‘Compensation for Excessive or Unfair Regulation: A
Comparative Overview of Constitutional Practice Relating to Regulatory Takings’ (1999) 14 SA
Public Law 273–331 for a comparative discussion.
60
See Laura S Underkuffler ‘On Property: An Essay’ (1990) 100 Yale LJ 127–48; Laura S
Underkuffler-Freund ‘Takings and the Nature of Property’ (1996) 9 Can J Law & Jur 161–205; Gray K
38 AJ van der Walt
The foregoing brief and superficial discussion cannot and does not pretend to
offer a conclusive or authoritative analysis of theories of property or of theories
of social participation rights, but it does signal a useful set of considerations for
theoretical work in either or both fields. Firstly, it appears from the work of
Frank Michelman that the provision and regulation of certain welfare
benefits—intended to provide immediate, emergency-type relief for people in
dire social and economic straits, the poorest of the poor and the weakest of the
weak—cannot and should not be construed and discussed in terms of the tradi-
tional property paradigm, in other words in terms of desert or vested rights. At
the same time, the protection of these people against arbitrary or heavy-handed
regulation is of the utmost importance, because the effect of such regulation on
them is so immediately devastating for chances of survival and for human dig-
nity on a personal level. In this context, it seems necessary to devise a theory of
social participation in state wealth and of due-process protection for welfare
entitlements that reflects and accommodates notions of human dignity, social
and political participation and civic responsibility rather than notions of indi-
vidual desert or vested and acquired rights. The work already done by
Michelman looks like a good starting point for further theoretical development
in this area.
‘Property in Thin Air’ (1991) 50 Cam LJ 252–307 for examples of theoretical analyses that accept
certain exclusivity assumptions, but nevertheless accommodate explanation of ceiling and threshold
issues. Gray attempts to construct a moral (and therefore moderating) perspective on exclusivity as
the key characteristic of property.
61
The most important examples of rights as relation theories in the property context are prob-
ably Jennifer Nedelsky ‘Reconceiving Rights as Relationship’ (1993) Rev Const Studies 1–26; Joseph
William Singer The Edges of the Field: Lessons on the Obligations of Ownership (2000);
Entitlement: The Paradoxes of Property (2000).
Protecting Social Participation Rights Within The Property Paradigm 39
62
See in this regard AJ Van der Walt ‘The Fragmentation of Land Rights’ (1992) 8 SAJHR
431–50; ‘Property Rights and Hierarchies of Power: An Evaluation of Land Reform Policy in South
Africa’ (1999) Koers 259–94.
63
Including creative and innovative legislative exceptions and special arrangements to support
the commercial value and security of title of the rights, eg with regard to deeds registration require-
ments.
Protecting Social Participation Rights Within The Property Paradigm 41
remains unsettling. As long as land reform thinking remains in place, with its
contextual focus and pragmatic attitude, it remains difficult or impossible to
construct a neatly closing overall legal aesthetic,64 and it remains necessary (and
possible) to construe endless exceptions, qualifications and inconsistencies that
are unexplained by the overall theoretical framework. For a legal theorist look-
ing for closure within enclosed conceptual structures this unsettled condition of
fragmentation and disarray is unsatisfactory, but for those who are free from
theory guilt it is liberating,65 as it remains possible to keep on searching amongst
the messy fragments of theory for different ways to explain the need for and the
possibilities of assisting and protecting those who are still excluded from the
benefits of state wealth.
64 As the term is used by Pierre Schlag ‘Rights in the Postmodern Condition’ in Sarat & Kearns
Critical and Complacent Pragmatism’ (1990) S Cal LR 1821–41 explains the notions of theory guilt,
complacent and critical pragmatism.
3
Fiducia in an Emerging Economy
PIOTR STEC
HISTORY
Civil law lawyers usually try to trace roots of any legal institution back to
Roman times. And in fact fiduciary devices did originate in that epoch. Romans
knew three types of such institution: fiducia cum amico contracta, fiducia cum
creditore and fideicomissum. The very word ‘fiducia’ comes from the Latin fides
meaning faith or trust.4
1
P Lepaulle, Traité théorique et pratique des trusts en droit interne, en droit fiscal et en droit
international (Paris, Rousseau & Co, 1932), passim.
2
Cf eg D Hayton, SCJJ Kortmann, HLE Verhagen (eds): Principles of European Trust Law
(Kluwer Law International, The Hague, 1999), passim.
3
For a detailed account of differences between trust and fiducia cf JP Béraudo, Les trusts anglo-
saxons et le droit français (LGDJ, Paris, 1992) at 28–32.
4
W Wołodkiewicz, M Zabłocka, Prawo rzymskie. Instytucje (C H Beck, Warsaw 1996) at 171–72.
44 Piotr Stec
Treuhand kraft privaten Rechtsgeschäfts (CH Beck, Mnchen 1973) at 11–12. D Johnston, ‘Trusts
and Trust-like Devices in Roman Law’ in R Helmholz, R Zimmermann, Itineria Fiduciae (Duncker
& Humblot, Berlin 1999) 53–3.
6 W Wołodkiewicz, M Zabłocka, above n 4 at 110.
7 J Kolańczyk, above n 5 at 367; H Coing above n 5 at 12–13.
8 J Kolańczyk, above n 5 at 326–7; W Wołodkiewicz, M Zabłocka, above n 4 at 172.
9 Ibid at 148.
10 D Johnston, ‘Trusts and Trust-like Devices in Roman Law’ above n 5 at 45 et seq.;
F Longchamps de Brier, Il fedecommesso universale nel dritto romano classico (Liber, Warsaw
1997), passim.
11 H Coing, above n 5 at 14–15.
Fiducia in an Emerging Economy 45
THE CONCEPT
The concept of fiducia in German, Swiss and Polish law seems to stem from the
common Roman core, although there are some local variations.
Germany
12
Ibid at 28 et seq.
13
Cf Ph Rémy, ‘National Report for France’ in D Hayton, SCJJ Kortmann, HLE Verhagen
(eds)above n 2 at 131.
14
F Longchamps de Bérier, ‘Podstawienie powiernicze’ [1999] Kwartalnik Prawa Prywatnego 2
at 333–4.
15
J Gołaczyński, Przewłaszczenie na zabezpieczenie (Wydawnictwo Stowarzyszenia Notariuszy
RP, Kluczbork 1998) at 37.
16
A Kędzierska—Cieślak, ‘Powiernictwo (próba określenia konstrukcji prawnej)’ [1977]
Państwo i Prawo 7–8 at 44; T Dybowski, ‘Zasada jedności władzy państwowej a stosunek powier-
nictwa’ [1984] Państwo i Prawo 10 at 17.
46 Piotr Stec
Switzerland
17
H Coing, above n 5 at 90; G Walter Das Unmittelbarkeitsprinzip bei der fiduziarischen
Treuhand (JCB Mohr (Paul Siebeck), Tübingen 1974) at 12 et seq.
18
H Coing, above n 5 at 26 et seq.
19
Cf L Thevenoz, ‘La fiducie cendrillon du droit suisse’ [1995] Revue de droit suisse 3 at
284–310.
Fiducia in an Emerging Economy 47
Poland
Amongst many definitions of fiducia in Polish law the most comprehensive one
seems to be the one proposed by Z Radwa ński. In his opinion the fiduciary legal
act (czynność prawna powiernicza) is composed of two elements. The first one
is that the fiduciant (powierzający) transfers some rights to a fiduciary
(powiernik). The second one relates to the powers of the fiduciary, who in rela-
tionships with third parties acts as an absolute master of the acquired rights. He
is however contractually bound to exercise these rights within the limits set out
by the fiduciant.20
Polish authors usually recognize three types of fiducia fulfilling more or less
the above definition: powiernictwo (fiducia) stricto sensu, powiernictwo largo
sensu and powiernictwo ex lege.
In the classical form the fiduciant transfers the ownership of assets to a
fiduciary. This can take a form of fiducia cum amico or cum creditore. In each
case the fiduciary is a legal owner of the estate. His duty is to act according to
the contract.21
Sometimes another construct, the fiducia sensu largo, is recognized. This type
of fiducia is often called authority-based (powiernictwo z upoważnienia).
Contemporary legal writing tends to treat as fiduciary relationships those where
one person (the fiduciary) acts on behalf of another (the fiduciant) but without
revealing the identity or even the existence of the fiduciant.22 This is even wider
than the German economic Treuhand. Again, as in its German counterpart
there is no transfer of ownership, so this construction can be classed as fiducia
only from an economic point of view.
Finally Polish law recognises two cases where a fiduciary relationship arises
by virtue of a statute. The Law on the Agency of Agricultural Property of the
State23 and the Law on the Agency of Army Property24 provide that both agen-
cies being separate legal persons are empowered to manage and to sell agricul-
tural and army property. Their powers are virtually identical with that of a legal
owner. The legal status of these bodies is rather difficult to assess. It is usually
considered to be either a fiducia in its pure form25 or fiducia largo sensu.26 It has
20
Z Radwański, Prawo cywilne-część ogólna (C H Beck, Warsaw 1997) at 195. For a detailed
account of other definitions see M Pazdan, ‘Przelew wierzytelności na zabezpieczenie’ [2002]
Kwartalnik Prawa Prywatnego 1 at 116–17.
21
G Tracz, F Zoll, ‘Przydatność pojęcia powiernictwa dla prawa prywatnego’ [1998] Przegląd
Prawa Handlowego 4 at 24.
22
Ibid at 24; J. Trzebiński, ‘Czynności powiernicze’, [1997] Przegląd Prawa Handlowego 2
at 27.
23
[1995] Journal of Laws of the Republic of Poland 57 entry 299 with amendments
24
[1990] Journal of Laws of the Republic of Poland 90 entry 405 with amendments.
25
J Szachułowicz, Własność publiczna (Wydawnictwo Prawnicze, Warsaw 2000) at 153.
26
A Bieranowski, ‘Polemika na temat statusu prawnego Agencji Własnośći Rolnej Skarbu
Państwa’ in R Sztychmiller (ed.), Nauki prawne wobec przemian (Wydawnictwo UW-M, Olsztyn
2000) at 54.
48 Piotr Stec
even been suggested by one author that this is the only type of fiducia recognized
by Polish law,27 but this idea is not commonly approved.
27
J Szachułowicz, above n 25 at 152.
28
R Rykowski, ‘Powiernicze przeniesienie udziału w spółce z o.o.’, [1997] Przegl ąd Prawa
Handlowego 6 at 10.
29
H Kötz, ‘National Report for Germany’, in D Hayton, SCJJ Kortmann, HLE Verhagen (eds)
above n 2 at 91–2.
30 [1994] Journal of Laws of the Republic of Poland 121 entry 591 with amendments.
31 A Chłopecki, ‘Współwłasność czy powiernictwo?’ [1993] Przegląd Podatkowy 3 at 21; for a
Let us deal now with the contractual framework of fiduciary legal acts.
Legality
In the case of fiduciary management (fiducia cum amico), the rights and duties
of parties to the contract are generally governed by the rules of a contract of
mandate, or agency.51 The fiduciary has to act according to the agreement. He
is bound to act with loyalty towards the fiduciant and (eventually) a
beneficiary.52
This agreement may be concluded for the benefit of the fiduciant who himself
does not want to manage his property. It is also possible to construe it for the
benefit of a third party. The contract can than take form of a pactum in favore
tertii. This is a contractual clause obliging the debtor to render performance to
a person who is not a party to a contract. The beneficiary may, if he declares
himself willing to benefit from the contract, sue the debtor for performance.53
In Polish contractual practice this version of fiducia cum amico is relatively rare.
Usually the fiduciant himself benefits from the contract.
automatically. However if the contract involves the sale of chattels in genus (eg.
one tonne of flour) possession has also to be transferred. So in fact in this case
two agreements have to be concluded—a contract for the transfer of the prop-
erty and an obligational one.55
Another essential element of the modern fiducia cum creditore is that
contrary to the simple pledge the fiduciant can use the objects owned by the
creditor. The rights and duties of the parties are then comparable of those of the
parties of the commodatum or a gratuitous loan.56
The contract should also include provisions relating to the rights of the
fiduciary in the case when the fiduciant–debtor fails to pay the debt. It is possible
to grant to the fiduciary the right to sell or rent the entrusted property in order
to cover the debts. Alternatively the fiduciary may simply remain its owner.
Unless otherwise stated in the contract the fiduciary can choose what to do with
the property.57
PROTECTION OF ASSETS
Although fiduciary assets do not form a patrimony separated from the personal
assets of a fiduciary, it would sometimes be possible to protect these assets from
the personal creditors of a fiduciary. It has been suggested in Polish legal writ-
ing that in the case of transfer of ownership as a security for a debt the fiduciant
has an expectancy that the property will be returned to him.66 Polish courts
recognise a right of a future enjoyment of property as a personal right. This right
allows the fiduciant to apply for the exclusion of the fiduciary assets from the
enforcement levied against the fiduciary.67 The assets will probably not be pro-
tected if the contract does not oblige the fiduciary to retransfer ownership upon
its termination.
62
H Kötz, ‘National Report for Germany’, in D Hayton, SCJJ Kortmann, HLE Verhagen
(eds)above n 2 at 96; the position of Polish law on this subject will be identical.
63
Z Radwański, Prawo cywilne-część ogólna (CH Beck, Warsaw 1997) at 289 in relation to
fiduciary transfer of ownershipas security.
64
[1982] Journal of Laws of the Republic of Poland 19 entry 147 with amendments.
65
S Rudnicki, Komentarz do ustawy o ksiêgach wieczystych i hipotece (Wydawnictwo
Prawnicze, Warsaw 1996) at 66.
66
J Gołaczyński, Przewłaszczenie na zabezpieczenie (Wydawnictwo Stowarzyszenia Notariuszy
RP, Kluczbork 1998) at 262–3.
67
Ibid at 264.
54 Piotr Stec
Insolvency of a fiduciary
A fiduciant may sometimes claim for the return of property held by the
fiduciary. The level of protection differs from country to country. The Swiss
Banking Law of 1997 allows it in the case of bankruptcy of a bank. The fiduciant
may also withdraw value received by a fiduciary acting on his behalf, but can-
not retrieve assets given by him to a fiduciary.68 Withdrawal of assets is also
admissible in German law upon the condition that the property passed directly
from hands of the fiduciant to the fiduciary.69 In Polish legal writing it has been
suggested that since the fiduciary has only a formal right to the property, the
fiduciant has a right to claim for the exclusion of such property from the bank-
rupt’s estate.70 Another view is that in the case of a fiduciary transfer of owner-
ship for the purpose of security the administrator of the insolvent estate should
simply perform according to the terms of the contract and subsequently trans-
fer property back to the fiduciant.71
The problem of protecting fiduciary assets against the personal creditors of the
fiduciant does not arouse much interest in legal writing. Generally authors dis-
cussing this problem state that since the fiduciary is the legal owner of the prop-
erty, the creditors of the fiduciant cannot seize it.72 That does not lead, of
course, to full protection of the assets. Article 895 et seq. of the Polish Code of
the Civil Procedure73 allows the creditor to seize the personal rights of the
debtor. This could include the rights of a fiduciant. Therefore if the fiduciary is
obliged to perform for the fiduciant or a third party (beneficiary), their creditor
may seize the assets the fiduciant is entitled to. The procedure in such cases is
relatively simple: the court enforcement officer informs the fiduciant that he can
not profit from performance and orders the fiduciary to render performance to
the court deposit or to the court enforcement officer.74
(eds)above n 2 at 94.
70
M Allerhand, Prawo Upadłościowe. Komentarz (Elinex, Waarsaw 1991) [reprint of the 1939
edition] at 81.
71 J Gołaczyński, Przewłaszczenie na zabezpieczenie (Wydawnictwo Stowarzyszenia Notariuszy
CONCLUSIONS
75 C Champaud, ‘La fiducie ou l’histoire d’une belle juridique au bois dormant du droit français’
INTRODUCTION
The wording of P1–1 raises two points. The first concerns the limitations on the
right to property. The travaux préparatoires show that the second sentence was
intended to describe the conditions on which the State could expropriate prop-
erty, and that the third sentence was intended to preserve the State’s power to
regulate and seize property in satisfaction of debts owing to it.1 Subsequently,
the Court recognised that treating the second and third sentences as a complete
statement of the limitations on the right to property might impose excessive
restrictions on a State’s power to regulate private property. To some extent, it
avoided this by reading the second and third sentences quite broadly. For exam-
ple, it has held that the second sentence covers both de jure and de facto expro-
priations of property2 and that the third sentence covers both the imposition and
enforcement of tax laws.3 It has also given the first sentence an important role,
by describing it as an overarching provision.4 The effect is that any interference
with possessions which does not come within the second or third sentences is
therefore subject to the general limitations of the first sentence. While the first
sentence does not contain express limitations, the Court has stated that it
reflects the principle that there must be a ‘fair balance’ between ‘the demands of
the general interest of the community and the requirements of the protection of
the individual’s fundamental rights’.5 This applies to all forms of interference,
including those covered by the second and third sentences. One of the implica-
tions of this approach is that the shift from ‘possessions’ in its first and second
sentences to ‘property’ in the third sentence is not particularly important. Since
the rule expressed in the first sentence encompasses the other two sentences, it
is the interpretation of ‘possessions’ which determines the scope of P1–1. In
addition, the emphasis on the ‘fair balance’ principle means that taking a broad
1 See, for example, Commentary by the Secretariat-General on the Draft Protocol, Doc AS/JA (3)
13; A. 5904 (Sept. 18, 1951) reprinted in the Council of Europe, Collected edition of the travaux pré-
paratoires of the European Convention on Human Rights (Nijhoff/Kluwer, 1975), vol 8, p 4.
2 Sporrong and Lönnroth v Sweden Series A No 52 (1982), §61.
3 See: Darby v Sweden Series A No 187, (1991) 13 EHRR 774, Špaček, s.r.o. v The Czech
Republic (2000) 30 EHRR 1010, Hentrich v France Series A No 296–A, (1995) 18 EHRR 440.
4 Sporrong and Lönnroth, above, §61.
5 Ibid, §69.
The Autonomous Meaning of ‘Possessions’ under the ECHR 59
ch 5; see also the comments of Mr Roberts, a UK member of the Consultative Assembly of the
Council of Europe, on proposed drafts of P1–1: ‘The word “possessions”, used in the English text,
is not a really satisfactory word. . . . It is a word that would not be found in a British Act of
Parliament or any other legal document’ (Council of Europe, Collected Edition of the travaux pré-
paratoires of the European Convention on Human Rights (Nijhoff/Kluwer, 1975), vol 6, p 88).
7 See Inze v Austria Series A No 126, (1988) 10 EHRR 394 and Marckx v. Belgium Series A No
sub-paragraph on p 28 and the first sub-paragraph on p. 35; see also Wemhoff v Germany Series A
No 7, (1979–80) 1 EHRR 55, pp 26–7, para 19; Ringeisen v Austria (No.1) Series A No 13 (1971),
(1979–80) 1 EHRR 455 p 45 para 110; Engel v Netherlands (No1) Series A No 22, (1979–80) 1 EHRR
647, §81.
9 Series A No 13, 1 EHRR 455.
10
Series A No 306–B, (1995) 20 EHRR 403. Although Gasus is the first case to refer explicitly to
the autonomous meaning doctrine in relation to ‘possessions’, in James v UK Series A No 98, (1986)
60 Tom Allen
claimed that the Dutch tax authorities had infringed P1–1 by seizing goods
belonging to him. He had delivered the goods to a Dutch buyer under a contract
which provided that property would not pass until payment. Before the buyer
made the payment, the tax authorities seized the goods to satisfy the buyer’s tax
debts. The applicant argued that the seizure amounted to a deprivation of his
possessions that did not comply with the conditions of the second sentence of
P1–1.11 The autonomous meaning doctrine arose; both the applicant and the
Dutch government seem to have assumed that it was essential to determine
whether the retention of title did give the applicant the ownership of the goods.
In fact, the Court concluded that the third sentence of P1–1 applied, and that
‘possessions’ includes interests short of ownership. In any case, the Government
argued that the retention of title clause only gave the applicant a ‘security right
in rem’ rather than ‘true’ ownership under Dutch law, as only the purchaser held
‘true’ or ‘economic’ ownership; hence, it claimed that there had been no inter-
ference with ‘possessions’.12 The majority in the Commission acknowledged
that the domestic laws of different countries may classify the interest held by the
seller under a retention of title differently; however, it also stated that
‘[n]ormally, both the seller and the buyer will in such cases be holders of a
limited property right which is protected under Article 1 of Protocol No 1’. It is
not clear whether this point was in fact disputed by either party; the real issue
seems to have been whether these facts amounted to a ‘deprivation of posses-
sions’ under the second sentence. On this point, the Commission stated that the
second sentence did apply with almost no discussion.
The Court also rejected the Government’s argument, but it raised the idea of
the autonomous meaning. It stated that ‘possessions’
has an autonomous meaning which is certainly not limited to ownership of physical
goods: certain other rights and interests constituting assets can also be regarded as
‘property rights’, and thus as ‘possessions’, for the purposes of this provision P1–1.13
It was therefore not conclusive that the rights held under the retention of title
clause would not be classified as an ownership interest under Dutch law.14
In Gasus, the autonomous meaning doctrine had a narrow role to play, as
the Dutch Government accepted that the retention of title clause did give the
8 EHRR 123, §42, the Court stated that the phrase ‘in the public interest’ in the second sentence of
P1–1 as a concept with autonomous meaning, and in Tre Traktörer Aktiebolag v Sweden Series A
No 159 (1989), (1991) 13 EHRR 309, §53, the Court concluded that a licence to sell alcohol was a
P1–1 possession, although it appears that it would not have been classified as a property interest
under national (Swedish) law.
11
The applicant might have argued that the seizure fell under the first or third sentences, but in
practice it is more difficult to establish that the compensation should have been paid for the types of
interference covered by the first and third sentences. In fact, the Court found that the third sentence
applied to this case, and concluded that no compensation was necessary to satisfy P1–1.
12 Series A No 306–B (1995), §52.
13 Ibid, §53.
14 The Court held that, although there was an interference with the applicant’s possessions, the
interference did not infringe the ‘fair balance’ principle: see ibid, §§60–74.
The Autonomous Meaning of ‘Possessions’ under the ECHR 61
applicant a kind of limited property over the goods. There was no dispute as to
the existence of the rights or their character as proprietary rights. Hence, while
Gasus shows that the Court believes that the autonomous meaning doctrine is
necessary to make the Convention effective, it does not tell us why the Court
believes the Convention would not be effective without the doctrine. In the
Article 6 cases, the Court has been concerned that a State might limit its
Convention obligations by exploiting the differences in the legal systems of the
member States. In particular, the Court would not allow States to avoid their
Article 6 obligations by claiming that a criminal process is only an administra-
tive or regulatory process. In König, the Court stated that ‘civil rights’ should be
given an autonomous meaning because ‘any other solution might lead to results
incompatible with the object and purpose of the Convention’15 and in the
Öztürk case, the Court stated that, in relation to ‘criminal charges’,
if the Contracting States were able at their discretion, by classifying an offence as ‘reg-
ulatory’ instead of criminal, to exclude the operation of the fundamental clauses of
Articles 6 and 7, the application of these provisions would be subordinated to their
sovereign will. A latitude extending thus far might lead to results incompatible with
the object and purpose of the Convention.16
This leads to the question: how does the Court determine the scope of ‘the
operation of the fundamental clauses of Articles 6 and 7’ (and, for that matter,
P1–1)? On this point, the Court has said that the meaning of ‘criminal charge’
under Article 6 should reflect the common standards of the Contracting States.
Accordingly, it does not rely solely on an abstract conception of criminality or
the criminal process to define ‘criminal charge’, but acts partly on its observa-
tions of the practice of other Contracting States.17 The Court does not pass
judgement on the justifiability of the common practice, in the sense that it does
not state whether certain kinds of conduct should or should not be decrimi-
nalised, but merely observes whether the processes by which States deal with the
case resemble the criminal process. As such, ‘criminal charge’ reflects a com-
mon, minimum standard. This is consistent with one of the original purposes of
the European Convention: to safeguard the minimum standards of the
European States, rather than to raise the standards of all States.18
With P1–1, the corresponding issue would arise if a State sought to reclassify
an established property interest as some non-property interest, without provid-
ing the property holder with the basic guarantees of P1–1. The Court has not yet
faced a case of this nature. In any case, one would expect that such a declaration
would itself be treated as an interference with possessions.19 The autonomous
15
Konig v Germany (No.1) Series A No 27 (1976), (1979–80) 2 EHRR 170, §88.
16
Öztürk v Germany Series A No 73, (1984) 6 EHRR 409, §49.
17
Ibid, §50 and §53.
18
Statute of the Council of Europe, Article 1(a).
19
This is confirmed by Brumărescu v Romania (2001) 33 EHRR 35 where a declaration by the
Romanian court that reversed earlier judicial declarations that the applicant held certain property
was treated as interference with possessions.
62 Tom Allen
20 Laurence H Tribe, American Constitutional Law (2nd ed.) (Mineola, New York, 1988), at
587. Tribe describes this as “the idea that the government must respect ‘vested rights’ in property
and contract—that certain settled expectations of a focused and crystallized sort should be secure
against governmental disruption, at least without appropriate compensation.”
The Autonomous Meaning of ‘Possessions’ under the ECHR 63
property, but simply that the national legal system has given the applicant the
expectation of security which should not be disappointed.
This is apparent from a series of cases where a State has imposed a settlement
of a civil dispute between itself and a private person. Since the private party is
denied the opportunity to have their claim heard before the national courts,
Article 6 should apply, but the Court has also indicated that the claims may con-
stitute possessions under P1–1. The Court has taken this view even where
national law does not classify the claims as proprietary interests. One example
is Pressos Compania Naviera S.A. and Others v Belgium.21 In 1983, a decision
of the Belgian Court of Cassation extended the State’s liability in tort for ship-
ping casualties. Since the decision unexpectedly opened the door to many new
claims, the Belgian legislature passed an Act in 1988 that retrospectively extin-
guished all pending and potential claims. Only cases that had been finally
resolved by the courts were unaffected. The applicants had already filed their
tort claims with the Belgian courts when the legislation took effect, but had not
yet received final decisions from the Belgian courts on their claims. In
Strasbourg, they maintained that the legislation deprived them of their posses-
sions contrary to P1–1; Belgium responded that P1–1 did not apply because none
of the tort claims ‘had been recognised and determined by a judicial decision
having final effect’.22 Belgium argued that a pending claim was no more than
a right to property, rather than a right of property,23 and therefore neither
property under Belgian law nor ‘possessions’ under the Convention. The
Commission agreed; however, the Court held that the pending tort claims were
possessions.
The Court’s position on Belgian law was somewhat ambiguous. It did say
that, to determine if there is a ‘possession’, ‘the Court may have regard to the
domestic law in force at the time of the alleged interference’.24 In this sense, the
meaning of ‘possession’ depends on national law. The Court noted that, under
Belgian law, a victim of a tort acquires a claim for compensation as soon as the
damage occurs. Although Belgian law does not classify a pending action as
property, this was not conclusive; it was more important that the claim ‘consti-
tuted an asset’ and that the Court of Cassation judgment gave the applicants a
‘ “legitimate expectation that claims deriving from the accidents in question
would be determined in accordance with the general law of tort” ’.25 The exis-
tence of this ‘legitimate expectation’ was enough to persuade the European
Court that the applicants had ‘possessions’ under P1–1.
The reasoning in the Pressos case contrasts with the Court’s reasoning in
National & Provincial Building Society and others v UK.26 The National &
21
Pressos Compania Naviera SA v Belgium Series A No 332, (1996) 21 EHRR 301.
22
Ibid, §29.
23
Ibid, §29.
24
Ibid, §31.
25
Ibid, §31.
26
(1998) 25 EHRR 127.
64 Tom Allen
In relation to the P1–1 claim, the Government argued that the applicant’s
right to bring restitution proceedings did not amount to ‘possessions’. The
Court began by saying that, in effect, the 1949 expropriation had extinguished
the father’s ownership in the land. Hence, the only rights which could constitute
‘possessions’ were those granted under the 1991 legislation. As in Pressos and
National & Provincial Building Society, the issue was whether the right to bring
proceedings was indeed a possession. The Court stated that ‘possessions’ can
include ‘assets, including claims, in respect of which the applicant can argue that
he has at least a “legitimate expectation” of obtaining effective enjoyment of a
property right’.
A claim with only a remote chance of success would not qualify: ‘the hope of recogni-
tion of the survival of an old property right which it has long been impossible to exer-
cise effectively cannot be considered as a “possession” . . . nor can a conditional claim
which lapses as a result of the non-fulfilment of the condition’.
In this case, it could be said that this ‘hope of recognition’ had been crystallised
by the 1991 legislation, as it did provide a means of claiming restitution; how-
ever, the applicant had failed to satisfy the conditions for the restitution of the
land itself. In that sense, the likelihood of success in any claim for return of the
land was remote before the 1991 legislation, and the legislation did not increase
that likelihood. However, although it was not necessary to its decision, the Court
did observe that the 1991 Act gave stronger claims for compensation in the form
of a monetary settlement or equivalent land, and hence these claims might well
constitute ‘possessions’. Accordingly, Malhous suggests that deciding whether
the holder has a ‘legitimate expectation’ focuses on the likelihood of success in
litigating a claim before the national courts. In this sense, the European Court of
Human Rights does not seek to resolve disputes concerning the meaning of
national law, but it does seem willing to predict the strength of the applicant’s
case under national law. As long as there is a strong case under national law for
the existence of a property right, the Court will say that there is a possession,
even if the dispute has not been finally determined by the national tribunals.
While Malhous suggests that stability is the only value underlying P1–1, there
are cases where the Court has given other values greater weight. A leading
example is Louzidou v Turkey, where the Court found a breach of P1–1 arising
from the prolonged denial of the exercise of proprietary rights by Turkish
Cypriot authorities, for which the Turkish government could be held responsi-
ble. The Turkish Government argued that the applicant’s title had been expro-
priated by a constitutional declaration of the ‘Turkish Republic of Northern
Cyprus’ (the ‘TRNC’) of 7 May 1985, by which all ‘abandoned’ property was
deemed to belong to the new government. Since Turkey accepts the jurisdiction
of the Court only with respect to its acts from 1990, it argued that it could not
be held responsible for any alleged breach of P1–1. However, the Court refused
to recognise the validity of the declaration at international law and therefore
concluded that the applicant still held a P1–1 possession in 1990. It also found
66 Tom Allen
that the acts of the Turkish Cypriot authorities could be imputed to Turkey,
with the result that Turkey could be held responsible for the fact that the appli-
cant was denied access to her land from 1990 and thereafter. It was clear that the
chances that the applicant could have recovered her property in 1990 were very
remote and had been for many years; moreover, there was no suggestion that
that either Turkey or the Turkish Cypriot authorites would make it less remote
in future. Plainly, the likelihood that the applicant could have been successful
before the relevant national courts was not relevant. In this sense, stability was
not the central value in the case.
Louzidou is an important case, but it represents an exception to the general
trend. Indeed, it can be compared with the recent case of Prince Hans-Adam II
of Liechtenstein v Germany. A painting belonging to the applicant’s father was
confiscated by Czechoslovakia in 1946 under laws authorising the confiscation
of property belonging to German persons. The applicant’s father disputed the
confiscation, but his claims were dismissed by the Bratislava Administrative
Court in 1951. Neither the applicant nor his father accepted the lawfulness of
the confiscation, but Czechoslovakia and its successor States had refused to dis-
cuss the possibility of restitution. In 1991, the painting was loaned to a German
art gallery. The applicant then brought proceedings in the German courts to
recover the painting. He was unsuccessful, as the German courts held that the
Convention on the Settlement of Matters Arising out of the War and the
Occupation (the ‘Settlement Convention’)30 excluded German jurisdiction
regarding the applicant’s case.
Prince Hans-Adam II differs from Malhous, as the Prince claimed that the
painting still belonged to his family. In effect, he claimed that his P1–1 posses-
sion was the painting itself, rather than a statutory right to the return of the
painting. However, the Court found that the likelihood of establishing contin-
ued ownership before the Czech courts was so remote that the painting could
not qualify as a P1–1 possession; hence, the likelihood of establishing a similar
claim before the German courts would have been equally unlikely. This seems
to have been enough to dispose of his claim before the European Court. Plainly,
there are significant differences between Prince Hans-Adam II and Louzidou; in
particular, the Turkish Government plainly had a higher degree of responsibil-
ity for the initial taking and subsequent retention of the property in Louzidou
than the German government in Prince Hans-Adam II. Nevertheless, it is note-
worthy that the examination of such considerations in Louzidou is the excep-
tion rather than the rule.
30
23 October 1954 between the United States of America, the United Kingdom of Great Britain
and Northern Ireland, the French Republic and the Federal Republic of Germany. The German
courts relied on Chapter 6, Article 3 § 3 of the Settlement Convention, in conjunction with § 1: claims
or actions against persons having acquired or transferred title to property on the basis of measures
carried out with regard to German external assets or other property, seized for the purpose of repa-
ration or restitution, or as a result of the state of war, or on the basis of specific agreements, were
not admissible. These provisions were confirmed on German unification.
The Autonomous Meaning of ‘Possessions’ under the ECHR 67
The importance of stability shows that the European Court is likely to say that at
least two types of interest should be treated as P1–1 possessions: (i) those interests
already classified as property under national law, and (ii) interests in the form of
claims to property which would have a reasonable chance of success before
national courts. There is also a third type of interest, where the applicant holds nei-
ther a recognised form of property nor a strong claim to a property. A good exam-
ple is the Beyeler case, which concerned the exercise of a right of pre-emption by
the Italian Government over a Van Gogh painting which the applicant had agreed
to buy. The applicant claimed that the pre-emption infringed his rights under P1–1,
where his possession consisted of the rights which he claimed he had acquired
under the contract. However, Italy claimed that the applicant did not have any
form of property in the painting, because his ‘contract’ had never come into exis-
tence. Under Italian law, sales involving certain works of art must be declared to
the appropriate authorities; if the declaration is not made, the sale is automatically
void. A full declaration should have been made for the sale of the painting, but it
was not. Accordingly, Italy argued that the applicant never acquired a proprietary
interest in the painting, and hence he did not have a ‘possession’ under P1–1.
The European Court found that the applicant did have a P1–1 possession,
although the basis for its decision is not entirely clear. It made the point that
‘possessions’ has an autonomous meaning, and then considered the relevant
provisions of the Italian Civil Code and statutory law. It acknowledged that
transfers and other legal transactions effected in breach of the rules laid down by the
statute or without complying with the prescribed terms and conditions shall be null
and void’;31 however, it ultimately concluded that the applicant had held
‘a proprietary interest recognised under Italian law—even if it was revocable in
certain circumstances—from the time the work was purchased until the right of pre-
emption was exercised’.32
In this sense, it could be said that the Court did make its own determination on
the application of Italian statutory law to the specific facts. However, the Court
also emphasised the conduct of the Italian authorities; in particular, it observed
that the authorities had treated the applicant as the owner of the painting for at
least some purposes, and hence it did not ‘need to give an opinion on the Italian
courts’ view that under the relevant domestic provisions the 1977 sale should be
considered as null and void’.33 In effect, the Court held that, even if the initial
sale was void, subsequent events demonstrated that the Italian authorities
regarded the applicant as holding a proprietary interest in the painting.34 That
31 Beyeler v Italy (2001) 33 EHRR 52, §101; the statute referred to is Law No 1089 of 1939.
32 Ibid, §105
33 Ibid, §106.
34 It did not find it necessary to state whether the interest was a full ownership interest or some
interest may not have been full ownership, as only a valid sale could have con-
ferred ownership on the applicant; nevertheless, the Court still regarded that the
applicant’s interest as a proprietary interest of some kind and therefore as a
‘possession’ under P1–1. The crucial point is that the Court was willing to find
that a proprietary interest existed, even where the applicable national laws
would have led to the opposite conclusion.
Beyeler was not a case where expectations were destroyed by the extinction
of a claim to property, although one could still say that the conduct of the Italian
authorities did create expectations which should have been respected. While it
might be argued that the European Court applied a kind of estoppel against the
Italian authorities, it did not identify any positive representation by the author-
ities regarding the future treatment of the applicant’s interests. Indeed, the
authorities did not make any specific representations to the applicant regarding
the likelihood that the right of pre-emption would be exercised. At the most, the
Italian authorities had treated the applicant as owner in some circumstances for
some purposes. In particular, between 1985 and 1987, officials of the Ministry
of Cultural Heritage communicated with the applicant’s lawyer and the appli-
cant, to request information on the painting’s location and to give permission
for it to be moved to the Guggenheim museum in Venice, and then to make
arrangements to inspect the painting and to inform him that the State was inter-
ested in purchasing the painting.35 None of these communications involved any
statement of intention regarding the applicant’s claim to ownership; arguably,
they merely indicated that the authorities had not been fully apprised of the legal
situation at the time of the communications.
A further example of this approach can be seen in Matos e Silva,36 where the
applicants claimed that Portuguese procedures for expropriation of land
infringed its rights under P1–1. The Portuguese Government claimed that the
applicants did not have P1–1 possessions because their legal position as owner
of the land in question was debatable under domestic law.37 It appears that the
Government claimed that the applicants derived their title to part of the land
from an 1884 concession which provided that the land could be expropriated
without any right to compensation for the grantees. The applicants bought the
land in 1899 from the original grantee and registered the purchase. They
remained in occupation, paid taxes on the land and were treated as the full
owner by public officials and others until the dispute over the expropriation
arose. Both the Commission and the Court concluded, with very little discus-
sion, that the applicants held a P1–1 possession with respect to the land. The
Court stated that it was not its function to determine the applicants’ rights of
property under domestic law, since ‘possessions’ has an ‘autonomous mean-
ing’.38 In this case,
35
Beyeler, §104.
36
Matos e Silva lda v Portugal (1997) 24 EHRR 573.
37 Ibid, §72.
38
Ibid, §75.
The Autonomous Meaning of ‘Possessions’ under the ECHR 69
the applicants’ unchallenged rights over the disputed land for almost a century and the
revenue they derive from working it may qualify as “possessions” for the purposes of
Article 1 (P1–1).39
It is not entirely clear what the Court meant by the ‘unchallenged rights’ of the
applicants, but the fact that the public officials had acted as though the
applicants held full ownership seems to have been relevant. Again, none of the
official communications with the applicant related to the issues in the case at
hand; as in Beyeler, it could have been argued that the authorities had not fully
researched the applicant’s title claims and should not be held to statements
made in ignorance of the true situation.
Finally, two Greek cases reflect similar views on the importance of stability.
Iatridis concerned a lengthy dispute over title to a cinema.40 The applicant held it
on a lease from a private person, whose title was disputed by the Greek officials.
The State claimed ownership of the cinema and evicted the applicant. The Court
did not resolve the title issue, but still held that the applicant had a P1–1 posses-
sion. It noted that, before the eviction, the applicant ‘had operated the cinema for
eleven years under a formally valid lease without any interference by the author-
ities, as a result of which he had built up a clientèle that constituted an asset’.41
The fact that he was treated as having a proprietary interest was just as impor-
tant as any legal rights that he could establish. Finally, The Former King of
Greece v Greece42 also illustrates this point. The former King of Greece claimed
to own certain assets in his private capacity; Greece argued that he held the assets
in his public capacity. The Court held that the assets were held in the former
King’s private capacity, and hence were P1–1 possessions, largely on the basis
that his family had been permitted to deal with the assets in a private capacity.
rights which must be found in the bundle of rights before it will treat it as a P1–1
possession. Nevertheless, it is likely that the real source of its conception of pos-
sessions in Gasus was derived from the shared conception of the European
judges of what a property bundle of rights looks like in their own legal systems.
In this way, the derivation of an autonomous meaning for ‘possessions’ was sim-
ilar to that of ‘criminal charge’. By contrast, in Beyeler, Matos e Silva, Iatridis
and Former King of Greece, the Court it did not ask whether similar conduct by
public authorities in other States would give rise to a property interest under
national law. Indeed, it is more likely that the analysis under other national sys-
tems would say that executive branch cannot create property rights simply by
acting as though a party had property. So, for example, if we transpose the facts
of Beyeler to the English context, it is doubtful that an English court would con-
clude that a ‘buyer’ under a void ‘contract’ has acquired property on the basis
that some public officials assumed and acted as though the ‘buyer’ had acquired
property. Such a decision would deprive the judiciary of its jurisdiction to deter-
mine property disputes; moreover, it could affect the rights of the ‘seller’ under
the void ‘contract’. Hence, the European Court’s emphasis on national law
seems to be more a matter of observing of local conduct than comparing its
effects with the effects of similar conduct in other Contracting States.
Where the Court relies on evidence of State conduct to establish whether the
applicant has possessions, it demonstrates its belief that the stability of rela-
tionships concerning access, use and disposition of resources is the underlying
purpose of P1–1. How those relationships came to exist is less important than
the fact of their existence. While these relations are not immutable or absolute,
modifications brought about by the exercise of State power cannot be too
abrupt or arbitrary. The importance of this kind of stability to the political and
economic systems of Europe would have been obvious in the immediate post-
war period, where there was a strong desire to re-establish the rule of law and
to protect social democracy against the communist threat. The recent jurispru-
dence of the Court suggests that it is still considered important to the rule of law
and social democracy.
As stated above, an alternative view of P1–1 would put less emphasis on stabil-
ity; instead of asking whether the applicant is treated as a property owner within
the national system, it would ask whether the applicant should be treated as
property owner. This, for example, appears to be the view of at least some of
the Irish members of the Constituent Assembly, as they argued that property is
a human right antecedent to any positive law.43 However, the impact of this
43
See: Council of Europe, Collected edition of the travaux préparatoires of the European
Convention on Human Rights (Nijhoff/Kluwer, 1975), vol. 2, p 88 (Mr MacEntee) and pp 102–3
(Mr de Valera).
The Autonomous Meaning of ‘Possessions’ under the ECHR 71
The Federal Constitutional Court has said that the overarching purpose of the
protecting fundamental rights in the Basic Law is the protection of personal
liberty and autonomy. The leading case on the purpose of Article 14 is the
Hamburg Flood Control Case. In 1964, after severe flooding, Hamburg enacted
legislation which provided that all land classified as ‘dikeland’ would be con-
verted in the land register to public property. All private rights to the land were
terminated. Owners were compensated, but several claimed that the Act
infringed their rights under Article 14. Their ownership of the land was not dis-
puted; hence, although the case is not specifically about the meaning or scope of
Article 14 ‘property’, it is important because it sets out the Court’s view of the
purpose of Article 14:
Article 14(I)(I) of the Basic Law guarantees property both as a legal institution and as
a concrete right held by the individual owner. To hold property is an elementary con-
stitutional right which must be seen in close context with the protection of personal
liberty. Within the general system of constitutional rights, its function is to secure its
holder a sphere of liberty in the economic field and thereby enable him [258] to lead a
self-governing life.45 . . .
[T]he property guarantee under Article 14(I)(2) must be seen in relationship to the per-
sonhood of the owner—i.e., to the realm of freedom within which persons engage in
self-defining, responsible activity. The property right is not primarily a material but
rather a personal guarantee.46
44
Basic Law for the Federal Republic of Germany (1995) 18 Official translation, Press and
Information Service, Federal Government, Bonn.
45
24 BVerfGE 367 (trans. by DP Kommers, The Constitutional Jurisprudence of the Federal
Republic of Germany 2nd edition (1997), at 251).
46
Ibid, at 252.
72 Tom Allen
47
The Constitutional Jurisprudence of the Federal Republic of Germany 2nd edition (1997), at
253.
48
58 BVerfGE 300 (trans. Ibid, at 257).
The Autonomous Meaning of ‘Possessions’ under the ECHR 73
law represented in the Civil Code does not exclusively define the content and limits of
property.49
This brief summary shows that Article 14 property is not based simply on pri-
vate law; nor is it expanded only to the extent necessary to secure expectations
based on the conduct of State officials. While it overlaps with private law prop-
erty, in difficult cases its extent is determined by the need to protect personal
autonomy. The ‘realm of freedom within which persons engage in self-defining,
responsible activity’ includes the ‘protection of economic existence’, because
economic measures can restrict the individual’s capacity to engage in the ‘self-
defining, responsible activity’ necessary to develop the personality. In constitu-
tional terms, this interest is best described as property, and the justification for
measures that interfere with this interest must be justified according to the prin-
ciples of Article 14.
49 Ibid (trans, by Kommers, 258, 259). The FCC also indicated that s 905 of the Civil Code did
not give an accurate picture of the private law of property, since the exploitation of the sub-
urface of land had long been subject to a variety of restrictions; hence, it could not be said that an
owner necessarily had a proprietary right to use the groundwater beneath the land.
50 53 BverfGE 257 (1980) (trans by Sabine Michalowski and Lorna Woods, German
Constitutional Law: The Protection of Civil Liberties (Aldershot: Ashgate, 1999), at 320.
51 Ibid (trans. Michalowski and Woods at 321).
52 Ibid.
53 Ibid.
74 Tom Allen
several early Commission decisions link the idea of possessions with person-
hood and autonomy, in the sense that basic subsistence requires a minimum
level of wealth and, if this wealth is not secured by property, life becomes too
precarious for an autonomous existence. In these decisions, the Commission
stated that social security claims may be treated as possessions, but only if there
is a direct link between contributions made by the claimant and the entitlement
to the claim.54 The emphasis on the link between contributions and possessions
reflects the jurisprudence on Article 6, where a claim to social welfare may be
regarded as a ‘civil right’. Although civil rights generally arise only under private
law, the Court has indicated that statutory claims to social insurance may also
qualify as civil rights. In Feldbrugge v Netherlands, the Court observed that
social insurance schemes have both public and private features; where the
private features dominate, the claim is a ‘civil right’.55 It found that the private
features dominated the social insurance scheme in that case, because (1) the
right in question was ‘a personal, economic and individual right’56 and the inter-
ference with it affected the applicant’s means of subsistence, (2) the right was a
positive statutory right, and not merely a possibility of benefiting from the exer-
cise of a discretionary power (3) it was ‘closely linked’ with a private contract of
employment57 because the applicant contributed directly to the statutory
scheme by salary deductions.58 Subsequently, the Court relaxed its approach. In
Salesi v Italy,59 the applicant argued that a statutory right to social assistance for
those unfit to work was a civil right under Article 6(1). There was no link with
a private law contract, and the applicant had not contributed to the statutory
scheme; nevertheless, the Court found that the applicant held a ‘civil right’,
because ‘she suffered an interference with her means of subsistence and was
claiming an individual, economic right flowing from specific rules laid down in
a statute’.60 The emphasis on the importance of the economic means of subsis-
tence has clear parallels with the reasoning of the Federal Constitutional Court
in the Equalisation of Pensions upon Dissolution of Marriage Case and, in par-
ticular, the emphasis on autonomy and the protection of economic existence.
Feldbrugge v Netherlands and Salesi v Italy dealt with Article 6 but, to an
extent, the Court has taken a similar view on the characterisation of social secu-
rity rights under P1–1. There are important differences between ‘civil rights’ and
‘possessions’; in particular, while possessions are civil rights, civil rights are not
54
See: X v UK (1970) 13 Yearbook 892; X v The Netherlands (1971) 14 Yearbook 224; Müller v
Austria [1976] 3 DR 25.
55 Feldbrugge v Netherlands Series A No 99, (1986) 8 EHRR 425, §§ 36–40; see also Deumeland
v Federal Republic of Germany, Series A vol 100, (1986) 8 EHRR 448, §§ 70–4.
56 Ibid, §37.
57 Ibid, §38.
58 Ibid, §39.
59 Salesi v Italy Series A No 257–E, (1998) 26 EHRR 187
60 Ibid, para 19. See also Schuler-Zgraggen v Switzerland Series A. No 263, (1993) 16 EHRR 405,
§46, where the Court stated that “the principle of equality of treatment warrant[s] taking the view
that today the general is that Article 6(1) does apply in the field of social insurance, including even
welfare assistance”.
The Autonomous Meaning of ‘Possessions’ under the ECHR 75
necessarily possessions. Article 6 is only concerned with the right to a fair hear-
ing; its focus is on procedural fairness rather than substantive fairness. It there-
fore applies to a wider range of rights than P1–1, but the protection given to
those rights is narrower. In a number of cases, such Marckx and Inze, Court has
stressed the difference between a right to property and a right of property. The
distinction may have been partly dissolved by the Pressos case, but in social wel-
fare cases the Court still seems to lay greater stress on the form of the rights in
question. In particular, in Gaygusuz v Austria, it appears that it is sufficient to
establish that a claim has the characteristics of a vested right under the relevant
statute, as opposed to a purely discretionary allowance. Gaygusuz v Austria
dealt with the claim of a Turkish national to emergency assistance under
Austria’s Unemployment Insurance Act. He had worked in Austria for over ten
years and met all the statutory conditions for entitlement, except a condition
which limited assistance to Austrian citizens. The Court held that Austria vio-
lated Article 14 in combination with P1–1. While the Court observed that only
those who had made contributions to the scheme were entitled to assistance
under the statute, it also stated that a statutory right to emergency assistance
is a
pecuniary right for the purposes of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1–1). That provision
(P1–1) is therefore applicable without it being necessary to rely solely on a link
between entitlement to emergency assistance and an obligation to pay ‘taxes or other
contributions.61
61
Gaygusuz v Austria (1997) 23 EHRR 364, §41.
76 Tom Allen
CONCLUSION
This paper has attempted to describe the autonomous meaning doctrine and
offer an explanation for why it has developed. It is worth mentioning two
important qualifications on its analysis of the Court’s jurisprudence. The first is
the Court’s own analysis of the autonomous meaning doctrine tends to be brief.
The reasoning discloses very little in the way of explaining, distinguishing and
applying earlier judgments in order to justify a result or lay down principles for
The Autonomous Meaning of ‘Possessions’ under the ECHR 77
* The author acknowledges the valuable advice and comments of Elizabeth Cooke of the
University of Reading, Dr Elise Histed of Monash University and Dr John Mee of Cork University.
1 JE Hogg, The Australian Torrens System (William Clowes & Sons, London, 1905), at 1–2.
2 Hereafter the LRA 2002. The Act, which replaces the Land Registration Act 1925, does not
7 Eg, K and SF Gray, Land Law (Butterworths, London, 1999) at para 9.7 states that the Torrens
legislation ‘was in many ways, the inspirational force behind the LRA 1925’; see also SR Simpson,
Land Law and Registration (Cambridge, CUP, 1976) at 78.
8 Eg, TB Ruoff, An Englishman Looks at the Torrens System (Sydney, Law Book Co, 1957), at
6: ‘Modern land registration was invented almost simultaneously and quite independently in both
England and South Australia’. Anderson states that ‘what emerged [in England] was an indigenous
scheme’: JS Anderson, Lawyers and the Making of English Land Law 1832–1940 (Oxford,
Clarendon Press, 1992)., at 171. See also Ontario Law Reform Commission Report on Land
Registration (Department of Justice, Ontario, 1971), at 15.
9
Simpson, above n 7, at 78; Garro, above n 6, at 76 and fn 6
10
The registration of title legislation of Alberta, Saskatchewan, Manitoba and the Northwest
Territories and Yukon is based closely on the Australasian model, British Columbia has a modified
form of the Torrens system. Ontario and Nova Scotia followed English legislation: Hogg, above
n 4, at 14; V Di Castri, above n 3, at paras [12]–[16].
11 For example, the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe defines ‘registration of
title’ as ‘a system whereby a register of ownership is maintained based upon the parcel rather than
the owner or the deeds of transfer’. ‘Land registration’ is used as a broader term to mean ‘the process
of recording rights in land either in the form of registration of deeds or else through the registration
of title to land’: Land Administration Guidelines (UN, New York and Geneva, 1996), glossary,
at 91.
12 Ruoff, above n 8 at 1
Registration of Title in England and Australia 83
‘the great dominions’ that England had a system of registered title comparable
in its aims to that of the Torrens system.13
The mutual ignorance that Ruoff perceived has persisted. Believing the
English system to be unique, Torrens jurisdictions pay insufficient notice to
English legislative innovation and the outstanding law reform work of the UK
Law Commission. For their part, English practitioners, legal commentators and
law reformers apparently assume that Torrens cases, scholarship and law
reform are of little relevance to them. RJ Smith has remarked on the failure of
the UK Law Commission to consider the Torrens cases with respect to the
meaning of good faith and the registration of forged transfers,14 while Jackson
criticized English courts for ignoring relevant Torrens case law.15 The failure to
pool ideas and experience impoverishes both systems. It also discourages the
comparative study that can deepen our understanding of our own system.
The problem lies partly in over-generalisation about foreign registration
systems. Some commentators speak of ‘the Torrens system’ as if it were a mono-
lithic institution that operates uniformly in all the jurisdictions of the Torrens
‘family’. We should be wary of generalisations about ‘the Torrens system’ that
refer to more than one country or legislative unit. While they may have a com-
mon ancestor, today’s much-amended ‘Torrens’ statutes draw inspiration from
multiple sources, and are modified by reference to local needs and experience.
The six Australian states and two territories each have their own registration
of title statutes, by no means uniform. The statutes, and the judicial interpreta-
tions of them are, however, sufficiently similar that it is feasible to group them
together as one system for purposes of an international comparative study.16
The statutes of Australia, New Zealand, and the prairie provinces and territo-
ries of Canada share a number of similar provisions, a factor which has enabled
them to develop, to some extent, a common jurisprudence. This case law has
also influenced the development of registration law in other Torrens jurisdic-
tions such as Malaysia and Singapore.17
The aim of this paper is to provide a foundation for the comparative study of
English and ‘Torrens’ systems of title registration. The paper offers a theoreti-
cal framework for comparative analysis, highlighting those rules that have a
substantive effect on the rights of individuals. While many of the observations
relating to the Australian system can be applied to other Torrens jurisdictions,
I have selected a single comparator from the Torrens group to avoid the risk of
over-generalisation. In the latter part of the paper, I will explore the reasons for
the misconception that the systems are fundamentally and originally distinct,
and advance my own theory of the essential differences between them.
13
Ibid.
14
RJ Smith, ‘Forgeries and Land Registration’ (1985) 101 LQR 79 at 95.
15
D Jackson, ‘Security of Title in Registration Land’ (1978) 94 LQR 239 at 241, 247–54.
16
JE Hogg, The Australian Torrens System above n 1, at 2.
17
Bhagwan Singh & Co Sdn Bhd v Hock Hin Bros Sdn Bhd [1987] 1 MLJ 324 at 326 (Penang
High Court).
84 Pamela O’Connor
As both the English and Australian are mature systems that have virtually
completed the registration of eligible land parcels, the focus of this comparison
will be on dealings following first registration.
While lawyers tend to view registration of title as a law reform project to over-
come problems in common law conveyancing, governments and economists
regard it as a market-supporting mechanism operated as a government
program.18 The system is, as Mapp said, ‘overwhelmingly administrative in
operation’,19 with economic objects, namely, to improve security of title and to
facilitate the transfer of interests in land.20 These two objects are found in the
preamble to the very first English registration of title statute, the Land Registry
Act 1862, which began: ‘Whereas it is expedient to give certainty to the title of
real estates and to facilitate the proof thereof and also to render the dealing with
land more simple and economical’.
Economists have long recognised that secure property rights are a precondi-
tion for investment and economic growth.21 Puzzled by the difficulty of repli-
cating the economic success of Western capitalism in the Third World,
economists have in the past decade turned their attention to examining the
nature of the legal institutions and property laws that underpin capitalism in
developed countries.22 The new ‘institutional economics’ has rediscovered a
long-overlooked connection between property laws and prosperity.23 Laws that
ensure the security and transferability of property establish the framework of
incentives that enable the creation of new wealth from existing assets.
Secure titles have been found to contribute to economic growth in a multi-
plicity of ways.24 They provide owners with an incentive to invest in improving
and developing their land, for they are assured of reaping the benefits for them-
18 World Bank Development Report, 2002: Building Institutions for Markets; Economic
St Martin’s Press, 1998), esp ch 1; H De Soto, The Mystery of Capital (Bantam Press, London, 2000);
TJ Miceli, CF Sirmans and J Kieyah, ‘The Demand for Land Title Registration: Theory with
Evidence from Kenya’ (2001) 3 American Law and Economics Review 275–87.
23
Bethell, Ibid chs 1, 2, 20.
24
An economic consultant to the World Bank has developed an analytical and conceptual model
to explain the various ways in which land ownership security contributes to financial development
and economic growth: FK Byamugisha, ‘The Effects of Land Registration on Financial
Development and Economic Growth: A Theoretical and Conceptual Framework’, Policy Research
Working Paper N 2240 (World Bank, November 1999) .
Registration of Title in England and Australia 85
selves. Owners who wish to invest are better able to obtain the development
capital they need on favourable terms if they can offer a good title as collateral
for a loan. If purchasers can easily satisfy themselves that the title they are
acquiring is clear, the costs of transacting in land will fall. Lower transaction
costs assist the market to allocate land assets to their most productive uses, by
allowing them to pass to those who value them most highly.25
A title to land is secure if it is at no risk, or no significant risk, of being found
to be defective or subordinate to another interest. While economists assume that
security of title is a good that property laws can bestow, it is, as Mapp said, ‘an
elusive ideal’,26 for it incorporates contradictory elements. There are two com-
peting aspects of security of title, that Demogue called ‘static’ and ‘dynamic’
security.27
Static security
The law of private conveyancing was based on the principle of static security,
which protects the rights of existing owners at the expense, if necessary, of
purchasers.28 This was achieved through rules such as nemo dat quod non
habet,29 the preference of both law and equity for the interest first in time when
adjudicating the priority of competing interests, and the doctrines of notice and
equitable fraud. Equity’s preference for the ‘bona fide purchaser for value with-
out notice’, was an attempt to balance static security against the reasonable
expectations of purchasers in good faith, but the standard of inquiry required of
purchasers under the extended doctrine of notice was onerous.
Conveyancing rules based on static security suited a society emerging from
feudalism, where land ownership was confined to the privileged few, and was
rarely traded. By the mid nineteenth century, England and Australia were devel-
oping market economies, in which value is captured through exchange. The old
conveyancing rules inhibited exchange of land by imposing high transaction
costs upon purchasers, and exposing them to the risk of acquiring defective or
subordinate titles.
Dynamic security
The key elements of a system of registered title are designed to relieve pur-
chasers of the risks of unwittingly acquiring a defective or subordinate title.
30
Di Castri, above n 3, vol 1, [6].
31
So called because the need for dynamic security arises from change in the ownership of land.
32
GW Paton and DP Derham (eds), A Textbook of Jurisprudence 4th edn (Clarendon Press,
Oxford, 1972) at 447; PS Atiyah, The Sale of Goods (Pitman, London, 1957).
33
De Soto, above n 22, at 61.
34
Demogue, above n 27, at 429–30.
Registration of Title in England and Australia 87
These ‘dynamic risks’35 created by the old law of private conveyancing left pur-
chasers with the following problems:36
(1) determining the validity of all the instruments through which the grantor derived
title;
(2) determining the validity of the immediate conveyance from the grantor to the
grantee;
(3) the possible existence of unknown legal interests granted by the grantor or a for-
mer owner; and
(4) the possible existence of unknown prior equitable interests or equities that are
enforceable against a grantee, unless he or she is a bona fide purchaser for value with-
out notice.
Dynamic risks (3) and (4) relate to the priority of competing interests in
land,37 and can be solved by deeds registration or interest recording schemes.38
These are schemes that establish a public register of instruments or interests and
rules for determining priority between them, usually by reference to the date of
registration. The English Land Charges Act 1972 incorporates such a scheme.
The system of registered title relieves against risks (3) and (4) by providing that,
except in case of fraud or acquisition by a volunteer,39 the priority of registered
interests inter se is determined by their date of registration (or lodgment for
registration).
Dynamic risks (1) and (2) do not raise a question of priority but arise from the
operation of the common law principle nemo dat quod non habet. Under this
principle, a purchaser does not obtain a good title if the transfer from seller to
purchaser is void, or if any of the instruments through which the seller’s title
devolves are void. Interest recording statutes alone cannot eliminate risks (1)
and (2), although the American solution is to insure privately against the risks
that flow from them.
The principal technique that registration of title systems use to address all
four dynamic risks is the concept of State-guaranteed title. This has, as Hogg
explained, a dual operation:
35
Willett uses the term ‘dynamic losses’ to mean the losses arising from change of ownership, and
‘dynamic risks’ to mean the risk of such losses: AH Willett, The Economic Theory of Risk and
Insurance, (Richard Irwin, Illinois, 1951), at 13–22.
36
This exposition of the problems is based on the analysis of Mapp, as simplified in the report of
Canada’s Joint Land Titles Committee: Mapp, above n 19, Ch 2 and summary at 41–2; Canada.
Joint Land Titles Committee, Renovating the foundation: proposals for a model land recording
and registration act for the provinces and territories of Canada (The Committee, Edmonton, 1990),
at 6.
37
With respect to problem (3), there is a debate as to whether the law’s preference for first in time
is a priority rule or an application of nemo dat quod non habet. The latter view is supported by
AJ Bradbrook, SV McCallum and AP Moore, Australian Real Property Law 2nd edn (Law Book Co,
Sydney, 1997), at para [3.06]; M Neave, CJ Rossiter and MA Stone, Sackville & Neave’s Property
Law: Cases and Materials 6th edn (Butterworths, Sydney, 1999), at para [5.2.6].
38
Mapp, above n 19, at 56.
39
Not all jurisdictions make an exception for volunteers, as explained below under the heading
‘registered volunteers’.
88 Pamela O’Connor
The warranty of title given by the statutory conclusiveness of the register operates in
two ways, and the register has two functions—affirmative and negative respectively.
Affirmatively, the register warrants that the title of the owner is as stated on the regis-
ter; and negatively, the warranty is that the owner’s title is not affected by anything
that is not stated on the register. This is equivalent for many purposes to a warranty
that the owner’s legal title is as it appears to be on the register, and that there are no
equitable interests enforceable against the owner, other than any actually notified on
the register.40
The conclusiveness of the register finds its counterpart in the concept of the
‘indefeasibility’ of registered title, as it is called in the Torrens jurisdictions. The
term should not be taken literally.41 Torrens titles are no more absolute than the
English concept of ‘absolute title’.
The affirmative aspect of the conclusive register overcomes dynamic risk (1)
by curing prior title defects. It substitutes for the chain of title a single status
indicator—a registered title, affirmed by the state. Except as allowed by statute,
it cannot be challenged by reason of a defect in the chain of instruments and
transactions through which the previous owner derived title.
The affirmative operation of the register can also overcome dynamic risk (2),
which is the risk that the immediate conveyance from the previous registered
owner to the purchaser is void or voidable. The extent to which the system
should relieve against this risk is perhaps the most important policy question in
registration law. As I will explain below, the Australian system goes further to
eliminate dynamic risk (2) than the English.
The negative aspect of the conclusive register reduces dynamic risks (3) and
(4). By protecting registered owners from being affected by notice of prior inter-
ests, it reinforces the rule that interests rank in priority by their date of registra-
tion. In both the English and Australian systems, even actual notice of a prior
unregistered interest does not per se make it enforceable against a purchaser who
registers.42 All the Australian statutes have a ‘notice’ provision that states that a
transferee is not affected by actual or constructive notice of any unregistered
interests and is not required to inquire into the circumstances under which the
transferor or the previous proprietor was registered.43 As in England, difficult
questions have arisen concerning the dividing line between ‘mere notice’ and
conduct amounting to fraud or lack of good faith on the part of the transferee.44
40
Above n 4, at 96. All Australian statutes embody this principle in the ‘indefeasibility’ provision,
eg Transfer of Land Act 1958 (Vic), s 42. The LRA 1925 followed a similar format: ss 20(1) and
23(1), cf the LRA 2002, s 58 (affirmative operation of registration) and negative operation: (ss 11, 12
and Sched 1; ss 28–30 and Sched 3).
41 Mapp says that the epithet ‘indefeasible’ is deceptive, and notes that Torrens statutes generally
above n 42, at para [6–105]; (2001) UK Law Com. No 271, at paras 3.39–3.50; Bradbrook,
Registration of Title in England and Australia 89
The combined negative and affirmative operation of the title register gives
registered owners a degree of dynamic security that could not be achieved under
the law of unregistered conveyancing. It facilitates the transfer of land by reduc-
ing dynamic risks and transaction costs. It is, however, subject to various
qualifications and exclusions, as detailed below.
Overriding interests
As in England and Wales, all the Australian registration of title statutes provide
for a list of ‘overriding interests’ that bind the registered owner whether shown
on the register or not. The list varies from one jurisdiction to another, com-
monly including short term occupation tenancies, rates and taxes, public rights
and certain easements.45 The term ‘overriding interest’ does not designate a
homogenous group of interests. It is best understood as a legislative device for
subjecting registered titles to interests that are deemed worthy of ‘passive’
protection, in circumstances where the persons entitled to the benefit of the
interests cannot reasonably be expected to enter them on the register.
Some of the Australian statutes, like the 1925 English Act,46 treat the interests
of squatters as an overriding interest.47 While recognition of squatters’ rights
detracts from the completeness of the register as a mirror of title, there is a prac-
tical need to reconcile the register with the change of possession on the
ground.48 In an attempt to resolve the dilemma, legislatures have experimented
with various measures for dealing with possessory rights in a system of title by
registration. This has produced some instability and variation in the rules of the
various jurisdictions.
None of the Australian statutes provide a wide exception for the interests of
a person in actual occupation of land, like that found in the English legislation.49
The English provision protects the static security of persons occupying land
McCallum & Moore, above n 37, at paras [4.40]–[4.46]; P; MP Thompson, ‘Registration, Fraud and
Notice’ (1985) 44(2) Cambridge Law Journal 280.
45 For a summary of the exceptions to the indefeasibility of registered titles in each of the
Australian jurisdictions, presented in tabular form, see Neave, Rossiter & Stone, above n 37, at
494–5.
46 LRA 1925 (UK), s 70(1)(f). The provision has not been replicated in the 2002 Act, but squat-
ters’ rights will be protected as overriding interests for three years under the transitional provisions:
Sched 12, paras 7, 11.
47 Victoria, Queensland, Western Australian and Tasmania: see generally Bradbrook, McCallum
mit flexibility in reconciling the possession of land with its ownership’: above n 11, at, 21.
49 LRA 2002, Sched 3, cl 2 (cf s 70(1)(g) of the 1925 Act) and similar provisions in the Registration
of Title Act 1964 (Ir), s 72(1)(j) and the Land Registration Act (NI) 1970, Sched 5, pt 1, para 15).
90 Pamela O’Connor
under informal agreements, who may be unlikely to appreciate the need to pro-
tect their interests by an entry in the register.50 As interpreted by the House of
Lords in Williams & Glyn’s Bank Ltd v Boland,51 the provision in the 1925 Act
has been criticised for the dynamic risks (or burden of inquiry and risk) that it
places on purchasers and mortgagees.52
In Australia, such interests would be destroyed by registration of a later inter-
est, unless the unregistered claimants took timely action to enter a caveat or to
assert their rights in court. Neither the English nor the Australian approach is
entirely satisfactory, but there seems to be no middle course. Either the unregis-
tered interests are extinguished by a purchaser’s registration, or they override it.
Faced with this invidious choice, the 1925 English Act prefers the static security
of the occupying owners,53 while Australia opts to maximise dynamic security.
Voluntary transfers
50
(1998) Law Com. No 254, at para 4.17. See, eg Hodgson v Marks [1971] 1 Ch 892.
51
[1981] AC 487.
52
Property Law: The implications of Williams & Glyn’s Bank Ltd. v Boland (‘the Boland report’)
(1982) Law Com, No 115, esp at para 28; but see (1987) Law Com. No 158, at para 1.3 as to subse-
quent developments. The Commission resiled from its recommendations in the Boland report,
and found that practitioners had come to terms with the implications of the court’s decision: para
2.7.
53 As to whether the LRA 2002, s 26 diminishes the protection for beneficial interests, see Ferris,
ch 6.
54 LRA 2002, ss 29–30 (cf LRA 1925, s 20(1),(4); s 23(1), (5)).
55 Ibid.
56 [1958] VR 273. See also Biggs v McEllister (1880) 14 SALR 86; Washington Constructions v
Ashcroft (1982) Q Conv R paras [54–056]; Official Receiver v Klau (1987) 74 ALR 67; Rasmussen v
Rasmussen [1995] 1 VR 613.
57 (1988) 12 NSWLR 472.
58 A registered owner who had taken under a will was held to have an indefeasible title and was
not subject to an equitable interest created by the previous registered owner. In Rasmussen v
Registration of Title in England and Australia 91
has found favour in Western Australia,59 and has been legislatively adopted in
Queensland and the Northern Territory.60
The conflict in the Australian authorities is partly due to equivocation in the
statutes, but also to competing policy arguments. In Australia and Canada, all
law reform bodies who have examined the question in recent years have con-
cluded that registration should afford volunteers the same protection from prior
equities as it does to purchasers for value.61 The principal argument for extend-
ing dynamic security to registered volunteers, is that it enables the owner to use
his or her land assets to generate new wealth.62 It is not in the interests of
general economic welfare to allow the titles of volunteers to remain clouded.
Rectification of titles
Dynamic risk (2) is the risk that a purchaser will not get a good title if the imme-
diate conveyance from the previous owner is void or voidable for any reason, eg,
forgery, fraudulent misrepresentation, illegality or breach of mandatory statu-
tory procedures. The extent of protection from this risk depends on whether the
statute allows rectification of the register adversely to the purchaser’s registered
title.
The original Torrens statutes gave conflicting indications on whether
rectification could be ordered against a registered title obtained without fraud
on the basis of a void instrument.63 As a result, this important question was left
to the judges to decide. After decades of conflict in the judicial authorities, the
High Court of Australia decided in 1971 that a title obtained by registration of
a void instrument was not liable to rectification in the absence of fraud.64
Rasmussen [1995] 1 VR 613 (Supreme Court of Victoria), Coldrey J doubted the correctness of this
decision.
59
Conlan v Registrar of Titles (2001) 24 WAR 299.
60
Land Title Act 1994 (Qld), s 180; Land Title Act 2000 (NT), s 183.
61
Victorian Law Reform Commission, Discussion Paper No 6: Priorities, (1988) at para 10, p 5;
and Report No 22: Priorities (1989), at paras 7–8 and recommendation 3; Canada, Joint Land Titles
Committee, above n 36 at 36–7, and s 5.3(1) of the Model Act; Alberta Law Reform Institute. and
Canada. Joint Land Titles Committee, Towards a new Alberta Land Titles Act (Alberta Law
Reform Institute, Edmonton, 1990), at 64.
62
RF Atherton, ‘Donees, Devisees and Torrens Title: The Problem of the Volunteer Under the
Real Property Acts’. (1998) 4(2) Australian Journal of Legal History 121, at 157–9; Mapp, above
n 19, 124–8; and see Law Reform reports, ibid.
63
Neave, Rossiter & Stone, above n 37, at paras [6.3.27]–[6.3.32]. Whalan says that no distinc-
tion has been made in the cases between void and voidable instruments, since the central question is
whether it is registration or the instrument that confers title: D Whalan, The Torrens System in
Australia (Sydney, Law Book Co, 1982), at 319–20; P Butt, Land Law 4th ed (Law Book Co, Sydney,
2001), at 298, fn 25.
64
Breskvar v Wall (1971) 126 CLR 376: [1972] ALR 205, following Frazer v Walker [1967] 1 AC
569; [1967] 1 All ER 649, on appeal to the Privy Council from New Zealand. Ziff says that ‘the pre-
ponderant view in Torrens jurisdictions today favours indefeasibility: B Ziff, Principles of Property
92 Pamela O’Connor
‘Fraud’ means actual fraud by the applicant for registration or his or her agent.65
The adoption of this principle of ‘immediate indefeasibility’ dramatically
reduced dynamic risk (2), but this came at a cost to static security. As Mapp
observed:
To whatever extent C [a purchaser] can acquire an interest from a predecessor
through error, he is vulnerable to losing that interest to a successor through the same
error repeated after his registration.66
In Australia, actual fraud on the part of the registered owner or his or her agent
is the only ground upon which the register may be rectified adversely to a regis-
tered owner who took bona fide and for value.
Law 3rd edn (Carswell, Ontario, 2000), at 426. See, eg, Adorna Properties Sdn Bhd v Boonsom
Boonyanit @Sun Yon Eng [2001] 1 MLJ 241 at 246 (Malaysia) and Administration of the Territory
of Papua New Guinea v Blasius Tirupia [1971–72] PNGLR 229 (Papua New Guinea). However, Di
Castri says that the majority of Canadian decisions on the subject of forged instruments do not
accept the principle: Di Castri, above n 3, vol 2, at para [758].
65 Assets Company Ltd v Mere Roihi [1905] AC 176.
66 Mapp, above n 19, at 68; W Taylor, ‘Scotching Frazer v Walker’ (1970) 44 Australian Law
Journal 248–60.
67 LRA 2002, Sched 4, cl 2(1).
68 LRA 2002, Sched 4, cl 3 and s 131.
69 LRA 2002, s 131(2)(b).
70 LRA 2002, s 103 and Sched 8, cl 1(a).
71 Di Castri, above n 3, vol 2, at para [980], commenting on another statute.
Registration of Title in England and Australia 93
Fraud may have a narrower scope under the English rectification provi-
sions,72 where it has been held to mean a fraud practised on the registry in order
to obtain registration.73 In the more usual case where the fraud is practised on
the former registered owner, the remedy in England might be an in personam
action.74
Rectification of boundaries
Conveyancing, (Sweet & Maxwell, London, loose-leaf orig. 1991) at para 2–04).
76 For a list of the Australian provisions, see Bradbrook, McCallum & Moore, above n 37, at
In personam remedies
The English and Australian systems recognise that the conclusive effect of
registration does not prevent the assertion of claims against the registered owner
personally (eg, arising from mistake, breach of contract or a trust obligation
incurred by the proprietor).81 These claims can lead to an order against the reg-
istered owner in personam for the transfer of a title.82
Courts have occasionally used the device of a constructive trust to deem the
registered owner to take subject to a prior interest in cases where the registered
owner had expressly or impliedly agreed to do so.83 In England and in Australia,
commentators have cautioned that ‘the trusteeship concept must be very care-
fully and sparingly used in the context of indefeasibility’ lest it undermine the
objects of the registration system.84
The general scheme of the English and Australian statutes is to allow registra-
tion only of estates and interests that existed as ‘legal’ interests under the gen-
eral law.85 Trusts and other equitable interests are excluded from the register in
the interests of simplicity and ease of transfer. In England, trusts are protected
by the entry of a restriction,86 a device broadly similar in function to the regis-
trar’s caveat used in some Australian jurisdictions.87
In both systems, unregistered interests take effect in equity, and are liable to
be destroyed by the registration of another disposition unless they are protected
under the provisions of the Act. In Australia, protection is available through the
entry of a caveat against dealings. The function and operation of the caveat is
similar to that of the caution against dealings under the Land Registration Act
1925 (UK), s 54(1).88 It halts the registration of a subsequent adverse dealing
until the person who lodged the caveat has been notified and has been given the
81 Frazer v Walker [1967] 1 AC 569 at 582; Harpum, above n 42, at para [6–195].
82 Ziff suggests that claims for proprietary relief should be termed inter se rather than in per-
sonam: Ziff, above n 64 at 431.
83 Eg Waimiha Sawmilling Co v Waione Timber Co [1926] AC 101; Lyus v Prowsa Developments
Ltd [1982] 1 WLR 1044; Bahr v Nicolay (No 2) (1988) 164 CLR 604.
84 Whalan, above n 76, 335; M-A Hughson, M Neave and P O’Connor. ‘Reflections on the
Mirror of Title: Resolving the Conflict Between Purchasers and Prior Interest Holders’ (1997) 21
Melbourne University Law Review 96., at 490–3. See criticism of this device when imposed solely
on the basis of notice, as in Peffer v Rigg [1977] 1 WLR 285: RJ Smith ‘Registered Land: Purchasers
with Actual Notice’ (1977) 93 LQR 341., at 343–4; MP Thompson, above n 44, at 287–302.
85 LRA 2002, s 27.
86 LRA 2002, ss 40–6.
87 Eg, in New South Wales, the caveat forbids the registration of an instrument not in accordance
with the terms of the trust: S Colbran and SM Jackson, Caveats (FT Law & Tax, Melbourne, 1996),
at [3.2.2].
88 Stein, above n 85 at 618.
Registration of Title in England and Australia 95
Like the caution under the 1925 English Act, the Australian caveat does not
confirm or affect the validity of the interest claimed by the person who lodged
it.90 For so long as it remains on title, the caveat prevents the registration of a
dealing that affects the interest of the caveator.91 If the caveator chooses to
assert his or her claim in court, the matter is disposed of as a priority contest
between the caveator and the person whose application for registration has been
stopped.
Priority disputes involving unregistered interests in registered land have pro-
duced more litigation in Australia than in England,92 although the rules for their
adjudication are the same as under the 1925 English Act. The disputes are
resolved under the rules that determine the priority of equitable interests in
unregistered land.93 The interest created first in time prevails, unless its holder’s
conduct warrants postponement to the later interest.94 The Australian courts
tend to the same view that the English courts took under the LRA 1925, namely
that failure to protect a minor interest by registration of a caveat/caution is not
per se conduct justifying loss of priority to a later interest.95
89
Leros Pty Ltd v Terara Pty Ltd (1991) 174 CLR 407 at 419; cf LRA 1925, s 56(4); Ruoff &
Roper, above n 75, at para [7–03].
90
Clark v Chief Land Registrar [1993] Ch 294; LRA 1925, ss 56(4), 102(2); Harpum, above n 42,
at para [6–090]; Ruoff & Roper, above n 75, at 824
91 The statutes do authorise the registrar to register certain dealings adverse to the caveator’s
interest. See generally, Bradbrook, McCallum & Moore, above n 37, at paras [4.88], [4.89]. The
effect of the caveat in interdicting registration is the same as that of the caution under the LRA 1925:
Willies-Williams v National Trust (1993) 65 P & CR 359 at 362; Harpum, above n 42, at para
[6–083].
92
While it is beyond the scope of this paper to evaluate the reasons for this difference, factors
contributing to the lower rate of litigation in England, including different conveyancing practices,
the protection for persons in actual occupation, and the role of the Chief Land Registrar in settling
disputes.
93 Bradbrook, above n 37, at para [4.80]; Colbran, above n 87 at [11.6], R Sackville, ‘Competing
Equitable Interests in Land under the Torrens System’ (1971) 45 Australian Law Journal 396.
94 Abigail v Lapin (1934) AC 491; Heid v Reliance Finance Corporation Pty Ltd (1983) 154 CLR
326; cf McArthy & Stone Ltd v Julian S Hodge & Co Ltd [1971] 1 WLR 1547; Barclays Bank Ltd v
Taylor [1974] Ch 137 at 146–7; Mortgage Corporation Ltd v Nationwide Credit Corporation Ltd
[1994] Ch 49 at 56; Ruoff & Roper, above n 75, at para [36–03]; Harpum, above n 42, at para
[6–095].
95
J & JH Just (Holdings) Pty Ltd v Bank of New South Wales (1971) 125 CLR 546 at 554 per
Barwick CJ; cf Mortgage Corporation Ltd v Nationwide Credit Corporation Ltd [1994] Ch 49 at 56;
Freeguard v Royal Bank of Scotland (1998) 95/13 LS Gaz 29; P Stubbs, ‘Equitable Priorities and the
Failure to Caveat’ (1989) 6(2) Auckland University Law Review 199; TD Castle, ‘Caveats and pri-
orities: the ‘mere failure to caveat’ (1994) 68 Australian Law Journal 143.
96 Pamela O’Connor
Reformers in Australia and Canada have called for the caveat to be refashioned
or replaced by interest recording, a system under which the entry of an interest
on the register confers priority, but no warranty of title.96 Notices under the
LRA 1925 are a form of interest recording, re-ordering priorities as agreed by
the parties or decreed by a court.97 The LRA 2002 section 34(2) extends this
protection to disputed interests by allowing claimants to enter a notice unilater-
ally. An interest protected by a notice will take priority over a subsequent regis-
tered disposition.98 The equitable priority rules will continue to apply as
between unregistered interests, but when electronic conveyancing is fully imple-
mented, it will no longer be possible to create interests in land formally without
either registering them or entering a notice.99 When the creation of an interest
becomes simultaneous with the entry of a notice, the date of entry of a notice
will determine its priority, except against interests created by informal
means.100 This is an important reform that will be closely studied in overseas
jurisdictions like Australia, where an increased role for interest recording has
been mooted.
The English and Australian registration of title statutes provide for payment of
an indemnity to persons who suffer loss caused by certain prescribed events.
The list of losses for which indemnity is payable in Australia usually include the
following seven categories: loss in consequence of fraud, loss through the first
registration of the land, loss through the registration of another as owner, loss
sustained by reliance on the register, loss of documents in the registry or from
an error in an official search, loss arising from the exercise of the registrar’s
powers and loss in consequence of any error, omission or misdescription.101
Notwithstanding that the indemnity provisions are entitled to a beneficial inter-
pretation, the courts and the Registrars have generally interpreted these grounds
restrictively.
96 Canada, Joint Land Titles Committee, above n 36, at 13–18, and Part 4 of the Model Act;
Victorian Law Reform Commission, Report No 22 priorities (1989), Rec 10; S Colbran and SM
Jackson, Caveats (FR Law & Tax, Melbourne 1996) at 536–7; Hughson, above n 84, at 487–9.
97 LRA 1925, s 48(1), (2), s 52.
98 LRA 2002, ss 29, 30.
99 LRA 2002, s 28; Lord Chancellor’s Dept, Explanatory Notes to Land Registration Act 2002
(HMSO, 2002) at para 68. LRA 2002, s 93 authorises the making of rules prescribing dispositions to
which the requirement of simultaneous registration will apply.
100 Explanatory Notes, ibid.
101 LA McCrimmon, ‘Compensation Provisions in Torrens Statutes: The Existing Structure and
102
Simpson, above n 7, at 76–7. For an explanation of the different experience of the two coun-
tries, see D Whalan, ‘Immediate Success of Registration of Title to Land in Australasia and Early
Failures in England’ (1967) 2 NZULR 416.
103
Simpson, ibid, at 77.
104
Simpson, ibid, at 76–7; SE Dowson and VLO Sheppard, Land Registration 2nd edn (HMSO
Colonial Research Publications No 13, London, 1956), 73.
105
M Raff, German Real Property Law and the Conclusive Land Title Register, PhD Thesis,
University of Melbourne, (1999) at 14 and passim, S Robinson, Transfer of Land in Victoria (Law
Book Co, Sydney, 1979) at 11–25; D St L Kelly, ‘Huebbe, Ulrich (1805–1892)’ in D Pike (ed),
Australian Dictionary of Biography (Melbourne University Press, Melbourne, 1972), at 1851.
106 Although this idea was not entirely new, being an aspect of deeds and other instrument regis-
tration schemes.
107 Because of its Roman law origins, Raff argues that the Torrens mortgage is the clearest evi-
CONCLUSION
Despite their striking similarity, the English and Australian systems differ in the
way they balance dynamic and static security. English law protects the static
security of occupying owners by giving overriding status to the rights of holders
of unregistered interests who are in actual occupation of land.112 Australia
allows the interest of a non-fraudulent purchaser to prevail over such unregis-
tered interests unless they are protected on the register, or there are additional
circumstances that place the purchaser in the position of a constructive trustee
for the prior interest holder.
The English concession to static security is also evident in the wider grounds
for rectification allowed by the English statute, although the difference narrows
significantly where the registered owner is a ‘proprietor in possession’. Australia
pursues dynamic security more unequivocally, through its rule of immediate
indefeasibility. Under this rule, the registered interest of a purchaser for value,
including that of a mortgagee, cannot be adversely affected by rectification of
the register unless the registered owner is personally or vicariously guilty of
actual fraud. Some Australian jurisdictions even extend immediate indefeasibil-
ity to registered volunteers, provided that they are not party to fraud.
The Australian approach recognises the economic function of law in provid-
ing security for transactions, but economics provides no clear guidance as to
how much dynamic security is actually required to ensure an efficient land mar-
ket. English law has probed these limits empirically through ongoing review and
110
Raff, above n 105, at Part I; Robinson, above n 105, at Ch 1; Kelly, above n 105.
111
Raff, above n 108, at 1, fn 1; Hogg, above n 1 at 5 and fn 19, referring to information about
the continental systems in the Appendices to the Second Report of the Real Property
Commissioners, 1830, Appendix to the First Report of the Registration and Conveyancing
Commissioners in 1850, and to JW Probyn (ed), Systems of Land Tenure in Various Countries
(London, Cassell, 1881). Charles Fortescue-Brickdale, a Chief Land Registrar who influenced the
design of the English legislation, studied and wrote on the Prussian schemes: C Fortescue-Brickdale,
Methods of Land Transfer—Eight Lectures (Stevens & Sons, London, 1914), at 129–30.
112
The LRA 2002 has abolished the protection for owners of interests in receipt of rents and
profits; Sched 3 cl 2, subject to transition provision Sched 12 cl 8.
Registration of Title in England and Australia 99
reform, and has discovered that it can preserve some elements of static security
without appreciable adverse impact on the market.113 The result is a more
finely-tuned balance of dynamic and static than the Australian system.
On the other hand, the long-term trend of the English system appears to be in
the direction of more dynamic security. The English rectification provisions
were amended in 1977 to protect proprietors in possession from losing their
titles simply on the ground of an innocent error, omission or mistake.114 The
amending Act also repealed a provision that allowed rectification where the
immediate disposition to the proprietor was void.115 Roger Smith noted that
these legislative reforms paralleled the 1971 shift in the Australian case law
towards the principle of immediate indefeasibility, and offered the following
comment on the direction of the changes:
It may be that as registration systems develop, so one becomes more ready to accept
the current state of the register as conclusive, one becomes more registration-
minded.116
It is beyond the scope of this chapter to evaluate the English and Australian
systems in detail, or to propose methods for resolving the conflicts between
interests and policies. What I have sought to show is that the distinctive way in
which each system seeks to balance dynamic and static security provides the key
parameter for comparing English, Australian and other ‘Torrens’ systems of
registration of title.
113
See, eg, how the Law Commission initially rejected the wide interpretation of LRA 1925,
s 70(1)(g) in Boland, but changed its mind after finding minimal market effects: (1987) Law Com No
158, at para 2.7, above n 52.
114
Amendments to the LRA 1925, s 82(3)(a), as amended by the Administration of Justice Act,
1977, s 24.
115
LRA, 1925, s 82(3)(b).
116
Smith, above n 14, at 188.
6
Making Sense of Section 26 of the
Land Registration Act 2002
GRAHAM FERRIS
INTRODUCTION
The Land Registration Act 2002 (‘LRA 2002’) is the latest in a series of statutes
that, taken together, constitute the largest programme of reform in the field of
property law since 1925. The reform process began with the Trusts of Land and
Appointment of Trustees Act 1996 (‘TLATA’), which was followed by the
Trustee Act 2000 (‘TA 2000’). All three pieces of legislation followed reports by
the Law Commission, and were intended to give effect to the recommendations
contained in these reports. This paper is an attempt to construe a single section,
section 26 of the LRA 2002, which was enacted, at least in part, to remedy a
problem caused by the provisions of the TLATA.
The problem caused by the TLATA derives from the relationship between
trustees’ powers and overreaching.1 Overreaching occurs when trustees make a
disposition they are empowered to make by the general law, statute, or their
trust instrument. Therefore, when the TLATA changed the statutory regime
governing trustees powers it also affected the operation of overreaching.
Although purchasers of unregistered land were given protection against the
novel hazards this created in the TLATA purchasers of registered land were
excluded from this protection.2 Section 26 of the LRA 2002 was drafted with the
intention of extending to purchasers of registered land protection analogous to
the protection the TLATA extended to purchasers of unregistered land. This
intention is clearly apparent from a consideration of the report that preceded the
LRA 2002, Land Registration for the Twenty-First Century: A Conveyancing
Revolution (‘the Report’).3 It is also apparent from the Report that section 26
was intended to cure defects of legal capacity.4 Therefore, the challenge to any
1 See C Harpum, ‘Overreaching, Trustees’ Powers and the Reform of the 1925 Legislation [1990]
Cambridge Law Journal 277; State Bank of India v Sood [1997] Ch. 276; Ferris and Battersby, ‘The
General Principles of Overreaching and the Reforms of 1925’ (2002) 118 Law Quarterly Review 270.
2 See s 16 TLATA; G Ferris and G Battersby, ‘The Impact of the Trusts of Land and Appointment
STATUTORY INTERPRETATION
Section 26 of the LRA 2002 was originally clause 26 of the draft bill annexed to
the Report. The Report identified eleven ‘key features’ or ‘striking changes’ con-
tained in the annexed bill. Among these eleven striking changes was:5
in favour of those dealing with them, owners of registered land will be presumed to
have unrestricted powers of disposition in the absence of any entry on the register.
This change was effected by section 26, which is intended to remove any possi-
bility of a registered proprietor, or a person entitled to be registered as a pro-
prietor,6 making a disposition that would be invalid due to any limitation upon
their powers of disposition not imposed by the LRA 2002 or apparent upon the
face of the Register.
The task of construing section 26 has been undertaken in the manner advo-
cated by Lord Diplock and Lord Simon of Glaisdale in their joint dissenting
speech in Maunsell v Olins:7
What Maxwell on Interpretation of Statutes, 12 ed (1969), p 28, calls ‘the first and
most elementary rule of construction’ ‘is that it is to be assumed that the words and
phrases of technical legislation are used in their technical meaning if they have
acquired one, and otherwise in their ordinary meaning’. This ‘golden’ canon of con-
struction has been so frequently and authoritatively stated that further citation would
be otiose.8
Statutory language, like all language, is capable of an almost infinite gradation of ‘reg-
ister’—ie, it will be used at the semantic level appropriate to the subject matter and to
the audience addressed (the man in the street, lawyers, merchants, etc). It is the duty
of a court of construction to tune in to such register and so to interpret the statutory
language as to give to it the primary meaning which is appropriate in that register
(unless it is clear that some other meaning must be given in order to carry out the statu-
5 Ibid at 1.11–1.14.
6 In the text below the possibility of a person entitled to exercise the powers of a registered pro-
prietor, but not a registered proprietor, is usually ignored in order to avoid tedious repetition, unless
the possible existence of such a person is relevant to any issue being considered.
7 [1975] AC 373. The case concerned the construction of s 18(5) of the Rent Act 1968.
8 [1975] AC 373 at 390H–391A.
Making Sense of Section 26 of the Land Registration Act 2002 103
It is essential that this ‘golden rule’ is adhered to. An English court of construc-
tion must put itself in the place of the draftsman, and ascertain the meaning of
the words used in the light of all the circumstances known by the draftsman-
especially the ‘mischief’ which is the subject matter of the statutory remedy.10
SECTION 26
Section 26 falls into Part 3 of the LRA 2002, which is headed ‘Dispositions of
Registered Land’. Part 3 is divided into three ‘sub-parts’, headed: ‘Powers of dis-
position’; ‘Registrable dispositions’; and ‘Effect of dispositions on priority’.
Section 26 falls into the first of these sub-parts. Obviously section 26 must be
construed as an integral element of Part 3. In particular section 26 should be
read with the other provisions included in the sub-part headed ‘Powers of dis-
position’, sections 23, 24, and 25.
Section 23(1), which is headed ‘Owner’s powers’, provides:
(1) Owner’s powers in relation to a registered estate consist of–
(a) power to make a disposition of any kind permitted by the general law in rela-
tion to an interest of that description, other than a mortgage by demise or sub-demise,
and
9 Ibid at 391E.
10 Ibid at 391G.
11 S 52 LRA 2002, which is also headed ‘Protection of disponees’, provides: ‘(1) Subject to any
entry in the register to the contrary, the proprietor of a registered charge is to be taken to have, in
relation to the property subject to the charge, the powers of disposition conferred by law on the
owner of a legal mortgage. (2) Subsection (1) has effect only for the purpose of preventing the title
of a disponee being questioned (and so does not affect the lawfulness of a disposition)’.
104 Graham Ferris
(b) power to charge the estate at law with the payment of money.12
The Report
The Report refers to the provisions of clause 26 of the draft bill, which became
section 26 of the LRA 2002, in Part II (summary of the main changes made by
the bill),13 and Part IV (dispositions of registered land).14 Clause 52, which
became section 52, is referred to in Part VII (charges).15 Finally, there is a brief
reference to clauses 26 and 52 in Part IX (the register and registration).16 The
Report should help us to identify the purpose that lay behind section 26, or as
Lords Diplock and Simon of Glaisdale expressed it: ‘the “mischief” which is the
subject matter of the statutory remedy’.17
The Report informs us that the mischief sections 26 and 52 were intended to
remedy was the risk to a disponee of registered land (or an interest therein) tak-
ing an invalid title to the land (or interest therein) because the disposition was
charge consist of—(a) power to make a disposition of any kind permitted by the general law in rela-
tion to an interest of that description, other than a legal sub-mortgage, and (b) power to charge at
law with the payment of money indebtedness secured by the registered charge. (3) In subsection 2(a),
“legal sub-mortgage” means—(a) a transfer by way of mortgage, (b) a sub-mortgage by sub-demise,
and (c) a charge by way of legal mortgage’.
13 Law Com No 271 at 2.15 and 2.20.
14 Ibid at 4.3, 4.10, and 4.11.
15 Ibid at 7.7 and 7.8.
16 Ibid at 9.30(2), n 80.
17 [1975] AC 373 at 391G. On the permissible uses of Law Commission Reports in construction
made ultra vires the disponor.18 The Report uses the expression ultra vires,19
and does not distinguish between ultra vires at law and ultra vires in equity.20
Consonant with this absence of discrimination the Report does not distinguish
between validity at law and validity in equity. The Report gives examples of the
intended operation of clauses 26 and 52, and these include both dispositions
ultra vires at law,21 and dispositions ultra vires in equity.22 This conflation
creates peculiar problems in construing section 26.
One problem that requires immediate notice is the absence from section 26
of any express reference to a disposition being ultra vires, and the use of the
expression ‘any limitation affecting the validity of a disposition’ in preference.
Consideration of the Report suggests that the statutory phrase is intended to
indicate potential applications of the ultra vires doctrine.23 However, the
decision to use the language actually employed in section 26, rather than the
available technical term, suggests that there is some difference in meaning that
led to the choice of the words used.
Section 26 is one element of the statutory scheme laid down by the LRA 2002.
Section 26(2) provides that any limitations upon an owner’s powers imposed by
the LRA 2002 are unaffected by the operation of the section. Therefore, if there
proves to be a conflict between section 26 and some other provision of the LRA
2002 then the presumption must be that section 26 would give way. Part 3 of the
LRA 2002 proceeds to establish a scheme for the priority of both legal and equi-
table interests in registered land which recognises, inter alia, the overriding
nature of the rights of those in actual occupation of registered land.24 The LRA
2002 recognises the possibility of equitable rights, rights that lack the definition
18 Law Com No 271 at 2.15, 2.20, 4.3, 7.7, 9.3.
19 Ibid at 2.15 n 28, 9.30(2).
20 Ibid at 2.15 n 28 (legal) and n 33(equitable), 4.3, 7.8.
21 Ibid at 2.15: ‘One ground on which a disposition of land might be challenged is that the party
who made it was acting outside his or her powers in some way, as for example, where a statutory
body such as a local authority made a disposition that it was not permitted to make’. The footnote
to this sentence cites Hounslow London Borough Council v Hare (1990) 24 HLR 9, and refers to the
case as one involving an ultra vires disposition. At 4.3: ‘A registered proprietor’s powers of disposi-
tion may be limited, for example, by statute (perhaps because it is a statutory body), if it is a corpo-
ration, by its public documents,’ and n 7. At 7.7: ‘The purpose of the Clause is to protect any
disponee in the case where, for example, the chargee purports to exercise a power of disposition
(typically a sale or the grant of a lease) in circumstances where either it had no such power at all or
that power had not become exercisable’. At 7.8(2).
22 Ibid at 2.15 n 33: ‘If, for example, trustees sell land without obtaining the consent of a
beneficiary that is required by the trust instrument’. At 4.3: ‘A registered proprietor’s powers may
be limited . . . or where the proprietors are trustees, by the terms of the trust upon which they hold
the land’. At 4.10, 4.11, and 7.8(1).
23 Ibid most clearly at 2.15, and n 28. If not for n 33 the Report would clearly be directing itself
and status as equitable interests that beneficial interests under a trust undoubt-
edly possess, surviving registered dispositions of registered land.25 The LRA
2002 recognises the continuing relevance of the general law, as regards the
nature of interests in land, and dispositions thereof26 and the continuing opera-
tion of the law of overreaching upon dispositions of registered land.27 There
was no intention to upset the law as established by Williams & Glyn’s Bank v
Boland28 that a disposition by a single trustee of land in breach of trust would
not pass a title free of an occupying beneficiary’s interest under the trust.29 The
rights of an occupying beneficiary are protected by the provisions of section
29(2)(a)(iii) and paragraph 2 of Schedule 3 of the LRA 2002.
The Report informs us that section 26 is intended to allow a title to be trans-
ferred free of equitable interests in some circumstances. An example of the oper-
ation of section 26 is given by the Report at 4.10. The example supposes a
disposition without consent made by two trustees, W and X, holding land on
trust for a beneficiary in actual occupation of the trust land whose consent is
required before any disposition can rightfully be made by the trustees. In this sit-
uation the Report states the actual occupation of the wronged beneficiary would
have no effect, and the beneficiary’s interest would not be overriding.
In the context of the example this result can be explained as the combined
effects of section 26 and sections 2 and 27 of the Law of Property Act 1925 (sub-
sequently the LPA). If this supposition is correct then it provides an insight into
the intended operation of section 26. The section is intended to facilitate over-
reaching by trustees of land by deeming the trustees to be empowered to make
any disposition. A beneficiary’s occupation is irrelevant: ‘because W and X’s
right to exercise owner’s powers is taken to be free of limitation’.30 The section
would effectively render all dispositions by trustees of land overreaching and,
where the requirements of sections 2 and 27 of the LPA are met, actual occupa-
tion by a beneficiary would be irrelevant. However, this leaves the intended
effect of section 26 wholly obscure when the requirements of sections 2 and 27
of the LPA are not met. What must be avoided is giving section 26 a construc-
tion which facilitates overreaching when the requirements of sections 2 and 27
of the LPA are not met, as otherwise the section could be used to undermine the
law as laid down in Boland, which the Report makes clear is not intended.
When section 26 is operating to allow a corporation to effect an ultra vires
transaction it must be assumed that a disponee from a single corporate regis-
tered proprietor could shelter behind its provisions. The challenge posed by the
25
Section 116.
26
For example s 23 grants those entitled: ‘power to make a disposition of the kind permitted by
the general law’, and s 52 in similar fashion grants a proprietor of a registered charge: ‘the powers
of disposition conferred by law on the owner of a legal mortgage’.
27
Evidenced by s 42(1)(b).
28
[1981] AC 487.
29
Law Com No 271 at 2.27(2)(b)(i); 8.14–8.22; 8.53–8.64, especially 8.53. For relevant restrictive
changes to the former law see 8.61, 8.54–8.58, 8.18 and 8.64.
30
Ibid at 4.10.
Making Sense of Section 26 of the Land Registration Act 2002 107
As explained in the Report section 26 protects the title of disponees, whilst leav-
ing them liable to such personal remedies as follow from the knowing receipt of
trust property in breach of trust (and presumably from dishonest assistance in a
breach of trust).31 Two observations are apposite. First, the blocking of any pro-
prietal claim would frustrate any attempt to follow misappropriated property
into the hands of a disponee.32 Secondly, the liability to account as a construc-
tive trustee following the receipt of trust property would support a constructive
trust of any property retained by a disponee.33 Both of these observations
suggest that there will be judicial reluctance to recognise the clear distinction
between personal and proprietary remedies that the Report’s explanation of
section 26 rests upon.
section has effect only . . . (and so does not . . .)’. Section 26(1) is the operative
part of the clause, and 26(3) restricts its operation. It follows that any flaws in
the title of a disponee not derived from an invalidity due to a limitaton of the
disponor’s right to exercise her dispositive powers are not cured by section 26.
However, if a registered proprietor whose right to exercise her dispositive
powers is limited purports to effect a disposition that disregards the limitation
then her disponee’s title to the interest disposed of is unquestionable.
Section 26(1) operates when a person has the ‘right to exercise owner’s powers’.
This phrase echoes the heading to section 24. As the section only operates when
the statutory grant of powers has been made the potential mischief must be the
possibility that a person entitled under section 24 to the owner’s powers granted
by section 23 might exercise them wrongfully. The wrong would be to make a
disposition in disregard of some limitation of her powers, thereby invalidating
the disposition. The most obvious source of a limitation upon powers of dispo-
sition capable of invalidating a disposition would be a want of capacity.
The Report confirms that section 26 is concerned with legal capacity to effect
dispositions,34 as is section 52.35 In this connection clause 26(1) is clearly
concerned with capacity, and reading ‘right’ as synonymous with ‘ability’ would
accurately express this statutory intention. Section 26(1) deems a registered
proprietor’s capacity to effect dispositions unlimited. Thus, an ultra vires
disposition will not be void because of the effect of section 26(1).
The Report makes it quite clear that clause 26(1) is also intended to have an
effect upon some unauthorised dispositions by owners with legal capacity.36
Trustees of registered (or unregistered) land have legal capacity to dispose of the
land, but are limited in the use of these legal powers of disposition by the terms
of their trust, and the general law governing trustees. The improper use of their
legal powers of disposition by trustees is sometimes described as an ultra vires
disposition.37 We have already noted the example of the operation of section 26
given at 4.10 of the Report. The sole other example of the section’s operation
given by the Report also involves a wrongful disposition by trustees of land.38
34
Law Com No 271 at 2.15 (quoted at n 21 above) and at 2.20, which is concerned with restric-
tions that prevent dispositions: “where a corporation or other body has limited powers, to indicate
this limitation”, 2.20 (3) n 47 which refers to 2.15; and 4.3 (quoted at n 21 above).
35 Ibid at 7.7: “The purpose of the Clause [52] is to protect any disponee in the case where, for
example, the chargee purports to exercise a power of disposition (typically a sale or the grant of a
lease) in circumstances where either it had no such power at all or that power had not become exer-
cisable”, and at 7.8: “even if a chargee’s power of disposition has not arisen at all . . . a disponee will
obtain a good title”.
36 See text to n 22 above.
37 Oceanic steam Navigation Co. v Sutherberry (1880) 16 Ch D 236, per Little VC at 240.
38 Law Com No 271 at 4.11.
Making Sense of Section 26 of the Land Registration Act 2002 109
The word ‘right’ in section 26(1) cannot be read as synonymous with ‘ability’
in connection with trustees’ ultra vires use of their powers of disposition.
Trustees have full legal capacity, when making an ultra vires disposition they act
without authority. An ultra vires disposition by trustees is not null and void, it
is legally effective. However, due to the wrong committed equity may hold the
trustees,39 or the disponee,40 or both, liable to action by the beneficiaries. Thus,
in connection with trustees of land the word ‘right’ in section 26(1) imports rec-
titude to what would otherwise be a breach of trust. This construction of the
word is supportable in the light of the remaining words of section 26(1). If
trustees’ of registered land ‘right to exercise owner’s powers’ is ‘to be taken to
be free from any limitation’ then trustees of registered land must be taken to
have unlimited authority to make dispositions. Section 26(1) deems trustees
to be always acting within the limits of their authority, by deeming that no
relevant limits exist.
The expression ‘any limitation affecting the validity of a disposition’ defines
the phrase ‘any limitation’ in terms of the phrase ‘affecting the validity of a dis-
position’. The limitations reached are those that are capable of ‘affecting . . .
validity’, therefore, the key term is ‘validity’ and the construction of this word
will determine the extent of the expression: ‘any limitation affecting the validity
of a disposition’.
Given the explanation in the Report ‘any limitation’ applies both to any lim-
itation on the powers of a registered proprietor, as registered proprietor (ie
capacity), and to any limitation upon the powers of a trustee, as trustee, of reg-
istered land. The removal of any limitations upon the powers of a registered
proprietor as registered proprietor (ie capacity) will validate a disposition at
law. The removal of any limitations upon the powers of trustees of registered
land will validate a disposition in equity. However, the word ‘powers’ is being
used in reference to two different grants of powers, and to grants of two differ-
ent types of power in these two statements. The powers of a registered propri-
etor are granted by sections 23 and 24 of the LRA 2002. These powers are
incidents of the registered proprietor’s property rights in the registered land, and
are granted to the legal owner to allow her to dispose of her property. The pow-
ers of a trustee are granted by her trust instrument, or by the TLATA, or by sec-
tion 8 of the TA 2000. These powers authorise the trustee to deal with the trust
property, and any disposition made by the trustee within the powers they enjoy
has the potential to overreach the equitable interests under the trust.
The attributes and incidence of legal invalidity are fairly well defined. Legal
invalidity of a disposition results in no legal interest being created or trans-
ferred. What is meant by equitable invalidity is less easily discerned. Courts of
39 The trustees’ liability may be personal or proprietary in nature. Equity can impress the con-
unless the disponee’s conscience is affected. Equity may impose proprietary liability by holding that
the property disposed of is still subject to the trust in the disponee’s hands.
110 Graham Ferris
equity have tended to view the difference between void and voidable disposi-
tions as one of form rather than substance.41 The expression void in equity has
been used to signify ineffective to pass a legal estate free of prior equitable
interests.42 The Report makes it clear that section 26(1) was intended by the
draftsman to validate a disposition in equity in the sense that a disposition
validated by the section will transfer an equitably unencumbered interest.43
In order to properly understand the manner in which clause 26 must operate
when it makes a disposition valid in equity it is necessary to reflect upon the
nature of the limitations placed upon trustees by equity. In order to give effect
to the rights of the beneficiaries under a trust equity controls the use made of the
trustee’s undoubted legal powers of disposition. Equity imposes duties of good
faith and due care upon trustees, and prohibits trustees from acting beyond their
authority. A trustee who acts in breach of these duties breaches her trust, and
may incur personal liability. Anyone that receives trust property from a trustee
transferred in breach of trust will take the property subject to the rights of the
beneficiaries, unless they are bona fide purchasers for value of a legal estate
without notice. Statutory provisions have extensively modified the operation of
the bona fide purchaser defence, especially in respect of trustees of land. Indeed
it is probably safer when dealing with registered land to speak of the analogue
of the bona fide purchaser defence, as the defence proper is wholly excluded by
the statutory provisions governing land registration.44
Section 26(1) does not purport to extend the registered land analogue of the
bona fide purchaser defence to new categories of disponees. Nor does section
26(1) purport to operate by deferring the priority of one interest to another.
Section 26(1) deems unauthorised dispositions authorised, and thereby renders
them valid in equity. The section does not use words of grant to effect this end,
section 26 does not grant to trustees unlimited powers of disposition as trustees.
If this were the effect of the section it would replace the relevant provisions of
the TLATA 1996 and the TA 2000 for trustees of registered land. The section
treats the situation as if it were other than it is, it deems trustees are acting legit-
imately: ‘a person’s right . . . is to be taken to be free from any limitation affect-
ing the validity of a disposition’. The limitations still exist, they are not
abrogated, however, when section 26(1) operates the limitations are disre-
garded, and their potential effect upon the validity of a disposition is nullified.
This construction of section 26(1) as operating by suspending some of the
equitable duties of trustees of registered land derives strong support from the
provisions of section 26(3). Section 26(3) restricts the operation of section 26(1)
by providing that only the title of a disponee is protected by section 26(1). This
41
Cloutte v Storey [1911] 1 Ch 18, per Farwell LJ at 30.
42
Bowes v East London Water Works Co. (1820) Jacob 324; 37 ER 873.
43
Law Com No 271 at 4.10.
44
The authority usually given to demonstrate the exclusion of the bona fide purchaser defence
from registered land is William’s & Glyns Bank v Boland [1981] AC 487 per Lord Wilberforce at
504C. For notice and registered land under the LRA 2002 see Law Com No 271 at 5.16–.21.
Making Sense of Section 26 of the Land Registration Act 2002 111
implies that if section 26(3) did not restrict the operation of section 26(1) then it
could have effects beyond the protection of a disponee’s title. Section 26(3) is
needed to prevent the deemed authority of trustees from affecting their personal
liability to the beneficiaries of the trust. The bracketed words of section 26(3)
clearly imply that in the absence of any restriction on the operation of section
26(1) to questions of title, the lawfulness (or more accurately the unlawfulness)
of a disposition by a trustee would be affected by section 26(1). Section 26(1)
prevents the unlawful nature of a disposition (being in breach of trust) from
affecting the equitable validity of the disposition, by deeming the disposition
authorised. Section 26(1) read together with section 26(3) deems unlawful dis-
positions lawful whenever the illegality would threaten the equitable validity of
the disposition. The effect of this is to suspend equitable duties to the extent nec-
essary to validate dispositions. No personal liability follows from a lawful dis-
position, and thus the necessity for section 26(3) to preserve the personal
liability of both trustee and disponee.
In order to establish which equitable duties are suspended by the operation of
section 26(1) we need to return to the key word in section 26(1) for determining
which limitations are intended to be suspended: ‘validity’. The Report identifies
one mischief section 26 is designed to remedy as ultra vires dispositions that
would be invalid in equity. The examples of the operation of section 26 given in
the Report both concern the validity of dispositions by two trustees of registered
land. In both of these examples the trustees’ powers of disposition are limited by
the trust instrument in a manner provided for by the TLATA. In the first exam-
ple a beneficiary is in actual occupation of the trust land, in the second example
the question of actual occupation is not addressed.45 When trustees of land
make a disposition without obtaining a consent they have a duty to obtain
before making such a disposition;46 or, when trustees of land whose powers of
disposition have been cut down by the trust instrument, pursuant to section 8 of
the TLATA, make a disposition they do not have the power to make;47 then they
act outside their authority, or ultra vires. It is submitted that the equitable
‘validity’ section 26(1) operates to secure is whatever is necessary to make the
disposition capable of overreaching equitable interests, and thus bring the dis-
position within the operation of section 2(1)(iii) of the LPA 1925, and no more
than this.
The failure of section 26 to discriminate between legal powers of disposition
and equitable powers of disposition, and as a necessary corollary of this lack of
distinction between legal validity of a disposition and equitable validity of a
disposition, creates a tension in any construction of the section. The Report
does not resolve this tension, rather it increases it by making the draftsman’s
intention to reach both types of invalidity plain beyond a peradventure. The
normal rules of construction can take us no further. We must resort to clearly
45 Law Com No 271 at 4.10 and 4.11.
46 Ibid at 4.10.
47 Ibid at 4.11.
112 Graham Ferris
identifying the choices between different possible readings of section 26(1), none
of which can satisfy all of our requirements for a satisfactory construction of the
section.
A first, and the most natural, construction of the section is to treat section 26(1)
as solely concerned with the legal powers of disposition granted by the LRA
2002 and limitations that affect the legal validity of dispositions. In the absence
of the references in the Report to invalidity due to limitations upon trustees
powers of disposition imposed by other statutes or trust instruments this con-
struction would be almost unavoidable. However, the indications in the Report
as to the intended effects of the section undermine this construction, as it fails to
meet one of the mischiefs the section was drafted to remedy.
A second, and the widest, construction of the section would make any limita-
tion imposed by law or equity upon a registered proprietor exercising the
powers of disposition granted by the LRA 2002 incapable of preventing a fully
valid disposition at law and in equity. This construction gives the words ‘any
limitation affecting the validity of a disposition’ the fullest operation possible.
This enables the section to operate when a trustee of registered land disposes of
the land in breach of trust. Therefore, this construction cannot be supported, as
it would mean that section 26(1) would have a further reaching effect than could
have been intended. A single trustee of registered land could effect a disposition
that would pass clean title to a volunteer disponee.48
The failure of the first two constructions leads to the need to put forward a
third construction of section 26(1). This third construction relies upon the pro-
priety of ascribing an unique meaning to the word ‘validity’ as used in section
26(1). It has been established above that when dealing with ultra vires disposi-
tions by trustees of registered land the intended meaning of ‘valid’ is ‘capable of
overreaching the interests under a trust’. Thus, the section suspends any limita-
tion on trustees’ authority that could prevent a disposition being capable of
overreaching the interests under the trust of land. This reading of validity is
defensible on the ground that it is a technical word used within the context of
the law concerning ultra vires dispositions by trustees of land. Although this
third construction meets the Report’s concern that section 26 should operate
upon ultra vires dispositions by trustees of land it is ill suited to deal with prob-
lems of legal validity.
If the first and third constructions could be combined this would give full effect
to the intention of the Law Commission as expressed in the Report, which leads to
the need to consider a fourth construction. If the expression: ‘a person’s right to
48
See discussion above at ‘The Scheme of the LRA 2002’. This construction would fatally under-
mine Williams & Glyn’s Bank v Boland [1981] AC 487.
Making Sense of Section 26 of the Land Registration Act 2002 113
exercise owner’s powers’ refers to the ‘right’ to exercise the powers granted by
section 23 (first construction), then it does not refer to the ‘right’ to exercise the
powers granted by a trust instrument, the TLATA, or the TA 2000 (third con-
struction). In order to achieve a marrying of the two constructions the word ‘right’
would have to be read as a reference to the grant of powers to trustees of land, ie
‘right’ is read as meaning ‘authority granted by the trust instrument, the TLATA,
or TA 2000, or by any other source, such as the public documents of a company’.
This possibility has been considered above.49 Whilst unnatural it does allow the
possibility of section 26 being concerned with both legal and equitable powers of
disposition. If the expression ‘free from any limitation affecting the validity of a
disposition’ refers to the legal validity of a disposition (first construction), then it
does not entail the disposition being capable of overreaching the interests under a
trust (third construction), as legal validity would be only a necessary, and not a
sufficient requirement. It is possible to read ‘validity’ as requiring legal and equi-
table validity, but this would bring us back to the rejected second construction.
Therefore, to combine the first and third construction the meaning of ‘validity’
would have to be ‘capable of overreaching the interests under a trust’ as this would
entail legal validity. Thus, in order to achieve both of the intended effects section
26(1) must be read as meaning:
‘. . . a person’s [ability and authority, however bestowed] to exercise owner’s powers
. . . is to be taken to be free of any limitation affecting the [capacity to overreach the
interests of beneficiaries under any trust of land that could exist] of a disposition’.
This must be the preferred construction, unless it violates the ‘golden rule’ of
statutory construction referred to above.50
Section 26(2)(a) prevents section 26(1) operating to suspend any limitation pro-
tected by an entry on the register. The Report informs us that in the future the
reference to a limitation being ‘reflected by an entry in the register’ in section
26(2) indicates the entry of a restriction.51 However, during a transitional period
it also refers to cautions and inhibitions.52
Clearly this restricts the operation of section 26(1), and it might be hoped that
the provisions of the LRA 2002 that deal with those entries on the register that
reflect limitations on owner’s powers can be consulted with a view to illuminat-
ing section 26. There are, however, few clues in Part 4 of the LRA 2002 (Notices
and Restrictions) as to the ambit of section 26. The effect of a restriction is
not expressed as a limitation on, or as reflecting a limitation on, the powers of
a registered proprietor. Rather it is described as preventing registration of a
49
Text following n 40 above.
50
Text to n 10 above.
51
Law Com No 271 at 2.15 n 31, 2.20, 4.10, 4.11, and generally at 6.33–6.61, for s 52 see 7.8.
52
Ibid.
114 Graham Ferris
53 Section 41.
54 Section 42(1)(a) provides: ‘The registrar may enter a restriction in the register if it appears to
him that it is necessary or desirable to do so for the purpose of—(a) preventing invalidity or unlaw-
fulness in relation to dispositions of a registered estate or charge’.
55 Or a disposition under s 29(4), which takes effect as if it were registrable, see ss 29, 29(2)(a)(i),
Section 26(3) restricts the operation of section 26(1) to the extent necessary to
protect the title of a disponee, and expressly preserves the unlawful character of
a disposition made in excess of a registered proprietor’s powers of disposition.
The word ‘disponee’ is not a term of art, nor is it defined in the LRA 2002.59
57 Section 284 Insolvency Act 1986 provides: ‘(1)Where a person is adjudged bankrupt, any dis-
position of property made by that person in the period to which this section applies is void except
to the extent that it was made with the consent of the court, or is or was subsequently ratified by the
court’. S 86(4) provides: ‘As soon as practicable after registration of a bankruptcy order under the
Land Charges Act 1972 (c 61), the registrar must, in relation to any registered estate or charge which
appears to him to be affected by the order, enter on the register a restriction reflecting the limitation
under section 284 of the Insolvency Act 1986 (c 45) (disposition by bankrupt void unless made with
the consent of, or subsequently ratified by, the court)’.
58 Section 86(5) provides: ‘Where the proprietor of a registered estate or charge is adjudged bank-
rupt, the title of his trustee in bankruptcy is void as against a person to whom a registrable disposi-
tion of the estate or charge is made if—(a) the disposition is made for valuable consideration, (b) the
person to whom the disposition is made acts in good faith, and (c) at the time of the disposition—
(i) no notice or restriction is entered under this section in relation to the registered estate or charge,
and (ii) the person to whom the disposition is made has no notice of the bankruptcy petition or the
adjudication’.
59 Section 129 does not define the word.
116 Graham Ferris
In the context of section 26 ‘title’ must surely refer to the right itself, as the
evidence of the right would be the Land Register, and section 26 cannot be
CONCLUSION
The major difficulty encountered in construing section 26 has been the need to
respect the dual operation of the section, preventing invalidity both at law and
in equity, that the Report informs us was intended by the draftsman. Of these
two functions it is the prevention of equitable invalidity that must be considered
the most important. The problem of legal invalidity is minimised by the vesting
effect of registration.71 The problems caused by the failure of section 16 of the
TLATA to provide protection for purchasers of registered land are limited by
the provisions of sections 27–31 of the LRA 2002. However, where a beneficiary
of a trust, under which the trustees have limited powers of disposition, is in
actual occupation of the trust land there is a lacunae in purchaser protection in
registered land. If section 26 is construed in such a way that this lacunae is closed
then this would be a useful function for the section. This would also reflect the
emphasis of this role of section 26 in the Report.
The failure to limit the protection of section 26 to those that take a legal
interest for consideration remains problematic, although the adoption of any
construction of section 26(1) identified above other than the second, would alle-
viate the problems. The courts have already shown a willingness to analyse
dispositions of land subject to equitable interests as if the statutory machinery
69 Law Com No 271 at 2.15 n 32, 4.11, and 7.7.
70 Ibid at 2.15, 4.11, and at 7.7 for s 52.
71 Section 58.
Making Sense of Section 26 of the Land Registration Act 2002 119
72
Lyus v Prowsa Developments Ltd [1982] 1 WLR 1044; Collings v Lee [2001] 2 All ER 332.
Part III
Equity
7
Mortgages and Undue Influence
MARK THOMPSON
V E R T H E past thirty years, there can be little doubt that one of the domi-
O nating themes of English Land Law has been the law relating to mortgage
repossessions. Over that period, there has been legislation seeking to improve
the lot of the borrower, personally,1 that legislation being the progenitor of a
good deal of litigation prior to the satisfactory exposition of the manner in
which judicial discretion afforded by the Acts is to be exercised in Cheltenham
and Gloucester Building Society v Norgan.2 Other issues which came to the fore
concerned the enforceability of the rights of tenants against the mortgagee,3
and, of course, the question of the ability of beneficial co-owners of a house to
resist possession proceedings by asserting that that beneficial interest is binding
upon the mortgagee. This issue first attracted attention in Caunce v Caunce,4
and then led to the change in judicial attitude to this matter in Williams and
Glyn’s Bank v Boland,5 a decision which spawned its own cottage industry and
led to two Law Commission Reports6 and an ongoing debate as to whether the
rights of beneficial co-owners will be overreached if the mortgage is created by
two co-owners.7 Related to that issue is the question of the right of one of the
legal co-owners to argue that a mortgage is not binding upon him or her because
the consent to that mortgage has been secured by the exercise of misrepresenta-
tion or undue influence. It is with this matter with that paper is concerned. It
MP Thompson in F Meisel and P Cook (eds) Property and Protection, (Hart Publishing, Oxford,
2000) 157 at 167–72.
7 For the view that this does not happen, see Graham Ferris and Graham Battersby [1998]
Conveyances168 and [2001] Conveyancer 221, responding to the opposite view of Martin Dixon
[2000] Conveyancer 227; a debate which centres on whether the decision in City of London BS v
Flegg [1988] AC.54 was inadvertently reversed by the Trusts of Land and Appointment of Trustees
Act 1996. See also Mark P Thompson, Modern Land Law (OUP, Oxford, 2001), 209–11.
124 Mark Thompson
involves a fascinating chapter in the judicial development of the law which has
involved an adaptation of old principles of law to a modern setting, in order to
achieve a proper balance between the competing pressures of the protection of
occupation rights on the one hand, and the ability of lending institutions to be
able to have confidence in the securities that they have taken to underpin their
lending on the other.
EARLY DEVELOPMENTS
The essential problem with which the law had to grapple was when a mortgage
was created to secure lending unconnected with the acquisition of the house
itself 8 and one of the signatories to the mortgage subsequently argued that, as
against him or her, the mortgage should be regarded as void. Initially, the man-
ner in which this issue was resolved was to employ the law of agency and this
approach had a long pedigree. Early examples of this angle are to be found in
Turnbull &. Co. v Duvall,9 where a husband had persuaded his wife to sign a
security and had pressured her to do so. It was held that the security was void
because, in the words of Lord Lindley, ‘It is impossible to hold that . . . Turnbull
&. Co. are unaffected by such pressure and ignorance. They left everything to
Duvall, and must abide by the consequences.’10
More modern authority took a similar line. In Avon Finance Co. Ltd v
Bridger,11 a son got his elderly parents to mortgage their house to provide funds
for him and, when doing so, misrepresented to them what it was that they were
signing. Because the finance company had entrusted the son to obtain their sig-
natures, the vitiating effect of the misrepresentation was attributed to the com-
pany: ‘The company left everything to the son to arrange for their benefit. The
son was fraudulent and they must abide by the consequences’.12 In cases where
the lending institution had not entrusted the borrower to obtain the requisite
signature then, save for one important exception to be discussed shortly, the
mortgage would be held to be valid, even if undue influence or misrepresenta-
tion had been employed to obtain the requisite signature or signatures.13
The exception referred to above was if the lender had notice that undue
influence had been used. In Bank of Credit and Commerce International SA v
8 For the resolution of the worries of mortgagees that they might not be able to enforce acquisi-
tion mortgages, see Bristol and West BS v Henning [1995] 1 WLR778 and Paddington BS v
Mendelsohn (1995) 50 P & CR 244. See MP Thompson (1986) 49 Modern Law Review 245 and
[1986] Conveyancer 57. For a better rationale of those decisions than that which was actually
employed, see Skipton BS v Clayton (1993) 25 HLR 596 at 602 per Slade LJ.
9
[1902] AC 429. See also Chaplin &. Co. Ltd v Brammall [1908] 1 KB 233 at 238 per Vaughan
Williams LJ.
10
Ibid at p 435.
11
[1985] 2 All ER 281.
12
Ibid at p 288 per Brandon LJ See also Kings North Trust Ltd v Bell [1986] 1 WLR 119 at 124
per Dillon LJ
13
See Coldunell Ltd v Gallon [1986] QB 1184.
Mortgages and Undue Influence 125
Aboody,14 a case which was to exert considerable influence on the future devel-
opment of the law, the defendants were a husband and wife. In order to secure
finance for a family company, mortgages were created over the matrimonial
home, title to which was in the sole name of Mrs Aboody. She was in a room
with a solicitor who was advising her when her husband burst into the room and
a shouting match ensued before she would sign the mortgage. In a distressed
condition, she signed it and the issue was whether it was valid. The Court of
Appeal held that it was, but on the now discredited basis that, even if the exis-
tence of actual undue influence had been proved, which it had been in the pre-
sent case, the transaction would not be set aside unless it could also be shown
that it was to the manifest disadvantage of the person seeking to set it aside. On
the facts, it was held that this was not the case, in that the Court of Appeal
perceived that is was, in any event, in her interest to sign the mortgage in order
to keep the business afloat and, consequently, the mortgage was held to be
binding upon her.
The requirement that the victim of actual undue influence must establish that
the transaction was to her manifest disadvantage was subsequently overruled in
CIBC Mortgages Ltd v Pitt,15 but the general tenor of the reasoning was to prove
to be highly influential. The Court of Appeal held that there were two distinct
grounds on which the bank could be affected by the actual undue influence
exerted by Mr Aboody on his wife: agency and notice. The first issue did not
arise. As to the second, Slade LJ, giving the judgment of the Court said that
If a creditor has actual or constructive notice, at the time of the execution of the charge
or guarantee in question, that the guarantee or charge on which it relies has been pro-
cured by the exercise of undue influence, it cannot enforce the transaction; an equity
is raised against the creditor irrespective of any question of agency.16
On the facts of Aboody, it was clear that there was actual undue influence
exerted by the husband upon his wife and that the bank had notice of that undue
influence because the solicitor, who was acting for the bank, had observed what
had happened. The opportunity was taken, however, to analyse the nature of
undue influence. Slade LJ in a passage which was, for some time afterwards to
exert considerable influence on the law, expounded a classification of undue
influence. Class 1 concerned situations where the complainant established that
she had entered into a particular transaction as a result of actual undue
influence. Class 2, which was to be come much the more important category,
was subdivided into two sub-classes. Class 2A involves a situation where the
relationship between the parties is such that the law will presume that one party
exercised undue influence upon the other. Such relationships include solicitor
14
[1990] 1 QB 923.
15
[1984] 1 AC 200.
16
Ibid at 973. Italics supplied.
126 Mark Thompson
client,17 and priest and penitent.18 Class 2B involves a relationship which does
not, of itself, gives rise to a presumption of undue influence but, on the estab-
lishment that the relationship is of a particularly trusting nature, can give rise to
that presumption.19
Before the landmark decision in Barclays Bank Plc v O’Brien,20 it was probably
true to say that rather greater emphasis in the present context was placed on
agency arguments, as outlined above, than a more general role for the applica-
tion of the doctrine of undue influence. All this changed as a result of the
O’Brien litigation. Mr and Mrs O’Brien were legal co-owners of their matrimo-
nial home. He was closely involved with a company, Heathrow Fabrications
Ltd, which was in financial difficulty. The company exceeded its original over-
draft limit and it was agreed that the company could have a £60,000 overdraft
for a period of one month, that overdraft to be secured against the O’Briens’
matrimonial home. At a subsequent meeting between Mr O’Brien and a bank
official, it was agreed to extend the facility to £135,000, again to be secured by
a mortgage over the matrimonial home. The mortgage document which Mrs
O’Brien signed gave the bank security for the total indebtedness of the company.
When she signed the mortgage and a side letter, which included a recommenda-
tion that she take legal advice before signing the mortgage, she had read neither
document. Neither had the bank official, who was present when she signed,
made any attempt to explain the full nature of the transaction to her, despite it
being the policy of the bank that he should do so. When the company’s indebt-
edness exceeded £154,000, the bank brought possession proceedings and this
was resisted by Mrs O’Brien.
In the Court of Appeal,21 an extensive review of the authorities was under-
taken and a hitherto undetected principle of equity was unearthed to afford
some relief to Mrs O’Brien. According to Scott LJ, the cases referred to earlier,
based upon the agency principle, were suspect in that it was not accepted that
the principal borrower could really be said to be the agent of the bank.22 Instead,
he discerned a wider equitable principle. In his view, the authorities led to the
conclusion that there was a special principle of equity. This principle was to
afford ‘a treatment of wives who have given security to support their husband’s
17
Harris v Tremenhere (1808) 15 Ves.34; Rhodes v Bate (1865) 4 Giff 670, although in this latter
case this was not necessary for the decision: see at 680 per Sir John Leach VC.
18 See Huguenin v Baseley (1807) 14 Ves Jun 272; Billage v Southee (1852) 9 Hare 534; Allcard v
debts more tender than that which would have applied to other third party
sureties’.23 The effect of this tenderness of treatment was that it was incumbent
upon the creditor when, as in the instant case, a wife is acting as a surety for her
husband’s debts to ensure that she understands the full import of the trans-
action. As in the instant case, owing to a misrepresentation by her husband,
Mrs O’Brien thought herself to be signing a short-term mortgage to secure a
debt of £60,000, whereas she was actually signing a mortgage to secure all the
liability of the company. As the bank had not fully explained this to her, the
mortgage was held to be enforceable only to the extent of her understanding of
it. The bank could, therefore, as against her, only secure the mortgage to the
extent of her understanding: £60,000.
Unsurprisingly, the bank appealed against this judgment.24 Doubtless to its con-
siderable chagrin, the House of Lords held that the mortgage was not even valid
to the extent of her understanding of it; it was held, as against her, to be void.25
The opportunity was taken to lay down general principles to be applied to this
type of problem although, as will be seen, these principles occasioned consider-
able difficulty in their application and, subsequently, have had to be consider-
ably modified.
Lord Browne-Wilkinson, giving the only reasoned speech, disapproved of the
agency principle. He also declined to accept the existence of the special princi-
ple of equity protective of wives who stood surety for their husband’s debts, a
conclusion to be welcomed, resting, as it did, on a somewhat tendentious view
of the earlier authorities.26 Instead, he sought to provide a solution to problems
of the type exemplified in the case before him by an application of general prin-
ciples, these general principles being based upon the law relating to undue
influence and the application of the doctrine of notice, although the running of
the two together did much to add obscurity to the law.
At the outset of his discussion of the principles of undue influence. Lord
Browne-Wilkinson accepted the tripartite classification expounded in Aboody
and then proceeded to explain its application to a situation involving only two
parties: the complainant and the wrongdoer. If a transaction had been brought
about by the actual exercise of undue influence, Class 1, then the complainant is
entitled to have that transaction set aside. Secondly, if the transaction is between
23
Ibid at p127.
24
[1994] 1 AC 180.
25
See also TSB Bank Ltd v Camfield [1995] 1 WLR 430 and commentary by Alison Dunn [1995]
Conveyancer 325 and Patricia Ferguson (1995) 111 Law Quarterly Review 555.
26
See MP Thompson [1992] Conveyancer 443. The main authority in support consisted of dicta
in Yerkey v Jones (1939) 63 CLR 64. The special equity theory is still followed in Australia: see
Garcia v National Australia bank Ltd (1998) 72 AJLR 1243; PJ Clarke [1998] All E. Rev 276.
128 Mark Thompson
two people such as lawyer-client or priest-penitent, Class 2A, then there is a pre-
sumption that undue influence was used and, in the absence of evidence to the
contrary, the transaction will be set aside at the instigation of the complainant.
Thirdly, he came to Class 2B. Here, the particular relationship involved does
not, of itself, give rise to a presumption that a transaction between them was
brought about by the use of undue influence. What the complainant must do is
to establish that the relationship was one where she did, in fact reside trust and
confidence in the wrongdoer. This was explained in the following terms:
In a Class 2(B) case therefore, in the absence of evidence disproving undue influence,
the complainant will succeed in setting aside the impugned transaction merely by
proof that the complainant reposed trust and confidence in the wrongdoer without
having to prove that the wrongdoer exerted actual undue influence or otherwise
abused such trust and confidence in relation to the particular transaction impugned.27
This then led to the next issue: the circumstances necessary for the transac-
tion, the mortgage, to be set aside as between the complainant and the
mortgagee. Here, as noted, above, there is usually no question of there being a
relationship of trust and confidence between these two parties and so something
else is necessary before the complainant can set aside the mortgage. That some-
thing else was the misguided introduction of the doctrine of notice.
For Lord Browne-Wilkinson, if the complainant established the existence of
a Class 2B relationship then, as between her and the wrongdoer, there existed
an equity to set aside the impugned transaction. The effect of this equity upon
third parties, such as the mortgagee, would depend upon the doctrine of notice;
a doctrine he regarded as being ‘at the heart of equity’.32 He explained this in the
following terms:
A wife who has been induced to stand as a surety for her husband’s debts by his undue
influence, or some other legal wrong has an equity as against him to set aside that
transaction. Under the ordinary principles of equity, her right to set aside that trans-
action will be enforceable against third parties (eg against a creditor) if either the hus-
band was acting as the third party’s agent or the third party had actual or constructive
notice of the facts giving rise to her equity.33
The impact of this assertion of the role of the doctrine of notice will be
considered shortly. First, attention will be turned to the circumstances when a
mortgagee will be considered to have constructive notice of the complainant’s
equity.
As Lord Browne-Wilkinson was not prepared to accept that every transaction
involving a husband and wife gave rise to a presumption of undue influence he
took care to identify, from the perspective of the mortgagee, when it would have
notice of the complainant’s equity. As to this, he said:
. . . a creditor is put on inquiry when a wife offers to stand surety for her husband’s
debts by the combination of two factors: (a) the transaction is not on its face to the
financial advantage of the wife; and (b) there is a substantial risk that, in procuring the
wife to act as surety, the husband has committed a legal wrong that entitles the wife
to set aside the transaction.
It follows that unless the creditor who is put on notice takes reasonable steps to sat-
isfy himself that the wife’s agreement to stand surety had been properly obtained, the
creditor will have constructive notice of the wife’s rights.34
This important passage highlights two key parts to the decision. The first is that
it is the nature of the transaction, itself, which is the triggering element in
putting the creditor on notice of the possibility of the use of undue influence or
misrepresentation. Secondly, it makes clear that the existence of this triggering
element does not preclude the mortgagee from going ahead with the mortgage
32
[1994] 1 AC180 at 195.
33 Ibid Italics supplied. For an equally explicit assertion of the traditional role of the doctrine of
notice, see CIBC Mortgages Ltd v Pitt [1994] 1 AC 200 at 210 per Lord Browne-Wilkinson.
34 [1994] 1 AC 180 at 196.
130 Mark Thompson
transaction. What then becomes an issue is the steps which must be taken to
ensure that the wife’s agreement to the transaction has been properly obtained.
Taking the second issue first, Lord Browne-Wilkinson spelled out what he
considered reasonable steps to be. Somewhat unusually, in that judicial state-
ments are normally taken to operate retrospectively, the theory being that the
judges are stating what the law has always been rather than what it is to be for
the future,35 he laid down a procedure to be followed in transactions taking
place after the instant decision. He said:
As to past transactions it will depend upon the facts of each case whether the steps
taken by the creditor satisfy this test. However for the future in my judgment a credi-
tor will have satisfied these requirements if it insists that the wife attends a prior meet-
ing (in the absence of the husband) with a representative of the creditor at which she
is told of the extent of her liability as a surety, warned of the risk she is running and
urged to take legal advice.36
A number of key elements emerged from the decision in O’Brien, all of which,
it can be said, gave rise to difficulties in the future.37 The starting point was that,
in transactions between husband and wife, or other people in a relationship of
trust and confidence, one of the parties, usually, but not inevitably, the hus-
band,38 may use undue influence or misrepresentation to secure the other party’s
agreement to it. Then, if that transaction is to the manifest disadvantage of the
complainant, it can, as against the wrongdoer, be set aside. This equity to set the
transaction aside will be binding upon a mortgagee who has notice of the rela-
tionship giving rise to that equity. A bank will be regarded as being put on notice
if the transaction in question is, on its face, not to the financial advantage of the
wife. If the transaction, at least as presented to the mortgagee, appears genuinely
to be a joint venture, such as where the stated purpose of the loan is to buy a hol-
iday home, then, even if undue influence was exerted by the husband upon the
wife, the mortgage will not be set aside as it was not put on notice that the rela-
tionship was such that undue influence might have been in play.39 If the trans-
action is of a nature to put the mortgagee on notice then, in order for the validity
of the mortgage to be immune from subsequent attack, the mortgagee should
follow the precautions outlined in the judgment.
35 For an extreme example of this, see Kleinwort Benson Ltd v Lincoln City Council [1999] 2 AC
349, criticised on this issue by MP Thompson [1999] Conveyancer 40. For a general discussion of
this issue in property law, see MP Thompson [1984] Conveyancer 302.
36 [1994] 1 AC 180 at 196.
37 See Belinda Fehlberg (1996) 59 Modern Law Review 675; Mika Oldham (1995) 7 Child and
Family Law Quarterly 104. For the most comprehensive discussion of the issues involved, see
Fehlberg, Sexually Transmitted Debt (Oxford, Clarendon Press 1997).
38 For the reverse situation, see Barclays Bank plc v Rivett [1999] 1 FLR 730.
39 CIBC Mortgages Ltd v Pitt [1994] 1 AC 200.
Mortgages and Undue Influence 131
Central to the decision in O’Brien is the acceptance that it is not every occasion
when a family home is used as security for a loan that the mortgage is open to
attack on the ground that the wife’s consent to it has been secured by the use of
undue influence.40 Such an absolutist view would, it was considered, swing the
balance too much in favour of mortgagors and provide an unacceptable imped-
iment to mortgagees and consequently have a deleterious effect on people’s abil-
ity to unlock the capital in their homes by borrowing money against the security
of their equities of redemption. For the mortgage to be open to attack, it was
necessary for the lender to be put on notice of the possible existence of a vitiat-
ing factor, and the source of notice was the reason given to the lender for the
loan. This reasoning, however, while, superficially attractive, was problematic,
the problems being both conceptual and practical.
On a conceptual level, it is quite clear from the speech in O’Brien and also in
CIBC Mortgages Ltd v Pitt,41 that Lord Browne-Wilkinson saw the resolution
of disputes of this nature as being dependent upon the application of orthodox
principles of property law: the question was whether the mortgagee was to be
regarded as having notice of a wife’s equity to set aside a transaction as against
her husband. This reasoning, however, is flawed, it being predicated on a false
analysis of the nature of the transaction. Inherent in the reasoning is that there
are two transactions. The first is the transaction between the husband and wife
where, because of the surrounding circumstances, the wife has an equity to set
it aside. There then follows the mortgage transaction between the husband and
wife on the one hand and the mortgagee on the other. The issue is then, accord-
ing to the House of Lords, whether the mortgagee has notice, actual or con-
structive, of the wife’s equity. This, however, does not present an accurate
picture of the reality of the situation.42
In a case such as O’Brien, it is simply not true that there are two separate
transactions. There is but one, which is the mortgage created by the couple.
Consequently, there is no prior equity of which the bank can be affected. Any
equity to set the mortgage aside arises because the mortgagee is regarded as
being privy to the impropriety of the husband.43 The reasoning employed in
O’Brien obscures this fact and it soon became clear that notice in this context
40
For an argument in favour of such a position see Belinda Fehlberg (1996) 59 Modern Law
Review 675 at 682.
41
[1994] 1 AC 200.
42
For a debate as to the correct role of notice, see MP Thompson [1994] Conveyancer 140;
Charles Harpum and Martin Dixon [1994] Conveyancer 421; Peter Sparkes [1995] Conveyancer
250; Graham Battersby (1995) 15 Legal Studies 35. It has become apparent that, although the words
actually used by Lord Browne-Wilkinson support the view taken by Thompson and Sparkes, sub-
stantively, the correct analysis is that by Harpum and Dixon.
43
See Harpum and Dixon at 423.
132 Mark Thompson
was not being used in the sense in which this concept is ordinarily used in
property law.44
A related issue concerned the need for the complainant to show that the trans-
action that had been secured by the use of undue influence was also to her man-
ifest disadvantage. This additional requirement appeared to have its genesis in
National Westminster Bank plc v Morgan,45 where it was said that, in cases of
presumed undue influence, in order for the claimant to succeed in having the
transaction set aside, it had to be shown that it was to her manifest disadvan-
tage. This was subsequently applied in a case of actual undue influence, so that
in Bank of Credit and Commerce International SA v Aboody,46 Mrs Aboody
failed to have the mortgage which she had signed set aside on the basis that,
although she had signed it as a consequence of her husband’s undue influence,
she could not establish the further requirement that the transaction was to her
manifest disadvantage.
In cases where undue influence was actually used, it was made clear in CIBC
Mortgages plc v Pitt47 that the complainant did not need, additionally, to show
that the transaction was manifestly to her disadvantage. As Lord Browne-
Wilkinson, again giving the only reasoned speech, explained:
Actual undue influence is a species of fraud. Like any other victim of fraud, a person
who has been induced by undue influence to carry out a transaction which he did not
knowingly or freely enter is entitled to have the transaction set aside as of right.48
Aboody was therefore overruled and it was made clear that if the complainant
established that undue influence had been used, the transaction would, without
more, be set aside. What, however, was left open was the position when rather
than establishing a case of actual undue influence, the complainant relied,
instead, on presumed undue influence. This point was considered in Barclays
Bank plc v Coleman,49 where the Court of Appeal came to the reluctant conclu-
sion that it was bound to hold that the establishment that the transaction was
manifestly to the complainant’s disadvantage was an additional hurdle which
had to be surmounted if the mortgage was to be set aside.
At the time when this was decided, the distinction being made between Class
1 and Class 2 cases of undue influence could be said to be incoherent.50 This is
because in both Class 2A and 2B it was the establishment of a particular rela-
tionship which, of itself, gave rise to a presumption of undue influence. Once
that relationship was established, undue influence was presumed to have
44
See Barclays Bank plc v Boulter [1999] 4 All ER 513 at 518 per Lord Hoffmann. See
MP Thompson [2000] Conveyancer 43 at 47–8.
45
[1985] AC 686 at 704 per Lord Scarman. For criticism, see David Tiplady (1983) 48 Modern
Law Review 579.
46
[1990] 1 QB 925.
47
[1994] 1 AC 200.
48
Ibid at p 209.
49
[2000] 1 All ER 385 affirmed in the compendious litigation Royal Bank of Scotland v Etridge
(No 2) [2001] 4 All ER 449.
50
See M P Thompson [2000] Conveyancer 444 at 454.
Mortgages and Undue Influence 133
occurred; it was unnecessary for the complainant actually to prove that it had.51
Consequently, as between the parties themselves, it should make no difference
whether undue influence was actually proved or was presumed. In both cases,
the transaction would have been procured by fraud with the result that the com-
plainant should be able to set it aside.
A good deal of the force of this criticism has since been dispelled, however, owing
to the restatement of the basis of presumed undue influence52 to be considered
shortly. In the present context, however, when the issue is whether a mortgage
should be set aside on the ground of undue influence, the point was largely acade-
mic. This is because, before the mortgagee was put on notice that the relationship
between the two mortgagors was within Class 2B, it was made clear that the mere
fact that the two were married to each other would not suffice to do this. Before the
bank was put on notice, it had to be shown that the intended transaction was not,
on its face, to the financial advantage of the wife.53 If the complainant could satisfy
this condition then, of itself, this should also enable her to surmount the hurdle of
showing that the transaction was to her manifest disadvantage. This left, however,
the task of showing that the transaction was not to her financial advantage.
As has been seen, before a mortgagee was put on notice of the danger that the com-
plainant’s consent to the mortgage had been obtained by undue influence, it had to
be the case that the transaction was not, on its face, to her financial advantage. This
requirement was the source of considerable practical difficulty. In some cases, it is
true, the satisfaction of this criterion was straightforward. So, when an employee
was prepared to mortgage her flat to provide security for the total indebtedness of
her employer, the court found that this was patently not to her financial advan-
tage.54 Such facts are obviously unusual. A more common situation where the cred-
itor would be put on notice was when the mortgage was not created to secure an
agreed sum but was to secure unlimited borrowing: an ‘all monies’ clause. The view
taken of such a clause was that, as it enabled the alleged wrongdoer ‘without
recourse to the [complainant] to subject the house to much greater financial risks
than she could have ever known’,55 the bank would be regarded as being put on
notice. Rather greater difficulty was occasioned by the situation, which was quite
common, where the purpose of the loan was to support a business in which the hus-
band was involved, and in which the wife might or might not be involved.
51 Barclays Bank plc v O’Brien [1994] 1 AC180 at 189–90 per Lord Browne-Wilkinson.
52 See Royal Bank of Scotland v Etridge (No 2) [2001] 4 All ER 449 at 461 per Lord Nicholls of
Birkenhead.
53 Barclays Bank plc v O’Brien [1994] 1 AC180 at 196 per Lord Browne-Wilkinson.
54 Credit Lyonnais Bank Nederland NV v Burch [1997] 1 All ER 144.
55 Barclays Bank plc v Coleman [2000] 1 All ER 385 at 401 per Nourse LJ See also the comments in
Royal Bank of Scotland v Etridge (No 2) [2001] 4 All ER 449 at 485–6 per Lord Hobhouse of
Woodborough.
134 Mark Thompson
The real difficulty in such cases was that the success of the business was likely
to benefit the claimant.56 If, as is likely, this was the case then it could easily be
argued that the loan was for their mutual benefit so that the bank should not be
regarded as having been put on notice with the resulting need to take precau-
tions to ensure that the signature was freely given. While in some cases the
courts would seek to assess the involvement of the claimant in the business,57
this exercise has an air of artificiality to it and it may not be at all obvious if the
potential complainant is an enthusiastic participant in an attempt to secure
funding for the family business or a reluctant signatory to a mortgage the pur-
pose of which is to secure borrowing for the purposes of the other party.
PRECAUTIONS
Assuming the facts to be such that a mortgagee is put on notice that some viti-
ating factor may have been present in obtaining a requisite signature to the
mortgage, Lord Browne-Wilkinson laid down what, in the future, mortgagees
should do to avoid being fixed with constructive notice of the complainant’s
equity. He envisaged that a representative of the bank should have a private
interview with the wife, in the absence of the husband, and that, during the
course of that interview, the official should explain to her the extent of her lia-
bility as a surety, the risk that she was running and also counsel her to obtain
legal advice.58 While he also made clear that when cases came before the courts
where the facts giving rise to the litigation had occurred prior to the decision in
O’Brien, the court must then judge on the facts whether or not adequate steps
had been taken to ensure that the wife had received proper advice prior to sign-
ing the mortgage, it became evident that, in subsequent litigation, the courts
appeared to be willing to whittle down the guidelines laid down by Lord
Browne-Wilkinson.59
In the post-O’Brien litigation, it became plain that banks were not conduct-
ing a private interview with the potential complainant. Instead, the issues which
came to be litigated concerned the independence of the legal advisor and the
quality of advice given. From the outset, it became apparent that, in virtually all
cases, if the complainant had seen a solicitor in connection with the disputed
mortgage, then arguments that it should subsequently be set aside would fail. In
terms of the identity of the advisor, the courts did not seem to be unduly
concerned about potential conflicts of interest. Thus in Banco Exterior
56 See the comments of Anthony Mann QC speaking to the Chancery Bar Association, reported
Scotland v Etridge (No.2) [2001] 4 All ER 449 at 480 and 486 per Lord Hobhouse.
Mortgages and Undue Influence 135
Internacional v Mann,60 a solicitor certified to the bank that he had advised the
wife prior to her signing a mortgage against the matrimonial home. The mort-
gage was to secure a loan of £175,000 to a company owned and controlled by
her husband. Notwithstanding the fact that the solicitor who had advised the
wife was also the company’s solicitor, and had not seen her separately from her
husband, the majority of the Court of Appeal held that the bank was entitled to
rely on a certificate from him that he had advised her and so upheld the validity
of the mortgage.
This decision proved to be the start of a trend whereby the courts were pre-
pared to accept that mortgagees were not to be fixed with constructive notice of
a complainant’s equity if a solicitor had certified that the transaction had been
explained to her. Provided that the bank had supplied the solicitor with relevant
information which it held concerning the loan,61 or, in extreme situations,
where the transaction is so disadvantageous to one party that no solicitor could
do otherwise than to advise against proceeding with it and, indeed, should
refuse to act rather than facilitate the transaction,62 a bank would be safe to rely
on confirmation from a solicitor that he had advised the wife, it seeming not to
matter in what other capacity the solicitor was acting.63 Neither did it matter if
the advice was inadequate, as, indeed, was frequently the case.64 A bank is enti-
tled to assume that a solicitor has done his or her job properly and, if that is not
so, the claimant’s remedy is against the solicitor. The mortgage will not be set
aside.
It is evident that Barclays Bank plc v O’Brien was a landmark decision which
sought to strike a balance between affording protection to a legal co-owner of
property, frequently a wife, who is prepared to mortgage the family home to
secure debts of the other co-owner on the one hand and the commercial interest
of banks who, subsequently, seek to enforce their securities. In so doing, the
House of Lords sought to adapt and apply the law relating to undue influence to
these situations. The methodology was to employ property law concepts and, in
particular, to embark upon the exploration of when a complainant would be
able to establish that the lender had notice of an equity to set aside the impugned
transaction.
Unfortunately, the speech of Lord Browne–Wilkinson generated problems.
The conceptual basis of the speech was highly questionable. The analysis relied
60
[1995] 1 All ER 936, criticised by Alison Dunn [1995] Conveyancer 325 at 330–2.
61
See Northern Rock BS v Archer (1998) 78 P & CR 65; MP Thompson [1999] Conveyancer 510.
62
Credit Lyonnais Bank Nederland SA v Burch [1997] 1 All ER 144.
63
See for example Barclays Bank plc v Thomson [1997] 4 All ER 816, criticised by MP Thompson
[1997] Conveyancer 216.
64
See Belinda Fehlberg (1996) 59 Modern Law Review 675 at 683; Sir Peter Millett (1998) 114
Law Quarterly Review 214 at 220.
136 Mark Thompson
upon the law relating to undue influence, which is principally relevant to two
party transactions, where one party seeks, as against the other, to set a transac-
tion aside. To superimpose this onto a three party situation where one of the
parties, the mortgagee, does not usually exert any undue influence on the com-
plainant led to a misuse of the doctrine of notice. That doctrine is based upon
working out when a third party takes subject to a pre-existing equity; not some-
thing which was actually true in the present context. The conceptual problem
led also to the practical one: to determine when a mortgagee would be put on
notice of the fact that some vitiating factor might be present in the obtaining of
the complainant’s signature to the impugned mortgage. Finally, an issue which
had, as a result of litigation spawned by O’Brien, become unclear was what pre-
cautions a mortgagee should take to ensure that the mortgage would not later
be vulnerable to attack on the basis of some wrongdoing having occurred when
it was created. For these reasons, a review of this area by the House of Lords
became essential and this occurred in Royal Bank of Scotland v Etridge (No 2).65
Etridge involved eight conjoined appeals which raised similar issues. In all of the
cases, a matrimonial home had been mortgaged to secure the indebtedness of
either a husband or the husband’s business and the essential issue in them all
was the circumstances in which the mortgages were created. In seven of the
appeals, the wives argued that the mortgages should be set aside on the ground
of undue influence; in the eighth, the action was one in negligence against the
solicitor who had advised the wife. Perhaps unusually, the importance of the
case lies much less in the application of the law to the facts. Instead the case con-
tains an extensive restatement of the applicable principles and involved sub-
stantial modifications to the principles enunciated in O’Brien.
In O’Brien, a pivotal part of the reasoning was based upon the presumption
of undue influence. This then led to a consideration of the circumstances when
a mortgagee would be fixed with notice of the vitiating factor. In Etridge, the
House of Lords took a rather different tack. The leading speech was given by
Lord Nicholls of Birkenhead. He turned first to a discussion of the doctrine of
undue influence and then to the role of notice. He first observed that the doctrine
of undue influence was developed by equity to supplement the common law doc-
trine of duress. In equity this took the form of one of two types. These were
cases where improper coercion was established and the second, and for present
purposes the most important, situations where the undue influence arises from
65 [2001] 4 All ER 449. For the fullest commentary on this decision, see MP Thompson [2002]
Conveyancer 174. See also Michael Haley (2002) 14 Child and Family Law Quarterly 93; Mika
Oldham [2002] Cambridge Law Journal 29.
Mortgages and Undue Influence 137
The husband and wife relationship, it was made emphatically clear, did not fall
into this category.
The reasoning at this stage is a little difficult to follow. The distinction drawn
by Lord Nicholls seems to be akin to the Class 2A and 2B categorisation adopted
in O’Brien. This, however, would not appear to be the case as this categorisa-
tion was rejected, it being variously described as adding mystery rather than illu-
mination, as not being a useful forensic tool and as having set the law on the
wrong track.70 What seems to be meant is this. In the case of the very close type
of relationship adverted to by Lord Nicholls, the law will presume that one
party has influence over the other. That is not to say, however, that the influence
was either used or undue. As was made clear, certain transactions within that
relationship are unexceptionable and will not be set aside. Examples of this
would be a situation where a patient gave a birthday present to his doctor. The
law would, rightly, be regarded as being absurd if such a transaction was
regarded as suspect. Something more is needed to raise the presumption of
undue influence, that something being that the nature of the transaction calls for
In other words, in cases of this type, one has to deduce from the transaction
whether the relationship is one where one party reposed faith and confidence in
the other. Yet this is an almost impossible task. As Lord Nicholls pointed out,
the wife may be a willing and, indeed, enthusiastic participant in the proposal.
Alternatively, she might not be and may have been subject to undue pressure
and misrepresentation.73 Accordingly, to attempt to resolve disputes of this kind
by reference to presumptions of undue influence of the type identified as Class
2B was not seen as the best way forward.
NOTICE
An integral part of the reasoning in O’Brien was the role to be played by the
doctrine of notice. Perhaps charitably, Lord Nicholls said that Lord Browne-
Wilkinson would have been the first to have recognised that the doctrine of
notice was not being used in its conventional sense, that sense being to deter-
mine whether a third party had notice of, and was therefore bound by, a pre-
existing equitable right.74 The point, addressed earlier in this paper, was made
that there is no equity in existence prior to the creation of the mortgage; the issue
is whether the mortgagee is privy to the misconduct which induced the wife to
sign the mortgage with the consequence that it is liable to be set aside. He then
made a further, telling, criticism of the use of the doctrine of notice. The central
idea of notice is to ascertain what information should be acquired by a pur-
chaser of property by the making of reasonable enquiries prior to the purchase.
As Lord Nicholls pointed out, however, the precautions which mortgagees
should take to ensure that the wife’s concurrence in the mortgage are not
designed to fulfil this role. The steps suggested in O’Brien are not designed to
discover the existence of a wrong; they are designed to prevent the wrong occur-
ring in the first place.75 Accordingly, the purported application of the doctrine
of notice was rejected; as Lord Scott of Foscote put it, the references to the doc-
trine of notice ‘were contractual questions, not questions relating to competing
property interests’.76
The House of Lords in Etridge rejected much of the reasoning in O’Brien. It was
not, however, prepared to jettison the underlying policy approach adopted in
that case. As Lord Bingham of Cornhill observed, it is important that a wife (or
person in a like position) should not charge her interest in the matrimonial home
without understanding the nature and effect of it and her ability to agree or not
to agree to go ahead with it. Conversely, it is also important that lenders should
be able to advance money against the security of the matrimonial home
confident in the knowledge that they can, if necessary, enforce that security by
possession and sale.77 What the House was concerned to do was to devise a
scheme which protected both competing interests and to do so by putting them
on a sounder conceptual footing than had previously been the case.
To this end, the presumption of undue influence of Class 2B and the role of
the doctrine of notice was abandoned. Instead, what was done was to alter the
law of contract insofar as it related to mortgage and surety contracts. The type
of contract involved in a case such as O’Brien is a tripartite one, involving the
debtor, the lender, and the guarantor. In such cases, so far as the guarantor is
concerned, he or she usually derives no benefit from it. As such, these contracts
are one-sided. To reflect that, what the House of Lords did was to lay down that
in contracts of this type, for the contract to be valid vis-à-vis the surety, the
lender must take certain steps prior to the entry into the contract.
In establishing this principle, two important points were made. First, one of
the difficulties with O’Brien, as noted previously, was to establish when a par-
ticular transaction which involved the creation of a charge over the matrimonial
home was not to the wife’s financial advantage. Difficulties arise with this test,
for example, where the purpose of the loan is to provide finance for a company
in which the wife is a director or employee and so might be expected to benefit
from the success of the company. To avoid such difficulties it was made clear
that in every case when a wife is asked to take on the role of surety in respect of
her husband’s debts then the precautionary measures spelled out later must be
taken. This is so regardless of whether the borrowing is in respect of a company
in which she has an interest. The only mortgage transactions in respect of the
matrimonial home where no particular precautions need be taken prior to their
75 Ibid at 464–5.
76 Ibid at 498.
77
Ibid at 456.
140 Mark Thompson
The House of Lords in Etridge laid down that, in every case where a property is
being mortgaged and the purpose of that mortgage is to secure the debts of one
co-owner or the business of one of the co-owners, then the lender must take cer-
tain precautions if the mortgage is not successfully to be challenged by the other
co-owner. Although in O’Brien, Lord Browne-Wilkinson had laid down his
own guidelines to be followed by mortgagees, it was felt necessary, for a num-
ber of reasons, to revisit this area. First, Lord Browne-Wilkinson had said that
a representative of the mortgagee should conduct a private interview with the
potential complainant. This, however, was not happening and the question
arose as to whether this aspect of the guidelines should be reasserted or dropped.
Various matters which then needed consideration related to the legal advice
which should be given. Issues which were not addressed in O’Brien related to the
independence of the legal advisor and, more particularly, as to whether he or she
could act for more that one party to the transaction, and then what was
expected of the advisor.
In addressing the various issues, Lord Nicholls went into some detail as to the
precautions which the lender should take. In doing so, he made clear that the
steps which he was laying down were applicable to future transactions. In
respect of past transactions, the bank will be regarded as having fulfilled its
obligations if it receives confirmation from a solicitor that he has brought home
to the wife the risks she was running by agreeing to act as a surety.81
PRIVATE INTERVIEW
The role of the solicitor in transactions of this type is clearly crucial. Before con-
sidering what the role of the solicitor is, the anterior question arises as to
whether it is permissible for the solicitor to act for both debtor and surety in
respect of the mortgage. It was accepted that there were arguments on both
sides. On one side is the perception that the solicitor’s advice to her may be less
robust if he is also acting for her husband; on the other is the increased cost
which would be incurred if it were necessary to employ two solicitors. It was
felt, on balance, that the latter consideration had more weight but it was
stressed that, when advising the wife, the solicitor must be clear that her inter-
ests are then paramount and, if there is perceived to be a conflict of interest
between the two roles, then he or she should cease to act for her.82
In much of the litigation which has occurred since O’Brien was decided, the
complainant has actually seen a solicitor but it was evident that the advice
received was of a perfunctory and inadequate nature. The House in Etridge was
concerned to institute a regime which would maximise the chances of her being
properly advised, so that, if she agrees to sign the mortgage, her agreement
should be free and informed. To achieve this outcome, the lenders are required
to follow certain procedures.
Lord Nicholls commented on the fact that, in a number of post-O’Brien cases,
the involvement of the solicitor has been at a late stage in the proceedings, with
the wife not having a clear idea of what the purpose of the advice was or given
any choice in who that solicitor should be. To avoid this, and to prevent the
process of taking advice from being a charade, he said that the bank should do
82 Ibid at 472. See also at 479 per Lord Clyde.
142 Mark Thompson
certain things. First, the bank must communicate directly with her. It is not clear
whether this involves an actual meeting with her but it is probable that written
communication is adequate, given the reluctance of lenders to engage in a direct
dialogue with the wives of borrowers, a reluctance which had earlier been con-
sidered to be quite understandable.83
The lender should inform the wife that, for its protection, it will require writ-
ten confirmation from a solicitor, acting for her, that the solicitor has fully
explained to her the nature of the transaction and the practical consequences of
it. She should be told that when this written confirmation is received, this will
preclude her, subsequently, from disputing the validity of the mortgage. She
should be asked to nominate a solicitor to act for her, it being pointed out that
this can be the solicitor who is also acting for her husband or, alternatively, she
can nominate a different solicitor. The bank should not proceed further until it
receives an appropriate reply directly from her.
The bank knows best the financial position of the husband and, as it is not
willing to conduct a private interview concerning the transaction with her, the
bank is also required to supply the nominated solicitor with certain financial
information. Normally this will include the purpose of the mortgage, the cur-
rent amount of his indebtedness, the amount of his current overdraft facility and
the amount to be borrowed and the terms of the loan. If he has already submit-
ted a mortgage application, a copy of that application should also be provided.
Such information is, of course, confidential to the husband and the bank cannot,
without his consent, release that information to his wife’s solicitor. Unless such
consent is forthcoming, however, the transaction cannot be allowed to proceed.
If the bank complies with these guidelines then the mortgage will, save for very
unusual situations, be immune from subsequent attack.84
The solicitor’s role is crucial but, provided that the lender has followed the
procedure outlined above, should the advice be defective, then this is a matter
between the solicitor and the wife; the inadequacy of the advice will not affect
the validity of the mortgage. The solicitor should in all cases see the wife alone.
The nature of the transaction should be explained to her and the consequences
of a failure to repay the loan—the potential loss of her home and possible bank-
ruptcy—explained. The terms of the loan should be explained including, if this
is the case, that the amount of the loan may be increased without reference to
her.85 The financial position of both parties should be explored and it should be
made clear to her that the decision as to whether or not to proceed is hers and
hers alone and she should be asked if she wishes the solicitor to negotiate on her
behalf with the lender as to the terms of the proposed transaction.86
83 For a different view, see Michael Haley [2002] Conveyancer 499 at 502, commenting on
Hobhouse.
86 Ibid at p 470.
Mortgages and Undue Influence 143
CONCLUSIONS
As was pointed out at the beginning of this paper, the law relating to possession
actions has seen an immense amount of development over the past thirty years.
This development has sought to strike a balance between the interests of occu-
piers of the property being able to maintain their homes and the ability of
lenders to enforce their securities over family property. If the balance is tilted
too much in favour of the occupiers then the unwelcome consequence would
tend to be a drying up of a valuable source of finance, which is a significant
source of capital for small businesses.87 If tilted too far in favour of the banks,
then unacceptable decisions will ensue with co-owners who have either not been
consulted at all,88 or who have been the victims of undue influence or misrepre-
sentation, losing their homes.
The House of Lords in Barclays Bank plc v O’Brien sought to strike an appro-
priate balance between these competing tensions but, in doing so, used an
inappropriate conceptual basis for so doing, placing as it did the emphasis on
presumptions of undue influence and the doctrine of notice. Because of the
artificiality of the reasoning, various difficulties surfaced in the welter of litiga-
tion which ensued when co-owners of properties sought to use the ‘O’Brien
defence’ to resist possession proceedings. By concentrating on the law of con-
tract, rather than the law of property, the House of Lords in Royal Bank of
Scotland v Etridge (No 2) has succeeded in placing the law on a much clearer
footing and, at the same time, struck a reasonable balance between the compet-
ing interests referred to above. While it has placed quite a significant burden on
solicitors who are called upon to advise in these transactions, it has also, it is
suggested, restored a good deal of certainty to an increasingly important area of
law.
INTRODUCTION
The integration of equitable principles and restitution has been described as,
‘still the greatest challenge in the law of restitution’.1 One aspect of this inte-
gration is the relationship between restitution and equitable estoppel; particu-
larly proprietary estoppel. It is clear that to some extent these principles overlap.
This is acknowledged, for example, by Hobhouse LJ in Sledmore v Dalby. He
notes:
One element which is often present in proprietary estoppel . . . is restitution. In many
of its applications the equitable doctrine of proprietary estoppel bears a close rela-
tionship to restitutionary principles where one party has acquiesced in or encouraged
another in conduct whereby that other at his own expense would have, if no remedy
were granted, unjustly enriched the former.2
1
J Beatson The Use and Abuse of Unjust Enrichment—Essays on the Law of Restitution
(Clarendon, Oxford, 1991), 245.
2
(1996) 72 P & CR 196, 208. See also, eg, Sarah Worthington (1999) 26 Journal of Malaysian and
Comparative Law 226, 242. She notes that there are proprietary estoppel cases which, ‘stripped of
the equitable estoppel tag, seem to provide simple illustrations of the law of unjust enrichment in
action’.
146 Nicholas Hopkins
292 suggests there is no reason why estoppel and unjust enrichment should not exist concurrently.
4 Contrast Hussey v Palmer [1972] 1 WLR 1286 where the claimant chose to seek only restitution.
5 Below n 31 and text.
6 See the discussion of estoppel remedies by Elizabeth Cooke ‘Estoppel and the Protection of
Expectations’ (1997) Legal Studies 258, 281–2 and Andrew Robertson ‘Reliance and Expectation in
Estoppel Remedies’ (1998) 18 Legal Studies 360, 364.
7 Below n 30 and text.
Estoppel and Restitution: Drawing a Divide 147
The combined effect of these first two scenarios is that where the facts giving
rise to an estoppel also reveal an unjust enrichment, a claim to estoppel may or
may not produce the same outcome as restitution. This may be criticised in
terms of remedial certainty. At the least, it ought to be considered whether it is
possible to identify the type of case in which the same result is achieved (that is,
the type of case falling within the second scenario) and, if so, whether it would
be advantageous for such claims to be explicitly recognised as giving rise only to
restitution.
The third and fourth scenarios relate to the minority of cases in which claims
to estoppel and restitution coincide: that is, those cases in which the overlap
between the principles extends to the reasoning of the case. The third scenario
arises where, in such a case, an estoppel claim leads to the award of a remedy
equivalent to restitution. As regards this scenario similar considerations arise as
in relation to the second scenario above: that is, whether it is desirable for the
same outcome to be achieved through different principles. The fact that the rea-
soning underlying the principles is the same makes a case for explicitly recog-
nising the facts as giving rise to restitution more compelling. The fourth, and
perhaps the most problematic scenario is where, in the context of a case in
which estoppel and restitution are based on the same reasoning, a remedy is
awarded for estoppel which differs from restitution. It is submitted that this
scenario ought to be prevented. It seems unsatisfactory, not least in terms of
remedial certainty, to retain a situation whereby on the same set of facts the
same reasoning could lead to a different outcome, depending on whether the
case is decided on the basis of restitution or estoppel.
To appreciate the respective likelihood of these scenarios arising, it is helpful
to consider the relationship between the elements of claims to estoppel and
those to restitution.
8
Cf Robertson above n 6, at 364.
9
Cooke above n 6, at 282. This point is made in the context of arguing against the award of
reliance loss in estoppel cases. However as is noted below n 30 and text, there is no necessary equiv-
alence between reliance and restitution. See further Robertson above n 6.
148 Nicholas Hopkins
10 [1982] 1 QB 133.
11 [2000] 2 All ER 289.
12 Ibid, 301.
13 Ibid.
14 Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Ltd v Westpac Banking Corporation (1988) 164
Quarterly Review 66, 90–4. See further Joshua Getzler ‘Unconscionable Conduct and Unjust
Enrichment as Grounds for Judicial Intervention’ (1990) 16 Monash University Law Review 282.
Estoppel and Restitution: Drawing a Divide 149
16 Birks above n 3, at 19. See also Getzler ibid, 324. Getzler comments that ‘[a] finding of unjust
enrichment logically seems to be the conclusion of a process of reasoning whereby the acquisition
or retention of wealth is judged to be unwarranted by some principle of law or morality’ (emphasis
included).
17 Graham Virgo, in The Principles of the Law of Restitution (Oxford, Clarendon, 1999), at 121
Acquisition of Rights in Land (Sweet and Maxwell, London, 2000), 156–8 and by Simon Gardner
‘The Remedial Discretion in Proprietary Estoppel’ (1999) 115 Law Quarterly Review 438.
25 Above n 6, at 366. See further Andrew Robertson ‘Satisfying the Minimum Equity: Equitable
Estoppel Remedies After Verwayen’ (1996) 20 Melbourne University Law Review 805.
26 Above n 24, at 452–60 and 466.
27 [1996] 4 All ER 630, 641.
28 Gardner above n 24, at 453 argues that where expectation is not awarded because it would be
wrong in principle to do so (eg, because of misconduct by the defendant), there is no reason why the
award should be capped at the measure of expectation.
29 Eg, Gillett v Holt above n 11. There, the award of immediate relief by the court inherently
William R Perdue ‘The Reliance Interest in Contract Damages: 1’ (1936) 46 Yale Law Journal 52,
53–4.
Estoppel and Restitution: Drawing a Divide 151
defendant’s gain. Hence the quantum of the remedy awarded under each prin-
ciple may be the same. In this regard, the quantum of restitution is more likely
to coincide with that of the claimant’s reliance than the claimant’s expectation.
This is significant as to the extent that the claimant’s expectation is seen as the
paradigm estoppel remedy, the likelihood of the quantum of the remedy
awarded in estoppel and restitution being the same is reduced.
The potential link between the quantum of restitution with the claimant’s
reliance or expectation can be illustrated through an example. Assume that a
claimant pays the defendant £x for improvements to the defendant’s house, fol-
lowing an assurance that the defendant can live in the house rent-free for life.
Here the claimant’s reliance (payment of £x) coincides with the unjust gain that
will be obtained by the defendant should he renege on the assurance. In contrast,
it may usually be anticipated that the claimant’s expectations will exceed the
amount of the defendant’s enrichment. That is, the value of the claimant’s rent-
free accommodation is likely to exceed the sum of £x paid.
Exceptionally, however, it is possible that the quantum of restitution will
equate with or exceed the claimant’s expectation. This would be the case if the
value of the claimant’s rent-free accommodation is in fact assessed as being
commensurate with or less than the sum paid to the defendant. Baker v Baker31
assists in illustrating this point. There the claimant, who was elderly and in poor
health, provided a large sum of money (approximately £34,000) to the defen-
dant (his son) to enable the defendant to purchase a home for his own family, in
which the claimant would also live rent free for the rest of his life. Within the
first year of occupation relations between the parties irrevocably broke down
and the claimant left the home. The claimant successfully established an estop-
pel but the remedy granted at first instance, of the repayment of the full sum
paid, was reduced by the Court of Appeal to a sum representing the value of the
rent-free occupation. The Court considered that this represented the claimant’s
expectation interest. Dillon LJ explained:
. . . the greatest interest in the property that the parties envisaged [the claimant] hav-
ing was the right . . . to occupy the granny room rent-free for the rest of his life . . ..32
In light of the claimant’s age and health, the value of his occupation would
clearly be substantially less than the sum he had paid:33 the difference reflecting
the fact that the claimant’s occupation was only one of two purposes for which
he had assisted in the purchase of the house. However it is at least arguable that
without the assurance of occupation the claimant would not have paid any
money. Hence, although he was prepared to pay a sum far in excess of the finan-
cial value of the benefit he would receive (his expectation) he was prepared to
do so only because of that benefit. Therefore, on a restitutionary analysis, the
unjust gain received by the defendant in light of the breakdown of relations and
31
[1993] 2 FLR 247.
32
Ibid, 250.
33
The Court of Appeal directed an inquiry to determine the amount of the compensation.
152 Nicholas Hopkins
the claimant’s loss of his occupation could be quantified as being the full sum
paid. On this analysis, the award of the claimant’s expectation loss fell below
that available in a possible claim for restitution.34
A further aspect of the courts’ remedial discretion is that, in all cases, propri-
etary estoppel may lead to a personal or a proprietary remedy. In contrast, in
restitution, proprietary remedies are available only to vindicate a proprietary
right. The claimant to restitution must establish a ‘proprietary base’35 by show-
ing either that legal title did not pass or that the circumstances surrounding the
transfer of legal title give rise to an equitable interest in the claimant’s favour
(that is, the existence of a trust). For the purpose of this paper, it is sufficient to
note that a failure of consideration does not prevent title from passing while, in
the context of mistake, only a fundamental mistake will do so.36 Hence the
ready availability of a proprietary remedy in estoppel further reduces the possi-
bility of the quantum of the outcome under each claim being the same.
As has been noted, the current trend of the courts is to emphasise the role of
unconscionability in estoppel.37 In the context of restitution for wrongs, uncon-
scionability may be a form of equitable wrongdoing giving rise to a claim for
restitution. As a general proposition this is controversial, as unlike the other
forms of equitable wrongdoing (for example, breach of fiduciary duties and
breach of confidence) unconscionability does not involve the breach of a pri-
mary duty. Partly as a consequence of this, a ground of restitution founded on
unconscionability would be of uncertain scope.38 If unconscionability is
accepted as a ground of restitution, then establishing estoppel inherently reveals
a ground of restitution because it necessarily involves a finding of uncon-
scionable conduct. Linking restitution with estoppel also overcomes the latter
objection, as the other elements of an estoppel claim would impose some limi-
tation on the circumstances in which unconscionable conduct leads to restitu-
tion.39 If unconscionability is accepted as a ground of restitution, then a remedy
based on restitution for wrongs may necessarily be available in an estoppel
claim.
34 On the facts of the case a claim to restitution would not have been unproblematic. The most
likely basis of the claim would be a failure of consideration and as the claimant had occupied for a
period of time the failure was not total. However it is possible that restitution could have been
awarded subject to a claim for counter restitution in relation to the period of occupation.
35 A phrase coined by Birks above n 3, at 378–85.
36 These examples are given as failure of consideration and mistake appear to be the most likely
grounds of restitution to overlap with estoppel. For a full discussion of establishing a proprietary
base see Virgo above n 3, at 601–41.
37 Above n 11 and text.
38 Virgo above n 17, at 549.
39 See the discussion of estoppel by Virgo ibid, 549–53.
Estoppel and Restitution: Drawing a Divide 153
SUMMARY
leading to restitution under that branch of law. The provision of greater cohe-
sion may be particularly persuasive in the context of restitution as it has been
acknowledged that that branch of law is often a ‘latecomer’ in legal systems. It
cuts across other principles (including established principles of estoppel) and
must ‘struggle for a place in the legal firmament’.47
As has been noted, the possibility of the same quantum of relief being
awarded under estoppel and restitution is reduced by the tendency of estoppel
remedies to focus on expectations and by the greater availability of proprietary
remedies. With this in mind, a starting point in identifying where the quantum
of relief will be the same under both principles may be to consider those estop-
pel cases in which the court deviates from expectations. However, judged
against the suggested criteria of remedial certainty and greater cohesion at least
three difficulties arise.
First, the parallel existence of an unjust enrichment may often be coinciden-
tal. It is dependent, in particular, on whether the claimant’s acts constituting
detrimental reliance are such as to confer a benefit (enrichment) on the defen-
dant. It is questionable whether cohesion is achieved by carving cases out of an
established estoppel principle because of the coincidental existence of an unjust
enrichment. Secondly, focusing on cases in which expectations are not awarded
would not identify all situations in which an estoppel remedy provides the same
quantum as restitution since, as has been seen, expectations may exceptionally
coincide with restitution. As a result, any claim to greater cohesion is necessar-
ily weakened, as it must be acknowledged that in some cases estoppel will still
lead to an award equivalent to restitution. Thirdly, while it is possible to iden-
tify factors indicating that the award of expectations is not appropriate, such
factors do not necessarily lead to the suggestion that an approach based on resti-
tution would be appropriate. With these factors in mind, the award of estoppel
remedies other than expectations can be considered.
In the context of an estoppel claim, when expectations are not awarded this is
generally either because the courts do not consider it appropriate to do so or
because it is not possible to do so.48 Examples of situations falling within the
former are provided by Sledmore v Dalby.49 There, Hobhouse LJ appeared to
express concerns regarding the proportionality of the award of expectations50
while Roch LJ (with whom Butler-Sloss LJ expressed agreement) emphasised
the need to balance the competing needs of the claimant and representor.51 In
47
Beatson above n 1, at 244.
48
This working summary of the courts’ approach is sufficient for the purposes of this paper. For
a full analysis see Gardner above n 24.
49
Above n 2.
50
Ibid, 207 and 209. See Gardner above n 24, at 457.
51
Ibid, 204–5. See Gardner ibid, 458–9.
156 Nicholas Hopkins
such circumstances, a logical remedial response is one that does ensure propor-
tionality or that provides an appropriate balance between the competing needs
of the parties. The advantage of the remedial discretion in estoppel is that it
enables such a remedy to be determined.52
Chalmers v Pardoe53 and Lee-Parker v Izzet (No 2)54 provide examples of sit-
uations in which the award of expectations was not possible. In the former case,
but not the latter, unjust enrichment was coincidentally present. In Chalmers v
Pardoe the claimant had erected buildings on the representor’s land in the
expectation that he would be granted an interest in the land. The Privy Council
was unable to fulfil this expectation as prior consent to any alienation or other
dealing with the land was required from the Native Land Trust Board.55 On the
facts, the claimant was left without a remedy. This seems to leave the represen-
tor unjustly enriched. A modern approach would perhaps be to provide a rem-
edy other than expectations or allow a claim to restitution.56 In Lee-Parker v
Izzet (No 2), a claim to estoppel was made by the defendant in the action, who
had moved into possession of property on the basis of a contract for sale which
was held to be void for uncertainty. The defendant had paid ‘rent’ and effected
improvements and repairs. The court considered that in principle the defendant
was entitled to ‘compensation’57 against the claimant in the action, who was an
equitable mortgagee of the representor. Here, the award of expectations (an
opportunity to complete the purchase) was not possible as the defendant was
unable to raise the necessary funds.58 The court looked instead at a remedy
based on the defendant’s expenditure (reliance) but considered that the value of
her possession exceeded her expenditure and therefore no award was made. As
the claim was against the mortgagee rather than the representor there was no
question of an unjust enrichment.
The parties seeking relief through estoppel in Chalmers and Lee-Parker may
both be described as risk-takers: in the events that transpired the parties had
52 In Sledmore v Dalby ibid the majority considered that in light of the respective needs of the par-
ties it was no longer inequitable for the representor to defeat the claimant’s expectations. His equity
had ‘expired’ (at 205 per Roch LJ) by his previous use of the property. Hobhouse LJ considered that
no relevant expectation had been reneged upon.
53 [1963] 1 WLR 677.
54 [1972] 1 WLR 775.
55 The representor had initially been willing to apply for such consent and the dispute arose
encouragement, the appropriate ground of restitution would seem to be failure of consideration. See
below n 82 and text.
57 Above n 54, at 780.
58 An opportunity to complete the purchase had been offered in light of the possibility that the
mispredicted the grant to them of rights in the land. In Chalmers, the claimant
ran the risk, perhaps slight, that the Native Land Trust Board would not
approve the assignment or grant of a lease to him.59 (Though not the risk, that
transpired, that the representor would not make the requisite application.) In
Lee-Parker the defendant in the action had expended money on the basis of a
contract that remained subject to her obtaining a satisfactory mortgage. Insofar
as the defendant acted on the basis of a conditional contract the case may be
seen as related to a particular category of risk: that undertaken by a person who
acts on the basis of pre-contractual negotiations. The appropriate basis of
claims arising from pre-contractual expenditure remains subject to debate,
though both estoppel and restitution are considered to be possible sources of
claims. This area of overlap is particularly notable as it is possible for the claims
to estoppel and restitution to arise only in parallel or to coincide.60 There is a
body of academic opinion in favour of using estoppel rather than restitution.61
Spence, for example, argues that the doctrine of equitable estoppel derived from
the Australian cases of Waltons Stores (Interstate) Ltd v Maher 62 and
Commonwealth of Australia v Verwayen63 offer a more convincing rationale
for claims than a number of other possible grounds.64 Hence in this context
where estoppel and restitution overlap the response of some commentators has
been to encourage estoppel reasoning. Spence’s argument is particularly notable
in this respect insofar as he considers that the purpose of estoppel is to compen-
sate reliance.65 Expectations should be awarded as a ‘last resort’ where this is
the only satisfactory way to protect reliance.66 Spence provides an analysis of
pre-contractual expenditure cases in which he demonstrates how estoppel could
explain reliance-based relief. Hence, he supports the use of estoppel to provide
a form of relief which has a greater likelihood of matching the quantum of a
restitution claim.
In part the support afforded to estoppel reflects perceived difficulties in the
nature of a restitution claim. This is especially the case insofar as the restitution
claim is based on free acceptance. However, the need to rely on free acceptance
may arise only where the defendant has done no more than acquiesce in the
59 The court noted above n 53, at 681 that it was ‘probable’ consent would be given.
60 To the extent that free acceptance is used as the ground of restitution in such cases estoppel
and restitution coincide. Where a different ground of restitution exists, the claims arise in parallel.
61 See in particular Michael Spence Protecting Reliance—The Emergent Doctrine of Equitable
Estoppel (Hart, Oxford, 1999), 87–106. The application of estoppel also receives some support from
M P Thompson ‘Compensation for Pre-Contractual Expenditure’ [1995] Conveyancer 135 and Paul
Key ‘Detrimental Reliance in Anticipation of a Contract’ (1995) 111 Law Quarterly Review 576. In
contrast, see Ewan McKendrick ‘Work Done in Anticipation of a Contract which does not
Materialise’ in Restitution Past, Present and Future above n 42, at 188–94. He doubts the usefulness
of estoppel in such cases and suggests, at 194 that unless there is a contract or unjust enrichment the
case for imposing liability on the defendant is less secure.
62
(1987) 164 CLR 387.
63
(1990) 170 CLR 394.
64
Spence above n 61, at 87–106.
65
Ibid, 67.
66
Ibid, 69.
158 Nicholas Hopkins
claimant’s expenditure.67 To some extent the support for estoppel also reflects
advantages inherent in the nature of the claim. Further, in this context again
there would be no advantage in terms of remedial certainty or cohesion by
precluding estoppel.
Spence’s discussion of estoppel leading to the award of reliance-based reme-
dies in pre-contractual cases is convincing, but ultimately the same approach to
remedies is adopted here as in any other estoppel case. In practice, as has been
seen, it may be anticipated that expectations will be awarded unless it is not pos-
sible to do so, or the court does not consider such an award to be appropriate.
The mere fact a case arises from pre-contractual negotiations does not seem to
be a factor barring expectation–based relief. For example, expectations were
awarded in Waltons Stores itself and in the proprietary estoppel case of JT
Developments v Quinn.68 Factually there may be more likelihood of pre-
contractual claims arising in situations in which the award of expectations is not
possible. This would be the case where, for example, following negotiations
with the claimant for the redevelopment of land, the owner instead sells the
land.69 Lee-Parker may also fall within this category. There, as has been seen,70
the award of expectations was not possible due to the inability of the defendant
to raise money to complete the purchase. In terms of cohesion, not every case
concerning pre-contractual expenditure involves an unjust enrichment. For
example in Lee-Parker, as has been noted, no question of unjust enrichment
arose as the claim was against the representor’s equitable mortgagee.
There is one type of pre-contractual case, however, in which the claims to
estoppel and restitution coincide. This is where the defendant merely acquiesces
in the claimant’s acts. In this type of case the only possible claim to restitution
is based on free acceptance which, as has been seen, is based on the same under-
lying reasoning as an estoppel claim. This type of overlap will now be discussed.
Where a claim to estoppel and restitution are based on the same underlying rea-
soning it seems undesirable for that reasoning to be capable of producing dif-
ferent outcomes, depending on whether the language of estoppel or restitution
is adopted. In such situations, the argument for providing remedial certainty
seems particularly compelling. In terms of cohesion, the advantage in focusing
on an overlap with free acceptance is that where this principle is used as a
67 This suggestion reflects the discussion of the scope of free acceptance below n 73 and text. For
a full discussion of the possible unjust factors in this situation see McKendrick above n 61, at 181–6.
68 (1990) P & CR 33. The claim to estoppel arose from negotiations carried out expressly ‘sub-
ject to contract’.
69 This example is based on William Lacey (Hounslow) Ltd v Davis [1957] 1 WLR 932. On
Spence’s analysis of that case above n 61, at 104 an estoppel claim would lead to the award of
reliance loss amounting to compensation for the actual cost of providing the service.
70 Above n 58 and text.
Estoppel and Restitution: Drawing a Divide 159
ground of restitution it establishes both that there is an enrichment and that the
enrichment is unjust. Hence where estoppel coincides with free acceptance the
existence of an unjust enrichment is not merely coincidental but is inherent in
the claim. The extent to which estoppel does coincide with free acceptance has
been reduced significantly as the scope of free acceptance has been refined. The
effect of this is that the dual existence of these claims is now restricted to situa-
tions in which the defendant has acquiesced in the claimant’s misprediction as
to the (future) grant of rights. The application of estoppel by acquiescence in the
context of a misprediction is not beyond doubt.71 On the basis that it does
apply, Birks has suggested that restitution is, in any event, the appropriate
remedy.72 Hence estoppel and restitution appear to coincide only in a context in
which it has already been suggested that restitution is the appropriate remedy
(that is, claims that would fall within the third scenario identified above). If this
is the case, then restricting claimants to restitution should prove relatively
uncontroversial.
while based in essence on the same reasoning, produce different results. On this
classification, Inwards v Baker would fall within the fourth, and most problem-
atic scenario, identified above. Both claims are based on the unconscionable
conduct of the father. In the language of restitution, it is unconscionable for the
father to refuse to pay for a benefit he has freely accepted, despite having
the opportunity to reject; he is therefore unjustly enriched. In the language of
estoppel, the father has unconscionably reneged on an assurance of rights.77
Adopting the language of restitution leads to the return of the unjust enrich-
ment, while estoppel enables the son to receive his expectations.78
In refining the scope of free acceptance,79 Birks has removed this broad over-
lap. Where, as in Inwards v Baker, there is active encouragement of a mispre-
diction (in Birks’ terms, where a benefit is requested)80 free acceptance is no
longer considered to be the ground of restitution in the majority of cases. Free
acceptance is required as a ground of restitution only in those cases in which
there is mere acquiescence in the misprediction. This limitation arises because
free acceptance is based on unconsionability existing at the time the benefit is
received, as it focuses on the defendant’s conduct in the acceptance of the
benefit.81 In Inwards v Baker, and generally where a positive assurance of rights
is made, the unconscionable conduct occurs at the later stage when the repre-
sentor reneges on the assurance. Hence in Inwards v Baker the father did not
receive the benefit unconscionably as he intended to grant his son rights in the
land. The unconscionable conduct arose only at the later stage when, following
the son’s detrimental reliance, his father did not give effect to the assurance of
rights. This refinement of free acceptance does not mean that cases based on a
misprediction following a positive assurance do not involve an overlap between
estoppel and restitution. However, the ground of restitution in such cases is now
seen as being the claimant-oriented ground of failure of consideration.82 Hence
Inwards v Baker now falls within the first scenario, where the different remedies
available through estoppel and restitution are based on different reasoning.
77 The timing of the unconscionable conduct differs under the two claims. In restitution, the
unconscionability lies in the free acceptance of the benefit while in estoppel it lies in reneging on the
assurance.
78 Commenting on the remedial uncertainty in estoppel claims, Birks above n 3, at 290–3 sug-
gested a division whereby the existence of a positive assurance would lead to the award of expecta-
tions while in cases of acquiescence the claimant should be confined to restitution. The current
author does not endorse this broad distinction above n 24, at 163–5. See further Getzler above n 15,
at 310–14.
79
Peter Birks ‘In Defence of Free Acceptance’ in Andrew Burrows (ed) Essays on the Law of
Restitution (Clarendon, Oxford, 1991).
80
Ibid, 109.
81
Ibid, 111.
82
Birks ibid, 111 accepting an argument by AS Burrows ‘Free Acceptance and the Law of
Restitution’ (1988) 104 Law Quarterly Review 576.
Estoppel and Restitution: Drawing a Divide 161
CONCLUSION
Judged against the criteria of legal certainty and achieving greater cohesion the
conclusion reached is that where claims to estoppel and restitution exist in par-
allel no advantage is obtained by seeking to identify a type of case in which the
claimant should be restricted to restitution. In relation to coinciding claims,
which arise only where estoppel overlaps with a claim to restitution based on
free acceptance, the same criteria appear to justify restricting claimants to resti-
tution. In this way, a division between estoppel and restitution can be drawn
based on the existence of the twin elements of a misprediction, rather than a
mistake, and acquiescence, rather than a positive assurance.
So drawn, the circumstances in which a claimant is restricted to restitution
are admittedly narrow. Further, it is a division operating on the margins of both
estoppel and restitution. Estoppel claims arising from acquiescence in a mispre-
diction are relatively rare. The use of free acceptance as a ground of restitution
is based more on academic theory than judicial authority and even in the view
of Birks, as one of its strongest advocates, it is a ‘long-stop’ to be used only
where no other ground of restitution is available.94 Despite this, however, the
division is a significant one as it touches on the basis of claims which remain
93 (1981) 41 P & CR 179.
94 Above n 79, at 145.
Estoppel and Restitution: Drawing a Divide 163
subject to debate; for example, claims arising from pre-contractual acts. This
can be used briefly to illustrate the effect of the division. Claims arising from
pre-contractual expenditure are necessarily concerned with claimants who have
mispredicted the grant of rights. The suggested division indicates that where the
claimant acts on a positive assurance (in Birks’ terms, where the service is
requested) estoppel is a suitable basis for a claim. Where the defendant does no
more than acquiesce in the claimant’s acts any action by the defendant should
be confined to the award of restitution.
9
Proprietary Estoppel and Formalities
in Land Law and the Land Registration
Act 2002: A Theory of
Unconscionability
MARTIN DIXON 1
1
Responsibility for this essay is mine, but I am grateful for the comments of Professor John
Adams, and Gerwyn Griffiths.
2
Court of Appeal Transcript, 16 February 2000.
3
[2001] EWCA Civ 1754. See [2002] Conv 584.
4
There is little reference to authority, although see the similar approach of Lawrence Collins QC
(Deputy High Court Judge) in Locabail (UK) Ltd v Bayfield Properties Ltd, Transcript, 9 March
1999. See Megarry & Wade, Law of Real Property (6th edn. 2001) at 745 et seq where a majority of
the relevant authorities are collected. In any event, section 116 of the Land Registration Act 2002 set-
tles the matter for land of registered title: see below n 39. In Lloyd, it was held that Mr Dugdale was
not in ‘actual occupation’ and so had no overriding interest.
5 Transcript, 30 November 2001.
6 [2002] 09 EG 222.
7
[2001] EWCA Civ 2001.
166 Martin Dixon
8 £35,000. This was not the ‘expectation loss’ of the claimant (who had been encouraged to
believe he would have a home for life), but the court’s interpretation of the ‘minimum equity neces-
sary to do justice to the plaintiff’ per Scarman LJ in Crabb v Arun District Council [1976] Ch 179 at
198. See also Cook v Norlands Ltd., [2001] 1 All ER (D) 24 (Dec), on appeal from the Isle of Man,
where the estoppel was satisfied by an award of £25,000 ‘in compensation’.
9 [2002] EWCA Civ 159.
10 Transcript, 6 March 2002.
11 [2000] Ch 162.
12 Above n 10 para 69 per L Henderson QC, dismissing an application for summary judgement
want ‘a portable palm tree’. In relation to remedies, Robert Walker LJ in Jennings, above n 9 at para
43, rejects the suggestion made by Gardner in The Remedial Discretion in Proprietary Estoppel
(1999) 115 Law Quarterly Review 438 that ‘the approach is for the court to adopt whatever style and
measure of relief it thinks fit, for whatever reason it thinks fit’.
A Theory of Unconscionability 167
A : AN ESTOPPEL BOOM ?
In one sense it is not important to the central argument of this paper about the
proper confines of the law of proprietary estoppel that there will be an estoppel
boom. For the present writer, the rather haphazard way in which uncon-
scionability (and hence estoppel) is currently approached is reason enough to
provoke a re-examination. Nevertheless, if there is an estoppel boom, particu-
larly if that is a consequence of the application of the radical provisions of the
Land Registration Act 2002, those charged with deciding issues or advising
clients will have need of guidance, however imperfect.14 Furthermore, there is
the very real risk that the central provisions of the new Act concerning electronic
conveyancing could be undermined by the application of proprietary estoppel in
cases where, on a proper understanding of the role of unconscionability, that
would be wholly unwarranted.
It is, of course, trite law that proprietary estoppel can be either a sword for
the claimant or a shield for the defendant. In either case, a successful plea can
result in the award of something concrete for the ‘victim’, although this need not
be an immediate proprietary right nor, indeed, any property right at all.15 The
types of factual situations in which estoppel may arise have been thoroughly
researched with considerable skill by others and in this respect there is little that
may be usefully added here.16 Of particular interest for the purposes of this
paper, however, are those cases where proprietary estoppel has been used to
establish a claim by a person who is unable to rely on the normal rules concern-
ing the creation or transfer (and sometimes enforcement) of interests in land.
These are what might be called the ‘formality cases’, being instances where the
parties could have, should have or nearly did use the proper formality, but
where estoppel is pleaded to fill the void. As the judge said in Yeo v Wilson,
[p]roprietary estoppel is one of the oldest devices of equity for giving effect to appar-
ent understandings about the disposition of property, which for one reason or another
are not enforceable at law.17
So, proprietary estoppel has been used to support some sort of remedy where a
contract for the transfer of land was void for uncertainty of subject matter
(Flowermix Ltd v Site Development (Ferndown) Ltd18); where there was no con-
tract at all despite the prospect of one (Yaxley v Gotts); where there was no will
14 As Megarry & Wade indicates, ‘[t]he flexibility of proprietary estoppel . . . is its strength and
its weakness—this is not conducive to the settlement of disputes and leads to costly litigation’, above
n 4 at 728
15 Money awards were made in Jennings, Campbell and Norlands. In Sledmore v Dalby, [1996]
72 P & CR 196, the claim to a life interest was denied because, even if there had been the necessary
assurances, the claimant had received all that he could have expected.
16 See generally Pawlowski, The Doctrine of Proprietary Estoppel (1996) and Cooke, The
in favour of the claimant or anybody else (Jennings v Rice); where there was a
will in favour of someone other than the claimant (Gillett v Holt19); where an
intended devise in a will had lapsed (Campbell v Griffin); where a deed was
defective as to witnessing (Mukesh Shah v Panachand Shah20); where an
intended lease (the terms of which were settled) was never executed (Lloyd v
Dugdale); and where a lease may have been uncertain as to its commencement
(Liverpool City Council v Walton21).
The essence of the issue in these formality cases is that one party claims to be
entitled to some proprietary right (or its monetary equivalent22) even though in
the normal course such a right should not exist because of the absence of
required formality. Estoppel is seen in such cases as an antidote for the formal-
ity defect. Typically, the requirement of formality arises because of some statu-
tory rule.23 These may be statutory provisions of general import, such as
sections 1 and 2 of the Law of Property (Miscellaneous Provisions) Act 1989
(LPA 1989), the Wills Act 1837 and section 53 of the Law of Property Act 1925,
or less commonly statutory provisions designed to deal with some specific mis-
chief, as in Oakley v Airclear Environmental Ltd and the need for a written con-
tract under section 107 of the Housing Grants, Construction and Regeneration
Act 1996.24 In either type of case, there is always the problem that the use of
estoppel appears to contradict the policy behind the legislation by attaching an
element of validity to an arrangement that the legislation requires to be in a cer-
tain form but which the parties have failed to observe.25 This is what Robert
Walker LJ in Yaxley v Gotts calls the ‘public policy principle’26 and it is consid-
ered more fully below for it lies at the heart of the debate about the proper reach
of estoppel. For the moment, the simple point is that such concerns (ie the
public policy principle) do not appear to have unduly hindered the use and
development of estoppel. If anything, estoppel claims appear to have increased
in frequency as formality rules have been tightened. The abolition of the doc-
trine of part performance and the insistence on written formality under the LPA
1989 perhaps being the chief reason for the current level of estoppel claims.
Importantly, however, the 1989 Act is not to be the last change that will be made
19 [2000] 3 WLR 815.
20 [2002] QB 35.
21 Transcript, 25 July 2001, Neuberger J. Presumably, the local authority is acting in its ‘private
capacity’ (see Mobil Oil Company v Birmingham City Council, [2001] EWCA Civ 1608) and estop-
pel is not being used to fetter the discretion of a public authority. For this ongoing debate see lately
R v East Sussex County Council ex p Reprotech [2002] UKHL 8.
22 Not ‘merely’ recovery of the costs incurred as a result of the reliance, for such recovery lies in
restitution rather than in estoppel, as in Ravenocean Ltd v Gardner, [2001] All ER (D) 116 (Jan) and
Singh v Khan [1988] EGCS 92.
23 Though not exclusively, see Walton above n 21, where there is non-compliance with the com-
ing out of the circumstances in which the agreement was attempted. Hence, the remedy may not be,
indeed often is not, equivalent to that which would have occurred had the agreement been valid.
26 Above n 11 at 172.
A Theory of Unconscionability 169
to the formality rules for land transactions. Indeed, its importance will diminish
when the Act of 2002 fully enters force.27
The Land Registration Act 2002 has much to say about the way proprietary
rights affect land of registered title. As is well known, its primary purpose is to
facilitate the introduction of electronic conveyancing and thereby the compila-
tion of a register that is a near perfect mirror of the title to the land and all the
proprietary rights affecting it.28 Many strategies are employed to this end and
not all are relevant here.29 However, there are a number provisions concerning
the circumstances in which proprietary rights may be granted, transferred or
enforced and, in consequence, a potential impact on the law of estoppel. First,
under the provisions of the LRA 2002 and the Electronic Communications Act
2000, it will be possible in due course to create or transfer proprietary rights
either by means of a paper (‘material’) deed or written contract (as now) or by
an ‘electronic’ (‘non-material’) deed or written contract.30 Of itself, this raises
no fundamental concerns because it is clear that the electronic deed or contract
will be treated as having the same effect as its paper counterpart. Presumably,
however, some defect in the execution of the electronic deed or contract will be
curable by proprietary estoppel, at least to the extent that a defect in a paper
deed or written contract is curable. So, for example, a failure to meet one of the
four conditions specified in section 91(3) LRA 2002 for the validity of an elec-
tronic disposition would render the disposition itself ineffective but, we might
suppose, a claim in proprietary estoppel could still succeed.31 Secondly, it is the
ultimate aim of the LRA 2002 that the act of creation or transfer of most pro-
prietary rights will occur simultaneously with their electronic entry on the reg-
ister. Or, to put the matter the other way round, the attempted creation or
transfer of most proprietary rights will be completely ineffective to create or
transfer a right at law or in equity unless an appropriate entry is made on the
register. This is the effect of section 93(2) LRA 2002 when it stipulates that a
27
Note also that proprietary estoppel can be used to circumvent the general policy behind an Act
of Parliament, as in JS Bloor (Measham) Ltd v Calcott above n 6 regarding the Agricultural
Holdings Act 1996 and in Colchester Borough Council v Smith [1992] Ch 421 regarding the
Limitation Act 1980.
28
The fundamental objective of the Bill is that, under the system of electronic dealing with land
that it seeks to create, the register should be a complete and accurate reflection of the state of the
title of the land at any given time, so that it is possible to investigate title to land on line, with the
absolute minimum of additional enquiries and inspections’, Law Commission Report No 271, Land
Registration for the Twenty-first Century, para 1.5.
29
See Cooke, The Land Registration Bill [2002] Conv 11.
30
An Order may be made under s 8 of the Electronic Communications Act 2000 permitting the
use of electronic deeds by inserting a new s 144A in the LRA 1925 and permitting electronic con-
tracts by inserting a new s 2A into the LPA 1989. Section 144A will be superseded by the entry into
force of s 91 of the LRA 2002. See generally, LCD Consultation Paper 05/2001, March 2001 and LCD
Consultation Response, December 2001.
31
Pending the introduction of full electronic conveyancing, failure to register a valid electronic
deed where that is required will result (as now) in a failure to transfer an estate at law (s 27(1) LRA
2002), but the valid electronic deed will be effective to create or transfer an interest in equity. Section
27(1) will be disapplied in relation to those estates and interests required to be completed by regis-
tration under s 93 LRA 2002 for such a failure will render the transaction completely ineffective.
170 Martin Dixon
denied by section 93 LPA 2002.36 Thirdly, registration (ie the act of creation or
transfer) will be electronic, and only authorised persons will be able to transact.
Thus, not only is it likely that individuals will continue to deal with each other
without the benefit of legal advice and hence without understanding the relevant
formality rules (as in Yaxley v Gotts), even if they did comprehend section 93
LRA 2002, how would they ensure the registration of their right? While it may
be true that less than 1 per cent of all transactions are DIY conveyances,37 the
Act will apply to much more than conveyances: as already noted, it will extend
to the creation or transfer of most third party rights in land. DIY conveyances
may be relatively rare, but the DIY attempted creation or transfer of other rights
in property is far more common.38 Fourthly, and perhaps most importantly, it
is now clear from Lloyd v Dugdale that an ‘estoppel’ is a proprietary right capa-
ble of binding a third party as an overriding interest under the current section
70(1)(g) LRA 1925 and hence will be an ‘interest that overrides’ within Schedules
1 and 3 LRA 2002. Indeed, even if Lloyd had said otherwise, section 116 LRA
2002 puts the matter beyond doubt.39 Thus, whereas the failed creation or trans-
fer of a proprietary right under the rubric of electronic conveyancing will be of
no effect at all (s 93 LRA 2002), and so cannot trigger an ‘interest that overrides’
within the Schedules, a successful estoppel can do just this—the Act itself makes
that clear even without Dugdale. How tempting then to use estoppel both to
acquire the right despite the absence of compliance with sections 91 or 93 LRA
2002 (or the intended section 2A LPA 1989) and then when the estoppel is estab-
lished to ally it with actual occupation to make it binding against a third party.
In other words, estoppel may well come to be the single most effective way of
creating, transferring and enforcing property rights outside of electronic for-
malities. The greater the injunction to use electronic measures, the greater the
scope for claims in estoppel.
Of course, this analysis rather assumes that estoppel actually can save a trans-
action that fails to comply with the relevant formalities relating to creation and
registration as required by the LRA 2002. We might think, for example, that
such is the conveyancing revolution and so clear is the Act that the above analy-
sis overestimates the role for estoppel in land registration. However, in reality,
36 Carefully drafted Land Registration Rules and appropriate training will minimise the risk, but
it is all too clear that clients are not always advised at present to adhere to the requirements of s 2
LPA 1989. How likely then that compliance with s 93 LRA 2002 will proceed with ease?
37 Law Commission Report No. 271 para 13.72.
38 It is clear that private individuals often feel the need for writing when dealing with land, irre-
spective of any knowledge of formality requirements and thus there is often ‘accidental’ compliance
with s 2 LPA 1989. No doubt this will continue, but will they feel the same way about electronic reg-
istration/creation and so visit the District Land Registry for help?
39 ‘It is hereby declared for the avoidance of doubt that, in relation to registered land, each of the
following—
(a) an equity by estoppel, and
(b) a mere equity,
has effect from the time the equity arises as an interest capable of binding successors in title (sub-
ject to the rules about the effect of dispositions on priority)’.
172 Martin Dixon
this is no new dilemma but merely a version of an old problem: viz. when can
proprietary estoppel protect a claimant who has not used the degree of formal-
ity or followed the correct process required by statute. Whether it be non-
compliance with sections 2 or (the intended) 2A of the LPA 1989, (the possible)
section144A Land Registration Act 1925, section 53 of the LPA 1925, or sections
91 or 93 of the LRA 2002, can estoppel come to the claimant’s aid, and why?
The revelation that there is a tension between the strict requirements of formal-
ity (including registration issues) and the court’s desire to achieve a measure of
equitable justice between the parties surprises no-one. This is the ancient equi-
table jurisdiction and the maxim that ‘equity will not permit a statute to be an
instrument of fraud’ is no mere mantra. Yet, when it comes to land, there is a
greater reluctance to side-step formality rules. For example, there is still uncer-
tainty about the justification for secret trusts of land40 and the courts find great
comfort in the fact that there are statutory exemptions in favour of constructive
trusts of land, so providing a ready answer that avoids the need for an enquiry
in to the fundamental reasons why such transactions are enforceable despite the
absence of the appropriate formality.41 In particular, there is great concern
about the relationship between section 2 of the LPA 1989 and the law of estop-
pel, as witness the argument in Yaxley and the dictum in Moloo v Standish
Hotels that ‘the precise relationship between proprietary estoppel and section 2
of the 1989 Act has yet to be definitively stated’.42 The point is made succinctly
(indeed dogmatically) in Halsbury’s Laws, that the ‘doctrine of estoppel may
not be invoked to render valid a transaction which the legislature has, on
grounds of general public policy, enacted is to be invalid’.43 Consequently, this
suggests that intended dispositions of interests in land that the law requires to
take a certain form—for example, in writing or by deed—may not be enforced
by estoppel for that would be to undermine the legislative purpose and policy.44
In fact, however, the position is more complex. The available evidence sug-
gests that courts will use estoppel to circumvent ‘secondary’ statutory formality
rules or to bar reliance on protective provisions in legislation where this sup-
40
See Re Ballie and Ottaway v Norman [1972] Ch 698.
41
See s 53(2) LPA 1925 and s 2(5) LP (MP) A 1989. Perhaps this is why Robert Walker LJ prefers
the constructive trust solution in Yaxley. In Jennings above n 9 at para 45 he says that when pro-
prietary estoppel has ‘a consensual character falling not far short of an enforceable contract, if the
only bar to the formation of a contract is non-compliance with section 2 of the Law of Property
(Miscellaneous Provisions) Act 1989, the proprietary estoppel may become indistinguishable from a
constructive trust’. Quare whether it is distinguishable if these conditions do not obtain.
42 Above n 10.
43 4th edn Reissue, vol 16 (1992) para 962, cited in Yaxley, above n 11 at 172.
44 For the classic analysis see Fuller, Consideration and form (1941) 41 Columbia Law Review
799.
A Theory of Unconscionability 173
ports (or at least does not contradict) the underlying purpose of the legislation.45
Consequently, if this underlying statutory purpose can be supported (or not
evaded) through the use of estoppel, it is taken for granted that its application is
appropriate without proof of special facts over and above those commonly
required to establish the estoppel. However, with section 2 of the LPA 1989 the
position is quite different and this may explain why its particular relationship
with proprietary estoppel generates such uncertainty. The whole point of sec-
tion 2 of the 1989 Act is to invalidate transactions that do not comply with its
formality rules: it is a “primary” formality rule. The use of formality is the
policy of the statute and so to use estoppel to circumvent it needs a convincing
explanation. As Robert Walker LJ made clear in Yaxley,
[p]arliament’s requirement that any contract for the disposition of an interest in land
must be made in a particular documentary form, and will otherwise be void . . . can be
seen as embodying Parliament’s conclusion, in the general interest, that the need for
certainty as to the formation of contracts of this type must in general outweigh the dis-
appointment of those who make informal bargains in ignorance of the statutory
requirement.46
The same is true, mutatis mutandis, of the relevant provisions of the Wills Act
and, it is submitted, of the intended section 2A of the LPA 1989 and sections 91
and 93 of the LRA 2002. The whole point of the latter, as made clear in Law
Commission Report No 271, is to force the use of electronic dealings with land
by invalidating those dealings that do not comply. Again, the very purpose of
the provisions is to force the use of this electronic formality and its circumven-
tion by estoppel will need some justification.
In one sense, of course, this might be a matter of degree. If it is true that certain
types of statutory formality (in its broadest sense to include registration require-
ments) can be circumvented by proprietary estoppel when this furthers the policy
of the relevant statute (or at least does not undermine it), then surely proprietary
estoppel can be used to circumvent ‘primary’ formality rules providing there is a
similar policy justification? This is not uncontroversial, as it is now well known
that at least one major academic authority suggests that a proprietary remedy by
way of estoppel would be inappropriate, even in the face of unconscionable con-
duct, if the effect would be to circumvent section 2 of the LPA 1989.47
Nevertheless, despite these reservations, it is submitted that is now beyond rea-
sonable doubt that proprietary estoppel can be used to save a transaction which
falls foul of section 2 of the LPA 1989. There is no absolute incompatibility
between section of the 2 LPA 1989 and proprietary estoppel. First, there is no sug-
gestion in the Law Commission’s 1987 Report on The Transfer of Land:
45
For example, JS Bloor (Measham) Ltd v Calcott, above n 6.
46
Above n 11 at 175.
47
Goff & Jones, The Law of Restitution, 5th edn (Sweet and Maxwell, London, 1998), 580.
Note, however, it is the form of remedy that is disputed, not the possibility that the claimant may
be successful. This is in line with the authors’ general position that the restitutionary base of many
established remedies should be recognised.
174 Martin Dixon
Formalities for Contracts of Sale etc. of Land (No. 164) (which led to the 1989 Act)
that section 2 should have such an uncompromising effect. In fact, the view of the
Commission in the earlier Working Paper No. 92 was that it ‘appears to us obvi-
ously out of the question to exclude the application of these general judicial doc-
trines (restitution as well as equitable estoppel) in this particular area of sales etc.
of land’.48 Of course, we might be tempted to dispute the relevance of Law
Commission Reports when determining the effect of primary legislation—as noted
in Yaxley itself—but it cannot be denied that the raising of the formality threshold
was not intended to prevent a claim by proprietary estoppel. As for other ‘formal-
ity rules’, it is submitted that likewise there is no absolute prohibition on the use
of proprietary estoppel to save an otherwise void transaction—providing of course
that the paramount test of unconscionability is passed. In respect of sections 91
and 93 LRA 2002 in particular, it is not surprising that the role of proprietary
estoppel is not canvassed directly in the relevant preparatory material published by
the Law Commission. Given that the point of the LRA 2002 is to ensure that many
more proprietary rights become registered, it would be a surprise to see the
Commission flagging up a ready device by which the fundamental provisions could
be avoided. In fact, it may well be significant that the new legislation establishes
conclusively the ‘proprietary effect’ of estoppel within the new world of electronic
conveyancing: see section 116 LRA 2002. After all, it is not critical to the success
of the new scheme that the true nature of estoppel should be spelt out, not, that is,
unless it is anticipated or suspected that many more cases of estoppel will arise
when the new provisions take effect. Secondly, while Robert Walker LJ concludes
in Yaxley, following on from Godden v Merthyr Tydfil Housing Association 49
that ‘estoppel by convention’ has not survived the enactment of section 2 of the
LPA 1989,50 he has ‘no hesitation in agreeing—that the doctrine of estoppel may
operate to modify (and sometimes even counteract) the effect of section 2 of the
Act of 1989’.51 Once again, it is submitted that what is good for section 2 of the
LPA 1989 is also good for other formality requirements. Thirdly, this author has
found no case where the alleged incompatibility of proprietary estoppel with the
requirements of section 2 (or its equivalents) has been raised successfully as a com-
plete defence to an estoppel claim. It is not always wise to speculate, but perhaps
48
Working Paper No 92 at 35 and see Report No 164 at 19–20.
49
Court of Appeal Transcript, 15 January 1997.
50 ‘Estoppel by convention’ is founded on the existence of an agreed state of affairs between the
parties as the basis of their transaction. If this shared assumption proves to be false, neither may
resile from it: Amalgamated Property Company v Texas Bank [1982] 1 QB 84. Clearly, a shared
assumption that a contract concerning land is valid, when in fact it is void due to the absence of the
required formality, cannot of itself justify the court in enforcing it. This would, to use Sir John
Balcombe’s words in Godden ‘drive a coach and horses through a recent Act of Parliament [the 1989
Act] enacted for very specific reasons of public policy’, above n 49. That is not to say, however, that
a claim that once fell within ‘estoppel by convention’ could not fall within proprietary estoppel, pro-
vided of course that the unconscionability test was met.
51 Above n 49 at para 174. On one view, Robert Walker LJ preserves proprietary estoppel because
it falls within the saving of constructive trusts under s 2(5) LPA 1989, the doctrines being synony-
mous in these types of cases: see above n 11. This is not the current author’s reading of Yaxley.
A Theory of Unconscionability 175
this is because it is commonly assumed that the requirements of the section do not
ipso facto bar a claim in proprietary estoppel. If, instead, it is thought that the rel-
ative absence of discussion about the relationship of proprietary estoppel and for-
mality requirements (especially section 2) can be explained because not all cases
involve failed contracts, it must be remembered that the great majority of propri-
etary rights can exist only through some degree of formality and this has not ham-
pered the steady march of estoppel claims. Fourthly, and most importantly, there
is a reason why section 2 and its equivalents (including sections 91 and 93 LRA
2002) do not ipso facto prevent a claim in proprietary estoppel. Put simply,
reliance on the lack of normally required formality will not defeat a claim to a pro-
prietary right where this would unconscionable. Put positively, the reason why it
is possible to use proprietary estoppel to generate a property interest despite the
absence of formality—be this required by the LPA 1989, section 53 of the LPA 1925
or sections 91or 93 of the LRA 2002—is because of the need to prevent uncon-
scionable conduct. This is why unconscionability is the foundation of estoppel52
and why estoppel is the antidote to an otherwise fatal absence of formality.
Consequently, as argued below, a coherent understanding of the role of uncon-
scionability can be achieved only by relating it to these formality rules. The
requirements of the latter are the key to understanding the former.
C : ANALYSING UNCONSCIONANBILITY
The central role that unconscionability plays in the law of estoppel seems, at
least to the present writer, to be in inverse proportion to the analysis devoted to
it in the cases. All judges are agreed that unconscionability is vital, but few seem
willing to share their understanding of the concept. There is a denial that the
court is engaged in ‘palm tree justice’, but little to tell us where the beach has
ended. The implication is, of course, that unconscionability must mean some-
thing reasonably definable, but the identification of its essential elements seems
to be unimportant provided that in the case before the judge it is clear that
in all the circumstances, it is unconscionable for the representor to go back on the
assumption which he permitted the representee to make.53
52 See Oliver Js dictum in Taylor Fashions Ltd. v Liverpool Victoria Trustees Co. Ltd. [1982] QB
133n at 151 that what is required is a ‘broader approach which is directed rather at ascertaining
whether, in particular individual circumstances, it would be unconscionable for a party to be per-
mitted to deny that which, knowingly or unknowingly, he has allowed or encouraged another to
assume to his detriment than to enquiring whether the circumstances can be fitted within the
confines of some preconceived formula serving as a universal yardstick of unconscionable behav-
iour’. Or, in the words of Robert Walker J in Gillett, ‘the fundamental principle that equity is con-
cerned to prevent unconscionable conduct permeates all the elements of the doctrine’, above n 19.
See also Thompson [1998] Conv 210 at 216 and Dixon [1999] Conv 46 at 47.
53
Per Lord Brown–Wilkinson in Lim Teng Huan v Ang Swee Chuan [1992] 1 WLR 113 at 117.
176 Martin Dixon
Academically, the seam is deeper and richer, but apart from the robust analysis
of those commentators who for policy reasons favour a broad and largely
undefined concept of unconscionability, there is little that helps in the search for
a firmer concept if one does not accept that unconscionability should be left
shapeless.54 The present author is not content with a shapeless concept of
unconscionability, but instead sees both good reason and good need to define
unconscionability more tightly. The reason is that, as will be argued below, the
concept actually fulfils more than one function in the law of estoppel, one of
which is vital to the very existence of a successful claim. The need is, as argued
above, that if there is to be an estoppel boom, it is better to have a clearer idea
of when an estoppel plea can be successful before the boom arrives.
It is well known that a court will search for some form of assurance issuing
from the person alleged to be estopped in favour of the claimant, on which the
claimant has detrimentally relied. Although, as Gillett says, the court should
take an holistic approach to proof of the estoppel, it is clear that many claimants
fail because they cannot establish one of these three elements.55 What is less fre-
quent is the rejection of an estoppel plea on the simple ground that there is no
unconscionability, at least in terms of disallowing the claim ab initio rather than
modifying the remedy.56 Such cases are rare, and we must wonder why. For the
present writer, there are two possibilities. Possibly, the concept of uncon-
scionability is so poorly understood that judges prefer (or are forced by the
paucity of analysis) to deny an estoppel on the ground of the absence of either
assurance, reliance or detriment rather than venturing into the murky waters of
unconscionability. If we have no clear concept of unconscionability, it is
difficult to deny a claimant on the basis that it is absent. Alternately, we could
argue that unconscionability is so bound up with ‘assurance, reliance and detri-
ment’ that it has ceased to have a meaning independent of these criteria and
hence the denial of a claim proceeds most easily by denying the existence of one
of these three elements for lack of unconscionability adds nothing.
In fact, although the present writer is of the view that first alternative is very
near the mark, it is this second approach that now seems to be gaining ground. In
Gillett v Holt, Robert Walker LJ endorses the view that it is the detrimental
reliance by the claimant on the representor’s assurance that makes any subsequent
attempt to revoke the assurance unconscionable.57 This echoes Carnwath Js views
54
See Thompson above n 52 and [2001] Conv 78; Cooke above n 16 at 85; Dixon, [2000]
Cambridge Law Journal 453.
55
For example, in Bryan v Shoultz, Court of Appeal, 21 April 1999, there was no reliance, the assur-
ance having been withdrawn before it was acted on (see also Stoeckert v Geddes, (2000) 80 P & CR D11
and Aylwen v Takla, Court of Appeal, 6 April 2000). In Jones v Stones [1999] 1 WLR 1739 there was
no assurance (see also Yeo v Wilson, above n 17). In Orgee v Orgee (1997) EGCS 152 there was no detri-
ment (and see also Singh v Khan, above n 23 and Takla). In Gillett itself, the holistic approach did not
prevent the court identifying with some precision the relevant assurance, reliance and detriment.
56
For example, Oakley v Airclear, above n 24.
57
Above n 19, approving Swadling’s comments on Dickens at [1998] Restitution Law Review
220. See also Gillett at 229 where Robert Walker LJ says that ‘it is the other party’s detrimental
reliance on the promise which makes it irrevocable’.
A Theory of Unconscionability 177
60 It is submitted that this is precisely what occurred in Flowermix, above n 18, where Arden J
effectively enforced a contract that was void for uncertainty, apparently on the ground that the
failed contract constituted an assurance relied on to detriment. There is no indication of where the
unconscionability resides.
61
[1987] 1 AC 114.
62
Court of Appeal Transcript, 20 July 2000.
63
[2001] 23 EG 158.
64
Transcript, No 1997 T No 76.
65
A claim of estoppel was also denied in Canty v Broad, Court of Appeal Transcript, 25 May
1995 (expressly subject to contract); Akiens v Salomon (1993) 65 P & CR 364 (occupation expressly
“subject to lease”); Derby & Co Ltd v ItC Pension Trust Ltd [1977] 2 All ER 890 (expressly subject
to contract) and Pridedean Ltd v Forest Taverns Ltd [1996] PLSCS 66 (where the whole basis of deal-
ings was that a formal contract would be concluded).
A Theory of Unconscionability 179
The burden of the above analysis does not deny that unconscionability is cen-
tral to a successful claim in proprietary estoppel. However, the contention is
66 Above n 61 at 127. See Salvation Army Trustee Co. Ltd. v West Yorkshire M.C.C 1981 41 P &
CR 179 where the agreement from which the estoppel successfully arose appears not to have been
made ‘subject to contract’, despite an intention to do so.
67 This is not to suggest that the ‘revocability’ of such an assurance is the litmus test of uncon-
scionability: see Gillett for rejection of this. But, it does suggest that the common understanding that
‘house contracts’ must be in writing, and that wills can be changed, means that the representor’s
subsequent withdrawal of the assurance cannot be unconscionable in most cases precisely because
no party could reasonably expect to acquire an interest without the required formality.
180 Martin Dixon
that this core concept has largely escaped the attention paid to the other ‘ele-
ments’ of estoppel and that, in consequence, there is a degree of uncertainty and
inconsistency in the case law that should not continue in the new world of the
LRA 2002. The argument also has suggested that there is an intimate connection
between estoppel and the statutorily imposed requirements of form required for
the valid creation, transfer or enforcement of a proprietary right. In turn, it has
been argued that ‘unconscionability’ is the key concept in explaining this link
and that, in consequence, the definition of the latter is bound up with the
requirements of the former. However, it is also clear that in apparent contra-
diction to this view, a very broad approach to ‘unconscionability’ has been
adopted in some cases and in turn this has been greeted with academic approval.
Yet, for the present author this does not destroy the central argument of this
essay because it is submitted that ‘unconscionability’ fulfils more than one role
in the law of proprietary estoppel. First, it is the defining feature of a successful
estoppel and is a narrow concept, related to formality. Without it, a claimant
cannot win. Secondly, it is used broadly to describe the background merits of a
claim and will affect the court’s response to an estoppel that is already estab-
lished under the first, narrow concept of unconscionability. It does not establish
a claim, but concerns its consequences.
In so far as the general law requires the creation, transfer or enforcement of pro-
prietary rights to be undertaken in a certain form, estoppel can be used to side-
step these requirements only when there is a clear justification. That it would be
‘unconscionable’ for one of the parties to rely on the absence of the required for-
mality is that justification. This means that unconscionability cannot be merely
a function of an assurance, reliance and detriment (the factual elements of estop-
pel) for otherwise it is devoid of meaning. Such a view does not explain why it
is justifiable to validate an arrangement without compliance with the formality
rules. Despite judicial affirmation of such an approach, it is entirely circular
and, in any event, cannot explain how estoppel works (or rather does not work)
in a number of situations. However, ‘unconscionability’ can explain why the
absence of formality may be ignored—in the sense that a right still ensues for the
claimant—if the concept is tied to the formality rules. Hence, it will be uncon-
scionable for a representor to withdraw an assurance, relied on to detriment, if
the assurance of the right carries with it (expressly or impliedly) a further assur-
ance that the right will indeed be granted despite the absence of the formality
that is normally required to create, transfer or enforce it. Thus a successful
estoppel can be triggered only by a ‘double assurance’: an assurance that the
claimant will have some right over the representor’s land combined with an
assurance that the right will ensue even if the formalities necessary to convey the
right are not complied with. It is the withdrawal of the promise of the right after
the second assurance (assuming detrimental reliance) that constitutes the
A Theory of Unconscionability 181
It is not always the case with a principle of equity that proof of certain ‘condi-
tions’ necessarily leads to a remedy for a claimant. So it is with proprietary
estoppel. Although it is submitted that unconscionability in the narrow sense
just discussed must be present before a claim can succeed, that does not mean
that the claim must then succeed. The ‘double assurance’, withdrawn after
detrimental reliance is necessary but not sufficient. There still remains the broad
equitable jurisdiction either to deny the remedy or to modify the remedy because
of the background circumstances of the case. This, it is submitted, is what is
meant by many authorities when they refer to a broad principle of uncon-
scionability. For example, it is clear from the judgment in Yeo v Wilson that the
claimant would not have gained a remedy even if he had been able to prove the
required elements for proprietary estoppel. As the judge said, the claim would
be denied
on the additional ground70 that in the unusual circumstances of this case it could not
have been unconscionable for Mr Ellis to bequeath his estate elsewhere [because] the
history of his relationship with Mr Yeo is an appalling story of deliberate persistent
and oppressive manipulation of a vulnerable old man by a greedy and self-obsessed
lover who had established a powerful psychological hold over him.71
Likewise, it seems that the courts do consider wider principles of justice and
fairness when seeking to satisfy the equity of an established estoppel. In
Campbell v Griffin, a monetary remedy was granted in order to be even-handed
between the claimant and the persons benefiting under the deceased’s will as the
court did not want a property claim clogging the title and keeping the other
beneficiaries out of their money.72 Of course, this is not the unfettered and
unprincipled discretion rejected by Robert Walker LJ in Jennings v Rice73 but it
is in keeping with the use of estoppel as a remedy protecting those who cannot
rely on formality and who instead must plead the favour of the court.
70
The relevant elements of estoppel were not in fact made out.
71
Above n 17. See also the reference to the plaintiff’s character in Moloo, above n 10.
72
Above n 7.
73
Above n 9.
10
The Equitable Ownership of Shares
PAUL EDEN
INTRODUCTION
1
The most commonly quoted judicial definition of the legal nature of a share is the statement of
Farwell J in Borland’s Trustee v Steel Bros and Co Ltd [1901] 1 Ch 279 at 288 that a share ‘is the
interest of the shareholder in the company measured in a sum of money’ cited with approval by Lord
Russell of Killowen in IRC v Crossman [1937] AC 26 (HL) at 66. See also R Pennington, ‘Can shares
in companies be defined?’ (1989) 10 Company Lawyer 140 and G Barton, ‘The legal nature of a
share’ in N Palmer and E McKendrick (eds), Interests in Goods (2nd edn, LLP, London, 1998) 111.
2
Colonial Bank v Whinney (1886) 11 App Cas 426 (HL). Section 182(1) of the Companies Act
1985 states that shares are personal estate or, in Scotland, movable property and are transferable in
a manner provided by the company’s articles but subject to the Stock Transfer Act 1963 and to reg-
ulations made under s 207 of the Companies Act 1989.
3 Section 183(1) of the Companies Act 1985.
4 Section 188(1) of the Companies Act 1985 provides that, if so authorised by its articles, a com-
pany limited by shares may issue a ‘share warrant’ stating that the bearer of the warrant is entitled
to the shares specified in it.
5 Section 188(2) Companies Act 1985. The holder of the share warrant, although entitled to the
shares specified in the warrant, is not a member of the company until s/he presents the warrant to
the company in order to obtain registration as a member. Thus the holder of a share warrant,
although the legal owner of the shares, does not enjoy all the rights of the shareholder vis-à-vis the
company.
6 Where the Stock Transfer Act 1963 is not applicable the form of transfer must be in accordance
with the articles. See Gore-Browne on Companies (44th edn, Jordans, Bristol, 2001) §16.3.1.
184 Paul Eden
allotment or transfer7 and a share certificate, executed under the common seal
of the company is, in England and Wales, prima facie evidence of title.8 Transfer
restrictions are permitted in the articles of association and the articles of private
companies often contain a right of pre-emption in favour of the remaining
shareholders or a power for the directors to refuse to register a transfer to a per-
son of whom they do not approve. With regard to shares that are listed on the
London Stock Exchange, The Listing Rules require that fully paid up shares are
not subject to any restrictions on transfer (apart from any restrictions imposed
on a shareholder who is in default in complying with a notice under section 212
of the Companies Act 1985).9
The shares of companies registered on the London Stock Exchange are usu-
ally transferable by means of the electronic share dealing system CREST.10 The
object of the CREST system is to replace the paper based stock transfer system
prescribed by the Stock Transfer Act 1963 with a paperless electronic settlement
system.11 Section 207 of the Companies Act 1989 gives the Secretary of State
wide powers to make provision by regulations for title to securities to be to be
evidenced and transferred without written instrument and the legal aspects of
CREST are now governed by the Uncertificated Securities Regulations 200112
that revoked the Uncertificated Securities Regulations 199513 with effect from
26 November 2001.
A company participating in the CREST system must enter on its register of
members, in respect of any class of shares that is a participating security, how
many shares each member holds in uncertificated form and certificated form
respectively.14 An entry on the register (where the units are capable of being held
in certificated form) is, in England and Wales, prima facie evidence that the per-
son to whom the entry relates has such title to the shares as would be evidenced
by the entry related to shares held in the certificated form.15 Although it is not
possible to find a categorical statement to this effect in the Companies Act 1985,
it would appear that whether registered shares are held in certificated or
uncertificated form, the legal title is only transferred by the registration of the
edn, Bristol, Jordans, 2001) §16.15. See also E Micheler ‘Farewell Quasi-Negotiability? Legal Title
and Transfer of Shares in a Paperless World’ [2002] Journal of Business Law 358.
12 SI 2001/3755.
13 SI 1995/3272. For a discussion of the background to the reform see E Micheler, ‘Modernising
2001 SI 2001/3755.
15 Regulation 24(7).
The Equitable Ownership of Shares 185
SALES OF SHARES
A contract for the sale of shares need not be in writing.18 When shares are sold
through a stock exchange, the seller and buyer will usually be brought together
by negotiations carried out on their behalf by brokers on the exchange but the
brokers are not ordinarily regarded as parties to the contract of sale.19
If the shares to be sold are not specified in the contract eg where the seller is only
parting with a portion of a holding in a particular company, appropriation will not
occur until the transfer form is processed by the company.20 A constructive trust
can deliver equitable ownership to an intending purchaser in advance of the trans-
fer of legal ownership—as contracts for the sale of land demonstrate21—but there
is strong legal authority for the proposition that a trust can only be created if the
asset that is the subject matter of the sale is appropriated to the beneficiary.22
Although the rule requiring appropriation was developed in relation to sales of
tangible goods, there is arguably some attraction in applying a single principle to
transfers of all types of property including shares. According to Sarah
Worthington the general rule should be that the purchaser will only be regarded as
16
Shropshire Union Railways and Canal Company v R (1875) LR 7 HL 496, Société Générale de
Paris v Walker (1885) 11 App Cas 20 at 28 and Colonial Bank v Hepworth (1887) 36 ChD 36 at 54.
See also s 22(2) of the Companies Act 1985.
17
See http://www.londonstockexchange.com/electronicshareholding/ for information about the
London Stock Exchange’s electronic shareholding service.
18 See Oughtred v Inland Revenue Commissioners [1960] AC 206 (HL).
19 Bowring v Shepard (1871) LR 6 QB 309.
20 See Re London, Hamburg and Continental Exchange Bank, Ward and Henry’s Case (1867) 2
Ch App 431 at 438. Where a transferor is only selling a part of the holding to which the share
certificate relates, a procedure known as ‘certification of transfer’ is followed whereby the transferor
sends the share certificate and the instrument of transfer to the company to be endorsed by the com-
pany secretary. This procedure is used to avoid the risk of a fraudulent transfer of the entire hold-
ing to which the share certificate relates. See s 184 of the Companies Act 1985.
21 See, eg, Lysaght v Edwards (1876) 2 ChD 499 at 506–07.
22 Re Wait [1927] 1 Ch 606 (CA), Re London Wine Company Limited [1986] PCC 121 and Re
the equitable owner of sale property, with that ownership interest arising by oper-
ation of law, ‘if the vendor is under a specifically enforceable and unconditional
personal obligation to transfer identified property to the purchaser’.23
The difficulty with imposing a requirement that the obligation must be
specifically enforceable is that a contract for the sale of shares in a private
company will only be enforceable by specific performance once the shares have
been specified and contracts to acquire shares that are listed on a stock exchange
are not generally regarded as being specifically enforceable under any circum-
stances.24
Although the Court of Appeal’s decision in Re Wait is generally regarded as
authority for the proposition that specific enforceability is an essential pre-con-
dition for a contract of sale to give rise to a constructive trust of the sale prop-
erty, this aspect of the decision has been criticised by Sir Frederick Pollock on
the grounds that Atkin LJ overstated the effect of Lord Westbury’s ‘not wholly
felicitous language in Holroyd v Marshall25 about specific performance’.26 In
Tailby v Official Receiver27 Lord Watson made a similar criticism to the refer-
ence made to specific performance by Lord Westbury in Holroyd v Marshall.28
The House of Lords’ decisions in both Holroyd v Marshall and Tailby v Official
Receiver have been read as denying a general requirement for specific perfor-
mance29 but this reading of the cases has been criticised.30
In his preface to volume 138 of The Revised Reports Sir Frederick Pollock
stated:
Holroyd v Marshall is a first rate authority on equitable assignments and the creation
of equitable charges to take effect on the debtor’s after acquired property. Lord
Westbury, however, exposed himself to misunderstanding (if it was a misunderstand-
ing) by the concise and dogmatic form of his opinion. When even the most learned per-
sons undertake to overrule the Court of Appeal, and convert some of their own
colleagues, ‘by the application of a few elementary principles’ (p 111), the cautious
reader will keep his eyes pretty wide open. Those who are new to the subject may be
196 (emphasis in original). See also S Worthington, ‘Proprietary Remedies: The Nexus between
Specific Performance and Constructive Trusts’ (1996–97) 10 Journal of Contract Law 1 at 2.
24 See Duncuft v Albrecht (1841) Sim 189, Harvela Investments Ltd v Royal Trust Co of Canada
(CI) Ltd [1986] AC 207 (HL) and Grant v Cigman [1996] 2 BCLC 24. See also G Jones and
W Goodhart, Specific Performance (2nd edn, Butterworths, London, 1996) 161–6.
25
(1862) 10 HLC 191.
26
F Pollock, ‘Re Wait’ (1927) 43 LQR 293.
27 (1888) 13 App Cas 523.
28 At 547.
29 See R Meagher, W Gummow and J Lehane, Equity: Doctrines and Remedies (3rd edn,
Butterworths, Sydney, 1992) paras 647–53. ‘It is suggested, therefore, that it is preferable to regard
the principle in Holroyd v Marshall as an application, quite independent of specific performance, of
the maxim that equity regards as done that which ought to be done’. [At para 653]
30 See S Worthington, Proprietary Interests in Commercial Transactions (Clarendon, Oxford,
1996) 200–1 and reproduced in S Worthington, ‘Proprietary Remedies: The Nexus between Specific
Performance and Constructive Trusts’ (1996–1997) 10 Journal of Contract Law 1 at 6–7. See also
J Keeler, ‘Some Reflections on Holroyd v Marshall’ (1969) 3 Adelaide Law Review 360.
The Equitable Ownership of Shares 187
well advised if they begin with Lord Macnaghton’s judgment in Tailby v Official
Receiver 13 App Cas at p 541 and then read Holroyd v Marshall with an enlightened
mind.31
In Holroyd v Marshall Lord Westbury stated that ‘[a] contract for valuable con-
sideration, by which it is agreed to make a present transfer of property, passes
at once the beneficial interest, provided the contract is one of which a court of
equity will decree specific performance’.32 In Tailby v Official Receiver Lord
Macnaghton sought to distinguish the operation of the doctrine of specific per-
formance from cases of equitable assignment on the grounds that the consider-
ations applicable to suits for specific performance were distinct from cases
involving equitable assignment where the basis of the decision was the real
meaning of the agreement between the parties.
It had been conceded in argument in Holroyd v Marshall that the obligation
was one for which specific performance could be decreed, so it is legitimate to
regard Lord Westbury’s comments about specific performance as obiter and to
speculate that Lord Westbury did not intend to base the whole doctrine of equi-
table assignment on the availability of specific performance. This is certainly the
view that Lord Macnaghton took of Lord Westbury’s judgment in Holyroyd v
Marshall but even supporters of Lord Macnaghten’s judgment in Tailby v Official
Receiver (such as Sir Frederick Pollock) concede that it is also possible that Lord
Westbury, by referring no less than three times to specific performance in the oft-
quoted paragraph, fully intended to lay down a generally applicable rule that
equitable assignments and specific performance were inseparably connected.
In Re Wait33 the Master of the Rolls, Lord Hanworth, although willing to
reject the test of the right to specific performance (as a pre-requisite for an equi-
table assignment) held that there was insufficient identification of the subject
matter of the contract for an equitable assignment to have occurred.34 Lord
Hanworth’s ‘identification’ test was based on the judgment of Lord Watson in
Tailby v Official Receiver.35 Sargant LJ (dissenting) found that on the facts there
had been an equitable assignment and, relying on the judgment of Lord
Macnaghton in Tailby v Official Receiver, based his decision on a distinction
between the doctrine of specific performance and equitable assignments and
held that the prior cases established that ‘equitable assignments were enforced
even where specific performance was impossible’.36
Atkin LJ conceded that the authority of Lord Westbury’s dictum regarding
specific performance in Holyrod v Marshall was weakened, first, by a discrep-
ancy in the reporting of the crucial passage between the House of Lords cases
31
The Revised Reports, Volume CXXXVIII, 1862–1864 (Sweet and Maxwell, London, 1913)
v–vi.
32
(1862) 10 HLC 191 at 209.
33
[1927] 1 Ch 606 (CA).
34
At 622.
35
(1888) 13 App Cas 523 at 533.
36
[1927] 1 Ch 606 (CA) at 647–9.
188 Paul Eden
and the report in the Law Journal37 and, secondly, by the criticism of Fry LJ in
his book on Specific Performance38 but, in spite of this, Atkin LJ was not only
prepared to apply the words of Lord Westbury but to go even further by hold-
ing that even where a Court of equity would decree specific performance, it was
not logically true nor was it the law that the beneficial interest would have
passed.39 In response to the question whether common honesty demanded that
a beneficial interest should be created on the facts of the case, Atkin LJ stated
that the test of honesty was inadequate and that the recognition of equitable
interests in business transactions would throw the business world into confu-
sion and restrict the willingness of banks and financial houses to finance sales
transactions.40 The basis of Atkin LJ’s decision in Re Wait is that in a contract
for the sale of goods governed by the Sale of Goods Act specific performance is
only possible if the goods are specific or ascertained and that an equitable
assignment was only possible if the contract was one for which a Court of equity
would decree specific performance. Atkin LJ was also of the view that the
codification of the law relating to the sale of goods in the Sale of Goods Act
meant that an equitable assignment could only occur outside the contract of sale
ie the parties to the contract of sale would have to expressly agree for this to
occur.41
In Re London Wine (Shippers) Ltd 42 Oliver J regarded the judgment of Atkin
LJ as conclusive of the arguments relating to the creation of a trust on the facts
before him.43 With regard to the case where a single purchaser of a particular
wine of generic description had purchased what was in fact the total stock of
that wine at the date of purchase (the first category),44 Oliver J declined to find
that that the sale was for specific or ascertained goods on the grounds that the
company was not contractually bound to fulfil the order from the wine it
already owned but was at liberty to deliver to the purchaser any bottles of wine
which tallied with the description.45 Where a number of purchasers of a partic-
ular wine of a particular description whose purchases together exhausted the
whole of the company’s stocks of wine of that description (the second category),
Oliver J declined to find that a proprietary interest had passed to the buyers. By
contrast, in Re Stapylton Fletcher Ltd,46 a case with rather similar facts, Judge
Baker QC held that the physical segregation of the wine coupled with the fact
37
(1863) 33 LJ Ch 193 at 196.
38
[1927] 1 Ch 606 (CA) at 634.
39
At 637.
40 At 639–40.
41 At 635–6.
42 [1986] PCC 121 (ChD). The case was originally decided in 1975 and, although a summary of
the judgment was published in the New Law Journal at the time (see (1975) 126 NLJ 977), the impor-
tance of the case was only recognised when it was published as an appendix in R Goode, Proprietary
Rights in Insolvency and Sales Transactions (Sweet and Maxwell, London, 1985).
43 [1986] PCC 121 at 149.
44 See [1986] PCC 121 at 131.
45 At 152.
46 [1994] 1 WLR 1181 (ChD).
The Equitable Ownership of Shares 189
that the sellers made it clear in their annual accounts that the segregated wine
was not their property supported the inference that the property in the segre-
gated wine had passed to the purchasers and that purchasers who were in a
similar position to the second category in Re London Wine (Shippers) Ltd case
were to be regarded as tenants in common in the proportion that their goods
bore to the entire stock.47 Judge Baker QC accepted, on the basis of Atkin LJs
judgment in Re Wait that ‘normally a contract for the sale of goods takes effect
at law, and gives rise to no equitable interest in favour of the buyer’48 and he also
stated that:
The court must be very cautious in devising equitable interests and remedies which
erode the statutory scheme statutory scheme for distribution on insolvency. It cannot
do it because of some perceived injustice arising as a consequence only of the insol-
vency.49
In Re Goldcorp Exchange Ltd50 the Privy Council had to deal with the insol-
vency of a company that dealt in gold and other precious metals. The company
had sold ingots and coins on either an allocated or non-allocated basis.
Although the promotional literature promised that metal stocks would be
audited on a monthly basis to ensure that there were sufficient stocks to meet all
commitments, when the company went into receivership it became apparent
that not only was there a considerable shortfall in available bullion but also that
the stock of bullion had not been managed in the manner promised by the pro-
motional literature (i.e. there was generally no earmarking of gold stocks for
‘allocated’ customers). When the company got into difficulties, the Bank of New
Zealand appointed receivers under the terms of a debenture issued by the com-
pany, whereupon the bank’s floating charge over the company’s assets crys-
tallised. As the amount owed to the secured creditors exceeded total assets
including the bullion stocks, the non-allocated claimants sought to establish a
proprietary interest in the bullion stocks. In the course of his judgment in the
New Zealand Court of Appeal, Cooke P noted that more than a quarter of the
money raised by the sale of the bullion stocks (NZ $3.7 million) had already
gone on legal fees.51
The New Zealand Court of Appeal (McKay J dissenting) held that the non-
allocated customers enjoyed a proprietary interest in the proceeds of the mon-
eys paid to the company. Cooke P, relying on the judgment of Goulding J in
Chase Manhattan Bank NA v Israel-British Bank (London) Ltd,52 held that the
non-allocated customers retained a property interest in the monies paid to the
company giving rise to a constructive trust on orthodox lines and a right to trace
47
There are interesting similarities between the facts in Re Stapylton Fletcher and the Walker &
Hall claimants in Re Goldcorp Exchange Ltd, see [1995] 1 AC 74 (PC) at 107–10.
48
At 1197.
49
At 1203.
50
[1995] 1 AC 74 (PC).
51
Liggett v Kensington [1993] 1 NZLR 257 (CA) at 260 line 15.
52 [1981] Ch 105.
190 Paul Eden
the proceeds. It is submitted with respect that, in finding that the payments were
made by mistake,53 Cooke P failed to pay due regard to the vital proprietary dis-
tinction that has been drawn between a void and a voidable contract.54
Although it may be possible to describe the customers as ‘mistaken’ in a collo-
quial sense, the company obtained the moneys by misrepresentation.55
Cooke P sought to distinguish the Privy Council’s decision in Space
Investments Ltd v Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce Trust Co (Bahamas)
Ltd 56 and stated that the bank as debenture holder had taken the risk of insol-
vency in relation to the assets over which they had no fixed charge but that the
non-allocated purchasers did not understand that they were taking any risk of
insolvency.57 Gault J agreed with the conclusions reached by Cooke P and the
consequences58 but in Gault Js view the remedy was best classified as a remedial
constructive trust. With regard to the non-allocated customers, McKay J held
that the contract between the company and its customers was a commercial con-
tract for the purchase and storage of bullion that did not give rise to a fiduciary
relationship per se and that any representations made by the company were no
different in character from the normal advertising of any trader selling goods to
the public and thus they did not give rise to a fiduciary relationship.59 Rejecting
the arguments that the non-allocated claimants were to be regarded as the
beneficiaries of either an express or a constructive trust, McKay J held that their
remedy was an action in damages for breach of contract and that they were not
entitled to priority against other creditors whether secured or unsecured.
The Privy Council, per Lord Mustill, relying on the New Zealand equivalent
of section 16 of the Sale of Goods Act 1979 held that, as the contract was for the
sale of unascertained generic goods that were not sold ‘ex-bulk’, no property in
the goods could be transferred to the buyers unless and until the goods were
ascertained. Although Lord Mustill declined to examine in detail the decision of
the Court of Appeal in Re Wait on the grounds that the sale in that case was ex-
bulk, he stated:
Nevertheless, the reasoning contained in the judgment of Atkin LJ, at pp 625–641,
which their Lordships venture to find irresistible, points unequivocally to the conclu-
sion that under a simple contract for the sale of unascertained goods no equitable title
can pass merely by virtue of the sale.60
53 [1993] 1 NZLR 257 at 271 line 24 ‘in any commonsense use of words, the payments here were
243 and Lewis v Avery [1972] 1 QB 198 (CA). But see also S Worthington, ‘The Proprietary
Consequences of Contract Failure’ in F Rose (ed), Failure of Contracts: Contractual, Restitutionary
and Proprietary Consequences (Hart, Oxford, 1997) 80 and especially fn 59.
55 [1993] 1 NZLR 257 at 270 line 45 ‘Exchange obtained the money by misrepresentation’.
56 [1986] 1 WLR 1072 (PC).
57 At 274.
58 [1993] 1 NZLR 257 at 281 line 25.
59 At 299–300.
60 [1995] 1 AC 74 (PC) at 91B.
The Equitable Ownership of Shares 191
Lord Mustill acknowledged the statement by Atkin LJ that it was possible for a
seller or a purchaser to create an equitable assignment ‘as one of the terms
expressed in the contract of sale’61 and turned to consider whether there was
anything in the collateral promises that would effect an immediate transfer of
title to the customers.
Although Lord Mustill rejected the proposition that the collateral promises
could be treated as a declaration of trust by the company in favour of the cus-
tomer on the grounds that the company could not have intended to create a trust
of its general stock of gold that would have inhibited its dealings with what it
regarded as its stock-in-trade, Lord Mustill stated that
[t]heir Lordships do not doubt that the vendor of goods sold ex-bulk can effectively
declare himself trustee of the bulk in favour of the buyer, so as to confer pro-tanto an
equitable title.62
Lord Mustill also rejected the argument that the collateral promises gave rise to
an estoppel on the grounds that there was no existing bulk from which a title
could be carved out by a deemed appropriation and, in any event, the bank was
not a party to the collateral promises.63
Lord Mustill rejected the argument that there was a fiduciary relationship
between the company and its customers that entitled the customers to a propri-
etary interest in the stocks on the grounds that ‘the essence of a fiduciary rela-
tionship is that creates obligations of a different character from the contract
itself’ and their Lordships had not heard in argument any submission that would
transform the basic commercial nature of the transaction.64 Even if their
Lordships had been willing to hold that the company could properly be
described as a fiduciary, Lord Mustill held that there was never an identifiable
stock of bullion over which a proprietary interest could be created.65 The fail-
ure to find the breach of a fiduciary relationship between the company and its
customers was also fatal to the argument that the court should declare in favour
of the claimants a remedial constructive trust66 over the bullion in the com-
pany’s vaults.
In response to the argument that a proprietary interest should be imposed ret-
rospectively not to the bullion but to the moneys originally paid by the cus-
tomers, Lord Mustill held67 that this was not a situation where the customer
engaged the company as agent to purchase bullion on his or her behalf, nor
could it be shown that there was a mutual intention that the moneys paid should
not fall within the general fund of the companies assets but should be applied
for a specially designated purpose.68
In Re Harvard Securities69 Neuberger J, relying on the Court of Appeal’s
decision in Hunter v Moss70 (a case involving a gift of shares), held that the
parcels of shares governed by English law71 and held by Harvard Securities Ltd
on behalf of their clients, although not registered in the name of the individual
clients,72 were beneficially owned by the clients notwithstanding the fact that
the precise shares were never identified or appropriated.
Worthington has criticised the decision in Re Harvard Securities on the
grounds that
[w]here the intended transaction is . . . a sale of specifically identified property, the
general rule is that the purchaser will acquire equitable ownership of the property in
advance of the legal title only if the contract is unconditional and specifically enforce-
able.73
68
See Barclays Bank Ltd v Quistclose Investments Ltd [1970] AC 567(HL) and Re Kayford Ltd
[1975] 1 WLR 279 (ChD) and S Worthington, Proprietary Interests in Commercial Transactions
(Clarendon, Oxford, 1996) ch 3.
69
[1997] 2 BCLC 369 (ChD).
70
[1994] 1 WLR 452 (CA). See further below page 199–200.
71
Neuberger J concluded that the former clients of Harvard Securities Ltd would not have a
beneficial interest in any of the shares governed by Australian Law. For a critique of this aspect of
Neuberger J’s judgement see P Eden, ‘Beneficial ownership of shares: the implications of Re Harvard
Securities’ (2000) 16 Insolvency Law and Practice 134–7 and 175–8 at 177.
72 Due to the cost of, and delay in, registration, the inconvenience in having stock registered in
smaller quantities, and the fact that the smaller quantities of registered stock would obtain lower
prices on resale.
73 S Worthington, ‘Sorting Out Ownership Interests in a Bulk: Gifts, Sales, and Trusts’ [1999]
what the justice of a particular case demanded75 unless the courts were prepared
to extend greatly their discretion to order specific performance for fungibles.76
If, notwithstanding the arguments made above, specific performance is to be
regarded as a pre-requisite for the equitable assignment of shares, it is possible
to find a few reported cases where specific performance was ordered for a con-
tract to sell shares quoted on the London Stock Exchange77 Although the cases
where specific performance for public quoted shares was ordered involved par-
tially paid up shares in companies that subsequently failed and the vendors were
anxious to ensure that the purchasers were liable, there is no reason why the
same principle cannot also be applied to the sale of fully paid up shares.78
The second difficulty with regarding Atkin LJs judgment in Re Wait as provid-
ing authority for a principle of general application is that Atkin LJ was at pains
to emphasise that his decision was based on his view that the effect of the
codification of the law relating to the sale of goods in the Sale of Goods Act meant
that an equitable assignment could only occur if the parties to a contract for the
sale of goods expressly agreed to the application of equitable principles.79 Not
only does the Sale of Goods Act not apply to sales of shares,80 the reference to reg-
istration ‘in the name of a trust corporation or in the name of an authorised
depository’ contained in condition 5 of the standard terms and conditions pub-
lished by Harvard Securities Ltd indicates that there was a mutual intention to
create an equitable assignment as one of the terms of the contract of sale.
The third difficulty with regarding Atkin LJs judgment in Re Wait as provid-
ing authority for a principle of general application is that Atkin LJ was of the
view that the recognition of equitable interests in business transactions such as
c.i.f. contracts ‘would throw the business world into confusion’.81 Sir Frederick
Pollock however was of the opinion that the decision of the majority in Re Wait
would ‘be as inconvenient to many merchants as it is surprising to the Equity
Bar’.82 Subsequent events favour Sir Frederick Pollock on this point. The
75 See, for example, the statement of Edmund–Davies LJ in Carl-Zeiss Stiftung v Herbert Smith
& Co (No 2) [1969] 2 Ch 276 (CA) at 300 that ‘English law provides no clear and all-embracing
definition of a constructive trust. Its boundaries have been left perhaps deliberately vague, so as not
to restrict the court by technicalities in deciding what the justice of a particular case may demand’.
76 As Goulding J was prepared to do in Sky Petroleum Ltd v VIP Petroleum Ltd [1974] 1 WLR
576 (ChD). But see also the remarks of Oliver J in Re London Wine Co Ltd [1986] PCC 121 (ChD)
at 149.
77 See, for example, Paine v Hutchinson (1866) LR 3 Eq 257 affirmed by (1868) 3 LR Ch App 388.
For further litigation on the same facts see also Cruse v Paine (1868) LR 6 Eq 641.
78 See also M Cope Constructive Trusts (Law Book Co, Sydney, 1992) 993 who asserts that the
effect of the House of Lords decision in Tailby v Official Receiver is that equity will specifically
enforce all agreements to assign future property where the assignee has provided consideration and
if property which can be identified as fitting the description of the property assigned comes into the
hands of the assignor. If Cope’s assertion is correct, then a contract to sell shares which the seller
does not own—known as a ‘short’ sale—would ipso facto be specifically enforceable when shares
fitting the description came into the hands of the seller.
79 [1927] 1 Ch 606 (ChD) at 635–6.
80 The definition of ‘goods’ in s 61(1) of the Sale of Goods Act 1979 excludes ‘things in action’.
81 [1927] 1 Ch 606 (CA) at 640.
82 F Pollock, ‘Re Wait’ (1927) 43 LQR 293.
194 Paul Eden
83
See B Davenport, ‘Ownership of Bulk Cargoes (The Gosforth)’ [1986] LMCLQ 4.
84
The Law Commission, Sale of Goods forming Part of a Bulk (Law Com No 215, 1993) para
6.1.
85
For a discussion of the effect of the Sale of Goods (Amendment) Act 1995 see inter alia
R Bradgate and F White, ‘Sale of Goods forming Part of a Bulk: Proposals for Reform’ [1994]
LMCLQ 315; T Burns, ‘Better Late than Never: The Reform of the Law on the Sale of Goods
Forming Part of a Bulk’ (1996) 59 MLR 260; J Ulph, ‘The Sale of Goods (Amendment) Act 1995: Co-
ownership and the Rogue Seller’ [1996] LMCLQ 93; M Bridge, The Sale of Goods (Clarendon,
Oxford, 1997) 86–90; E McKendrick ‘The Passing of Property in Part of a Bulk’ in N Palmer and E
McKendrick (eds), Interests in Goods (2nd edn, LLP, London, 1998) chapter 16; L Gullifer,
‘Constructive Possession after the Sale of Goods (Amendment) Act 1995’ [1999] LMCLQ 93 and
S Worthington, ‘Passing of Property’ in E McKendrick (ed) Sale of Goods (LLP, London, 2000) ch 2
para 2–057 et seq.
86 See, for example, British Eagle International Airlines Ltd v Cie Nationale Air France [1975] 1
WLR 758 (HL) where the House of Lords held (by a majority of three to two) that a clearing house
arrangement that amounted to a ‘contracting out’ of the statutory scheme for distribution on insol-
vency was contrary to public policy. See also the views expressed by Lord Goff and Lord Browne-
Wilkinson in Westdeutsche Landesbank Girozentrale v Islington London Borough Council [1996]
AC 669 (HL) and the judgment of Mummary LJ in Re Polly Peck International plc (in administra-
tion) (No 2) [1998] 3 All ER 812 (CA).
87 See, inter alia, R Goode, ‘The Right to Trace and Its Impact in Commercial Transactions—II’
(1976) 92 LQR 528 at 565; D Paciocco, ‘The Remedial Constructive Trust: A Principled Basis for
Priorities over Creditors’(1989) 68 Canadian Bar Review 315; J Ulph ‘Equitable Property Rights on
Insolvency: The Ebbing Tide?’ [1996] Journal of Business Law 482 and R Goode, ‘Proprietary
Restitutionary Claims’ in W Cornish et al (eds) Restitution Past, Present and Future (Hart, Oxford,
1998) 63 at 64–7.
88 But see also the remarks of Templeman J (as he then was) in Business Computers Ltd v Anglo-
African Leasing Ltd [1977] 1 WLR 578 (ChD) at 580 and S Wheeler, Reservation of Title Clauses:
Impact and Implications (Clarendon, Oxford, 1992).
The Equitable Ownership of Shares 195
GIFTS OF SHARES
Where shares are transferred by way of gift, the legal rule has traditionally been
that the beneficial ownership in shares does not pass to the donee until the donor
89 [1975] 1 WLR 279 (ChD).
90
See S Worthington, Proprietary Interests in Commercial Transactions (Clarendon, Oxford,
1996) 207 and the authorities cited in fn 113.
91
See RV Ward Ltd v Bignall [1967] 1 QB 534 (CA) per Diplock LJ at 545.
92
[1951] 1 All ER 22 (ChD).
93
At 27. See also A Borrowdale, ‘The Effect of Breach of Share Transfer Restrictions’ [1988]
Journal of Business Law 307 and P Luxton ‘Share Transfer Restrictions and the Relative Nature of
Property Rights’ [1989] Journal of Business Law 14.
94 Section 18 rule 5 of the Sale of Goods Act 1979 read together with s 16 of the same Act.
95 See Carlos Federspeil & Co SA v Charles Twigg & Co Ltd [1957] 1 Lloyd’s Rep 240 (QBD) for
an example of the deleterious effects of the strict application of the rule whose effects have now been
tempered by the coming into force of the Sale of Goods (Amendment) Act 1995.
96 [1994] 1 WLR 452 (CA).
97
See below p 199.
196 Paul Eden
has done everything within his or her power to implement the registration of the
shares in the donee’s name. The basis of this rule is the principle that equity does
not assist volunteers and the leading authority is the Court of Appeal’s decision
in Milroy v Lord98 and, in particular, the judgement of Turner LJ. In a passage
that has become regarded as the classic statement of the perfect gift rule, Turner
LJ stated:
I take the law of this Court to be well settled, that, in order to render a voluntary set-
tlement valid and effectual, the settlor must have done everything which, according to
the nature of the property comprised in the settlement, was necessary to be done in
order to transfer the property and render the settlement binding upon him. He may of
course do this by actually transferring the property to the persons for whom he intends
to provide, and the provision will then be effectual, and it will be equally effectual if
he transfers the property to a trustee for the purposes of the settlement, or declares
that he himself holds it in trust for those purposes; and if the property be personal, the
trust may, as I apprehend, be declared either in writing or by parol; but, in order to
render the settlement binding, one or other of these modes must, as I understand the
law of this Court, be resorted to, for there is no equity in this Court to perfect an
imperfect gift. The cases I think go further to this extent, that if the settlement is
intended to be effectuated by one of the modes to which I have referred, the Court will
not give effect to it by applying another of those modes. If it is intended to take effect
by transfer, the Court will not hold the intended transfer to operate as a declaration
of trust, for then every imperfect instrument would be made effectual by being con-
verted into a perfect trust.99
This oft-quoted passage lays down two separate principles. First, that the sett-
lor must have done everything which, according to the nature of the property
comprised in the settlement, was necessary to be done in order to transfer the
property and render the settlement binding upon him, and secondly, that the
modes of conferring a benefit are mutually exclusive i.e. equity will not treat
the intention of the donor to make an outright gift that fails for one reason or
another as a self declaration of a trust.100
As noted in the introduction, the transfer of the legal title to a share is a com-
plex process involving a number of discrete steps101 and the penultimate step is
the delivery—by the transferor or the transferee—of the completed instrument
of transfer and the share certificate to the company.102 Subsequent cases have
sought to modify the application of the perfect gift rule as laid down by Turner
LJ in Milroy v Lord to avoid harsh and paradoxical results. In Re Rose, Rose v
98 (1862) 4 De G F & J 264.
99
At 274.
100
See, for example, Jones v Lock (1865) LR 1 Ch App Cas 25 and Richards v Delbridge (1874)
LR 18 Eq 11.
101
See also R Meagher, W Gummow and J Lehane, Equity: Doctrines and Remedies (3rd edn,
Butterworths, Sydney, 1992) para 619.
102
If there are transfer restrictions in the articles of association (or a consent from a third party
is required for the transfer), then the delivery of the completed instrument of transfer and the share
certificate would only be the penultimate step if the provisions in the articles regarding transfers had
been complied with (or the relevant consent has been obtained—see Re Fry [1946] Ch 312).
The Equitable Ownership of Shares 197
IRC103 the Court of Appeal (per Evershed MR) adopted the decision of Jenkins
J in Re Rose104—the facts of the two cases are unconnected—and held that
where donors have done everything in their power to divest themselves of the
shares in question, the gift is valid notwithstanding the fact that further steps are
required to transfer the legal title. The Court of Appeal’s decision in Re Rose,
Rose v IRC is not without its difficulties105 but the principle it lays down has
been applied by the Court of Appeal subsequently.106
In Pennington v Waine107 the Court of Appeal had to decide whether there
had been a valid gift of shares in a private company. The donor had signed the
stock transfer form and handed it to a partner in the company’s auditors, who
placed it ‘on the company’s file’ but took no further action prior to the donor’s
death shortly thereafter. The company’s articles of association contained a right
of pre-emption in favour of existing members. This provision of the articles was
not complied with. Lady Justice Arden, after summarising the views of oppos-
ing counsel on the effect of Milroy v Lord and its progeny, stated that the cases
did not reveal any, or any consistent single policy consideration behind the rule
that the court will not perfect an imperfect gift.108 After considering the ambit
of the rule laid down by the Court of Appeal in Re Rose, Rose v IRC, Arden LJ
held that the delivery of the share transfer forms to the donee or the company
can in some circumstances be dispensed with and that, on the facts of the case,
the point had been reached where it would have been unconscionable for the
donor to recall the gift before her death and it would also have been uncon-
scionable for the donor’s personal representatives to refuse to hand over the
share transfer to the donee after the donor’s death.109 Arden LJ further held
that, even if she was wrong to dispense with the requirement that the share
transfers must be delivered to the donee or the company, then the words of the
letter written by the partner in the company’s auditors to the donee informing
him of the donor’s gift and informing the donee that there was no action he
needed to take, could be construed as meaning that the donor and, through her,
the partner in the company’s auditors became agents for the donee for the pur-
pose of submitting the share transfer to the company.110
103
[1952] Ch 499 (CA).
104
[1949] Ch 78. The similarity of the names is pure coincidence.
105
See L McKay, ‘Share Transfers and the Complete and Perfect Rule’ (1976) 40 The
Conveyancer and Property Lawyer 139 who favours the approach adopted by Romer J in Re Fry
[1946] Ch 312. See also E Tyler and N Palmer, Crossley Vaines’ Personal Property (5th edn, London,
Butterworths, 1973) 315 and S Lowrie (now Wilson) and P Todd, ‘Re Rose Revisited’ (1998) 57
Cambridge Law Journal 46 for an analysis of the rule in Re Rose, Rose v IRC in the light of the
House of Lords decision in Westdeutsche Landesbank Girozentrale v Islington London Borough
Council [1996] AC 669 (HL).
106 See Mascall v Mascall (1984) 50 P & CR 119 (CA).
107 Pennington v Waine [2002] EWCA Civ 227, [2002] I WLR 2075.
108 At para 62.
109 At para 66.
110 At para 67.
198 Paul Eden
Schiemann LJ concurred with the judgment of Arden LJ111 but Clarke LJ,
while concurring with the result, added a separate judgement that dealt more
sympathetically with the reasoning in the prior cases. Clarke LJ would have pre-
ferred to have left the authorities undisturbed by holding that the executed trans-
fer form came into the possession of the company but this was not the conclusion
of the judge at first instance and this finding was not challenged on appeal.112
It is difficult to reconcile the decision in Pennington v Waine with the require-
ment laid down in Re Rose, Rose v IRC that a gift will only be effective when
the donor has done everything s/he is obliged to do to make the gift valid. On
the facts of the case the donor was required by the articles of association to offer
the shares to the existing members of the company. Counsel for the donee had
submitted that a transfer of the equitable interest in shares in breach of the arti-
cles of association would nonetheless be effective.113 Counsel cited Hawks v
McArthur114 as authority for this proposition but this case involved a sale of
shares and in his judgment Vaisey J was at pains to stress the significance of the
payment of full consideration:
The one thing, however, that seems to me to be important is that [the transferees] paid
[the transferor] the money, and I cannot bring myself to suppose that they got noth-
ing in the bargain and that the whole property in the shares remained in [the trans-
feror], notwithstanding the transfers that had been executed and the money that he
had received. I should however have been content to come to the opposite conclusion
because I think that there is almost something scandalous in the way in which [the
transferees and the transferor] all seem to have disregarded the articles of association
by which they and the other members of the company were bound.115
Crampton Bros (Coopers) Ltd & Ors [2002] EWHC 1375 (Ch) where Jacob J held (at para 38) that
the donor was in breach of the articles of association when she, by executing the transfer form,
transferred the shares to the donee and, thus, what the donee got was not an entitlement to the
shares but only to the price paid if a right of pre-emption were exercised.
118
[2001] 1 WLR 1 (PC).
The Equitable Ownership of Shares 199
The donor wished to set up a charitable foundation and it was his intention that
the foundation would receive most of his assets when he died. Terminally ill, the
donor executed the foundation trust deed and made a declaration of gift of his
shares and wealth to the foundation.119 Although the words used by the donor
were normally appropriate to an outright gift, Lord Browne-Wilkinson held
that as the foundation had no legal existence, apart from the trust declared by
the foundation trust deed, the words ‘I give to the foundation’ can only mean ‘I
give to the trustees of the foundation trust deed’ and thus the donor, as one of
the trustees of the foundation, was in fact declaring himself to be a trustee of the
gifted property for the donee.
Lord Browne-Wilkinson’s benevolent interpretation of the words used by the
donor—that some might regard as reminiscent of the exchange between Alice and
Humpty Dumpty in Lewis Carroll’s Through the Looking Glass120—is difficult to
reconcile with the second principle laid down by Turner LJ in Milroy v Lord,
namely that the modes of conferring a benefit are mutually exclusive and that
equity will not treat the intention of the donor to make an outright gift that fails
for one reason or another as a self declaration of a trust. Lord Browne-Wilkinson’s
ingenious response to the difficulty was to hold that the modes of conferring a
benefit mentioned by Turner LJ in Milroy v Lord should not be regarded as an
exclusive list and that the donor’s mode of conferring a benefit, although appear-
ing to fall between the two common form situations, was to be regarded as novel
and thus it did not breach the principle in Milroy v Lord because ‘[a]lthough equity
will not aid a volunteer, it will not strive officiously to defeat a gift’.121
In Hunter v Moss122 the Court of Appeal held that the donor’s oral declara-
tion of a trust of 50 shares was not void for uncertainty of subject matter due to
the donor’s failure to specify to which 50 of the 950 shares owned by the donor
the trust applied. The academic response to the decision in Hunter v Moss has
been largely,123 but not universally,124 hostile and much of the criticism has
119
There were pre-emption rights in favour of existing shareholders in the memorandum and
articles of association of the companies but all the shareholders waived their rights within a week of
the declaration of gift—see [2001] 1 WLR 1 at 6.
120
L Carroll, Through the Looking Glass and What Alice Found There (1872) chapter VI.
121
[2001] 1 WLR 1 at 11.
122 [1994] 1 WLR 452 (CA).
123 For academic criticism of the Court of Appeal’s decision in Hunter v Moss see, inter alia,
D Hayton, ‘Uncertainty and subject matter of trusts’ (1994) LQR 335; M Ockelton, ‘Share and share
alike?’ (1994) 53 Cambridge Law Journal 448; P Clarke, ‘Land Law and Trusts’ [1994] All ER Annual
Review 250; H Pigott, ‘Hunter v Moss revisited’ (1999) Butterworths Journal of International Banking
and Financial Law 363; G Moffat, Trust Law: Text and Materials (3rd edn, Butterworths, London,
1999) 134–5 and J Benjamin, Interests in Securities (University Press, Oxford, 2000) 55–9.
124 For academic support for the Court of Appeal’s decision in Hunter v Moss see, inter alia,
A Jones, ‘Creating a trust over an unascertained part of a homogenous whole’ [1993] The
Conveyancer and Property Lawyer 460; A Clarke, ‘Identifiability and choses in action: Hunter v
Moss’ (1995) 48 Current Legal Problems: Part I 117–20; J Martin, ‘Certainty of subject Matter: A
Defence of Hunter v Moss’ [1996] The Conveyancer and Property Lawyer 223; R Goode,
Commercial Law in the Next Millennium (Sweet and Maxwell, London, 1998) 73 and P Eden
‘Beneficial ownership of shares: the implications of Re Harvard Securities’ (2000) 16 Insolvency Law
and Practice 134–7 and 175–8.
200 Paul Eden
sought to argue that the decision cannot be reconciled with the Privy Council’s
decision in Re Goldcorp Exchange Ltd.125 It is submitted that the basis of this
criticism is the proposition that the judgment of Atkin LJ in Re Wait126 is
authority for a principle of general application. For the reasons stated above, it
is submitted that this proposition is untenable.127 In particular, it is submitted
that the need for certainty of the subject matter of an express trust should not be
confused with the rule that the transfer of the legal interest in a contract for sale
governed by the Sale of Goods an unconditional appropriation is required
(unless the provisions of the Sale of Goods (Amendment) Act 1995 apply).
Worthington criticises the Court of Appeal’s decision in Hunter v Moss on
the grounds that, if a donor intends to make a gift of specifically identified legal
property, the decision in Re Rose128 is authority for the proposition that equity
will only view the donee as obtaining equitable ownership once the donor has
done everything in his or her power to transfer title in the property to the donee.
In Worthington’s view, this means that equity will never assist with the gift of
part of an identified bulk unless the donor, either personally or via an agent, has
physically segregated the portion to be given away.129 It is submitted that there
is nothing in judgment of Turner LJ Milroy v Lord or the subsequent cases that
mandates physical separation. There is, for example, no need for appropriation
for the equitable assignment of an unascertained part of a debt or fund.130 In Re
Harvard Securities, Neuberger J stated that the effect of the decision in Hunter
v Moss was that, in this context, shares fall to be treated in the same way as a
debt or a fund rather than chattels.131
In the United States it has long been accepted as trite that an undivided
interest in fungible property is a sufficiently definite subject matter for a trust
to be created without the need for segregation.132 In Herdegen v Federal
Commissioner of Taxation,133 the point was deliberately left open but
Gummow J was prepared to assume without deciding that a trust of shares
could be created without the need for specific identification to establish cer-
tainty of subject matter.134 In Herdegen v Federal Commissioner of Taxation
Gummow J seems to have adopted the view that a failure to segregate or appro-
priate may lead a court to conclude that the evidence fails to show an intention
Butterworths, Sydney, 1992) para 634–5 and the cases cited therein.
131 [1997] 2 BCLC 369 at 383.
132 See Rollestone v National Bank of Commerce in St Louis 252 SW 394 (1923) and Busch v
Truitt 160 P 2d 925 (1945) affirmed by 163 P 2d 734. See also G Bogert Trusts and Trustees (Revised
2nd edn, Wests, St Paul, 1984) § 111.
133 (1988) 84 ALR 271 (FCA).
134 At 279 lines 20–30.
The Equitable Ownership of Shares 201
to create a present trust but merely a promise to make a gift ie a failure of cer-
tainty of intention to create a binding trust obligation rather than a failure to
clearly identify the property intended to form the subject matter of the trust
obligation.
Halsbury’s Laws of England states, in relation for the necessity for certainty
of subject matter in order to create a valid trust that:
In the case of a trust of intangible assets, such as a purported trust of a specific sum of
money forming part of a larger credit balance in a particular bank account, the ques-
tion of certainty depends not on any immutable principle based on the requirements
of a need for segregation or appropriation, but rather on whether immediately after
the purported declaration of the trust, the court could, if asked, make an order for the
execution of the purported trust.135
It is submitted that some caution should be exercised when applying this prin-
ciple to trusts of money which present special problems136 and a requirement to
keep moneys separate is normally an indicator that they are the subject of a
trust.137
CONCLUSION
Given the economic importance of public confidence in the markets and the
increasing dematerialisation of and immobilisation of securities, it is rather
worrying that the proprietary rights of investors—who do not request paper
share certificates or who are not personal members of CREST—rest entirely on
the authority of the much criticised Court of Appeal decision in Hunter v
Moss138 that was only reluctantly applied to sales of shares by Neuberger J in
Re Harvard Securities Ltd.139 It is noteworthy that to date an English court has
not had to decide a case where the rights of ‘owners’ of non-allocated demateri-
alised shares are contested by the holders of a floating charge over the assets of
the depository and it is hoped that this paper will provide some assistance to
investors in the event of the insolvency of a nominee.
135
P Pettit, ‘Trusts’ Volume 48 Halsbury’s Laws of England (4th edn (2000 reissue)) para 553
(footnotes omitted).
136
For example, the legal problems associated with tracing and overdrafts.
137
See Mac-Jordan Construction Ltd v Brookmount Erostin Ltd (in receivership) [1992] BCLC
350 (CA).
138
[1994] 1 WLR 453.
139
[1997] 2 BCLC 369 (ChD). See also Re CA Pacific Finance Ltd (in Liquidation) [2000] 1 BCLC
494 (HK CFI).
11
Northern Ireland: A Forgotten
Jurisdiction. Falling Behind or Forging
Ahead?
HEATHER CONWAY and SHEENA GRATTAN
INTRODUCTION
Of Poor Relations
The seeds of this paper were sown at the Third Biennial Conference hosted by
the Centre for Property Law at Reading University in March 2000.
Conversation after conversation with fellow delegates left the authors in no
doubt that the knowledge of Northern Ireland property law among their coun-
terparts in English universities could invariably be summed up in the mantra
‘but you don’t have the 1925 legislation there, do you’? The tenor varied in its
level of disinterest but in all cases the implication was clear. A jurisdiction that
had fallen behind so fundamentally was unworthy even of comparative study.
This last observation has probably struck a chord with property law scholars
from Commonwealth institutions who themselves have more than a little cause
to retort ‘so what’s new, then’? It remains a fact that the revered ‘1925 reforms’
were the one major development that the home of the common law failed to per-
suade the rest of the Dominions to embrace, yet their continued absence from
other jurisdictions has rarely provoked English lawyers to ponder why this
might be the case. On the contrary, they have tended to regard it as axiomatic
that the 1925 reforms set them apart from the rest of the world and as a result
eschewed comparative study. Indeed, the theme that English property law has
much to learn from the differences—but also the similarities—found in
Australia, New Zealand, Canada and both Irish jurisdictions is developed else-
where in this book in the context of land registration.1 The present paper is
rather narrower in focus. Its modest objective is to raise awareness among non-
Irish lawyers of contemporary issues in Northern Ireland property law and,
more particularly, to make the case that this small and for too long forgotten
Indeed the landscape of succession law is typical also on a more general level of
those primarily statute-based areas of property law where conformity with
England has been the aim. In most respects the basic provisions are precisely the
same; England leads and Northern Ireland eventually follows. In the context of
succession this time lag has ranged from thirty years (as with the Administration
of Estates Act (NI) 1955 which broadly corresponds to the Administration of
Estates Act 1925) to less than two years (as with the enactment of the Succession
(NI) Order 1996, the counterpart of the Law Reform (Succession) Act 1995).
Yet, as in virtually all other areas, the provisions are not a mirror image of those
in England. A number of small but significant differences still exist, most
notably in relation to intestate distribution but not exclusively so. This pattern
—broad parity with occasional differences implemented by a legislative pro-
gramme which drags behind—is replicated in many branches of property law,
including housing law, planning law and the law of mortgages.
On a daily basis, therefore, the Northern Ireland judiciary is called upon to
interpret statutory provisions that are in identical terms to English legislation
and, in the absence of ‘home-grown’ authorities, will automatically look to the
English jurisprudence for illumination. In theory, the courts in Northern
2 Report of the Family Provision Committee, Cmd (NI) 330 (1953) at para 37.
Northern Ireland: Falling Behind or Forging Ahead? 205
Ireland3 are not bound by decisions of the English courts and even a House of
Lords decision is strictly binding only if it originated in Northern Ireland.4 In
practice, however, all decisions of the appellate courts are treated as effectively
binding while decisions of the English High Court are regarded as being of the
strongest persuasive authority. Indeed so heavy is the reliance of Northern
Ireland lawyers—both academic and practising—on English case law that it is
often cited and reported as if it had emanated from the Northern Ireland courts.
It is rare to find reference to the rules of precedent or to have a differentiation
made between the two types of authority. In short, Northern Ireland has essen-
tially integrated English jurisprudence fully into its legally separate jurisdiction,
perhaps the ultimate act of consumerism. Of late, however, as shall be seen
below, there has been some evidence that our courts are increasingly prepared
not to follow English decisions, invoking the rules of precedent as a flexible and
imaginative tool.
While we have outlined the rules of precedent as they apply in Northern
Ireland in relation to English decisions, nothing has yet been said of the converse
arrangement—that decisions of the Northern Ireland courts are of persuasive
authority in England. The unfortunate truth is that very little has been said any-
where. A perusal of the standard textbooks and journal articles in the property
field establishes very quickly that Northern Ireland jurisprudence is a source of
persuasive authority which has yet to excite much interest beyond its own
shores, a state of affairs which contributes to the sense of jurisdictional isolation
experienced by its lawyers.
Selected Snapshots
Within the space constraints of a single paper our approach can only be highly
selective. We have chosen to highlight four topics which we feel best illustrate
the full spectrum of ways in which Northern Ireland law is most likely to be of
interest to comparative property lawyers, not only in England but farther afield.
We start with an example of what may be described as an ‘exclusively Irish
phenomenon’—a legal animal which has been shaped by the peculiar socio-
economic context of a ‘country of small farmers’.5 The classic case, perhaps,
of a jurisdiction falling behind? A propos the claims made in the preceding
paragraph about persuasive authority, we then focus on a decision of the
Northern Ireland High Court on section 36 of the Administration of Justice Act
1970, a statutory provision which extends both to England and Northern
3 The basic structure in terms of hierarchy is High Court, Northern Ireland Court of Appeal and
Ireland. The decision in National and Provincial Building Society v Lynd6 has
rarely been cited in English texts, yet in our view it demonstrates a more insight-
ful and pragmatic judicial approach than that taken by the English courts.
Thirdly, we examine a pioneering statutory provision that has recently swept
away the cumbersome rules for the enforceability of freehold covenants and
which, inter alia, provides for the benefit of positive covenants to run. Finally,
we look to the future with an assessment of the recent radical proposals of the
Law Reform Advisory Committee of Northern Ireland in relation to the family
home.
a right to reside in the dwelling-house . . . and be kept maintained and fed by my son
as she has hitherto been accustomed to but not clothed, and have the use of the pony
and trap when going to mass or on other necessary business7
I give my wife the right to reside in my house for her life but my wife will lose all inter-
est in this will if she allows any man (including any relative of mine) to stay overnight
in the house
(will proved in Belfast in 1967)
6 [1996] NI 47.
7 B Harvey, ‘Irish Rights of Residence—The Anatomy of an Hermaphrodite’ in [1970] NILQ 389
at 390.
8 It should be noted that where the donee is a surviving spouse and she makes a family provision
claim under the relevant Northern Ireland provisions, she will be likely to succeed to a larger award,
perhaps a full life estate together with a capital sum—see Gillespie v Scott, High Court (NI), unrep,
12 October 1997.
Northern Ireland: Falling Behind or Forging Ahead? 207
which has been left to a son, coupled with a right to maintenance out of the
profits of the farm itself.
A Chequered History
In legal terms, however, the history of the right of residence has been one of
inactivity, uncertainty and confusion, and notwithstanding how often such
rights have arisen judicial analysis of them has been scant. Prior to 1999 they had
never been considered by the Northern Ireland courts and what little authority
that existed was either decisions of pre-Partition Irish courts or those of the
Republic, but they were far from clear. For example, National Bank v Keegan9
suggested that an exclusive right of residence conferred a life estate on the
donee, an approach in line with that of the English courts on the few occasions
when similarly drafted interests had been before them.10 However, such an
analysis presents an obvious problem in the context of the small family farm,
namely that the donee immediately acquires the extensive powers conferred on
the tenant for life by the Settled Land Acts 1882–1890,11 with the consequence
that she could lease, or even sell, the farm from under other members of the
family. While few judges have expressly referred to this legislation there can be
little doubt that it influenced their decisions to avoid a life estate. Kelaghan v
Daly12 is often cited as authority that a non-exclusive right of residence is a right
‘in the nature of a lien for money’s worth’,13 and Re Shanahan14 for the propo-
sition that it is an ‘annuity or money charge’. On closer examination, however,
it is questionable whether either case is authority for such general principles.15
Since 1970 there has been a modicum of protection for the donee of rights of
residence granted on registered land, for section 47 of the Land Registration
Act (NI) 1970 provides that, while a right of residence is personal to the donee
and incapable of assignment, any such right registered as a burden against the
land will bind the landowner’s successors in title. However, notwith-
standing this legislative intervention the precise scope of the right remained
ill-defined, and of course not all rights of residence were granted on registered
land.
9 [1931] IR 344.
10 Re Carne [1899] 1 Ch 324; Re Baroness Llandover’s Will Trusts [1902] 2 Ch 679; Re Gibbons
[1920] 1 Ch 372 and Bannister v Bannister [1948] 2 All ER 133.
11 This legislation is still in force in Northern Ireland. The Settled Land Act 1925 did not extend
to Northern Ireland and the jurisdiction has no equivalent of the Trusts of Land and Appointment
of Trustees Act 1996.
12
[1913] 2 IR 328.
13
Ibid, per Boyd J at 330.
14
[1919] 1 IR 131. See also Johnston J at first instance in National Bank v Keegan [1931] IR 344
at 346.
15
See the discussion in B Harvey, ‘Irish Rights of Residence: The Anatomy of an Hermaphrodite’
[1970] NILQ 389 and in Jones v Jones [2001] NI 244 at 254.
208 Heather Conway and Sheena Grattan
The most thorough academic study of the Irish right of residence remains an
article written by Professor Brian Harvey over thirty years ago.16 At the time of
publication there was virtually no judicial support for his thesis that rights of
residence are a type of irrevocable licence. In the last three years, however, there
have been two decisions of Girvan J of the Northern Ireland High Court,17 Re
Walker’s Application for Judicial Review18 and Jones v Jones,19 both of which
adopt this licence analysis.
The issue before the court in Jones20 was the precise scope of a right of residence
which had been reserved for the plaintiff by her late husband when he had trans-
ferred the family farm to their son. Due to deteriorating health the plaintiff had
spent some time in a nursing home but now wished to return to exercise her
right of residence. The defendants, her son and grandson (to whom the son had
agreed to transfer the house and who was now living in it with his wife) pre-
vented her doing so on the ground that it would not be in her best long-term
interests and the plaintiff sought to enforce the right.
In a very thorough judgment, Girvan J provided a full and systematic review
of the existing jurisprudence, observing that the development of the law had
been characterised by ‘statements of principle arrived at by a flawed generalised
interpretation of specific cases turning on their own terms and clauses in partic-
ular instruments’.21 The learned judge expressly rejected both the life estate and
lien analogy. Neither, he opined, reflected the donor’s true intention:
Where a person grants or reserves an exclusive right of residence the right by definition
is intended to be restricted to the very purpose of the grant or reservation. The grantee
will fully appreciate that the right of residence does not, for example, envisage a right
to use the premises for some non-residential purpose. Nor would the parties envisage
the sale, letting or exchange of the property.22
16
Ibid.
17
In Northern Ireland one of the High Court judges is assigned to the Chancery Division and
known as the Chancery Judge. Since 1995 the Chancery Judge has been Girvan J. While all judges
must take a certain allocation of criminal work each year, the Chancery Judge will hear about 90
per cent of the cases in the Chancery Court.
18
[1999] NI 84.
19
[2001] NI 244.
20
Re Walker was not a ‘classic’ right of residence dispute but rather the issue for the court was
whether the donee of a right of residence has sufficient interest in the property to apply for an
improvement grant under the governing legislation.
21
[2001] NI 244 at 256.
22
[2001] NI 244 at 254, comments which the learned judge first made in Re Walker [1999] 84
at 99.
Northern Ireland: Falling Behind or Forging Ahead? 209
tractual licence but in each case the precise proprietary context varied with the
category of licence concerned. In the case before him the plaintiff had been
granted an irrevocable contractual licence to reside in the premises during her
lifetime, which the court would protect by an injunction or specific performance
if appropriate. The precise scope of the licence was a matter of construction of
the agreement set in its proper context as to what contractual rights it conferred
on the plaintiff. On the facts, the learned judge held that the plaintiff enjoyed an
exclusive right to reside in the premises (together with persons to provide care
and supervision if required) and that her grandson and his wife could only reside
in the house with her consent.
Unfortunately it has not been possible in the space restraints to engage in a fuller
critique of the decision in Jones. Suffice to say that the clarification which it
provides is to be welcomed. The analysis of the right of residence as a type of
irrevocable licence has borrowed heavily from the evolving principles of equi-
table licences during the last thirty years in England23 and it is interesting that
even in this very culture-specific context Northern Ireland again finds itself in its
traditional role of a consumer of law. More pertinent to the themes which are
being developed in this paper, the experience in relation to rights of residence
illustrates how a couple of enigmatic and poorly reasoned decisions can heavily
influence legal development (or non-development) in a small common law juris-
diction. It almost beggars belief that there was no case before the Northern
Ireland courts between Partition and 1999 concerning a phenomenon which still
occurs in one-tenth of rural wills. It is almost as remarkable that, in the face of
such uncertainty, members of the legal profession have continued to proliferate
such rights in wills and deeds without seeking to define the precise scope of the
interest intended. In Jones the learned judge rejected the submission made on
behalf of the defendants that ‘right of residence’ was a legal term of art, holding
that in all cases the terms of the licence had to be interpreted in the light of the
factual context and in light of the agreement as a whole or the drafting of the
instrument which created it. However, the vast majority of Northern Irish wills
(professionally drafted as well as home-made)24 create a right of residence by
using the phrase ‘right to reside’ without further elaboration. In both Walker
and Jones Girvan J counselled against this practice, giving a salutary warning
to those responsible for drafting wills of the need to address their minds to the
precise nature of the interests that they wished to create. Time will tell if these
23
Although the learned judge did not engage in an analysis of the relevant English jurisprudence.
24
It is relevant to this point that in Northern Ireland the legal profession is dominated by small
non-specialist firms—more than 80 per cent of the firms of solicitors in Northern Ireland have two
partners or less.
210 Heather Conway and Sheena Grattan
This would give borrowers the maximum possible opportunity to make good
their default, while avoiding multiple applications to court under s 36 with all
the attendant expense. Any further exercise of the s 36 powers would, however,
be unlikely in the event of any subsequent default.28
The decision in Norgan prompted mixed reactions. On the one hand, it was
welcomed as dispensing with the former ‘broad brush’29 approach under
section 36 and providing a more cohesive set of principles for determining such
applications, while preventing ‘serial litigation’30 by giving the borrower a ‘once
and for all opportunity’31 to make good his default. However, concern was
25
[1996] NI 47.
26
[1996] 1 All ER 449.
27
[1996] 1 All ER 449 at 458.
28
[1996] 4 All ER 449 at 459–60.
29
M Haley, “Mortgage Default: Possession, Relief and Judicial Discretion” (1997) 17 LS 483 at 493.
30
MP Thompson, Modern Land Law (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2001) at 366.
31
J Morgan, ‘Mortgage Arrears and the Family Home’ (1996) 112 LQR 553 at 556.
Northern Ireland: Falling Behind or Forging Ahead? 211
expressed that the Court of Appeal had effectively reversed the burden of proof
in repossession cases, while placing lenders at the mercy of a ‘drip feed repay-
ment system’ and the unpredictability of the property market at the end of the
mortgage term.32
The decision also attracted interest in Northern Ireland in view of the shared
legislative provisions.33 Speculation as to whether courts in this jurisdiction
would follow Norgan was brought to an end some six months later in National
and Provincial Building Society v. Lynd.34
Mr and Mrs Lynd had purchased a dwelling house in 1988 with a mortgage from
the plaintiff for the sum of £24,800. The mortgage was payable in monthly instal-
ments for a term of just under 17 years. By 1991, the defendants had fallen into
serious arrears. The plaintiff obtained orders for possession in January and
October 1994, but these were suspended following assurances from the defen-
dants that they would be able to discharge the arrears. The defendants continued
to default. In November 1995, with the arrears totalling £9,400, the building soci-
ety sought leave to execute the possession order granted in October 1994. The
master felt that he was bound by the ruling in Norgan to take the remaining term
of the mortgage as the ‘reasonable period’ for the purposes of section 36. On that
basis, he made an order suspending possession on condition that the defendants
paid £100 per month towards the arrears. The building society appealed to the
High Court where Girvan J suggested a different approach when determining the
‘reasonable period’ for postponing possession under section 36.
Girvan J reviewed the decision in Norgan and pointed out that courts in
Northern Ireland had previously followed the practice of English courts in post-
poning possession for two to four years in most cases.35 He agreed with the deci-
sion insofar as it ‘stresse[d] the duty of the court to take all the circumstances of
the case into account’36 and envisaged that, in appropriate cases, a reasonable
period might be the remaining term of the mortgage. In this respect, the Court
of Appeal was ‘correcting an established practice which had in effect fettered the
court’s discretion under section 36’.37 However, insofar as Norgan suggested
that courts should start with the strong presumption in favour of the remaining
term of the mortgage being taken as the ‘reasonable period’ for the purposes of
32 HW Wilkinson, ‘Mortgage Repayments—In Your Own Time?’ (1996) 146 NLJ 252 at 253.
33
See A Dowling and H Wallace, ‘Land Law’ in S Grattan (ed), Third Annual Review of Property
Law (SLS, Belfast, 1996) 1 at 7.
34
[1996] NI 47.
35
See Alliance and Leicester Building Society v Carlisle, High Court (NI), unrep, 8 September
1995.
36
[1997] NI 47 at 56.
37
[1997] NI 47 at 56.
212 Heather Conway and Sheena Grattan
section 36, Girvan J felt obliged to part company with the Court of Appeal. The
reasons behind this departure merit closer analysis.
Prior to 1970, courts had a limited power to grant defaulting borrowers relief
against the lender’s contractual claim to possession.38 The Report of the Payne
Committee39 considered this restriction to be too severe, thus paving the way for
section 36 of the 1970 Act. However, Girvan J noted that the Committee had
contemplated a postponement of 6 months as the norm in most cases, while the
General Council of the Bar and the Law Society had recommended periods of
one to six months and three months respectively. In this context, a presumption
in favour of the remaining term of the mortgage was not a ‘logical or justifiable
inference to be drawn from the inherent context of the legislation’.40
So far as the relevant case law was concerned, Girvan J suggested that the
decision in Halifax Building Society v Clark41 had only presented a problem
because a ‘reasonable period’ was taken as being far shorter than remaining
term of the mortgage.42 The Court of Appeal in Norgan had relied upon dicta
in First Middlesbrough Trading Co Ltd v Cunningham43 and Western Bank Ltd
v Schindler44 as supporting postponement of possession for the remaining term
of the mortgage. However, both cases were distinguished by Girvan J as being
decided in different factual contexts which did little to support the interpreta-
tion placed on them by the Court of Appeal.45
By presuming that the court should take the remaining term of the mortgage as
the ‘reasonable period’ under section 36, Girvan J suggested that Norgan directs
the court to begin its inquiry from the wrong starting point. Instead:
What the court must do under s 36 is to consider all the circumstances of the case,
approaching the matter with an open mind seeking to do justice between the mort-
gagor and the mortgagee—A determination of the facts set out by Evans LJ [in
38
See Birmingham Citizens Permanent Building Society v Caunt [1962] Ch 883.
39
Cmd 3909 (1969).
40
[1996] NI 47 at 58.
41
[1973] 2 All ER 33.
42
The case held that the reference in s 36 to ‘any sums due under the mortgage’ meant the entire
mortgage debt, and led to enactment of s 8 of the 1973 Act.
43
(1974) 28 P & CR 69.
44
[1976] 2 All ER 393.
45
See the discussion at [1996] NI 47 at 59–60.
Northern Ireland: Falling Behind or Forging Ahead? 213
Norgan46]—without any pre-disposition for or against the relevant period being the
balance of the term of the mortgage is in my respectful view the proper approach.47
The court should focus on the amount which the borrower could afford to pay
and calculate the length of time which it would take to discharge the arrears at
that rate. It could then ask itself, applying the checklist devised by Evans LJ,
whether that period was reasonable in all the circumstances of the case.
46 [1996] 1 All ER 449 at 463. Various factors were suggested, including the amount which the
borrower could reasonably afford to pay both now and in the future, the reason for the arrears, and
how much remained of the original term.
47
[1996] NI 47 at 60.
48
See above.
49
[1996] NI 47 at 60.
50
[1996] NI 47 at 60–1.
51
Although it has been suggested that the lender nevertheless gets ‘substantially what he bar-
gained for, albeit at a later date’—J Morgan, ‘Mortgage Arrears and the Family Home’ (1996) 112
LQR 553 at 556.
214 Heather Conway and Sheena Grattan
account of the fact that lenders do not resort to court lightly. By that stage there
will usually have been a ‘serious history of default and broken promises’.52
It has already been noted that, while Northern Ireland courts will usually follow
decisions of the English Court of Appeal, such decisions are not strictly binding
on them. Thus in Lynd, the decision in Norgan was rejected insofar as it sug-
gested that courts should start with the presumption in favour of the remaining
mortgage term representing the ‘reasonable period’ for the purposes of section
36. Girvan J also distinguished Norgan on the basis that the lender’s security
was not at risk. It was significant that the Court of Appeal in Mortgage
Corporation Ltd v Leslie53 had declined to apply Norgan because the mortgage
debt in that case was on the point of exceeding the value of the security. In the
present case, the mortgage debt owed by Mr and Mrs Lynd was also close to
exceeding the value of the property.54
It is suggested that the decision in Lynd presents a more pragmatic and balanced
approach than that of the Court of Appeal in Norgan. While not disputing the
rationale behind Norgan and the need to protect borrowers against the loss of
the family home in cases of financial hardship, Lynd posits this protection on a
more equilibristic basis.
The Court of Appeal in Norgan stressed the importance of the court weigh-
ing up the interests of both borrowers and lenders when exercising the delaying
powers under section 36 of the 1970 Act. The court’s objective was to be ‘even-
handed’ in its approach to the competing claims, allowing the borrower an
opportunity to make good his default while ensuring that the lender was not
forced to wait for repayment through an ‘enforced capitalisation of arrears’.55
However, in suggesting the remaining term of the mortgage as the presumed
‘reasonable period’ for the purposes of section 36, it is arguable that Norgan
pushed the balance too far in favour of the borrower. By proposing that the
remaining term of the mortgage should only be assessed as a relevant factor in
weighing up all the circumstances of an application under section 36, the deci-
sion in Lynd perhaps achieves a fairer balance between both borrower and
lender. Moreover, it addresses some of the concerns expressed in relation
to Norgan and recognises that, while section 36 performs an important social
52 [1996] NI 47 at 62.
53 Court of Appeal, unrep, 1 February 1996.
54 [1996] NI 47 at 63.
55 [1996] 1 All ER 449 at 458.
Northern Ireland: Falling Behind or Forging Ahead? 215
Had the newly created Northern Ireland not been troubled by more pressing
constitutional concerns in the mid-1920s, her law reformers may have been in a
position to give their attention to matters of property law. Attempts at mod-
ernisation were sporadic and piecemeal and it was not until the 1960s that the
land law and conveyancing system came under the microscope of the Northern
Ireland Land Law Working Group. Its findings were published in 1971 but only
a few of the recommendations were implemented.59 During the 1980s the Land
Law Working Group undertook a more comprehensive study. Some of the rec-
ommendations made in its Final Report, published in 1991, have recently been
enacted in the Property (NI) Order 1997. In this next section we examine the fea-
ture of this legislation which is likely to be of most interest outside the jurisdic-
tion. Article 34 of the 1997 Order, which only became effective on 12 January
2000, replaces the old common law and equitable rules for the running of the
benefit and the burden of freehold covenants that have been so beloved of gen-
erations of law students. Its major claim to novelty, however, lies in the fact that
it provides for the burden of certain positive covenants to run, a development
56 See M Haley, ‘Mortgage Default: Possession, Relief and Judicial Discretion’ (1997) 17 LS 483
at 496.
57 See Mortgage Corporation Ltd v Leslie, Court of Appeal, unrep, 1 February 1996 noted above,
as well as Gallagher v Abbey National Building Society, Court of Appeal, unrep, 14 December 1999.
58 The decision does merit a passing reference in K Gray and SF Gray, Elements of Land Law (3rd
edn, Butterworths, London, 2001) at 1423, but is notably absent from other leading property law
texts and does not appear to have been cited in any English case on the point.
59 For example, the Property (NI) Order 1978 which makes provision for the extinction or
which has Northern Ireland forging ahead not only of England but most of the
common law world.60 In addition to the enforcement of positive covenants, the
other main change is that prior registration of the covenant will not be required
to secure its enforcement. However, Article 34 is limited in its application to
specific types of covenant. Article 34(4) provides:
The following kinds of covenant (and only covenants of those kinds) are enforceable
(as appropriate to the nature of the covenant and the circumstances of the breach of
the anticipated or threatened breach) by the owner for the time being of the land
benefited by the covenant against the owner for the time being of the land burdened
by it—
(a) covenants in respect of the maintenance, repair or renewal of party walls or fences
or the preservation of boundaries;
(b) covenants to do, or to pay for or contribute to the cost of, works on, or to permit
works to be done on, or for access to be had to, or for any activity to be pursued on,
the land of the covenantor for the benefit of land of the covenantee or other land;
(c) covenants to do, or to pay for or contribute to the cost of, works on the land of the
covenantee or other land where the works benefit the land of the covenantor;
(d) covenants to reinstate in the event of damage or destruction;
(e) covenants for the protection of amenities or services or for compliance with a
statutory provision (or a requirement under it), including-
(i) covenants (however expressed) not to use the land of the covenantor for specified
purposes or otherwise than for the purposes of a private dwelling;
(ii) covenants against causing nuisance, annoyance, damage or inconvenience;
(iii) covenants against interfering with facilities;
(iv) covenants prohibiting, regulating or restricting building works or the erection of
any structure, or the planting, cutting or removal of vegetation (including grass, trees
and shrubs) or requiring the tending of such vegetation—
Estate schemes also come within the remit of the new provision. Article 34(6)
provides:
Where there is a development, [paragraph (4) applies]—as if (if it is not the case) the
covenants made by parcel owners with the developer had been made also with other
parcel owners to the extent that those covenants are capable of reciprocally benefiting
and burdening the parcels of the various parcel owners and as if references in those
paragraphs to the land benefited by a covenant, the land burdened by a covenant and
the land of the covenantee and the covenantor included (to that extent) references to
parcels.
Article 34 is not retrospective, so the former rules will always remain relevant.
As yet the new provision has generated no case law, or even, so far as the authors
are aware, significant teething problems. Indeed it will not be until land has been
transferred to successors in title that an effective assessment can be made of its
operation. Such developments will deserve to provoke interest in many quarters.
60 The burden of positive covenants runs in Trinidad and Tobago. See Bell, ‘Enforcement of
Judicial and legislative attempts to deal with the vexed issue of property rights
in the family home have often been hindered by two competing aims: balancing
the interests of couples vis-à-vis each other, and protecting the interests of third
parties engaged in dealings with the family home.61 While the focus in the post-
Boland62 era was firmly on the latter objective, the emphasis has once again
shifted to the property entitlements of persons living in the family home. This
movement has been reflected in a number of recent policy initiatives, culminat-
ing in the Law Commission’s consultation paper on Sharing Homes which is
stimulating renewed interest in the subject in England and Wales.63
The Law Reform Advisory Committee for Northern Ireland (hereinafter the
‘LRAC’) has recommended its own changes to the law regarding ownership of
the family home which may result in the two jurisdictions taking different
approaches.64 Although some of the LRAC proposals can trace their genealogy
to measures put forward by the Law Commission in the past,65 it is significant
that the Northern Ireland recommendations preceded the current Law
Commission report. In addition, the LRAC proposals go much further than
those suggested by Law Commission in the past.66
61 For an overview see J Dewar, ‘Land, Law and the Family Home’ in S Bright and J Dewar (eds)
Land Law: Themes and Perspectives (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1998) ch 13.
62
Williams and Glyn’s Bank Ltd v Boland [1980] 2 All ER 408.
63
Other recent developments in England and Wales include the Relationships (Civil
Registration) Bill introduced by Jane Griffiths MP in October 2001, and the Civil Partnerships Bill
introduced by Lord Lester of Herne Hill QC in January 2002.
64
Law Reform Advisory Committee for Northern Ireland Report No 10, Matrimonial Property
(2000) (hereinafter the ‘Final Report’).
65
See Law Com No 52 (1973), Law Com No 86 (1978) and the subsequent Matrimonial Homes
(Co-Ownership) Bill 1980, as well as Law Com No 175 (1988).
66
Most notably as regards the inclusion of cohabitants—see below.
67
Final Report, p 36.
218 Heather Conway and Sheena Grattan
spouses who did not wish to subscribe to the proposed regime.68 However, the
LRAC also recommended that the same scheme of statutory co-ownership
should apply to ‘qualifying cohabitants’.69 These were defined as persons who:
(a) have been living together in the same household for at least a total of two years
within the period of the three years preceding the property transaction effectively as
husband and wife though not married; or
(b) have had a child by the relationship and have been living together in the same
household effectively as husband and wife though not married.70
68 The presumption of statutory co-ownership would also apply to property acquired or trans-
ferred in contemplation of marriage and intended to be the parties’ joint residence—Final Report,
p 36.
69 Final Report, p 36.
70 Final Report, p 37.
71 Similar recommendations were made in respect of housekeeping money and household goods
acquired by spouses or qualifying cohabitants—Final Report, pp 37–8. The LRAC also recom-
mended that the presumption of advancement between husbands and wives be abolished—Final
Report, p 39.
72
Since a retrospective effect would be ‘intrinsically unfair’ in the absence of an opportunity to
contract out of the scheme, and might constitute a disproportionate interference with existing prop-
erty rights contrary to the ECHR—Final Report, pp 29–30.
73
For example, the contribution in money and money’s worth towards the cost of acquiring,
maintaining, repairing and improving the premises or towards discharging any debt secured on the
premises; any agreement, understanding or arrangement, express or implied, made in respect of the
parties’ beneficial interests—see Final Report, p 32 for a full list.
Northern Ireland: Falling Behind or Forging Ahead? 219
A Shift in Ideology
The presumption of equal sharing from the outset as proposed by the LRAC is
in stark contrast to the current law in Northern Ireland and in England and
Wales which is premised upon the doctrine of separate ownership of the family
home.74
At present, legal ownership of the family home is determined by the names on
the title documents. Where title is not in joint names, courts have developed a
trusts-based approach for determining beneficial interests in the family home on
the basis of financial contributions. In these circumstances, a non-legal title
holder can assert an equitable interest in the property by means of a resulting or
constructive trust where he/she has made a direct contribution to the purchase
price, or has made indirect contributions premised on an agreement or under-
standing that these would give rise to a beneficial interest.75 However, judicial
efforts at superimposing trust principles on informal domestic arrangements
have caused problems in practice, most notably in the context of indirect
contributions with courts struggling to find a discernible common intention76 or
to quantify domestic labour when calculating the resultant beneficial entitle-
ment.77
The LRAC proposals indicate a fundamental shift in ideology by quantifying
property rights in the family home on the basis of status as opposed to financial
contributions. The proposals recognise marriage and cohabiting relationships
of sufficient standing as a partnership of equals which should be reflected in
equal sharing of the family home. In this respect, they also recognise the unique
status of the property and the unique nature of the relationships which arise in
the spousal or quasi-matrimonial context, while implicitly rejecting the doctrine
of separate ownership and its attendant theory that ownership of the family
home should be determined as if the parties were strangers. Moreover, by shift-
ing the emphasis from contributions to status, the proposals arguably promote
equality between the sexes. Despite increased economic power and status for
women, the current law may still work against the female spouse or cohabitant,
most often in the case of indirect financial contributions, and in this respect may
‘help to perpetuate . . . [an] inherently discriminatory system’.78 An automatic
74 However, this automatic presumption of equal sharing has not received universal support—
see R Deech, ‘Williams and Glyn’s and Family Law’ (1980) 130 NLJ 896 and MT Murphy and
RW Rawlings, ‘The Matrimonial Homes (Co-ownership) Bill: The Right Way Forward’ (1980) 40
Fam Law 136.
75 See, for example, the decision of the Northern Ireland Court of Appeal in McFarlane v
McFarlane [1972] NI 59, as endorsed by the House of Lords in Lloyds Bank plc v Rosset [1991] 1 AC
107. The same principles apply irrespective of whether the parties concerned are spouses or cohab-
itants—see Grant v Edwards [1986] 2 All ER 426.
76 The absence of which lead to ostensibly meritorious claims being rejected in McFarlane v
presumption of joint and equal ownership of the family home would go some
way towards redressing these perceived inequalities.79
type housewife’—R Deech, ‘Williams and Glyn’s and Family Law’ (1980) 130 NLJ 896 at 899. It has
also been suggested that assumptions about the role of women in society and their contributions
(both domestic and financial) within relationships are often underestimated and not reflective of
their true positions—see R Probert, ‘Cohabitants and The Law’ (2000) 30 Fam Law 925 at 928.
80 See the Law Commission Reports at n 65 above.
81 Equivalent to the Matrimonial Causes Act 1973.
82 See generally Final Report, ch 4.
83 Final Report, p 20.
84 Other homesharing relationships are outside the scheme and would require a more substantive
inquiry, such as that conducted by the Law Commission in its report on Sharing Homes.
85 See, for example, ss 1(ba) and (1A) of the Inheritance (Provision for Family and Dependants)
Where the parties are living together as husband and wife, and have had a child,
the two year qualifying period does not apply. The birth of the child operates as
a magic talisman which presumptively elevates the relationship from casual to
committed and stable, and attracts the conferral of substantive property rights
upon a subsequent acquisition or transfer of the family home. Although not
specifically addressed by the LRAC, it is assumed that the reference to having
‘had a child by the relationship’ denotes a child of both cohabitants,89 and
would presumably include a child born by assisted conception.90 The definition
almost certainly assumes a birth process, so that conception and miscarriage
would not suffice, although more problematic issues arise in the context of still-
births. The outcome depends on whether birth or parenthood is regarded as the
86
See, for example, Re Watson (Deceased) [1999] 1 FLR 878 which held that a sexual relation-
ship is not essential. For a Northern Ireland perspective, see Gibson v Bell, High Court (NI), unrep,
29 October 1999.
87
See Pounder v London Underground [1995] PIQR 217.
88
Such as that proposed under Part I of the Civil Partnerships Bill where cohabitants could apply
to register their relationship in certain circumstances.
89
As opposed to a child of one cohabitant for which the other party has assumed responsibility.
90
With parenthood being determined by the principles laid down by ss 27 and 28 of the Human
Fertilisation and Embryology Act 1990.
222 Heather Conway and Sheena Grattan
The reference to living together ‘effectively as husband and wife’ would seem to
restrict the LRAC proposals to heterosexual couples. The use of the word ‘effec-
tively’ in this context may be a matter of semantic debate. One possible line of
argument is that effectively living together in a spousal context merely points to
a set of circumstances—a couple who are to all intents and purposes living
together in a quasi-matrimonial structure, whether they are of the opposite sex
or not. However, the House of Lords in Fitzpatrick v Sterling Housing
Association91 held that the words ‘husband and wife’ are gender specific and
connote a relationship between a man and a woman.92 This might suggest that
the marriage yardstick assumes a heterosexual definition of qualifying cohabi-
tants under the LRAC proposals.93
When addressing the issue of qualifying cohabitants, it is clear that the LRAC
only contemplated heterosexual couples.94 Neither the Final Report nor the
Discussion Paper which preceded it95 makes any reference to same-sex cohabitants,
and no explanation is given as to why the proposals should not extend to them.96
In applying the scheme of statutory co-ownership to heterosexual cohabitants, the
91
[1999] 4 All ER 705.
92
See however the decision in Mendoza v Ghaidan [2002] 4 All ER 1162 discussed below.
93
Transsexuals who are cohabiting with a member of their original sex would probably be regarded
as a same-sex couple, since the definition of ‘living together—as husband and wife’ is gender-specific,
and the sex of a transsexual is determined by the chromosomal, gonadal and genital criteria assigned
at birth—see Bellinger v Bellinger [2001] 1 All ER 311 applying Corbett v Corbett [1970] 2 All ER 33.
The decision in Corbett has recently been rejected in Australia—In Re Kevin (2001) 28 Fam LR 158.
94
Final Report, p 21.
95
Law Reform Advisory Committee for Northern Ireland Discussion Paper No 5, Matrimonial
Property (1999).
96
While the reasons behind the exclusion of homosexual cohabitants are at best speculative, it may
have been a tactical gamble to ensure that the proposals progress to a further stage. This would depend
on public and political support, and same-sex couples do not as yet have widespread social acceptance
in Northern Ireland. Perhaps the LRAC was of the opinion that it would encounter less risk of the entire
proposals being lost by avoiding the type of adverse reaction which would almost certainly arise from
the inclusion of same-sex couples.
Northern Ireland: Falling Behind or Forging Ahead? 223
LRAC was conscious of the possible implications of Article 8 and Article 14 of the
ECHR, as well as section 75 of the Northern Ireland Act 1998.97 However, these
provisions could be invoked by homosexual cohabitants seeking to challenge their
exclusion from the LRAC proposals. The early Strasbourg jurisprudence suggests
that cohabiting same-sex couples do not have a right to family life for the purposes
of Article 8.98 Likewise, the fact that such persons do not qualify as ‘living together
as husband and wife’ does not fall foul of Article 14.99 However the Court of
Appeal in Mendoza v Ghaidan100 recently held that the exclusion of homosexual
cohabitants from the definition of living together as husband and wife for the pur-
poses of succeeding to a statutory tenancy under the Rent Act 1977 (which engages
Article 8) amounts to discrimination under Article 14. Accordingly, the reference in
the relevant legislation101 to living together ‘as his or her wife or husband’ should
be construed as meaning ‘as if they were his or her wife or husband’ thus including
same-sex couples.102 In this respect, the use of the word ‘effectively’ in the LRAC
proposals might achieve a similar result. Closer to home, section 75 of the Northern
Ireland Act 1998 makes specific reference to public authorities promoting equality
of opportunity on the grounds of sexual orientation. However, the definition of
‘public authority’ does not expressly include a court, and the extent to which the
Northern Ireland judiciary will allow the spirit of this provision to develop in keep-
ing with the emerging human rights culture remains to be seen.
A Problem Solved?
The recommendations put forward by the LRAC are at this stage embryonic,
and are likely to undergo a lengthy gestation period. However, the aims of the
proposals are laudable and they have much to commend them. The proposals
reflect the social ideology of marriage and cohabiting relationships as partner-
ships, and shift the emphasis on ownership of the family home from economics
to status. In more general policy terms, the prevailing ethos has shifted to pro-
tecting the ‘shelter aspect’ of the family home, as opposed to the Boland-driven
‘security aspect’, and LRAC proposals are reflective of this.
If implemented, the proposals would alleviate the need to resort to cumbersome
trust principles for determining property rights in the family home. Instead, prop-
erty rights would be allocated on the basis of inferred joint and equal beneficial
ownership, or according to a specific legislative framework in cases falling outside
the proposed scheme of statutory co-ownership. In this respect, the proposals
would significantly improve the position of non-legal title spouses and qualifying
97 See above.
98 X and Y v UK (Application 9369/81).
99 S v UK (Application 11716/85). The prohibition on same-sex marriage does not violate Article
CONCLUSION
In legal terms Northern Ireland has hardly been inconspicuous from the world
stage during the last three decades. However, during a period when Diplock
Courts, Human Rights violations, post-conflict resolution processes or some
other aspect of our unfortunate recent history have generated volumes of schol-
arly ink from the pens of the international academy, one of the few aspects of
our property laws to merit outside attention was the very generous rule against
accumulations,103 resulting in the claim to fame that a number of up-market
trusts (most famously those of the Vesteys)104 were expressly governed by the
law of Northern Ireland.
Property lawyers came late to comparative study, but an increasing number
have become persuaded of the value of such work. With the wider availability
of case law through electronic databases this trend is set to continue. Some texts
103 The Accumulations Act 1800 was enacted just before the Act of Union and did not extend to
Ireland. Neither Irish jurisdiction has since been persuaded to restrict the accumulation of income.
104 The fact that some of the Vestey trusts were governed by Northern Ireland law is commented
on by Lord Wilberforce in Vestey v IRC (Nos 1 and 2) [1979] 3 WLR 915 at 920.
Northern Ireland: Falling Behind or Forging Ahead? 225
now quote Commonwealth authorities and perspectives105 but, as yet, there has
been scant evidence of English lawyers looking to Northern Ireland either to
provide persuasive authority relating to matters which are the same, or food for
thought in matters which are different.106 This paper has sought to show that,
in both respects, Northern Ireland now has much to offer. There is a sense in
which Northern Ireland has been legally stigmatised in the absence of the 1925
reforms. Moreover, the failure of English property lawyers to embrace the rich
vein of Northern Ireland jurisprudence has done little to counter this sense of
jurisdictional isolation. It is unquestionably the case that during ‘the Troubles’
property law stagnated in the face of more pressing concerns. Now the juris-
diction has emerged to enjoy an exciting phase of its legal development and a
burgeoning self-confidence, no better evidenced than by the LRACs proposals
for matrimonial property. Whatever the shortcomings of these proposals, they
represent a quantum-leap in the thinking of what has been traditionally one of
the most socially and politically conservative societies in western Europe.
No one would suggest that a jurisdiction of 1.5 million people could ever lose
its characteristic as a consumer of law. However, to date the relationship which
Northern Ireland has enjoyed with its larger neighbour has been entirely para-
sitic. In the light of some interesting products, the time has surely come for that
larger neighbour to explore the possibility of transmuting that relationship into
a more symbiotic one.
105
The best example being K Gray and SF Gray, Elements of Land Law (3rd edn, Butterworths,
London, 2001).
106
The odd exception does exist. For example, the most recent editions of both of the standard
practitioner works on the law of family provision, R Oughton, Tyler’s Family Provision
(Butterworths, 1997, 3rd ed) and S Ross, Inheritance Act Claims (Sweet & Maxwell, 2000, 2nd edn)
make liberal use of Northern Ireland decisions on the Inheritance (Provision for Family and
Dependants)(NI) 1979. Richard Oughton commends the approach of the Northern Ireland judiciary
to applications by spouses and infant children as ‘exemplary and in some cases [they] have shown a
better approach than that adopted by the English judiciary’.
Part IV
Landlord and tenant
12
New Terms or New Lease: Principles
of Leasehold Variation
WARREN BARR 1
INTRODUCTION
The main issue under discussion in this paper is at what point an alteration of
the terms of the lease bargain will result in the destruction of the existing lease
at law, and the substitution of a completely new lease agreement. It is clearly
desirable that the law should allow for the alteration of leasehold terms in the
light of changing circumstances, without this having to be accomplished in all
respects by the execution (deemed or actual) of a fresh tenancy agreement.
Nevertheless, there must come a point when the original lease can be said to
have been varied out of all existence; when it is no longer sensible to talk of the
continuance of the old, amended lease.
Following the important decision in Friends Provident Life Office v British
Railways Board,2 it appears that the variation of the terms of a lease need not
result in the destruction and substitution of the lease unless either the parcels
demised or the length of the term are increased. In all other cases, whether the
old lease stands as amended or is replaced by the execution of a new lease is a
matter for the intentions of the lessor and lessee. However, the intellectual basis
of this decision, and the practical problems which can result, have drawn sharp
academic criticism.3 Moreover, there remain outstanding practical questions,
such as whether a decrease in either the term or the parcels should have the same
effect as an increase.4
The purpose of this paper is to consider the principles applicable to leasehold
variation. This necessarily involves revisiting the reasoning in Friends
1
The author wishes to acknowledge the comments made at the conference by Susan Bright,
Sandi Murdoch and Elizabeth Cooke, which have helped to add depth to the discussion. The views
expressed herein, and any errors or omissions, are, of course, the author’s alone.
2
[1996] 1 All ER 336; approved in Beegas Nominees Ltd v BHP Petroleum Ltd [1998] 2 EGLR 57.
3
See S Bright, ‘Variation of Leases and Tenant Liability’ in P Jackson and D Wilde (eds), The
Reform of Property Law (Ashgate Publishing, Dartmouth, 1997) 73–9 ; L Crabb, ‘Contracts and
Leases: Variation of Terms’ in R Buckley (ed) Legal Structures: Boundary Issues Between Legal
Categories (Chancery Wiley Law Publications, 1996); A Dowling, ‘Variation of Lease or New
Tenancy’ [1995] Conv 124.
4 See PJG Williams, ‘Regrant Revisited’ (2001) 110 EG 152.
230 Warren Barr
Formal Requirements
5 See, generally, Chapter 3 Chitty on Contracts (28th edn, Sweet & Maxwell, London, 1999).
Briefly stated, in order to furnish consideration, the promisee (the recipient of the promise) must
either confer a benefit on the promisor, or suffer a detriment for which the promisor’s promise com-
pensates him, which has ‘value in the eye of the law’—Thomas v Thomas (1842) 2 QB 851 at 859.
6 British Benningtons Ltd v N.W. Cachar Tea Co. [1923] AC 48.
7 Where the lease is parole, there would be consideration for the variation of the leasehold con-
tract, because in a bilateral contract each party gives up his rights against the other under the origi-
nal contract and ‘[t]he same consideration which existed for the old agreement is imported into the
new agreement, which is substituted for it’—Steel v Dauber (1839) 10 A & R 57 at 66.
8 See Berry v Berry [1929] 2 KB 316. It is also accepted that there will be no consideration for a
rescission where a contract has been wholly executed by one party, in the sense that he has per-
formed all his obligations thereunder, because he derives no benefit from his promise to the other
party, and the other suffers no detriment—Commissioner of Stamp Duties v Bone [1977] AC 511 at
519. Leases were traditionally viewed as wholly executory on the lessor’s part when the conveyance
of the legal estate had been completed; but modern cases and thinking suggest that the lessor’s oblig-
ations continue by virtue of any covenants he may have entered into in the lease—see, for example,
Quinn & Phillips, ‘The Law of Landlord—Tenant: A Critical Evaluation of the Past with Guidelines
for the Future’ (1969) 38 Fordham L Rev 225 at 234. Therefore, if contractual rules were imported
to leases, under a contractual analysis consideration would not be problematic.
New Terms or New Lease: Principles of Leasehold Variation 231
Earlier this century, the contractual approach to variation of terms was a strict
one which ignored the distinction between alterations which merely amend the
contractual bargain and those which result in its destruction. In Williams v
Moss Empires Ltd,9 Sankey J applied a purely logical approach and expressed
the view that ‘the result of varying the terms of an existing contract is to
produce, not the original contract with a variation, but a new and different
contract’.10
This view was soon to fall out of favour, and in British Benningtons Ltd v
N.W. Cachar Tea Co,11 Lord Sumner, while he accepted the validity of the rea-
soning of Sankey J ‘as a matter of formal logic’,12 preferred to approach the
issue of whether a variation of a contract led to its discharge and replacement in
terms of the intention test expressed by their Lordships in Morris v Barron &
Co.13
In the absence of an express indication of intention, their Lordships applied an
objective test. In the words of Lord Atkinson, an intention to rescind:
will be implied legitimately, where the parties have entered a new contract entirely or
to an extent going to the very root of the first and inconsistent with it.14
How does this test actually work in practice? How do the courts consider
whether a change is fundamental or not? What happens if the stated intentions
of the parties and the fundamental nature of the changes made to the existing
contract conflict? How easy is it to, say, add a party to a contract? It is suggested
that the answers to these questions are not at all straightforward, and reveal
some conceptual and practical weaknesses in the contractual test.
9
[1915] KB 242
10
Ibid at 247.
11
[1923] AC 48.
12
Ibid at 68. His Lordship explained Sankey J’s reasoning: ‘a varied contract is not the old con-
tract, and as you cannot have a new and varied contract and an old and unvaried contract regulat-
ing the same thing at the same time, the old contract, like other old things, must be disregarded’.
13
[1918] AC 1.
14
Ibid at 31; this particular statement approved in British Bennigtons Ltd v N.W. Cachar Tea Co,
above n 6, per Lord Sumner.
232 Warren Barr
The import of these dicta is clear. Where the amending agreement in fact reg-
ulates the essence of the bargain entered into between the two parties, there is a
rescission and substitution. This is far off saying that there must be rescission
and substitution in this situation. The answer must lie in the fact that the
dividing line has to be drawn somewhere, for the purposes of the certainty of the
parties.
After all, can it reasonably be maintained that if a contract for the sale of a
quantity of tea at a set price due on one delivery date becomes a contract for the
sale of a quantity of coffee at a higher price on a different delivery date, that the
parties are dealing under one and the same contract, simply because they
expressed it to be so? There must come a point, no matter what parties to a con-
tract may themselves be said to intend, when the fact of what they have agreed
undermines what they have said. Determining the parties’ intentions is a useful
evolution of a previously absolute rule; it would be a logical absurdity if it were
to be an absolute rule in itself. Yet, the possibility remains.
It was trite law that only parties who were privy to the contractual arrangement
could enforce it; a contract which was entered into for the benefit of a third
party did not entitle that party to sue or be sued on it. From May 2000, this
familiar picture has been altered by the Contracts (Rights Of Third Parties) Act
1999, which allows a third party to enforce a benefit conferred by a contract to
which he is not a party, and puts limits on the powers of contracting parties to
vary the nature of those benefits.19 The Act allows the third party to enforce
benefits without a contractual nexus, but it does not allow for the imposition of
contractual burdens.
It is well established that the substitution of one party for another can only
be occasioned by a novation. The whole nature of novation is rescission and
18 Ibid at 26.
19 For a succinct statement of the operation of the Act see Andrews, ‘Strangers to justice no
longer: the reversal of the privity rule under the Contracts (Rights of Third Parties) Act 1999’ [2001]
CLJ 353.
234 Warren Barr
Basis of rules
A new lease may only be granted if the original lease is surrendered; otherwise
the lessor will be in derogation of grant. Therefore, where a new lease is substi-
tuted for the old on the basis of a variation of the lease terms by the parties, it is
done so through a surrender by operation of law of the original lease, and a
regrant of the new lease. The basis of this deemed surrender lies in estoppel:
Thus where a lessee for years accepts a new lease for [sic] his lessor, he is estopped
from saying that his lessor had not the power to make the new lease; and, as the lessor
could not do this until the prior lease had been surrendered, the law says that the
acceptance of such new lease is of itself a surrender of the former.24
20 Rashburn v JCL Marine [1977] 1 Lloyd’s Rep. 645. This distinguishes novation from an assign-
that some of the statements contained herein are of importance in the field of contract law also.
22 Ibid at 4J.
23 [1944] AC 402 at 429.
24 Lyon v Reed (1844) 13 M & W 285 per Parke CB.
New Terms or New Lease: Principles of Leasehold Variation 235
In contrast to contract law which allows for rescission if the new contract is
void for want of formality, there can be no surrender of the existing lease by
operation of law if the new lease is ineffective, as it will not be inconsistent with
the existing lease to found the estoppel.25 This surrender is also said to take
place independently and even in spite of intention,26 since by its very nature
what the parties have intended to do by keeping the original lease on foot can
only be achieved by a deemed surrender.
In the leading case of Friends Provident Life Office v British Railways Board,27
an underlease had been varied by deed between an assignee and the then
landlord. The deed was expressed to be subject to the continuation of the orig-
inal lease and effected three main changes to the lease: a covenant restricting
alienation was widened to allow easier sub-letting or licensing of the demised
premises, the user clause was widened and the rent was increased from £12,000
per annum payable in quarterly arrears to £35,000 per annum payable in
advance. The present tenant went into liquidation owing almost £40,000 which
the landlord was now trying to recover from the original tenant. The original
tenant claimed that the alterations to the lease in the deed of variation were so
substantial as to bring about a surrender and regrant.
Bedlam LJ, delivering the leading judgment, reviewed existing authority and
concluded that:
In the absence of an increase in the extent of the premises demised or of the term for
which they are to be held, both of which would change the legal estate, I can see no
reason why the lessor and assignee could not achieve the changes they desired in the
terms of the lease without the law implying a surrender and a regrant for the remain-
der of the term of the lease.28
likely to be rare, as if the parties actually intend to surrender and regrant the lease, they will do so
expressly.
236 Warren Barr
This approach does seem unduly restrictive when set beside the apparent free-
dom afforded by the contractual test of intention, in which no particular varia-
tions of necessity produce a rescission and substitution of the original
agreement. It is suggested that the property test is explicable on sensible and
strong conceptual grounds. It accords with the reality that a lease is more than
a simple contract to occupy, like a contractual licence, because it also grants an
estate in land. The estate is the definitional element in the dual relationship of
the lease and governs it, whereas the contract is a subsidiary which works within
the discipline of the estate and whose existence is co-extensive with it, even
though on the surface it contains clauses which are sometimes thought to be
more important to the parties than the fact that they have been given an estate
in land. If this were not so, the distinction between a lease and a licence as dis-
tinct forms of occupying land would be rendered illusory.
On this analysis, the test gives enviable certainty and freedom to the parties
beyond the defining element of variations to the estate, and, contrary to first
impressions, is really no more restrictive than the general contractual approach.
The question must then be raised whether the position outlined is an accurate
statement of the law, which can best be discovered by considering the existing
cases on particular alterations of terms.
be that they cannot convert a rent of £X issuing out of land into a rent of £X and £Y
issuing out of the aggregate land.33
The reduction in the parcels had not been enough to bring about the surren-
der. His Lordship noted that a surrender and regrant could be avoided where
there was an addition to the parcels by means of a reversionary lease of the fresh
land at a separate rent. It is suggested that the hesitance of Russell LJ to commit
himself to saying that an increase in the premises must lead to a surrender and
regrant, preferring to say that it may, is due to the fact that the question of an
increase did not arise before him on the facts and should not be taken as indica-
tive of anything more.
Again, in Jones v Bridgman,34 the suggestion that a reduction in the parcels
demised did not require a surrender and regrant by operation of law receives
passive support. Here, the landlord had distrained for rent and the tenant
brought an action for trespass and conversion on the basis of unlawful distress.
He pleaded that an oral agreement, under which he had relinquished two
rooms in consideration of a reduction in rent, caused a surrender and regrant.
Denman J found that there was ample evidence upon which the jury had
concluded that there was a fresh letting of the remaining rooms. It is submitted
that the intention was to destroy the lease, which, as outlined, is the proper role
for intention in this area. Effect could be given to the intention because the law
did not require a surrender and regrant for a reduction in the parcels.35
Finally, in Holme v Brunskill,36 an agreement was entered into that the
tenant, inter alia, should surrender a field from his demised farm holding to the
landlord and the rent should be reduced. A surety of the tenant argued that this
surrender occasioned a surrender and regrant of the premises and his conse-
quent release from any liability. Cotton LJ dismissed this plea because ‘notwith-
standing the surrender to a landlord of part of the land demised, the former
tenancy of the remainder of the farm still continues’.37
Why should the surrender of a part of the demised parcels not bring about the
destruction and recreation of a lease when a subsequent of further parcels will
do so? How can this be explained with regard to alterations of the estate? It is
submitted that the key to understanding lies in the realisation that the estate is
an interest limited in time subject to a right of reservation in the landlord. In cre-
ating an estate in the tenant, the landlord gives him exclusive possession of the
demised premises for a limited time in a unitary block, and reserves to himself a
right to rent as compensation and a right to have the parcels demised returned
33 Ibid at 419h.
34
(1878) 39 LT 500.
35
PJG Williams (above n 31) asserts that, in considering a reduction of the term ‘the intentions
of the parties are irrelevant’. If this was meant otherwise than in the sense that intention is irrelevant
where a deemed surrender and regrant is considered necessary, then, with respect, this is not an
accurate statement of the law.
36
(1878) 3 QBD 495.
37
Ibid at 504.
238 Warren Barr
to him when the lease comes to an end. Indeed, it is the existence of the
reversion which separates leasehold ownership from ownership of the freehold
(fee simple absolute). Accordingly, since it is inherent in the nature of the legal
relationship that what has been granted will be returned, the surrender of part
of the parcels demised does not alter what is granted, since the landlord retains
a reversionary interest in the rest of the demised premises and an estate remains
vested in the tenant. One part of the parcels has simply come back to the land-
lord at an earlier date than expected. In contrast, where the landlord demises
additional parcels, unless he does so by means of a separate lease which will
create a separate estate and reversion over those parcels, the estate of the tenant
is actually altered.
It is worth noting that the common law position does not apply to all leases.
A fixed term farm business tenancy, as regulated by the Agricultural Tenancies
Act 1995, allows for variation of the land comprised in the tenancy without a
new tenancy being created, provided that the alterations are ‘small in relation to
the size of the holding and do not affect the character of the holding’.38 This can
be either through subtraction or addition to the demised parcels, and therefore
applies irrespective of whether the estate is changed. This does not provide any
intellectual quandary, as an addition would still technically be classed as an
alteration to the estate; statute has simply modified the effect of the common
law position.
38 Agricultural Tenancies Act 1995, s 3. This obviates the need for the parties to serve fresh
notices as required under s 1(4) of the Act to preserve the advantages of allowing diversification out
of farming activities, which would otherwise be necessary if the existing lease had been surrendered
and a new tenancy re-granted. For a succinct account of the operation of the Act, see P Smith (ed),
Evans & Smith The Law of Landlord and Tenant (5th edn, Butterworths, London, 1995) ch 33.
39 Above n.32. His Lordship also relied on dicta in Barker v Merckel [1960] 1 QB 657.
40 Ibid at 419g–j.
New Terms or New Lease: Principles of Leasehold Variation 239
The key element is that the estate has been altered. A reduction in the term
would not have the effect of altering the estate demised, since it is inherent in the
nature of the estate as an interest limited in time that it will come to an end and
the concept of the estate is wide enough to encompass both the maximum fixed
term and any other. Hence, if the landlord agrees, the tenant can give back what
was granted at any time by means of an express surrender. The shortening of the
term is therefore only doing what it is expected at the time of the original grant
and would not have to take place by a surrender and regrant.
One case stands in opposition to this line of reasoning and authority, which
is Fenner v Blake.41 Here, a yearly tenant holding from Lady Day agreed with
his landlord to quit earlier. It was held that the agreement did result in a
surrender of the yearly tenancy because
the defendant accepted a new tenancy for six months terminable in June in lieu of the
existing tenancy. And if so, then all the authorities agree that the acceptance of a new
tenancy works a surrender of the old by operation of law.42
It is submitted that here the new tenancy was based on an intention to bring
about a new lease, not on any requirement that any reduction in the term must
bring about this result. The spectral authorities on which the court relied can
also be explained as evidence of intention. This line of reasoning also explains
Ive’s Case,43 where a reduction actually took the form of a new lease, so that a
surrender and regrant was necessary.44 The position is clear, not ‘unresolved’.45
(c) Rent
On a strict proprietary analysis,46 rent is an incident of the estate, not the estate
itself and may be varied either upwards or downwards without actually affect-
ing the nature of the estate at all. The authorities support this view.
In Lord Inchquin v Lyons,47 for example, it was held that there was no
authority that an increase in rent would of itself operate to terminate a tenancy,
such an alteration was on a similar footing to an alteration of obligation to pay
local rates. Russell LJ in Kerman also said:
it is difficult to see why the fiction of a new lease and a surrender by operation of
law should be necessary in this case, for by simply increasing the amount of rent, and
41 [1900] 1 QB 426.
42 Ibid per Channell J at 428.
43 (1597) 5 Co Rep 11a.
44 Ibid ‘—[B]y acceptance of a future lease to begin divers years after, the said lease of the wood
for 62 years was presently surrendered, because the lessee by acceptance thereof had affirmed the
lessor to have ability to make the new lease, which he had not, if the first lease shall stand’.
45 See PJG Williams, ‘Regrant Revisited’ (2001) EG 152.
46 It is considered trite law that rent is now considered as a purely contractual payment, although
the practice of reserving rent in the reddendum of a lease continues to this day. It is also well estab-
lished that the absence of rent is not fatal to a finding of a lease rather than licence, though the
absence may require explanation—Ashburn Anstalt v Arnold [1988] 2 All ER 147.
47 (1887) 20 LR Ir 474.
240 Warren Barr
providing that the additional rent shall be annexed to the reversion, one is not alter-
ing the nature of a pre-existing item of property.48
This line of reasoning was also evident in the more recent case of Trustees of
JW Childers Will Trust v Anker,49 where the combination of two rents over two
adjacent agricultural holdings into a single rental payment for the purpose of
rent review did not effect a surrender and regrant, as the estate granted was not
affected. The parties had not sought to create a single lease at an aggregate rent.
It should be noted that a variation of the rental obligation may result in the
creation of a new tenancy under statutory codes of protection, even though it
does not operate a surrender and regrant at common law. Under the Housing
Act 1988, section 36, a variation of the rental obligation is statutorily deemed to
create a new contract.50 The chief import is to change the protected status of the
agreement from a restricted contract under the Rent Act 1977 and bring it
within the assured tenancy scheme of the new legislation.51 While practically
significant, this statutory alteration of the common law is really part of a series
of transitional provisions to phase out Rent Act protection, and should not be
interpreted in any wider context. Indeed, the exception is limited to variations
of rent, as the Housing Act 1988, section 36(2)(b) also provides that any change
in the terms of the contract other than rent may trigger a loss of restricted
contract status, but only if the variation is such as to give rise to a new contract.
In other words, a new contract of tenancy will arise where there is either an
addition to the term or the parcels demised, preserving the common law
approach.
(d) Parties
The position under consideration here is where the parties vary the terms of the
lease so as to either substitute or add parties to the tenancy.
In general terms, where there is a substitution of a new tenant for the original
tenant, this will normally take the form of a new lease to the new tenant. This
can only occur with the consent of the original tenant and his relinquishing of
possession, in which case the original lease will be surrendered by operation of
law.52
Substitution of the parties is, of course, also possible through an assignment
of the term by the party wishing to be substituted, which may have influenced
48
Above n 32.
49
[1996] 1 EGLR 1.
50
Any alteration in the rent as a result of a rent tribunal determination, or through an agreement
between the parties to make the rent payable the same as the registered rent is not to be treated as a
‘variation’ for the purposes of this section—Housing Act 1988, s 36(3). Such an alteration will not,
therefore, necessitate a surrender and regrant of the existing tenancy.
51
See further Rowe v Matthews (2001) 33 HLR 81, which illustrates that s 36(2) also has the
effect of treating the new contract as ‘entered into’ for the purposes of the Housing Act 1988, s 34(1),
so that the new contract is prevented from conferring any other type of protective status previously
afforded by the Rent Acts.
52
Wallis v Hands [1893] 2 Ch 75.
New Terms or New Lease: Principles of Leasehold Variation 241
the thinking in Collins v Claughton. However, in many leases, the right to assign
the remainder of the term is restricted, either by express covenant or statutory
implication, so that assignment is not possible without the consent of the land-
lord.53 If the landlord is unwilling to consent, in practice this method is not open
to the tenant.54
Where the parties decide to vary the lease to substitute a party by consensual
agreement, it is unclear whether this necessitates a surrender and regrant by
operation of law. In Collins v Claughton,55 for example, the landlord and ten-
ant agreed that the wife would in future be responsible for the rent and the rent
book would be put in her name. It was held that there was a new lease and there-
fore a surrender by operation of law, though whether through intention or
necessity is not clear from the reasoning.
In relation to the addition of a party, it is clear that this need not cause a
surrender and regrant by necessity. Given this, it would be anomalous if the
position were different for the substitution of a party. In Saunders (Francis
Perceval) Dec’d v Ralph,56 some years after taking a lease of an agricultural
holding, the landlords, the original tenant and the original tenant’s son agreed
by memorandum that henceforward the original tenant and his son should be
viewed as joint tenants of the agricultural holding. Both joint tenants had died,
and had been succeeded by the claimant. It became necessary for the purposes
of succession under Part IV of the Agricultural Holdings Act 1986 to know
whether the claimant held under a first successor tenancy or a second successor
tenancy, as, if it were the latter, there could be no further succession within the
Act. It was contended that variation of the terms in creating a joint tenancy had
led to a surrender and regrant of the lease. Jowitt J said that to hold that the
addition necessitated a surrender and regrant ‘smacked of artificiality rather
than principle’ and he held that in accordance with the intention of the parties,
the memorandum took effect by way of a simple variation of the lease, and that
the tenancy was therefore a first successor tenancy.
This position accords with an estate based approach. While it is true that the
estate is vested in the tenant for the term, it is suggested that it can also survive
53 For an exhaustive list of statutorily impied covenants restricting assignment, see Woodfall’s
Law of Landlord and Tenant (2002, Sweet & Maxwell) 11.115. Express covenants restricting assign-
ment come in two main forms, absolute and fully qualified. In the former, the tenant covenants not
to assign the term, in the latter, not to assign the term without the consent of the landlord, such con-
sent not to be unreasonably withheld. In theory, qualified restrictive covenants (not to assign with-
out the consent of the landlord) are possible in leases, but s 19(1)(a) Landlord and Tenant Act 1927
intervenes in most leases and transforms a qualified covenant into a fully qualified covenant.
See further L Crabb, Leases: Covenants and Consents, (Sweet & Maxwell, London, 1991) ch 2
passim.
54 In theory, the tenant retains the power to validly assign the lease, but the assignment will be in
breach of covenant, which means that it may trigger forfeiture proceedings by the landlord—see Old
Grovesbury Farm Ltd v Seymour Plant Hire (No 2) Ltd [1979] 1 W.L.R. 1397. For further details of
forfeiture generally, see M Pawlowski, The Forfeiture Of Leases (Sweet & Maxwell, 1993).
55 [1959] 1 WLR 145 CA.
56
(1993) 28 EG 127.
242 Warren Barr
Under both property law and contract law, there is no longer any support for
the view that any variation of the existing agreement will always result in the
destruction of that agreement and its replacement by another. Beyond that there
are important differences:
(i) Under the current property system, any variation of the estate in the sense
of an addition to the parcels or an extension of the term will result of necessity
in the end of the old lease and the creation of a new lease between landlord and
tenant. Under contract law, there are no specific terms which when altered must
result in rescission and substitution. Instead, when considering the intention
57 On an assignment, the original tenant ceases to have privity of estate with the landlord which
Letitia Crabb, writing before the decision was delivered in Friends Provident,
argued that the necessity of deemed surrender on alterations to the estate was
unduly restrictive and unprincipled, and that contract provided a more agree-
able solution:
Why cannot a lessor and a lessee agree that a lease for seven years be deemed to have
been granted for eleven? Can it not be topped up while remaining vested in the tenant?
Why does the fact that a change is fundamental preclude the parties from making it?
In the absence of an answer to these questions, it would seem to be appropriate to sug-
gest that the law of landlord and tenant—takes a long draught at the fountain of
Morris v Barron.60
The suggested analysis of property law, under the outlined principle of estate
supremacy in the leasehold relationship, answers Crabb’s criticisms. The estate
is the definitional element of the lease which separates it from the contractual
licence or from ownership in fee simple absolute. Variation of the estate is not a
question of fundamentality, it is the fact that in changing the very nature of the
legal relationship of tenancy what results can not on any reasonable basis be
60 ‘Contracts and Leases: Variation of Terms’ in R Buckley (ed), Legal Structures: Boundary
Issues Between Legal Categories (Chancery Wiley Law Publications, 1996) at 170.
244 Warren Barr
said to be the same as what was there before, and a new leasehold tenancy is
needed to represent this alteration. Alteration of all other terms is possible,
because they do not alter the nature of what has been granted, only the way in
which that legal relationship operates. Similarly, this answers Susan Bright’s
concern that:
If the law is to encompass the notion that certain leasehold variations will cause a
deemed surrender this must rest on a more satisfactory intellectual foundation.61
There is much force in this argument, especially as the parties themselves will
doubtless be surprised to find that adding to either the premises or the length of
term, simply because it alters the estate, results in law in the surrender and
regrant of the existing tenancy. This will almost certainly not be what the par-
ties intended, and minor changes such as the tacking on of additional storage
space, or the lengthening of the duration of the lease are something which
happen often in practice.
The regrant of a new tenancy also has very real practical consequences for
both the lessor and the lessee.64 The lessor might, on assignment of the new
lease, lose the benefit of original tenant liability throughout the term of the lease,
due to the regrant qualifying as a new tenancy under the Landlord and Tenant
61
‘Variation of Leases and Tenant Liability’ in P Jackson and D Wilde (eds), The Reform of
Property Law (Dartmouth, Ashgate Publishing, 1997) at 79. In her analysis, Bright suggested that
the basis of deemed surrender lay in impossibility, in the sense that the agreed variation could not
take effect unless the earlier lease is deemed to be surrendered and a new lease granted. The postu-
lated estate-based approach provides a more compelling justification.
62
Hence, repudiatory breach and the doctrine of frustration are said to be available to terminate
leases, on the basis that: “[h]owever much weight one may give to the fact that the lease creates an
estate in land. . . In many cases [the lessee] is interested only in the accompanying contractual right
to use that which is demised to him—and the estate in land which he acquires has little or no mean-
ing for him’— National Carriers Ltd v Panalpina [1981] 2 AC 45 at 76C per Lord Roskill. For a brief
but balanced discussion of this so-called ‘contractualisation’ of leasehold law, see Bright & Gilbert,
The Nature of Tenancies (Clarendon Press, Oxford, 1995) ch 3.
63
Above n 61 at 86.
64 See PJG Williams, ‘Accidents will happen’ (2001) 111 EG 168.
New Terms or New Lease: Principles of Leasehold Variation 245
(Covenants) Act 1995.65 Similarly, where the original lease is a business tenancy
which has been successfully contracted out of the Landlord and Tenant Act
1954, Part II, the new lease would not be so protected, and the lessee would
acquire security of tenure.66 The lessee would be liable to pay stamp duty on the
deed of variation, as it will have to be stamped as if it were a new lease, and, if
the new lease falls within the category of interests which require substantive reg-
istration, an application will need to be made to register it, even if the existing
lease was already registered.67
It is possible to increase either the length of the term or the extent of the
premises by the grant of an additional lease, without having to vary the original
estate at all. Tacking on a reversionary lease, for example, to take effect at the
end of the current term is a well recognised method of adding time to an exist-
ing lease. Nevertheless, these methods are open to the same problems, in that
they will be ‘new’ leases with any attendant statutory consequences, and stamp
duty will be payable on them.68
Benefits of Contract?
from continuing liability once the estate passes to the assignee, and the landlord does not have an
automatic entitlement under a regranted lease to require the assignor to enter into an Authorised
Guarantee Agreement—Landlord and Tenant (Covenants) Act 1995, ss 3, 5 and 16.
66 Above n 64. Landlord and Tenant Act 1954, s 38(1).
67 Above n 64.
68 Note, however, that the problems associated with the Landlord and Tenant Act 1954 could be
overcome by expressly contracting out this new lease. The position in relation to continuing tenant
liability can not be answered in this way, but is there really a good reason to allow a lessor to avoid
the will of Parliament by extending his old lease ad infinitum to escape alterations in the law for the
benefit of the lessee? Indeed, Parliament has not always been silent on the issue of continuing
protection where it is considered warranted—see, for example, the Agricultural Tenancies Act 1995,
s 4(1)(f) which provides that where a tenancy of an agricultural holding to which the Agricultural
Holdings Act 1986 applied is varied, any new tenancy created will be granted subject to the 1986 Act,
unless the parties expressly agree in the instrument of variation to create a farm business tenancy
under the 1995 Act.
246 Warren Barr
which the tenant is to enjoy the premises is merely one of the provisions of the
contract which can be varied like any other’.69
There are, however, problems with the operation of the contractual test, as
already illustrated, and it should not be viewed as a panacea for the ills of the
current situation. The loss of predictability, which the property law approach
allows, would be lamentable. Moreover, the delineation between the lease and
licence as separate forms of property holding would, in a very real sense, be lost.
Is it really objectionable to suggest that a change to the fundamental legal basis
of a relationship must result in the destruction of the old, and replacement by a
new agreement? Is this not an entirely sensible place in which to draw the divid-
ing line, rather than depend upon the vagaries of each individual change and the
court’s interpretation of the parties’ intentions in making those changes?
Bright suggests that the weakness of the property law approach lies in the inabil-
ity to assess the extent of the alteration to the leasehold bargain as a whole,
incorporating both the contractual and proprietary elements of the relationship.
Rather than resort to the vagaries of the contractual test, she argues that what
is needed is the introduction of a test of fundamentality:
Changes to executory obligations within a lease will be capable of causing a deemed
surrender, but only where the changes are extensive and fundamentally change the
nature of the landlord and tenant relationship. . . . If these changes can be sufficient
to end a lease by frustration or by repudiatory breach, surely it must follow that
some variations to the bargain may be sufficiently fundamental to cause a deemed
surrender.70
Conclusion
INTRODUCTION
consent to medical examination and treatment, including contraceptive treatment, if she had
sufficient maturity and intelligence to understand the nature and implications of the treatment.
3 See, eg, s 1(3)(a) of the 1989 Act which requires the court in certain circumstances to have regard
to “the ascertainable wishes and feelings of the child concerned considered in the light of his age and
understanding”.
4 The age of majority in England is 18: s 1 Family Law Reform Act 1969.
5 In Hypo-Mortgage Services Ltd v Robinson [1997] 2 FCR 422 (CA) it was held that two minors
with beneficial interests in the family home could not have an overriding interest under s 70(1)(g) of
the Land Registration Act 1925. The children were regarded as having ‘no right of occupation of
their own’ but were there because their parent was there, as ‘shadows of occupation of their parent’.
Secondly, no enquiry could be made of minor children or consent obtained from them in the man-
ner contemplated by s 70(1)(g), especially when they were of ‘tender years’ at the material date. See
too K Gray and S Gray, Elements of Land Law (London, Butterworths, 2000) 1030, 1032, n 3. For a
criticism of the decision in Hypo-Mortgage Services Ltd v Robinson, see PH Kenny, ‘Children are
spare ribs’ (1997) 61 Conveyancer 84–5.
6 Among men born between 1940 and 1954, 73% had left home by age 25. Among those born
between 1965 and 1969, only 61% had left home by the age of 25: Department of the Environment,
Transport and the Regions, Housing Research Summary, Housing in England 1995/96 (No 69)
(DETR, London: 1997). This growth in the incidence of ‘extended transitions’ is attributable to a
250 Jill Morgan
number of factors including an increase in the number of young people entering further and higher
education, the decline of the private rented sector, and the withdrawal of welfare benefits from
young people.
7
‘Many parents of homeless young people have multiple problems including physical and some-
times sexual abuse of their children, alcohol and drug problems, mental health problems, poor par-
enting, new partners and step-parents leading to disputes with children, and poverty’, Department
for Transport, Local Government and the Regions, Homeless Strategies: A Good Practice
Handbook (DTLR, London, 2002), para 6.33. See too G Jones, Leaving Home (Open University
Press, Buckingham, 1995).
8
S Hutson and M Liddiard, Youth Homelessness: The Construction of a Social Issue
(MacMillan, Basingstoke, 1994); S Fitzpatrick and D Clapham, ‘Homelessness and Young People’in
S Hutson and D Clapham (eds), Homelessness: Public Policies and Private Troubles (Cassell,
London, 1999).
9
D Quilgars and I Anderson, ‘Addressing the problem of youth homelessness and unemploy-
ment’ in R Burrows, N Pleace, and D Quilgars (eds), Homelessness and Social Policy (Routledge,
London, 1997).
10
J Rugg, Opening Doors: Helping People on Low Income Secure Private Rented
Accommodation (Centre for Housing Policy, York, 1996); Closing Doors? Access Schemes and the
Recent Housing Changes (Centre for Housing Policy, York, 1997).
11
G Randall and S Brown, The Rough Sleepers’ Initiative: An Evaluation, (HMSO, London,
1993).
12
D Cowan and J Fionda, ‘Back to Basics: The Government’s Homelessness Consultation Paper’
(1994) 57 MLR 610.
13
See, eg, ‘Curfew won’t stop teenagers’ rule of terror’, Evening Standard, 5 February 2002; ‘Last
man standing’, Daily Mail, 11 December 2001, p 32.
14
(1999) 31 HLR 794.
The Child as Tenant: Rights and Responsibilities 251
authority housing. First, local authorities are still responsible for the lion’s share
of social housing. Secondly, access to local authority housing has been (and, to
some extent, still is) largely regulated by statute. By contrast, registered social
landlords (RSLs)15 are left very much to their own devices in allocating their
housing, although the majority of their new tenants are taken from waiting lists
maintained by local authorities.
The social rented sector comprises the housing stock owned and managed by
local authorities (and certain other public bodies), and that of registered social
landlords and other housing associations. Together, their housing accounts for
about 20 per cent of all housing in England.16
As far as ‘independent’ minor children are concerned, there are three
principal access routes17 into social housing: the Children Act 1989, as amended
by the Children (Leaving Care) Act 2000, Part VI of the Housing Act 1996 (the
housing register), and Part VII of the Housing Act 1996, as amended by the
Homelessness Act 2002 (the homelessness legislation).
Section 20(1), Children Act 1989 requires social services authorities to provide
accommodation for ‘children in need’ within their areas who appear to require
accommodation because no-one has parental responsibility for them, or they are
lost or have been abandoned, or whoever has been caring from them (whether or
not permanently and for whatever reason) is prevented from providing suitable
accommodation and care. Subsection (3) obliges them to house children over the
age of 16 whose welfare will otherwise be ‘seriously prejudiced’.18 Under section
15
RSLs are housing associations registered with the Housing Corporation. Approximately 2,200
of the 4,000 or so housing associations in Great Britain are registered with the Housing Corporation
as RSLs.
16
DTLR Housing Statistics Postcard January 2002.
17
By s 91, Housing Act 1985 property (including a tenancy owned by one parent or spouse) can
also be transferred by order of the court directly to a minor child without loss of any security if it is
assigned in accordance with an order made under s 24 of the Matrimonial Causes Act 1973, s 17 of
the Matrimonial Proceedings and Property Act 1984, or Sch 1, para1 to the Children Act 1989.
18
In addition, s 17(1) of the 1989 Act imposes a general duty on every local authority (a) to safe-
guard and promote the welfare of children within their area who are in need; and (b) so far as is con-
sistent with that duty, to promote the upbringing of such children by their families, by providing a
range and level of services appropriate to those children’s needs. By s 17(10) ‘a child shall be taken
to be in need if—(a) he is unlikely to achieve or maintain, or to have the opportunity of achieving or
maintaining, a reasonable standard of health or development without the provision for him of ser-
vices by a local authority under this Part; (b) his health or development is likely to be significantly
impaired, or further impaired, without the provision for him of such services; or (c) he is disabled’.
The definition may, therefore, include an unaccompanied asylum-seeking child. See http://www.
doh.gov.uk/pub/docs/doh/lac20002.pdf.
252 Jill Morgan
27 of the 1989 Act, a local social services authority can request a local housing
authority to help in delivering services for children in need, and the housing
authority must comply with such a request to the extent that it is compatible with
its own statutory duties and other obligations, and does not unduly prejudice the
discharge of any of its own functions. 19
The Children (Leaving Care) Act 2000 (which came into force on 1 October
2001) amends the Children Act 1989 by, inter alia, requiring that 16 and 17-year
old care leavers are provided with, or maintained in, suitable accommodation
unless social services are satisfied that their welfare does not require it.20 The
authority responsible for meeting the duties under the 2000 Act is the one which
last looked after the child. This applies regardless of where the child may now
be living in England and Wales. If a relevant or eligible child presents him or her-
self in the area of another local authority, the second authority should provide
short-term assistance under section 17 Children Act 1989.21 The two authorities
should then agree on how the young person should continue to be assisted,
although the responsibility remains with the last local authority which looked
after the young person. Local authorities are likely to make use of a range of
options, such as supported lodgings, foyers, hostels, and specialist accommoda-
tion for young people with particular support needs22 (in which cases licences
are likely to be granted) as well as self-contained accommodation (in respect of
which a tenancy may well exist).
Housing register
Until Part VI, Housing Act 1996 came into force, local housing authorities had
no duty to operate housing registers (more commonly known as ‘waiting lists’).
However, those authorities which retained a stock of housing invariably did
keep such registers on which general applicants for council housing could regis-
ter, and from which the authorities made their allocations in accordance with
their individual selection schemes. Research carried out soon before the 1996
Act was implemented revealed that only half of authorities in England and
Wales allowed 16-year-olds to register on their housing registers, and nearly a
third denied access to households with children where the parent was less than
18 years old.23 Additional restrictions were placed upon young people as regards
the allocation of properties. In some areas, while young people could join the
waiting list at 16 or 17, they did not normally become eligible for a tenancy until
19
Section 27 cannot be used to obtain permanent accommodation for an applicant and his or her
children when a housing authority has already determined that the applicant was intentionally
homeless: R v Northavon DC, ex p Smith (1994) 26 HLR 659.
20
Section 23B(8)(b), Children Act 1989.
21
Above n 18.
22
T Benjamin, ‘Housing rights of 16- and 17-year olds’ (2002) 183 Childright 18–20.
23
I Anderson, ‘Young single people and access to housing’ in J Rugg (ed), Young People,
Housing and Social Policy (Routledge, London, 1999) 39.
The Child as Tenant: Rights and Responsibilities 253
they reached 18. Single people and couples were eligible for re-housing at 16
in only one third of authorities. Sixteen and 17-year-olds with children were
eligible for re-housing in just over two fifths of authorities. Where local author-
ities did allocate tenancies to applicants under 18, over three fifths said they
would require a guarantor for rent or other tenancy matters, reflecting their
legal status as minors.24
In its 1995 White Paper the Government expressed its commitment to main-
taining a safety net (in the form of the homelessness legislation) ‘for families and
vulnerable people’ but asserted that this should be separate from a fair system
of allocating long-term accommodation in a house or flat owned by a local
authority or housing association. Achieving that separation would be by
reforming the homelessness legislation and the introduction of new arrange-
ments for the allocation of social housing. It stated that allocation schemes
should reflect ‘the underlying values of our society’, balancing ‘specific housing
needs’ against ‘the need to support married couples who take a responsible
approach to family life, so that tomorrow’s generation grows up in a stable
home environment’.25 The emphasis was clearly placed upon families, with no
acknowledgement that ‘vulnerable people’ might include young people who
could not turn to a family to provide them with housing.
The Housing Act 1996 obliged each local authority to maintain a housing reg-
ister of qualifying persons with details of the members of the person’s household
and the circumstances in which s/he lived.26 The Allocation of Housing
Regulations 199627 prescribed who must be allowed on the list and this included
those over the age of 18 who were homeless or threatened with homelessness
and not intentionally so. Apart from the Regulations authorities were free to
decide their own criteria for qualification although the Department of
Employment’s Code of Guidance28 (which supports the legislation on home-
lessness and allocations) suggested that authorities might wish to consider
including vulnerable young persons within a class of qualifying persons, for
example, where there was a referral by a social services authority, or where an
adult was prepared to act as a guarantor.29 The Homelessness Act 2002 (which
received the Royal Assent on 26 February 2002) abolishes the duty of local
authorities to maintain a housing register, thereby paving the way for the
development of ‘choice-based letting systems’. However, in those areas where
24 Ibid, 40. See too S Butler, Access Denied (London, Shelter, 1998) 20.
25 Department of the Environment, Our Future Homes: Opportunity, Choice, Responsibility,
Cmnd 2901, (HMSO, London, 1995), 36.
26 Section 161, Housing Act 1996.
27 SI 1996/2753
28 DoE, Code of Guidance on Allocation of Housing and Homelessness (DETR, London, 1996).
Authorities must ‘have regard’ to the Code of Guidance (s 182(1), Housing Act 1996) but need not
follow it slavishly: De Falco v Crawley [1980] QB 460.
29 Ibid para 3.16. The Code also states that where accommodation is allocated to a minor (ie a
person under 18 years of age), authorities should ensure that there is proper support from social ser-
vices or voluntary organisations to sustain the tenancy.
254 Jill Morgan
Homelessness
30 This provision was inserted by s 9 of the Housing (Scotland) Act 2001. The 2001 Act received
royal assent in July 2001 and will be brought into effect progressively.
31 R v Oldham MBC, ex p Garlick; R v Bexley LBC, ex p Bentum; R v Tower Hamlets LBC,
ex p Begum (Ferdous) [1993] 2 WLR 609 (HL). For a critical analysis see I Loveland, ‘The status of
children as applicants under the homelessness legislation—judicial subversion or legislative intent?’
(1996) 8 CFLQ 89–104. It is also worth noting the apparently insuperable hurdle for any applicant
seeking recourse to the ECHR in this regard, insofar as Article 8 establishes no right to a home:
X v FRG (1956) 1 YB 202.
32 Above n 23 at 15.
33 Young people who have children or are pregnant, therefore, are in priority need.
The Child as Tenant: Rights and Responsibilities 255
been the case for young people despite their much higher probability of experi-
encing homelessness. The test of vulnerability is whether the applicant is, when
homeless, less able to fend for him- or herself, so that injury or detriment will
result when a less vulnerable person would be able to cope without harmful
effects.34 Thus in Kelly v Monklands DC35 a homeless girl of 16 with no assets
or income who had left home because of violence was held to be vulnerable
because of some ‘other special reason’. Research by Shelter, however, has
revealed that the quality of service provided to young homeless applicants has
varied greatly, and that that ‘they are often turned away without being properly
interviewed or are not considered to be vulnerable’.36 An important recent
development, therefore, is the extension of the priority need categories to
include 16- and 17-year-olds by the Homelessness (Priority Need for
Accommodation) (England) Order 2001.37 This effectively removes the discre-
tion which local authorities have to decide whether a homeless 16- or 17-year-
old is vulnerable and therefore in priority need.
In Scotland, the Homelessness Task Force has expressed the view that, over
time, the rights possessed by those assessed as being in priority need under the
Housing (Scotland) Act 1987 should gradually be extended to all those assessed
as homeless. The target should be to eliminate the priority need distinction
within a decade (ie by 2012).38 This radical proposal accords with the aims of
those who originally framed the homelessness legislation as a rights-based mea-
sure which would assist all homeless people.39 It can be argued, however, that
the extension of priority need to homeless 16- and 17-year-olds has recognised
the needs (and legitimated the rights) of independent children as regards hous-
ing, and that such recognition could be lost with the elimination of the priority
need groups.
Until the decision of the Court of Appeal in Prince, it was generally accepted
that children could not be tenants because of their inability to hold a legal estate
in land.40 The issue in Prince was whether, on the death of a secure tenant, his
34
R v Camden LBC, ex p Pereira (1999) 31 HLR 317 (CA)).
35
(1986) SLT 165.
36
Above n 22.
37
The National Assembly for Wales extended the priority need groups by the Homeless Persons
(Priority Need) (Wales) Order 2001 (SI No.607(W.30)) which came into effect on 1 March 2001.
38
Scottish Executive, Homelessness: An Action Plan for Prevention and Effective Response.
Report from the Homelessness Task Force to Scottish Ministers (Scottish Executive, Edinburgh,
2002).
39
The transformation of the Housing (Homeless Persons) bill in its passage through Parliament
in 1977 into ‘a series of obstacles to be negotiated before the right to housing could be claimed’ is
well-documented by P Robson and M Poustie, Homeless People and the Law (Butterworths,
London, 1996).
40
N Goss, ‘Can children be tenants of their own homes?’ (1996) May Childright 5.
256 Jill Morgan
13-year-old grand-daughter (who had been living with him for three years and
thereby satisfied the 12 month residence requirement of section 87 of the
Housing Act 1985) was ‘a person qualified to succeed the tenant’ so that ‘the
tenancy’ vested in her.41 Counsel for the local authority argued that the 1985 Act
did not allow for the separation of the legal and equitable interests: by ‘tenancy’,
it referred only to the legal estate and excluded an equitable tenancy, and by
‘person’, it referred to an adult person and excluded a minor. The argument ran
that because the minor lacks the capacity to hold the legal estate, he or she can-
not be ‘the tenant’ and cannot, therefore, fulfil the tenant condition in section 81
(ie that ‘the tenant’ is an individual and occupies the dwelling-house as his or her
only or principal home). Hale J disagreed. She had no doubt that a minor is
quite capable of becoming a tenant (albeit only in equity) of any property,
including a council house, and that ‘housing legislation may include an equi-
table tenancy without catering for it expressly’.42 She pointed out that a would-
be lessor is perfectly free to grant an equitable tenancy to a minor. It followed,
therefore, that a minor could succeed to the actual tenancy held by a deceased
secure tenant. The deceased’s estate would continue to hold the legal estate on
trust for the minor until he or she reached the age of 18 when a conveyance of
the legal estate could be called for.
The decision produced a practical solution to an unusual set of circumstances
and has moved forward the debate on childrens’ rights. However, it raises a
number of conceptual issues which will now be addressed.
First, what happens to the legal estate when the equitable tenancy vests in a
minor? Until the enactment of the Law of Property Act 1925 a minor was capa-
ble of holding both legal estates and equitable interests in land although the
minor’s powers to deal with his or her property—by way of its alienation or let-
ting, for example—were subject to a number of limitations. Now however, as
already indicated, section 1(6) of the Law of Property Act 1925 provides that a
minor is not competent to hold a legal estate in land. Before 1997 a conveyance
of a legal estate to a minor operated only as an agreement for valuable consid-
eration to execute a settlement in favour of the minor.43 In the meantime, the
grantor held the legal estate on trust for the minor. It would pass when the
minor attained majority (although he or she could then disclaim the interest).
The situation is now governed by the Trusts of Land and Appointment of
Trustees Act 1996 (TOLATA), the effect of which is that an existing or future
conveyance of a legal estate to a minor will operate to create a trust of land. The
legal estate remains with the grantor, unless one of the grantees is over 18 (in
which case, that person takes as trustee) or another adult, such as a parent or
41
Section 89(2), Housing Act 1985.
42
R v Tower Hamlets LBC ex p Von Goetz [1999] QB 1019 in which it was held that a ten-year
assured shorthold tenancy made in writing but not by deed was a valid equitable lease. The tenant
had, therefore, an ‘owner’s interest’ for the purposes of s104 Local Government and Housing Act
1989, and was entitled to apply for a renovation grant.
43
Section 27(1), Settled Land Act 1925.
The Child as Tenant: Rights and Responsibilities 257
social worker, accepts the role of trustee. Pre-existing trusts subject to section 27
of the Settled Land Act 1925 have also become trusts of land. Thus, the grant of
a legal tenancy to a minor operates as a contract by the landlord/grantor of the
tenancy to hold the legal estate in trust for the minor.
Instead of granting a legal tenancy, a social landlord may simply grant an
equitable tenancy to the minor. The usual situation in which an equitable ten-
ancy comes into existence is where there is an agreement for the creation of a
legal lease but the requisite formalities have not been complied with.44 Provided
that there is a specifically enforceable contract, the doctrine of Walsh v
Lonsdale45 results in the immediate acquisition by the prospective tenant of an
equitable interest in the land, consisting of an equitable right to call for a future
grant of a legal estate.46 This suggests that an equitable tenancy may exist inde-
pendently of a legal estate, and that the grant of an equitable tenancy to a minor
need not involve a legal estate which must be vested in an adult (or retained by
the grantor). Nonetheless, social landlords will generally wish to see a responsi-
ble adult placed in the position of trustee of the legal estate, thus bringing
TOLATA into play.
In Prince, the original tenant had been granted a legal tenancy. On the suc-
cession by his grand-daughter to the equitable tenancy, the legal estate was left
in limbo. The Court of Appeal held (without giving reasons) that the grand-
daughter’s mother could succeed to the legal tenancy even though she did not
qualify to succeed to the secure tenancy herself as she failed to fulfil the 12
month residence requirement, Hale J simply stating that ‘Marie’s mother was
declared trustee because she was willing to act and no-one objected’.47
The second conceptual issue to which the decision in Prince gives rise con-
cerns the obligations owed by the trustee. As indicated above, the grant of a
legal tenancy to a minor will take effect as a contract by the landlord/grantor of
the tenancy to hold the legal estate in trust for the minor and, unless a trustee is
expressly appointed, will leave the legal estate vested in the landlord. Moreover,
as has already been mentioned, social landlords will generally wish to appoint
an adult as trustee of the legal estate. It has been argued 48 that the fiduciary rela-
tionship—which forbids the trustee from putting him- or herself in a position in
which interest and duty conflict49—does not affect the landlord’s ‘broader hous-
ing management responsibilities, nor its public law responsibilities to the wider
44 In order to be legal, a lease for more than three years must be made by deed (s 52(1), Law of
Property Act 1925). However, there is no such requirement in respect of a lease for less than three
years provided that it takes effect in possession, it is for the best rent which can reasonably be
obtained, and no fine (ie, premium or lump sum) is paid to the landlord (s 54(2) LPA 1925). An equi-
table lease may also come into being where the grantor has only equitable title him- or herself.
45 (1882) 21 Ch D 9.
46 London and South Western Railway Co v Gomm (1882) 20 ChD 562; Property Discount
Corporation v Lyon Group [1980] 1 All ER 334, affirmed [1981] 1 WLR 300.
47 Above n 14 at 802.
48 D Cowan and N Deardon, ‘The minor as (a) subject: the case of housing law’ in J Fionda (ed),
community’ and that where there is a breach of the tenancy agreement by the
minor sufficient to justify a possession order, the fiduciary relationship must
concede to the minor’s breach of obligation. In other words, ‘the fiduciary rela-
tionship refers to the grant and continuation of the property interest, but not to
its end through legal processes’.50 It is doubtful, however, that the situation is
quite as clear cut as this argument suggests. For example, as Mills and Joss51
point out, there is considerable scope for conflict of interest where, for example,
possession is sought because of rent arrears and the tenant wishes to counter-
claim in respect of damages for disrepair.52 They suggest, therefore, that hous-
ing authorities should take steps to divest themselves of the legal estate to an
independent trustee, preferably the person who has parental responsibility for
the child. Such a person may also be persuaded to guarantee the child’s perfor-
mance of his or her obligations under the lease. If there is no alternative, the
Director of Social Services should be appointed trustee although there will still
be potential for the conflict of interest discussed in the previous paragraph in
relation to unitary housing and social services authorities.
As stated earlier, the arrangement may be subject to TOLATA which con-
tains a number of provisions whereby minor beneficiaries are treated differently
from their adult counterparts. By section 9 the trustees may delegate their func-
tions to a beneficiary only if s/he is an adult. Where the consent of a beneficiary
is needed for the exercise of the trustees’ functions (eg because the trust deed so
provides), and the beneficiary is a minor, section 10 provides that the trustees
must obtain instead the consent of a person who has parental responsibility or
a guardian. Section 11 imposes a duty on the trustees to consult the beneficiaries
in the exercise of their functions—but this is so only in respect of adult beneficia-
ries. By sections 19 and 20 only adult beneficiaries may appoint and retire
trustees. There is, therefore, as Cooke points out, ‘no Gillick competence for
children as beneficiaries of trusts of land—they are excluded from any decision-
making role’.53 However, section 14 of the 1996 Act provides that ‘any person
who . . . has an interest in property subject to a trust of land’ may make an appli-
cation to the court. The court may make any order it thinks fit in relation to the
exercise by the trustees of any of their functions, or declare the ‘nature or extent’
of any person’s interest in the trust property. Here, there is no requirement that
the person who makes the application is of full age.54
50
Above n 48.
51
S Mills and N Joss, ‘Children and secure tenancies’ (2001) 5 L& T Rev 53–6.
52 Mills and Joss also state that there is potential for conflict where the landlord seeks possession
because the minor tenant is in arrears with rent caused by problems relating to housing benefit. It is
highly unlikely, however, that a social landlord would ever seek to recover possession in such cir-
cumstances. Even if it were to do so, the court would not deem it reasonable to make an order for
possession.
53 E Cooke, ‘Children and Real Property—Trusts, Interests and Considerations’ (1998) 28 Family
Law 349.
54 In determining these questions, s 15(1) of the 1996 Act directs the court to have regard, inter
alia, to ‘the welfare of any minor who occupies or might reasonably be expected to occupy the trust
land as his home’.
The Child as Tenant: Rights and Responsibilities 259
Thirdly, what are the consequences of the arrangement as regards the minor’s
contractual rights and obligations? The general rule is that a contract is not
enforceable against a minor though it is enforceable by the minor. The rationale
for this rule is that because the minor is ‘young and inexperienced’ he or she
requires protection, not only from ‘unscrupulous adults’ but also from him- or
herself.55 The minor’s lack of experience may mean that he or she is less likely
than an adult to appreciate the significance of his or her actions, and may be
more easily led to enter into obligations which he or she cannot perform, or
which have consequences which he or she cannot foresee.56 On the other hand,
it is recognised that the greater the protection which is afforded to the minor,
the greater will be the potential prejudice to an adult who contracts with a
minor, as the adult ‘must himself bear any loss which he may sustain if the
minor breaks the contract’.57 There is also the risk that adults may be deterred
from contracting with minors for fear that they might be disadvantaged by
doing so.58 To the general rule, therefore, there are two exceptions. First, con-
tracts for ‘necessaries’ are binding on a minor and may be enforced against him.
Secondly, there is a group of other contracts which are binding unless and until
repudiated by the minor before or within a reasonable time after s/he reaches the
age of 18.
Section 3(3) of the Sale of Goods Act 1979 defines a contract for ‘necessaries’
as a contract for the provision of a good which is ‘suitable to the condition in
life of the minor and to his actual requirements at the time of sale and delivery’.
The section does not apply to services, but these may be necessary under the
common law which would define them similarly. The common law regards such
contracts as for the minor’s benefit and (if he or she is married) for the benefit of
his or her family. Goods and services which have been held to be necessary
include lodging.59 It follows that accommodation provided for occupation by a
minor is almost certain to be regarded as a necessary if it is appropriate in size
and allocated on the basis of the minor’s housing need.
There is some authority that during his or her minority a minor is liable to pay
for the use and occupation of premises only if they can be said to be necessary.60
Generally, however, a contract under which the minor agrees to take or grant a
lease of land is an example of a contract which is binding unless repudiated
before or within a reasonable time after attaining majority.61 The minor is
regarded as having acquired an interest in some subject-matter of a permanent
nature, ie, to which continuing obligations are attached, so that it would be
unjust if he or she were allowed to retain the interest without fulfilling the oblig-
ations it entails. While in possession the minor is subject to the liabilities
imposed by the contract and may, for instance, be successfully sued for non-
payment of rent.62
The effect of repudiation is to allow the minor to escape liability for future
obligations. However, there are conflicting dicta as to whether he is also
released from obligations which have already accrued at the date of repudiation.
For example, is the minor who repudiates the lease nonetheless liable for rent
already due? One view is that repudiation is the equivalent of rescission and
therefore retrospective in its effect.63 However, according to Blake v
Concannon64, an Irish case, repudiation has no retrospective effect so that a
minor tenant is still liable for his past use and occupation of the premises. On a
separate point, repudiation of the contract will not enable him to recover rent
which he has already paid unless there has been a total failure of consideration
and he has received no part of what he bargained for.65
Where the landlord intentionally creates a trust, granting the equitable ten-
ancy to a minor but appointing an adult (such as a parent or social worker) as
trustee, the adult may be made personally liable for rent and for the other
covenants in the lease or tenancy agreement. The landlord may be able, there-
fore, to sue the adult for arrears of rent and for damages for any other breach of
covenant.
The decision in Prince means that whether the minor succeeds to or has been
granted a secure tenancy66 by a local authority landlord, the tenancy will take
62
Davies v Beynon-Harris (1931) 47 TLR 424. It should be noted, however, that application must
be made for the minor to be represented by a guardian at litem.
63
North Western Railway Co v M’Michael (1850) 5 Ex 114 at 128. Ketsey’s Case (1613) Cro Jac
320 aka Keteley’s Case (1613) 1 Brown 120.
64
(1870) IR 4 CL 323.
65
Valentini v Canali (1889) 24 QBD 166; Steinberg v Scala (Leeds) Ltd [1929] 2 KB 310. Compare
the views taken by Treitel (1957) 73 LQR 194, 202–5, and Atiyah (1958) 74 LQR 97, 101–3.
66 A useful alternative to a secure tenancy in the case of minors might be an introductory tenancy
(which would also take effect in equity). Local authorities may elect to operate an introductory ten-
ancy regime under which new periodic tenants are granted introductory tenancies instead of secure
tenancies (s 124, Housing Act 1996). An introductory tenancy lasts for a trial period of one year
beginning with the date the tenancy is entered into or, if later, the date when the tenant is first enti-
tled to possession (s 125(2)). At the end of the trial period, the tenancy automatically becomes a
secure tenancy unless the landlord has already begun possession proceedings and obtains possession
during or after the first year of the tenancy. The court cannot entertain proceedings for possession
unless a notice has been served which, inter alia, sets out the landlord’s reasons for seeking posses-
sion (s 128) but there is no need for the landlord to prove that a ground for possession exists.
Although the 1995 White Paper described the scheme as one for ‘tenancies on a probationary basis’
to allow landlords at any time during the probationary period to be able to terminate the tenancies
of ‘the minority of tenants who do not behave responsibly’ (above n 25, p 44), the landlord can
recover possession for reasons other than anti-social behaviour.
The Child as Tenant: Rights and Responsibilities 261
effect in equity.67 Having considered the obligations which arise under tenancies
vesting in minors generally, this section explores the extent to which a minor
enjoys the rights of a secure tenant. Four issues arise for consideration, namely
security of tenure, the right to exchange, the right to buy, and the right to be
consulted.
First, the minor tenant is in exactly the same position as an adult when it
comes to security of tenure and the landlord may obtain possession under any
of the discretionary grounds set out in Schedule 2 to the Housing Act 1985. The
grounds cover situations where, for example, the tenant fails to pay the rent or
otherwise discharge the obligations of the tenancy, or is guilty of nuisance and
annoyance. If the minor becoming the tenant by way of succession leads to
under-occupation of the dwelling-house, Ground 16 of the 1985 Act provides
that a possession order may be granted by the court if the accommodation
afforded by the dwelling-house is more extensive than is reasonably required by
the tenant who, as a member of the previous tenant’s family, succeeded to a peri-
odic tenancy by virtue of section 89. In determining whether it is reasonable to
make an order on this ground, the court must take into account the tenant’s age,
the period during which the tenant has occupied the dwelling-house as his or her
only or principal home, and any financial or other support given by the tenant
to the previous tenant.
The general rule is that notices given by a landlord or a tenant should ordi-
narily be given by the person for the time being legally entitled to the immediate
reversion or leasehold estate respectively,68 ie, to or by trustees of a lease, rather
than by or to the beneficiaries. This suggests that the local authority landlord
which grants an (equitable) tenancy to a minor and retains the legal estate can
terminate the tenancy by serving notice upon itself. However, even where the
landlord or an adult is holding the legal estate, it would appear that the Notice
of Seeking Possession under section 83 should be served on the minor who holds
the secure tenancy for the purpose of section 79.69 There are two other indica-
tors that any notices should also be served on minor tenant. As has already been
mentioned, an equitable tenant enjoys the protection conferred by the Rent Acts
and the Housing Act 1988, and it would be a nonsense if an adult equitable ten-
ant were not to be the recipient of any notices served in relation to such statutes.
Further, all the grounds for possession under the Housing Act 1985 are discre-
tionary and a failure to warn the minor tenant would doubtless affect the issue
67 This will also be the case as regards an assured or assured shorthold tenancy granted by a pri-
vate landlord or registered social landlord. Circular R3–05/96 issued by the Housing Corporation
states that RSLs ‘should normally grant assured shorthold tenancies . . . to young persons aged 16/17
until they have reached their 18th birthday when they should normally be granted an assured peri-
odic tenancy—’ (para 5.2). The Corporation’s Code of Practice on Tenure, published in July 1999,
notes that ‘some [RSLs] are granting equitable tenancies to 16 and 17 year olds living in supported
housing’.
68 Stait v Fenner [1912] 2 Ch 504.
69 Above n 51. The authors point out that whenever an authority is obliged to communicate with
the tenant, eg, when seeking to vary the terms of the lease under ss 102 and 103 of the 1985 Act, it
must communicate with the minor.
262 Jill Morgan
70
J Henderson, Children and Housing: Law and Practice in the Management of Social Housing
(London, Lemos & Crane, 2000) 109
71
Ashfeild v Ashfeild (1628) WJo 157.
72
Carnell v Harrison [1916] 1 Ch 328.
73
Section 119.
74
(1989) 21 HLR 320.
The Child as Tenant: Rights and Responsibilities 263
secure tenant’s (adult) daughter (who succeeded to the tenancy on her mother’s
death) was thus entitled to the same discount as her mother, rather than a lesser
one based on her own period of residence.
Fourthly, does the landlord have to consult with a minor tenant on matters of
‘housing management’75 or where it seeks to dispose of dwelling-houses by way
of a large-scale voluntary transfer?76 If tenants are being balloted, can a vote be
cast by a secure tenant who is a minor?
‘It simply cannot be assumed,’ said Hale J in Prince ‘that [children] are omit-
ted from legislation unless the contrary is expressly stated’.77 Her statement
lends support to the argument that minor tenants should be consulted, and have
their views taken into account, in relation to matters of housing management
etc. Such a view also accords with the United Nations Convention on the Rights
of the Child,78 Article 12 of which states that a child who is capable of forming
his or her own views has ‘the right to express those views freely in all matters
affecting the child, the views of the child being given due weight in accordance
with the age and maturity of the child’. Although there is no individual enforce-
ment mechanism for alleged breaches of the Convention, it is arguable that it
could to be used as an aid to interpretation of Article 879 of the European
Convention on Human Rights which is enforceable via the Human Rights Act
1998. This argument would appear to be unavailable where the minor is a
tenant of a registered social landlord.80
To conclude this section, there is little doubt that the decision in Prince will
impact upon other statutory codes. If the independent child has sufficient under-
standing and intelligence to be capable of entering into a contract, he or she
takes the benefit of all its terms, and can usually sue for damages for breach of
contract. A child can sue in his or her name by a next friend who will be respon-
sible for costs. An important source of protection for tenants with leases of less
than seven years (and therefore with periodic tenancies) exists in the form of sec-
tion 11 of the Landlord and Tenant Act 1985 which imposes repairing obliga-
tions upon landlords. Where there is continuing disrepair, a claim normally
includes an injunction ordering the landlord to carry out repairs. In other
75 Section 105, Housing Act 1985.
76 Section 106A, Housing Act 1985.
77 Above n 14 at 804.
78 The Convention was ratified by the United Kingdom on 16 December 1991.
79
By Article 8(1), ‘Everyone has the right to respect for his private and family life, his home and
his correspondence.’
(2) There shall be no interference by a public authority with the exercise of this right except such
as is in accordance with the law and is necessary in a democratic society in the interests of national
security, public safety or the economic well-being of the country, for the prevention of disorder or
crime, for the protection of health or morals, or for the protection of the rights and freedoms of
others.
80
The Human Rights Act 1998 makes it unlawful for a public authority to act in a way which is
incompatible with a Convention right (s 6(1)). ‘Public authority’ is defined to include ‘a court or
tribunal, and . . . any person certain of whose functions are functions of a public nature’ (s 6(3)).
The status of RSLs in this regard is deeply uncertain. See, eg, Donoghue v Poplar Housing and
Regeneration Community Association Ltd [2001] 3 WLR 183.
264 Jill Morgan
contexts it has been held that because the court will not force one party to carry
out an agreement if the responsibilities are not mutual, minors cannot claim
specific performance81 and that ‘if it would be wrong to grant specific perfor-
mance . . . it would be wrong to grant an injunction’.82 If the legal tenancy is held
by an adult other than the landlord it would presumably be possible, however,
for the action to be brought by, and an equitable remedy made in favour of, such
adult (and therefore satisfy mutuality).
CONCLUSION
81
Flight v Bolland (1828) 4 Russ 298.
82
Lumley v Ravenscroft [1895] 1 QB 683.
83
Above n 23 at 38.
84
Ibid at 47. Since October 1996, the amount of housing benefit payable to many single people
under the age of 25 living in private sector accommodation has been severely restricted and covers
only the ‘average’ cost of a non self-contained room (with only shared use of a kitchen or bathroom)
in the locality: Housing Benefit (General) Amendment Regulations 1996, SI 1996/965.
The Child as Tenant: Rights and Responsibilities 265
achieve certainty in the law and in recognition of the competence of many ‘inde-
pendent’ children to be able to make sensible, informed life choices, it is time to
revise that rule (and to reduce the age of full contractual capacity). In other juris-
dictions, special provision exists as regards minors and residential tenancies. In
New Zealand, for instance, (where the age of majority is 2085), section 9(1) of
the Minors’ Contracts Act 1969 provides that:
Every contract entered into by a minor shall have effect as if the minor were of full age
if, before the contract is entered into by the minor, it is approved . . . by a Magistrate’s
Court.
An application can be made, therefore, by a landlord and a prospective minor ten-
ant for approval to enter into a tenancy agreement. In addition, by section 14(1)
of the Residential Tenancies Act 1986, a person who has attained the age of 18
years or is or has been married under that age has the same capacity in respect of
tenancy agreements as persons of full age. By section 14(3), however, the minor
tenant may, within 10 working days after the date on which s/he attains the age
of 18 years or marries, apply to the Residential Tenancies Tribunal for an order
relieving the tenant of all or any of the obligations imposed on the tenant by the
agreement. In Australia, section 19 of the Residential Tenancies Act 1994
(Queensland) provides that ‘a minor has the capacity to enter into residential ten-
ancy agreements’ and that such an agreement is ‘enforceable in the same way as
if the agreement had been entered into by an adult’. A minor can hold a legal
estate in land under the Land Title Act 1994 (Queensland) and the problems
which might arise as regards transfer of the tenancy are thereby avoided.
The right of children of sufficient understanding to make decisions for them-
selves was enhanced by the House of Lords decision in Gillick in which Lord
Scarman pointed out that:
parental right yields to the child’s right to make his own decisions when he reaches a
sufficient understanding and intelligence to be capable of making up his own mind on
the matter requiring decision.86
In 1987 the Law Commission took a similar view87 setting out a number of
justifications for its proposal that the age of full contractual capacity be reduced
to 16. It pointed out that in practice young people of 16 exercise ‘a high degree
of responsibility for their own lives’88 and that the law recognises this in a num-
ber of ways: compulsory schooling ends and a minor is judged fit to enter the
labour market in search of his own living; the parental obligation to maintain
the child ceases; a person becomes eligible to claim social security benefits; a per-
son may legally marry (albeit with parental consent), and may legally consent to
sexual relations.89 The fact that a minor is unable to hold a legal estate is used,
85 Section 4 Age of Majority Act 1970.
86 Above n 2 at 189.
87 Above n 4.
88 Ibid para 3.15.
89 Ibid para 12.5.
266 Jill Morgan
English law has something to learn from those jurisdictions which make special
provision in relation to the contractual capacity of 16 and 17-year-olds and their
ability to hold a legal estate in land. There is no evidence that such measures lead
to an increased incidence of young people becoming tenants, but it does mean
that when they are tenants, there is greater certainty in the law to which they are
subject.
90
Above n 48 at 165.
91
Indeed this was a reason advanced by a number of those who responded to the proposal con-
tained in the Housing Green Paper, Quality and Choice: A Decent Home for All to extend priority
status to 16 and 17-year-olds.
92
Above n 14 at 804.
93
Above n 12 at 603.
14
The ‘Widows and Orphans’ of
Leasehold Reform
NICHOLAS ROBERTS 1
1
The author wishes to acknowledge the helpful comments made at the conference by Prof JE
Adams and Prof David Clarke.
2 See, for example, David Clarke, ‘Occupying “Cheek by Jowl”: Property Issues Arising from
Communal Living’ in S Bright and J Dewar (eds), Land Law: Themes and Perspectives (OUP,
Oxford, 1998) 380, n 21.
3 For a more detailed account, ibid 391–401.
4 Report of the Committee of Inquiry on the Management of Privately Owned Blocks of Flats
managed (Part III); allows courts to vary defective leases (part IV); provides for service charges to
be held on trust (s 42); and requires that certain information be supplied to tenants (Part VI); but no
further reference will be made to these provisions.
268 Nicholas Roberts
charges and applications for the appointment of a receiver and manager of a block of
flats to the Leasehold Valuation Tribunal.6
Commonhold and Leasehold Reform Act 2002 (‘the CLRA’): besides introducing
commonhold, Part 2 of this act also amends the acts mentioned above.7
Essentially, therefore, one is dealing with those measures which have (a) enabled
leaseholders to acquire their freehold; (b) dealt with management problems,
especially service charges, by preventing ground landlords from abusing their
position in various ways.
To speak of ‘Widows and Orphans’ is to borrow a term of printing jargon—
it is the term used in typesetting when lines get left out from the main body of
the text and stranded on a page of their own.8 Having acted as a legal adviser in
this field over a number of years, it is the author’s view that a number of sub-
groups of homeowners have been left out by the various reforms. In some cases
reforms have not included them; in others they have been included, but have
been treated in an inappropriate manner. In both cases their special require-
ments have been overlooked. Some of the groups who have been left out include:
(a) The enfranchising owners of leasehold houses where there is a real need for con-
tributions to be levied for common services.
(b) The owners of holiday chalets on leasehold estates who to date have not been able
to enfranchise either individually or collectively. Their position has been altered by the
CLRA, but they have been treated inappropriately.
(c) Owners of freehold houses whose position corresponds with those at (a) and (b)
above, but who are paying an estate rentcharge and then find that the provisions of
sections 18 to 30 of the LTA 1985 do not apply to them.
(d) The owners of maisonettes, and possibly owners of very small blocks of flats,
whose position is arguably made worse by the CLRA.
It is proposed to examine these categories in turn, and then to look at the ques-
tion of whether these are just odd residual categories, or whether some common
threads can be found running through them. If there are, then any lessons may
be useful in considering the future course of residential leasehold reform.
6 Ie the Rent Assessment Committee, constituted as a Leasehold Valuation Tribunal. This has
arguably become an embryonic ‘Housing Court’ for this area of law. See further a series of four arti-
cles by S Gallagher ‘The new powers of Leasehold Valuation Tribunals’ [1999] JHL 41, 58, 79 and
95; M Biles ‘Leasehold Valuation Tribunals and managers of flats’ [1999] Conv 472; and N Roberts
‘The Leasehold Valuation Tribunals and service charges—some problems of jurisdiction’ [2001]
Conv 61.
7 No further reference is made to certain other statutes which may be relevant to residential lease-
hold law such as the Landlord and Tenant Act 1927; the Leasehold Property (Repairs) Act 1938; the
Landlord and Tenant Act 1954, Part I; and the Landlord and Tenant (Covenants) Act 1995. Further,
some provisions may also apply to ‘renting tenants’ eg LTA 1985, ss 18–30.
8 Strictly speaking a ‘widow’ is the last line of a paragraph printed by itself on the top of a page,
and an ‘orphan’ is the first line of a paragraph printed by itself on the bottom of a page. Word-
processing programs have given the term wider currency.
The ‘Widows and Orphans’ of Leasehold Reform 269
The pressure for leasehold enfranchisement came from the older industrial areas
of England and Wales, especially south9 Wales, and London. In most cases
houses had originally been sold on the long leasehold system solely because it
was financially advantageous to the original landowners to continue to receive
the annual rental value of the land, but with the prospect of receiving the added
value of the houses at the end of the term.10 Although the houses concerned were
often terraced houses there were seldom any common facilities requiring
contributions to be made for their upkeep.11
The White Paper Leasehold Reform in England and Wales12 did acknowledge
that something would need to be done:
Most of the covenants under the existing lease concern the relations between the land-
lord and the leaseholder and will automatically and rightly disappear when the lease
is enfranchised. But where there is more than one leasehold property in the same free-
hold ownership it is common to provide by way of leasehold covenants for matters of
mutual advantage as between the leaseholders themselves affecting essential services
and amenity. Neither the leaseholder who enfranchises nor his neighbour will want to
lose these mutual advantages; and the Bill will ensure that, where they are important,
they will be preserved.13
Although the White Paper mentioned ‘mutual advantage’ the scope of this was
not considered in detail. Although the LRA provided for restrictive covenants
that had been contained in the lease to be re-imposed in conveyances of the free-
hold,14 it did not deal adequately with positive covenants, except in the limited
context of ‘estate management schemes’. The White Paper did give some con-
sideration to these:
There are some comprehensively managed leasehold estates where enlightened man-
agement contributes greatly to the well-being of the residents by maintaining the char-
acter of the estate. It would not be fair to deny to leaseholders on such estates the right
of enfranchisement, but it would be equally unfair to other residents on the estate if
the exercise of this right prevented the benefits of comprehensive management from
9 In deference to the strictures of Jan Morris, the author will refer to ‘south Wales’ and ‘north
Wales’ and not to ‘South Wales’ and ‘North Wales’, as if (in her words) ‘they were separate coun-
tries, like North Korea and South Korea’.
10 The author has seen it suggested that land was sold leasehold to facilitate the retention of min-
eral rights by the original landowners, which would be particularly advantageous in mining areas,
but this seems unlikely as many freehold conveyances ‘reserve mines and minerals’.
11 At least in south Wales, rear accessways were seldom maintained by the freeholder; if they
being any longer effective. The Government propose that, if the estate is recognised by
the appropriate Minister as a well managed estate, enfranchisement will be subject
to an agreed scheme for continued estate management, with suitable provision for
determination in the event of disagreement.15
15
Leasehold Reform in England and Wales, above n 12, at para 22.
16
The White Paper (see para 8) made no attempt to consider the enfranchisement of long lease-
hold flats: these were comparatively rare, though certainly not unknown in 1966.
17
The most detailed account is in NT Hague, Leasehold Enfranchisement (2nd edn, Sweet &
Maxwell, London, 1987), ch 10; the matter is dealt with more briefly in the 3rd edn (1999) at 36–01
to 36–04.
18
Few schemes were made under the LRA. 258 applications to the Minister were made, of which
105 were granted, 78 refused and 75 withdrawn. (Public Record Office, HLG 118/747). They are
listed in CC Hubbard and DW Williams, Handbook of Leasehold Reform (Sweet & Maxwell,
London, 1988), at 607. A further five made following the Housing Act 1974 are noted there. It is
believed that in the overwhelming majority of cases schemes were approved by the High Court.
Hague (eds A Radevsky and D Greenish), Leasehold Enfranchisement (3rd edn, Sweet & Maxwell,
London, 1999), ch 36, refers to at least a dozen schemes under the 1993 Act.
19
LRA, s 19(1)
20
Section 118(2).
The ‘Widows and Orphans’ of Leasehold Reform 271
of Appeal was unclear why the judge in the county court had rejected the defen-
dant’s unchallenged evidence that he used only an adopted road to gain access
to his property and that the sewers were the responsibility of a company other
than the plaintiff. But as there was no cross-appeal the Court of Appeal could
not upset the findings of fact on this point. The case thus re-iterates that two
conditions are necessary for the rule in Halsall v Brizell to apply: first, the con-
dition of discharging the burden must be relevant to the exercise of the rights
that enable the benefit to be obtained; and second, the successors in title of the
original covenantor must have, at least in theory, the right to renounce the
benefit of the right granted by the deed and so escape the burden of the covenant.
Peter Gibson LJ acknowledged36 that whilst Halsall v Brizell was clearly
correct in requiring the defendant to contribute to the use of estate roads and
sewers, so much of that decision as related to the maintenance of the sea-wall
was likely to be inconsistent with Rhone v Stephens and thus overruled by it.
It is difficult fully to square the judgment in Thamesmead Town with the out-
come of the case. The amount claimed was £211.10 and judgment was entered
for £41.65.37 It is easy to see why the cost of maintaining the common areas was
not enforceable. One can accept that the defendant would be liable, on the facts
as found, to pay for roads and sewers. It is not clear from the report of the case
how the payments for the ‘janitorial services’ fit into the picture or precisely
what facilities they relate to.
The second condition—that it is essential that one can, at least in theory,
renounce the benefit granted by a deed—is one that can be difficult to analyse
properly, and, if one does succeed in doing so, the results can seem capricious.
On the one hand, one has benefits which one can in theory not use, such as
drains and roads, and therefore one must pay for them if one does. On the other
hand, the maintenance of a sea-wall (such as in Halsall v Brizell) seems to be a
benefit that one cannot renounce, and so it is analogous to the rights of support
in Rhone v Stephens: a right where one has no choice but to take the benefit,
so one cannot be forced to contribute towards the cost of providing it. Further
reference will be made to this.38
A simple solution to the problem would be the power, in appropriate
cases, to impose an estate rentcharge under the Rentcharges Act 1977 on the
enfranchisement of leasehold properties. It is of course hardly surprising that no
reference was made to them in the LRA, as they did not exist as a separate
category until the Rentcharges Act 1977.39 It must be admitted that they have
36
EGLR at 99M.
37
Surely one of the smallest claims to be litigated in the Court of Appeal in recent years, although
it would of course have had potential repercussions for thousands of other properties on the estate.
38
Below, pp 275–6.
39
See s 2(4): ‘For the purposes of this section “estate rentcharge” means (subject to subsection (5)
below) a rentcharge created for the purpose—
(a) of making covenants to be performed by the owner of the land affected by the rentcharge
enforceable by the rent owner against the owner for the time being of the land; or
(b) of meeting, or contributing towards, the cost of the performance by the rent owner of covenants
274 Nicholas Roberts
‘Estate Rentcharges and the Enforcement of Positive Covenants’ [1988] Conv 99. If her doubts as to
the scope of s 2(4) to cover (a) the building up of a reserve fund and (b) contributions for the main-
tenance of eg communal landscaped areas retained by the rentowner are correct, then estate
rentcharges may not cover all the circumstances that a service charge ideally should.
41 For convenience they will be referred to as ‘chalets’. Nothing turns on whether they consist of
one storey or two or more storeys: the crucial distinction is that they are treated as ‘houses’ under
LRA, s 2, rather than as ‘flats’ under LRHUDA, s 101.
42
For an example of litigation involving such an estate (though not immediately relevant to the pre-
sent discussion) see Minster Chalets Ltd v Irwin Park Residents Association (27 April 2001) (Lawtel
09/07/01) and in full as LRX/53/1999 on the Lands Tribunal Website: http://www.courtservice.gov.uk/
tribunals/lands/decisions/dec-index.htm. It is understood that an appeal has been made to the Court of
Appeal.
43
LRA, s 1(1)(b).
44
The author is grateful to Prof David Clarke for pointing out this possibility.
The ‘Widows and Orphans’ of Leasehold Reform 275
It is not clear how many such developments there may be, and whether these
problems are commonplace. The writer is aware of at least three such develop-
ments in the Isle of Wight, and has come across one in north Wales, as well as
another in the Isle of Sheppey which has resulted in litigation in the Lands
Tribunal.45 To date they have in general been unable to enfranchise46 under the
LRA. Under the CLRA,47 the residence qualification for owners of leasehold
houses has been dropped, but that will present its own problems both for own-
ers of these leasehold chalets and for the reversioners.48 Owners of holiday
chalets are now able to enfranchise but (a) they will have no right to acquire the
common parts of their development; (b) the owners of the reversion (who will
probably be running the estate) will have no right to impose a positive covenant
or an estate rentcharge to ensure that contributions are made for the upkeep of
common facilities; and (c) even if the exercise of easements or other rights were
made conditional in the lease upon financial contributions, and so the condition
could be included in the freehold transfer,49 Halsall v Brizell and Thamesmead
Town will cause particular problems where contributions are required for
rights which may not even be easements and may be eminently à la carte.
Attempting to apply Halsall v Brizell and Thamesmead Town to the circum-
stances of the typical estate of holiday chalets reveals the depth of the problem:
(1) The right to benefit from certain facilities will not be optional, and so charges for
them cannot be recovered under Halsall v Brizell. Examples would be the maintenance
of any sea-defences, site security, and the provision of exterior lighting.
(2) The right to benefit from some facilities50 will in theory be optional, but in
practice the chalet-owner will have no choice. The charges for these will therefore be
recoverable from both the original covenantors and their successors. Examples of
these would be the right to use accessways to the chalet, mains services, and
drainage.51
(3) The right to use other facilities will be optional both in theory and in practice.
Owners of individual chalets will be liable to pay only for those that they actually use.
These may include the right to park a car, to use communal gardens, or to use club-
houses, swimming pools and other recreational facilities. Some of these rights are per-
sonal rights rather than easements, but there is no suggestion in Thamesmead Town
that the reasoning in Halsall v Brizell is confined to easements in the accepted sense.
Rights in this class are eminently à la carte and covering their cost by a service charge
45 Above, n 42.
46 Except in the case outlined above.
47 Section 138.
48 Dropping the residence requirement for owners of leasehold houses was floated in the August
2000 Discussion Paper Commonhold and Leasehold Reform: Draft Bill and Consultation Paper (Cm
4843) (HMSO, London, 2000), did not then appear in the December 2000 Bill, but did appear when
the Bill was re-introduced after the June 2001 General Election.
49 Assuming the editors of Hague, above, n 18 are correct and that the exercise of easements or
other rights can be made conditional upon the making of financial contributions only if the lease
itself contained such a condition. If they are not—or the enfranchising purchaser does not take the
point—then the other problems still remain.
50 It would seem inevitable that these will always be easements.
51 Unless the owners choose to provide their own septic tanks or even earth closets!
276 Nicholas Roberts
Assume, then, that with a new development of freehold houses, there are ser-
vices which are covered by an estate rentcharge. Or assume that on the enfran-
chisement of a leasehold house, or a leasehold holiday chalet, both parties agree
52 Above, pp 269–71 for further details and relevant references.
53 Which cannot usually be said of estates of holiday chalets.
54 Such estates would seem to fall within LRHUDA, s 70(1), a scheme being required ‘in order to
maintain adequate standards of appearance and amenity and to regulate redevelopment within the
area in the event of tenants acquiring the interest of the landlord in any property’—the ‘architectural
or historical associations’ mentioned in subsection (3) seem relevant but not obligatory. In any
event, some amendment could have been made to the criteria to meet these circumstances.
55 LRHUDA, s 72(3)(a).
56 Or were intended to be—see text to n 44, above.
57 Section 138 CLRA.
The ‘Widows and Orphans’ of Leasehold Reform 277
58 See Bright, above n 40 at 99. The existence of abuse was noted in Residential Leasehold Reform
in England and Wales: A Consultation Paper (para 11 of ch 5) (DETR, Nov 1998), but the point was
not raised in the 2000 Consultation Paper or the subsequent Bills (above, n 48).
59 [1976] 1 All ER 591. Since this paper was originally given, the first decision on the estate
rentcharge provisions of the Rentcharges Act 1977 has been reported: Orchard Trading Estate
Management Ltd v Johnson Securities Ltd [2002] EWCA Civ 406; [2002] 18 EG 155 (CA). As the
appeal was on narrow preliminary issues it does not shed a great deal of light upon the present issue.
For comment on the case, see S Bright ‘Estate Rentcharges and Reasonableness’ at [2002] Conv 507.
60 [1994] 2 EGLR 73.
61 At 75K.
278 Nicholas Roberts
Property Holdings Ltd v JS Darwen (Successors) Ltd.62 The Court of Appeal also
did not follow Finchbourne in Berrycroft Management Co Ltd v Sinclair Gardens
Investments (Kensington) Ltd,63 although, rather intriguingly, the court thought
it relevant64 that in Finchbourne the insurance premium made up only 4 per cent
of the total service charge, so implying that the court’s ability to intervene over
insurance premiums may be more restricted than its jurisdiction over service
charges in general.65 However, even if the court does have power under
Finchbourne to rule on the reasonableness of a variable estate rentcharge,66 there
is another ‘orphan’ lurking here, as such jurisdiction would have to be exercised
by the court and not, as is usually the case with service charges, by an LVT.67 This
would be a particular problem if all or part of what was intended to be the same
service charge was payable both by owners of leasehold flats and, via a variable
estate rentcharge, by owners of freehold houses. Such mixed developments are by
no means uncommon. In some cases they may be purpose-built developments of
flats and townhouses around a courtyard. In other cases a large old property is
converted into apartments and its outbuildings are converted into ‘mews cot-
tages’ and/or new houses are built in the grounds. Presumably if a dispute involv-
ing the reasonableness of a service charge which was levied on some properties as
an ordinary leasehold service charge and on others as a variable estate rentcharge,
that might be a reason to reserve the dispute to the county court.68
This area of law continues to throw up yet further anomalies. If the dispute also
involved the notice provisions of section 20—these can, ex hypothesi, relate only
to the leasehold service charge and not to the variable estate rentcharge—this
aspect could at present be dealt with by the County Court,69 but, for the future, the
CLRA has created its own ‘orphan’ here: under subsection (1)(b) of the new
section 20 of the LTA 1985,70 a dispute involving section 20 would in future have
62
[1968] 2 All ER 305.
63
[1997] 1 EGLR 47. The present author has previously criticised the reasoning of Beldam LJ in
this case in ‘Berrycroft Management Revisited—or Sidelined?’ at [2000] Conv 307.
64
At 50E.
65
The present author would maintain his stance in the article cited at n 63 to the effect that, with-
out having to rely on Finchbourne, LTA 1985, s 19 provides the necessary authority for the court or
the LVT to rule on the reasonableness of an insurance premium paid by the landlord and which has
to be reimbursed by the leaseholders.
66
If there is jurisdiction, it is less clear how the court could exercise the jurisdiction it enjoys
under s 19(2B) to rule prospectively on the reasonableness of expenditure which may be incurred in
the future—though possibly the declaratory jurisdiction of the court would be wide enough.
67
Following the transfer of jurisdiction over s 19 disputes to the LVT by HA 1996, s 83.
68
Aylesbond Estates Ltd v McMillan and Garg (2000) 32 HLR 1 sets out the principles upon which it
may be appropriate for the county court to retain s 19 disputes itself and not to transfer them to the LVT
(under LTA 1985, s 31C). Although this scenario was not specifically mentioned, it is clearly arguable
that it would be a reason not to transfer the service charge dispute involving the leasehold properties to
the LVT. (If the application were made directly to the LVT, on the other hand, the LVT would appear
to have no power to transfer the dispute to the County Court, and its power to stay its own proceed-
ings—except, under the existing law, to obtain an interpretation of a lease—would seem debatable).
69
Applying Aylesbond Estates Ltd v McMillan and Garg (ibid) this would be a good reason to
retain the dispute in the county court and not to transfer it to the LVT.
70 Inserted in the LTA 1985 by CLRA, s 151 .
The ‘Widows and Orphans’ of Leasehold Reform 279
By and large, owners of maisonettes76 have not faced the worst of the problems
encountered by leaseholders of flats. Usually there will be no service charge,77 with
all the problems that that brings. There are many defective leases of maisonettes
around, particularly of conversions, but variation of defective leases is consider-
ably easier when there are only two or three parties involved, and if the ground
landlord will not be involved it is also possible for the leasehold owners to make
arrangements between themselves by a deed of mutual covenants. If leaseholders
of maisonettes wish to enfranchise then they can if necessary obtain their collec-
tive freehold compulsorily from their ground landlord under the LRHUDA.
Although, in all fairness, it must be said that the CLRA has plugged more loop-
holes than it has created,78 the Act does treat the leaseholders of maisonettes inap-
propriately in requiring them to enfranchise using the medium of a ‘Right to
71
Above, n 68.
72
Inserted by CLRA, s 155.
73
So in effect statutorily overruling the unfortunate decision of the Lands Tribunal in Gilje v
Charlegrove Estates Ltd [2000] 3 EGLR 89.
74
Now CLRA, s 159.
75
Which are not estate rentcharges.
76
This is not a legal term of art, but most writers and practitioners reserve the term for where there
are only two units in a building, with few or no internal common parts. Some (eg EF George and A George
The Sale of Flats (5th edn, Sweet & Maxwell, London, 1984) at 29) would go further and restrict the use
of the term to cases where each unit has an external door, and there are no internal common parts at all.
77
Though not always. Some developments comprising a group of maisonettes have a service
charge to cover the upkeep of communal grounds.
78
Eg the abolition of the residence qualification for collective enfranchisement; the remedying of
the anomaly over dispensation from the notice requirements of LTA 1985, s 20 (CLRA, s 151—
though creating the further anomaly noted at n 70 above and text thereto); the statutory overruling
of Gilje v Charlegrove Estates Ltd (above, n 57) (LVT has no jurisdiction to interpret a lease where
280 Nicholas Roberts
Enfranchise’ (RTE) company.79 There seems little point in requiring the lease-
holders of only two units to set up an RTE company solely in order to acquire their
freehold. It must be very doubtful as to whether they will retain the corporate vehi-
cle or whether they will in the longer term dissolve the company and own the
maisonettes in some simpler way, for example, jointly owning the freehold, sub-
ject to a declaration of trust, or setting up mutual leases, so that each becomes the
reversioner of the other. The result of this misconceived idea can hardly have been
intended—it is surely likely to increase the price that owners of maisonettes will be
required to pay for their freehold, on the basis that when setting the price on a vol-
untary enfranchisement, the figure sought by the landlord will be influenced by the
greater costs that the leaseholders would incur on a statutory enfranchisement.80
Although the case is not so strong, the same could also be said for owners of blocks
comprising only three or four flats. They might well have preferred jointly to own
their freehold, with a suitable declaration of trust, rather than to have to go to the
trouble and expense of setting up and running an RTE company. Blocks of under
five flats should have been exempted.
It may also be noted in passing that, because of the problems with ‘flying
freeholds,’ any material element of undershot or overhang between adjacent
properties will mean that the owners of what might appear at first sight to be
adjacent houses will have to enfranchise collectively under the LRHUDA rather
than under the LRA.81
Of course, one can say that if the owners of two maisonettes are at logger-
heads, it will be no easier to resolve their differences under a trust deed or
mutual leases than under an RTE company. But if their disagreement is going to
end up in court,82 there would seem to be no good reason to encumber them
with the additional trouble and expense of a corporate vehicle to provide the
context for their dispute.
COMMON THEMES
incidental to a dispute under LTA 1985, s 19) (s 27A(1) of LTA 1985, inserted by CLRA, s 155); the
statutory overruling of Daejan Properties Ltd v London Leasehold Valuation Tribunal ([2001]
EWCA Civ 1095) (no jurisdiction to challenge service charge once paid) (s 27A(2) of LTA 1985,
inserted by CLRA, s 155); the bringing of tripartite leases within the management provisions of Part
II of the LTA 1987 (CLRA, s 160); the bringing of leases with arbitration clauses within the juris-
diction of the LVT under LTA 1985, s 19 (CLRA, s 169).
79 CLRA, s 121.
80 An aspect of the ‘Delaforce effect’ (Delaforce v Evans and Evans (1971) 22 P & CR 770).
81 For the meaning of ‘material’ see now Malekshad v Howard de Walden Estates Ltd [2002]
UKHL 49, [2002] 3 WLR 1881, disapproving Duke of Westminster v Birrane, [1995] QB 263.
82 Assuming that ADR is inappropriate or unsuccessful.
The ‘Widows and Orphans’ of Leasehold Reform 281
The continued failure to implement a proper regime for positive covenants, such
as that proposed in 1984 by the Law Commission83 is clearly an underlying
cause of some of these problems. Some of these problems would have been
avoided, or at least lessened, if it had been possible to ensure the passing of the
burden of positive covenants. But that does not address all the problems.
Positive covenants do not necessarily cope with problems such as who has to
arrange repairs or insurance, or the problems caused by widely differing docu-
mentation. These are the reasons why the Building Societies Association in
198484 preferred to see the implementation of a comprehensive strata-titles
regime rather than the more limited objectives of the Law Commission Report.
It is noteworthy that the CLRA, like its predecessor Bills in July 1996 and
December 2000, implements commonhold but not positive covenants; the
Aldridge Report,85 on the other hand, and the draft bill appended to the 1990
Consultation Paper,86 would have implemented commonhold as part of a
scheme for positive covenants generally. The matter is still under review by the
Law Commission.87
In the author’s view, leasehold reform took two wrong turns at the outset:
83 Transfer of Land: The Law of Positive and Restrictive Covenants (Law Com No 127) (1984).
84 In its report Leaseholds—Time for a Change? (BSA, London, 1984).
85 Commonhold, Freehold Flats and freehold ownership of interdependent buildings, Cm 179,
(HMSO, London, 1987).
86 Commonhold: A Consultation Paper, Cm 1345 (HMSO, London, 1990).
87 Ms Sally Keeble, Parliamentary Under-Secretary of State for Transport, Local Government
88
Now considered by the House of Lords in Malekshad v Howard de Walden Estates Ltd (above,
n 81) and see also Hague, above n 18 at 2–02 to 2–09, pp 39–45.
89 Above n 81.
90 The CLRA will mean that in future the owners of overlapping buildings who have to enfran-
chise collectively (because their problem cannot be resolved under LRA, s 2(5)) will have to set up
an RTE company to do so.
91 The only reported decision on the meaning of a ‘building’ is apparently that of the Lands
Tribunal in Saga Properties Ltd v Palmeira Square Nos 2–6 Ltd [1995] 1 EGLR 199, commented
upon by P Dollar and S Thompson-Copsey in ‘Mixed use buildings and Part I of the Landlord and
Tenant Act 1987’ (1999) 3 L&T Rev 96.
92 Or if the freehold had been transferred to a Residents’ Management Company at the outset.
The ‘Widows and Orphans’ of Leasehold Reform 283
Finally, one can observe that leasehold reform has dealt adequately with the
properties that are closest to what one may term the two archetypes: the indi-
vidual leasehold house, usually with few or no shared services, and the detached
block of flats in its own grounds. One should perhaps add a third: the leasehold
house (or block of flats) within the comprehensively managed estate manage-
ment scheme. Inevitably legislation is framed to cover the most common situa-
tions, and seems no coincidence that the owners of these properties have the
most political clout, and are an important element in a number of constituen-
cies. They are also the property owners who are most likely to have associated
themselves with one of the many pressure groups campaigning in the area of
leasehold reform.93 The LRA was a response to pressure from leasehold house-
owners in industrial areas; estate management schemes were conceded in
response to pressure from the large estates and amenity societies. Others fell
between the two stools. In the two decades before 1993 the owners of leasehold
flats lobbied and organised themselves. The further one gets away from these
three models, the less well the law seems to deal with the problems that arise.
The fact that owners of maisonettes have been treated inappropriately under the
CLRA may well be because they are less likely than flat owners to be members
of leaseholders’ associations.
FUTURE REFORMS ?
93
Eg, the Leasehold Reform Association, the Campaign Against Residential Leasehold Abuse,
the Freehold Flats Campaign, and the Federation of Private Residents’ Associations.
94
Possibly subject to their eventual replacement by some form of land obligation.
Part V
Environment and neighbours
15
The New Forest: Ancient Forest And
Modern Playground
SARAH NIELD
INTRODUCTION
Extending to 37,900 hectares, the New Forest is the largest area of forest in
lowland Britain. It lies tucked into the southwest corner of Hampshire between
Southampton and Bournemouth and is bounded on the south by the Solent and
to the north by the lower reaches of Salisbury Plain. Although called a forest, it
is in fact an area of very mixed habitats comprising enclosed forest,1 open pas-
ture woodlands,2 heath land,3 lawns4 and bogs.5 It is a naturalists haven6 and
was designated a Site of Special Scientific Interest in 1971 under National Parks
and Access to the Countryside Act 1949.7 The forest has developed a fascinating
legal framework which displays vestiges of its origins as a royal hunting ground
and which, particularly over the past one hundred and fifty years, has been
shaped to meet the changing and often competing demands of those with a stake
in the forest.
The latest development is the proposed designation of the New Forest as a
National Park. The forest did not become a National Park in the 1950s because
of the view that it was amply protected by existing legislation that related
specifically to the New Forest.8 Since the beginning of the 1990’s the question of
National Park status for the forest has been mooted. The process was finally set
in motion in 1999 and the Designation Order was made on the 24 January 2002.
Whilst there is little objection to National Park status, there are objections from
1
Approximately 23% of the forest is enclosed woodland, just over half is conifer plantations and
the remainder broadleaf woodland.
2
Approximately 11% of the forest is unenclosed woodland. It is referred to as ‘the ancient and
ornamental woodland’.
3
Approximately 30% is open heath land.
4
Approximately 1.0% is grass lawns, which provides the richest grazing.
5
Approximately 8% is bog and mire.
6
For a detailed study of the ecology of the New Forest see C Tubbs, The New Forest (2nd edn,
New Forest Ninth Century Trust, Lyndhurst, 2001).
7 It was renotified in 1986 under the Wildlife and Countryside Acts 1981 and 1985.
8 At that time the relevant legislation was the New Forest Acts 1877, 1879 and 1949, which have
since been joined by further New Forest Acts in 1964 and 1970.
288 Sarah Nield
those with influential voices9 to the proposed legal framework for the park and
a public inquiry is to be held so that the issue can be fully aired.
The purposes of this paper is to examine the current legal framework of the
New Forest in the light of its evolution over nine hundred years. Without a
sound appreciation of the legal status and institutions of the forest it is impossi-
ble to decide how this unique portion of Britain may best be protected.
OWNERSHIP
The physical extent of the forest is defined by the perambulation of the forest
that has waxed and waned over its nine hundred-year history.10 It is currently
defined by the perambulation undertaken under the New Forest Act 1964. This
act brought the adjacent commons to the north and west of the forest within the
perambulation11 and resulted in the griding and fencing of the forest perambu-
lation to prevent the straying of stock onto adjoining roads, towns and
villages.12
Almost three quarters of the New Forest is vested in the Secretary of State for
the Environment, Food and Rural Affairs13 and thus, although often referred to
as Crown land, it is more accurately a state forest. The management of the for-
est passed to the Forestry Commission in 1923.14 Following a review of the
Forestry Commission’s operations in 1992 its responsibility for the management
of national forests, including the New Forest, was assigned to one of its agen-
cies, Forest Enterprise. The remaining quarter of the forest is made up of pri-
vately owned land comprising the towns and villages of the forest, privately
owned estates, farms and dwellings as well as the adjacent commons, which are
owned by a number of private land-owners including the National Trust and
local parish councils.
The open forest15 and adjacent commons are subject to appurtenant profits in
the form of common rights that are attached to a number of properties both
within and outside the forest perambulation. These common rights are thought
9
The Hampshire County Council, the New Forest District Council and the Verderers have all
objected to the proposed administrative arrangements.
10
The earliest known perambulation was conducted in 1217–18 by Henry III, although records
of changes to forest boundaries include those made by William 1, Henry II, Richard I and John.
Subsequent perambulations were undertaken by Edward 1 in 1278–9, 1297 and 1300–1 and by
Charles II in 1681. The 1681 perambulation largely defined the forest boundaries up to 1964.
11 Section 1. The adjacent commons are Cadnam, Penn, West Wellow, Hyde, Ibsley, Plaitford,
Half Moon with Black Hill, Gorley, Hightown, Furzley, Hale Purlieu, Rockford and Kingston
Great.
12 Sections 3 and 5.
13 Section 4(5) Forestry Act 1945. Previously Minister of Agriculture, Fisheries and Food.
14 By the Forestry (Transfer of Woods) Act 1923.
15 Excludes the statutorily inclosed woodland and privately owned land within the forest, includ-
ing the Crown freeholds. The Crown freeholds are the privately owned estates of the Crown, often
the sites of the old forest lodges.
The New Forest: Ancient Forest And Modern Playground 289
to date back to the establishment of the forest. Under forest law claimants were
required to make periodic claims before the highest of the forest courts, the
Forest Eyre. An Act of 1689 gave statutory recognition to the claims made before
the last Forest Eyre of 1670. Present claims stem from the registration process set
in motion by the Deer Removal Act 1851. This Act together with supplemental
legislation passed in 1853 and 1854 provided for the proving of claims before
specially appointed commissioners. In all just over 1300 claims were submitted
of which 850 were approved and published in the New Forest Register of
Decisions on Claims to Forest Rights 1858. To deal with rights that were not
included in this registration process because no claim was submitted, the
Verderers have power to allow those who have no registered right to pasture
their stock on the forest.16
The 1858 register was entirely descriptive and contained no illuminating map
and so as time went by it became difficult to trace claims easily. The problem
was addressed by the preparation of two Atlases of Forest Rights.17 The first
came into force in 1953 as a result of the New Forest Act 1949.18 This Atlas com-
prises seven large volumes of Ordinance Survey maps upon which the tithe areas
of the parishes in and around the forest have been transcribed. Against each
tithe area there is a record of the registered rights.19 A second Atlas was pre-
pared in 1964 to record the rights of pasture over the adjacent commons.20 The
Forestry Commission was charged with the task of preparing this Atlas and, as
there was no pre-existing register to guide them, they merely invited those who
thought they had a right of pasture to put in a claim. A check was made on these
claims by examining the relevant title deeds but there was no rigorous process
of proof. The result was the publication of a further eight volumes of Ordinance
Survey maps, showing the area of each claim outlined in colour.
COMMON RIGHTS
There are six different types of common rights although only four of these rights
are of any significance today. There are also a number of privileges that the
Crown has customarily allowed over the open forest.
The right of pasture is the most important right that is exercised today.
Currently there are about five thousand animals grazing on the forest, about
three thousand of which are ponies and the remainder mostly cattle with a few
donkeys. The right is thought to have its origins in forest law, which prohibited
the fencing and cultivation of land within the forest. As a result the forest inhab-
itants were allowed to let their stock roam the forest. Even so stock had to be
removed during the winter months, known as winter heyning,22 when grazing
was scarce and during fence month,23 when the deer fawned. As the importance
of the forest as a royal hunting reserve declined these restrictions were converted
to money payments, which in turn became uneconomic for the Crown to collect.
In an attempt to reduce the value of common rights as a prelude to enclosure the
Crown did seek to reassert these restrictions at the beginning of the nineteenth
century but they failed when winter heyning and fence month were rendered
nominal by the New Forest Act 1877.24 These restrictions were finally abolished
by the Wild Creatures and Forest Laws Act 1971.25
The numbers of stock that can be turned out are not currently restricted. The
numbers could be controlled through the common law rules of levancy and
couchancy.26 These rules provide that a commoner should not turn out more
stock than can be accommodated on his or her holding during the winter
months, with the assistance of fodder produced on the holding during the sum-
mer. The Verderers could also restrict stock numbers through their byelaws.27
The right is subject to the observance of the Verderers’ byelaws.28 These
byelaws regulate the rights of common, including the common of pasture. For
instance they require the commoners to mark their stock with a recognised
brand and to pay marking fees to the Verderers29 and empower the Verderers to
order the removal of stock from the forest by reason of their poor health or con-
dition or their dangerous temperament. The marking fees are used to defray the
Verderers’ expenses, in particular the wages of the Agisters, who are employed
to oversee the day to day management of the stock. Drifts are conducted in dif-
ferent areas of the forest towards the end of the summer when stock are rounded
up and corralled so that the foals and calves can be branded. To show that
21 Commonable animals include ponies, horned cattle and donkeys.
22 Michelmas to Hocktide or 22 November to 4 May from the seventeenth century.
23 Two weeks either side of midsummer’s day.
24 Section 9.
25 Section 1(3).
26 Literally the animals that can get up and lie down on the holding.
27 Section 9(1)b New Forest Act 1949.
28 The byelaws are made under the New Forest Acts 1877 and 1949. The current byelaws were
made by New Forest (Confirmation of the Verderers of the New Forest) Order 1999.
29 The Verderers may vary the level of marking fees for animals that are pastured by common-
ers, non-commoners and Crown tenants—ss 9(3) & (4) New Forest Act 1949. Also under The
Commons Agreement 1964, the commoners of the adjacent common withdrew their opposition to
the New Forest Act 1964 in return for reduce marking fees until 2025.
The New Forest: Ancient Forest And Modern Playground 291
marking fees have been paid the ponies tails are cut in a distinctive design,
according to which area of the forest they roam, and the cattle’s ears are tagged.
These drifts also provide an opportunity to check on the condition of the stock
and to worm and inoculate as necessary. Owners who wish to sell their stock
can also identify their stock and take them off the forest. A series of pony and
cattle sales are held to coincide with the drifts.
There are a few rights to graze sheep that are mostly attached to the old monas-
tic lands of Beaulieu and Godshill or over some of the adjacent commons.30
Right of Mast
The right to turn out pigs during the pannage season serves a dual purpose. The
commoners can fatten their pigs on the autumn harvest of acorns and beech
mast while removing these crops, which can be fatal if consumed by ponies or
cattle. The pannage season historically ran from 25 September until 22
November but is now a period of not less than 60 days set by the Forestry
Commission in consultation with the Verderers.31 The right is subject to the
common law rules of levancy and couchancy and the Verderers’ byelaws, which
provide that the pigs must be ringed to prevent routing.
There is also a recognised privilege to turn out breeding sows throughout the
year, providing that they can return to the commoner’s holding each night.
Right to Estovers
The old forest laws prevented the felling of trees or the removal of cover but the
right to estovers allows the collection of dead wood for fuel that can be burnt in
the hearth of the holding to which the right is attached. The right can only be
exercised with ‘the view and allowance of the foresters’ and is now controlled
by the Forestry Commission, who meet it largely from the felling of trees from
the inclosures. The entitlement is measured in cords, being a stack of wood mea-
suring eight foot long by four feet wide and high.
As the Crown became increasingly concerned with timber production during
the nineteenth century they sought to reduce the number of commoners holding
estovers by buying in the right whenever possible. Recent records show that less
than one hundred properties still enjoy the right.
30
Eg Penn Common.
31
Section 7 New Forest Act 1964.
292 Sarah Nield
Right of Turbary
The right of turbary, being the right to cut turves, could also satisfy a com-
moner’s fuel requirements in the days before an effective national fuel distribu-
tion system, although it is no longer exercised today.
The right could only be exercised with ‘the view and allowance of the
foresters’. Commoners had to apply to the Crown for a ticket authorising the
cutting of a certain number of turves for a small fee. The rule was that for every
turf cut two should be left to allow for natural regeneration.
There was also an established privilege for commoners to cut and collect
gorse and holly for winter feed and bracken for bedding for their stock. The
privilege is rarely exercised nowadays.
Right of Marl
The right to dig clay from designated marl pits in the south of the forest is also
no longer practised. The clay was used both as a fertiliser and as a building
material for the traditional cob cottages of the area.
The exercise of these rights and privileges formed the basis of an economic
system of farming that only declined after the Second World War.32
Commoners could keep a much larger head of stock than their farms or small-
holdings could otherwise sustain by taking advantage of their right to pasture
their stock on the forest. They could also keep overheads low by capitalising on
the forest produce to supplement their own fuel requirements and feed and bed-
ding for their stock. Beef and dairy cattle were grazed on the forest and their
produce sold to the local market. The ponies could be profitably sold in the days
before motorised transport while pigs could be bought cheap to be fattened on
the autumn harvest.
Commoning no longer remains economic by any yardstick. Its economic
value lies more in the picturesque draw that ponies grazing on the forest hold for
the many visitors to the forest. But the commoning community remains a strong
and vibrant part of forest life. Stock levels on the forest remain robust as the
commoners staunchly maintain their traditions and social ties. Newcomers to
the forest who find their properties enjoy rights to pasture stock on the forest
sometimes take to the tradition with as much enthusiasm as those whose fami-
lies have done so for generations. Some measures have been taken to try and
support commoning including the schemes to improve the quality and mar-
ketability of New Forest ponies, to subsidise marking fees33 and to providing
assistance to commoners priced out of the local property market.34
32 For a more detailed account of commoning see Tubbs, above n 6, Ch 7.
33 A local premium scheme for ponies and cattle was established by the Countryside Commission
in 1983, it is now administered by the Verderers.
34 New Forest Commoners’ Housing Trust.
The New Forest: Ancient Forest And Modern Playground 293
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
The New Forest has a long and fascinating history but there is only scope in this
paper to provide an overview.35 For this purpose the history of the forest falls
into three broad periods. Firstly, its importance as a royal hunting forest dating
from the Norman conquest until the Stuart period when the forest was subject
to the separate jurisdiction of the forest law for the protection of the vert and
the venison. Secondly its importance as a source of timber, mainly for the navy.
This period saw the first enclosures to promote the growth of timber, protected
from damage caused by grazing stock and browsing deer. Finally there is the his-
tory of the modern forest dating from the passing of the New Forest Act 1877
when the Crown’s wish to partition and enclosure the forest was finally
defeated. This period has seen the often fine balancing of the interests of the
Crown and the commoners. Over recent decades there has also been the need to
accommodate the growing number of visitors to the forest, who wish to take
advantage of its recreational opportunities, whilst continuing to conserve its
unique landscape and ecology.
William the Conqueror established the New Forest some time between 1066 and
1086. It is likely that the area was a royal hunting preserve even before that time
but what is clear is that William enforced the forest law with greater rigour than
any of his predecessors. The forest laws applied to both Crown and private land
within the perambulation of the royal forests and were administered by a
distinct hierarchy of forest officials and enforced through a separate system of
forest courts.
The aim of the forest law was to protect the deer, or venison, and the woods
and cover, or vert, upon which they depended. The significance of the royal
hunting forests lay beyond the mere enjoyment of sport, they were an important
source of provisions to the royal court at a time of low agricultural production.
The penalties for breach of forest laws imposed by the Norman kings could be
35 For more detailed accounts of the forest’s history see D Stagg, A Calendar of New Forest
Documents 1244–1334, Hampshire Record Series Vol 3 (Hampshire County Council, 1979) and A
Calendar of New Forest Documents 15th–17th Centuries Hampshire Record Series Vol 5
(Hampshire County Council 1983), A Pasmore, Verderers of the New Forest (Pioneer Publications
Ltd 1977), Tubbs, above n 6, Chs 5 & 6.
294 Sarah Nield
severe including mutilation and even death but later medieval kings preferred to
use the forest laws as an opportunity to raise revenue.
Our knowledge of forest law is gleaned from a number of forest statutes36 and
sources,37 none of which give a comprehensive view but tantalising insights into
a system of law that was finally only abolished with the passing of the Wild
Creatures and Forest Laws Act 1971. The main aspects of forest law prevented
the killing and chasing of deer and other wild beast of the forest, the felling of
trees or the clearance of cover, the keeping of hounds within the forest and the
lamming of other dogs, which might worry the deer.
Agriculture was also restricted. Stock had to be removed during winter heyn-
ing and fence month so that they did not compete with the deer and prohibitions
on the enclosure (purpastures) and cultivation (assarts) of land within the forest
limited cultivation. When the Crown’s interest shifted towards the raising of
revenue, encroachments were tolerated with the imposition of an initial fine and
the subsequent collection of yearly rents. By the seventeenth century these rents
were no longer systematically collected, although the foresters would still
declare the Crown’s rights by entering the land to fire a ritual shot once a year.
The exercise of common rights also provided another opportunity to collect
revenue.
The forest law was administered by a panoply of officials headed by the Lord
Warden down to the Foresters, who maintained the forest, and the Agisters or
Riders, who monitored the exercise of common rights. Private land within the
forest and even land that had been part of the forest but had been disafforested
did not escape regulation. Woodwards had to be appointed over private land
and Rangers over the disafforested land or purlieus.
The lowest forest court was the Court of Attachment at which offences
against the vert were brought by the Foresters to be heard before the Verderers.
There were four elected Verderers who appear to have played a role similar to
that of coroners. They settled the issue and the facts, with the assistance of local
witnesses and later juries, and attached the offender for later judgement and sen-
tencing by the forest justices. Attachment could be of the person, ie imprison-
ment, but only for the most serious offences or for repeated offenders. Usually
attachment took the form of seizure of goods or the taking pledges or sureties to
ensure the offender’s attendance before the forest justices.
The Forest Eyre was the highest court and was held periodically to pass judge-
ment and sentence and to collect the resulting fines. It also had administrative
functions. Under its auspices Regarders were appointed to conduct a regard, or
survey, of the forest and report to the justices on the condition of the forest. No
doubt this survey itself would have revealed a number of forest offences that had
escaped the notice, whether innocent or deliberate, of the Foresters.
36 Charter of the Forest 1217 reissued 1225, Statute of 1293, Ordinances of 1305 and 1306, and
the Statute of 1327, Statute of Purveyors 1350, Statute of 1383, Order and Rules of the Forest 1537.
37 Dialogus de Scaccoria of 1175 by Richard FitzNigel, Assize of Woodstock 1184, Leges Henrici
Primi, J Manwood, Treatise and Discourse on the Lawes of the Forest (1598).
The New Forest: Ancient Forest And Modern Playground 295
Between these two courts the court structure is a little obscure. The sources
refer to a Court of Swainmote, which was to be held three times a year to coin-
cide with the pannage season, fence month and Michelmas, when the payment
of grazing dues was made. The Verderers and Agisters attended the pannage
and Michelmas courts, but the Verderers alone attended the fence month
court.38 In time the Court of Swainmote may have been held at the same time or
even became part of the Verderers’ Court of Attachment. There is also evidence
of the holding of special inquests or inquisitions to enquire into the events sur-
rounding a serious venison offence and to general inquests to enquire into any
offences that may have been committed during a certain time period within a
particular area. These inquests appear to have been held before the forest jus-
tices or their deputies.
During the medieval period the trees of the forest provided building materials
and the underwood was cut to provide firewood, wattle fencing and other
domestic products. Underwood was encouraged through natural regeneration
in coppices from which the deer were excluded but it was not until the Tudor
and Stuart periods that the Crown’s interest began to turn to the timber pro-
ducing potential of the forest. Greater agricultural efficiency coupled with the
increase in trade, which called for more ships, underpinned this change of focus.
There was a decline in the enforcement of forest law39 and an overhaul of the
administration of timber resources in the forest. An Act of 1542 created a new
administrative structure for the Crown forests headed by the Surveyor General
of the King’s Woods with a Deputy Surveyor responsible for the New Forest.
The Lord Wardens establishment remained so there was a dual administrative
structure within the forest, the one concerned with the vert and the venison and
the other responsible for timber production.
Coppicing was abolished and early enclosure sanctioned by An Act for the
Increase and Preservation of Timber in 1689, which provided for the planting
and enclosure of two thousand acres with two hundred acres to be added annu-
ally for twenty years. In fact progress was slow and only 3296 acres was ever
enclosed under this statute. A survey that was ordered by George III at the end
of the eighteenth century40 concluded that the forest was in a sorry economic
state. It was highly critical of the dual administrative structure whose aims more
often competed than coincided. They also were critical of the now uneconomic
preservation of the forest deer and the open abuse of common rights. Their
report eventually resulted in a further inclosure act in 1808, which confirmed the
38 There may have been a fourth court held at winter heyning.
39 The last Forest Eyre was held in 1670.
40 Fifth Report of Commissioners to Enquire into Woods Forests and Land Revenues of the
Crown 1789.
296 Sarah Nield
1689 Act and provided for an additional six thousand acres of inclosures. There
was also some reform of the administrative structure with the appointment of
the Commissioner for Woods in 1810. However it was with the Deer Removal
Act 1851 that the Crown finally made a concerted effort to capitalise on the
timber potential of its estate in the New Forest. The act provided for the
removal of all deer from the forest within a period of three years. The Crown
was compensated for their loss with the grant of power to enclosure a further
ten thousand acres, making a total of sixteen thousand acres that could be
enclosed at any one time. Forest administration was overhauled with the Lord
Warden establishment dismantled and absorbed into Office of Woods, which
become solely responsible for protecting and promoting the Crown’s interests in
the forest. The act also provided for the registration of common rights and
rather surprisingly, given the removal of the deer, restated the fence month and
winter heyning restrictions. These provisions are perhaps only explicable in the
light of the Crown’s wider agenda that became evident in the years following the
act, which was to reduce the value of the commoners’ rights as a prelude to par-
tition and enclosure of the forest. This agenda was to be frustrated however by
the battle that developed between the Crown and the commoners over the exer-
cise and extent of the Crown’s enclosure powers.
A powerful lobby of large landowners, who were as keen as the smaller com-
moners to preserve the common rights attached to their estates, drove the oppo-
sition to partition. They did not stand to benefit from partition because of the
higher rents that they could derive from their farms that enjoyed common
rights. Valuable support was also derived from the emergent conservation
lobby. The new railways were bringing visitors to the forest in ever-increasing
numbers and the general enclosure movement had roused those keen to protect
what common land remained.
Matters came to a head with the outcry that resulted when a bill for disaf-
forestation was introduced in 1871. The bill was abandoned following a House
of Commons resolution that no more trees should be felled or inclosures made
until further legislation. The legislation that emerged was the New Forest Act
1877, which followed the recommendations of a Select Committee of the House
of Commons that reported in 1875.
The New Forest Act 1877 put pay to the Crown’s hopes of partitioning the for-
est. It balanced the interests of the Crown and the commoners by limiting the
Crown’s powers of enclosure to that sanctioned by previous acts and limited the
total area that could be enclosed to sixteen thousand acres.41 The winter heyn-
ing and fence month restrictions were commuted to nominal payments so the
41 Ss 5, 6 and 7.
The New Forest: Ancient Forest And Modern Playground 297
commoners were free to pasture their stock throughout the year.42 The Court of
Verderers was reconstituted to represent the interests of the commoners and
control the exercise of commoners’ rights.43 The act also recognised the need to
preserve the ancient and ornamental woodlands and to maintain the open
forest.44
The act was dubbed ‘The Commoners Charter’ but it did not immediately put
pay to the bitter conflict between the Crown and the commoners. Skirmishes
continued between the Crown, represented by the Office of Woods and the com-
moners, represented by the Court of Verderers. Every real or imagined attempt
to limit or infringe the commoners’ rights was taken up by the Verderers.
Relations between the Verderers and the Crown, represented by the Forestry
Commission after 1923, only entered an era of more constructive partnership in
the late 1920s.
The forest was not immune from the significant changes to social and eco-
nomic life witnessed during the twentieth century nor from the military impact
of the two world wars. Indeed its open spaces proved most useful for military
manoeuvres and for the siting of various military establishments. It became
clear at the end of the Second World War that a major review was required. This
was undertaken and resulted in the Baker Report,45 named after its chairman,
whose recommendations formed the basis of the New Forest Act 1949.
The Act sought to resolve the conflicts that had dogged the relations between
the Verderers and the Forestry Commission. One of it the main thrusts was to
overhaul the Verderers’ Court to reflect a wider constituency of those with inter-
ests in the forest.46 This was achieved by increasing the number of Verderers by
the addition of appointed members representing the Ministry of Agriculture,
Fisheries and Foods, the Forestry Commission, the local planning authority
and conservation interests. The commoners continued to be represented by
Verderers elected from within their number.
The Act sought to satisfy the Forestry Commission’s desire for greater timber
production and the commoners’ growing concern with the toll taken on their
stock by road accidents with what became known as the Verderers’ Inclosures.47
It authorised the enclosure of a further five thousand acres of open forest on
terms to be agreed between the Forestry Commission and the Verderers.48 These
inclosures were to be sited so as to try and prevent stock roaming onto the major
roads and to screen the growing towns fringing the east and west of the forest
but they have proved controversial and only two thousand five hundred acres
have been enclosed.
42
Section 9.
43
Ss 14–25.
44
Section 8.
45
Cmnd 7245.
46
Sections 1, 2 & 3.
47
Section 2.
48
The terms agreed were for periods of 150 years subject to the inclosures being thrown open to
stock by at least 2015 and compensation for loss of grazing being paid to the Verderers.
298 Sarah Nield
The Act also made the first proposals for the fencing of the forest’s main
roads to prevent stock deaths through accidents.49 This development was more
successful and has been taken further by the New Forest Acts 1964 and 1970 so
that all the main roads through the forest as well as the forest perambulation are
now fenced.50
The Act also regulated the Forestry Commission’s power to grant licences
allowing the use of the forest for various public purposes, including utility and
recreational facilities as well as car parks, by requiring the consent of the
Verderers and the payment of compensation to reflect the loss to common
rights.51 In 1964 these provisions were extended to allow for the provision of
campsites on the open forest.52
The poor quality of some of the grazing within the forest was addressed by
giving the Forestry Commission responsibility for the drainage and the clear-
ance of seedlings and coarse herbage and by incorporating provisions intended
to try and improve the grazing.53 The act also widened the powers of the
Verderers to make byelaws for the control of stock.54
Finally the Act granted the Forestry Commission power to enclose parts of
the ancient and ornamental woodlands to encourage their regeneration.55 The
New Forest Act 1964 built on this power by authorising the Forestry Commis-
sion to carry out maintenance works within these woodlands.56 Innocuous as
these provisions first appeared they proved most controversial.
The 1949 Act set the scene for the major issues that have dominated forest
politics during the rest of the twentieth century, namely the Forestry
Commissions’ concern with commercial silviculture and amenity development
within the forest.
The Forestry Commission has relinquished their commercial forestry aspira-
tions only gradually and reluctantly. They adopted a policy of reducing the area
of broadleaf woodlands and increasing the conifer plantations, which reached a
head in the woodland crisis of the late 1960s and early 1970s. The Forestry
Commission under their statutory regeneration powers clear felled significant
areas of the ancient and ornamental woodlands. A public outcry resulted which
was only quelled by a mandate issued in 1971 by the then Minister, James Prior,
which directed that commercial timber production and conifer planting within
the forest was to cease, with a restoration of the broadleaf woodland traditional
to the forest. The Mandate, the essence of which has subsequently been
49
Section 16.
50
The roads presently fenced are the A 31, A35 and A337.
51
Section 18.
52
Sections 6 New Forest Act 1964.
53
Sections 11 and 14. Section 3 of the New Forest Act 1970 conferred upon the Verderers a gen-
eral power to undertake grazing improvements, subject to the agreement of the Forestry
Commission.
54
Section 9. The byelaws are subject to confirmation by the Minister.
55
Section 13.
56
Section 10(3).
The New Forest: Ancient Forest And Modern Playground 299
FOREST ADMINISTRATION
The Forestry Commission, through Forest Enterprise, the Verderers and local
planning authorities today shares responsibility for the administration of the
forest with growing input from a number of conservation bodies.
The Forestry Commission has the ultimate authority to manage the forest but
subject to the common rights. They can operate within the statutory inclosures
and their Crown freeholds without interference by the Verderers or the local
planning authority but they must do so in accordance with the directions of their
master, the government. Their management of other parts of the forest is sub-
ject to varying degrees of control by the Verderers.
The control of development of private land within the forest is subject to the
control of the local planning authority, the New Forest District Council. The
council has identified for planning purposes a New Forest Heritage Area, which
embraces not only the forest but also a broad peripheral zone around the forest
perambulation, which in historical and socio-economic terms is essentially part
57
Section 1.
300 Sarah Nield
of the forest. Within this heritage area particularly restrictive planning policy
guidelines apply, akin to those affecting National Parks.58
Conservation
The conservation organisations have a key role to play in the forest administra-
tions. By virtue of its SSSI designation the Forestry Commission and the
Verderers have a duty to consult English Nature in the exercise of their man-
agement functions and a formal Declaration of Intent has been entered into
between the three organisations. Three international designations are
significant for the forest. The first is its designation as a Special Protection Area
(SPA) in accordance with the EEC directive on the Conservation of Wild Birds
1979. The second is its designation as a ‘Ramsar Site’ under the Convention on
Wetlands of International Importance adopted at Ramsar, Iran in 1971 and
ratified by the government in 1976.60 The third arises as its likely designation as
a Special Area of Conservation under the EU Directive on the Conservation of
Natural Habitats and of Wild Fauna and Flora 1992.61The directive has been
implemented in this country through the Conservation (Natural Habitats)
Regulations 1994,62 which call for the primary objective of management to be
nature conservation.
58 The proposed National Park boundary is even larger than this heritage area.
59 For instance the Wiltshire County Council, National Farmers Union and the Country
Landowners Association.
60 Cmnd 6465, Treaty series No 34, 1976.
61 92/43/EEC.
62 SI No 2716, 1994.
The New Forest: Ancient Forest And Modern Playground 301
THE VERDERERS
The Verderers of today take their name from their medieval forbears, who as
elected judicial officers of the Crown, presided over the Courts of Attachments
and Swainmote, hearing offences against the vert. The Verderers are still con-
cerned with the preservation of the open forest but their primary interest is to
protect the common rights rather than those of the Crown.
Although the power and functions of the Verderers under the forest law has
been preserved,63 the Verderers of today are constituted and derive their powers
and functions from statute.
Constitution
The Verderers as constituted under the New Forest Act 1877 were more closely
allied to the commoners than today. Under this Act there was one Official
Verderer, nominated by Her Majesty and six elected Verderers elected by open
ballot by the parliamentary electors within forest and the registered common-
ers.64 The qualification to stand as a Verderer was the holding of not less than
seventy five acres of land subject to common rights.65
The Baker Committee concluded that the composition of the court was in
need of amendment. They felt it inadequately reflected an appropriate balance
between all those with a legitimate interest in the forest, the Verderers’ property
qualification was unduly restrictive,66 and the open voting procedures were
undemocratic. The New Forest Act 1949 addressed these failings by increasing
the number of Verderers to ten comprising the Official Verderer, five elected
verderers and five appointed verderers representing the Government, the
Forestry Commission, the local planning authority and such body as may be
designated as having special responsibility for amenity within the countryside.67
The property qualification for elected Verderers was reduced to the occupation
of not less than one acre to which the right of pasture is attached.68 The fran-
chise for elected Verderers was reduced to persons over the age of twenty one
years in occupation of not less than one acre to which rights of common are
attached.69 Lastly voting was to be by secret ballot.70 These provisions continue
to govern the constitution of the Verderers today.
The Verderers of the New Forest have the status of a body corporate.71
63 Sections 1(2) Wild Creatures and Forest Law Act 1971.
64 Section 17.
65 Section 15.
66 By 1949 only 16 persons were eligible to stand for election.
67 Sections 1 & 7.
68 Section 2.
69 Section 3.
70 Section 5.
71 Section 33(1).
302 Sarah Nield
The Verderers are primarily concerned with the regulation of the rights of com-
mon and the maintenance and preservation of the open forest over which those
rights are exercised.
The rights of common are regulated through the Verderers’ Byelaws that the
Verderers are empowered to draft at a court comprising not less than five
Verderers for confirmation of the Minister. The byelaws apply to all stock
pastured within the forest perambulation, including the adjacent commons.72
Section 25 of the 1877 Act and section 29 of the 1949 Act define the matters over
which the Verderers can make byelaws, these include:
—the control of disease and measures for maintaining the health of stock;
—the conditions regulating the running of stallions, bulls or other entire male stock;
—the removal of animals not belonging to commoners;
—fixing the number and type of stock;
—varying payments due in respect of marking fees and for pannage;
—the ringing of pigs;
—removal of dangerous animals; and
—the regulation of rights of common.
72
By a legislative oversight the byelaws do not extend to the Manor of Minstead.
73 Section 14 New Forest Act 1949 and s 3 New Forest Act 1970.
74
Section 15 New Forest Act 1949 as amended by s 8 New Forest Act 1964.
The New Forest: Ancient Forest And Modern Playground 303
The Verderers elected following the 1877 Act took their new responsibilities to
protect common rights conscientiously. In a series of disputes with the Crown
the Verderers vigorously argued that any exploitation of the forest beyond the
Crown’s statutory inclosures was an unlawful interference with common rights
and thus required their consent. This question has never been judicially resolved
although several disputes resulted in litigation. Early legislation concerning the
use of the forest did however acknowledge the role of the Verderers both in
terms of seeking their consent and in the payment of compensation for interfer-
ence.75
Current legislation continues to acknowledge this role by requiring the
involvement of the Verderers in almost all development affecting the forest. For
instance, the Forestry Commission must consult the Verderers in carrying out
drainage work and the clearance of coarse herbage,76 licences for the running of
public utilities across the forest requires the consent of the Verderers,77 the cre-
ation of any new roads or the widening of any existing roads also involves the
Verderers78 and the exchange of forest land again requires Verderers’ consent.79
The Verderers do not have a role to play within the statutory inclosures, which
are free of common rights, but their approval is required to any work within the
unenclosed woodlands.80
In the early years the Verderers’ energies were focussed on restraining the
commercial aspiration of the Crown and Forestry Commission but since the
Forestry Commission has abandoned overt commercial silviculture, their focus
has shifted towards trying to achieve an acceptable balance between the inter-
ests of commoning, amenity and conservation. By section 23 of the Countryside
Act 1968 as amended by the New Forest Act 1970 the Verderers’ consent is
required and compensation payable for any tourist, recreational or sporting
facilities developed over the open forest.81 While section 15 of the New Forest
Act 1964 provides that in the performance of their statutory duties the
Verderers, along with the Forestry Commission, are to have due regard to the
preservation of the ecology of the forest. The forest’s national and international
designations also require the Verderers and the Forestry Commission to consult
English Nature and have regard to conservation in the discharge of their func-
tions, a duty which can conflict with their interests to maintain and improve the
available grazing.
75 See for instance New Forest (Sale of Land and Public Purposes) Act 1902.
76 Section 11 New Forest Act 1949.
77 Section 18 New Forest Act 1949.
78 Sections 16 & 17 New Forest Act 1949.
79 Section 19 New Forest Act 1964.
80 Section 13 New Forest Act 1949 and s 10 New Forest Act 1964.
81 See also s 18 New Forest Act 1949 as amended by s 6 New Forest Act 1964.
304 Sarah Nield
Judicial Functions
Although the Verderers rarely resort to the exercise of their judicial functions,
they do have power to enforce their own and the Forestry Commission’s
byelaws82 and to inquire into all unlawful inclosures, encroachments and tres-
passes to the forest.83 Following the abolition of forest law and repeal of asso-
ciated statutes by the Wild Creatures and Forest Laws Act 1971, the Verderers’
powers under the old forest law remain obscure and of little practical value.84
The 1949 Act provides that the when exercising their judicial functions the
court should comprise the Official Verderer and four other Verderers appointed
by the Lord Chancellor, of whom not less than three should be elected.85 By the
1877 Act each Verderer is granted the same powers as a justice of the peace and
the court, when transacting judicial business, the same powers as a Magistrates’
Court, including the same powers to recover any fines that the Verderers may
impose.86 A right of appeal lies to the Crown Court.87
82
Sections 47(3) Forestry Act 1967.
83
Section 23(4) New Forest Act 1877.
84
Though it saves the functions of the Verderers see s 1(2) and s 23(5) New Forest Act 1877.
85
Section 8.
86
Sections 33–5.
87 Section 36 New Forest Act 1877.
The New Forest: Ancient Forest And Modern Playground 305
The Verderers’ open courts and the method of making presentments provides
an interesting example of local democracy and consultation. The court is always
well attended and provides an effective forum for debate on forest matters and
a sensitive barometer of forest opinion.
CONCLUSION
How does the proposed National Park fit in with this administrative structure?
The Countryside Commission is recommending a standard appointed National
Park Authority, which will overlay the existing structures, for there are no pro-
posals to amend the New Forest legislation or to significantly reduce the devel-
opment control input of the local planning authority. They suggest that a joint
committee co-ordinate the work of the authority, the Forestry Commission and
the Verderers, presumably in a similar manner to the existing New Forest
Committee. The hope in many circles is that the Countryside Commission
would have recognised the unique features of the current administration of the
New Forest and recommended a structure that would have supported and
reinforced that administration and not merely have added another layer of
bureaucracy.88 There is a deep seated suspicion, based upon past bitter and long
experience amongst the commoners, of any shift of authority away from those
who are deeply connected with the day to day life of the forest to faceless gov-
ernment departments or statutory authorities. They know the Verderers, both
appointed and elected, and their Agisters and feel comfortable with the open-
ness of their court that provides a venue for all and sundry to air their concerns
and to receive a considered and public response.
Whatever administrative changes the National Park will bring there is no
doubt that there are significant challenges to be met. The most difficult is to
establish a balance between all the competing demands and expectations that
are made upon the forest. Conservation of this unique area must be the highest
priority but how does that balance with the public’s growing expectation to free
access and recreational freedom? The proximity of the forest to large centres of
population means it is particularly accessible.89 Tramping feet often with
accompanying dog(s), relentless cycle wheels and pounding hooves take their
toll not only on the ground over which they pass but the wildlife they disturb.
Forest Enterprise may have been forced to abandon commercial timber produc-
tion but they have not been relieved of profit objectives by their masters; thus
exploitation of the forest, whether through the sale of fallen timber or the
accommodation of visitors, remains on their agenda. Tourism and recreation
based upon the forest or the adjoining coastline also provide vital sources of
income for the local economy. The commoners and their stock may shape and
preserve the forest but how can a viable future be secured in such a bleak agri-
cultural environment? If it can, the pasture demands of their stock may cease to
be overriding in the face of the need to conserve rare mire or other habitats.
The forest’s location also makes it susceptible to both commercial and resi-
dential development. Being pinched between Southampton and Bournemouth
the forest is in danger of being nibbled from either side. The latest proposed bite
comes from plans to expanded the port facilities on Southampton Water to
Dibden Bay to the east of the forest and within the proposed National Park. It
is presently the subject of an inquiry. On the residential front house prices have
soared as commuters to as far away as London seek to make their home, or to
acquire a second home, within the forest or its environs. Local house buyers
with lower earnings potential find themselves unable to compete. In response
and in common with other areas of outstanding natural beauty, the local plan-
ning authority is contemplating policies that will restrict future house building
to meet the demands of local people.
With these challenges to meet the life of the forest will continue to be as inter-
esting as the past nine hundred years.
16
Protected Area Values: National Parks
and Public Land Ownership
CHRISTINE WILLMORE
decisions are taken about the relationship between National Park and other
objectives. The lack of an articulated strategy for the role of land owned by pub-
lic bodies—or even a debate about the role of such lands—affects the ability to
deliver National Park objectives, not least because of the influence of landown-
ers in rural communities.
Marsden et al have argued that the critical resource in a rural area is land—
and that access to property rights is critical in any group’s ability to influence the
local agenda.1 The precise significance of property rights in shaping the agenda
depends upon the other tools deployed, and in particular the role of regulatory
action that tempers the choices of landowners. In a period of movement from
state regulation to civil/self-regulation, control of property rights within a com-
munity can play an enhanced role in determining outcomes. If the state fails to
deploy its own property rights in pursuit of the full range of public policy goals,
it is failing to play an equal role in shaping the rural agenda alongside private
landowners.
INTRODUCTION
The IUCN has established a typology for protected sites. The classification can
be used both normatively and descriptively to outline the way in which sites in
each class should be managed, and to provide a descriptive classification for
sites already managed in a particular way. However there is no requirement for
countries to re-name domestic classifications to fit these categories or their
descriptors.
In total nearly nine and a half percent of the landmass of the planet is within
one of these protected areas,7 including over twelve per cent of the land area of
Europe.8 Despite the typology, ‘national park’ may not mean the same thing
everywhere,9 and even where a country affixes an IUCN descriptor, this can be
as much an aspirational statement as a description of protection actually in
place.10
Both the Countryside Agency and Scottish Executive stress the international
significance of the ‘National Park’ descriptor.11 Yet, whilst carrying the name of
a Category II site, British use of ‘National Park’ reflects neither the definition,
nor organisational approaches for Category II.
Organizational Responsibility
Ownership and management should normally be by the highest compe-
tent authority of the nation having jurisdiction over it. However, they
may also be vested in another level of government, council of indigenous
people, foundation or other legally established body which has dedicated
the area to long-term conservation.
7
12.8 million km2 . M Green and J Paine, ‘State of the World’s Protected Areas at the End of the
Twentieth Century’ IUCN World Commission on Protected Areas Symposium on ‘Protected Areas
for the 21st Century: From Islands to Networks’ Albany, Australia, 24–9 November, 1997.
8 Including 30% of the world’s Category V areas.
9 The World Commission on Protected Areas web site uses a Scottish landscape to illustrate a
Protected Areas in Europe. A Waycott, National Parks of Western Europe (Southampton Inklon,
1983).
11 New Forest National Park, Countryside Agency ‘Questions and Answers’ paper, Question 1
The objectives of Category V are those which most closely fit domestic uses
of ‘National Park’.12
Organisational Responsibility
The area may be owned by a public authority, but is more likely to
comprise a mosaic of private and public ownerships operating a variety of
management regimes. These regimes should be subject to a degree of
planning or other control and supported, where appropriate, by public
funding and other incentives, to ensure that the quality of the
landscape/seascape and the relevant local customs and beliefs arc main-
tained in the long term.
This suggests that a mosaic of public and private ownership is the most likely
mode of management for these areas, in contrast to the high level of state own-
ership envisaged for true ‘National Parks’. For Category V sites, public owner-
ship is seen as having a role, it is just not the main organizational tool. The
emphasis is upon developing partnerships with local people, including private
landowners:
Thinking on protected areas is undergoing a fundamental shift. Whereas protected
areas were once planned against people, now it is recognized that they need to be
planned with local people, and often for and by them as well.13
This organisational shift can be seen in the operation of British National Park
policy. The key to English and Welsh National Park designation is ‘the striking
12
See A New Forest National Park Authority, proposed special arrangements, http://www.
countryside.gov.uk, 2001, p 8 for Countryside Agency attitudes.
13
IUCN Task Force on Protected Landscapes Report (IUCN, 2001).
312 Christine Willmore
quality and remoteness of much of their scenery, the harmony between man and
nature it displays, and the opportunities it offers for suitable forms of recre-
ation’.14
National Parks are those extensive tracts of country where
‘by reason of
(a) their natural beauty and
(b) the opportunities they afford for open air recreation, having regard both to their
character and to their position in relation to centers of population’
1995, s 62.
18 Sandford Committee Report of the National Parks policy review committee, HMSO 1974.
19 ONS 1999.
20 Peak District, Lake District, Snowdonia, Dartmoor (1951), Pembrokeshire and the North York
Moors (1952), Yorkshire Dates and Exmoor (1954), Northumberland (1956), Brecon Beacons
(1957). Norfolk and Suffolk Broads (1989) are protected by parallel legislation: Norfolk and Suffolk
Broads Act 1988. The New Forest is part way through its statutory process for designation. The
South Downs are also under consideration.
21 Countryside Agency Regional Annual Reports, 2001.
22 Cmd 6631.
23 See C Reid, ‘National Parks (Scotland) Act 2000’ [2000] SPEL 81, 112.
Protected Area Values: National Parks and Public Land Ownership 313
with conservation.24 These differences reflect both the changing IUCN empha-
sis and experience south of the border, but in a manner differing from the
English response.25 Whilst the Scottish Executive sees social and economic
development and conservation as mutually supportive, with the balance of
interest favouring long-term protection of natural resources,26 in practice, the
aspirations of people living in the National Parks are being given headline
billing.27 Despite these differences of emphasis, on the critical question of the
role of publicly owned lands there is little difference.
There has been no significant move from private to public ownership since the
conception of National Parks in 1949. The same patchwork of ownership has
continued, with National Park objectives pursued through regulation, economic
incentives and persuasion.
Designation itself results in
—labelling: national and international status, recognition and influence
—oversight by a regulatory body with statutory remit to consult that body
before other bodies use some statutory powers
—focus upon the park as a geographical unit
—opportunities for stronger planning protection.
And there we have it: the primary difference between a National Park and any
other area of countryside is status and oversight backed by planning and finan-
cial incentives.
National Park Authorities are very much left to themselves to devise how best
to pursue their statutory objectives—a deliberate approach within the 1949 leg-
islation, which continues to form the basis of government policy:
The Government believes that individual National Park Authorities are best placed to
identify the nature of the special qualities of their Parks.28
Central agendas are deployed at arm’s length through advice, guidance and
financial incentives.29 Their success depends upon the extent to which institu-
tional representation can promote those aims.
24 National Parks (Scotland) Act 2000, s 1. Juxtaposition to urban areas has gone, and an empha-
sis upon the benefits to be had from a co-ordinated approach has been added.
25 Sandford Report 1974; National Parks in Focus, Countryside Commission 1991. A similar
approach was recommended for England and Wales but was rejected in favour of an exhortation to
‘take full account of such needs: Fit for the Future, Report of the National Park Review Panel 1991;
s 5 Environment Act 1995, DOE Circular 12/96.
26
Consultation on the National Parks (Scotland) Bill 2000.
27
See SE1378/2001 press release, 11 June 2001.
28
See paragraphs 10–15. DoE Circular 12/96.
29
The Countryside Agency (in Wales the Countryside Council) advises government and
National Park Authorities National Parks and Access to the Countryside Act, s 1.
314 Christine Willmore
This in turn relies upon the articulation of plans for the area, making concrete
the statutory aspirations. Much emphasis internationally is now placed upon
positive planning for Category V areas—working with local communities to
identify how conservation, access and economic needs can be reconciled and
promoted.30 Initially seen as a Town and Country Planning issue in Britain,31 a
wider approach analogous to the local government ‘community plan’ is now
adopted. This five yearly National Park Management Plan32 comes closest to
the concept of a Management Plan envisaged by the IUCN, but need only be a
plan for the authority on how it will carry out its functions. In practice National
Park Management Plans go beyond consideration of the authority’s own role,
and take the form of community plans exploring issues such as the future of
farming and housing, providing a practical and more detailed exposition of the
Park purposes, as applied to their area. As such they are a guide to landowners
and public agencies about strategies for the area.
Public landownership plays, at most, a minimal role. Before moving on to
consider the role of this, it is necessary to consider the other powers available
and their limitations.
Regulatory powers
30 Above.
31 A requirement to map areas of ‘mountain, moor, heath, woodland, down, cliff or foreshore’
in National Parks whose natural beauty is particularly important to conserve was added (s 43
WLCA 1981), but this lacks any linked powers to protect those areas.
32 Environment Act 1995, s 66, See DoE Circular 12/96 paragraphs 51–2; compare the National
Parks (Scotland) Act 2000, s 11, which requires a plan to also set out and co-ordinate ‘the functions
of other public bodies and office-holders so far as affecting the National Park’.
33 Most recently in consultation upon New Forest National Park status: Consultants’ Report on
and Access to the Countryside Act, s 12 as amended by Countryside Act 1968) and waterways (s 13).
35 Most significantly in planning, but also see ss 37/38 Countryside Act 1968: transferred to
National Park Authorities by the Environment Act 1995. National Parks still have a different func-
tion from the local authorities within their area eg in relation to education.
Protected Area Values: National Parks and Public Land Ownership 315
JPEL 229.
39 Compare the provisions of 1949 Act on access with the nationwide provisions of the
power alone was an important reason to extend National Park status to lowland Britain.
41 Wildlife and Countryside Act 1981, s 42.
42 Three months notice is required. Even if the Minister objects work can proceed after twelve
Planning powers
The Dower Report45 and the 1949 legislation assumed that Town and Country
Planning Act powers would play a central role in the delivery of National Park
aims. Until very recently agriculture was largely unregulated by the Planning
Acts, making any additional planning controls in National Parks a significant
benefit. Whilst the legislation differs only in relation to permitted development
rights, the assumption and practice have been of different nationally imposed
policy criteria within those schemes, differently applied locally. This anticipated
difference is delivered now (although not initially) by making National Park
Authorities the planning authority for their area.
The policy framework is largely locally derived, albeit in the light of
Countryside Agency guidance,46 so a diversity of approach to planning policies
and development control can be found within National Parks, but sharing the
common feature of exerting stronger environmental and aesthetic controls than
would be permitted elsewhere.47 There is no Planning Policy Guidance Note
devoted to National Parks—indeed National Parks are not even mentioned in
PPG9 on nature conservation or PPG15 the historic environment.48
It is anticipated in government policy that local policies within National
Parks will ‘give greater priority to restraint’.49 This is expanded upon in PPG7,50
where the Department states that ‘conservation of the natural beauty of the
countryside, and of its wildlife and cultural heritage, should be given great
weight in planning policies and development control decisions’. ‘Major devel-
opment should not take place in the National Parks . . . save in exceptional
circumstances . . .’51 where they are demonstrated to be in the public interest.
One has only to look at Trawsfyndd Nuclear Power Station and Fylingdales to
see the weakness of preservation based upon policy in this way.
These policy commitments are backed up not by extra planning controls as
such, but by lower levels of exemption from planning control: permitted devel-
opment rights are less in National Parks,52 with increased control over items
such as telephone masts,53 fish farming, and agricultural buildings,54 adding up
the countryside.
49 PPG1, para 28.
50 The Countryside: Environmental Quality and Economic and social development, see paras
4.2–4.6.
51 Paragraph 4.5 ibid See DoE Circular 12/96 paragraph 49.
52 Eg control over roof extensions to dwelling houses.
53 Telecommunications Act 1984.
54 See Town and Country Planning (Agriculture and Forestry Development in National Parks
etc) Special Development Order 1986, /1176; Brand C, ‘Planning control in national parks: the new
Special Development Order’ (1987) EG 281 (6322) 762.
Protected Area Values: National Parks and Public Land Ownership 317
to a touching of the tiller, rather than a radically different level of state control
over land use.
Economic Instruments
A second critical set of tools to influence land use are economic instruments.
Throughout the countryside, not specifically linked to National Parks, powers
exist55 to establish Management Agreements in relation to countryside to
conserve or enhance the natural beauty of land,56 with similar powers
specifically linked to conservation and access.57 National Park Authorities have
been able to enter Management Agreements since 1995, but only in the new
Scottish legislation is there a power specifically designed to deliver National
Park objectives.58 Subject to the availability of funds, these confer power to
reach agreements to secure the statutory purposes of the National Park, which
bind successors in title, and may therefore exist as long as the National Park
authority considers them to be useful.
Economic tools are also deployed through an ever more complex web of
countryside incentives, grants, agreements and subsidies. Whilst the willingness
of national agencies to enter such agreements may be greater within a National
Park than elsewhere,59 each scheme has its own criteria for funding, none
explicitly linked to the delivery of National Park objectives.
Even after the 1995 reforms, the key difference in terms of protection of land
within a national park as opposed to land outside is the way in which statutory
powers are exercised, not the nature of the powers: this is particularly important
in relation to bodies other than the National Parks Authority.
Until 1995 public bodies other than the National Parks Authority had no par-
ticular obligations in relation to National Parks—unless expressly included in
the particular statutory power—so the Ministry of Defence had no particular
obligation to have regard to National Park status when deciding how to act
within a National Park. That changed, to some extent, with the Environmental
Act 1995, which requires any public body, in exercising any function affecting
schemes with agricultural, environmental or rural objectives, run through Department for
Environment, Food and Rural Affairs.
58 National Parks (Scotland) Act 2000, s 15.
59 Currently £40million plus of public funds goes into National Parks each year from government
and EU sources by these routes. Association of National Parks http://www.anpa.gov.uk/. See for
example Agriculture Act 1986.
318 Christine Willmore
land in a National Park to “have regard” to the purposes of National Park des-
ignation.60 This applies to Ministers, public bodies, statutory undertakers and
any persons holding public office. The duty is only to “have regard”, an obliga-
tion that creates little more than a procedural or evidential burden to show the
matters have been considered.
Reference to the Scottish position again underlines the limited nature of the
English and Welsh position: in Scotland, in addition to having regard to the
general statutory purposes of the National Park, public bodies must also have
regard to the National Park Management Plan—a far more detailed and specific
agenda.61
Acquisition of land
Rather than seeking to persuade others another major tool available is to use the
property rights available to the state as a landowner.
The 1949 Act set its face against public ownership of land as a tool to deliver
national park objectives. Indeed the starting point is altogether different. At that
time the Crown was immune from statutory regulatory controls unless
expressly bought within the statutory regime. It was felt necessary in the 1949
Act in England and Wales to state that National Park controls could extend to
Crown land.62 Similarly, planning and regulatory controls, which control pri-
vate landowners, did not necessarily apply to Crown lands. Whilst these partic-
ular limitations did not apply to other lands in public ownership, they reflect an
important attitude towards one major potential owner. The roots of this British
failure to address landownership as a tool are to be found in the Dower
Report,63 which formed the starting point of the manoeuvrings in the run up to
the National Parks and Access to the Countryside Act 1949. The report recog-
nized the impracticality of widespread state ownership of land on the US model,
but saw public acquisition as an indispensable last resort. The emergent plan-
ning system—rather than state ownership of land—was the principle instru-
ment to deliver the objectives. No attention was given to the role of existing
Crown, local authority, or other public body lands in potential National Park
areas. Whilst the Treasury was willing to use the National Land Fund to sup-
port the compulsory acquisition of land for National Parks, should this prove
necessary, concerns in the Ministry of Agriculture about a loss of influence
should the Ministry of Town and Country Planning become a major rural
60
Section 62 inserted National Parks and Access to the Countryside Act, s 11A(2).
61
National Parks (Scotland) Act 2000, s 14.
62
National Parks and Access to the Countryside Act, s 101.
63
Cmd 6628 (1945); for the equivalent Scottish report see Cmd 6631. Hobhouse Report, Report
of the National Parks Committee Cmd 7121 (1947).
Protected Area Values: National Parks and Public Land Ownership 319
the benefit of the nation of lands and tenements (including buildings) of beauty or historic interest
and as regards lands for the preservation (so far as practicable) of their natural aspect features and
animal and plant life’.
Protected Area Values: National Parks and Public Land Ownership 321
and for public access and recreation, with the full rights of ownership, enabling
it to do anything not incompatible with its express purpose.74 This can secure
one key aspect of property ownership—durability of protection—as the Trust
has the unique statutory power to declare land inalienable.75 This special power
means that where the Trust and National Park aims are the consistent, owner-
ship by the Trust can be a particularly powerful tool to deliver National Park
aims in the long term.
However, the Trust’s statutory purposes are not synonymous with those of
National Parks, and even where there is overlap, the emphases or priorities can
differ. The National Trust is not obliged to follow National Park objectives any
more than other landowners—it merely has a power to do so. The Trust is sub-
ject to the views of its current leadership and, at least notionally, to the wider
membership voting at the AGM. Whilst, therefore, acquisition of land by the
National Trust can assist in the delivery of National Park objectives, this does
not necessarily follow. In any event, reliance upon a private trust places delivery
of National Park objectives within the control of the Trust’s members or man-
agement rather than making them subject to democratic accountability to the
public at large.
77 R v Somerset County Council ex parte Fewings [1995] 1 WLR 1037; League Against Cruel
Agency.
Protected Area Values: National Parks and Public Land Ownership 323
This imposes no particular duty on Crown lands to be used for the purposes of
the National Park, it merely removes any barrier to such conduct which might
otherwise be held to flow from the particular statutory purpose on which the
land is held by the Crown. Thus, land held by the Ministry of Defence can be
used for military purposes in a manner which is inconsistent with the National
Park designation: whether the scars of tank runs or defence structures such as
Fylingdales. Without section 101, if the Ministry decided to use defence land in
a less intensive manner than they might otherwise do, in order to support the
work of the National Park, this might be seen as a breach of their obligation to
make efficient use of land for the purpose held. With this provision the MoD can
agree to limit its uses to those compatible with National Park status—although
they need not do so.81
The requirement on all public bodies82 in exercising any function affecting
land in a National Park to ‘have regard’ to the objectives of National Park des-
ignation has an only slightly stronger effect.83 This does not require landowners
to use their ownership powers to deliver National Park objectives, but does
require them to demonstrate they have taken the objectives into account. Local
authority land ownership is subject to this, as well as at least Crown lands held
by government departments. How the public body reacts to this obligation as a
landowner varies. The Ministry of Defence continues to give little weight to
such matters, arguing that access and defence are inconsistent and taking its
own view of what amounts to conservation rather than acting with National
Park authorities to integrate its approach to conservation into wider strategies.
More positively, the Duchy of Lancaster, whilst giving emphasis to economic
management of resources, will respond to good proposals. The Duchy of
Cornwall, an extensive landowner in the Dartmoor National Park, contributed
positively to the introduction of enhanced access and conservation provisions
under the Dartmoor Commons Act 1986.
Defence use of National Parks was already extensive before the National
Parks were designated. Restraint of these uses depends solely upon government
policy from time to time, which at present, whilst not seeking to reduce current
defence use subjects new, renewed or intensified use to consultation, environ-
mental impact assessment and testing against planning policies.84 Planners have
no power to refuse and the Ministry conducts the test: there is no promise
not to do it, just a promise to check the impact first. The only solution proffered
to conflicts between MoD use and National Park objectives is to suggest co-
operation. This is not to say that state uses are always inconsistent (some con-
servation work has been delivered indirectly at Fylingdales for example) but
progress is incidental and ad hoc.
The Forestry Commission Crown land holding illustrates the problems of
seeking to reconcile specific statutory purposes with other statutory policy
objectives. As managers of 40 per cent of the New Forest,85 the Forestry
Commission could play a central role in delivery of National Park objectives.
However, the Forestry Commission’s statutory role is to:
81 In practice the Ministry of Defence and National Park Authorities have a working memoran-
lic office.
83 National Parks and Access to the Countryside Act s 11A(2).
84 Currently to be found in DoE Circular 12/96 paragraphs 56–7.
85 A New Forest National Park Authority, proposed special arrangements, Countryside Agency,
2001.
Protected Area Values: National Parks and Public Land Ownership 325
Only in 1995 was any wider agenda incorporated into the statutory role of
the Commission, and then as a response to the Habitats Directive87 as opposed
to being part of any wider rethink of the role of Crown lands in delivering
underlying government objectives. Even then, the provision only requires the
Commission to:
so far as may be consistent with the proper discharge of those functions, endeavour to
achieve a reasonable balance between the development of afforestation, the manage-
ment of forests and the production and supply of timber, and the conservation and
enhancement of natural beauty and the conservation of flora, fauna and geological or
physiographical features of special interest88
This falls well short of the National Park aims, in particular excluding reference
to recreation,89 and subjects any balance to the primary duty of the proper dis-
charge of the forestry function. How far the Forestry Commission actually
delivers recreation or conservation therefore depends on its national policy
approach to their primary duty and upon local working relationships and man-
agement decisions. This can lead to patchy outcomes. In contrast to public con-
cerns voiced in the New Forest about the Forestry Commission, in the North
York Moors the Parks Authority and Forestry have developed a range of access
opportunities.
This is by no means an isolated example. In many cases no such ‘balance’
clause exists, but even where they exist, such clauses are subject to a primary
purpose. Indeed Crown lands are potentially less subject to National Park
objectives than other lands within the park because of the differential applica-
tion of restrictions available in relation to Crown lands through planning and
other regulatory provisions. The Crown is seen as being subject to fewer oblig-
ations to deliver otherwise universal policy objectives in a whole host of areas:
the starting point being that the Crown is not subject to regulatory measures,
unless the authorising statute expressly extends that control to include the
Crown.
The status of the Sandringham Estate in Norfolk, whilst not in a National
Park, exemplifies the complexity of the current position—and the complete lack
of any principled overview of the role of Crown lands. The estate was purchased
by the Prince of Wales in the nineteenth century, but is currently held by the
Monarch in her personal capacity. In 1949 the Agents took the view that the
land was not subject to the Definitive Map provisions of National Parks and
Access to the Countryside Act. As a result, no public rights of way appear on the
ing many Parliamentary Questions in the 1980s, but has improved in recent years.
326 Christine Willmore
Definitive Map covering the Sandringham Estate. This is not to say that public
rights of way do not exist—only that the statutory duty to map was perceived
as not applying. Whether the estate was entitled to do this depends not on an
overarching principle of Crown lands, but upon the complex question of the
precise nature of the Queen’s title to this land.
What emerges is a fragmentary view of Crown and other public ownership of
land, with a series of ad hoc statutory efforts to reconcile conflicting policy
objectives in relation to the use of land. This is in contrast to the US approach
at least in relation to unappropriated land owned by the federal government.
Congress regulates the use and disposal of public lands.90 Congress has all the
powers of ownership91 and may deal with public lands as a private individual
would deal with their property, which may include putting the environmental
above economic considerations92 as long as it protects and preserves the land for
the public,93 with disposal at a fair market rent limited to disposals which will
‘serve the national interest’.94 A coherent, published, scheme of public policy
objectives are applied when taking land use decisions.95
The US approach has not had to cope with the fragmentation and historical
complexities of Crown land holdings, and it is not possible even to begin to
articulate an equivalent approach to Crown lands in Britain in general. It is only
possible to do so in relation to particular parcels of land, where the particular
statute authorizing the land holding has set out the criteria upon which man-
agement decisions are to be taken. Where such criteria exist, for example in rela-
tion to unappropriated Crown Estate, they are found to be purely economic:
good management to maintain value.
CONCLUSION
This lack of an articulated strategy for the role of lands held by public bodies—
and even of a debate about their role—affects the ability to deliver National
Park objectives, not least because of the influence of landowners in rural com-
munities.
Ultimately, the 1949 legislators did not see property ownership as necessary
in the light of the anticipated power of the Town and Country Planning Act
1947, but in a time of deregulation it may be wise to review the role of landown-
ership in achieving National Park (and other) goals.
90
US Const. Art IV. §3, cl 2. Public lands see 43 USCA, §1702.
91 State of Alabama v State of Texas 347 US 272.
92 Sinclair v US 279 US 263.
93 Utah Power Co v United States (CA8 Utah) 230 F 328.
94 43 USCA, §1701.
95 §1701(8): ‘the public lands be managed in a manner that will protect the quality of scientific,
scenic, historical, ecological, environmental, air and atmospheric, water resource, and archeologi-
cal values; that, where appropriate, will preserve and protect certain public lands in their natural
condition; that will provide food and habitat for fish and wildlife and domestic animals; and that
will provide for outdoor recreation and human occupancy and use’.
Protected Area Values: National Parks and Public Land Ownership 327
In relation to the National Park objectives there has never been a commitment
to place those objectives above the freedoms of landowners, except on a case-
by-case approach through planning and other regulatory schemes. This is as
true for the public bodies as landowners as for any other landowners. Use of
public body ownership of land to deliver National Park objectives would
require those bodies to articulate a strategy for use of its land, with an explicit
and overarching understanding of the interplay between different public policy
objectives. By failing to articulate a strategy, those statutory aims which require
land ownership for their implementation, such as defence training lands which
requires land to train on, or forestry which requires land upon which to grow
the trees, are inevitably placed above those which are not seen as requiring
land ownership such as conservation: these can be delivered on privately owned
land.
Instead of a concerted approach to Crown ownership of land, there are a
series of skirmishes: between horse riders and the Forestry Commission about
public recreation on Crown Estate; between environmentalists and the Ministry
of Defence; between the Council for the Protection of Rural England and the
Property Services Agency concerning land disposals for development. Is this
fragmented approach to Crown ownership still appropriate?
17
The Crichel Down Rules: Conduct
or Misconduct in the Disposal of
Public Lands?
ROGER GIBBARD
INTRODUCTION
1
[1957] 1 QB 485.
2
As, for instance, was the situation with the Channel Tunnel Rail Link land purchase.
3
Department of the Environment—Disposal of surplus government land: Obligation to offer
land back to former owners or their successors—The Crichel Down Rules (October 1992) (HMSO).
330 Roger Gibbard
Rules, itself a controversial process, and will proceed to examine the operation
of the current rules from the perspective of justice.
Research was conducted on behalf of the former Department of the
Environment, Transport and the Regions (DETR),4 as part of the review of
compulsory purchase and compensation.5 Many of the recommendations of
the report have been included in the Government’s Planning Green Paper6
published at the end of 2001 and will be referred to in this paper.
In the history of modern parliament, the Crichel Down affair takes on momen-
tous significance, and has been described as a ‘political bombshell’.7 The public
inquiry8 established in April 1954 into the Crichel Down events revealed a
catalogue of ineptitude and maladministration and resulted directly in the res-
ignation of the Secretary of State for Agriculture (Sir Thomas Dugdale) in July
1954. The post was at that time a senior cabinet position, and was the first case
of Ministerial resignation since 1917. Whilst the underlying case was, in the
scale of things, trivial, involving the transfer of some seven hundred acres of
mediocre agricultural land in Dorset, the ramifications for subsequent govern-
ment procedure have been enormous. One of the accepted rules of Ministerial
Responsibility to Parliament, whereby a Minister accepts responsibility for the
actions of his officers, was laid down in the aftermath of the affair, and Crichel
Down is regarded as one of the key events leading to the creation of the post of
Ombudsman.9 Crichel Down was probably the first instance of close and very
public scrutiny being directed at a Minister of the Crown in the execution of his
duties.
The significance today of the events of fifty years ago is two-fold. Firstly, and
the main topic for this paper, are the Rules themselves, and the way in which
they impact on the management of public sector estates. Secondly, the profound
effect that the events had on the principle of ministerial responsibility10 and on
the relationship between Government and the Civil Service11 is not to be under-
4
Department of the Environment, Transport and the Regions: The operation of the Crichel
Down rules [2000].
5
Published as: Department for Transport, Local Government and the Regions [2001]
Compulsory Purchase and Compensation—the Government’s proposals for Change, Chapter 5.
This forms part of the Government’s Green Paper on Planning below n 6.
6 Department of Local Government, Transport and the Regions Planning: Delivering a funda-
brochure
The Crichel Down Rules 331
estimated. This assumes relevance today in the light of this Government’s pen-
chant for ‘joined up’ government, and is behind much of the ethos surrounding
the current application of the Rules, and of the wider functioning of Govern-
ment departments.
In terms of land disposals, the Rules are of ever-increasing importance. Most
notable are the disposals of Ministry of Defence (MoD) lands under the MoD
Strategic Defence Review,12 under which the Defence Estate are targeting dis-
posals of £700m by March 2002. It has been estimated that approximately five
hundred sites are sold each year in the South East alone13 and listed on the
Defence Estates website as current disposals include for example land at
Chelsea, Millbank, Woolwich, Didcot, Thatcham and Farnborough. Some take
on national importance, such as the disposals of former RAF sites at Bentwaters
and Upper Heyford. At the time of the research, there were over two hundred
and forty MoD sites on the market, all of which were being considered under
the Rules. Similar examples can be drawn from the National Health Service
(NHS), challenged with making disposals of £1.2bn over the next five years.
Other significant disposing authorities include the Highways Agency, the
former British Rail,14 and the privatised water authorities, all of whom have
developed their own disposal strategies.
The Crichel Down Rules relate to the disposal of land formerly acquired by,
or under the threat of, compulsory purchase. They set out the procedures for
offering former owners the opportunity to repurchase land that was acquired
from them and which has since become surplus to the purpose for which it was
acquired. The Rules themselves are complex, having been developed piecemeal
over a number of years,15 their applicability is uncertain (for some bodies they
are mandatory, for others, merely discretionary), and their precise authority far
from clear. Moreover, they exist only as non-statutory guidance.
The principle of offering to former owners surplus land acquired under com-
pulsory powers dates back to the Lands Clauses Consolidation Act 1845.16 The
Rules themselves however were first published as a Treasury Circular in 195417
in response to the recommendations of the Clark Report, above n 8.
The Crichel Down ‘case’18 concerned land acquired by the Air Ministry from
the Crichel Estate and others, and used during the Second World War as a
bombing range. After the war, the land became surplus to requirements, and the
former owners, particularly one Commander Marten, sought to repurchase.
12
Ministry of Defence, The Strategic Defence Review White Paper: Modern forces for a modern
World. Cmnd 3999. (NSO, London, 1998).
13
J Doak, ‘Planning for the reuse of redundant Defence estate: disposal Processes, policy
Frameworks and development impacts’ [1999] Planning Practice and Research Vol 14 (2) 211–4.
14
Through the property division, Rail Property Ltd.
15
I Smith, ‘Managing Defence Estates’ [2001] htpp:/www.publicservice.co.uk/pdf/central-gov
16
Sections 127–32. These actually went further than the current rules in many respects, includ-
ing the right of neighbours to be considered in the offer-back procedure where former owners
declined to purchase.
17
No.6/54.
18 Not a ‘case’ in strict legal terms, as no judicial proceedings were involved.
332 Roger Gibbard
Despite early representations made by Marten and others, the Air Ministry
decided to transfer the land to the Commissioners of Crown Lands (one of
whom was the Minister of Agriculture), on the grounds of maximising produc-
tion, and subsequently to let to one pre-selected tenant. Further representations,
and the ensuing and protracted public disquiet, with accusations of civil service
cover-up, ministerial corruption and departmental maladministration,19 led to
the establishment of a public inquiry20 in April 1954. In reporting on the inquiry
findings to the House of Commons, full ministerial responsibility for the affair
was accepted by Dugdale, who promptly resigned from the Government,21
effectively ending his political career and those of a number of civil servants. In
his resignation speech, the Minister set out the main principles on which future
disposals of surplus land would be based, adding that the procedure would be
applied retrospectively to Crichel Down. The Clark Inquiry itself has been sub-
ject to considerable criticism,22 Clark himself being accused of incompetence
and arrogance.23 The detail of the events is beyond the scope of this paper, and
is well-documented elsewhere.24
In the ensuing years, the Rules developed in a piecemeal fashion, in response
to changing economic and political imperatives, and as a result of several key
decisions of the courts.
The 1954 Rules placed a duty on some government bodies to consider
whether the offer-back procedure should apply, and if so, the procedure that
should be followed. Significantly there was no statutory right granted to former
owners. The offer-back procedure only applied to land which was agricultural
at the time of the acquisition. There were a number of exceptions,25 where the
offer back procedure would not apply; the most important being where the land
had been so substantially altered in character that it could not be returned sat-
isfactorily to agricultural use, and a pre-emptive right to transfer land to another
government department who would themselves have been able to justify the use
of compulsory purchase. Where the Rules did apply, the repurchase was to be
at the current market price as assessed by the District Valuer, not at the historic
price at which the original compulsory purchase took place.
Replacement Rules were published in 1957,26 substantially modifying the
1954 set. Certain ‘special procedures’ were introduced which more formally
recognised that the land, if still predominantly agricultural, could be transferred
without offer-back to other departments or public bodies as long as they had
above n 22.
25 Now contained in Rule 14.
26 Treasury Circular No.5/57 and No.5/57(Addendum).
The Crichel Down Rules 333
The current Rules were published by the DoE and the Welsh Office on
30 October 1992. Strictly they apply to government departments including
executive agencies and non-departmental public bodies but additionally are
commended to, but are not binding on, Local Authorities and bodies in the pri-
vate sector to which public sector land holdings have been transferred eg the pri-
vatised utilities. This, and the fact that statutory development bodies are
exempt, is a source of much confusion and conflict32 Where a government body
falls under the Rules, freehold disposals of the following will be covered; land
acquired by or under the threat of compulsion or by voluntary sale, if the power
to acquire the land compulsorily had existed at the time of acquisition, and land
acquired under the blight conditions in the Town and Country Planning Act
1990.
The presumption in the Rules is that former owners or their successors will
be given a first opportunity of purchasing the land previously in their owner-
ship, providing it has not been materially changed in character. The Rules iden-
tify examples of such changes as being: where houses have been erected on
agricultural land; where mainly open land has been afforested; where offices
have been built on urban sites; and where substantial works to an existing build-
ing have effectively altered its character. Where only part of the land has been
materially changed, the general obligation to offer back will apply only to the
parts that have not been changed. The 1992 Rules also extended the twenty-five-
year cut-off rule to agricultural land, although this did not operate retrospec-
tively: only land purchased after 1992 would be subject to the cut off period.
When the twenty-five-year rule was first introduced in 1981, it had operated ret-
rospectively, applying to all non-agricultural land, irrespective of the date of
purchase.
The exceptions, contained in Rule 14, are largely unchanged from previous
versions of the Rules and include:
—where the land is needed by another Department (on specific ministerial
authority),
—where there are strong and urgent reasons of public interest for the land to be
disposed of to a local authority as a body with compulsory powers,
—small areas of agricultural land which would have no satisfactory agricultural
use even if used with other adjoining land;
—where it is advantageous to the Department and the adjoining owners to
adjust boundaries through a land exchange;
—where the land was originally acquired for development purposes;
—where the disposal accords with Government policies of transfer of functions
to the private sector providing particular services;
32 Civic Trust (2000) Commentary on the Defence Estates consultation March 2000.
The Crichel Down Rules 335
33
Contained in the Government Accounting Guidelines 3/1998 Annex 32.1 Disposal of land and
buildings and other land transactions. [1998] NAO.
34
Civil Service IN 26/96—Disposal of land to former owners—the Crichel Down Rules [1996]
Civil Service Central Administrative Unit.
35
Valuation and Lands Agency. Disposal of surplus land and buildings by public sector bodies
[2000] www.vla.nics.gov.uk/au/disposalguide4).
36
DETR, above n 4.
336 Roger Gibbard
Essentially then, the Crichel Down Rules are about the public right of private
individuals to be given the opportunity to buy back property that was taken
from them under compulsory powers. As such, they should not only be operated
fairly, but be seen to be operated fairly. Failure to apply them consistently or
indeed properly, may now leave the disposing department open to a claim that
it has contravened Article 1 of Protocol 1 of the European Convention on
Human Rights.37
The question of equity or fairness of the Rules can be examined from three
perspectives: firstly, is the principle underlying the Rules intrinsically one of
fairness? Secondly, are the Rules, as they are written, ‘fair’? And thirdly, are the
Rules being applied in an equitable manner?
Ultimately a consideration of these will lead to a fourth question needing to
be addressed, namely whether there are any changes which need to be imple-
mented in order to make the Rules more equitable.
Throughout this paper, the examination of ‘fairness’ will be made on the
principles of natural justice, and the two underlying principles, that no man is
to be judge and jury in his own case, and that no man should be condemned
without the opportunity of a hearing. Such ethics are binding not only on the
courts, but on all tribunals, arbitrators and all persons and bodies having the
duty to act judicially, including government departments. It will be argued that
the attitude towards Crichel Down breaches the rules of natural justice, and at
times can be seen further to operate in a manifestly unreasonable and irrational
manner.
The DETR (2000) research examined whether the original philosophy behind
having an offer-back procedure was one of equity, and if so, whether this has
changed over time, and whether it is still valid. Most of those organisations
dealing with the Rules claimed not to know on what moral, ethical, financial or
legal principles the Rules are based. The interpretation of, and any changes to,
the Rules will depend to a significant degree on whether their overriding raison
d’etre is to give a right of pre-emption to a landowner dispossessed of his prop-
erty, or to appease former owners whilst principally having regard to the public
purse by enabling surplus land to be disposed of as quickly as possible and at the
‘Compulsory purchase and compensation and Human Rights’ Journal of Planning and
Environment Law [1999] 315–26 and G Parker, ‘Planning and Rights. Some repercussions of the
Human Rights Act 1998’ [2001] Planning Practice and Research 16(1) pp 5–8. For a discussion of
‘fairness’ in the context of compensation for land, see Human Rights Practice (Sweet and Maxwell,
London, 2000) ch 15.
The Crichel Down Rules 337
best possible price. The adherence to the Rules undoubtedly has a negative
effect on cost control and on the time taken to dispose, neither of which are
beneficial to government or the taxpayer. Indeed earlier research conducted for
the DETR in 1998 concluded that ‘—the rules are a significant complication to
the disposal process for the Ministry of Defence’.38
The presence of the Rules seems to imply that the taxpayer in some way
‘owes’ the claimant something. Landowners might argue that the Rules are a
recognition that former owners have suffered an injustice or that a right to be
offered land back exists. Conversely it could be argued that owners are fully
compensated at the point of sale.
Could it be that the Rules represent a tacit acceptance of the existence of an
‘emotional tie’ between the owner and his land? If this tie gives rise to an element
of value which is not compensated at the point of compulsory purchase then it
would seem reasonable to contend that the former owner should have some
right of redress should the land cease to be held in the public interest. The most
appropriate right would seem to be a ‘first refusal’ to buy the land back. This
would appear to be the underlying moral principle on which the Rules are
based. However, it has been argued39 that the lack of an explicit philosophy
undermines the understanding and application of the Rules.
The closest to an explicit philosophy was put by Maxwell Fyfe, the Home
Secretary, in the 1954 House of Commons debate on the Rules:
When that purpose is exhausted, when that need is past, what is wrong, on any con-
sideration of morality or justice, in allowing the person from whom the land was
taken the chance of getting it back.40
The precise nature of the redress is more complex to assess, and will ulti-
mately depend on how the owner was originally compensated. This is quite a
separate, and indeed subordinate, question as to whether there should be a right
of repurchase. The fairness of the Rules with regard to pricing will be investi-
gated below.
One example of the underlying philosophy is given by the exception to the
Rules where the land has seen a material change in character. The rationale for
this provision needs examination. Firstly, the arbiter of what constitutes a mate-
rial change is the disposing authority themselves. If they deem that the charac-
ter of the land is significantly altered, then the Rules do not come into operation,
and former owners will not be notified. Ignorance of the impending disposal will
consequently rule out the opportunity for any legal challenge on the part of
former owners. Why should material change in the character of property pre-
clude the right to buy it back? The valuation principle (whether best price or
current market value) will dictate that the purchase price reflects such change in
38
Department of the Environment Transport and the Regions Review of the Redundant Defence
Estate [1998] (HMSO London).
39
Ibid.
40
530 Hansard, HC Debs, 1292, 20 July 1954.
338 Roger Gibbard
41 Ministry of Agriculture Fisheries and Food (1992) Untitled internal document. Land and
The drafting of the Rules will here be examined against the standards of natural
justice as apply to public bodies in the execution of quasi-judicial functions. It
is further contended that in order to satisfy the requirements of ‘justice’44 the
Crichel Down Rules need to enable such bodies to act without irrationality,
unreasonableness, manifest unreasonableness or irrelevant considerations.45
It is argued that the Rules have been poorly drafted and lack clarity. The orig-
inal draft and subsequent changes were often knee-jerk policy reactions to the
rulings in hard cases, with the consequence that they have developed in a hap-
hazard way without reference to the original Crichel Down ruling or the rea-
soning behind their introduction. Consequently the guidance is often poor, and
the wording is vague and open to wide interpretation. This may be perceived as
a failing by former owners but conversely it may be seen by disposing organisa-
tions as conferring a degree of flexibility on the process. The DETR research
confirmed earlier findings46 that ‘. . . there was a clear lack of understanding
amongst property practitioners, local planning authorities and even within
government departments as to the precise status of the Rules and which set
currently apply’.
42 [1977] 2 All ER 182.
43 For example, see 238 Hansard, HL Debs, 1050, Nov 1996.
44 Defined in Duhaimes’ Law Dictionary as ‘ a state of affairs in which conduct or action is both
for the Environment and Ipswich Borough Council (1990) 22 HLR 274 and Bushell v Secretary of
State for the Environment [1981] AC 75.
46 DETR above n 38.
340 Roger Gibbard
It is not clear from the Rules themselves which organisations they cover.
Certainly they apply to all government departments but they are only discre-
tionary on local authorities. It is less clear whether they apply to disposals made
by successor organisations, by privatised utilities and by other privatised
bodies. The new forms of public—private partnership arrangements arising over
the past twenty years have added to the confusion. It would seem to be
inequitable, and to run counter to the spirit in which the Rules were intended, for
the Government to have transferred land to which the Rules applied, and from
departments on which they are binding, to private utilities and the like for which
the Rules are only discretionary. Further, the transfer of land to bodies that
would not necessarily have had the powers to purchase the land themselves gives
rise to disquiet, particularly as subsequent disposals may not be subject to the
application of the Rules. The perception arises of a climate of ‘backdoor’ avoid-
ance of the Rules, an observation which was apparent in a number of represen-
tations made to the DETR research.47 For privatised utilities there remains the
unanswered question as to whether the courts will hold them to be ‘exercising
public functions’ and therefore under the remit of the Human Rights Act 1998.48
If the underlying principle of former owners being offered-back surplus prop-
erty is accepted as being desirable, then there is a compelling argument for such
a right to be enshrined in legislation, rather than to be contained in departmen-
tal circulars and guidance notes. As currently set out, the Rules do not consti-
tute a legal right: they have no statutory force nor are they principles of law.
They are policy guidance to be taken into account, where relevant, by the bod-
ies to which the Rules are addressed, and any decision on whether or not to
apply them will be made by the body in question. This must raise questions of
natural justice—with the disposing organisation acting as both judge and jury.
Perhaps surprisingly, Crichel Down ‘decisions’ have not been explicitly chal-
lenged on these grounds in the courts.49 Dispossessed owners are not given the
opportunity of making representations that Crichel Down should apply: they
need not even be aware that the organisation has considered their relevance.
Aggrieved private owners, without any right of appeal, may subsequently find
that they do have recourse to the Human Rights legislation for satisfaction.
There is no clear definition of what constitutes a ‘disposal’. Freehold transac-
tions are expressly included, but it is less clear whether or not the Rules also
apply to other disposals such as the granting of long leases or disposals under
the Private Finance Initiative and Public/ Private Partnership schemes. Some
departments do issue guidance (Department of Health 2000), but often this is
hidden away in circulars and memoranda. ‘Fairness’ would imply that the Rules
should apply no matter what the status of the disposing (or acquiring) body.
47 Above n 4.
48 D Hart, ‘The impact of the European Convention on Human Rights on Planning and
Environmental Law’ [2000] JPEL: 117–34.
49 But see R (on the application of Holding & Barnes plc) v Secretary of State for the
50 Reported in Plans, Plots and Talking shops. Daily Telegraph, 17th November 2001.
51 (1996) RICS, London.
342 Roger Gibbard
market value is an open market sale. Sales off the market to former owners, even
where they may be backed up by a professional valuation, do not provide the
same reassurance of value for money.
Most compulsory purchase compensation is determined by statute52 as
interpreted by subsequent case law. Two overriding principles are that there is
no allowance for the acquisition being compulsory and furthermore that com-
pensation for the land taken is assessed at current market value. It is contended
that were the original purchase to have occurred at a premium reflecting the
compulsory nature of the purchase, the argument in favour of re-purchase rights
would be weaker. That the option to repurchase should be at market value in
current use seems reasonable (and would appear to justify offerback even where
material changes have occurred), and the counter-argument that repurchase
should proceed at a price equating to the original compensation price would
appear to convey too great an element of gain back to the owner, potentially
giving rise to ‘windfalls of vast proportion’.53 It is the position of the former
owner as a ‘special purchaser’ which potentially exposes the weaknesses of the
definitions. Where former owners still retain adjacent land, there is a compelling
argument for regarding them as special purchasers. Where no such retention is
present, special status is open to question.
However, in the case of agricultural land, landowners do often retain adja-
cent land, and in addition to receiving compensation for land taken, they can
claim considerable sums for severance, injurious affection and disturbance in
respect of damage to land retained.54 The Crichel Down Rules make no explicit
allowance for these sums and the question needs to be asked whether former
owners should be required to repay or make some allowance for these items
when they get land back. In reality, the re-amalgamation of parcels of land is
likely to result in the creation of marriage value of benefit to the former owner.
The loss of marriage value on the original purchase would to some extent have
been compensated through a severance claim. Such additional severance pay-
ments were really intended to compensate the owner for the loss in perpetuity
of value in his retained land and the business he operates on it. Clearly only if
the resale to him occurs significantly soon after the original appropriation will
the owner stand to make any substantial gain, and it is argued that only in those
circumstances should they be regarded as ‘special purchasers’ and reasonably be
required to pay a price reflecting marriage value.
The rules do not clarify the mechanism of the offer back procedure in respect
to how price is agreed. Is it sufficient to have the property externally valued and
then offer it at that price on a ‘take it or leave it basis’, or does the disposing
52
Most notably the Compulsory Purchase Act 1965, the Land Compensation Acts 1961 and 1973
and the Planning and Compensation Act 1991.
53
Freedman v British Railways Board (1995) 69 P & CR 13.
54
R Gibbard, ‘The compulsory purchase of farmland: identifying severance and injurious
Affection claims’ [2001]. Working Papers in Land Management O3/01. Department of Land
Management and Development, The University of Reading.
The Crichel Down Rules 343
Perhaps not surprisingly, in view of the lack of clarity of the Rules, the research
(DETR, 2000) suggests that the total number of cases covered by the Rules and
which have resulted in a return to the original ownership since 1992 may be
small; almost certainly less than one hundred, and in all probability less than
fifty.
55
As defined in Rule 12.
56
Ibid.
344 Roger Gibbard
Government agency 17 49 40 6 6
Government Dept 4 56 44 0 0
Local authority 34 44 3 10
NHS authority 14 45 45 0 10
NHS Trust 0 56 32 2 10
Transport 1 100 0 0 0
Utilities 5 91 9 0 0
Valuation Office 5 0 30 0 0
Source: Department of the Environment, Transport and the Regions: the Operation of
the Crichel Down Rules (2000)
Of the post–1992 disposals where the Rules were known to apply, at least
fifty-four per cent of sites were not offered back. Of those that were, fifteen per
cent were purchased by their former owner. Of these, sixty-eight per cent were
single houses, ten per cent were development sites, and eight per cent were agri-
cultural land.
The research discovered a number of public sector schemes being prepared
which include land, which, under more normal circumstances, would have been
offered back to the former owner, suggesting that the applicability of the Rules
to the privatised utilities needs clarification. These bodies claim that they pos-
sess little evidence on the details of land acquisitions, which occurred prior to
privatisation, leading to the almost universal presumption that such land had
been acquired without threat of compulsion, or that a material change had
taken place, rendering the Rules inappropriate to most disposals from this sec-
tor. A number of representations to the DETR research were made concerning
whether it is equitable that the offer back procedures cease to apply once land is
transferred from an organisation for whom the consideration of the Rules is
mandatory to one where they are discretionary. This can lead to the inconsis-
tent application of the Rules by the same type of organisation. Departments
should be seen to act in a procedurally fair manner, and in such a way as to fulfil
The Crichel Down Rules 345
the legitimate expectations of the former owners.57 Not operating the Rules
properly or consistently could be regarded as an abuse of power. In defence, it
is not clear from the Rules themselves which private utility and other compan-
ies they apply to. It would be more equitable if they were mandatory on all
bodies with compulsory powers or which have been assigned land to which the
Rules would otherwise have applied.
Indeed, the problem of accessing former records was cited as the main
practical difficulty, preventing offer back in forty-three per cent of cases. This is
perhaps evidence of a lack of rigour in the process of privatisation rather than
deliberate maladministration, but nonetheless raises serious questions of moral-
ity and justice. Lack of adequate records is a particular concern for successor
organisations, which casts doubt on their ability to operate fairly under the
Rules. This is particularly so where transfers between departments have already
taken place, and is exacerbated where transfers to non-governmental depart-
ment bodies and others have occurred with the result that few organisations are
proactive in seeking to identify former owners. Given the low proportion of sites
actually sold back, this may be a rational strategy, although it stands outside the
spirit of the Rules if not their actual provisions.
The fact that decisions on the applicability of Crichel Down are made in the
absence of public scrutiny by the body seeking to dispose of property, and that
they can approach other government departments or even non-governmental
bodies (effectively third parties) in an attempt to pre-empt the rights of former
owners is unfair, and is clearly manifestly unreasonable. A decision that the
Rules do not apply or that the particular circumstances justify a departure from
them can only be challenged on public law grounds by way of a judicial review,
on the basis that they have been misinterpreted or irrationally applied. It follows
that the Rules give former owners no rights, as such, which can be asserted and
protected by law. The most that a former owner has is a right to challenge by
way of judicial review any decision by a disposing organisation in relation to the
applicability of the Rules. The failure of judicial review to provide an adequate
remedy was discussed in Cowan v Department of Economic Development58
where a government department was held to be in breach of the interests of pro-
cedural fairness where they were acting as both applicant and decision-maker.
Even a successful judicial review will not inevitably result in the land being
offered back to the former owner, but only in the disposing organisation being
required to remake the decision in accordance with the Rules. In all such
instances the former owner firstly needs to be aware that a transfer has occurred,
and this will probably only be immediately apparent where the sale is conducted
on the open market, and only then if it comes to the owner’s attention. It is this
difficulty of evidence that creates the real issue for former owners. A disposing
body which deems the Rules to be inapplicable is under no obligation to inform
57 See Re Preston [1985] 2 All ER 327, and R v North & East Devon Health Authority ex parte
former owners that any such consideration has been made. It is contended that
this breaches the code of natural justice requiring the opportunity of individu-
als to have their case heard, and as such is manifestly unfair. Even where author-
ities do adopt the Crichel Down procedures, the nature of the searches involved
(often needing to establish title over long periods and through poor quality
records) means that often the presumption to ignore is strongly evident. As a last
resort, where searches prove fruitless, some agencies do resort59 to placing pub-
lic notices in for instance, The Farmers’ Weekly, the Estates Gazette and the
London or Edinburgh Gazette, with a two-month period for owners to come
forward. The public have no way of knowing whether this process has been con-
ducted fairly or arbitrarily if at all.
There is an understandable if regrettable lack of understanding amongst
practitioners in both the public and private sector and in government depart-
ments as to the precise status of the Rules and which set (if any) currently
applies. It may be that this is somewhat overstated in the public sector in order
to preserve flexibility in whether to apply the Rules or not—better to assume
that they do not apply, than to assume that they do. There is a legitimate expec-
tation from members of the public that the Rules will be considered and
followed where they apply, but the public have no way of knowing whether a
department has made this consideration, unless they do decide to apply the
Rules and offer back is deemed appropriate.
Further confusion exists because the Crichel Down Rules are not the only for-
mal guidance that government and other bodies have to take account of when
considering disposing of surplus land. Eighty-six per cent of organisations
responding to the DETR research had some form of written guidance on
disposals, (see Table 2) sixty per cent of which made some reference to the
Rules. However, organisations’ awareness of their own procedures was not
always thorough—for instance over half of the health-related organisations
incorrectly said that their particular guidance made no reference to Crichel
Down procedures.
The complexity of the offer-back procedure is further added to by the sepa-
rate obligation placed on departments to follow the ‘Treasury Guidance on the
Disposal of Assets’.60 Whilst this makes rather obtuse reference to the Crichel
Down Rules, it conflicts with them in several respects, particularly in the
definition of ‘value’, adding confusion to the pricing of repurchases.
Often strict adherence to these supplementary rules and guidance notes takes
precedence over the Crichel Down Rules and creates pressures which conceiv-
ably lead to conflict with them. From the perspective of the public purse, appli-
cation of the Rules adds delay to the disposal process, increasing the time
between declaration of a site as surplus and its final disposal by an average of
seventeen months,61 with obvious public policy implications. Consequently
59
As is obligatory under Rule 20.
60
NAO, above n 33.
61
DETR, above n 4.
The Crichel Down Rules 347
Ministry of Circular 38/1992: The disposal of surplus government land for the
Defence Defence Estates;
Ministry of Defence—identifying and selling surplus property
1997/8; Defence Estates Guide for MoD- Stages and procedures in
disposal.
Environment Estates Manual Volume 15
Agency
National Health Estate Management in the National Health Service 1988;
service Estate code 1995
Department of Acquisition, management and disposal of land and property pur-
Transport chased for road construction NAO 1994;
Commission for Guidance note on disposal of land and built assets, disposal of land
New Towns and assets NAO 1994-5;
Forest Enterprise Disposal of property-rules and procedures for offer-back to former
owners and lessors
Highways Agency Procedures manuals on land disposal
Local Authorities Local Government Ombudsman (Disposal of land-guidance on
good practice 5).
Source: Department of the Environment, Transport and the Regions: the Operation of
the Crichel Down Rules (2000)
there has developed a real and strong tension between meeting the requirements
of the Rules, Treasury Guidance on disposal and the disposal targets of indi-
vidual departments. This prompted previous research to conclude that the Rules
are ‘outmoded and counter-productive’.62
In the light of previous comments, it is perhaps not surprising that an analy-
sis of information on disposals revealed that there are a significant number of
disposals where the land should have been offered back to former owners but
was not. Of the three thousand two hundred disposals since 1954 where the
Rules were known to apply, over half proceeded without any offer back.63
The DETR research64 identified a ‘significant number’ of recent cases where
surplus land has been sold under the Rules with the authority retaining a ‘ran-
som strip’, thereby protecting future development values. Such a practice is
62
DETR, above n 38.
63
DETR, above n 4.
64
Ibid.
348 Roger Gibbard
liable to question on the grounds of ethics and equity. Similarly, the inclusion of
clawback provisions, although it is specifically provided for under the Rules,65
would appear equally unjust. The original land purchase at market value would
have included hope value not attributable to the scheme, but not any develop-
ment value arising at a later date.66 It would seem inequitable therefore that
clawback should be included at the time of repurchase by the former owner.
Rather the purchase price should reflect any latent development value, as would
a true open market transaction67 It could be argued that these schemes reflect a
lack of confidence in the external valuation.
The Rules make provision for the effect on valuation of site fragmentation,68
that is the devolution of a site into its original separate ownership entities. The
obligation to offer land back does not apply where disposal is in respect of a site
for development which comprises two or more previous land holdings and
where there is a risk that the fragmented sale would realise substantially less
than the best price that could be obtained for the site as a whole. However, there
is no guidance on how the risk of achieving a lower aggregate sale price is to be
assessed nor what degree of risk leads to exemption under the Rules. The prepa-
ration of fragmentation valuations is difficult, complex and open to question.
Former owners can form consortia, to legitimately thwart such a fragmentation
argument under the Rules, and many departments have argued that this is being
abused by developers, with consequent delays and frustrations and with the
result that best price has not always been obtained.
Many of the organisations questioned found the Rules to be an irritation
rather than a central concern. Some organisations do have them firmly embed-
ded in their disposal procedures (eg highways departments), others clearly do
not actively consider their application unless and until contacted by a claimant,
which from the public perspective is surely unacceptable.
IMPROVEMENTS
The DETR (2000) research recognised and explored a number of possible solu-
tions to the identified problems surrounding the applicability and implementa-
tion, and overall fairness, of the current Rules. These varied from abandoning
the rules altogether, through maintaining the status quo, to primary legislation.
Abandoning them altogether would run counter to the principle of fairness
which currently underlies the Rules. There is a recognition that compulsory pur-
chase is somehow ‘unfair’—that unwillingly dispossessed owners do not get
compensated for the compulsory nature of the acquisition, and that corre-
65 Rule 25.
66 Unless due under the Planning and Compensation Act 1991, s 66.
67 G Sams, ‘Compensation in compulsory purchase: Revisions to procedures and miscellaneous
spondingly they should be entitled to repurchase if the land ever becomes sur-
plus. Any changes to the underlying ethos of no extra compensation being paid
due to the purchase being compulsory would, it is argued, compromise the
Crichel Down philosophy.
A number of organisations and individuals consulted in the research sug-
gested a major shift in the operation of the Rules, whereby the emphasis is
placed onto former owners, who would be required to register an intent to pur-
chase at a future date should the circumstance arise. Such a move would require
nationwide publicity in order to ensure fair implementation, and this would
bring with it additional cost implications. However, non-awareness of the Rules
is a huge issue even under the current regime. Both the National Farmers’ Union
and the Country Land and Business Association (CLA) recognise the need to
make landowners aware of the existence of the offerback rules, whether or not
they are changed.
If the Rules are therefore going to be retained in some form, there is an out-
standing desire for them to be encapsulated in a single document, for example—
‘Treasury Regulations on the disposal of surplus property—the Crichel Down
Rules’. This would expressly supersede all previous guidance, so that there
could be no confusion over which set of rules was currently in force. Primary
legislation may be required to alert bodies to the applicability of the Rules. This
would clearly confirm the bodies to which the Rules would apply. It is argued
that the only equitable solution is for the Rules to apply to all organisations and
for all land acquired by or under threat of compulsion. In essence they should
apply to the land rather than the disposing body, and would be mandatory for
all land acquired by bodies with compulsory purchase powers. Government
should consider accompanying the legislation with a Practice Manual to guide
departments on procedural matters.
The Rules (or Regulations, as they would be likely to become) should more
carefully define the offerback procedure, and the exceptions to it. Terminology
currently causing confusion, particularly in the area of exceptions, such as
‘material change’, ‘surplus’ and ‘disposal’ should be defined clearly and unam-
biguously, so that the Rules can be applied consistently. The debate over ‘value’
should be settled: a definition should be adopted with wider professional cur-
rency and in accordance with accepted convention. The practice of the retention
of ransom strips or clawback clauses to protect future development values
should be abandoned, except where it can clearly be shown that the former
owner has already received compensation for subsequent development value, or
that these are the last–resort methods of safeguarding development value.
A simplification of the Rules could be based on the principle that all land sales
should be conducted by public auction (or by tender). It would be adequate
under the new Rules for the disposing authority to take steps to trace former
owners and notify them of the impending sale, and to advertise locally and
nationally. Former owners would then be required to bid in order to secure
the property, and the marketplace would in theory, find its own level. This
350 Roger Gibbard
procedure would not be without valuation problems however; where the former
owner was a special purchaser, and no other third parties were interested, they
could conceivably repurchase at a very low price at auction. This would neces-
sitate setting a reserve market valuation price, determined in advance by the
District Valuer or by an appointed external valuer.
There is compelling argument for the application of a disputes procedure, by
way of the Lands Tribunal with an attendant right to appeal. This may lead to
yet more delay in the disposals process, and cost implications, but may be nec-
essary to ensure that ‘safe’ decisions are made. The Lands Tribunal already deal
with land price disputes, and it would seem logical to extend their jurisdiction
to offer–back disputes. The Department for Local Government, Transport and
the Regions (DLTR) should explore the possibility of cheaper, less time-
consuming methods of dispute resolution, with arbitration, or arbitration by
written submission as alternative means.
In the recently published Green Paper.69 the DLTR make a number of rec-
ommendations for the procedures for the disposal of compulsorily acquired
land Most importantly, in recognition that the Rules should be retained, but as
a universally mandatory form, that there should be primary legislation defining
the main principles, and secondary legislation incorporating the detailed rules.
The Green Paper proposes new legislation to introduce an appeals/arbitra-
tion mechanism, to be used additionally to settle disputes as to whether the
Rules should apply to a particular disposal. Additionally the DLTR recognises
that property negotiations are often lengthy, and recommend increasing the
time limits to eight months.
The DLTR proposes to retain the concept of applying the rules only where
there has been no material change in character, retain the time horizon of 25
years along with the list of exceptions, and the continuance of clawback as a
legitimate tool in the protection of the public purse.
CONCLUSIONS
The Crichel Down Rules were introduced hastily by a resigning Minister, as the
result of a parliamentary scandal, and were based on the findings of a public
inquiry which has itself been the target of criticism. The rules have never been
widely publicised, and have been the subject of numerous reviews and revisions,
confusing their underlying philosophy and making their application increas-
ingly uncertain. Running parallel to the Rules, and often overriding them or
directly conflicting with them are guidance materials published by the Treasury
and others. Additionally, many of the organisations to which the Rules apply
have their own guidance on disposals which may or may not deal explicitly with
how they are to interact with the Crichel Down Rules.
69
DETR, above n 5.
The Crichel Down Rules 351
Author’s note:
Since the conference delivery of this paper, (January 2002) the Town &
Country planning functions of the DLTR have passed to the Office of the
Deputy Prime Minister. This new department has assumed responsibility for the
review of planning under the 2001 Green paper.
18
Proprietarian Conceptions of
Statutory Access Rights
SCOTT GRATTAN*
INTRODUCTION
At common law, a person who wished to enter a neighbour’s land for the pur-
pose of carrying out work on her or his own land required the consent of the
neighbour. If that consent was not forthcoming, the person who nevertheless
entered the neighbour’s land left himself or herself open to an action in tres-
pass.1 In England and Wales and in various Australian States the common law
position has been varied by legislation empowering the relevant court to make
an order authorising the applicant to enter land (‘servient land’) for the purpose
of carrying out work on other land (‘dominant land’) without the consent of the
owner of the servient land. The legislation that creates compulsory rights of
access can be divided into two categories, which can be designated ‘first-
generation’ and ‘second-generation’.
First-generation access legislation has been enacted in Queensland,2
Tasmania3 and New South Wales.4 The origins of the legislation can be found
in the recommendations of the Law Commission for England and Wales (‘Law
Commission’).5 Despite this, England and Wales does not have first-generation
access legislation. The hallmarks of the first-generation legislation are as fol-
lows. Firstly, it allows the creation of easements over the servient land, rather
than simply temporary rights of access.6 Secondly, the power of the court to
impose the easement is not limited to the doing of some type of work on the
land. Thirdly, the power has been enacted in the form of a section inserted into
the general property law statute of the jurisdiction. Fourthly, it is the Supreme
Court of each jurisdiction that has been given the power to compulsorily impose
1
The classic case is John Trenberth Ltd v National Westminster Bank Ltd (1979) 39 P & CR 104.
2
Property Law Act 1974, s 180.
3
Conveyancing and Law of Property Act 1884, s 84J.
4
Conveyancing Act 1919, s 88K.
5
The Law Commission, Appurtenant Rights (Working Paper No 36, 1971).
6
Property Law Act 1974 (Queensland), s 180(7); Conveyancing and Law of Property Act 1884
(Tasmania), s 84J(2); Conveyancing Act 1919 (New South Wales), s 88K(1).
354 Scott Grattan
the easement. This has meant that the cases in which the power has been
invoked have usually been reported.
Second-generation access legislation has been enacted in the last decade, in
the England and Wales,7 Tasmania8 and New South Wales,9 and has certain
characteristics that distinguish it from the first-generation legislation. Firstly, as
will be discussed, it permits the imposition of access rights only for the purpose
of facilitating certain types of work on the dominant land. Secondly, those rights
subsist for only a limited period of time.10 Thirdly, in each jurisdiction the
second-generation legislation takes the form of a stand-alone Act that was the
result of an extensive law reform review process.11 Fourthly, the second-
generation legislation is administered by lower courts,12 the decisions of which
are not routinely reported. This means that there is a dearth of available case
law in which the legislation has been considered.13 Because of this, heavy
reliance will be placed on the published work of the law reform bodies in the
relevant jurisdictions.
One way of interpreting both the first–generation and second-generation
access legislation is through the lens of economic efficiency. The legislation can
be seen as a means of ensuring the efficient allocation of resources in the context
of market failure.
The owner of the putative dominant land might value the right to access more
highly than the owner of the putative servient land values the right to refuse
access, so that the possibility of mutually beneficial exchange exists. This
exchange would take the form of the servient owner granting access to the dom-
inant owner in return for a money payment. However, such an exchange may
not take place because the situation in which bargaining occurs is a bilateral
monopoly,14 with neither party having an alternate source of supply because of
7
Access to Neighbouring Land Act 1992 (UK), which extends only to England and Wales
(s 9(3)), and which will be referred to below as the ‘E&W Act’).
8
Access to Neighbouring Land Act 1992, (referred to below as the ‘Tasmanian Act’).
9
Access to Neighbouring Land Act 2000 (referred to below as the ‘NSW Act’).
10
E&W Act, s 2(1)(c); Tasmanian Act, s 6(1)(b); NSW Act, s 17(c).
11
The E&W Act was preceded by the Law Commission, Rights of Access to Neighbouring Land
(Working Paper No 78, 1980), referred to below as the ‘E&W Working Paper’, and the Law
Commission, Rights of Access to Neighbouring Land (Report No 151, 1985), referred to below as
the ‘E&W Report’. The Tasmanian Act was preceded by the Law Reform Commission of
Tasmania, On Private Rights of Access to Neighbouring Land (Report No 42, 1985), referred to
below as the ‘Tasmanian Report’. The NSW Act was preceded by the New South Wales Law
Reform Commission, Neighbour and Neighbour Relations (Discussion Paper 22, 1991), referred to
infra as the ‘NSW Discussion Paper’ and the New South Wales Law Reform Commission, Right of
Access to Neighbouring Land (Report No 71, 1994), referred to below as the ‘NSW Report’.
12 In England and Wales, the High Court or a county court, although applications are to be com-
menced in the county court: ss 7(2), 8(3); in Tasmania, a magistrate or the small claims division of
the Magistrates Court: s 3; in New South Wales, the Local Court: ss 7, 13(1).
13 The only fully reported case, dealing with the E&W Act, is Dean v Walker (1996) 73 P & CR
366, in which a two-member Court of Appeal upheld the judgments of the lower courts that the
definition of land in the E&W Act was wide enough to include a party wall between the dominant
and the servient land.
14 SE Sterk, ‘Neighbors in American Land Law’ (1987) 87 Col L Rev 55 at 57–8, 70.
Proprietarian Conceptions of Statutory Access Rights 355
the geophysical relationship between the relevant parcels of land. The only per-
son from whom the dominant owner can buy access is the putative servient
owner, and the only person to whom the servient owner can sell access is the
putative dominant owner. This situation means that each of the parties has
ample opportunity for strategic bargaining by trying force up or down the price
paid for access. This may result in an inefficient allocation of resources due to
the unreasonable attitude of the parties. The legislation can be seen as address-
ing this inefficient outcome by allowing the court to grant access rights over the
servient land when it is efficient to do so.
In reading the first–generation and second–generation legislation in these
economic terms, one holds the view that the legislation is ultimately designed to
satisfy individual preferences: the right to access has gone to the person who val-
ues it the most. In this way, one is subscribing to what Gregory Alexander calls
the ‘property-as-commodity’ view. As Alexander says:
Property satisfies individual preferences most effectively through the process of mar-
ket exchange, or what lawyers call market alienability. The exchange function of
property is so important—that property is often thought to be synonymous with the
idea of market commodity.15
Of course, the imposition of access rights by the courts under the legislation
is the antithesis of free exchange. The granting of access constitutes an exchange
nonetheless, as a valuable resource—access—has moved from a person who val-
ues it less to a person who values it more. This movement has not taken place
through the market, but by a process which mimics the market.
However, for Alexander, the economic view of property as a commodity
constitutes only ‘one-half of a dialectic’. The other half is the concept of ‘prop-
erty as propriety’, which conceives of property as ‘the material foundation for
creating and maintaining the proper social order’.16 Alexander describes the
‘proprietarian conception of property’ in this way.
At its core, however, is the idea that the proper society is more than just whatever
emerges from market relations. The properly ordered society may coincide with the
market society, but the two are not identical. The market view of society is essentially
empty.—The proprietarian, by contrast, is always committed to some particular sub-
stantive view of how society should be ordered.17
In this paper I will argue that the second-generation, but not the first-
generation, access legislation can be viewed as having an explicit proprietarian
function. The proper social order that the legislation seeks to secure is of course
not the one envisioned by the civic republicans of revolutionary America,
namely a natural social and political order dominated by the citizen-
freeholder.21 Rather, it is my contention that the second-generation legislation
is built on a normative vision of a proper relationship between neighbours,
where, in certain circumstances, the interests of an individual landowner have
to be subordinated to the interests of her or his neighbour. This subordination
is required in order to maintain a harmonious relationship between them. Such
a harmonious relationship is the proper—natural—state of affairs that will
flourish from the virtue of right-thinking and right-acting neighbours. However,
it is always possible that this virtue will be subject to corruption, where one
neighbour will put her or his own narrow interests first. It is the role of the
second-generation legislation to defeat corruption and restore virtue by bring-
ing about the proper state of affairs by forcing access where appropriate.
The next section of this paper will outline the first-generation access legisla-
tion. It will argue that despite the references to public policy and public interest
in the justifications given for the legislation, the first-generation can seen as
manifesting only an economic, and not a proprietarian, spirit. Next, the paper
will examine the second-generation legislation and will identify its explicit pro-
prietarian purpose. In each of these sections I will examine not only the legisla-
tion itself, but also the law reform preceding its enactment. The final section of
this paper will evaluate the proprietarian credentials of the second-generation
legislation by comparing the core provisions of the legislation with material that
articulates the meaning of being a ‘good neighbour’.
19 GS Alexander, Commodity & Propriety (University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1997), 29–30.
20 Ibid, 30–1 (reference omitted).
21 Ibid, 4.
22 Law Commission, above n 5.
Proprietarian Conceptions of Statutory Access Rights 357
sation of the law of easements, restrictive covenants and other rights appur-
tenant to land through the introduction of the concept of ‘Land Obligations’.
One of the recommendations was to give the Lands Tribunal the power to com-
pulsorily impose a Land Obligation over servient land. This could be done in
order to make ‘effective’ a desired ‘specific development’ or ‘specific change of
the use’ of dominant land. For the Land Tribunal to impose such a Land
Obligation, it must be satisfied that: (i) it is in ‘the public interest’ for the dom-
inant land to be developed in the desired manner; (ii) the owner of the servient
land can be ‘adequately compensated’ for any ‘loss or disadvantage’ caused by
the imposition; and (iii) the refusal of the servient owner to agree to the imposi-
tion is ‘unreasonable’ in ‘all the circumstances’.23
The Law Commission gave this example of where the compulsory imposition
of a Land Obligation might be necessary.
Let it be supposed that in a particular case it would be in the public interest that a
housing estate should be built on a particular site, and, further, that such a develop-
ment would require the acquisition of drainage rights over neighbouring land. It is
always to be hoped that the developer will obtain those rights from his neighbour by
agreement; but what if he cannot? The probable consequence will be that the devel-
oper’s land will not be put to optimum use, unless the development is carried out by
some body having compulsory powers.24
Perhaps the most interesting aspect of this statement is the nexus that is
drawn between the optimum use of land and the public interest. The same nexus
is drawn in another passage. The Law Commission stated that the proposal ‘is,
essentially, an instrument of public policy’, and that
the time may have come for the law, in the public interest, to go some way towards
helping an owner to acquire such rights as are essential to enable him to put his land
to better use.25
At first blush it might be thought that the linkage between the increased devel-
opment of land and the public interest is consistent with a proprietarian view of
property rights. The linkage seems to require the subordination of individual
interests (the ability of the servient owner to exclude others) to a particular
vision of the wider social good. However, a moment’s reflection shows that this
argument is firmly within the tradition of property as commodity: it is all about
how resource ownership satisfies individual preferences.
Identifying a nexus between increasing the value of resources and the public
good brings us very close to Posner’s ‘ethical’ system of wealth maximisation.26
Posner argues that the value of a resource is simply a function of the value
that a person places on that resource.27 When a resource is transferred from
23
Ibid, 118.
24
Ibid, 59 (emphasis added).
25
Ibid, 119 (emphasis added).
26
See RA Posner, Economics of Justice (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass, 1981),
60–103.
27
Ibid, 60–1, 64–5.
358 Scott Grattan
someone who values it less, to someone who values it more, then society as a
whole is wealthier. Central to this view is that the public interest (or greater
good) is simply an aggregate of the extent to which individuals’ preferences are
satisfied.28
The Law Commission adopted the position that access rights should be com-
pulsorily imposed because more intensive development of land is desirable. The
only reason for this must be that such development is what people (individuals)
want. The ‘netting off’ of what people want is then equated with the public
interest. The view that the public good is simply an aggregation of individual
preferences can be described as a ‘thin’ view of the public interest. Support for
the assertion that the Law Commission takes a ‘thin’ view of the public interest
can be found in the Commission’s statement that ‘[w]e do not think that it
would be necessary or desirable to define “the public interest” ’.29 In my view,
such a definition would only be unnecessary if the term had no independent
content.
What we can conclude from this discussion is that the rationale given by the
Law Commission for its recommendation is consistent only with the view that
property rights should be shaped to bring about the efficient use of resources.
The Law Commission has no other vision as to what constitutes a proper social
ordering. The proposed access regime had no proprietarian function.
Australian legislation
The Law Commission’s proposal to allow the Lands Tribunal to have the power
to impose a Land Obligation on servient land in these circumstances has not
been taken up in the England and Wales. However, first-generation access leg-
islation has been enacted in various Australian jurisdictions in a form that is
generally faithful to the Law Commission’s proposal.
The first jurisdiction to do so was Queensland, in the form of section 180 of
the Property Law Act 1974. Section 180 allows the Supreme Court to impose ‘a
statutory right of user’ over servient land where this is ‘reasonably necessary in
the interests of effective use in any reasonable manner’30 of dominant land. A
similar provision was inserted into Tasmania’s Conveyancing and Law of
Property Act 1884 as section 84J in 197831 In New South Wales, section 88K was
added to the Conveyancing Act 1919 in 1995.32 This section allows the Supreme
Court to impose an easement over land ‘if the easement is reasonably necessary
for the effective use or development of other land’.33
28 See RA Posner, Economics of Justice (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass; 1981), 61.
29 Law Commission, above n 5, 60 (reference omitted).
30 Section 180(1).
31 Conveyancing and Law of Property Act (No 2) 1978, s 3.
32 Property Legislation Amendment (Easements) Act 1995.
33 Section 88K (1).
Proprietarian Conceptions of Statutory Access Rights 359
There has been a common approach by the Queensland and New South
Wales courts in addressing the requirement that the right of access be ‘reason-
ably necessary’.34 The courts have said that although possession of the right
need not be absolutely necessary for the use or development of the dominant
land, having the right must be more than merely desirable or preferable. Put
another way, use or development with the right must be substantially preferable
to use or development without the right.35
The Queensland and the New South Wales provisions have been used in three
factual contexts. Firstly, to impose permanent rights of way over servient land
where the dominant land was landlocked36 or where there was no practical
vehicular access to the dominant land.37 Secondly, to impose easements over
servient land in order to satisfy planning approval requirements for a proposed
development of the dominant land.38 Thirdly, to impose easements that would
facilitate some form of construction or building work on the dominant land,
such as easements to allow a crane39 or scaffolding40 to encroach into the air-
space above the servient land.
There are various conditions that need to be satisfied before a right of access
can be imposed under the first-generation legislation. As the concern of this
paper is the proprietarian aspect to statutory access rights, I will consider only
the condition prescribing a particular relationship between the proposed ease-
ment and the ‘public interest’.
We have seen that the concept of public interest as used by the Law
Commission is essentially an empty one, being simply tied to the satisfaction of
individual preferences through the efficient use of resources. We now examine
whether the case law that has considered the ‘public interest’ requirement of the
first-generation Queensland and New South Wales legislation has given propri-
etarian substance to this concept.
Section 180(3)(a) of the Property Law Act requires that in order for a statutory
right of user to be imposed, the proposed use of the dominant land must be
‘consistent with the public interest’. When one looks at the specific findings of
consistency with the public interest in the majority of the Queensland cases,
one discovers that the public interest is conceived of as being a function of the
34 Eg Tregoyd Gardens Pty Ltd v Jervis (1997) 8 BPR 15,845 at 15,853–4, and Re Kindervater
The construction of ‘the public interest’ by the Australian courts in the con-
text of the first-generation access legislation does not support a proprietarian
vision of the contour of property rights in this context. The reference to the pub-
lic interest does not involve a substantive vision of how the preferences of indi-
viduals should be subordinated to a conception of a proper social ordering.
Echoing the approach of the Law Commission, the Australian courts conceive
of the public interest as a function of the efficient or productive use of resources.
As both Alexander and Posner explain, this conception of property-as-com-
modity is based upon giving effect to individual preferences.
41 [1977] Qd R 86 at 90.
42 [1987] Qd R 400 at 404.
43 Above n 34 (emphasis has been added).
44 Section 88K(2)(a).
45 Eg Blulock Pty Ltd v Majic [2001] NSWSC 1063 (unreported) at para 12.
46 (2000) 10 BPR 18,163 at 18,168.
Proprietarian Conceptions of Statutory Access Rights 361
In this section, the E&W Act and the NSW Act will be considered in some detail.
For reasons of space, the Tasmanian Act will not be dealt with, other than to say
that it constitutes a half-way house between the E&W Act and the NSW Act.
Like the E&W Act, the Tasmanian Act only allows compulsory access in respect
of preservation work;47 in other respects it is very similar to the NSW Act.
The starting point for understanding the second-generation legislation is the
provision enabling a person to apply for an ‘access order’.48 A person who
desires entry to adjoining or adjacent land for the purpose of carrying out work
on other land may apply to the relevant court for an access order. The applicant
for the order need not be the owner of the dominant land, but the NSW Act
requires the applicant to obtain the consent of the owner of the dominant land
in such a case, unless this requirement is waived by the court.49
Under the E&W Act an access order can only be granted in respect of work
that is reasonably necessary for the ‘preservation’ of the dominant land.50 A
number of activities are expressly included within the concept of works of
preservation.51 These activities include the repair, maintenance or renewal of
buildings52 and, where this is reasonably necessary for the preservation of the
land, the alteration, adjustment, improvement or demolition of a building.53
The NSW Act does not limit the types of work for which an access order can be
granted,54 and the non-exhaustive list of work includes ‘construction’ of build-
ings and other structures.55
Although somewhat different in form, the second-generation access legisla-
tion provides for a common approach to be taken by the court in determining
whether an access order should be granted. This approach is essentially a cost-
benefit analysis. The court must examine the benefit that would flow to the
applicant if access were granted. This involves assessing whether the work ‘can-
not be carried out, or would be substantially more difficult to carry out’ with-
out entry to the servient land.56 The court is then to consider the cost to the
owner of the servient land of granting access. This requires the court to assess
47
Section 5(2)(a).
48
E&W Act, ss 1(1), 8(3); NSW Act, ss 3, 7, 11(1). A reference in this paper to an ‘access order’
under the NSW Act will refer to a ‘neighbouring land access order’ and not a “utility service access
order”. For this latter type of order, see ss 8, 13.
49
Section 7(2) and (3).
50
Section 1(2)(a).
51
Section 1(4).
52
Section 1(4)(a).
53
Section 1(5).
54 Section 12(2).
55 Section 12(1)(a).
56 E&W Act, s 1(2)(b); NSW Act, s 15(a).
362 Scott Grattan
whether entry under an access order would cause unreasonable hardship to the
owner of the servient land.57
A finding that (i) the work would be substantially more difficult to carry out
if there were no right of access; and (ii) the owner of the servient land would not
suffer unreasonable hardship would mean that an access order would be
granted, as the benefit would outweigh the cost. However, if either (i) the work
would not be substantially more difficult to undertake without access to the
servient land than with it; or (ii) access would cause unreasonable hardship to
the owner of the servient land, then the cost would outweigh the benefit and
the order could not be granted.
Interpreted this way, the Acts are consistent with the view that property rights
have the purpose of securing an efficient use of resources. Our task is to ascer-
tain whether they can also be seen as undertaking a proprietarian function, but
we must postpone that question for a little longer while we continue to outline
the mechanics of the second-generation legislation.
Both the E&W Act and the NSW Act give the court wide discretion in
including in the access order conditions that are designed to avoid or minimise
loss, damage or injury any person,58 and to minimise ‘inconvenience or loss of
privacy’ to the owner of the servient land or any other person.59 Such condi-
tions might include the manner in which the work is to be carried out, the days
and hours during which the work may be carried out, precautions and safe-
guards and the taking out of insurance.60 In addition, unless varied by the
court, the access order automatically requires the applicant to: (i) ensure that
the servient land is made good so far as is reasonably practicable; and (ii)
indemnify the owner of the servient land against damage to the servient land
or goods.61
An important aspect of the second-generation legislation is the regime for the
payment of compensation by the applicant to the owner of the servient land.
Both Acts provide for the payment of compensation in respect of any ‘loss, dam-
age or injury’ to the owner of the servient land arising from the access.62 Under
the NSW Act, compensation is not payable for loss of privacy or inconvenience
suffered by the owner of the servient land that is solely caused by the access
authorised by the order.63 This prohibition follows the recommendation of the
Law Commission in denying compensation for inconvenience caused by the
authorised access.64 By contrast, the E&W Act does allow for the awarding of
compensation ‘for substantial loss of privacy or other substantial inconve-
57
E&W Act, s 1(3); NSW Act, s 15(b).
58
E&W Act, s 2(2)(a); NSW Act, s 16(2)(a).
59
E&W Act, s 2(2)(b); NSW Act, s 16(2)(b).
60
E&W Act, s 2(3), (4)(b); NSW Act, s 16(2)(c), (d) and (f).
61
E&W Act, s 3(3)-(5); NSW Act, ss 16(2)(e), 21.
62
E&W Act, ss 2(4)(a)(i); NSW Act, s 26(1).
63
Section 26(2).
64
E&W Report, para 4.54. Also see NSW Report, para 4.9.
Proprietarian Conceptions of Statutory Access Rights 363
nience’ caused by reason of the authorised access.65 It should be noted that the
first-generation access legislation requires the payment of compensation that is
‘just’66 or ‘appropriate’67 for the granting of the easement. This has been held to
include compensation for loss of amenities such as peace and quiet.68
The E&W Act is also more generous than the NSW Act in that it allows for
the payment to the owner of the servient land of an amount ‘by way of consid-
eration for the privilege of entering’ the servient land. Such a payment can only
be made where the dominant land is not residential in nature. The quantum
payable is that ‘as appears to the court to be fair and reasonable having regard
to all the circumstances of the case’. In particular, the court is to have regard
to the degree of inconvenience suffered by the servient owner and, more
significantly, the financial advantage of the access order to the applicant.69 By
providing for the payment of ‘compensation’ by the applicant for the privilege
of access, and for the financial benefit flowing from such access, the E&W Act
directly goes against the recommendations of the Law Commission.70
An access order authorises the applicant and others71 to enter72 the servient
land for the purpose of carrying out work on the dominant land. The owner of
the servient land who was a party to the proceedings, or a successor in title to a
party to the proceedings,73 is required to allow the applicant access to the
servient land in accordance with the order.74 In addition to any other applicable
remedy, the applicant has a statutory right to damages against the owner of the
servient land if that person does not allow the applicant access as required by
the order.75 Under the NSW Act, failure to comply with an access order is a
criminal offence subject to the imposition of a fine.76
65 Section 2(4)(a)(ii). This is consistent with the provisional view of the Law Commission in the
E&W Working Paper (para 5.15), that compensation should be payable for actual, but not trivial
inconvenience.
66
Property Law Act 1974 (Queensland), s 180(4).
67
Conveyancing Act 1919 (NSW), s 88K(4). On the difference between the compensation payable
under s 88K and the NSW Act, see RG Stokes, ‘Thy Neighbour’s House: Quiet Enjoyment versus
the Access to Neighbouring Land Act’ (2001)7 LGLJ 106 at 108–09.
68 Wengarin v Byron Shire Council (1999) 9 BPR 16,985 at 16,989.
69 Section 2(5). The method of assessing the financial benefit of the access order is set out in s 2(6).
70 E&W Report, paras 4.55, 4.59. The rationale for this view is that the servient owner should
not be given an incentive to litigate rather than negotiate. Also see NSW Report, para 4.19.
71 Such other persons authorised by the applicant as are ‘reasonably necessary’ to undertake the
The main contention of this paper is that the second-generation access legisla-
tion is based upon a proprietarian vision of property rights. However, it must be
noted that as the second-generation legislation uses a form of cost-benefit
analysis to determine whether access should be granted, it, like the first-
generation legislation, can be seen as promoting the satisfaction of private
preferences through facilitating the productive use of resources. This view of the
second-generation legislation certainly comes through in the work of the law
reform authorities that preceded its enactment. And just as with the first-
generation legislation, this is often equated with the public interest. This state-
ment of the Law Commission is representative:
there is also to be borne in mind the argument based on the public’s interest in main-
taining the country’s stock of buildings in good repair. Inability to do this through
denial of necessary access must result in a waste of resources.77
Yet side by side with statements that link the satisfaction of individual
preferences (through the productive use of resources) with the public interest
are justifications which Alexander would call truly proprietarian. These
justifications do envision the subordination of individual preferences to a sub-
stantive vision of a proper social order. The social ordering that is envisioned is
one of a harmonious relationship between neighbours: a relationship where one
neighbour voluntarily puts his or her own interest behind that of the other. This
view is consistent with Alexander’s notion of property rights being shaped so as
to promote virtue, rather than wealth. Neighbours interact not merely as
quasi–buyers and quasi–sellers in a quasi–market, (in which rights of access are
the quasi–commodities), but as people in continuing relationships of mutual
dependence. The second-generation access legislation is designed to ensure that
the natural order of things is maintained.
The following is one example of the Law Commission employing this form of
proprietarian justification for the enactment of access legislation:
reasonable neighbours do not in practice object to access for repairs on the ground
that such access would be a major erosion of their rights. The facts that most people
do not object to temporary incursions by their neighbours at times of need shows that
such incursions are not generally considered to be objectionable. . . . It appeared from
the consultation that when access was refused, the immediate cause of the refusal was
often some existing ill-feeling between neighbours, the origins of which lay in some
incident unconnected with the request for access. In these cases, the purpose of the
refusal was to spite [the applicant] rather than to protect [the servient owner’s]
rights.78
77
E&W Report, para 3.15 (emphasis added). Also see NSW Report, paras 1.7, 2.19.
78
Ibid, 3.24 (emphasis added).
Proprietarian Conceptions of Statutory Access Rights 365
What emerges very strongly from this passage is that it is natural that a spirit
of goodwill exists between neighbours and that one neighbour should not
unreasonably refuse access to another. However, these passages suggest that it
is also quite common for reality to depart from the ideal. A spirit of ill-will may
exist between neighbours. This state of affairs is regarded as a perversion of the
proper order, however. The access legislation is designed to provide a corrective
mechanism and, as Alexander might say, to protect virtue against corruption.
The concept of ‘neighbourliness’ as an axiom strongly permeates the
arguments of the New South Wales Law Reform Commission (‘NSWLRC’) for
the enactment of access legislation. One of the reasons for this is that the
NSWLRC’s examination of the need for reform in this area initially grew out of
a general reference on neighbour and neighbour relations in the context of resi-
dential land, rather than the discrete issue of access to neighbouring land. In its
initial examination, the issue of access was bundled together with areas of con-
cern such as problems caused by trees and noise.79 The primary concern of the
NSWLRC was to consider ‘the issues of dispute resolution and the availability
of appropriate remedies and forums to deal with conflicts between neigh-
bours’.80 The NSWRLC identified disputes between neighbours as frequently
having their origin in the ‘continuous’ and ‘broadly based’ relationship between
the parties which arises out of their close proximity and frequent interaction.81
As a consequence of this:
a dispute which ends up in court is often simply a by-product or symptom of a more
wide-ranging problem in the relationship. Disputes about personalities, interest, man-
ners and lifestyles and values are transformed into disputes about issues which are
recognised at law when legal action is taken.82
79
NSW Discussion Paper, paras 1.1, 1.3–1.4.
80
Ibid, para 1.2.
81
Ibid, paras 7.2–7.3.
82
Ibid, para 7.3 (emphasis added).
83
NSW Report, para 1.4.
366 Scott Grattan
The above discussion has shown how the concept of neighbourliness has been
used to justify the enactment of the second–generation access legislation: legal
redress is seen as needed when actual behaviour does not measure up to the ideal
of how good neighbours should act. The central role of the concept of neigh-
bourliness in justifying the contours of the legislation is encapsulated in the
divergence of opinion regarding the scope of work for which access may be
ordered. As previously noted, the E&W Act allows access for preservation work
only, whereas the NSW Act allows access for preservation work and new build-
ing work. Both sides of the debate invoked the concept of neighbourliness to
support its position. The Law Commission justified its recommendation to limit
the type of work for which access could be compulsorily ordered in this way:
although the line between new building work and preservation work may be difficult
to draw with precision, the difference between the two is in principle a difference in
kind and not merely in degree. To see this one has only to ask whether good neigh-
bourly relations would normally be enough at present to ensure that access was given.
In relation to preservation work, we think the answer is, Yes. In relation to new build-
ing work, we think it is more probably, No.85
Given the heavy reliance placed upon the concept of ‘neighbourliness’ in the
work of the law reform authorities that gave birth to the second-generation leg-
islation, it might seem strange that the second-generation legislation does not
use the term ‘neighbour’ at all, and only uses the term ‘neighbouring’ in their
respective titles. Instead, the legislation refers to ‘adjoining or adjacent land’.88
We must assume that ‘neighbour’ and ‘neighbouring’ are not sufficiently precise
to employ in the language by which rights, duties, privileges and immunities are
created. The question thus arises: why is the term ‘neighbouring’ used in the title
of the legislation? The answer must be that the term is intended to give the leg-
islation an aura of ‘naturalness’ by providing a link to the ‘rhetorically charged’
concept of neighbourliness so readily utilised by the relevant law reform author-
ities. We now proceed to ‘unpack’ the concept of ‘neighbour’ to see to what
extent the second-generation legislation is faithful to it.
Yet other commentators have questioned the utility of trying to deduce par-
ticular legal rules from the neighbour principle outside the ‘legitimate realm of
88 E&W Act, 1(1); NSW Act, s 7(1). The Law Commission, which uses ‘adjoining or adjacent’ in
cl 1(a) of its draft bill, states (E&W Report, para 4.14) that ‘neighbouring’ does not mean contigu-
ous, but means ‘any land access to which is required by [the applicant] in order to carry out the
work’.
89 [1932] AC 562.
90 AM Linden, ‘Viva Donoghue v Stevenson!’ in PT Burns (ed), Donoghue v Stevenson and the
Modern Law of Negligence (The Continuing Legal Education Society of British Columbia,
Vancouver, 1991), 230.
91 Ibid, 228.
368 Scott Grattan
preventing physical harm’.92 In particular, JC Smith points out that the neigh-
bour principle does not, and should not, impose a ‘prima facie duty to prevent
foreseeable harm that you are in no way responsible for causing’.93 Perhaps
inspired by Linden’s religious theme, Smith says
Saintly acts and behaviour must remain voluntary. The price of enforced saintly con-
duct is the paralytic loss of freedom of action. . . . If we recognise a duty to prevent
foreseeable harm and to compensate what we do not prevent, then our lives will not
be our own, nor can any of us retain any property or resources.94
92 JC Smith, ‘The Good Neighbour Still on Trial: Is Paisley’s Decayed Snail the Pilgrim’s Holy
Theories of Neighbourliness
The first of these ‘law and society’ pieces to be used is Bruce Mann’s Neighbors
and Strangers,97 which examines the transformation of the ways in which dis-
putes were resolved in seventeenth and eighteenth century Connecticut. Mann
argues that in the seventeenth century the model of dispute resolution that
was employed was fundamentally ‘communal’ or ‘neighborly’ in nature.98 The
methods of adjudication—arbitration proceedings, church tribunals and even
the legal system itself—had the goal of acknowledging the individuality of dis-
putes by fully airing the grievances of the parties. What was sought was a solu-
tion that allowed the parties to ‘reconcile their differences in a manner that
allowed them to resume their sometimes quarrelsome, but mutually dependent
neighborly relations’.99
By contrast, the eighteenth century saw the rise of a hegemonic legal system
based on a paradigm of ‘generalizable, predictable rules and results’.100 Such a
system subordinated the analysis of the specific facts of disputes to a process
designed to yield predictable outcomes. This was a system that treated neigh-
bors as strangers in an effort to achieve uniformity and certainty through the
application of universal, abstract rules.101
The transformation noted by Mann can be seen to mirror a transformation
from the common law to the statutory regimes governing access to land, except
that (as is appropriate for a ‘mirrored’ phenomenon) the transformation has
been in the opposite direction. The common law rules governing trespass to
land are inflexible and unforgiving. The motivation, extent and even effect of
the incursion are irrelevant to the outcome of the dispute: liability is strict and
the outcome is certain.
The second-generation access statutes are fundamentally different from the
common law rule of trespass. This difference is not just in outcome—at times
permitting access without consent—but also in technique. The statutes are
receptive to the richness of the particular facts of the dispute. In this respect we
must recall the test of ‘reasonable necessity,’ which is fundamental to the ques-
tion of whether access should be granted, as well as the myriad of conditions
that can be imposed to minimise the adverse impact upon the servient owner.
Both of these mechanisms have the aim of balancing the interests of the parties
and reaching a result that will allow them to live, in Mann’s words, ‘if not in
peace, then at least in a truce’.102
The second of the law and society pieces is one of the most famous recent
works in the area. In his Order Without Law,103 Robert Ellickson conducted a
97
(The University of North Carolina Press, Chapel Hill, 1987).
98
Ibid, 9–10.
99
Ibid, 163.
100
Ibid, 168.
101
Ibid, 9–10, 167.
102
Ibid, 164.
103
RC Ellickson, Order Without Law (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass, 1991).
370 Scott Grattan
detailed study of how the residents of rural Shasta County in California resolved
disputes concerning straying cattle. Ellickson found that in the vast majority of
cases, disputes were resolved by the parties concerned, not only without
recourse to legal processes, but without regard to the underlying formal legal
rules that supposedly ‘governed’ the dispute. Instead, the parties involved
applied informal norms to regulate their relationships in situations of potential
conflict.104 The various informal norms that were applied in specific situations
were found to be a function of the ‘overarching substantive norm . . . that one
should be a “good neighbor” ’. This is ‘a general call for cooperative behav-
ior’105 and above all meant ‘no law suits’.106
A major aspect of Ellickson’s study was how the rural residents of Shasta
County dealt with the common problem of cattle trespass. What makes the
study of the resolution of cattle trespass in Shasta County such an interesting
subject from the law and society perspective is that different legal regimes
applied in different areas of the county. In ‘open range’ areas the owner of live-
stock is generally not liable for damage caused by straying cattle to unfenced
land, even when the event was caused by the negligence of the owner. In ‘closed
range’ areas the owner is strictly liable for damage caused by straying cattle.107
What Ellickson found, however, was that the owner of the straying cattle and
the owner of the damaged crops typically dealt with the event in the same way,
irrespective of whether it occurred on an open or closed range.
Most rural residents are consciously committed to an overarching norm of coopera-
tion among neighbors. In trespass situations, their applicable particularized norm,
adhered to by all but a few deviants, is that an owner of livestock is responsible for the
acts of his animals. Allegiance to this norm seems wholly independent of formal legal
entitlements. Most cattlemen believe that a rancher should keep his animals from eat-
ing his neighbor’s grass, regardless of whether the range is open or closed.108
104
RC Ellickson, Order Without Law (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass, 1991), 1.
105
Ibid, 185.
106
Ibid, 251.
107
Ibid, 3, 44.
108
Ibid, 52–3.
109
Ibid, 53.
110
Ibid, 54.
Proprietarian Conceptions of Statutory Access Rights 371
Ellickson claims that this practice of ‘reciprocal restraint’ arises out of the fact
that, over time, most residents will be both the ‘perpetrators’ and victims of cat-
tle trespass. Because the risks associated with cattle trespass are symmetrical, a
practice under which the victims routinely bear losses means that, in the long
run, losses will even themselves out without the need to waste time and spend
money in the resolution of disputes.111
From this study, and others, Ellickson formulates the following general
hypothesis:
members of a close-knit group develop and maintain norms whose content serves to
maximise the aggregate welfare that members obtain in their workaday affairs with
one another. [S]tated more simply, the hypothesis predicts that members of tight
social groups will informally encourage each other to engage in cooperative behav-
iour.112
111
Ibid.
112
Ibid, 167 (emphasis in original; references omitted).
113
Ibid, 176.
114
Ibid, 177, 181, 284.
115
Ibid, 130, 143.
116
E&W Report, para 4.54.
372 Scott Grattan
the dominant and the servient land so as to give them common membership of
Ellickson’s close-knit group. Put another way, there is simply too much ‘social
distance’120 between the parties for them to be regarded as neighbours in any-
thing other than the physical sense.
This extended reach of the NSW Act cannot be justified on the basis of
preventing a departure from a natural spirit of neighbourliness. If the second-
generation access legislation is to extend to this situation, then one must rely on
an economic, rather than a proprietarian, justification. In that case it would be
appropriate to include in the NSW Act a provision that allows for the payment
of compensation to the servient owner to reflect the financial value of the access
rights to the dominant owner. It will be recalled that such a provision exists in
the E&W Act in relation to non-residential dominant land.121 This would result
in a fair amount of compensation to be paid in circumstances where there is no
natural ‘neighbourliness’ that would otherwise require the granting of access.
CONCLUSION
In one of her many stimulating pieces about property, Carol Rose identifies the
role of storytelling in the classical justifications for the institution of private
property.122 Rose argues that a gap exists in the theories of Locke and
Blackstone between the self-interested individuals who need private property to
provide them with the incentive to labour, and the kind of individual needed to
create and maintain the very same property system. In order to ‘slide smoothly’
over this gap, ‘property needs a tale, a story, a post hoc explanation’.123
There is a similar gap with regard to justifications for legislation that creates
access rights. How do we reconcile our endorsement of the freedom that private
property affords to self-interested individuals with our desire to avoid such
property rights being exercised unreasonably? The answer is that the
justifications given by the law reform authorities responsible for the enactment
of access legislation have a narrative quality which glosses over the irreconcil-
able nature of the problem.
We have seen that the first-generation legislation, though couched in the dis-
course of public interest, is simply based on the efficient use of resources. This
boils down to setting-off the respective private preferences of different individ-
uals. By contrast, the dominant narrative adopted for the justification of the sec-
ond-generation legislation is bona fide proprietarian. The narrative involves the
subordination of the private preferences of the servient owner to a vision of a
proper social ordering: the co-operative and harmonious relations between
neighbours. We are told that it is unnatural for neighbours to rely on their strict
legal rights with respect to access issues.
The work of Ellickson has been examined in order to flesh out the concept of
what is involved in good neighbourly behaviour. We have noted that the E&W
Act can be seen as conforming to Ellickson’s theoretical model of mutually
beneficial co-operative behaviour among members of a close knit group with
respect to their everyday affairs. However, the NSW Act, in allowing access for
major new building projects, is something akin to a Trojan Horse. Hidden
inside the harmless looking vehicle of neighbourly behaviour, is the harsh iron
of compulsory access for commercial development. Some might even regard this
as the triumph of corruption over virtue.
Part VI
Keynote address
19
Sharing Homes: Property or Status?
STUART BRIDGE
A PROBLEM OF PROPERTY
Two or more people live together in a house or flat the title to which is vested in
at least one, possibly both or all, of them. They share occupation. Their respec-
tive rights to beneficial ownership, determined by reference to the law of trusts,
will in turn impact on many vital issues, four of which can be detailed here:
(a) The division of the property, or its proceeds of sale, when the persons cease to
share the home, possibly on the breakdown of a relationship between them, possibly
when one leaves to take up employment elsewhere. Not only may it be necessary to
determine the parties’ respective interests in the property to effect an appropriate allo-
cation, it may also be necessary to decide whether a sale of the property should be
ordered to realise the capital represented by the home.
(b) The effect on the property, and on the rights of those continuing to live there, of
the death of one of the persons sharing the home. Before the rules of succession (as set
out in the deceased’s will, or as statutorily imposed in the event of intestacy) can be
applied, it must be established what rights the deceased had in the home (and, indeed,
whether death may have extinguished any interest by virtue of survivorship).
(c) The rights of creditors who have security over the shared home, by way of mort-
gage, in the event of default by the debtor. The question arises whether those who are
living in the home (and who may not be personally indebted to the creditor) can assert
an interest against the mortgagee, and whether they can defend proceedings for re-
possession.
(d) The rights of unsecured creditors over the home, where one of the persons living
there is indebted to them.
There are many reasons why the outcome of this kind of litigation is difficult to pre-
dict. In practice the most important is, perhaps, that so much depends on inferences as
to the parties’ intentions drawn from their behaviour; different tribunals will
inevitably reach different conclusions. But a more fundamental reason is that the pre-
cise juristic basis underlying a successful claim to entitlement is uncertain. Not only is
it unclear from what facts the court should be prepared to infer the necessary agree-
ment, it is also far from clear what terms the notional agreement must contain.2
Over the last twenty years, developing case-law has done little to clarify the
principles on which the courts are to act in determining beneficial entitlement,
while at the same time the circumstances in which those principles are called
upon have multiplied. Not only has there been a further increase in owner-
occupation such that seven out of ten English homes are now owned by their
occupiers, but the number of persons sharing homes outside marriage, or indeed
a marriage-like relationship, is greater than ever before.3
In an ideal world, all those sharing a home would come to an amicable agree-
ment before they begin to share, detailing their respective beneficial entitle-
ments, which agreement would be perfected by an express declaration of trust.
This is good practice, and on more than one occasion the Court of Appeal has
warned solicitors of the necessity to advise clients to make express provision
when they are purchasing property which they intend to share as a home.4 The
Land Registry has promoted this practice by requiring a declaration of trust to
be made where title is vested in persons as joint registered proprietors.5
Unfortunately, as the cases demonstrate, this degree of organisation is not uni-
versal. In particular, when a registered proprietor of a house invites another to
come and share the home with them, and they move in, there is often no discus-
sion of their respective rights, and no legal advice is taken. As no property is
being purchased, there is no obvious reason to have recourse to a solicitor.
Dr Cretney, highlighting the uncertainty of the principles applicable where no
express declaration of trust had been made, was doing so at a time when the
common law was already showing signs of inability to cope. In the two water-
shed cases of Pettitt v Pettitt6 and Gissing v Gissing,7 the House of Lords had
addressed the problem of informality by reference to the doctrines of implied,
resulting and constructive trust. There can be little doubt that Lord Diplock’s
famous speech in Gissing was intended to restrict, not to expand, the circum-
stances in which a beneficial interest could be claimed. But certain dicta, taken
ONS.
4 Walker v Hall [1984] 5 FLR 126, 129, per Dillon LJ, Carlton v Goodman [2002] EWCA Civ 545,
r 2(2)).
6 [1970] AC 777.
7 [1971] AC 886.
Sharing Homes: Property or Status? 379
out of context, proved to be the germ of a much more generous view adopted by
divisions of the Court of Appeal over the following decade. The salient passage
is well-known:
A resulting, implied or constructive trust—and it is unnecessary for present purposes
to distinguish between these three classes of trust—is created by a transaction between
the trustee and the cestui que trust in connection with the acquisition by the trustee of
a legal estate in the land, whenever the trustee has so conducted himself that it would
be inequitable to allow him to deny to the cestui que trust a beneficial interest in the
land acquired. And he will be held so to have conducted himself if by his words or con-
duct he has induced the cestui que trust to act to his own detriment in the reasonable
belief that by so acting he was acquiring a beneficial interest in the land.8
The relatively expansive first sentence, inferring that a trust would be imposed
whenever the legal owner had acted in such a way that it would be inequitable
(unfair, unjust) to deny the claimant a beneficial interest, became frequently
cited. In isolation, it appears to provide the court with the power to do as it sees
fit in response to the behaviour of the legal owner, and to award a beneficial
share of whatever size it thought appropriate in the circumstances of the indi-
vidual case. This invocation was enthusiastically accepted by Lord Denning
who proclaimed the birth of equity’s ‘latest progeny’, the ‘new model’ con-
structive trust, brought into the world by Lord Diplock and nourished by the
Court of Appeal.9 It is doubtful that Lord Diplock would have recognised his
own offspring, and it is notable that in nurturing the child, the second sentence
of Lord Diplock’s dictum, which was clearly intended to qualify the first, was
given little emphasis.
Take Eves v Eves,10 later to be cited as an example of a party acting in reliance
on an express agreement to share beneficially.11 The male legal owner tricked
his female partner into believing that she would be added to the legal title when
she became 21. The property was conveyed into his sole name. They had two
children, and she carried out extensive works to the house and garden. When the
relationship broke down, she claimed a share in the house. The language of
Lord Denning, holding that she was entitled to one-quarter of the equity in the
home, is redolent of discretion:
It seems to me that this conduct of Mr Eves amounted to a recognition by him that, in
all fairness, she was entitled to a share in the house, equivalent in some way to a dec-
laration of trust; not for a particular share, but for such share as was fair in view of all
she had done and was doing for him and the children and would thereafter do.12
Throughout the 1970s, the Court of Appeal adopted a flexible approach
towards those living together outside marriage, and applied broad notions of
8
[1971] AC 886, 905.
9
‘. . . a few years ago even equity would not have helped her. But things have altered now. Equity
is not past the age of child bearing’. per Lord Denning MR in Eves v Eves [1975] 1 WLR 1338, 1341.
10
[1975] 1 WLR 1338.
11
Lloyds Bank v Rosset [1991] 1 AC 107.
12
[1975] 1 WLR 1338, 1342.
380 Stuart Bridge
fairness and justice in deciding their respective shares in the property on the
breakdown of the relationship.13 The retreat from this attractively malleable,
albeit conceptually arid, position was probably heralded by the decision of the
House of Lords in Williams & Glyns Bank Ltd v Boland14 at the end of the
decade. It was implicit in Boland that where two persons had jointly contributed
towards the acquisition of a home the title to which was vested in one only, it
followed that the implied trust to which that arrangement gave rise would take
effect as a trust for sale with the potential to bind third parties, most
significantly mortgagees. This constituted a tacit acceptance of the reasoning of
Lord Denning in the seminal decision in Bull v Bull15 twenty-five years previ-
ously. As Boland went on to hold that mortgagees could be bound by persons
‘in actual occupation’ whose interests were hidden behind the legal title even
though those interests were not appropriately recorded in the land register, con-
cern gripped the lending institutions.16 As time went on, banks found practical
means of dealing with the problems to which Boland gave rise,17 but the clear
acceptance of the proprietary effect of the beneficial interest behind the trust led
the courts to reassess the principles on which such interests were being claimed.
Burns v Burns18 was decided two years after Lord Denning’s retirement as
Master of the Rolls. It would have been difficult to conceive of a claimant more
likely to obtain a beneficial interest in the home pursuant to a ‘new model’ con-
structive trust. She and her male partner had lived together from 1961 until 1979.
A house was purchased, with the assistance of mortgage finance, for their joint
occupation in 1963 and conveyed into his sole name. He paid the deposit and the
mortgage instalments. She stayed at home, looking after their two children, and
did not take up any paid work until 1975, after which she paid the rates, the tele-
phone bills, and provided some fixtures and fittings. However, as these pay-
ments were not referable to the acquisition of the house, and she could not
establish, by proof of discussions or conversations, that they had a ‘common
intention’ to share the property beneficially, the Court of Appeal rejected her
claim to a beneficial interest:
The mere fact that parties live together and do the ordinary domestic tasks is, in my
view, no indication at all that they thereby intended to alter the existing property
rights of either of them.19
May LJ, sympathising with Mrs Burns, considered the only solution to the prob-
lem facing those like her was by way of legislation:
13 Eg Cooke v Head [1972] 1 WLR 518, Richards v Dove [1974] 1 All ER 888, Hall v Hall [1982]
3 FLR 379.
14 [1981] AC 487.
15 [1955] 1 QB 234.
16 This led to a reference to the Law Commission: see Law Com No 115 Property Law: The
When one compares this ultimate result with what it would have been had she been
married to the defendant, and taken appropriate steps under the Matrimonial Causes
Act 1973, I think that she can justifiably say that fate has not been kind to her. In my
opinion, however, the remedy for any inequity she may have sustained is a matter for
Parliament and not for this court.20
Burns v Burns and the later Court of Appeal decision in Grant v Edwards21
cleared the decks for the House of Lords in Lloyds Bank v Rosset22 to re-state
the orthodox view of the ‘common intention’ constructive trust. Lord Bridge set
out two possible routes to the establishment of a beneficial interest in the
absence of an express declaration of trust.
First, where prior to the acquisition of the home (or, exceptionally, at some
later date), there has been an agreement, arrangement or understanding reached
between those sharing occupation that the property is to be shared beneficially.
This must be proved by evidence of express discussions between the partners,
however imperfectly remembered or however imprecise the terms might have
been. The claimant must also show that they acted to their detriment or
significantly altered their position in reliance on the agreement so as to give rise
‘to a constructive trust or a proprietary estoppel’.
Secondly, although there is no evidence of an agreement or arrangement to
share beneficially, an interest may be claimed on the basis of conduct alone.
However, that conduct is apparently limited to direct financial contributions to
the purchase price of the property by means of an initial capital payment or pay-
ment of mortgage instalments: ‘it is at least extremely doubtful whether any-
thing less will do’.23 This dimension of the ‘common intention’ constructive
trust bears the hall-marks of the resulting trust.
It must be acknowledged that the re-statement of principle in Rosset did not
ultimately lead to a greater clarity of reasoning in the decision-making process.
In particular, it did not solve the problems which the courts were experiencing
with the quantification of beneficial entitlement. Two subsequent decisions of
the Court of Appeal illustrate the inconsistency of approach. In Midland Bank
Plc v Cooke,24 the parties married in 1971 and moved into a house which had
been conveyed into the sole name of the husband. The purchase price of £8,500
had been provided as to £6,540 by way of a mortgage, as to £1,000 out of the
husband’s savings, and as to the remainder by gift from the husband’s parents.
This gift was crucial. Although no express common intention could be found by
the court, the gift, construed as a gift to both spouses jointly, conferred on the
wife a beneficial interest in the home. Moreover, the court was then obliged, in
quantifying the wife’s share, to take account of all conduct which threw light on
20
Ibid, at 345.
21
[1986] Ch 638.
22
[1991] 1 AC 107.
23
Ibid, at 133.
24
[1995] 4 All ER 562.
382 Stuart Bridge
the shares which were intended.25 In other words, the court was not bound to
deal with the matter on the strict basis of the trust which resulted from the cash
contribution to the purchase price, but was free to attribute to the parties an
intention to share the equity in different proportions. The Court of Appeal held
that the wife was entitled to a half-share in the equity to give effect to the par-
ties’ common intention, although she had made a financial contribution of less
than one twelfth to the acquisition of the home.
In Drake v Whipp,26 an unmarried couple joined in the purchase of a barn
which they intended to convert into a dwelling-house for their joint occupation,
the property being conveyed into the sole name of Mr Whipp. The purchase
price of £61,254 was met as to £25,000 by Mrs Drake, and as to the remainder
by Mr Whipp. Conversion works totalling £129,536 were then carried out, only
£13,000 of which were contributed by Mrs Drake, although both parties put in
many hours of their own labour into the property. The Court of Appeal con-
sidered that there was a clear common intention that the property be shared
beneficially. It accordingly applied constructive trust principles to quantify the
parties’ respective shares, approached the matter broadly, looking at the parties’
entire course of conduct together, and held that Mrs Drake had obtained a one-
third share of the equity.
It may be that these two authorities, indicating that the size of the contribu-
tion may bear little relation to the quantum of the beneficial interest, can be
reconciled by reference only to the elusive factor of common intention.27 But
this is an element which requires considerable ingenuity, if not inventiveness, to
‘discover’ and leads inevitably to a lack of consistency in the decided cases.28
The invocation of common intention requires in many cases that the court
examine in great detail the parties’ conversation and correspondence over many
years, as well as their financial dealings. This is a time-consuming and costly
exercise, which has rightly been criticised by the courts.29 Much depends on
findings of fact, as oral statements of intent and entitlement are bound to be con-
tested in the climate of acrimony and incrimination which pervades these dis-
putes. In consequence, it is extremely difficult for those advising clients of what
they can reasonably expect to obtain from litigation and for those seeking to
mediate disputes under what is a continually shifting shadow of the law.
Some have argued that proprietary estoppel, mentioned in the same breath as
constructive trust by Lord Bridge in Rosset, may be of greater utility in ascer-
taining the rights of those who live together without having made any formal
arrangements.30 Estoppel does have an attractive flexibility, based upon its
broad view of unconscionability and its readiness to tailor the remedy to the
25
[1995] 4 All ER 562, 574, per Waite LJ.
26 [1996] 1 FLR 826.
27 See, for example, Megarry & Wade, The Law of Real Property, 6th edn, 2000, 10–029, n 78.
28 Gardner (1993) 109 LQR 263.
29 Hammond v Mitchell [1991] 1 WLR 1127.
30
Hayton [1990] Conv 369.
Sharing Homes: Property or Status? 383
individual case. However, there remain difficulties which have yet to be ad-
dressed satisfactorily. First, orthodox property rights are not conferred until the
court has intervened. The inchoate equity which exists prior to judicial decree is
of uncertain scope and it has yet to be definitively settled whether it binds a third
party acquiring the land in question.31 Secondly, the relationship between
estoppel and constructive trust is far from clear. While there are clearly some
common traits (notably the requirement of detrimental reliance), there are also
significant differences. Thirdly, the exercise of equitable discretion to give effect
to the expectation which has been generated leads to further inconsistency and
unpredictability.32
This final point is probably the most telling. In so far as proprietary estoppel
may respond with subtlety and sophistication to the demands of informal living
arrangements, it does not, indeed cannot, do so with consistency. As a result, the
predictability of outcome which is a reasonable expectation of those seeking to
bring claims for beneficial entitlement is not necessarily assisted by the opera-
tion of estoppel. In Pascoe v Turner,33 the plaintiff and defendant lived together
for the best part of ten years as husband and wife. Although the house was
legally owned by the plaintiff, following the breakdown of their relationship he
assured her that the house (and everything in it) was hers. In reliance on this
assurance, she spent money on redecorations, improvements and repairs, reduc-
ing her life-time savings to £300. Although the sum expended was relatively
small when compared to the value of the property, the duty of the court was to
give effect to the equity which had arisen in her favour, and that equity could
not be satisfied without granting a remedy which assured to her security of
tenure, quiet enjoyment and freedom of action in respect of repairs and
improvements without interference from the plaintiff. The Court of Appeal
concluded that the plaintiff had to be compelled to give effect to his promise and
her expectations, and upheld the order of the court below that the plaintiff exe-
cute a conveyance of the freehold interest in the property into the defendant’s
name.
Twice in the last year the Court of Appeal has considered a claim, founded on
proprietary estoppel, made by a claimant carer.34 In each case, the carer was
assured by an elderly person that if he continued living with them and caring for
them, he would have a home for life. In each case, he was disappointed when
that person died and he discovered that no provision to such effect had been
made. There is no doubt that each of these claimants could establish uncon-
scionability—the central element of proprietary estoppel according to recent
31
Megarry & Wade, 6th ed, 13–028 et seq. Land Registration Act 2002, s 116, Lloyd v Dugdale
(2002) 2 P & CR 167.
32
Cooke (1997) LS 258, Gardner (1999) 115 LQR 438. Note also Sledmore v Dalby (1996) 72
P & CR 196, Jennings v Rice [2002] EWCA Civ 159, CA 22 February 2002.
33
[1979] 1 WLR 431.
34
Campbell v Griffin [2001] EWCA Civ 990; Jennings v Rice [2002] EWCA Civ 159, CA 22
February 2002.
384 Stuart Bridge
The work of the Law Commission has concentrated on the beneficial ownership
of the shared home, in all its manifestations. As described in its Eighth
Programme36a the scope of its project was to review the law:
as it relates to the property rights of those who share a home, in relation to that shared
home, except—for example—where a person’s occupancy is attributable to a tenancy,
contractual licence or his or her employment. Our review therefore covers a broad
range of people, including friends and relatives who share a home as well as unmar-
ried couples and married couples (other than on the breakdown of the marriage).
The Sharing Homes project was not therefore limited by reference to any rela-
tionship between individuals, but by reference to the property being shared. The
Law Commission was very keen to ensure that any proposals were not restricted
to particular kinds of relationship- that they cover married as well as unmarried
couples, and also those who live together as friends or companions, as relatives,
or where one person cares for another. However, the project was narrower in its
ambit than other reform exercises which have concentrated on the rights and
obligations of ‘cohabiting couples’ in many areas of the law. In this sense, the
project focused on property rather than status. It comprised an attempt to intro-
duce certainty, consistency and predictability in the ascertainment and
quantification of beneficial entitlement to the shared home.
35
‘The fundamental principle that equity is concerned to prevent unconscionable conduct per-
meates all the elements of the doctrine. In the end the court must look at the matter in the round’.
Gillett v Holt [2001] Ch 210, 225, per Robert Walker LJ.
36
[2001] 1 AC 596, 605.
36a Law Com No 274.
Sharing Homes: Property or Status? 385
41
Para 3.22.
42
It would be sufficient to assert a property interest that one of the parties had a beneficial inter-
est in the home. However, in the vast majority of cases the claim would be brought against a legal
owner. For the purposes of this discussion, that shall be assumed.
Sharing Homes: Property or Status? 387
bringing up her partner’s child and working in the home. G’s claim is of course
similar in kind to that of Mrs Burns.
These examples were deliberately chosen in an attempt to see how a contri-
bution-based scheme could apply neutrally to circumstances which would tend
to give rise to different responses:
There can be little doubt that a court would instinctively have greater sympathy for
the unmarried mother (G) . . . than for the child of elderly parents (C) . . . But when it
comes to characterising their respective claims, it is not really possible to articulate the
differences without reference either to the probable intentions of the parties or to the
nature of the relationship from which the claim has arisen.43
43 Para 3.71.
44 Para 4.25 et seq.
45 [2001] 2 FLR 970.
388 Stuart Bridge
the wife had made no initial cash contribution to the purchase of the house and
her contribution to the mortgage was at best ‘indirect’, the court held that she
should nevertheless be able to establish a beneficial interest. As Nicholas
Mostyn QC, sitting as a deputy High Court judge, stated:
Otherwise these cases would be decided by reference to mere accidents of fortune,
being the arbitrary allocation of financial responsibility as between the parties.46
STATUS AS SOLUTION
These ‘new legal approaches’ all involve the deployment of ‘status’. A status
may be ‘voluntary’ in that its legal consequences are applied only to those who
have given their consent (and who, one hopes, are aware of those conse-
quences). Many would argue that it is more acceptable to accord a status to
persons who agree to its application than to impose a status on persons who
have not so agreed and who, if asked, may well have been fiercely opposed to
the legal consequences which it carries. Marriage is of course a voluntary status.
While it does not have significant consequences for the spouses’ property enti-
tlements during its subsistence,49 on breakdown and divorce the reallocative
jurisdiction contained in the Matrimonial Causes Act can be invoked and the
parties’ resources redistributed according to the statutory criteria. In particular,
the court is to have regard to the future needs of the spouses as much as their
strict property entitlements. The existence of the statutory jurisdiction means
that when spouses separate there is rarely any need to invoke the principles of
implied trust or proprietary estoppel to determine their respective interests in
the matrimonial home. The district judge, concentrating on financial realloca-
tion to accommodate the spouses’ future needs, simply will not want to know.
A detailed proposal to create a new form of voluntary status was made in the
Civil Partnerships Bill introduced into the House of Lords in January 2002 by
Lord Lester of Herne Hill.50 Unrelated couples of the same or opposite sex who
had been living together in the same household for a minimum period of six
months were to be entitled to register their partnership with the Registrar-
General of Births, Deaths and Marriages. The effect of registration would be to
equate the partners with spouses in many, although not all, respects. The impact
of the proposals would be felt in areas as diverse as mental health, certain social
benefits, protection from domestic violence, life assurance, death registration,
succession to residential tenancies, intestacy, family provision, pension schemes
and rights of action in respect of fatal accidents. The Bill made provision for a
divorce equivalent, terminating the civil partnership, known as a ‘cessation
order’, and—of greatest significance to the current discussion—for a form of
ancillary relief, an ‘intervention order’, whereby on cessation the court would
have power to transfer property from one party to another or to make orders for
financial provision or to require the sharing of pension rights.51
Although warmly received in its Second Reading debate,52 the Lester Bill was
withdrawn from the House of Lords in February 2002 as the government con-
sidered the cost implications of a civil partnership scheme. In the following
December, Barbara Roche, the Minister for Social Exclusion and Equalities,
reported the conclusion of a review by the Cabinet Office that there was a
‘strong and clear’ case for allowing same-sex couples to register their relation-
ships and that a consultation paper would be published in due course.53 It was
not, however, intended to offer the benefits of a registration scheme to unmar-
ried couples of the opposite sex, on the basis that they are not prevented from
marrying. In that respect, the government’s plans are narrower in their scope
50 Hereafter ‘the Lester Bill’. A Bill to similar effect was also introduced into the House of
than the provisions of the Lester Bill, but its acceptance in principle that same-
sex couples should obtain rights broadly analogous to those currently enjoyed
by married couples is a highly significant development. We shall of course have
to await the outcome of the consultation exercise for details of the scheme
ultimately to be adopted.
One thing is clear. The impact of a civil partnership scheme is inevitably
restricted, in that it can only apply to those couples who duly register their part-
nership. It confers, like marriage, a status based upon the consent of the
participants. It cannot, and does not purport to, deal with the problems of
informality affecting those who have not sought to regulate their relationship or
their property affairs. The reluctance of parties to accord formal recognition to
their relationship and to make adequate express arrangements governing their
property entitlements has led some jurisdictions to ‘fill in the gap’ by resort to
an adjustive discretion based on the imposition of status. This has been partic-
ularly prevalent in Australia, where the majority of states have enacted ‘de
facto’ legislation making provision for those (of the same or opposite sex) who
live together outside marriage.54 New Zealand has gone even further, its
Property (Relationships) Act (which came into force on 1 February 2002) effect-
ing an assimilation of the rights of married and unmarried couples on separa-
tion or death.
The Scottish Law Commission considered the financial consequences of
breakdown of relationships outside marriage in its 1992 Report on Family
Law.55 It did not favour a comprehensive system of financial provision on
termination of cohabitation similar to that applicable on divorce, in part
because it was felt that the imposition of a property-sharing regime (and also the
recognition of continuing financial support) was inappropriate for couples who
may well have opted not to marry in order to avoid such consequences.
However, the Commission did consider that there was some unfairness in
allowing economic gains and losses arising out of the contributions and
sacrifices made during a relationship of cohabitation to lie where they fell on its
breakdown. It accordingly recommended that where a cohabitation terminated
otherwise than by death, either party should be able to apply to court, within
one year of the termination, for financial provision on the basis of the statutory
principle enshrined in section 9(1)(b) of the Family Law (Scotland) Act 1985. In
making this proposal (which has not yet been acted upon), the Scottish Law
Commission argued that it would give cohabitants the benefit of a principle
designed to redress imbalances arising out of the circumstances of a non-
commercial relationship where a party is likely to have made contributions or
sacrifices without counting the cost or bargaining for a return.
54 Certain states (eg New South Wales) also make provision for the regulation of other ‘domes-
tic relationships’. As well as vesting a discretion in the court to adjust the parties’ property rights,
the legislation renders enforceable any cohabitation contracts which the parties may have entered
on condition that each party has obtained prior independent legal advice.
55 (1992) Scot Law Com No 135.
Sharing Homes: Property or Status? 391
The Law Society has for some time argued that legislation making provision
for cohabiting couples should be introduced in England and Wales alongside a
system of civil partnership recognition.56 The approach it advocates involves
the imposition of a status on ‘cohabitants’, who would be defined so as to
include both opposite sex and same sex couples.57 Claims would only be pos-
sible once the parties had shown commitment by living together for two years,
or by having a child.58 If that threshhold condition were met, each would have
the right on separation to apply for capital provision from the other, taking
account of ‘any economic advantage derived by either party from contributions
by the other, and of any economic disadvantage suffered by either party in the
interests of the other party or of the family’.59 This formula, borrowed from the
Scots law of ancillary relief on divorce, would allow the court to take account
of contributions made towards the upbringing of children and the upkeep of any
shared property.
Although the Law Society considers the case for capital provision orders is
strong, to protect those who have been disadvantaged by the relationship which
has broken down, it does not consider that maintenance orders should be
available to the courts save in exceptional circumstances. They should be nei-
ther automatic nor permanent, and should be designed merely to provide
resources for training (or re-training) or to reflect the economic disadvantage
suffered which cannot be compensated through capital provision.60 In no cases
should maintenance orders extend beyond four years after separation. The Law
Society is clearly at pains to make a very clear distinction between the rights of
married couples and those of unmarried couples. The latter have not evinced the
commitment of the former, and so it is justifiable to apply more restrictive prin-
ciples where an unmarried couple part.
It appears extremely likely that civil partnerships between same-sex couples
will soon obtain legal recognition in England and Wales at least, and that one
of the most important consequences of registration will be entitlement to apply
to the court for property adjustment orders on breakdown of the relationship.
But while such reform will be welcomed by those who are currently denied the
right to marry, it is important that its limitations are acknowledged, in particu-
lar that it does not offer any solution to the problem of informality identified by
the Law Commission. Sooner or later, it is to be hoped sooner, it will be neces-
sary to consider again the desirability of the imposition of a status on those
couples, of the same or opposite sex, who neither marry nor register their rela-
tionship, with the vesting in the court of an adjustive discretion enabling it to
56
Cohabitation: the case for clear law (July 2002) contains the most recent statement of Law
Society policy in this area.
57
Two persons (either opposite or same sex) living together in the same household in a relation-
ship analogous to that of husband and wife, ibid., para 55.
58 Ibid, paras 57–62.
59 Ibid, paras 94–105.
60 Ibid, para 111.
392 Stuart Bridge
reallocate the parties’ property in the event of relationship breakdown. This will
require an assessment of the extent to which the autonomy of the parties to
come to their own arrangements should be compromised by the necessity for
paternalistic intervention—in short whether it is now necessary to impose on
parties to a particular kind of relationship a legal status irrespective of their
wishes.