0% found this document useful (0 votes)
20 views

Tutorial 2 Solution

Uploaded by

Minh
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
20 views

Tutorial 2 Solution

Uploaded by

Minh
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 7

Copyright

Copyright
c University of New South Wales 2021. All rights reserved.

Economics of Finance

Tutorial 2

1. An apple tree firm offers for sale a bond and stock. An apple tree produces 70GA and 45BA.
The bond pays 20GA and 20BA. The stock pays 50GA and 25BA. The price of the bond is 18PA,
and the price of the stock is 30PA.

(i) Construct and graph the opportunity set for future apples per present apple. Plot the bond and
stock on the opportunity set. Calculate the arbitrage-free atomic prices and also plot them on the
opportunity set.

Solution
The opportunity set describes what combinations of GA and BA can be obtained for 1PA. Let Q
{states*securities} be the payment matrix of the two securities:

Q: Bond Stock
Good Weather 20 50
Bad Weather 20 25

Let pS {1*securities} be a vector of security prices:

ps: Bond Stock


18 30

The matrix of the value relatives for the two securities will indicate their coordinates in the oppor-
tunity set.

VR: Bond Stock


Good Weather 20/18 50/30
Bad Weather 20/18 25/30

In plain words, 1PA can buy 1/18th of a bond which yields 20/18 GA and 20/18BA. The numbers
1.11 (GA) and 1.11 (BA) are the coordinates for the bond B in the opportunity set. 1PA buys
1/30th of a stock which yields 50/30GA and 25/30BA. The numbers 1.67GA and 0.83BA are the
coordinates for the stock S in the opportunity set.

The vector of the atomic prices patom can be found as

 20 50 −1
 
patom = pS · Q−1 = 18 30

= 0.3 0.6 .
20 25

To summarize, 1GA costs 0.3PA, and 1BA costs 0.6PA. In other words, 3.33GA cost 1PA and
1.67BA cost 1PA. These numbers indicate the coordinates for the points where the opportunity set
cuts the GA and BA axes.

1
Figure 1: Opportunity set

(ii) Holding the payments made by both the bond and stock in each state fixed, and the price of
the bond fixed, calculate the range of prices of the stock that generate positive prices for both the
atomic securities. (Hint: Observe the relative positions of the bond and stock on the graph, in
terms of security payoffs and prices).

Solution
Let cG B
B and cB denote the payments made by the bond in the good and bad states. Similarly, let
G B
cS and cS denote the payments made by the stock in the good and bad states. Finally, let pB and
pS denote the prices of the bond and stock.
The trick to this question is to note that the slope of the opportunity set is downward sloping
and the coordinates on the opportunity set represent different ratios of bundles of payments to price.

2
In addition, recall as illustrated in the previous question, the coordinates for the atomic security
points cut the GA and BA axes in the positive range.
Assuming that the stock pays more in the good state than in the bad state, then we will observe
positive prices for both the atomic securities if the following two inequalities are both satisfied:

cG
B cG
< S,
pB pS
B
cB cB
> S.
pB pS
The first inequality implies that the stock pays a higher return per PA invested if the good state is
observed. The second inequality states that the bond pays a higher return per PA invested if the
bad state is observed. If the stock pays a higher return in both states, then you can earn arbitrage
profits by going long on the stock and short on the bond. If the bond pays a higher return in both
states, then you should go long on the bond and short on the stock. If both inequality signs are
reversed, then everything is fine again, except that the stock now pays more in the bad state than
in the good state. This means effectively that the good and bad states should be relabelled.

In the question you are asked to construct bounds on pS . Rearranging the inequality constraints
with pS on the left hand side, we obtain the following:

cG
S
pS < pB ,
cG
B
cB
S
pS > pB .
cB
B

Substituting the values cG B G B


B = 20, cB = 20, cS = 50, cS = 25 and pB = 18, we obtain that pS < 45
and pS > 22.5. The actual price pS = 30 clearly lies within this range.

Alternatively,
Patom = PS · Q−1
   
pG  −0.05 0.10
= 18 pS ·
pB 0.04 −0.04
since pB = 18.
Therefore positive atomic prices require

pG = 18 · −0.05 + pS · 0.04 > 0


pB = 18 · 0.10 + pS · −0.04 > 0,

thus pS > 22.5 and pS < 45.

(iii) A new security X appears on the market that pays 10GA and 35BA and has a price of 24PA.
Plot this security on the opportunity set. Does it provide any arbitrage opportunities? If so, design
a profitable arbitrage strategy.

Solution
1PA buys 1/24th X which yields 10/24GA and 35/24BA. These numbers 0.42 and 1.46 provide the
coordinates for X in the opportunity set. Note that security X lies on the opportunity set frontier.

3
This means that there are no arbitrage opportunities. To see that, notice that the security X can
be derived from the existing Bond and Stock. The cash flow vector associated with the security X
is given by  
10
cX = .
35
Therefore, the replicating portfolio will be
 −1    
−1 20 50 10 3
n=Q cX = =
20 25 35 −1

The same time-state payoffs as provided by X can be obtained by buying 3 bonds and selling 1
stock. The total price of this portfolio is 3 × 18 − 1 × 30 = 24P A. This means that X is trading at
its arbitrage free price.

(iv) Another security Y appears on the market that pays 50GA and 30BA and has a price of 40PA.
Plot this security on the opportunity set. Does it provide any arbitrage opportunities? If so, design
a profitable arbitrage strategy.

Solution
1PA buys 1/40th Y which yields 50/40GA and 30/40BA. These numbers 1.25 and 0.75 provide the
coordinates for Y in the opportunity set.
The security Y creates arbitrage opportunities if it can be shorted since it lies below the op-
portunity set frontier. The same time-state payoffs can be obtained from the bond and stock as
follows:  −1    
−1 20 50 50 0.5
n = Q cX = =
20 25 30 0.8
The price of the replicating portfolio is 18 × 0.5 + 30 × 0.8 = 33PA. Hence, the arbitrage-free price
of any security providing the same time-state payments as Y must be 33PA. Since Y is traded for
40PA, you will make a profit of 7PA by buying 0.5 bonds, 0.8 stocks and selling 1Y. Furthermore,
you will remain perfectly hedged.

4
2. Suppose there are three possible states of the world in the next period, denoted by good weather
(GW), fair weather (FW) and bad weather (BW). Also, three securities are available on the market
with payoffs in each state listed below.

Bond Stock Security X


GW 20 43 26
FW 20 35 10
BW 20 30 0
(i) Suppose an investor desires the following portfolio:
 
10
c = 15 .

(states×1)
20

Is it possible? Why?

Solution
The payment matrix below  
20 43 26
Q = 20 35 10
20 30 0
is singular. This means that the payment vectors associated with the three securities are not linearly
independent. Indeed the time-state payments of X can be replicated by buying 2 units of the stock
and selling 3 units of the bond.
In general, this means that it will be impossible to construct a portfolio that generates the
time-state payoffs in c. In special cases, however, it might be possible. To check this, construct a
portfolio that delivers the desired time-state claims for two of the three states. Then, calculate the
payoff of the constructed portfolio in the remaining state. Check is the payoff equals to the desired
one. For instance, to obtain 10GA and15FA one needs to obtain the following portfolio:
 −1    
20 43 10 1. 843 8 bond
=
20 35 15 −0.625 stock

Buying today 1. 843 8 bonds and shorting −0.625 stocks will generate the following payoff in the
bad weather state:
 
 1. 843 8
20 30 = 18.125
−0.625
The constructed portfolio does not generate the required payoff in the bad state (i.e., 20). Hence,
it is impossible to generate the state-contingent payoffs in c by trading the bond, the stock and the
security X.

(ii) The prices of the three securities are as follows: pBond = 10, pStock = 20, pX = 15. Are there
arbitrage opportunities? If so, design a profitable arbitrage strategy; if not, explain why.

Solution
Yes, there are arbitrage opportunities. Buying two stocks and selling short three bonds generates
the same time-state payment vector as holding one unit of X. Buying the replicating portfolio (i.e.,

5
buying two stocks and shorting three bonds) and selling short X, yields a perfectly hedged portfolio
and a $5 profit.
That you make a profit of $5 can be deduced as follows: −2 × 20 + 10 × 3 + 1 × 15 = 5. That
you are fully hedged can be demonstrated as follows:

2S -3B -X
GW 86 -60 -26 =0
.
FW 70 -60 -10 =0
BW 60 -60 0 =0

(iii) Suppose security X disappears from the market.

(a) Construct a portfolio that pays 10 in GW and 15 in FW. What is the arbitrage-free price of
this portfolio? What is its payoff in the bad weather state?
Solution
This case has already been worked out above. The required portfolio consists of 1.84375 bonds
and −0.625 stocks. The arbitrage-free price of this portfolio is 10 × 1.84375 − 20 × 0.625 =
5.9375. Its payoff in the bad weather state is 20 × 1.84375 − 30 × 0.625 = 18.125.

(b) Construct a portfolio that pays 10 in GW and 20 in BW. What is the arbitrage-free price of
this portfolio? What is its payoff in the fair weather state?
Solution
The required portfolio is derived as follows:
 −1    
20 43 10 2. 153 8
=
20 30 20 −0.769

The arbitrage-free price of this portfolio is 10 × 2.1538 − 20 × 0.769 = 6.158.


Its payoff in the fair weather state is 20 × 2.153846 − 35 × 0.76923 = 16.15385.

(c) Construct a portfolio that pays 15 in FW and 20 in BW. What is the arbitrage-free price of
this portfolio? What is its payoff in the good weather state?
Solution
The required portfolio is derived as follows:
 −1    
20 35 15 2.5
=
20 30 20 −1

The arbitrage-free price of this portfolio is 10 × 2.5 − 20 × 1 = 5.


Its payoff in the good weather state is 20 × 2.5 − 43 × 1 = 7.

(d) Is it possible for an investment firm to provide the time-state claims in (i) to a client without
incurring any risk? Explain.
Solution
No it is not possible for an investment firm to provide the time-state claims in (i) without

6
incurring risk. In other words, the investment firm cannot fully hedge this position using just
the bond and stock. For example, the investment firm could buy 1.103448 × 1.84375 bonds
and sell 1.103448 × 0.625 stocks, and then provide c at a price of 6.551724. The investment
firm would then cover its costs and receive an additional 0.103448 × 10 in good weather,
0.103448 × 15 in fair weather and 0 in bad weather. The fact that its total payoff differs across
states means that it is not fully hedged.

(e) What is the minimum cost to for the investor? (Hint: use optimisation function.)
Solution

Linear Programming in Matlab

>> Q =[20 43; 20 35; 20 30]


>> c =[10 15 20]’
>> ps = [10 20]
>> n = linprog (ps’, -Q, -c);

n =

2.1538
-0.7692

>> p =ps*n

p =

6.1538

(f) What is the minimum cost if X becomes available? Comment on your results.
Solution
With X appears in the economy it is impossible to find minimum, because as we verified, the
market present arbitrage opportunity. The investor’s optimum strategy consists of exploiting
the arbitrage opportunity as much as possible and generate profit. No cost incurs and solution
is unbounded.

You might also like