Central Bank Digital Currencies. Motives, Economic Implications and The Research Frontier

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 30

BIS Working Papers

No 976
Central bank digital currencies:
motives, economic implications
and the research frontier
by Raphael Auer, Jon Frost, Leonardo Gambacorta,
Cyril Monnet, Tara Rice and Hyun Song Shin

Monetary and Economic Department

November 2021

JEL classification: C72, C73, D4, E42, E58, G21, O32, L86.

Keywords: money, digital currencies, central banks,


central bank digital currencies, CBDC, stablecoins,
cryptocurrencies, distributed ledgers, big tech, data
privacy.
BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic
Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other
economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical
interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their
authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS.

This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org).

© Bank for International Settlements 2021. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be
reproduced or translated provided the source is stated.

ISSN 1020-0959 (print)


ISSN 1682-7678 (online)
Central bank digital currencies: motives, economic implications
and the research frontier

Raphael Auer, Jon Frost, Leonardo Gambacorta, Cyril Monnet∗, Tara Rice and Hyun Song Shin1

Abstract

In just a few years, central banks have rapidly ramped up their research and development effort on
central bank digital currencies (CBDCs). A growing body of economic research informs these activities,
often focusing on the “reserves for all” aspect of CBDCs for retail use. However, CBDCs should be
considered in the full context of the digital economy and the centrality of data, which raises concerns
around competition, payment system integrity and privacy. This paper gives a guided tour of the
growing literature on CBDCs on the microeconomic considerations related to operational architectures,
technologies and privacy, and the macroeconomic implications for the financial system, financial
stability and monetary policy. A set of questions, particularly on the cross-border dimensions of CBDCs,
remains unresolved, and calls for further work to expand the research frontier.

Keywords: money, digital currencies, central banks, central bank digital currencies, CBDC, stablecoins,
cryptocurrencies, distributed ledgers, big tech, data privacy.
JEL classification: C72, C73, D4, E42, E58, G21, O32, L86.

 Bank for International Settlements.


∗ University of Bern and Study Center Gerzensee.
1 This paper was prepared for the Annual Review of Economics. When citing this paper, please use the following:
R Auer, J Frost, L Gambacorta, C Monnet, T Rice and H S Shin, “Central bank digital currencies: motives,
economic implications and the research frontier”, Annual Review of Economics, vol 14, 2022, submitted, DOI:
https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-051420-020324. The views expressed here are those of the
authors and not necessarily those of the Bank for International Settlements. The authors would like to thank
Giulio Cornelli for outstanding research assistance.

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 1


Introduction

The digitalisation of economies has far-reaching implications for many areas of economic inquiry, not
least for monetary economics and the concept of money itself. With the massive volumes of data that
digital activities generate come new opportunities and challenges for societies and the monetary
system.
A tradition in monetary economics is to view money as a coordination device that serves as a
substitute for the complete list of economic transactions – ie as society’s “memory” of all economic
transactions (eg, Kocherlakota (1998)). Yet this abstract definition of money leaves open its institutional
underpinnings, upon which the welfare consequences of the institution of money may crucially depend.
In particular, due to the inherent network effects in payments (Rochet and Tirole (2006)) and the
potential for the proprietary use of data, digital forms of money pose substantial challenges for
competition, privacy and integrity. It is in this context that an important public debate has arisen on the
issuance of new, digital forms of central bank money and how they will affect the architecture of the
monetary system.
The idea that central banks would issue digital forms of money for general use is a natural
progression from the issuance of physical cash. In addition, banks have had access to digital forms of
central bank money for several decades in the wholesale payment system. However, the debate on the
issuance of digital central money that is accessible to ordinary users has picked up pace only recently.
Initially, policy reports took a cautious approach to issuance (eg CPMI-MC (2018)). The last few years
have witnessed a broadening of the debate. Alongside the rise and fall of cryptocurrencies, the
emergence of global stablecoin proposals such as Facebook’s Diem, and increasing technological
disruption in finance, central banks have adopted a more proactive stance by anticipating a future when
innovation and the entry of new private forms of money will already have transformed the monetary
system, rather than treating the current system as the benchmark. Central banks have begun to engage
in research on CBDCs and, in some instances, also their development. According to a survey from late
2020, 86% of global central banks are conducting research on CBDCs, and as of July 2021, 56 central
banks have publicly communicated their research or development efforts (see Boar and Wehrli (2021)
and Auer et al (2020)). At the time of writing, two central banks have launched CBDCs and several are
conducting pilots. However, there is as yet no broad consensus among central banks on the need for
CBDC issuance.
Alongside a fast-changing and intense policy debate, a still nascent but rapidly growing academic
literature has emerged that examines the broader economic implications of CBDCs. The focus to date
has mostly been on the “reserves for all” aspect of CBDCs, and the associated balance sheet implications
for central banks in their interactions with commercial banks, the impact on the effectiveness of
monetary policy, and the implications for financial stability.2 In policy circles, meanwhile, there is
growing confidence that a targeted economic design can achieve public policy goals while limiting
systemic implications. Hence, the discussion focuses more on the potential enhancements to payments
inclusion and efficiency, and the policy objectives of ensuring competition, data privacy and integrity of
payment systems (see Auer and Böhme (2020, 2021) and BIS (2021)).3 Many central banks, meanwhile,

2 See the discussion in Section 4. Studies assess how the issuance of retail CBDCs could affect the balance sheets
of central and commercial banks and the respective volatility (ie Kumhof and Noone (2018), Brunnermeier and
Niepelt (2019)), lending and the interest rates of commercial banks (Andolfatto (2021)), and the bounds and
effectiveness of monetary policy (ie Bordo and Levin (2017), Davoodalhosseini et al (2020)).
3 See also Kiff et al (2020), Bank of Canada (2020), ECB (2020), Bank of England (2020), People’s Bank of China
(2021).

2 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


see CBDCs as a public infrastructure that could help to ensure competition and open markets in the
face of competitive threats from the incursion of big techs into payment systems.4
This chapter gives a guided tour of the growing literature on CBDCs in economics and other related
disciplines. It investigates the motivations for retail CBDC issuance, analyses the underlying trade-offs
in their design, and discusses their potential macroeconomic implications. In so doing, the chapter
brings together an academic and a policy perspective. It bridges these discussions and identifies
potential avenues for future research.
As currently discussed, CBDCs can be defined as a form of digital money, denominated in the
national unit of account, which is a direct liability of the central bank (Group of central banks (2020)).
These can be either for wholesale use (ie by financial institutions) or retail use (ie by households and
businesses – the general public). CBDCs can be either account-based, meaning that they rely on some
form of identification, or token-based, meaning that they allow for anonymity in payments. CBDCs can
be based on either distributed ledger technology (DLT) or conventional technological infrastructures. In
most cases, CBDCs are being designed such that they preserve the two-tier structure of the monetary
system, with a division of labour between the public and private sector.
Focusing mostly on retail CBDCs, research is helping to inform their design, as central banks have
worked with economists, computer scientists, legal scholars and other specialists to understand the
challenges and opportunities of CBDCs. Moreover, the research literature on CBDCs is developing
rapidly to keep pace with developments in economies around the world, fusing theory and practice. Yet
there are notable gaps in this literature. In particular, there are important questions around CBDCs and
cross-border payments, on which policy development is marching beyond the research frontier, and
where research insights could help to inform the design and international coordination of CBDC
projects. Understanding the international implications of CBDC issuance for issuing and receiving
countries, as well as the potential for CBDCs to improve cross-border payments and integrate (digital)
economies, remain important challenges where research can usefully inform real-world policy efforts.
The paper is organised as follows. Section 1 gives a brief historical account of CBDC research and
development, from predecessors of modern digital currencies to the work of central banks in the past
decade. Section 2 discusses the motivations of central banks to issue CBDCs in the light of the challenges
of the digital economy. Section 3 discusses microeconomic considerations on CBDC architectures,
technological infrastructures and data privacy. Section 4 then discusses the macroeconomic implications
for the financial system, monetary policy and society. Section 5 discusses the cross-border implications
and potential of CBDCs – a set of issues at the research frontier. Finally, Section 6 concludes.

1. A brief history of CBDC initiatives

Over the centuries, various forms of money have emerged to meet the economic needs of the time.
Coins, banknotes, cheques and credit cards were each innovations in their own day (Giannini (2011)). In
recent decades, new payment technologies have been added to this list, from phone-based mobile
money to smartphone-based payment apps, and from stablecoins to a new form of central bank-issued
money in the form of CBDCs.
CBDCs can be seen as a digital extension of the existing forms of central bank money, namely cash
(bills and coins) and central bank settlement accounts. As a digital liability of the central bank, wholesale
CBDCs could become a new instrument for settlement between financial institutions. Retail (or general

4 That said, the motivations differ across countries. Particularly in emerging market and developing economies,
CBDCs are often seen as a means to enhance financial inclusion, granting universal access to digital means of
payment (see ie Boar and Wehrli (2021). In the light of a more globalised economy, CBDCs are also being
explored to enhance cross-border payments.

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 3


purpose) CBDCs would be a central bank liability, a form of “digital cash” accessible to all.5 Graph 1 gives
a schematic overview that compares retail CBDC with cash and a consumer’s bank deposits.

The monetary system with a retail CBDC Graph 1

Source: Auer and Böhme (2021).

The idea of extending central bank money in digital form to the public is not new. For instance,
Tobin (1987) proposed the idea of “deposited currency”, or “a medium with the convenience of deposits
and the safety of currency”, to enhance payments and reduce the reliance on deposit insurance.
Over the past several years, a number of central banks have started internal projects to better
understand the technology of cryptocurrencies and more broadly the potential application of
distributed ledger technology (DLT) to government-issued digital currencies.6 Starting in 2015, central
banks in eg Canada, the Netherlands, Singapore and the United Kingdom ran internal experiments.
These generally concluded that DLT was not yet mature enough for use in major central bank payment
systems.
From 2016 onward, a number of central banks launched research projects on digital currencies for
wholesale purposes. Several focused on DLT for the settlement of high-value interbank payments.7
Some involved cooperation between central banks on wholesale CBDCs for cross-border payments.8

5 “General purpose” and “retail” are used interchangeably to refer to CBDCs that individuals and non-financial
firms could access. For an overview and relevant definitions, see Bech and Garratt (2017) and CPMI-MC (2018).
6 Grym (2021) discusses the Avant payment card, created by the Bank of Finland in the 1990s for retail use, as
an early form of CBDC. In 2014, the Central Bank of Ecuador launched a project called “Dinero electrónico”
(electronic money) to allow individuals to make mobile payments through a central bank-operated system
(Valencia (2015)). Yet the system failed to attract a significant number of users, and was discontinued in 2016
(White (2018); Arauz et al (2021)).
7 For instance, the Bank of Canada launched Project Jasper in early 2016 (Bank of Canada (2017)). In November
2016, the Monetary Authority of Singapore launched Project Ubin (MAS (2016)), on a tokenised form of the
Singapore dollar on DLT. The Bank of Canada, Bank of England and MAS subsequently worked in collaborative
research with banks on challenges in cross-border payments and settlement and how various initiatives –
including wholesale CBDC – could help. See Bank of Canada-MAS-Bank of England-HSBC (2018).
8 For instance, Project Stella involved joint research between the ECB and Bank of Japan (2019). Later, the
monetary authorities of Saudi Arabia and the United Arab Emirates, and of Hong Kong SAR and Thailand, also
announced cross-border work on wholesale CBDCs (SAMA-UAECB (2019); Bank of Thailand and HKMA (2020)).

4 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


The first publicly announced work on retail CBDCs was conducted by Sweden’s Riksbank (Sveriges
Riksbank (2017)). In Sweden, cash use has been declining precipitously (see Sveriges Riksbank (2020)),
and the Riksbank has initiated a societal discussion on access to a central bank payments instrument
for the general public. Over time, this “e-krona” project has been further developed (Sveriges Riksbank
(2020)).
Another particularly advanced CBDC project at present is the electronic Chinese yuan (e-CNY) of
the People’s Bank of China (PBC). Since 2020, this CBDC has been piloted in several cities in China. The
e-CNY will be a cash-like liability of the PBC available to the general public – and to foreign visitors of
China – through account-based interfaces.
Meanwhile, in October 2020, the Central Bank of the Bahamas issued the Sand Dollar, widely
considered to be the first live retail CBDC. The Sand Dollar is issued through authorised financial
institutions and allows accessibility to a digital wallet for residents via either a mobile phone application
or a physical payment card. The Eastern Caribbean Central Bank (ECCB) launched its DCash in March
2021. DCash is distributed by licensed financial institutions and used for financial transactions between
consumers and merchants, as well as in people-to-people (P2P) transactions.
Graph 2 gives a timeline of these and other CBDC projects. Overall, it is clear that work on CBDCs
has been under way at a number of central banks since at least the mid-2010s, accelerating into the
2020s. The stocktake in Auer et al (2020) of all central bank publications shows that, as of mid-July 2021,
at least 56 central banks had published retail or wholesale CBDC work. At least three countries (Ecuador,
Ukraine and Uruguay) have completed a retail CBDC pilot. Eight retail CBDC pilots are ongoing,
including in China, Korea and Sweden.9 Meanwhile, 40 central banks have published research on retail
CBDCs, and 19 have announced research or development work on a wholesale CBDC (in some cases in
addition to work on retail CBDCs).

9 Additionally, the Marshall Islands, which currently use the US dollar as legal tender and have no monetary
authority, have launched the SOV (short for sovereign) project, a digital currency proposed by private
developers. This project is not included in the database, as it is not a central bank project. See IMF (2018) for
a critical discussion.

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 5


Timeline of CBDC projects since 2016 Graph 2

Sources: Auer, Cornelli and Frost (2020); Auer and Böhme (2021).

2. Motivations for CBDC research and development

Motivations for retail CBDC research and development are driven by global trends, but also by country-
specific circumstances. Broadly, CBDCs should be seen in the context of the digitalisation of economies
and the growing centrality of data – particularly personal data – both in the economy and the monetary
system. The growing role of data brings many opportunities to reduce information asymmetries, cut
costs and enable new forms of money.10 Yet data also lead to new challenges for competition, privacy
and integrity – issues that the economics literature is only beginning to grapple with. Due to the network
effects inherent to money, new private players may quickly dominate the monetary system, leading to
serious competition concerns and working against the public interest.
These issues have been underscored by four developments. The first was the rapid rise in interest
in Bitcoin and other cryptocurrencies that compete with traditional forms of money (see Carstens
(2019)). However, cryptocurrencies are speculative assets rather than money. They are extremely volatile,
making it difficult to use them as a means of payment. In many cases, they are used to facilitate money
laundering, ransomware attacks and other financial crimes (Foley et al (2019), Paquet-Clouston et al
(2019)). Bitcoin in particular has few redeeming public interest attributes when its wasteful energy
consumption is taken into account. For instance, it is estimated that the Bitcoin network currently uses
as much electricity as the Netherlands (BIS (2021)).

10 For instance, the ability to keep full digital ledgers of transactions increasingly makes it feasible for agents to
have a full record of their interactions with other agents in the past – or money as memory (Kocherlakota
(1998)). Moreover, new “smart contracts” can make money programmable, allowing agents to automate
important functions (Bank of England (2020)).

6 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


A second development is the advent of private sector-issued stablecoins. Distinct from other
cryptocurrencies, stablecoins are designed to maintain a stable value through their backing of assets.
As such, these are only as good as the governance behind the backing. Despite progress made from
initial proposals,11 they still have the potential to fragment the liquidity of the monetary system and
detract from the role of money as a coordination device.12 In any case, to the extent that the purported
backing involves conventional money, stablecoins are ultimately only an extension of the conventional
monetary system.
A third development is the entry of big tech into payments, and more generally the disruption that
platform-based business models and big data bring to the financial system. The huge volume of
personal data that is collected and processed as an input into big tech business activity presents several
challenges for central banks (BIS (2020)). The first is that network effects make the payment system
prone to concentration and enable the formation of data silos that entrench the market power of firms
that have exclusive use of the data. The second is data privacy and governance. However, both the
competition and data governance imperatives need to be met while ensuring a third imperative: that of
ensuring the safety and integrity of the payment system against money laundering, ransomware attacks
and other illicit activities. Thus, digital innovation implies a “triple imperative” for the central bank in its
role at the centre of the monetary system: competition, data privacy and the integrity of the payment
system (Shin (2021)).
Finally, the Covid-19 pandemic has accelerated the adoption of digital payment technologies – a
trend that recalls previous epidemics (Saka et al (2021)). With that shift, it has also accelerated central
banks’ work on CBDCs in some jurisdictions. In the United States, early versions of Congressional
proposals for the pandemic-related fiscal stimulus included references to a “digital dollar” as a means
of quickly executing government-to-person payments, as an alternative to credit transfers and slow and
costly cheques (Brett (2020)).13
The general global trends aside, the motivations for CBDC research and development differ across
jurisdictions. Based on a survey of central banks of the BIS Committee on Payments and Market
Infrastructures (CPMI) in late 2019, Boar and Wehrli (2021) show that in advanced economies, central
banks are researching CBDCs to promote safety and robustness, or domestic payments efficiency (Graph
3). In other words, central banks see CBDCs as an opportunity to address risks to the safety of digital
payments, to reduce costs and to support central banks’ mandates for the smooth functioning of retail
and wholesale payments. Financial stability concerns are also an important driver of research and
development work – particularly in the light of the threat that private alternatives to sovereign fiat
currency may become dominant, issued by actors who are not accountable to the public and may not
support the stability of the financial system. Moreover, especially in emerging market economies (EMEs),
financial inclusion is an important motivation. Many central banks see CBDCs as a means of enhancing
access to payment services for the unbanked, ie those without access to a transaction account.

11 See for example the White Paper of the Diem Association, www.diem.com/white-paper/.
12 For a discussion of the risks to stablecoins’ value backing, see Arner et al (2020) and Frost et al (2020).
13 The Federal Reserve has ongoing research on retail CBDCs (Brainard (2020a,b)). In the Netherlands, the central
bank has emphasised that the pandemic underscores the need for a backup to private money (DNB (2020)).
In China, pilot testing for the e-CNY is coinciding with a phasing-out of pandemic-related mobility restrictions.
In Sweden, testing of the e-krona project continues even amidst central bank crisis management measures.

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 7


Motivations for issuing a CBDC
Average importance Graph 5

General purpose (retail) CBDC Wholesale CBDC

3 3

2 2

1 1

0 0
Payment Financial Payment Payment Financial Payment
safety/ Payment stability Monetary efficiency Financial safety/ Payment stability Monetary efficiency Financial
robustness efficiency policy (cross-border) inclusion robustness efficiency policy (cross-border) inclusion
(domestic) implementation (domestic) implementation

Average importance: AEs EMEs

1 = not so important; 2 = somewhat important; 3 = important; and 4 = very important.

Sources: CPMI survey of central banks; Boar et al (2020).

In addition to the stated preferences of central banks, some research looks at “revealed policy
preferences”, ie the factors that correlate with actual CBDC projects. Table 1 from Auer et al (2020)
shows that CBDC projects are more advanced in more digitised economies (as measured eg by mobile
cellular subscriptions) and in countries with a high capacity for innovation (measured by the World
Intellectual Property Organisation (WIPO) innovation output score). Moreover, they find that work on
retail CBDCs is more advanced where the informal economy is larger – consistent with the notion that
CBDCs, by creating a data trail for transactions, may help to formalise informal activities. Wholesale
CBDC projects are found to be more advanced in markets with greater financial development, which
may have higher demand for more efficient clearing and settlement services. Beyond research and
design issues, some central banks have sketched out scenarios in which they may consider CBDC
issuance, such as the encroachment of private stablecoins or cryptoassets, or a reduction in the use of
cash – eg Bank of Canada (2020), ECB (2020), Bank of England (2020)).

8 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


Multivariate ordered probit regressions on CBDC project indices1 Table 1

Wholesale CBDC project


Overall CBDC project index Retail CBDC project index
index
Mobile cellular subscriptions 0.013** 0.015*** 0.011** 0.022**
(per 100 people) (0.005) (0.006) (0.005) (0.010)
Innovation output score 0.045*** 0.067*** 0.082***
(WIPO) (0.010) (0.017) (0.019)
Informal economy 0.027* 0.033* 0.042*** -0.009
(% of GDP) (0.015) (0.018) (0.016) (0.026)
Financial development 3.909*** 3.303*** 4.287***
Index 2
(0.867) (0.775) (1.299)
Trade openness 3
-0.003 -0.016** 0.004* -0.001
(0.004) (0.007) (0.003) (0.004)
Number of observations 118 105 110 100 132 105
Pseudo R 2
0.167 0.241 0.144 0.244 0.263 0.352
Robust standard errors in parentheses; ***/**/* denotes results that are significant at the 1/5/10% level. Constants are not reported.
1
The table reports coefficients from an ordered probit model for the probability of a central bank engaging in no work on CBDCs (0), research
(1), a pilot (2) or a live retail or wholesale CBDC (3), as of August 2020. All independent variables are an average over the period 2013–19,
subject to data availability. 2 Svirydzenka (2016). 3 Sum of imports and exports divided by the country GDP. Data for 2018.

Source: Auer et al (2020).

While it is clear what drives central banks’ research efforts, the discussion on CBDCs also raises
more fundamental issues on their optimality, eg on the role of public versus private money and the key
distinctions between the two (eg Brunnermeier and Niepelt (2019), Bech and Garratt (2017), Adrian and
Mancini-Griffoli (2019), Fung and Halaburda (2016), Ketterer and Andrade (2016)). CBDC issuance might
also lead to an intensification of the competition between global currencies, and the need for central
banks to respond (or not) to CBDC issuance in other jurisdictions.
One concern with digital currencies in general, initially voiced with regard to global stablecoins, is
that they could threaten individual countries’ monetary sovereignty by displacing domestic currencies.
New “digital currency areas” may arise based on the business empires of individual digital platforms
rather than the boundaries of legal jurisdictions (Brunnermeier et al (2019)). Could similar concerns
apply to CBDCs? Many countries, particularly EMEs, already know the phenomenon of “dollarisation”
(or “euroisation” etc), where households and businesses use a foreign currency widely in daily
transactions and financial contracts (Levy Yeyati (2021)). Could CBDCs promote “digital dollarisation”?
Research on these aspects of CBDC issuance is scarce, but there are good reasons to think that
these risks could be mitigated. First, dollarisation is generally driven by the lack of public trust that the
domestic monetary authorities will maintain a stable value for the local currency – in particular a history
of high inflation or a lack of financial market development – rather than by the technological format of
a domestic or foreign currency. Second, a number of policy tools exist to address such risks. In particular,
an account-based design for CBDCs, based on identification, would mean that both the issuing central
bank and the central bank of a receiving country would need to agree to cross-border use, and would
have insights into aggregate cross-border use of a CBDC (see next section). Third, central bank
cooperation could mitigate the risks of currency substitution, as central banks from different
jurisdictions would have little interest in destabilising one another’s economies through widespread use

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 9


of a CBDC beyond the issuing country’s borders, and the FX mismatches for users that this entails.14
Thus, these concerns are unlikely to be a primary motivation of central banks to issue their own CBDC.
What of the concern that CBDCs could challenge the role of the US dollar as an international reserve
currency? In the public debate and in international relations research, such concerns have been aired
prominently (see Kumar and Rosenbach (2020)). Yet here too the economic drivers of international
reserve currency status are likely to far outweigh the availability of a sovereign fiat currency in digital
form. In particular, reserve currencies gain ground through deep capital markets with a large availability
of safe assets and hedging capabilities; trust in the long-term value of the currency and soundness of
the legal and regulatory system; and use in international trade, particularly for invoicing. In all these
areas, it is unlikely that a currency would displace the dollar by virtue of its digital nature alone.
Chorzempa (2021) refutes the idea of a “first mover advantage” in CBDC research and development,
showing that CBDC work in countries like China and the United States is driven primarily by domestic
motives, with little animus for currency competition. Still, this will likely remain an area of debate as
plans for the e-CNY, digital dollar and the digital euro move ahead, together with the projects of other
reserve currency central banks.

3. Microeconomic considerations: operations, technology, and privacy

Central bank motivations for issuing CBDCs are primarily of a microeconomic nature. They aim to
enhance payments inclusion and efficiency, as well as ensure competition, data privacy and the integrity
of their payment system. What does this imply for the optimal CBDC design and how such designs
would affect consumer welfare?15 This raises important issues pertaining to CBDC operational
architecture, the associated public-private sector cooperation and the welfare implications for
consumers, also in the context of data privacy considerations. In these cases, the literature has already
helped to inform the design of actual CBDC research and development, and to shed light on how CBDCs
may affect consumers. This section considers these issues in turn.

Operational architectures: what role for the private sector in a CBDC system?

A first consideration is how users would be convinced to adopt CBDCs in practice, and how the
operational architecture could involve the private sector so as not to overburden the central bank
operationally. One aspect is that retail payment behaviours show great inertia. For example, Brown et al
(2020) find that an exogenous introduction of more convenient payment methods led only to a
moderate average reduction in the cash share of payments. Arifovic et al (2017) show with experimental
evidence how fees influence the behaviour of buyers and sellers, and ultimately the take-up of a new
payment method.16 For CBDCs to be launched, to be adopted by the public and to enhance payments
efficiency, they must carefully define the role of the central bank and the private sector in line with their

14 Of course, the threat of dollarisation may discipline central banks and encourage low and stable inflation. In
some EMDEs, dollarisation is an active policy choice to import monetary stability. These considerations, too,
are largely independent of whether the foreign “hard currency” is offered in digital form.
15 For example, Bofinger and Haas (2020) see little justification for CBDCs based on allocative efficiency or user
demand. Yet notably, the starting point for their analysis is the current payment system, not the counterfactual
of platform dominance or widespread domestic currency substitution in the digital economy.
16 However, when behaviours change, they often do so quite persistently. In the same manner, changed payment
behaviours caused by the Covid-19 crisis, such as a greater use of digital payments, could have far-reaching
effects in the future.

10 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


respective comparative advantages, and improve payments without disintermediating the private
financial sector.
Almost all central banks considering a CBDC envisage that the private sector will play an important
role in a CBDC system, particularly in serving households and businesses. Both commercial banks and
non-bank PSPs must be able to provide consumer-facing services so that users can transfer funds from
a bank account, credit card or other payment services to a CBDC wallet. Users should further have the
choice to pay using a variety of payment devices, such as prepaid CBDC devices, cards with offline
capabilities or smartphone wallets that are standalone or integrated with bank or big tech apps. These
considerations show that there are cogent arguments for why a one-tier system fully operated by the
central bank (a so-called “Direct” CBDC following Auer and Böhme 2020 and 2021)) is undesirable. Direct
CBDCs would imply a large shift of operational tasks (and costs) from the private to the public sector.
Central banks neither aspire to replacing the private sector in these consumer-facing activities, nor are
they in a position to do so (Carstens (2019)).
An alternative is an operational architecture in which the private sector conducts all retail payments,
while the central bank operates a backup infrastructure. This class of “Hybrid” CBDC architectures (see
Graph 4, upper panel) combines the credibility of a direct claim on the central bank with the convenience
of private sector payment services. If a PSP fails, the central bank must be able to unambiguously honour
claims and, ideally, resume payments for the failing PSP’s customers without much delay. This capability
requires sufficient information about retail accounts (or pseudonyms in anonymous designs) to be
available to the central bank.
Some central banks may shy away from running a record of all retail data, for example due to
concerns about privacy and data security – an aspect that has been discussed in several advanced
economies (see below). Therefore, another option is a design in which the central bank has no
information on retail transactions, just as in today’s payment systems. One variant is an “Intermediated”
architecture, in which the central bank records only the wholesale balances of the individual PSPs (Graph
4, bottom panel). The downside is that the central bank needs to honour claims of which it has no direct
record. Consequently, to safeguard cash-like credibility, PSPs would need to be closely supervised to
ensure at all times that the wholesale holdings they communicate to the central bank add up to the
sum of all retail accounts.
A smart operational design may have profound welfare implications for consumers. Huynh et al
(2020) look at consumer preferences and adoption costs for various combinations of payment methods
and examine how the introduction of a CBDC affects welfare. Ultimately, CBDCs need to be designed
so that banks and PSPs continue to perform their core economic functions and maintain their resilience,
but do not exploit market power to collect excessive rents. There may be a role for the central bank to
set low fees on CBDC transactions to offer a competitive alternative and exert pressure in the margins
of private firms. This role is examined in Chiu et al (2019).

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 11


Retail CBDC architectures and central bank-private sector cooperation Graph 4

In the direct CBDC model (top panel), the CBDC is a direct claim on the central bank, which also handles all payments in real time and thus
keeps a record of all retail holdings. A hybrid CBDC architecture (middle panel) incorporates a two-tier structure with direct claims on the
central bank, while real-time payments are handled by intermediaries. The central bank however periodically retains a copy of all retail CBDC
holdings. An intermediated CBDC architecture, instead, runs a wholesale ledger (lower panel). In this architecture, PSPs would need to be
closely supervised to ensure at all times that the wholesale holdings they communicate to the central bank indeed add up to the sum of all
retail accounts.

Source: adapted from Auer and Böhme (2021).

Importantly, while the vast majority of central bank CBDC research and development projects
involve either a hybrid or intermediated (rather than direct) architecture (Auer et al (2020)), many
academic studies continue to describe CBDCs as if the central bank were taking on all operational tasks,
without any role for private intermediaries (see Section 4). In future, it will be important to model more
realistic CBDC designs, in line with the latest design choices of central banks. This will improve upon
current models that assume that the central bank conducts retail services or that CBDCs are offered in
unlimited quantities, fully displacing bank deposits.

12 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


CBDC technologies: how centralised is a CBDC?

Beyond the architecture of the operational design, a second consideration is the optimal technology
underpinning it. In this context, much emphasis has been put on novel forms of decentralisation enabled
via distributed ledger technology (DLT). The latter comes in two forms: the permissionless technology
that is used in Bitcoin, Ethereum and other cryptocurrencies, and the permissioned variant, in which a
network of known and vetted validators jointly augment a ledger.
CBDCs could in theory be run on a permissionless design that resembles Bitcoin, but this would be
inefficient and environmentally harmful. While it is technically possible to use the technology, based on
costly computing (ie “proof of work”) in which unknown validators perform the updating of transactions,
the economic cost is very high. Every batch of transactions has to be accompanied by a proof that a
substantial quantum of otherwise useless computations has been performed. This is not only inefficient
(see ie Budish (2018), Chiu and Koeppl (2019), and Auer (2019)), but it can lead to multiple equilibria (ie
“forks”, see Biais et al (2019)). For all these reasons, permissionless DLT based on proof of work is not a
viable technology for CBDCs.17
Instead, a number of central banks are considering decentralisation in the form of “permissioned”
DLT, in which a network of preselected entities performs the updating.18 Importantly, operational
resilience can also be achieved in traditional systems that store data multiple times and in physically
separate locations. The difference is that DLT is updated in a decentralised manner: in many DLT-based
systems, the ledger is jointly managed by different entities that do not trust each other’s data and
independently verify each new transaction. The cost is that each update of the ledger must be
harmonised between the nodes of all entities (generally known as “consensus mechanisms”), which, due
to the multiple involved rounds of communication, takes time.
Permissioned DLT is no silver bullet, however, and it only has economic merit under certain
circumstances. Such “permissioned” designs may have economic potential in financial markets and
payments due to enhanced robustness and the potentially lower cost of achieving good governance.
However, this does not come for free. In the setup of Auer, Monnet and Shin (2021), designated
validators verify transactions and update the ledger at a cost that is derived from a supermajority voting
rule. Without giving proper incentives to validators, however, their records cannot be trusted because
they cannot commit to verifying trades – thus giving rise to a public good provision game – and they
can accept bribes to incorrectly validate histories. These two frictions challenge the integrity of the
ledger on which credit transactions rely, and the process of permissioned validation supports
decentralised exchange as an equilibrium only if the rents validators receive are high enough. This
analysis suggests that a centralised operational design is often superior, unless weaknesses in the rule
of law and contract enforcement would necessitate a decentralised ledger.19

Data privacy and integrity

A third consideration centres on CBDCs and data privacy. The digitisation of payments is increasingly
generating a “data trail” of information on individual transactions, which can be easily transferred across
counterparties and used for a wide variety of purposes. For instance, transactions data from any digital

17 Abadi and Brunnermeier (2018), Saleh (2021), and Fanti et al (2019) examine the “proof-of-stake” variant, ie
betting on the truth instead of costly computation. However, it is unclear how robust this design is, due to the
possibility of so-called “long-range attacks” (see the survey of Deirmentzoglou et al (2019)).
18 Auer et al (2020) give a stocktake of CBDC designs, showing that DLT is envisioned in many current retail CBDC
prototypes that rely on software packages such as Corda, Hyperledger or Quorum.
19 This is closely related to Amoussou-Guenou et al (2019) whose analysis is the first to model the interaction
between validators as a game entailing non-observable effort to check transactions and amidst costly voting.

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 13


payment service can be used to determine individuals’ willingness to pay for goods and services and
thus to price-discriminate; individuals’ creditworthiness, ie ability to repay a loan; and – when combined
with other data sources – to give deep insights into individuals’ behaviour, beliefs and habits. A growing
strand of literature in economics assesses concerns around data privacy (Acquisti et al (2016)), which
are highly context-dependent. Digital applications generate troves of data but also severe information
asymmetries for users, who do not always know whether and where data are being collected and for
what purpose. As is already known in the literature on payments, cash has value to consumers because
it is by nature anonymous, thus protecting individuals’ privacy (Kahn and Roberds (2009)). Yet what
happens as cash use declines, and households are left only with private digital alternatives?
Several new papers model the privacy characteristics of different payment instruments and assess
the implications of their use for consumer welfare, including externalities between users. For instance,
Garratt and van Oordt (2021) discuss privacy in payments as a public good. Because individuals do not
internalise the full cost of using digital payment platforms, which fail to protect their privacy and help
to price discriminate against future consumers, social welfare is sub-optimally low. Introducing
“electronic cash” in the form of CBDC is one remedy. Relatedly, Garratt and Lee (2021) show that
payment data can drive the formation of a monopoly. Issuing a CBDC can help to preserve the market
structure and improve consumer welfare by giving an outside option to consumers that protects privacy.
This enables them to monetise private information. Key in this framework is that the central bank, as a
non-commercial entity, has no incentive to use private transaction data, and can credibly commit to
leaving such data untouched in a way that a private bank or digital platform provider could not. Agur
et al (2021) derive implications for an optimal CBDC design, which should trade off concerns about bank
disintermediation (competition with deposits) against the social value of maintaining a diverse set of
payment instruments (deposits, CBDC and cash) that offer different privacy benefits.
While CBDCs may thus offer benefits in terms of users’ privacy, there are trade-offs with other goals.
The most salient one is between user privacy and the integrity of the payment system. A fully
anonymous CBDC design, analogous to cash, could have severe downsides for payment system
integrity, allowing for illicit transactions, money laundering, terrorism financing etc. Wang et al (2021)
shows that a fully cash-like CBDC design could also increase tax evasion. Yet maintaining a full record
of transactions attached to users’ identities leads to its own challenges, in particular around cyber
security, with the potential for the central bank to become an attractive “honeypot” of data to hackers
(see Schilling (2019)). This is a further reason for some central banks to prefer an intermediated
architecture, as discussed above.20
Importantly, design features can help mitigate such trade-offs, as privacy does not need to be
synonymous with anonymity. In this area, too, research is helping to inform actual CBDC design. Darbha
and Arora (2020) outline the range of choices around the type of information to keep private and who
to keep it private from, as well as the cryptographic techniques and operational arrangements that can
support such decisions. Central banks can engineer systems to have greater privacy than private sector
systems, but there are costs involved, and adequate designs require public review and oversight. Gross
et al (2021) develop a proposal for cash-like privacy for users while addressing regulatory constraints,
using zero-knowledge proofs in a software-based CBDC system. Moreover, application programming
interfaces (APIs) in a CBDC system can constrict data exchange to only the necessary information for
any given transaction and give users greater control over the data that they generate (BIS (2021)).
Of course, technical design alone may not be sufficient to counter concerns that public authorities
(central banks and other government institutions) would use CBDC systems as an instrument for state
surveillance and control. It is easy to imagine how sensitive transactions data could allow authorities to

20 Even in a hybrid system, it may be possible to separate the individual transaction data from information on
individual user identities, and to enact rules and technological arrangements that restrict use of data to
specific, pre-defined purposes. For instance, the Bank of Jamaica is designing a CBDC system to require a court
order for insight into individual transactions.

14 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


track individuals, and to block their access to CBDC payments. Even if systems are designed to prevent
such practices, public concerns could also limit adoption of CBDCs. Here, institutional safeguards may
help to prevent abuse and ensure accountability for authorities.21
It is notable that in recent consultations, the public in some key jurisdictions has flagged privacy as
a key motivation for adopting a future CBDC (see ECB (2020)). Moreover, survey evidence shows that
users place greater trust in public authorities and traditional financial institutions, when it comes to
safeguarding their personal data, than they do in new players such as big techs (Armantier et al (2021)).
Sound technical designs and institutions for CBDC systems will be critical to ensure that the public trust
is maintained and that CBDCs deliver on the promise to users while upholding high standards of
payment system integrity.

4. Implications for banks, financial stability and monetary policy

Alongside a fast-changing and intense policy debate on CBDC technology and privacy, a growing
academic literature has emerged on the macroeconomic implications of CBDC introduction. This
academic literature centres around three main themes. First is the effect of CBDC issuance on
commercial banks and aggregate lending or investment. Second are the effects of introducing CBDCs
on financial stability, ie the ability of the financial system to absorb shocks and thus the likelihood of
financial crises. The third theme concerns CBDCs as a new monetary policy tool. In this section, we
review the academic literature according to these three themes.

CBDC issuance and commercial banks

Academics have pointed out that the structure of the banking system can determine the efficiency gains
(or losses) of introducing a CBDC. Three papers stand out here: Andolfatto (2021), Keister and Sanches
(2020) and Chiu et al (2019). They respectively consider the effects of introducing CBDC on a
monopolistic banking system with the perspective of the liability side, ie bank deposits (Andolfatto
(2021)), a perfectly competitive banking system (Keister and Sanches (2019)) and an imperfectly
competitive (but non-monopolistic) banking system (Chiu et al (2019)). On the asset side, ie loans, banks
can be considered as operating in a competitive market in all three papers. The line of reasoning is quite
similar across these papers: by offering a CBDC, the central bank induces commercial banks to make
their deposits more attractive and increases the costs of funds for commercial banks, which can
adversely impact aggregate lending and investment.
All three papers start from the premise that commercial bank deposits are used as a means to pay
some (digital) transactions where cash is not accepted by sellers. Banks, however, cannot satiate the
economy with deposits because they face some governance issues: they need to hold some assets as
collateral, and their net worth has to be positive. As a result, deposits carry a liquidity premium and they
pay a relatively low interest rate, making them a cheap and preferable source of funds for banks.22
However, the low interest rate reduces the value of deposits as a means of payment because it increases
the opportunity cost of holding funds in deposits (low payment efficiency).
When the central bank issues an interest-bearing CBDC, banks have to adjust the remuneration on
their deposits, since otherwise deposit holders would convert them into the better remunerated CBDCs.
Hence, bank deposits become a more expensive source of funds for banks (impacting banks negatively)

21 For instance, the Bank of Jamaica has clarified that individual CBDC data can only be shared with a court order.
22 Deposit insurance is another reason why deposits are a cheap source of funds, as we do not internalise the
cost of bank’s bankruptcy and do not require a risk premium in our deposits.

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 15


while they become a more sought after means to pay (impacting deposit holders in a positive manner).
This is the essential trade-off in these papers.
When the banking system is perfectly competitive, banks have no room to buffer the shock on their
funding cost and they pass it through to borrowers. As a result, aggregate lending and investment falls.
Keister and Sanches (2019) show that when payment efficiency is low (when banks’ governance friction
is high), introducing a CBDC may imply sufficiently large gains in payment efficiency to compensate for
the loss in aggregate investments. Of course, when the banking sector is imperfectly competitive (on
the liability side), introducing a CBDC can only make things better. Indeed, in that case, banks enjoy a
buffer that they can use to offset the increase in the cost of funds. In this context, Andolfatto (2021) and
Chiu et al (2019) show that introducing a CBDC with a relatively low interest rate always achieves a
higher allocative efficiency. Maybe more surprisingly, it can even increase the level of aggregate
investment by making deposits more attractive. The CBDC rate cannot be too high, however, as
otherwise banks deplete their buffer and they will start passing through to borrowers the increased
costs of funds.
In their calibration, Chiu et al (2019) find that a CBDC expands bank intermediation if its interest
rate is between 0.30% and 1.49%. At the maximum, it can increase loans and deposits by 1.96% and
total output by 0.21%. The CBDC leads to disintermediation, however, if its rate exceeds 1.49%.
If central banks issue CBDC, they can surely lower the cost of funds for commercial banks by
lowering the rate of their lending facility (while preventing banks, eg via regulation, from arbitraging
between CBDC and the lending rate).23 Under this scenario, the central bank becomes the main
intermediary between CBDC holders and the real economy. Analysing this, Brunnermeier and Niepelt
(2019) and Fernández-Villaverde et al (2021) derive a Modigliani-Miller theorem of sorts: when it is free
to move funds around and commercial banks do not face any cost to expand their balance sheet, the
equilibrium allocation the economy attains without a CBDC can also be attained with a CBDC. Yet this
result (like the Modigliani-Miller theorem) is fragile. For example, Piazzesi and Schneider (2020) show
that, when banks have to hold (liquid) assets to back their deposits and face asset management costs,
then the equivalence breaks down, even though banks could obtain funding directly from the central
bank.
One potential question is why don’t banks tap other sources of funds if deposits become more
expensive. In particular, banks could retain earnings to increase equity funding, or issue longer-term
bonds. This could offer more stable sources of funds to commercial banks to limit disintermediation.
These options are generally not present in the academic literature, or if they are, they are not used in
equilibrium (see Chiu et al (2019)), which makes the disintermediation result quite “easy” to obtain. The
reason for their absence is one of tractability: it is difficult to model the evolution of a bank’s balance
sheet in a dynamic model. Monnet et al (2020) take a first stab at this problem and consider how
introducing a CBDC would modify the way banks fund their investments. This is also important for the
effect of a CBDC on financial stability (see below). They show that, again, banks can buffer the higher
cost of funding after a CBDC issuance by changing the structure of their assets and passing those gains
on to deposit holders, to leave them indifferent between a CBDC and bank deposits. However, the true
reason for disintermediation is when the central bank increases its remuneration rate on reserves, a tool
that central banks in many jurisdictions already use. As this rate increases, banks find it profitable to
stop lending to the real economy and hold reserves instead.24 In a somewhat similar vein, Niepelt (2021)
shows that when the interest rate on reserves is set too high, banks could expand their balance sheets
beyond the optimal level by, for example, issuing too many deposits. However, in his setup, a CBDC is

23 This also raises the question: why was there investment inefficiency in the first place?
24 See eg Belton et al (2020), who examine the 2011 FDIC change in the assessment base for bank deposit
insurance. They show that banks can engage in liquidity hoarding and lower credit creation in the case of a
relatively high remuneration rate on reserves.

16 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


unable to correct that inefficiency because it can only increase the cost of funds for banks, while
optimality would require a low (negative) interest rate on deposits.
Relatedly, Eren et al (2021) argue that bank disintermediation can be efficient when it is
accompanied by lower reserves. In the long run, CBDC can mitigate negative externalities and allow
banks to increase lending despite a smaller balance sheet.
All the papers above take a stance on the structure of the banking sector, with little or no impact
on the broad end result: CBDCs can improve allocative efficiency as long as their remuneration rate is
not too high. However, note that CBDCs could also modify the structure of the banking system itself,
by weakening smaller banks without access to large funding markets. In this case, introducing a CBDC
might lead to a wave of mergers and acquisitions and ultimately to a more concentrated banking sector
(see Garatt and Zhu (2021)). Then, assessing the benefits of a CBDC on allocative efficiency becomes
intertwined with an equilibrium analysis of the structure of the banking sector, and so becomes more
elusive than ever.

The effects of CBDCs on financial stability

Being a liability of the central bank, a CBDC is a safe substitute for commercial bank deposits. Since the
latter can be risky when the amount held is more than the threshold defined by the deposit insurance,
there is a risk that, in a crisis, the availability of a CBDC would induce deposit holders to shift their
holdings from the commercial banking system to the CBDC. Note that it is the risk of a systemic run
that increases, rather than just the risk of a run on a single individual bank. The reason is that, with or
without a CBDC, households can always stage a run on an individual bank by moving their deposits to
a bank they think is safer, but leaving funds within the banking system. The presence of a CBDC will not
affect this type of run, but it could well increase the probability of a systemic bank run (Fernández-
Villaverde et al (2021)). Also, systemic bank runs may be reinforced by the fact that banks have lower
equity buffers when a CBDC is made available (see the previous subsection).
While this intuitive point has been made very early on, also in speeches by policymakers (eg
Broadbent (2016)), it is not always true that CBDC will increase fragility, and models can help clarify
which assumptions are necessary to drive the increased fragility result. Also, the picture is not all dark.
CBDCs being a digital instrument could help to alert the central bank as to whether a bank run is under
way (Keister and Monnet (2019)). Further, it might well be that, while bank runs may be inevitable, they
are less damaging to the economy when a CBDC is available (Williamson (2019)). The canonical model
of a bank run – Diamond and Dybvig (1989) – has become one of the most useful benchmarks for
studying the fragility of the banking system. The so-called DD model is a real model in the sense that
only real resources are deposited in the bank, and there is no cash; it places maturity transformation,
rather than liquidity issuance, at the forefront of the bank’s business. Depositors may run on the bank’s
resources when they expect that others will run as well because the bank will then not have enough to
pay them what it promised later. This run equilibrium depends, among other things, on an implicit
sequential service constraint.
Fernández-Villaverde et al (2021) analyse the effect of a CBDC in the context of the DD model. They
recognise that deposits in a CBDC would give the central bank access to real resources that it can invest.
They assume that, while the central bank does not have the ability, knowledge or technology to invest
in productive assets, it can lend to investment banks who have these attributes. They thus obtain
another equivalence result whereby the allocation obtained with a CBDC is the same as without it. Yet
there is more: they argue that CBDCs would eliminate the run equilibrium because deposits at the
central bank are not callable and nobody can force the central bank to liquidate the long-term project.
In other words, central bank deposits are protected against forced liquidation.25 Therefore, a CBDC

25
A similar argument is found in Brunnermeier and Niepelt (2019).

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 17


eliminates the run equilibrium in their model, and the allocation is efficient, because the central bank
can freely lend to investment banks that compete with commercial banks. This, however, comes at the
cost of having the central bank being the sole provider of deposits, which allows it to deviate from the
socially optimal contract (although it is not very clear why an independent central bank would want to
do so – see discussion above). It would also have the power to invest only in specific projects and face
pressure from political authorities. In this case, a CBDC could jeopardise the independence of the central
bank. See also Niepelt (2021) for a discussion of the political economy arguments surrounding CBDCs.
Schilling et al (2020) take the model with a monopoly central bank a step further by relaxing the
assumption that a CBDC is a real deposit claim. Rather, a CBDC is a nominal asset that households can
spend. Although households cannot force the central bank to pay them well, they can “run” on the
central bank by trying to get rid of CBDC holdings, ie they can engage in a “spending spree”. Such a
spree is triggered by the belief that a CBDC will lose its purchasing power in the future, which makes it
optimal to spend it today. They then show that the central bank will not be able to achieve allocative
efficiency, financial stability and price stability all at once. For example, to obtain financial stability the
central bank must make sure that a CBDC has enough purchasing power in the future – that is, there
must be enough goods produced later on – which might distort allocative efficiency. But we are very far
from this type of extremely centralised economy, and no major central bank is considering a CBDC with
these features.
Williamson (2019) departs from the basic DD structure to study the role of banks as providers of
liquidity insurance.26 In this setup, buyers do not know if they will meet sellers who only accept digital
deposits, or also cash. Holding a bank deposit insures buyers against those events. Williamson does not
impose the sequential service constraint but instead assumes that banks can go bankrupt because of
bad investment choices. After observing some signals, deposit holders learn that some banks will fail,
but they do not know if their bank will fail. This uncertainty may trigger a switch to the “safe harbour“
of a central bank liability instead, thus triggering a bank default. In addition, a novel aspect of
Williamson’s model is that bank deposits circulate as a means of payment, while in DD they are just
used for saving. In this, Williamson gets closer to the very idea underlying deposit insurance, that a
bank’s default is costly because it disrupts the payment system.
In this context, Williamson shows that, when cash (earning a zero interest rate) is the only
withdrawal option, the incentive to run is lowest when the nominal interest rate on a safe and illiquid
asset (typically government debt) is high; ie the interest rate spread is high. The reason is that in this
case, holding cash has a large opportunity cost and so households know that banks do not hold much
of it. Since the bank’s cash holdings will be split pro rata in the case of a run, they do not expect to
receive much cash if they run on the bank. This makes running a sub-optimal strategy.
Introducing an interest-bearing CBDC has a direct advantage: it improves payment efficiency
because it can be traded with all sellers, while cash was only accepted by a subset of sellers. However,
the relevant spread for the run decision is now smaller and runs will now be more likely. However, a
CBDC improves payment efficiency, so that runs will be less disruptive to the overall economy. There is
hence a greater tendency with CBDCs for banking panic equilibria to dominate equilibria without panics,
and Williamson concludes that “CBDC issuance may encourage banking panics, but that goes hand-in-
hand with panics being less disruptive than in a world with physical currency.”
All the above papers have in common that they consider how a safe, government-issued instrument
affects the stability of the financial system. Putting aside payment efficiency considerations, it is worth
stressing that households can already run on the banking system by eg purchasing government debt,

26 Maturity transformation could easily be included in Williamson’s analysis.

18 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


the long-term debt of large corporates, or any other non-bank related assets.27 These assets are usually
absent from the DD model. Speculating, it is likely that the effect of government debt on financial
fragility is the same as CBDCs when it is considered as a savings instrument (as in Fernández-Villaverde
et al (2021)), but CBDCs also bring payment efficiency. All in all, it is likely that a CBDC would not modify
the incentives to run, but it may well improve efficiency.
Keister and Monnet (2019) show that, aside from payment efficiency, another benefit of a CBDC is
information efficiency. As DD show, information is key when it comes to preventing a manageable
situation from becoming unmanageable from the banking regulator’s viewpoint. But more often than
not, banks have the incentives to delay relaying information about their situation, in the hope that, for
instance, they will be bailed out when the situation becomes unattainable. When households make a
run on the financial system by withdrawing cash, the central bank only becomes aware of this with a
lag. In the case of a CBDC, the story is different because transfers are digital and (should be) immediate.
When households make a run on the financial system, they transfer their commercial bank deposits into
a CBDC. Then the central bank can learn the origin of the funds that are being transferred. With such
real-time data, the central bank can react quickly and take measures to stop the outflow of funds, either
by proclaiming a bank holiday or by lending funds to the institutions undergoing a run.
While intuitive, the argument that a CBDC increases financial fragility is actually difficult to justify
when considering it in a general equilibrium model, with all facets of CBDCs. Therefore, design
recommendations based on financial stability arguments should be taken with a grain of salt. This
includes eg Kumhof and Noone (2018) who argue that bank deposits should not be freely convertible
into a CBDC, or Bindseil (2020) who argues for position limits on a CBDC. While these designs would
indeed make CBDCs more innocuous for financial stability, they would distort payment efficiency in all
states of nature where financial fragility is not an issue, ie in most states of the world.
Finally, we note that the higher payment and information efficiency that a CBDC brings in normal
times as well as in crisis time should induce the regulator to reflect on current policies to address too-
big-to-fail and banking sector resilience, including deposit insurance. These existing frameworks are
certainly not costless and addressing the subsidy to banks from systemic importance remains an
important area of international policy efforts (FSB (2021)).

The effects of CBDCs on monetary policy

As discussed in the previous subsection, the digital nature of CBDCs implies that they provide
information that the central bank can exploit in order to make the financial system less fragile. The same
applies for monetary policy: CBDCs supply information to the central bank regarding the economy, and
being digital they are also, almost de facto, programmable. These features considerably enlarge the
monetary authority’s toolkit. For example, Davoodalhosseini (2021) shows that by making transfers to
those who need money the most, the central bank improves the allocation relative to “helicopter drops”
that would affect all households in the same way. In short, the central bank has a better idea of when
households are using the CBDC, allowing it to act on that information. Also, when a CBDC is available
to all, it allows for a direct implementation of monetary policy, hitting the core of the intertemporal
decisions of households and firms, rather than through the indirect and imperfect banking channel.
With such a CBDC in its toolkit, the monetary authority can then rethink its overall monetary policy

27 Moreover, these risks are not new. Baubeau et al (2021) show that runs from commercial banks to government-
backed savings banks, which were only permitted to hold government securities or cash, worsened the credit
contraction in the French Great Depression in 1930–31. They suggest that this argues for careful CBDC design.

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 19


strategy (Bordo and Levin (2017)). The estimated gains for the United States could be substantial and
amount to a permanent increase of GDP of as much as 3% (Barrdear and Kumhof (2016)).28
In addition to being programmable and thus allowing information-specific monetary transfers, a
CBDC can change the implementation framework of monetary policy. In Assenmacher et al (2021), the
central bank essentially operates a corridor system “for all” – that is, all firms in the economy can access
the central bank lending facility and not only banks. The corridor is defined as the difference between
the CBDC lending and the CBDC deposit rate. They find that payment efficiency requires that there is
no cost of holding CBDC, which in this model means that the lending rate should be equal to the deposit
rate. Also, for investment efficiency there should neither be a cap on CBDC loans nor any haircut on the
collateral pledged to secure a loan, so that CBDC loans should be unconstrained.
Previous papers, however, do not say much on how CBDC would affect monetary policy over the
business cycle. Bordo and Levin (2017) offer some avenues in their discussion. They argue that the CBDC
interest rate could serve as the main tool for conducting monetary policy. With the disappearance of
cash, that interest rate could be set to (any) negative levels, thus doing away with the “zero lower bound”
on nominal rates. While the zero lower bound has been “broken” on central bank reserves in many
jurisdictions, the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates has often been used by central banks to
justify positive (and distortionary) levels for the inflation target, so as to get some room for manoeuvre
in recessions. On top of that, the zero lower bound has been found to be the basis for a multiplicity of
equilibria and the existence of an equilibrium with liquidity traps in some models (Benhabib et al (2001)).
Doing away with the zero lower bound would contribute to establishing optimal inflation targets in all
stages of the business cycle and possibly eliminate the presence of liquidity traps.
At a time when many central banks are adjusting their monetary policy strategy, Bordo and Levin
(2017) argue that CBDC would allow moving away from inflation targeting to price level targeting. In
their views, contingent CDBC transfers could make price level targeting easier to implement. They argue
that price level targeting would facilitate the formulation of consumption and investment plans of
households and firms because the cost of a representative basket of consumer items (as measured in
terms of the CBDC) would be reasonably stable over the medium run and roughly constant in the longer
run. They argue this could benefit lower-income households and small businesses, which typically have
little or no access to sophisticated financial planning advice or complex financial instruments that can
help insure against such risks.
While CBDCs would allow for targeted transfers and negative interest rates conditioned on data or
the stage of the business cycle, they would further blur the distinction between fiscal and monetary
interventions, thus making issues around the fiscal-monetary nexus more acute (see Bassetto and
Sargent (2020)). Some authors have argued that the central bank’s balance sheet would balloon if it
were to introduce CBDC as a central bank account for all (Bindseil (2020)), and the dangers of large
central balance sheets for their independence from the fiscal authority are well known. These were
discussed by Plosser (2019) in the context of quantitative easing. The fact that the central bank would
be able to make targeted positive or negative transfers would magnify these issues.
Finally, CBDCs could alter the international transmission of monetary policy. With a two-country
dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model, Ferrari et al (2020)) find that the presence of a
CBDC amplifies the international spillover of shocks. Yet such spillovers can be significantly dampened
if the CBDC possesses specific technical features, such as adjusting the remuneration rate on the CBDC
flexibly (eg using a Taylor rule). Careful design of CBDCs could help mitigate potentially adverse macro-
financial implications. For instance, CBDCs could be designed to preclude or limit their use outside the

28 The role of positive transfers in achieving better allocations is illustrated in Levine (1991). Davoodalhosseini et
al (2020) shows that the results extend when the information remains private, and the central bank can use a
menu of transfers of both cash and CBDCs so that households give (some of their) information by choosing
from the menu.

20 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


issuing country, eg through limits on non-resident holdings or fees on very large or frequent cross-
border transactions.

5. CBDCs, cross-border payments and the international monetary


system

CBDCs raise many questions at a domestic level, but they raise even more in the cross-border dimension.
Research in this area is still in its infancy. This section thus sheds light on issues at the research frontier,
in particular around the promise of CBDCs for improving cross-border payments in an increasingly
globalised economy. In what follows, we sketch the issues, and then offer avenues for future research
to inform international policy debates and CBDC design efforts.
Cross-border payments suffer from four primary challenges: they are generally costly, often slow,
suffer from low traceability and transparency, and are not widely accessible to some people. For this
reason, the G20 has made enhancing cross-border payments a priority, endorsing in 2020 a multi-year,
multi-dimensional programme to enhance such payments. Faster, cheaper, more transparent and more
inclusive cross-border payment services would deliver widespread benefits for citizens and economies
worldwide, supporting economic growth, international trade, global development and financial
inclusion (CPMI (2020)). CBDCs are seen by many central banks as an opportunity to address these
persistent challenges. However, most CBDC projects focus on domestic issues and use cases. Given this
early state of play, the thinking behind CBDCs for cross-border use is exploratory and will be subject to
considerable further economic and practical examination before the investigation of their cross-border
use gathers pace.
A key difference between CBDCs and efforts to improve the existing payments infrastructure is the
opportunity to start with a “clean slate”. Because many of today’s frictions are rooted in differences
between domestic payment systems (eg opening hours, technical standards, data requirements),
making large-scale changes across jurisdictions is challenging. If central banks take the international
dimension into account when designing their domestic CBDCs and commit to interoperability,
consistent standards and coordination of CBDC designs, many problems inherent in today’s legacy
technologies and processes could be avoided. That said, if CBDCs are not designed with the
international dimension in mind, fragmentation of CBDC systems similar to the current fragmentation
of payment systems is possible. That is why central banks are focusing on this issue from the get-go. A
survey of 50 central banks conducted in early 2021 shows that a quarter are thinking of incorporating
interoperable features in their CBDC design with a view to reducing frictions in cross-border and cross-
currency settlement (Auer, Boar, Cornelli, Frost, Holden and Wehrli (2021) and CPMI et al (2021)).
Cross-border CBDC arrangements could be designed in such a way that they allow a more diverse
group of banks and non-banks access to central bank money for settling payments. This might lead to
a greater variety of “front-end” cross-border payment services, helping to achieve more inclusive cross-
border payment services. In particular, Auer, Haehne and Holden (2021) consider three models for multi-
CBDC arrangements – ranging from basic compatibility between individual CBDCs to the establishment
of a single multi-CBDC system. A first model is one of compatible CBDC systems, which could provide
an additional means of settling transactions from existing markets in central bank money across borders,
allowing a more diverse group of banks and non-banks to settle payments in central bank money, and
hence a broader variety cross-border and cross-currency payment services. A second model involves
interlinked CBDC systems that could build on these potential improvements to offer additional safety
via payment-versus-payment (PvP) settlement through a technical interface between domestic systems.
Alternatively, common clearing mechanisms could also add efficiencies, especially when linked with FX
trading venues. The third multi-CBDC model, a single multi-CBDC system, could offer the same
improvements as interlinking systems but with additional integration. In such a single system, the

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 21


participating central banks jointly set the rule books and operate the infrastructure, and mutually
recognise each other’s participants.29 In a single jointly operated system, all foreign exchange
settlements would be PvP by default and trading venues could also be integrated into mCBDC systems
to further reduce complexity. Any design principles for such multi-CBDC arrangements would need to
be coordinated at the global level so that they meet the needs of all countries and are widely adopted
to limit arbitrage. Here multilateral collaboration is paramount.

6. Conclusion

CBDCs are an idea whose time has come. If properly designed, they present an opportunity to improve
payments with a technologically advanced representation of central bank money, one which preserves
the core features of finality, liquidity and integrity that only the central bank can provide. They could
form the backbone of a highly efficient new digital payment system by enabling broad access, and they
may also help to provide strong data governance and privacy standards.
Yet in order to achieve the potential benefits for public welfare while preserving financial stability
and public-private sector cooperation, further exploration on CBDC design choices and their macro-
financial implications is essential. Adam Smith defined money by the three main roles it plays in society:
as a unit of account, the yardstick of economic activity; a means of exchange to make payments; and as
a store of value to transfer purchasing power over time. With CBDCs, central banks’ main goal is to
provide a universal means of exchange for the digital economy. They do not, however, intend to
disintermediate the financial sector by offering a universal store of value.
In this context, research is helping to understand how the usefulness of CBDCs as a means of
payments can be maximised, while limiting the overall inflows to central bank balance sheets. Beyond
this, various important and complex questions are still to be further analysed, for instance as regards
the interoperability between existing and new infrastructures, the access to and control of central bank
money, the distinction between wholesale and retail CBDCs and especially the cross-border implications
of CBDCs.
To further push the frontier in the cross-border dimension, researchers will have to grapple with
the specifics of cross-border payments. While CBDCs have unique features, enhancements in existing
payment systems and arrangements, such as aligning regulatory, supervisory and oversight frameworks
for cross-border payments, AML/CFT consistency, PvP adoption and payment system access will also
be critical for cross-border CBDC use. Moreover, the eventual international adoption of CBDCs is likely
to proceed at different speeds in different jurisdictions, calling for interoperability with legacy payment
arrangements. Hence, the analysis of interoperability with non-CBDC payment arrangements calls for
further work. Answering these open questions will be crucial for a correct design of CBDCs as a new
form of money in the digital era.

29 See Auer, Haehne and Holden (2021) for more details. Such a model has, for instance, been adopted for Project
Dunbar and in Project Aber (see SAMA and CBUAE (2019, 2020)), which even goes a step further via the joint
issuance of a CBDC that is used in the single mCBDC arrangement. Because both the Saudi riyal and the UAE
dirham are pegged to the US dollar, the newly issued CBDC was effectively guaranteed to have a fixed
exchange rate vis-à-vis both local currencies.

22 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


References

Abadi, J and M Brunnermeier (2018): “Blockchain Economics,” NBER Working Papers, no 254.
Acquisti, A, C Taylor and L Wagman (2016): “The economics of privacy”, Journal of Economic Literature,
vol 54, no 2.
Adrian, T and T Mancini-Griffoli (2019): “The rise of digital money”, Annual Review of Financial
Economics, no 13.
Agur, I, A Ari and G Dell’Ariccia (2021) “Designing central bank digital currencies”, Journal of Monetary
Economics, forthcoming.
Amoussou-Guenou, Y, B Biais, M Potop-Butucaru and S Tucci-Piergiovanni (2019): “Rationals vs
Byzantines in Consensus-based Blockchains”, Research report, HAL ID: hal-020433.
Andolfatto, D (2021): “Assessing the impact of central bank digital currency on private banks”, The
Economic Journal, vol 131, no 634, pp 525–40.
Armantier, O, S Doerr, J Frost, A Fuster and K Shue (2021): “Whom do consumers trust with their data?
US survey evidence”, BIS Bulletins, no 42, May.
Jasmina A, J Duffy and J Jiang (2017): “Adoption of a new payment method: theory and experimental
evidence”, Bank of Canada Staff Working Papers, no 2017-28.
Arauz, A, R Garratt and D Ramos (2021): “Dinero Electrónico: The rise and fall of Ecuador’s central bank
digital currency”, Latin American Journal of Central Banking, vol 2, no 2.
Arner, D, R Auer and J Frost (2020): “Stablecoins: risks, potential and regulation”, Bank of Spain, Financial
Stability Review, November.
Assenmacher, K, A Berentsen, C Brand, N Lamersdorf (2021): “A unified framework for CBDC design:
remuneration, collateral haircuts and quantity constraints”, ECB Working Papers, no 2578.
Auer, R (2019):“ Beyond the doomsday economics of ‘proof-of-work ’in cryptocurrencies”, BIS Working
Papers, no 765, January.
Auer, R and R Böhme (2020): “The technology of retail central bank digital currency”, BIS Quarterly
Review, March, pp 85–100.
Auer, R and R Böhme (2021): “Central bank digital currency: the quest for minimally invasive
technology”, BIS Working Papers, no 948.
Auer, R, G Cornelli and J Frost (2020): “Rise of the central bank digital currencies: drivers, approaches
and technologies”, BIS Working Papers, no 880, August.
Auer, R, P Haene and H Holden (2021): “Multi-CBDC arrangements and the future of cross-border
payments”, BIS Papers, no 115, March.
Auer, R Monnet and H S Shin (2021): “Permissioned distributed ledgers and the governance of money”
BIS Working Papers, no 924.
Auer, R, C Boar, G Cornelli, J Frost, H Holden and A Wehrli (2021): “CBDCs beyond borders: results from
a survey of central banks”, BIS Papers, no 116, June.
Bank for International Settlements (BIS) (2020): “Central banks and payments in the digital era”, Annual
Economic Report, Chapter III, June.
Bank for International Settlements (2021): “Central bank digital currencies: an opportunity for the
monetary system”, Annual Economic Report, Chapter III, June.
Bank of Canada (2017): “Project Jasper primer”, January.
Bank of Canada (2020): “Contingency Planning for a Central Bank Digital Currency”, February.
Bank of Canada, Bank of England and Monetary Authority of Singapore (MAS) (2018): Cross-border
interbank payments and settlements: emerging opportunities for digital transformation, November.
Bank of England (2020): “Central bank digital currency: opportunities, challenges and design,” Discussion
Paper, March.
Bank of Thailand and Hong Kong Monetary Authority (HKMA) (2020): Inthanon-LionRock: Leveraging
Distributed Ledger Technology to Increase Efficiency in Cross-Border Payments, January.
Bassetto, M and T Sargent (2020): “Shotgun wedding: fiscal and monetary policy”, NBER Working Papers,
no 27004, April.

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 23


Barrdear, J and M Kumhof (2016): “The macroeconomics of central bank issued digital currencies”, Bank
of England Working Papers, no 605.
Baubeau, P, E Monnet, A Riva and S Ungaro (2021): “The real effects of bank runs: evidence from the
French great depression (1930–1931)”, CEPR Discussion Papers, no 16054.
Bech, M and R Garratt (2017): “Central bank cryptocurrencies”, BIS Quarterly Review, September, pp 55–
70.
Belton, D, L Gambacorta, S Kokas and R Minetti (2020): “Foreign banks, liquidity shocks and bank
stability”, BIS Working Papers, no 845.
Benhabib, J, S Schmitt-Grohé, and M Uribe (2001): “Monetary policy and multiple equilibria”, American
Economic Review, vol 91, no 1, pp 167–86.
Biais, B, C Bisière, M Bouvard, and C Casamatta (2019): “The blockchain folk theorem”, Review of Financial
Studies, vol. 32, no 5, May 2019, pp 1662–715.
Bindseil, U (2020): “Tiered CBDC and the financial system”, ECB Working Paper Series, no 2351, January.
Boar, C, H Holden and A Wadsworth (2020): “Impending arrival: a sequel to the survey on central bank
digital currency”, BIS Papers, no 107.
Boar, C and A Wehrli (2021): “Ready, steady, go? – Results of the third BIS survey on central bank digital
currency”, BIS Papers, no 114.
Böhme, R, N Christin, B Edelman and T Moore (2015): “Bitcoin: economics, technology, and governance”,
Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol 29, no 2, pp 213–38.
Bofinger, P and T Haas (2020): “Can central banks succeed in the market place for digital monies?”, CEPR
Discussion Papers, no 15489.
Bordo, M and A Levin (2017): “Central bank digital currency and the future of monetary policy”, NBER
Working Papers, no 23711.
Brainard, L (2020a): “The digitalization of payments and currency: some issues for consideration”, speech
at Stanford University, 5 February.
Brainard, L (2020b): “An update on digital currencies”, speech (via webcast), 13 August.
Brett, J (2020): “Federal Reserve reveals research plans for digital dollars”, Forbes, 13 August.
Broadbent, B (2016): “Central banks and digital currencies”, speech at the London School of Economics,
London, 2 March.
Brown, M, N Hentschel, H Mettler and H Stix (2020): “Financial innovation, payment choice and cash
demand – causal evidence from the staggered introduction of contactless debit cards”,
Oesterreichische Nationalbank, Working Papers, no 230, April.
Brunnermeier, M and D Niepelt (2019): “On the equivalence of private and public money”, Journal of
Monetary Economics, no 106, pp 27–41.
Brunnermeier, M, H James and J P Landau (2019): “The digitalization of money”, NBER Working Papers,
no 26300.
Budish, E (2018): “The economic limits of bitcoin and the blockchain”, NBER Working Papers, no 24717,
June.
Carstens, A (2019): “The future of money and payments”, Whitaker Lecture given at the Central Bank of
Ireland, Dublin, 22 March.
Carapella, F and J Flemming (2020): “Central bank digital currency: a literature review”, FEDS Notes,
November.
Chiu, J and T Koeppl (2019): “The economics of cryptocurrencies – Bitcoin and beyond”, Bank of Canada
Staff Working Papers, no 2019-40.
Chiu, J, M Davoodalhosseini, J Jiang, and Y Zhu (2019): “Bank market power and central bank digital
currency: Theory and quantitative assessment”, Bank of Canada Staff Working Papers, no 2019-20.
Chorzempa, M (2021), “China, the United States, and central bank digital currencies: how important is it
to be first?”, China Economic Journal.
Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (CPMI) and Markets Committee (MC) (2018):
Central bank digital currencies, March.
CPMI (2020): “Enhancing cross-border payments: building blocks of a global roadmap. Stage 2 report
to the G20”, July.

24 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


CPMI, BIS Innovation Hub, IMF and World Bank (2021): “Central bank digital currencies for cross-border
payments: Report to the G20”, July.
Darbha, S and R Arora (2020): “Privacy in CBDC technology”, Bank of Canada Staff Analytical Notes, no
2020-9.
Davoodalhosseini, M (2021): “Central bank digital currency and monetary policy”, Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, forthcoming.
Davoodalhosseini, M, F Rivadeneyra and Y Zhu (2020): “CBDC and Monetary Policy”, Bank of Canada
Staff Analytical Notes, no 2020-4.
Deirmentzoglou, E, G Papakyriakopoulos and C Patsakis (2019): “A survey on long-range attacks for
proof of stake protocols”, mimeo.
Demsetz, R, M Saidenberg and P Strahan (1996): “Banks with something to lose: The disciplinary role of
franchise value”, Economic Policy Review, vol 2, no 2.
Eren, E, T Jackson and G Lombardo (2021): “Efficient disintermediation: CBDC, monetary policy, and
banks”, BIS Working papers, forthcoming.
European Central Bank (ECB) (2020): “Report on a digital euro”, October.
ECB and Bank of Japan (2019): Project Stella – Synchronised cross-border payments, project Stella phase
3 report, June.
Fanti, G, L Kogan, S Oh, K Ruan, P Viswanath, G Wang (2019): “Compounding of wealth in proof-of-stake
cryptocurrencies”, 23rd International Conference on Financial Cryptography and Data Security, FC
2019 – Saint Kitts and Nevis.
Fernández-Villaverde, J, D Sanches, L Schilling and H Uhlig (2021): “Central bank digital currency: central
banking for all?”, Review of Economic Dynamics, no 41, pp 225–42.
Ferrari, M, A Mehl and L Stracca (2020): “Central bank digital currency in an open economy”, ECB
Working Paper Series, no 2488, November.
Financial Stability Board (FSB) (2021): “Evaluation of the effects of too-big-to-fail reforms”, March.
Foley, S, J Karlsen and T Putniņš (2019): “Sex, drugs, and bitcoin: how much illegal activity is financed
through cryptocurrencies?”, Review of Financial Studies, vol 32, no 5, pp 1798–853.
Friedman, M (1960): A program for monetary stability, New York: Fordham University Press.
Frost, J, H S Shin and P Wierts (2020): “An early stablecoin? The Bank of Amsterdam and the governance
of money,” BIS Working Papers, no 902.
Fung, B and H Halaburda (2016): “Central bank digital currencies: A framework for assessing why and
how”, Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Papers, no 2016-22.
Garratt, R and M van Oordt (202119): “Privacy as a public good: a case for electronic cash”, Journal of
Political Economy, vol 129, no 7, pp 2157–80. Bank of Canada Staff Working Papers, no 2019-24.
Garratt, R and M Lee (2021): “Monetizing privacy”, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports,
no 958, January.
Garatt, R and H Zhu (2021): “On interest-bearing central bank digital currency with heterogeneous
banks”, mimeo, MIT.
Giannini C (2011): The age of central banks, Edward Elgar Publishing.
Gross, J, J Sedlmeir, M Babel, A Bechtel, and B Schellinger (2021): “Designing a central bank digital
currency with support for cash-like privacy”, mimeo.
Group of Central Banks (2020): “Central bank digital currencies: foundational principles and core
features”, Joint Report, no 1, October.
Grym, A (2020): “Lessons learned from the world’s first CBDC”, Bank of Finland Economics Review, no 8.
Hayek, F (1978): Denationalisation of Money: The Argument Refined, London: Institute of Economic
Affairs.
Gu, C, C Monnet, E Nosal, and R Wright (2018): “On the instability of banking and financial
intermediation”, Department of Economics, University of Missouri, Working Papers, no 1901.
Huynh, K, J Molnar, O Shcherbakov and Q H Yu (2020): “Demand for payment services and consumer
welfare: the introduction of a central bank digital currency”, Bank of Canada Staff Working Papers,
no 2020-7.

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 25


International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2018): “Republic of the Marshall Islands: Selected Issues”,
September.
Kahn, C and W Roberds (2009): “Why pay? An introduction to payments economics”, Journal of Financial
Intermediation, vol 18, no 1, pp 1–23.
Keister, T and C Monnet (2019): “Central bank digital currency: stability and information”, mimeo.
Keister, T and D Sanches (2019): “Should central banks issue digital currency?”, Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia Working Papers, no 19-26.
Ketterer, J and G Andrade (2016): “Digital central bank money and the unbundling of the banking
function”, IADB Discussion Papers, no IDB-DP-449.
Kiff, J, J Alwazir, S Davidovic, G Huertas, A Khan, T Khiaonarong, M Malaika, H Monroe, N Sugimoto, H
Tourpe and P Zhou (2020): “A survey of research on retail central bank digital currency”, IMF Working
Papers, no 20/104.
Kocherlakota, N and N Wallace (1998): “Incomplete record-keeping and optimal payment
arrangements,” Journal of Economic Theory, vol 81, no 2, pp 272–89.
Kumar, A and E Rosenbach (2020): “Could China’s digital currency unseat the dollar?”, Foreign Affairs,
May.
Kumhof, M and C Noone (2018): “Central bank digital currencies – design principles and balance sheet
implications”, Bank of England Staff Working Papers, no 725.
Levine, R (1991): “Asset trading mechanisms and expansionary policy”, Journal of Economic Theory, no
54, pp 148–64.
Levy Yeyati, E (2021): “Financial dollarization and de-dollarization in the new millennium”, FLAR Working
Papers, February.
Meaning, J, B Dyson, J Barker and E Clayton (2018): “Broadening narrow money: monetary policy with a
central bank digital currency”, Bank of England Staff Working Papers, no 724.
Monetary Authority of Singapore (2016): “MAS, R3 and financial institutions experimenting with
Blockchain technology”, November.
Monnet, C, A Petursdottir and M Rojas-Breu (2020): “Central bank account for all: efficiency and
stability”, mimeo.
Netherlands Bank (DNB) (2020): “Central bank digital currency: Objectives, preconditions and design
choices”, Occasional Studies, no 1, April.
Niepelt, Dirk (2021): “Monetary policy with reserves and CBDC: optimality, equivalence, and politics”,
CEPR Discussion Papers, no 15457.
Paquet-Clouston, M, B Haslhofer and B Dupont (2019): “Ransomware payments in the Bitcoin
ecosystem”, Journal of Cybersecurity, May 2019, pp 1–11.
People’s Bank of China (2021): “Progress of Research & Development of E-CNY in China“, Working
Group on E-CNY Research and Development of the People's Bank of China, July.
Piazzesi, M and M Schneider (2020): “Credit lines, bank deposits or CBDC? Competition & efficiency in
modern payment systems”, mimeo.
Plosser, C (2019): “A limited central bank” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, vol 31, no 4, pp. 16–20.
Niepelt, D (2020): “Monetary policy with reserves and CBDC: optimality, equivalence, and politics”, CEPR
Discussion Papers, DP15457.
Rochet, J and J Tirole (2006): “Two-sided markets: a progress report.”, RAND Journal of Economics, vol
37, no 3, pp 645–67.
Saudi Arabian Monetary Authority and United Arab Emirates Central Bank (2019): “A statement on
launching the ‘Aber’ Project for a common digital currency between SAMA and UAECB”, 29 January.
Saudi Arabian Monetary Authority and United Arab Emirates Central Bank (2020): Project Aber final
report, 25 November.
Saka, O, B Eichengreen and C G Aksoy (2021): “Epidemic exposure, fintech adoption, and the digital
divide”, CEPR Discussion Papers, no 16323.
Saleh, F (2021): “Blockchain without waste: proof-of-stake”, Review of Financial Studies, vol 34, no 3, pp
1156–90.
Schilling, L (2019): “Risks involved with CBDC: on cash, privacy and information centralization”, mimeo.

26 CBDCs: motives, economic implications, and the research frontier


Schilling, L and H Uhlig (2019): “Some simple Bitcoin economics”, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol
106, pp 16–26.
Schilling, L, J Fernández-Villaverde and H Uhlig (2020): “Central bank digital currency: when price and
bank stability collide”. NBER Working Papers, no 28237.
Shin, H S (2021): “Central bank digital currencies: an opportunity for the monetary system”, speech on
the occasion of the BIS Annual General Meeting, Basel, 29 June.
Sveriges Riksbank (2017): “The Riksbank’s e-krona project”, September.
Sveriges Riksbank (2020): “Payments in Sweden 2020”, Report.
Svirydzenka, K (2016): “Introducing a new broad-based index of financial development”, IMF Working
Papers, no 15.
Tobin, J (1987): “The case for preserving regulatory distinctions”, Proceedings of the Economic Policy
Symposium, Jackson Hole, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp 167–83.
Valencia, F (2015): “Sistema de dinero electrónico, un medio de pago al alcance de todos”, CEMA
Bulletin, January-March.
Wang, Z (2021): “Tax compliance, payment choice, and central bank digital currency”, mimeo.
White, L (2018): “The world’s first central bank electronic money has come – and gone: Ecuador, 2014–
2018”, Cato Institute, 2 April.
Williamson, S (2019): “Central bank digital currency: Welfare and policy implications”, technical report.

CBDCs: motives, economic implications and the research frontier 27


Previous volumes in this series

975 ETFs, illiquid assets, and fire sales John J Shim and Karamfil Todorov
November 2021

974 The natural rate of interest through a hall of Phurichai Rungcharoenkitkul and
November 2021 mirrors Fabian Winkler

973 What does digital money mean for emerging Erik Feyen, Jon Frost, Harish
October 2021 market and developing economies? Natarajan and Tara Rice

972 Non-bank financial intermediaries and Sirio Aramonte, Andreas Schrimpf


October 2021 financial stability and Hyun Song Shin

971 Do term premiums matter? Transmission via Mitsuru Katagiri and Koji Takahashi
October 2021 exchange rate dynamics

970 Big techs in finance: on the new nexus Frederic Boissay, Torsten Ehlers,
October 2021 between data privacy and competition Leonardo Gambacorta and
Hyun Song Shin
969 Inter-agency coordination bodies and the Michael Brei and Blaise Gadanecz
October 2021 speed of prudential policy responses to the
Covid-19 pandemic
968 Indebted demand Atif Mian, Ludwig Straub and
October 2021 Amir Sufi

967 Joined at the hip: monetary and fiscal policy Guillermo A Calvo and Andrés
October 2021 in a liquidity-driven world Velasco

966 The Treasury market in spring 2020 and the Annette Vissing-Jørgensen
October 2021 response of the Federal Reserve

965 Technological capacity and firms' recovery Sebastian Doerr, Magdalena Erdem,
October 2021 from Covid-19 Guido Franco, Leonardo
Gambacorta and Anamaria Illes
964 Macroeconomic policy under a managed Pierre-Richard Agénor and Luiz A
September 2021 float: a simple integrated framework Pereira da Silva

963 The Fed takes on corporate credit risk: Simon Gilchrist, Bin Wei, Vivian Z
September 2021 an analysis of the efficacy of the SMCCF Yue and Egon Zakrajšek

962 Global lending conditions and international Enisse Kharroubi


August 2021 coordination of financial regulation policies

All volumes are available on our website www.bis.org.

You might also like