Central Bank Digital Currencies. Motives, Economic Implications and The Research Frontier
Central Bank Digital Currencies. Motives, Economic Implications and The Research Frontier
Central Bank Digital Currencies. Motives, Economic Implications and The Research Frontier
No 976
Central bank digital currencies:
motives, economic implications
and the research frontier
by Raphael Auer, Jon Frost, Leonardo Gambacorta,
Cyril Monnet, Tara Rice and Hyun Song Shin
November 2021
JEL classification: C72, C73, D4, E42, E58, G21, O32, L86.
© Bank for International Settlements 2021. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be
reproduced or translated provided the source is stated.
Raphael Auer, Jon Frost, Leonardo Gambacorta, Cyril Monnet∗, Tara Rice and Hyun Song Shin1
Abstract
In just a few years, central banks have rapidly ramped up their research and development effort on
central bank digital currencies (CBDCs). A growing body of economic research informs these activities,
often focusing on the “reserves for all” aspect of CBDCs for retail use. However, CBDCs should be
considered in the full context of the digital economy and the centrality of data, which raises concerns
around competition, payment system integrity and privacy. This paper gives a guided tour of the
growing literature on CBDCs on the microeconomic considerations related to operational architectures,
technologies and privacy, and the macroeconomic implications for the financial system, financial
stability and monetary policy. A set of questions, particularly on the cross-border dimensions of CBDCs,
remains unresolved, and calls for further work to expand the research frontier.
Keywords: money, digital currencies, central banks, central bank digital currencies, CBDC, stablecoins,
cryptocurrencies, distributed ledgers, big tech, data privacy.
JEL classification: C72, C73, D4, E42, E58, G21, O32, L86.
The digitalisation of economies has far-reaching implications for many areas of economic inquiry, not
least for monetary economics and the concept of money itself. With the massive volumes of data that
digital activities generate come new opportunities and challenges for societies and the monetary
system.
A tradition in monetary economics is to view money as a coordination device that serves as a
substitute for the complete list of economic transactions – ie as society’s “memory” of all economic
transactions (eg, Kocherlakota (1998)). Yet this abstract definition of money leaves open its institutional
underpinnings, upon which the welfare consequences of the institution of money may crucially depend.
In particular, due to the inherent network effects in payments (Rochet and Tirole (2006)) and the
potential for the proprietary use of data, digital forms of money pose substantial challenges for
competition, privacy and integrity. It is in this context that an important public debate has arisen on the
issuance of new, digital forms of central bank money and how they will affect the architecture of the
monetary system.
The idea that central banks would issue digital forms of money for general use is a natural
progression from the issuance of physical cash. In addition, banks have had access to digital forms of
central bank money for several decades in the wholesale payment system. However, the debate on the
issuance of digital central money that is accessible to ordinary users has picked up pace only recently.
Initially, policy reports took a cautious approach to issuance (eg CPMI-MC (2018)). The last few years
have witnessed a broadening of the debate. Alongside the rise and fall of cryptocurrencies, the
emergence of global stablecoin proposals such as Facebook’s Diem, and increasing technological
disruption in finance, central banks have adopted a more proactive stance by anticipating a future when
innovation and the entry of new private forms of money will already have transformed the monetary
system, rather than treating the current system as the benchmark. Central banks have begun to engage
in research on CBDCs and, in some instances, also their development. According to a survey from late
2020, 86% of global central banks are conducting research on CBDCs, and as of July 2021, 56 central
banks have publicly communicated their research or development efforts (see Boar and Wehrli (2021)
and Auer et al (2020)). At the time of writing, two central banks have launched CBDCs and several are
conducting pilots. However, there is as yet no broad consensus among central banks on the need for
CBDC issuance.
Alongside a fast-changing and intense policy debate, a still nascent but rapidly growing academic
literature has emerged that examines the broader economic implications of CBDCs. The focus to date
has mostly been on the “reserves for all” aspect of CBDCs, and the associated balance sheet implications
for central banks in their interactions with commercial banks, the impact on the effectiveness of
monetary policy, and the implications for financial stability.2 In policy circles, meanwhile, there is
growing confidence that a targeted economic design can achieve public policy goals while limiting
systemic implications. Hence, the discussion focuses more on the potential enhancements to payments
inclusion and efficiency, and the policy objectives of ensuring competition, data privacy and integrity of
payment systems (see Auer and Böhme (2020, 2021) and BIS (2021)).3 Many central banks, meanwhile,
2 See the discussion in Section 4. Studies assess how the issuance of retail CBDCs could affect the balance sheets
of central and commercial banks and the respective volatility (ie Kumhof and Noone (2018), Brunnermeier and
Niepelt (2019)), lending and the interest rates of commercial banks (Andolfatto (2021)), and the bounds and
effectiveness of monetary policy (ie Bordo and Levin (2017), Davoodalhosseini et al (2020)).
3 See also Kiff et al (2020), Bank of Canada (2020), ECB (2020), Bank of England (2020), People’s Bank of China
(2021).
Over the centuries, various forms of money have emerged to meet the economic needs of the time.
Coins, banknotes, cheques and credit cards were each innovations in their own day (Giannini (2011)). In
recent decades, new payment technologies have been added to this list, from phone-based mobile
money to smartphone-based payment apps, and from stablecoins to a new form of central bank-issued
money in the form of CBDCs.
CBDCs can be seen as a digital extension of the existing forms of central bank money, namely cash
(bills and coins) and central bank settlement accounts. As a digital liability of the central bank, wholesale
CBDCs could become a new instrument for settlement between financial institutions. Retail (or general
4 That said, the motivations differ across countries. Particularly in emerging market and developing economies,
CBDCs are often seen as a means to enhance financial inclusion, granting universal access to digital means of
payment (see ie Boar and Wehrli (2021). In the light of a more globalised economy, CBDCs are also being
explored to enhance cross-border payments.
The idea of extending central bank money in digital form to the public is not new. For instance,
Tobin (1987) proposed the idea of “deposited currency”, or “a medium with the convenience of deposits
and the safety of currency”, to enhance payments and reduce the reliance on deposit insurance.
Over the past several years, a number of central banks have started internal projects to better
understand the technology of cryptocurrencies and more broadly the potential application of
distributed ledger technology (DLT) to government-issued digital currencies.6 Starting in 2015, central
banks in eg Canada, the Netherlands, Singapore and the United Kingdom ran internal experiments.
These generally concluded that DLT was not yet mature enough for use in major central bank payment
systems.
From 2016 onward, a number of central banks launched research projects on digital currencies for
wholesale purposes. Several focused on DLT for the settlement of high-value interbank payments.7
Some involved cooperation between central banks on wholesale CBDCs for cross-border payments.8
5 “General purpose” and “retail” are used interchangeably to refer to CBDCs that individuals and non-financial
firms could access. For an overview and relevant definitions, see Bech and Garratt (2017) and CPMI-MC (2018).
6 Grym (2021) discusses the Avant payment card, created by the Bank of Finland in the 1990s for retail use, as
an early form of CBDC. In 2014, the Central Bank of Ecuador launched a project called “Dinero electrónico”
(electronic money) to allow individuals to make mobile payments through a central bank-operated system
(Valencia (2015)). Yet the system failed to attract a significant number of users, and was discontinued in 2016
(White (2018); Arauz et al (2021)).
7 For instance, the Bank of Canada launched Project Jasper in early 2016 (Bank of Canada (2017)). In November
2016, the Monetary Authority of Singapore launched Project Ubin (MAS (2016)), on a tokenised form of the
Singapore dollar on DLT. The Bank of Canada, Bank of England and MAS subsequently worked in collaborative
research with banks on challenges in cross-border payments and settlement and how various initiatives –
including wholesale CBDC – could help. See Bank of Canada-MAS-Bank of England-HSBC (2018).
8 For instance, Project Stella involved joint research between the ECB and Bank of Japan (2019). Later, the
monetary authorities of Saudi Arabia and the United Arab Emirates, and of Hong Kong SAR and Thailand, also
announced cross-border work on wholesale CBDCs (SAMA-UAECB (2019); Bank of Thailand and HKMA (2020)).
9 Additionally, the Marshall Islands, which currently use the US dollar as legal tender and have no monetary
authority, have launched the SOV (short for sovereign) project, a digital currency proposed by private
developers. This project is not included in the database, as it is not a central bank project. See IMF (2018) for
a critical discussion.
Sources: Auer, Cornelli and Frost (2020); Auer and Böhme (2021).
Motivations for retail CBDC research and development are driven by global trends, but also by country-
specific circumstances. Broadly, CBDCs should be seen in the context of the digitalisation of economies
and the growing centrality of data – particularly personal data – both in the economy and the monetary
system. The growing role of data brings many opportunities to reduce information asymmetries, cut
costs and enable new forms of money.10 Yet data also lead to new challenges for competition, privacy
and integrity – issues that the economics literature is only beginning to grapple with. Due to the network
effects inherent to money, new private players may quickly dominate the monetary system, leading to
serious competition concerns and working against the public interest.
These issues have been underscored by four developments. The first was the rapid rise in interest
in Bitcoin and other cryptocurrencies that compete with traditional forms of money (see Carstens
(2019)). However, cryptocurrencies are speculative assets rather than money. They are extremely volatile,
making it difficult to use them as a means of payment. In many cases, they are used to facilitate money
laundering, ransomware attacks and other financial crimes (Foley et al (2019), Paquet-Clouston et al
(2019)). Bitcoin in particular has few redeeming public interest attributes when its wasteful energy
consumption is taken into account. For instance, it is estimated that the Bitcoin network currently uses
as much electricity as the Netherlands (BIS (2021)).
10 For instance, the ability to keep full digital ledgers of transactions increasingly makes it feasible for agents to
have a full record of their interactions with other agents in the past – or money as memory (Kocherlakota
(1998)). Moreover, new “smart contracts” can make money programmable, allowing agents to automate
important functions (Bank of England (2020)).
11 See for example the White Paper of the Diem Association, www.diem.com/white-paper/.
12 For a discussion of the risks to stablecoins’ value backing, see Arner et al (2020) and Frost et al (2020).
13 The Federal Reserve has ongoing research on retail CBDCs (Brainard (2020a,b)). In the Netherlands, the central
bank has emphasised that the pandemic underscores the need for a backup to private money (DNB (2020)).
In China, pilot testing for the e-CNY is coinciding with a phasing-out of pandemic-related mobility restrictions.
In Sweden, testing of the e-krona project continues even amidst central bank crisis management measures.
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0
Payment Financial Payment Payment Financial Payment
safety/ Payment stability Monetary efficiency Financial safety/ Payment stability Monetary efficiency Financial
robustness efficiency policy (cross-border) inclusion robustness efficiency policy (cross-border) inclusion
(domestic) implementation (domestic) implementation
In addition to the stated preferences of central banks, some research looks at “revealed policy
preferences”, ie the factors that correlate with actual CBDC projects. Table 1 from Auer et al (2020)
shows that CBDC projects are more advanced in more digitised economies (as measured eg by mobile
cellular subscriptions) and in countries with a high capacity for innovation (measured by the World
Intellectual Property Organisation (WIPO) innovation output score). Moreover, they find that work on
retail CBDCs is more advanced where the informal economy is larger – consistent with the notion that
CBDCs, by creating a data trail for transactions, may help to formalise informal activities. Wholesale
CBDC projects are found to be more advanced in markets with greater financial development, which
may have higher demand for more efficient clearing and settlement services. Beyond research and
design issues, some central banks have sketched out scenarios in which they may consider CBDC
issuance, such as the encroachment of private stablecoins or cryptoassets, or a reduction in the use of
cash – eg Bank of Canada (2020), ECB (2020), Bank of England (2020)).
While it is clear what drives central banks’ research efforts, the discussion on CBDCs also raises
more fundamental issues on their optimality, eg on the role of public versus private money and the key
distinctions between the two (eg Brunnermeier and Niepelt (2019), Bech and Garratt (2017), Adrian and
Mancini-Griffoli (2019), Fung and Halaburda (2016), Ketterer and Andrade (2016)). CBDC issuance might
also lead to an intensification of the competition between global currencies, and the need for central
banks to respond (or not) to CBDC issuance in other jurisdictions.
One concern with digital currencies in general, initially voiced with regard to global stablecoins, is
that they could threaten individual countries’ monetary sovereignty by displacing domestic currencies.
New “digital currency areas” may arise based on the business empires of individual digital platforms
rather than the boundaries of legal jurisdictions (Brunnermeier et al (2019)). Could similar concerns
apply to CBDCs? Many countries, particularly EMEs, already know the phenomenon of “dollarisation”
(or “euroisation” etc), where households and businesses use a foreign currency widely in daily
transactions and financial contracts (Levy Yeyati (2021)). Could CBDCs promote “digital dollarisation”?
Research on these aspects of CBDC issuance is scarce, but there are good reasons to think that
these risks could be mitigated. First, dollarisation is generally driven by the lack of public trust that the
domestic monetary authorities will maintain a stable value for the local currency – in particular a history
of high inflation or a lack of financial market development – rather than by the technological format of
a domestic or foreign currency. Second, a number of policy tools exist to address such risks. In particular,
an account-based design for CBDCs, based on identification, would mean that both the issuing central
bank and the central bank of a receiving country would need to agree to cross-border use, and would
have insights into aggregate cross-border use of a CBDC (see next section). Third, central bank
cooperation could mitigate the risks of currency substitution, as central banks from different
jurisdictions would have little interest in destabilising one another’s economies through widespread use
Central bank motivations for issuing CBDCs are primarily of a microeconomic nature. They aim to
enhance payments inclusion and efficiency, as well as ensure competition, data privacy and the integrity
of their payment system. What does this imply for the optimal CBDC design and how such designs
would affect consumer welfare?15 This raises important issues pertaining to CBDC operational
architecture, the associated public-private sector cooperation and the welfare implications for
consumers, also in the context of data privacy considerations. In these cases, the literature has already
helped to inform the design of actual CBDC research and development, and to shed light on how CBDCs
may affect consumers. This section considers these issues in turn.
Operational architectures: what role for the private sector in a CBDC system?
A first consideration is how users would be convinced to adopt CBDCs in practice, and how the
operational architecture could involve the private sector so as not to overburden the central bank
operationally. One aspect is that retail payment behaviours show great inertia. For example, Brown et al
(2020) find that an exogenous introduction of more convenient payment methods led only to a
moderate average reduction in the cash share of payments. Arifovic et al (2017) show with experimental
evidence how fees influence the behaviour of buyers and sellers, and ultimately the take-up of a new
payment method.16 For CBDCs to be launched, to be adopted by the public and to enhance payments
efficiency, they must carefully define the role of the central bank and the private sector in line with their
14 Of course, the threat of dollarisation may discipline central banks and encourage low and stable inflation. In
some EMDEs, dollarisation is an active policy choice to import monetary stability. These considerations, too,
are largely independent of whether the foreign “hard currency” is offered in digital form.
15 For example, Bofinger and Haas (2020) see little justification for CBDCs based on allocative efficiency or user
demand. Yet notably, the starting point for their analysis is the current payment system, not the counterfactual
of platform dominance or widespread domestic currency substitution in the digital economy.
16 However, when behaviours change, they often do so quite persistently. In the same manner, changed payment
behaviours caused by the Covid-19 crisis, such as a greater use of digital payments, could have far-reaching
effects in the future.
In the direct CBDC model (top panel), the CBDC is a direct claim on the central bank, which also handles all payments in real time and thus
keeps a record of all retail holdings. A hybrid CBDC architecture (middle panel) incorporates a two-tier structure with direct claims on the
central bank, while real-time payments are handled by intermediaries. The central bank however periodically retains a copy of all retail CBDC
holdings. An intermediated CBDC architecture, instead, runs a wholesale ledger (lower panel). In this architecture, PSPs would need to be
closely supervised to ensure at all times that the wholesale holdings they communicate to the central bank indeed add up to the sum of all
retail accounts.
Importantly, while the vast majority of central bank CBDC research and development projects
involve either a hybrid or intermediated (rather than direct) architecture (Auer et al (2020)), many
academic studies continue to describe CBDCs as if the central bank were taking on all operational tasks,
without any role for private intermediaries (see Section 4). In future, it will be important to model more
realistic CBDC designs, in line with the latest design choices of central banks. This will improve upon
current models that assume that the central bank conducts retail services or that CBDCs are offered in
unlimited quantities, fully displacing bank deposits.
Beyond the architecture of the operational design, a second consideration is the optimal technology
underpinning it. In this context, much emphasis has been put on novel forms of decentralisation enabled
via distributed ledger technology (DLT). The latter comes in two forms: the permissionless technology
that is used in Bitcoin, Ethereum and other cryptocurrencies, and the permissioned variant, in which a
network of known and vetted validators jointly augment a ledger.
CBDCs could in theory be run on a permissionless design that resembles Bitcoin, but this would be
inefficient and environmentally harmful. While it is technically possible to use the technology, based on
costly computing (ie “proof of work”) in which unknown validators perform the updating of transactions,
the economic cost is very high. Every batch of transactions has to be accompanied by a proof that a
substantial quantum of otherwise useless computations has been performed. This is not only inefficient
(see ie Budish (2018), Chiu and Koeppl (2019), and Auer (2019)), but it can lead to multiple equilibria (ie
“forks”, see Biais et al (2019)). For all these reasons, permissionless DLT based on proof of work is not a
viable technology for CBDCs.17
Instead, a number of central banks are considering decentralisation in the form of “permissioned”
DLT, in which a network of preselected entities performs the updating.18 Importantly, operational
resilience can also be achieved in traditional systems that store data multiple times and in physically
separate locations. The difference is that DLT is updated in a decentralised manner: in many DLT-based
systems, the ledger is jointly managed by different entities that do not trust each other’s data and
independently verify each new transaction. The cost is that each update of the ledger must be
harmonised between the nodes of all entities (generally known as “consensus mechanisms”), which, due
to the multiple involved rounds of communication, takes time.
Permissioned DLT is no silver bullet, however, and it only has economic merit under certain
circumstances. Such “permissioned” designs may have economic potential in financial markets and
payments due to enhanced robustness and the potentially lower cost of achieving good governance.
However, this does not come for free. In the setup of Auer, Monnet and Shin (2021), designated
validators verify transactions and update the ledger at a cost that is derived from a supermajority voting
rule. Without giving proper incentives to validators, however, their records cannot be trusted because
they cannot commit to verifying trades – thus giving rise to a public good provision game – and they
can accept bribes to incorrectly validate histories. These two frictions challenge the integrity of the
ledger on which credit transactions rely, and the process of permissioned validation supports
decentralised exchange as an equilibrium only if the rents validators receive are high enough. This
analysis suggests that a centralised operational design is often superior, unless weaknesses in the rule
of law and contract enforcement would necessitate a decentralised ledger.19
A third consideration centres on CBDCs and data privacy. The digitisation of payments is increasingly
generating a “data trail” of information on individual transactions, which can be easily transferred across
counterparties and used for a wide variety of purposes. For instance, transactions data from any digital
17 Abadi and Brunnermeier (2018), Saleh (2021), and Fanti et al (2019) examine the “proof-of-stake” variant, ie
betting on the truth instead of costly computation. However, it is unclear how robust this design is, due to the
possibility of so-called “long-range attacks” (see the survey of Deirmentzoglou et al (2019)).
18 Auer et al (2020) give a stocktake of CBDC designs, showing that DLT is envisioned in many current retail CBDC
prototypes that rely on software packages such as Corda, Hyperledger or Quorum.
19 This is closely related to Amoussou-Guenou et al (2019) whose analysis is the first to model the interaction
between validators as a game entailing non-observable effort to check transactions and amidst costly voting.
20 Even in a hybrid system, it may be possible to separate the individual transaction data from information on
individual user identities, and to enact rules and technological arrangements that restrict use of data to
specific, pre-defined purposes. For instance, the Bank of Jamaica is designing a CBDC system to require a court
order for insight into individual transactions.
Alongside a fast-changing and intense policy debate on CBDC technology and privacy, a growing
academic literature has emerged on the macroeconomic implications of CBDC introduction. This
academic literature centres around three main themes. First is the effect of CBDC issuance on
commercial banks and aggregate lending or investment. Second are the effects of introducing CBDCs
on financial stability, ie the ability of the financial system to absorb shocks and thus the likelihood of
financial crises. The third theme concerns CBDCs as a new monetary policy tool. In this section, we
review the academic literature according to these three themes.
Academics have pointed out that the structure of the banking system can determine the efficiency gains
(or losses) of introducing a CBDC. Three papers stand out here: Andolfatto (2021), Keister and Sanches
(2020) and Chiu et al (2019). They respectively consider the effects of introducing CBDC on a
monopolistic banking system with the perspective of the liability side, ie bank deposits (Andolfatto
(2021)), a perfectly competitive banking system (Keister and Sanches (2019)) and an imperfectly
competitive (but non-monopolistic) banking system (Chiu et al (2019)). On the asset side, ie loans, banks
can be considered as operating in a competitive market in all three papers. The line of reasoning is quite
similar across these papers: by offering a CBDC, the central bank induces commercial banks to make
their deposits more attractive and increases the costs of funds for commercial banks, which can
adversely impact aggregate lending and investment.
All three papers start from the premise that commercial bank deposits are used as a means to pay
some (digital) transactions where cash is not accepted by sellers. Banks, however, cannot satiate the
economy with deposits because they face some governance issues: they need to hold some assets as
collateral, and their net worth has to be positive. As a result, deposits carry a liquidity premium and they
pay a relatively low interest rate, making them a cheap and preferable source of funds for banks.22
However, the low interest rate reduces the value of deposits as a means of payment because it increases
the opportunity cost of holding funds in deposits (low payment efficiency).
When the central bank issues an interest-bearing CBDC, banks have to adjust the remuneration on
their deposits, since otherwise deposit holders would convert them into the better remunerated CBDCs.
Hence, bank deposits become a more expensive source of funds for banks (impacting banks negatively)
21 For instance, the Bank of Jamaica has clarified that individual CBDC data can only be shared with a court order.
22 Deposit insurance is another reason why deposits are a cheap source of funds, as we do not internalise the
cost of bank’s bankruptcy and do not require a risk premium in our deposits.
23 This also raises the question: why was there investment inefficiency in the first place?
24 See eg Belton et al (2020), who examine the 2011 FDIC change in the assessment base for bank deposit
insurance. They show that banks can engage in liquidity hoarding and lower credit creation in the case of a
relatively high remuneration rate on reserves.
Being a liability of the central bank, a CBDC is a safe substitute for commercial bank deposits. Since the
latter can be risky when the amount held is more than the threshold defined by the deposit insurance,
there is a risk that, in a crisis, the availability of a CBDC would induce deposit holders to shift their
holdings from the commercial banking system to the CBDC. Note that it is the risk of a systemic run
that increases, rather than just the risk of a run on a single individual bank. The reason is that, with or
without a CBDC, households can always stage a run on an individual bank by moving their deposits to
a bank they think is safer, but leaving funds within the banking system. The presence of a CBDC will not
affect this type of run, but it could well increase the probability of a systemic bank run (Fernández-
Villaverde et al (2021)). Also, systemic bank runs may be reinforced by the fact that banks have lower
equity buffers when a CBDC is made available (see the previous subsection).
While this intuitive point has been made very early on, also in speeches by policymakers (eg
Broadbent (2016)), it is not always true that CBDC will increase fragility, and models can help clarify
which assumptions are necessary to drive the increased fragility result. Also, the picture is not all dark.
CBDCs being a digital instrument could help to alert the central bank as to whether a bank run is under
way (Keister and Monnet (2019)). Further, it might well be that, while bank runs may be inevitable, they
are less damaging to the economy when a CBDC is available (Williamson (2019)). The canonical model
of a bank run – Diamond and Dybvig (1989) – has become one of the most useful benchmarks for
studying the fragility of the banking system. The so-called DD model is a real model in the sense that
only real resources are deposited in the bank, and there is no cash; it places maturity transformation,
rather than liquidity issuance, at the forefront of the bank’s business. Depositors may run on the bank’s
resources when they expect that others will run as well because the bank will then not have enough to
pay them what it promised later. This run equilibrium depends, among other things, on an implicit
sequential service constraint.
Fernández-Villaverde et al (2021) analyse the effect of a CBDC in the context of the DD model. They
recognise that deposits in a CBDC would give the central bank access to real resources that it can invest.
They assume that, while the central bank does not have the ability, knowledge or technology to invest
in productive assets, it can lend to investment banks who have these attributes. They thus obtain
another equivalence result whereby the allocation obtained with a CBDC is the same as without it. Yet
there is more: they argue that CBDCs would eliminate the run equilibrium because deposits at the
central bank are not callable and nobody can force the central bank to liquidate the long-term project.
In other words, central bank deposits are protected against forced liquidation.25 Therefore, a CBDC
25
A similar argument is found in Brunnermeier and Niepelt (2019).
As discussed in the previous subsection, the digital nature of CBDCs implies that they provide
information that the central bank can exploit in order to make the financial system less fragile. The same
applies for monetary policy: CBDCs supply information to the central bank regarding the economy, and
being digital they are also, almost de facto, programmable. These features considerably enlarge the
monetary authority’s toolkit. For example, Davoodalhosseini (2021) shows that by making transfers to
those who need money the most, the central bank improves the allocation relative to “helicopter drops”
that would affect all households in the same way. In short, the central bank has a better idea of when
households are using the CBDC, allowing it to act on that information. Also, when a CBDC is available
to all, it allows for a direct implementation of monetary policy, hitting the core of the intertemporal
decisions of households and firms, rather than through the indirect and imperfect banking channel.
With such a CBDC in its toolkit, the monetary authority can then rethink its overall monetary policy
27 Moreover, these risks are not new. Baubeau et al (2021) show that runs from commercial banks to government-
backed savings banks, which were only permitted to hold government securities or cash, worsened the credit
contraction in the French Great Depression in 1930–31. They suggest that this argues for careful CBDC design.
28 The role of positive transfers in achieving better allocations is illustrated in Levine (1991). Davoodalhosseini et
al (2020) shows that the results extend when the information remains private, and the central bank can use a
menu of transfers of both cash and CBDCs so that households give (some of their) information by choosing
from the menu.
CBDCs raise many questions at a domestic level, but they raise even more in the cross-border dimension.
Research in this area is still in its infancy. This section thus sheds light on issues at the research frontier,
in particular around the promise of CBDCs for improving cross-border payments in an increasingly
globalised economy. In what follows, we sketch the issues, and then offer avenues for future research
to inform international policy debates and CBDC design efforts.
Cross-border payments suffer from four primary challenges: they are generally costly, often slow,
suffer from low traceability and transparency, and are not widely accessible to some people. For this
reason, the G20 has made enhancing cross-border payments a priority, endorsing in 2020 a multi-year,
multi-dimensional programme to enhance such payments. Faster, cheaper, more transparent and more
inclusive cross-border payment services would deliver widespread benefits for citizens and economies
worldwide, supporting economic growth, international trade, global development and financial
inclusion (CPMI (2020)). CBDCs are seen by many central banks as an opportunity to address these
persistent challenges. However, most CBDC projects focus on domestic issues and use cases. Given this
early state of play, the thinking behind CBDCs for cross-border use is exploratory and will be subject to
considerable further economic and practical examination before the investigation of their cross-border
use gathers pace.
A key difference between CBDCs and efforts to improve the existing payments infrastructure is the
opportunity to start with a “clean slate”. Because many of today’s frictions are rooted in differences
between domestic payment systems (eg opening hours, technical standards, data requirements),
making large-scale changes across jurisdictions is challenging. If central banks take the international
dimension into account when designing their domestic CBDCs and commit to interoperability,
consistent standards and coordination of CBDC designs, many problems inherent in today’s legacy
technologies and processes could be avoided. That said, if CBDCs are not designed with the
international dimension in mind, fragmentation of CBDC systems similar to the current fragmentation
of payment systems is possible. That is why central banks are focusing on this issue from the get-go. A
survey of 50 central banks conducted in early 2021 shows that a quarter are thinking of incorporating
interoperable features in their CBDC design with a view to reducing frictions in cross-border and cross-
currency settlement (Auer, Boar, Cornelli, Frost, Holden and Wehrli (2021) and CPMI et al (2021)).
Cross-border CBDC arrangements could be designed in such a way that they allow a more diverse
group of banks and non-banks access to central bank money for settling payments. This might lead to
a greater variety of “front-end” cross-border payment services, helping to achieve more inclusive cross-
border payment services. In particular, Auer, Haehne and Holden (2021) consider three models for multi-
CBDC arrangements – ranging from basic compatibility between individual CBDCs to the establishment
of a single multi-CBDC system. A first model is one of compatible CBDC systems, which could provide
an additional means of settling transactions from existing markets in central bank money across borders,
allowing a more diverse group of banks and non-banks to settle payments in central bank money, and
hence a broader variety cross-border and cross-currency payment services. A second model involves
interlinked CBDC systems that could build on these potential improvements to offer additional safety
via payment-versus-payment (PvP) settlement through a technical interface between domestic systems.
Alternatively, common clearing mechanisms could also add efficiencies, especially when linked with FX
trading venues. The third multi-CBDC model, a single multi-CBDC system, could offer the same
improvements as interlinking systems but with additional integration. In such a single system, the
6. Conclusion
CBDCs are an idea whose time has come. If properly designed, they present an opportunity to improve
payments with a technologically advanced representation of central bank money, one which preserves
the core features of finality, liquidity and integrity that only the central bank can provide. They could
form the backbone of a highly efficient new digital payment system by enabling broad access, and they
may also help to provide strong data governance and privacy standards.
Yet in order to achieve the potential benefits for public welfare while preserving financial stability
and public-private sector cooperation, further exploration on CBDC design choices and their macro-
financial implications is essential. Adam Smith defined money by the three main roles it plays in society:
as a unit of account, the yardstick of economic activity; a means of exchange to make payments; and as
a store of value to transfer purchasing power over time. With CBDCs, central banks’ main goal is to
provide a universal means of exchange for the digital economy. They do not, however, intend to
disintermediate the financial sector by offering a universal store of value.
In this context, research is helping to understand how the usefulness of CBDCs as a means of
payments can be maximised, while limiting the overall inflows to central bank balance sheets. Beyond
this, various important and complex questions are still to be further analysed, for instance as regards
the interoperability between existing and new infrastructures, the access to and control of central bank
money, the distinction between wholesale and retail CBDCs and especially the cross-border implications
of CBDCs.
To further push the frontier in the cross-border dimension, researchers will have to grapple with
the specifics of cross-border payments. While CBDCs have unique features, enhancements in existing
payment systems and arrangements, such as aligning regulatory, supervisory and oversight frameworks
for cross-border payments, AML/CFT consistency, PvP adoption and payment system access will also
be critical for cross-border CBDC use. Moreover, the eventual international adoption of CBDCs is likely
to proceed at different speeds in different jurisdictions, calling for interoperability with legacy payment
arrangements. Hence, the analysis of interoperability with non-CBDC payment arrangements calls for
further work. Answering these open questions will be crucial for a correct design of CBDCs as a new
form of money in the digital era.
29 See Auer, Haehne and Holden (2021) for more details. Such a model has, for instance, been adopted for Project
Dunbar and in Project Aber (see SAMA and CBUAE (2019, 2020)), which even goes a step further via the joint
issuance of a CBDC that is used in the single mCBDC arrangement. Because both the Saudi riyal and the UAE
dirham are pegged to the US dollar, the newly issued CBDC was effectively guaranteed to have a fixed
exchange rate vis-à-vis both local currencies.
Abadi, J and M Brunnermeier (2018): “Blockchain Economics,” NBER Working Papers, no 254.
Acquisti, A, C Taylor and L Wagman (2016): “The economics of privacy”, Journal of Economic Literature,
vol 54, no 2.
Adrian, T and T Mancini-Griffoli (2019): “The rise of digital money”, Annual Review of Financial
Economics, no 13.
Agur, I, A Ari and G Dell’Ariccia (2021) “Designing central bank digital currencies”, Journal of Monetary
Economics, forthcoming.
Amoussou-Guenou, Y, B Biais, M Potop-Butucaru and S Tucci-Piergiovanni (2019): “Rationals vs
Byzantines in Consensus-based Blockchains”, Research report, HAL ID: hal-020433.
Andolfatto, D (2021): “Assessing the impact of central bank digital currency on private banks”, The
Economic Journal, vol 131, no 634, pp 525–40.
Armantier, O, S Doerr, J Frost, A Fuster and K Shue (2021): “Whom do consumers trust with their data?
US survey evidence”, BIS Bulletins, no 42, May.
Jasmina A, J Duffy and J Jiang (2017): “Adoption of a new payment method: theory and experimental
evidence”, Bank of Canada Staff Working Papers, no 2017-28.
Arauz, A, R Garratt and D Ramos (2021): “Dinero Electrónico: The rise and fall of Ecuador’s central bank
digital currency”, Latin American Journal of Central Banking, vol 2, no 2.
Arner, D, R Auer and J Frost (2020): “Stablecoins: risks, potential and regulation”, Bank of Spain, Financial
Stability Review, November.
Assenmacher, K, A Berentsen, C Brand, N Lamersdorf (2021): “A unified framework for CBDC design:
remuneration, collateral haircuts and quantity constraints”, ECB Working Papers, no 2578.
Auer, R (2019):“ Beyond the doomsday economics of ‘proof-of-work ’in cryptocurrencies”, BIS Working
Papers, no 765, January.
Auer, R and R Böhme (2020): “The technology of retail central bank digital currency”, BIS Quarterly
Review, March, pp 85–100.
Auer, R and R Böhme (2021): “Central bank digital currency: the quest for minimally invasive
technology”, BIS Working Papers, no 948.
Auer, R, G Cornelli and J Frost (2020): “Rise of the central bank digital currencies: drivers, approaches
and technologies”, BIS Working Papers, no 880, August.
Auer, R, P Haene and H Holden (2021): “Multi-CBDC arrangements and the future of cross-border
payments”, BIS Papers, no 115, March.
Auer, R Monnet and H S Shin (2021): “Permissioned distributed ledgers and the governance of money”
BIS Working Papers, no 924.
Auer, R, C Boar, G Cornelli, J Frost, H Holden and A Wehrli (2021): “CBDCs beyond borders: results from
a survey of central banks”, BIS Papers, no 116, June.
Bank for International Settlements (BIS) (2020): “Central banks and payments in the digital era”, Annual
Economic Report, Chapter III, June.
Bank for International Settlements (2021): “Central bank digital currencies: an opportunity for the
monetary system”, Annual Economic Report, Chapter III, June.
Bank of Canada (2017): “Project Jasper primer”, January.
Bank of Canada (2020): “Contingency Planning for a Central Bank Digital Currency”, February.
Bank of Canada, Bank of England and Monetary Authority of Singapore (MAS) (2018): Cross-border
interbank payments and settlements: emerging opportunities for digital transformation, November.
Bank of England (2020): “Central bank digital currency: opportunities, challenges and design,” Discussion
Paper, March.
Bank of Thailand and Hong Kong Monetary Authority (HKMA) (2020): Inthanon-LionRock: Leveraging
Distributed Ledger Technology to Increase Efficiency in Cross-Border Payments, January.
Bassetto, M and T Sargent (2020): “Shotgun wedding: fiscal and monetary policy”, NBER Working Papers,
no 27004, April.
975 ETFs, illiquid assets, and fire sales John J Shim and Karamfil Todorov
November 2021
974 The natural rate of interest through a hall of Phurichai Rungcharoenkitkul and
November 2021 mirrors Fabian Winkler
973 What does digital money mean for emerging Erik Feyen, Jon Frost, Harish
October 2021 market and developing economies? Natarajan and Tara Rice
971 Do term premiums matter? Transmission via Mitsuru Katagiri and Koji Takahashi
October 2021 exchange rate dynamics
970 Big techs in finance: on the new nexus Frederic Boissay, Torsten Ehlers,
October 2021 between data privacy and competition Leonardo Gambacorta and
Hyun Song Shin
969 Inter-agency coordination bodies and the Michael Brei and Blaise Gadanecz
October 2021 speed of prudential policy responses to the
Covid-19 pandemic
968 Indebted demand Atif Mian, Ludwig Straub and
October 2021 Amir Sufi
967 Joined at the hip: monetary and fiscal policy Guillermo A Calvo and Andrés
October 2021 in a liquidity-driven world Velasco
966 The Treasury market in spring 2020 and the Annette Vissing-Jørgensen
October 2021 response of the Federal Reserve
965 Technological capacity and firms' recovery Sebastian Doerr, Magdalena Erdem,
October 2021 from Covid-19 Guido Franco, Leonardo
Gambacorta and Anamaria Illes
964 Macroeconomic policy under a managed Pierre-Richard Agénor and Luiz A
September 2021 float: a simple integrated framework Pereira da Silva
963 The Fed takes on corporate credit risk: Simon Gilchrist, Bin Wei, Vivian Z
September 2021 an analysis of the efficacy of the SMCCF Yue and Egon Zakrajšek