The Cross-Country Incidence of The Global Crisis: Preliminary, Comments Welcome
The Cross-Country Incidence of The Global Crisis: Preliminary, Comments Welcome
The Cross-Country Incidence of The Global Crisis: Preliminary, Comments Welcome
where
i
Y A
is the difference between average GDP growth in 2008-09 and 2004-07 (
0809 0407 i i i
Y Y Y A =
), the vector
i
R consists of real-side variables,
i
F of financial-side
variables and
i
Z of general control variables. Note that we do not include any regressors that
are based on 2008-2009 realizations; rather, our goal is to identify initial conditions that
help to explain the slowdown during this period.
The real-side variables are the level of trade openness in 2007, the manufacturing share in
GDP in 2007, and an oil dummy that scores 1 for oil producers and 0 otherwise. The first two
variables are included since the global transmission of the global recession was clearly
intermediated through a significant contraction in world trade and an especially large decline
in the manufacturing sector. An oil dummy is also included to take into account the impact of
the shift in oil prices on economic activity levels in oil-exporting nations. (We will also
report results for a subsample that excludes the oil-exporting group.)
We consider both domestic and international financial variables. In relation to the former, we
include the growth rate of private credit over 2004-2007. This is included in view of the
potential structural vulnerabilities generated by rapid credit growth during the pre-crisis
period. In relation to the international financial variables, we consider both net and gross
measures. We include the 2007 value for the current account balance, since the increase in
risk aversion during the crisis plausibly had a differential impact on deficit countries relative
11
to surplus countries.
8
In particular, output may be disrupted a sudden stop or reversal in
capital flows on countries operating with large deficit positions.
We also explore the contribution of measures of gross international financial integration. As
an aggregate summary indicator of international financial integration, we consider the gross
scale of the international balance sheet measured at the end of 2007, as captured by the
indicator ( ) / IFI FA FL GDP = + . This measure has been widely used in previous empirical
research.
9
The advantage of this variable is the level of cross-border investment positions
represents an important financial transmission mechanism. A countrys direct exposure to a
decline in asset values in a given market varies in proportion to the scale of its holdings in
that market. Similarly, disruption in a particular credit market has the most direct impact on
the biggest issuers of liabilities in that market. However, a larger international balance sheet
may also provide valuable diversification in the event of instability in the domestic financial
system. A country is less exposed to declines in domestic asset values to the extent that it
has issued claims on domestic assets to foreign investors and reduced domestic holdings in
favor of a more internationally diversified asset portfolio. Accordingly, it is not clear on an
ex-ante basis whether a larger international balance sheet should be associated with a greater
or lesser exposure to the global crisis. We enter this variable in log form, in view of the
skewed nature of the cross-sectional distribution of this variable, with a small number of
international financial centers showing very large values for this variable.
10
Finally, we include the level of GDP per capita and the excess growth rate of GDP over
2004-2007 (that is, average output growth during 2004-2007 relative to the 1990-2007
average growth rate) as general control variables. The level of GDP per capita is included
since financial development indicators are correlated with the overall level of development,
such that it is potentially important to differentiate between financial factors and the general
level of development. The excess growth rate is included, since above-trend growth during
the pre-crisis period may be a signal of overheating in an economy.
We report results for the full sample of countries; in addition, we also estimate the
specifications for subsamples that exclude the oil exporters, low-income countries (using a
threshold of $1000 for 2007 GDP per capita), and small financial centers. The rationales of
excluding low-income countries are data-quality issues, as well as the fact that low-income
countries rely more heavily on official forms of international finance and are less exposed to
8
We also experimented with the inclusion of the net foreign asset position. However, this variable is highly
correlated with the 2007 current account balance and did not provide any extra explanatory power.
9
Recent examples include Kose et al (2009a, 2009b).
10
Furthermore, we exclude Luxembourg from all the regressions, given the very extreme level of IFI for this
country.
12
private-sector financial flows. The rationale for excluding small financial centers is the fact
that variables related to financial openness and, in some cases, net foreign assets take
extreme values, complicating statistical inference.
Table 6 displays the results for the output slowdown. Column (1) reports results for the fill
sample; column (2) for a sample excluding oil exporters; column (3) for a sample excluding
low-income countries; and column (4) for a sample excluding both low-income countries and
financial centers. In relation to the full sample results, column (1) of Table 1 broadly
confirms the results of the analysis presented in the previous section. Namely, the decline in
growth performance was larger in countries with higher income per capita, high pre-crisis
credit growth, high pre-crisis output growth relative to trend, current account deficits, high
trade openness, and a high share of manufacturing output. Interestingly, higher international
financial integration is positively correlated with the change in output growth, in contrast
with the notion that financial globalization per se was detrimental to output performance.
Instead, this finding is consistent with an interpretation by which the positive diversification
properties of a large international balance sheet provided some insulation against the
downturn. Overall, the explanatory power of the regression reported in column (1) is quite
good, with an adjusted R2 of 0.45.
Results are generally robust to changes in sample specification (columns 2-4). The main
exception is that the coefficient on the size of the manufacturing sector is no longer
individually significant, and the significance of the current account balance declines, even if
the absolute magnitude of the coefficient on the current account balance doubles in size
relative to column (1). In terms of the specific sub-samples, oil exporters had similar growth
declines when compared to other countries, but a significantly higher current account
balance. It is worth noting that the collinearity between credit growth and the current account
balance increases when low-income countries are excluded.
In Table 7 we present a similar set of regressions to explain the decline in the growth rate of
domestic demand. Overall, results are similar to those presented in Table 6, and the fit of the
regressions is improved relative to Table 6 (in the first three samples the regression explains
over 50 percent of the variance in the change in demand growth). The coefficient on the
current account balance is now considerably higher and always strongly significant
countries with large current account deficits in the pre-crisis period experienced sharper
declines in domestic demand. Holding other variables constant, a current account deficit
larger by 4 percentage points of GDP is associated with a decline in demand growth which is
1 percentage point largeran economically significant effect. Similarly, the coefficient on
private credit growth is higher: higher pre-crisis credit growth is associated with a stronger
demand slowdown during the crisis.
In sum, the empirical results emphasize the advanced economies nature of the crisis, as
well as the importance for explaining the decline in output and demand growth rates of
13
various measures of buoyancy of economic activity pre-crisis (credit growth rates, growth
rate relative to trend), external vulnerabilities (larger current account deficits), and exposure
to trade and production of traded goods.
While the decline in output and demand growth are certainly key indicators of the impact of
the crisis, the theoretical literature also heavily emphasizes that international financial
integration may facilitate international risk sharing, with domestic consumption insulated
from the country-specific component of domestic GDP fluctuations. On the other hand,
financial integration also implies that domestic consumption will be affected by international
wealth shocks even if domestic GDP is unaffected. In addition to the risk sharing dimension,
it is also important to take into account that an increase in risk aversion and a tightening of
lending standards were central features of the global credit crisis. Accordingly, it is plausible
that there has been a shift in the ability to borrow, with a requirement that deficit countries
rebuild the value of their net external positions.
For these reasons, we also run a second set of regressions where the dependent variable is the
growth rate of consumption over 2008-2009. In particular, we examine how measures of
international financial integration and creditworthiness affect the relation between output
growth and consumption growth during the crisis period.
Our general specification can be written as
*
i i i i i i i
C Y IFI IFI Y VULN o | o u ; c = + + + + +
where
i
C is the consumption growth rate over 2008-2009,
i
Y is the output growth rate,
i
IFI is
a measure of international financial integration and
i
VULN are measures of net financial
vulnerability. In relation to financial vulnerability, we consider two main measures of
exposure to credit markets: the current account balance in 2007 (in percent of GDP) and the
growth rate of private credit during the 2004-2007 pre-crisis period.
We include the output growth rate, since a natural benchmark under limited financial
integration is that consumption growth should be influenced by output growth. For
international financial integration, we use a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the
sum of external financial assets and liabilities is over 150 percent of GDP and the country is
not a large net debtor.
11
We estimate whether IFI and VULN measures directly matter for
consumption growth. In addition, we interact the IFI measure with the output growth rate in
order to assess whether higher integration reduces or amplifies the sensitivity of domestic
11
We use a threshold of -50 percent of GDP for the net external position, so as to avoid counting as highly
financially integrated countries that have large net external liabilities as a ratio of GDP.
14
consumption growth to domestic output growth. To the extent that a high level of
international financial integration means that foreign investors share domestic output risk, we
would expect consumption growth to be less sensitive to GDP fluctuations. If access to credit
and the cost of credit disproportionately deteriorated for countries running current account
deficits and that experienced rapid credit growth during 2004-2007, we would expect to
observe lower consumption growth in these countries.
The results for the consumption growth regressions are presented in Table 8.
12
As in Tables
6 and 7, we report results for four cuts of the data, with the full sample included in columns
(1), oil exporters excluded in column (2), low-income countries excluded in column (3), and
low-income countries and financial centers excluded in column (4).
Overall, results clearly point to a very strong correlation between consumption growth and
domestic GDP growth, consistent with a globally-incomplete level of international financial
integration. We also find little evidence that this link is weaker in more financially integrated
countries. For the sample that excludes oil exporters, we find evidence that the slowdown in
private consumption growth was larger in countries with higher private credit growth. The
size and significance of the coefficient on private credit growth drops significantly when
financial centers are excludedthese countries had on average high private credit growth
and significant declines in private consumption. For the sample excluding low-income
countries and financial centers (column 4) a larger pre-crisis current account deficit is
significantly associated with lower private consumption growth.
Finally, the existence of financial frictions means that wealth shocks may also affect other
types of domestic demand (investment, inventories, and the government sector). For instance,
the state of corporate balance sheets may affect investment decisions. In addition, tax
revenues and funding costs for public debt may be adversely affected by a decline in wealth.
Accordingly, we also run a third set of regressions that adopt the same format as for the
consumption equations but with the growth rate in total domestic demand as the dependent
variable
*
i i i i i i i
D Y IFI IFI Y VULN o | o u ; c = + + + + + +
where
i
D is the growth rate of total domestic demand over 2008-2009.
12
We also ran the perfect risk sharing equation by which the cross-country variation in consumption growth
should be proportionate to real exchange rate dynamics: however, the pattern is that faster consumption growth
is associated with real appreciation, in violation of the benchmark hypothesis.
15
These results are reported in Table 9, which has the same format as Table 8. Again, there is a
very strong correlation between demand growth and GDP growth, and little evidence that the
link is affected by international financial integration. Instead, we find strong evidence that
larger pre-crisis current account deficits and high growth rates in private credit are associated
with a larger decline in domestic demand, holding GDP growth constant. This finding is
consistent with a tightening of credit constraints on current account deficit countries and on
countries that experienced fast credit growth, leading to a correction in net external
borrowing during the crisis period.
V. CONCLUDING REMARKS
Our goal in this paper has been to establish the extent to which various pre-crisis measures
help explain the cross-country variation in the macroeconomic incidence of the crisis. Real-
side variables such as trade openness and the manufacturing share are correlated with the
output and demand declines, consistently with the higher cyclicality of manufactured goods
and the dramatic decline in international trade that took place during the crisis. Also, the
evidence points to a strong link between pre-crisis domestic financial factors (fast private
credit growth) and external imbalances (current account deficits) on the one hand and the
decline in the growth rate of output and especially domestic demand during the crisis on the
other hand. The advanced economies nature of the crisis is highlighted by the negative
correlation between GDP per capita and the decline in output growth. It is also intriguing that
a greater level of financial development is associated with a smaller growth slowdown.
One limitation of our approach is that it does not establish the mechanisms by which these
variables may have affected macroeconomic outcomes. For instance, it clearly matters
whether and how these variables affected macroeconomic policy responses during the crisis.
Moreover, it would be also informative to gain a more precise understanding of the channels
by which shifts in international capital market conditions affected access to credit and the
cost of credit. Finally, explaining the dramatic decline in world trade during the crisis is
another important challenge.
16
Bibliography
Acharya, Viral, Philipp Schnabl, and Gustavo Suarez, 2009, Securitization without Risk
Transfer, mimeo, New York University, November.
Berglof, Erik, Yevgeniya Korniyenko, Alexander Plekhanov and Jeromin Zettelmeyer
(2009), Understanding the Crisis in Emerging Europe, mimeo, EBRD.
Brunnermeier, Markus (2008), Deciphering The Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007-2008,
NBER Working Paper 14612.
CES Ifo (2009), The Financial Crisis, in The EEAG Report on The European Economy
2009.
Devereux, Michael B. and James Yetman (2009), Financial De-Leveraging and the
International Transmission of Shocks, Kose, Ayhan, Eswar Prasad and Marco
Terrones (2009a), Does Financial Globalization Promote International Risk
Sharing?, Journal of Development Economics vol. 89 no. 2, July, pp. 258-270.
Kose, Ayhan, Eswar Prasad and Marco Terrones (2009b), Does Openness to International
Financial Flows Raise Productivity Growth?, Journal of International Money and
Finance Vol. 28 no. 4, June, pp. 554-580.
Krugman, Paul (2008), The International Finance Multiplier, mimeo, Princeton University.
Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2007, The External Wealth of Nations
Mark II, Journal of International Economics 73 no. 2 (November), 223-250.
Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria (2009), The International Transmission of the Financial Crisis,
mimeo, International Monetary Fund, November.
Rose, Andrew and Mark Spiegel (2009a), Cross-Country Causes and Consequences of the
2008 Crisis: Early Warning, NBER Working Paper 15357.
Rose, Andrew and Mark Spiegel (2009b), Cross-Country Causes and Consequences of the
2008 Crisis: International Linkages and American Exposure, NBER Working Paper
15358.
17
Table 1. The geographical impact of the crisis (I)*
A. Changes in growth (2008-09 minus 2005-2007)
Country group Emerg.
Europe
CIS Emerg.
Asia
Emg.
West.
Hem.
Carib. Africa Industr. Middle
East
Crisis intensity
Worst 20 8 3 1 4 0 1 3 0
Worst 30 12 3 3 4 0 2 5 1
best 20 0 0 4 3 0 9 0 4
best 30 0 0 4 4 0 16 0 6
B. Growth rates 2008-09
Country group Emerg.
Europe
CIS Emerg.
Asia
Emg.
West.
Hem.
Carib. Africa Industr. Middle
East
Crisis intensity
Worst 20 7 0 1 1 0 0 11 0
Worst 30
11 0 1 2 0 0 16 0
best 20 0 1 5 1 0 7 0 6
best 30 0 2 5 4 0 12 0 7
* The table lists the number of countries among the most affected and least affected by the
crisis. The crisis measure is obtained by constructing a global ranking for each of several
crisis measures (output growth, demand growth, private and public consumption growth,
investment growth, export growth, import growth) and averaging the rankings.
18
Table 2. The Geographical Impact of the Crisis (II)
Average change in growth rates
Output Demand Priv.
cons.
Pub.
Cons.
Invest. Exports Imports
Emerging Europe -8.2 -11.3 -9.4 -2.2 -20.9 -14.0 -18.7
CIS -7.5 -8.8 -11.3 -2.0 -6.4 -10.4 -6.9
Industrial -4.6 -5.3 -3.6 0.3 -13.9 -11.8 -14.1
Caribbean -4.3 -3.1 -2.8 -3.0 -4.3 -9.0 -5.6
Western Hem. -4.0 -5.0 -4.1 -1.0 -9.6 -6.9 -10.5
Emerging Asia -3.1 -4.3 -1.7 -0.7 -10.6 -9.5 -9.9
Africa -2.0 -0.9 0.3 0.1 1.1 -5.6 -2.5
Middle East -1.6 -1.8 -0.8 -2.8 -3.7 -6.3 -5.1
Average growth rates
Output Demand Priv.
cons.
Pub.
Cons.
Invest. Exports Imports
Emerging Europe -1.7 -3.2 -1.9 0.8 -8.4 -4.4 -6.9
Industrial -1.4 -1.9 -0.7 2.6 -8.3 -6.1 -7.5
Caribbean 0.2 -1.8 -1.6 -4.1 -0.8 6.4 -4.3
Western Hem. 1.9 2.3 2.5 4.5 1.3 -0.8 0.6
Emerging Asia 3.0 4.0 5.5 7.0 -0.2 -2.3 0.8
CIS 3.2 2.6 -2.0 7.6 9.6 -2.5 6.8
Africa 3.4 5.3 5.7 5.2 9.8 -0.2 4.9
Middle East 4.5 5.7 7.0 4.4 6.5 2.1 7.2
19
Table 3. Top 5 crisis countries
Changes in growth rates (2008-2009 minus 2005-2007)
Latvia Armenia Estonia Lithuania Azerbaijan
GDP growth -22.5 -18.7 -17.8 -16.6 -16.5
Latvia Ukraine Estonia Lithuania Iceland
Total demand growth -30.9 -24.7 -24.2 -23.0 -22.9
Latvia Ukraine Estonia Lithuania Iceland
Private cons. growth -34.1 -22.8 -21.2 -20.2 -19.7
Iceland Lithuania Ukraine Armenia Venezuela
Investment growth -50.9 -43.9 -40.9 -39.8 -39.5
Angola Cambodia Cape Verde Togo Namibia
Export growth -34.5 -26.3 -25.6 -24.3 -23.6
Latvia Iceland Venezuela Russia Estonia
Import growth -37.7 -37.0 -34.9 -32.3 -32.0
Growth rates (2008-09)
Latvia Estonia Lithuania Ukraine Zimbabwe
GDP growth -11.6 -8.9 -8.4 -6.3 -5.6
Latvia Iceland Lithuania Estonia Ukraine
Total demand growth -17.7 -14.9 -12.8 -12.6 -9.8
Latvia Iceland Estonia Bahrain Kazakhstan
Priv. cons. growth -18.5 -12.5 -10.6 -10.0 -8.9
Iceland Lithuania Guinea Ireland Maldives
Investment growth
-37.5 -32.6 -28.1 -24.1 -23.8
PNG Cambodia Cent. Afr. Rep. Eritrea Togo
Export growth -24.2 -16.3 -15.8 -15.6 -14.6
Iceland Latvia Estonia Yemen Spain
Import growth -24.6 -21.4 -17.2 -13.8 -13.3
Source: World Economic Outlook, October 2009.
20
Table 4. Severe crisis and stronger growth countries: full sample
Median
difference
Mean
difference t-test
Change in output growth
Change in output growth 6.6 8.2 12.0
Change in total demand growth 6.7 9.8 6.3
GDP per capita -12,845 -20,243 -5.2
mean CA 2004-07 0.9 1.9 0.8
Openness -28% -39% -2.8
Share of manufacturing GDP -8.6 -6.6 -4.3
Priv. credit/GDP -61% -59% -5.7
growth in priv. cr. /GDP -13% -19% -3.6
Financial openness -1.7 -8.5 -1.5
Debt/GDP (gross) -68.2 -367.0 -1.6
NFA/GDP -2.6 0.9 0.0
Net debt/GDP 8.1 -67.8 -0.9
BIS net /GDP 20.2 21.7 0.8
Trade with US/GDP 0.3 -1.3 -0.8
Growth in 04-07 relative to 1990-07 -0.1 -0.8 -2.0
Change in demand growth
Change in output growth 5.5 5.4 6.3
Change in total demand growth 7.7 12.3 10.4
GDP per capita -15,049 -16,757 -4.2
mean CA 2004-07 2.8 4.2 1.9
Openness -0.2 -0.2 -1.7
Share of manufacturing GDP -7.2 -5.1 -3.2
Priv. credit/GDP -64% -63% -5.5
growth in priv. cr. /GDP -15% -23% -4.2
Financial openness -1.2 -8.1 -1.4
Debt/GDP (gross) -43.2 -380.1 -1.6
NFA/GDP 6.0 12.1 0.7
Net debt/GDP 22.2 -53.9 -0.8
BIS net /GDP 25.6 57.8 3.3
Trade with US/GDP 1.4 0.1 0.1
Growth in 04-07 relative to 1990-07 0.2 -0.2 -0.3
Note: The first two columns report the difference between the median and the mean of a sample including the
countries least affected by the crisis and those most affected. The third column reports a t test for the hypothesis
that the sample means are equal.
21
Table 5. Severe crisis and stronger growth countries:
sample excluding low-income countries and financial centers
Median
difference
Mean
difference t-test
Change in output growth
Change in output growth 5.7 7.5 8.5
Change in total demand growth 4.6 8.4 4.8
GDP per capita -9,523 -10,044 -2.5
mean CA 2004-07 1.9 7.0 2.2
Openness -18% -10% -1.1
Share of manufacturing GDP -9.7 -6.5 -3.2
Priv. credit/GDP -34% -34% -3.6
growth in priv. cr. /GDP -13% -17% -4.2
Financial openness -1.1 -0.6 -1.8
Debt/GDP (gross) -42.9 -14.7 -0.6
NFA/GDP 10.9 41.7 1.7
Net debt/GDP 30.0 50.0 2.1
BIS net /GDP 21.1 35.4 5.0
Trade with US/GDP 1.9 1.5 0.7
Growth in 04-07 rel. to 1990-07 -0.2 -0.7 -1.6
Change in demand growth
Change in output growth 4.0 4.6 4.6
Change in total demand growth 6.3 10.3 7.4
GDP per capita -9,656 -7,694 -1.9
mean CA 2004-07 6.3 9.8 3.8
Openness 0.0 0.0 -0.2
Share of manufacturing GDP -6.2 -5.0 -2.5
Priv. credit/GDP -35% -37% -3.4
growth in priv. cr. /GDP -12% -15% -3.8
Financial openness -0.6 -0.4 -1.5
Debt/GDP (gross) -23.9 -7.1 -0.4
NFA/GDP 19.9 45.8 2.7
Net debt/GDP 33.1 45.1 3.6
BIS net /GDP 23.3 30.9 4.2
Trade with US/GDP 2.0 -0.6 -0.2
Growth in 04-07 rel. to 1990-07 0.0 -0.2 -0.3
Note: The first two columns report the difference between the median and the mean of a sample including the
countries least affected by the crisis and those most affected. The third column reports a t test for the hypothesis
that the sample means are equal.
22
Table 6. Explaining The Decline in Output Growth
(1) (2) (3) (4)
All countries Excl. oil
exporters
Excl. low income Excl. low income
and fin. ctrs
Trade openness -0.02*** -0.02*** -0.02*** -0.02*
[0.01] [0.01] [0.01] [0.01]
Manuf. Share -0.09** -0.06 -0.06 -0.05
[0.04] [0.04] [0.05] [0.05]
Oil dummy -0.27 0.47 0.73
[0.90] [1.12] [1.23]
CA/GDP 0.05** 0.06** 0.05* 0.04
[0.02] [0.03] [0.03] [0.03]
Priv. credit growth -4.67*** -4.66*** -5.03*** -6.79**
[1.53] [1.57] [1.72] [2.68]
Log GDP per capita -1.25*** -1.50*** -1.62*** -1.60***
[0.26] [0.28] [0.44] [0.53]
Growth gap -0.77*** -0.87*** -0.89*** -0.86***
[0.12] [0.15] [0.15] [0.18]
Log (financial openness) 1.26** 1.65*** 1.90** 2.10**
[0.56] [0.60] [0.73] [1.02]
Constant 5.04** 5.24** 4.96* 3.41
[2.04] [2.15] [2.86] [3.64]
Observations 145 125 111 94
R-squared 0.453 0.468 0.428 0.400
Note: Dependent variable is the change in output growth between 2008-2009 and 2005-2007. *,**,
*** denote significance at 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively. OLS estimation. Trade openness
is the sum of exports and imports divided by GDP. The manufacturing share is the ratio of
manufacturing output to GDP. CA/GDP is the ratio of the 2007 current account balance to GDP.
Private credit growth is the change in the ratio to GDP of private credit by banks and other financial
institutions between 2003 and 2007. GDP per capita is nominal GDP in US dollars in 2007. The
growth gap is the difference in output growth rates between 2005-2007 and 1990-2007. Financial
openness is the sum of external financial assets and liabilities assets divided by GDP. All ratios and
growth rates are multiplied by 100.
23
Table 7. Explaining the Decline in Demand Growth
(1) (2) (3) (4)
All countries Excl. oil
exporters
Excl. low
income
Excl. low
income and
fin. ctrs
Trade openness -0.02** -0.03*** -0.02* -0.01
[0.01] [0.01] [0.01] [0.02]
Manuf. Share -0.12** -0.05 -0.11 -0.12
[0.06] [0.06] [0.07] [0.09]
Oil dummy -1.39 -2.93 -3.10
[1.44] [1.99] [2.14]
CA/GDP 0.23*** 0.25*** 0.29*** 0.30***
[0.05] [0.06] [0.06] [0.07]
Priv. credit growth -9.13*** -9.10*** -7.79*** -7.19
[2.43] [2.36] [2.94] [4.59]
Log GDP per capita -1.75*** -2.06*** -1.92*** -1.97**
[0.39] [0.39] [0.70] [0.84]
Growth gap -0.68*** -0.78*** -0.56*** -0.52***
[0.12] [0.14] [0.16] [0.17]
Log (financial openness) 1.87** 2.50*** 1.85 2.06
[0.86] [0.84] [1.21] [1.77]
Constant 7.27** 6.24** 8.49* 6.88
[3.04] [2.99] [4.48] [5.67]
Observations 129 111 95 81
R-squared 0.554 0.598 0.533 0.479
Note: Dependent variable is the change in growth in total domestic demand between 2008-2009 and
2005-2007. *,**, *** denote significance at 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively. OLS estimation.
Trade openness is the sum of exports and imports divided by GDP. The manufacturing share is the
ratio of manufacturing output to GDP. CA/GDP is the ratio of the 2007 current account balance to
GDP. Private credit growth is the change in the ratio to GDP of private credit by banks and other
financial institutions between 2003 and 2007. GDP per capita is nominal GDP in US dollars in 2007.
The growth gap is the difference in domestic demand growth rates between 2005-2007 and 1990-
2007. Financial openness is the sum of external financial assets and liabilities assets divided by
GDP. All ratios and growth rates are multiplied by 100.
24
Table 8. Consumption Growth (2008-2009)
(1) (2) (3) (4)
VARIABLES All countries Excl. oil
exporters
Excl. low
income
Excl. low
income and
fin. ctrs
GDP growth 2008-09 1.06*** 0.99*** 1.05*** 1.14***
[0.12] [0.11] [0.15] [0.16]
Financial integration dummy 0.39 1.13 -0.29 -0.92
[0.96] [0.94] [1.03] [1.08]
GDP growth*fin. integr. dummy 0.28 -0.42 0.26 0.20
[0.26] [0.38] [0.27] [0.27]
Oil dummy 1.67 1.34 0.19
[1.23] [1.45] [1.44]
CA/GDP 0.05 -0.04 0.07 0.15***
[0.04] [0.05] [0.05] [0.06]
Growth in private credit -2.70 -5.27*** -3.17 0.82
[2.04] [1.95] [2.19] [3.40]
Constant 0.88 0.59 1.50** 1.18*
[0.60] [0.55] [0.66] [0.67]
Observations 130 112 95 81
R-squared 0.586 0.560 0.626 0.682
Note: Dependent variable is the average growth in private consumption over 2008-2009. *,**, ***
denote significance at 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively. OLS estimation. GDP growth 08-09 is
the average growth rate of real GDP over 2008-09. The financial integration dummy takes the value
of 1 if the sum of external assets and liabilities is at least 150 percent of GDP and the net external
position is not worse than 50 percent of GDP. CA/GDP is the ratio of the 2007 current account
balance to GDP. Private credit growth is the change in the ratio to GDP of private credit by banks
and other financial institutions between 2003 and 2007. All ratios and growth rates are multiplied by
100.
25
Table 9. Total Domestic Demand Growth (2008-09)
(1) (2) (3) (4)
VARIABLES All countries Excl. oil
exporters
Excl. low
income
Excl. low
income and
fin. ctrs
GDP growth 2008-09 1.13*** 1.10*** 1.17*** 1.21***
[0.08] [0.07] [0.11] [0.12]
Financial integration dummy -0.57 -0.35 -0.55 -1.04
[0.65] [0.64] [0.73] [0.83]
GDP growth*fin. integr. dummy 0.10 -0.12 0.06 0.06
[0.17] [0.26] [0.19] [0.21]
Oil dummy -0.08 -0.46 -0.84
[0.83] [1.03] [1.11]
CA/GDP 0.13*** 0.12*** 0.14*** 0.18***
[0.03] [0.03] [0.04] [0.04]
Growth in private credit -3.70*** -4.52*** -2.81* 1.62
[1.38] [1.32] [1.56] [2.63]
Constant 1.01** 1.01*** 0.87* 0.58
[0.40] [0.38] [0.47] [0.52]
Observations 131 113 96 82
R-squared 0.785 0.803 0.793 0.782
Note: Dependent variable is the average growth in total domestic demand over 2008-2009. *,**, ***
denote significance at 10, 5 and 1 percent levels respectively. OLS estimation. GDP growth 08-09 is
the average growth rate of real GDP over 2008-09. Financial openness is the sum of external
financial assets and liabilities assets divided by GDP. CA/GDP is the ratio of the 2007 current
account balance to GDP. Private credit growth is the change in the ratio to GDP of private credit by
banks and other financial institutions between 2003 and 2007. All ratios and growth rates are
multiplied by 100.
26
Figure 1. Change in GDP growth and GDP per capita
Note: Horizontal axis: log nominal GDP per capita in US dollars (2007). Vertical axis:
change in GDP growth between 2008-2009 and 2005-2007. Whole sample. The correlation
coefficient equals -0.39.
-
2
0
-
1
0
0
1
0
c
h
a
n
g
e
i
n
G
D
P
g
r
o
w
t
h
4 6 8 10 12
log GDP per capita
27
Figure 2. Decline in demand growth and current account balance
Note: Horizontal axis: 2007 current account balance in percent of GDP. Vertical axis:
change in total domestic demand growth between 2008-2009 and 2005-2007. Sample
excludes low-income countries. Correlation coefficient equals 0.47.
-
3
0
-
2
0
-
1
0
0
1
0
2
0
c
h
a
n
g
e
i
n
d
e
m
a
n
d
g
r
o
w
t
h
-40 -20 0 20 40 60
current account/GDP, 2007
28
Figure 3. Decline in demand growth and growth in private credit
Note: Horizontal axis: change in the ratio of private credit to GDP, 2003-2007. Vertical axis:
change in total domestic demand growth between 2008-2009 and 2005-2007. Sample
excludes low-income countries. Correlation coefficient equals -0.46.
-
3
0
-
2
0
-
1
0
0
1
0
2
0
c
h
a
n
g
e
i
n
d
o
m
e
s
t
i
c
d
e
m
a
n
d
g
r
o
w
t
h
-.5 0 .5 1 1.5
change in the ratio of private credit to GDP