All Sessions of Eco
All Sessions of Eco
All Sessions of Eco
Perfect Competition
Different Form
Monopolistic Competition
of Market
Oligopoly
Structures
Monopoly
Large Number of Buyers
and Sellers
Perfectly
Competitive Homogenous Products
Market
Price Taker
Examples of Perfectly Competitive Market
Monopoly Market
Characteristics
of Monopoly
Examples of Monopoly
Examples of Monopolistic Competition
A monopolistic competitive industry has the
following features:
Many firms.
Characteristics Freedom of entry and exit.
Marginal Revenue (MR)= d(TR)/dQ
Marginal Cost (MC)= d(TC)/dQ
Revenue, Profit (q)= TR-TC= R(q)- C(q)
Firm
Demand Curve, Average Revenue and
Marginal Revenue Curve
Short Run Profit Maximizing Condition by
a competitive firm
Competitive Firm Short Run Supply Curve
Long Run Profit Maximization
Session 1 : Introduction to Managerial
Economics
Chhavi Tiwari
PGDHRM2021-23
Email: [email protected]
T.A. Pai Management Institute (TAPMI), Manipal
FUNDAMENTAL
ECONOMIC
PROBLEM
• Constrained Optimization
• Marginal analysis- Comparing marginal
Introduction benefit and marginal cost
to • Managerial economics applies microeconomic
Economics theory to business problems
• How to use economic analysis to make decisions to
achieve firm’s goal of profit maximization
• You are interviewing three people for one sales job.
On the basis of your experience and insight, you
An example believe Jane can sell 600 units a day, Joe can sell 450
units a day, and Joan can sell 400 units a day. The daily
salary each person is asking is as follows: Jane, $200;
Joe, $150; and Joan, $100. How would you rank the
three applicants?
• Labor economics studies how labor
Introduction markets work.
to Labour
Economics • How are wages determined?
• What is the impact of government
intervention in the labour market?
Positive economics addresses the relatively narrow “What
is?”
• What is the impact of minimum wage on unemployment?
• What is the impact of a tuition assistance program on
Positive college enrollment rates?
• Microeconomics
• Greek for small
• The branch of economics that examines the functioning of the economy at the level of individual
consumers, workers, firms and markets.
• Looks at the individual unit- the household, the firm, the industry. It sees and examines the “trees”.
• Macroeconomics
• Macro is Greek for large.
• The branch of economics that examines the economic behavior of the aggregates-income,
employment, output and so on- on a national scale.
• Looks at the whole- the aggregate. It sees and analyses the “forest”.
SCOPE OF ECONOMICS
How much steel Price of medical care Wages in the auto Jobs in the steel
How much office Price of gasoline industry industry
space Price of Food prices Minimum wage No. of employees in a
How many cars Apartment Rent Executive salaries firm
No. of accountants
Macroeconomics National Aggregate price National Income Employment and
Production/Output level Unemployment in
the economy
Total Industrial Output Consumer prices Total wages and
Gross Domestic Producer prices salaries Total number of jobs
Product Rate of inflation Total Corporate Unemployment rate
Growth of output Profit
• Consumer- What to produce?
Economic
agents • Producers- How to Produce?
• Firms- How much to produce? What price to
charge?
Theory of Consumption- Preferences, Theory of Production- Cost,
Budget, Utility Maximization Production function, Cost Minimization
Short-run
Long-run
Shut-down (if not covering Oligopoly Monopoly
VC) Entry (Profit) versus Exit
(Losses)
versus continue
Pricing Decisions
A) If Abhaya orders food from Zomato this Saturday, he will not be able to afford buying ice cream.
B) If Riya studies for her economics quiz this evening, she will not have time to walk her dog.
C) If Hyundai increases its production of SUVs this year, it will have to spend more on advertising.
D) If Crossword Bookstores increases the number of titles it carries, it will have to reallocate shelf space to
accommodate the new titles.
Identify the positive statement?
A) The Prime minister of India ought to be elected by a direct vote of the Indian people rather than the
Electoral College.
B) A fundamental assumption of the economic theory of consumer behavior is that consumers always
prefer having more of any good to having less of it.
C) Because many adults cannot afford to go to college, tax credits for tuition should be introduced.
D) all of the above
E) none of the above
• Quantity demanded (QD): Amount of a good or service
consumers are willing & able to purchase during a given
period of time.
𝑄𝐷 = 𝑓(𝑃, 𝑀, 𝑃𝑅 , 𝑇, … . . )
• Law of Demand
• The claim that the quantity demanded of a good falls
when the price of the good rises, other things equal .
• QD increases when P falls & QD decreases when P rises,
all else constant
QD = QD(P)
LET’S TRY IT OUT
Price Quantity
• Example:
of pizza of pizza demanded
Kumar’s demand for
₹0.00 16
pizza.
1.00 14
2.00 12
3.00 10
• Notice that Kumar’s 4.00 8
preferences obey the
5.00 6
law of demand.
6.00 4
KUMAR’S DEMAND SCHEDULE & CURVE
Price of Quantity
Price
Pizza D of pizza
of pizza
₹
$6.00 demanded
₹0.00 16
₹$5.00
1.00 14
₹$4.00
2.00 12
₹$3.00 3.00 10
₹$2.00 4.00 8
5.00 6
₹$1.00
D 6.00 4
₹$0.00
Quantity
0 5 10 15 of Pizzas
MARKET DEMAND VERSUS INDIVIDUAL DEMAND
• The quantity demanded in the market is the sum of the quantities demanded by all buyers at
each price.
• Suppose Kumar and Aisha are the only two buyers in the Pizza market. (𝑸𝑫 = quantity
demanded)
• Market demand curve is the horizontal summation of individual demand curves.
P D P 𝑄𝐷 (Market)
₹
$6.00
₹0.00 24
₹
$5.00
1.00 21
₹
$4.00 2.00 18
₹
$3.00 3.00 15
4.00 12
₹
$2.00
5.00 9
₹
$1.00 6.00 6
D
₹
$0.00 Q Mathematically, a linear demand
0 5 10 15 20 25 curve be represented as;
𝑄𝐷 = 𝑎 − 𝑏𝑃 Rate of
Intercept change
DEMAND CURVE SHIFTERS
• Taste/ Preference
• Expectations
SUMMARY: VARIABLES THAT INFLUENCE DEMAND
Chhavi Tiwari
• The quantity supplied of any good is the amount
that sellers are willing and able to sell.
• 𝑄𝑆 = 𝑄𝑆 (𝑃)
THE SUPPLY SCHEDULE
• Example:
Dominos’ supply of pizzas. Quantity
Price
of pizzas
of pizza
supplied
₹0.00 0
▪ Notice that Dominos’ 1.00 3
supply schedule 2.00 6
obeys the 3.00 9
law of supply. 4.00 12
5.00 15
6.00 18
DOMINOS’ SUPPLY SCHEDULE & CURVE
Price Quantity
P S of of pizzas
₹
$6.00 pizzas supplied
₹
$5.00
₹0.00 0
1.00 3
₹$4.00
2.00 6
₹$3.00 3.00 9
₹$2.00 4.00 12
5.00 15
₹
$1.00
6.00 18
S
₹
$0.00 Q
0 5 10 15
MARKET SUPPLY VERSUS INDIVIDUAL SUPPLY
𝑸𝑺
P P
S (Market)
₹
$6.00
₹0.00 0
₹
$5.00 1.00 5
₹
$4.00 2.00 10
₹
$3.00 3.00 15
4.00 20
₹$2.00
5.00 25
₹
$1.00 6.00 30
S
₹
$0.00 Q Mathematically, a linear supply
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 curve be represented as;
𝑄𝑆 = 𝑐 + 𝑑𝑃
SUPPLY CURVE SHIFTERS
P S S’
Suppose the
₹$6.00 price of bread
falls.
₹$5.00
At each price,
₹$4.00 the quantity of
pizzas supplied
₹$3.00
will increase
₹$2.00 (by 5 in this
₹$1.00 example).
S S’
₹$0.00 Q
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
Slide 27
SUMMARY: VARIABLES THAT INFLUENCE SELLERS
P Equilibrium condition:
₹$6.00 D S P has reached
₹$5.00 the level where
quantity supplied equals
₹$4.00
quantity demanded
₹$3.00
𝑄𝐷 = 𝑄𝑆
₹$2.00
₹$1.00
₹$0.00 Q
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
EQUILIBRIUM PRICE AND EQUILIBRIUM QUANTITY:
Equilibrium Price: the price that equates quantity supplied with quantity demanded
Equilibrium Quantity : quantity at which demand, and supply are equal
P
₹$6.00 D S
P 𝑸𝑫 𝑸𝑺
₹$5.00
₹0 24 0
₹$4.00 1 21 5
₹ $3.00 2 18 10
3 15 15
₹ $2.00
4 12 20
₹ $1.00
5 9 25
₹$0.00 Q 6 6 30
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
SURPLUS (EXCESS SUPPLY):
when quantity supplied is greater than quantity demanded
P Example:
₹
$6.00 D Surplus S If P = ₹ 5,
₹
$5.00 then
₹
$4.00 QD = 9 pizzas
₹
$3.00 and
QS = 25 pizzas
₹
$2.00
₹
resulting in a
$1.00
surplus of 16 pizzas
₹
$0.00 Q
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
SURPLUS (EXCESS SUPPLY):
when quantity supplied is greater than quantity demanded
P Facing a surplus,
₹
$6.00 D Surplus S sellers try to increase
₹
$5.00 sales by cutting price.
₹
$4.00 This causes
𝑸𝑫 to rise and 𝑸𝑺 to fall…
₹
$3.00
₹
$2.00 …which reduces the
₹ surplus.
$1.00
₹
$0.00 Q
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
SURPLUS (EXCESS SUPPLY):
P Facing a surplus,
₹
$6.00 D Surplus S
sellers try to increase
₹
$5.00 sales by cutting price.
₹
$4.00 This causes
₹
$3.00 QD to rise and QS to fall.
₹
$2.00 Prices continue to fall
until market reaches
₹
$1.00
equilibrium.
₹
$0.00 Q
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
SHORTAGE (EXCESS DEMAND):
when quantity demanded is greater than quantity supplied
Example:
P
₹
$6.00 D S If P = ₹1,
₹
$5.00 then
₹
$4.00 𝑸𝑫 = 21 pizzas
₹
$3.00 and
𝑸𝑺 = 5 pizzas
₹
$2.00
resulting in a
₹
$1.00
shortage of 16
₹
$0.00 Shortage Q pizzas
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
SHORTAGE (EXCESS DEMAND):
when quantity demanded is greater than quantity supplied
P Facing a shortage,
₹
$6.00 D S sellers raise the price,
₹
$5.00 causing QD to fall
₹
$4.00 and QS to rise,
₹
$3.00 …which reduces the
₹
shortage.
$2.00
₹
$1.00
Shortage
₹
$0.00 Q
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
SHORTAGE (EXCESS DEMAND):
P Facing a shortage,
₹
$6.00 D S sellers raise the price,
causing QD to fall
₹
$5.00
and QS to rise.
₹
$4.00
Prices continue to rise
₹
$3.00 until market reaches
₹
$2.00 equilibrium.
₹
$1.00
Shortage
₹
$0.00 Q
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN THE LABOUR MARKET
• Price controls:
• Price Ceiling: a legal maximum on the price of a good or service Example: rent control
Chhavi Tiwari
INTERVENTIONS?
• Price controls:
• Price Ceiling: a legal maximum on the price of a good or service Example: rent control
2. Use supply and demand curves to illustrate how each of the following events would
affect the price of butter and the quantity of butter bought and sold:
a. An increase in the price of margarine
b. An increase in the price of milk
c. A decrease in average income levels
CHAPTER 2- PROBLEM. 1
• Suppose the demand curve for a product is given by Q = 300 - 2P + 4I, where I is average income
measured in thousands of dollars. The supply curve is Q = 3P - 50.
a. If I = 25, find the market-clearing price and quantity for the product.
• Given I = 25, the demand curve becomes Q = 300 − 2P + 4(25), or Q = 400 − 2P. Set demand equal to supply
and solve for P and then Q:
• 400 - 2P = 3P - 50
P = 90
Q = 400 - 2(90) = 220.
CHAPTER 2- PROBLEM. 1
• Suppose the demand curve for a product is given by Q = 300 - 2P + 4I, where I is average income
measured in thousands of dollars. The supply curve is Q = 3P - 50.
b. If I = 50, find the market-clearing price and quantity for the product.
Given I = 50, the demand curve becomes Q = 300 - 2P + 4(50), or Q = 500 - 2P. Setting demand equal to supply,
solve for P and then Q:
500 - 2P = 3P - 50
P = 110
Q = 500 - 2(110) = 280.
CHAPTER 2- PROBLEM. 6
Scenario:
The rent control agency of New York City has found that aggregate demand is 𝑄𝐷 = 160 – 8𝑃.
Quantity is measured in tens of thousands of apartments. Price, the average monthly rental rate, is
measured in hundreds of dollars. The agency also noted that the increase in Q at lower P results from
more three-person families coming into the city from Long Island and demanding apartments. The city’s
board of realtors acknowledges that this is a good demand estimate and has shown that supply is
𝑄𝑆 = 70 + 7𝑃.
CHAPTER 2- PROBLEM. 6
a. If both the agency and the board are right about demand and supply, what is the free-market price?
What is the change in city population if the agency sets a maximum average monthly rent of $300
and all those who cannot find an apartment leave the city?
Solution:
Equilibrium Condition : Demand = Supply, 𝑄𝐷 = 𝑄𝑆 .
160 − 8𝑃 = 70 + 7𝑃
𝑜𝑟 𝑃 = 6
which means the rental price is $600 since price is measured in hundreds of dollars.
𝑄𝐷 = 160 − 8(6) = 112
And
𝑄𝑆 = 70 + 7(6) = 112.
The quantity of apartments rented is 1,120,000 since Q is measured in tens of thousands of apartments.
CHAPTER 2- PROBLEM. 6
Solution:
If the rent control agency sets the rental rate at $300, the quantity supplied would be 910,000 (QS = 70
+ 7(3) = 91), a decrease of 210,000 apartments from the free-market equilibrium. Assuming three
people per family per apartment, this would imply a loss in city population of 630,000 people.
CHAPTER 2- PROBLEM. 6
b. Suppose the agency bows to the wishes of the board and sets a rental of $900 per month on all
apartments to allow landlords a “fair” rate of return. If 50 percent of any long-run increases in
apartment offerings come from new construction, how many apartments are constructed?
Solution:
At a rental rate of $900, the demand for apartments would be 160 − 8(9) = 88, or 880,000 units, which
is 240,000 fewer apartments than the original free-market equilibrium number of 1,120,000.Therefore,
no new apartments would be constructed.
THREE STEPS TO ANALYZING CHANGES IN EQ’M
Chhavi Tiwari
• Law of Demand : Direction of relationship
between demand and price
• Elasticity: Magnitude, How sensitive is the
ELASTICITY demand to the changes in the determinants
OF • Elasticity
DEMAND • Percentage change in one variable resulting
from a 1-percent increase in another.
• Elasticity of Demand
• Price elasticity
• Income elasticity
• Cross elasticity
• Price elasticity of demand
• a measure of how much the quantity
demanded of a good responds to a
PRICE change in the price of that good.
ELASTICITY • percentage change in quantity
OF demanded of a good resulting from a 1-
DEMAND percent increase in its price.
COMPUTING PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
𝜕𝑄 𝑃
𝑒𝑝 = .
𝜕𝑃 𝑄
PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
From A to B,
P rises 25%, Q falls 33%,
elasticity = 33/25 = 1.33
Demand for
your websites From B to A,
P P falls 20%, Q rises 50%,
B elasticity = 50/20 = 2.50
₹2500
A
₹2000 Mid-point method
D
Q
8 12 ∆𝑄 𝑃(𝐴𝑣𝑔)
|𝑒𝑃 | = .
∆𝑃 𝑄(𝐴𝑣𝑔)
• If, |𝑒𝑃 |<1 ⟹ percentage change in demand is
less than the percentage change in price.
Demand is inelastic.
PRICE
ELASTICITY • If, |𝑒𝑃 | >1 ⟹ percentage change in demand is
more than the percentage change in price.
OF Demand is elastic.
DEMAND • If, |𝑒𝑃 | =1 ⟹ percentage change in demand is
equal to the percentage change in price.
Demand is unitary elastic.
• The price elasticity of demand is closely related to
the slope of the demand curve.
• Rule of thumb:
VARIOUS The flatter the curve, the bigger the elasticity.
DEMAND The steeper the curve, the smaller the elasticity.
CURVES • Five different classifications of D curves.…
“PERFECTLY INELASTIC DEMAND” (ONE EXTREME C ASE)
Price elasticity % change in Q 0%
= = =0
of demand % change in P 10%
D curve: P
D
vertical
P1
Consumers’
price sensitivity: P2
none
P falls Q
Elasticity: by 10% Q1
0 Q changes
by 0%
“INELASTIC DEMAND”
Price elasticity % change in Q < 10%
= = <1
of demand % change in P 10%
D curve: P
relatively steep
P1
Consumers’
price sensitivity: P2
relatively low D
P falls Q
Elasticity: by 10% Q1 Q2
<1
Q rises less
than 10%
“UNIT ELASTIC DEMAND”
D curve: P
intermediate slope
P1
Consumers’
price sensitivity: P2
intermediate D
P falls Q
Elasticity: by 10% Q1 Q2
1
Q rises by 10%
“ELASTIC DEMAND”
D curve: P
relatively flat
P1
Consumers’
price sensitivity: P2 D
relatively high
P falls Q
Elasticity: by 10% Q1 Q2
>1
Q rises more
than 10%
“PERFECTLY ELASTIC DEMAND” (THE OTHER EXTREME)
D curve: P
horizontal
P2 = P1 D
Consumers’
price sensitivity:
extreme
P changes Q
Elasticity: by 0% Q1 Q2
infinity
Q changes
by any %
ELASTICITY ALONG LINEAR DEMAND CURVE
Chhavi Tiwari
TOTAL REVENUE AND PRICE ELASTICITY.
C ASE I: DEMAND IS ELASTIC
Now, demand is
inelastic:
. increased
elasticity = 0.82
revenue due to
P higher P
If P = ₹2000,
Q = 12 and
revenue = ₹2500
₹24000. ₹2000
If P = ₹ 2500, D
Q = 10 and
revenue = ₹
25000. Q
10 12
When D is inelastic, a price increase causes revenue to rise.
PROBLEM
Two friends Ravi and Vijay go to petrol pump. Ravi wanted to buy 100 Rs.
Petrol whereas Vijay wanted to buy 100 Litres of petrol. Calculate each
friend’s price elasticity.
INCOME ELASTICITY
𝑑𝑄/𝑄 𝑑𝑄 𝑀
η= = .
𝑑𝑀/𝑀 𝑑𝑀 𝑄
• For normal goods, higher income raises the quantity demanded. Hence, for
normal goods, income elasticity > 0.
• For inferior goods, higher income lowers the quantity demanded. Hence, for
inferior goods income elasticity < 0.
INCOME ELASTICITY: CH. 4 EXERCISE 10
a. Bill spends all his income on books and coffee. He finds $20 while rummaging through
a used paperback bin at the bookstore. He immediately buys a new hardcover book of
poetry.
Solution: Books are a normal good since his consumption of books increases with income.
Coffee is a neutral good since consumption of coffee stayed the same when income
increased.
b. Bill loses $10 he was going to use to buy a double espresso. He decides to sell his new
book at a discount to a friend and use the money to buy coffee.
Solution: When Bill’s income decreased by $10 he decided to own fewer books, so books
are a normal good. Coffee appears to be a neutral good because Bill’s purchase of the
double espresso did not change as his income changed.
ONE MORE PROBLEM: CHAPTER 4. EXERCISE 8
Judy has decided to allocate exactly $500 to college textbooks every year, even
though she knows that the prices are likely to increase by 5 to 10 percent per year
and that she will be getting a substantial monetary gift from her grandparents next
year. What is Judy’s price elasticity of demand for textbooks? Income elasticity?
Solution: Judy will spend the same amount ($500) on textbooks even when prices
increase. We know that total revenue (i.e., total spending on a good) remains constant
when price changes only if demand is unit elastic. Therefore Judy’s price elasticity of
demand for textbooks is –1. Her income elasticity must be zero because she does not plan
to purchase more books even though she expects a large monetary gift (i.e., an increase
in income).
CROSS PRICE ELASTICITY
Suppose the demand curve for a product is given by Q = 10 − 2P + 𝑃𝑠 , where P is the price of the product and 𝑃𝑠
is the price of a substitute good. The price of the substitute good is $2.00.
a. Suppose P = $1.00. What is the price elasticity of demand? What is the cross-price elasticity of demand?
Solution:
𝜕𝑄 𝜕𝑄
= −2, =1
𝜕𝑃 𝜕𝑃𝑠
𝜕𝑄 𝑃 1
Price elasticity of demand = 𝑒𝑝 = 𝜕𝑃 . 𝑄 =(−2). 10 = −0.2
𝜕𝑄 𝑃 2
Cross-price elasticity of demand = 𝑒𝑐 =𝜕𝑃 . 𝑄𝑠 = 1. 10 = 0.2
𝑠
CROSS PRICE ELASTICITY: PROBLEM 11, CH.2
b. Suppose the price of the good, P, goes to $2.00. Now what is the price elasticity of demand? What is the cross-
price elasticity of demand?
SESSION 7: ELASTICITY GAME
Chhavi Tiwari
“ TAPMI Cafe”
Situation 1
Twinkie (Rs.10)
Milk (Rs. 10)
Situation 2
• In your working groups, Determine the market quantities for situation 1 and situation 2.
• Develop the demand curve for snickers bar.
• Compute the price elasticity.
• Determine the market quantities for situation 3.
• Compute the income elasticity.
• Compute the cross-price elasticity for other goods.
• Coke, Twinkie, Milk
SESSION 8: THEORY OF
CONSUMPTION
Chhavi Tiwari
CONSUMER BEHAVIOR
• “Best” : Preferences
• “what consumers can afford”: Budget constraint
CONSUMER PREFERENCES
Assumptions
1. Completeness: For every pair of consumption bundles, A and B, the consumer can say
one of the following:
• A is preferred to B
• B is preferred to A
• The consumer is indifferent between A and B
Utility
• Benefits consumers obtain from goods &
services they consume is utility
Marginal utility
• Addition to total utility attributable to the
addition of one unit of a good to the current
rate of consumption, holding constant the
amounts of all other goods consumed,
𝜕𝑈
• For Good x, 𝑀𝑈𝑥 =
𝜕𝑥
LAW OF DIMINISHING MARGINAL UTILITY
B
A, B, and all other bundles on U1
make Sachin equally happy: he is A
indifferent between them.
U1
Quantity
of Food
FOUR PROPERTIES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES
If the quantity of
food is reduced, B
the quantity of
A
clothes must be
U1
increased to keep
Sachin equally
happy. Quantity
of Food
FOUR PROPERTIES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES
Quantity Sachin’s
3. Indifference curves of Clothes indifference curves
cannot cross.
Suppose they did.
Sachin should prefer
B to C, since B has B
more of both goods.
Yet, Sachin is indifferent C A
between B and C: U1 U4
He likes C as much as A
(both are on U4).
He likes A as much as B Quantity
of Food
(both are on U1).
FOUR PROPERTIES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES
Quantity
4. Indifference curves of Clothes
are bowed inward.
A
Sachin is willing to
give up more clothes 6
for one unit of Food if
1
he has few food (A)
B
than if he has many 2
(B). 1 U1
Quantity
of Food
THE MARGINAL RATE OF SUBSTITUTION
Marginal rate of
substitution (MRS): Quantity MRS = slope of
Maximum amount of a good that a consumer is of Clothes indifference curve
willing to give up in order to obtain one additional
unit of another good.
A
Sachin’s MRS is the amount of Clothes he would MRS = 6
substitute for another unit of food.
1
MRS falls as you move down along an indifference
B
curve.
MRS = 2
1 U1
Convexity : The decline in the MRS reflects a
diminishing marginal rate of substitution. When the Quantity
MRS diminishes along an indifference curve, the curve of Food
is convex.
SESSION 9: THEORY OF
CONSUMPTION
Chhavi Tiwari
THE MARGINAL RATE OF SUBSTITUTION
Marginal rate of
substitution (MRS): Quantity MRS = slope of
Maximum amount of a good that a consumer is of Clothes indifference curve
willing to give up in order to obtain one additional
unit of another good.
A
Sachin’s MRS is the amount of Clothes he would MRS = 6
substitute for another unit of food.
1
MRS falls as you move down along an indifference
B
curve.
MRS = 2
1 U1
Convexity : The decline in the MRS reflects a
diminishing marginal rate of substitution. When the Quantity
MRS diminishes along an indifference curve, the curve of Food
is convex.
UT I L I TY AND UT I L I TY FUNCT I ONS
Utility: Numerical score representing the satisfaction that a consumer gets from a given market
basket.
Utility function: Formula that assigns a level of utility to individual market baskets. 𝑈 = 𝑓(𝑥, 𝑦) ; [x= Food, y=
Clothes]
• 𝑈 = 𝑓(𝑥, 𝑦)
• Taking total differential,
𝜕𝑈 𝜕𝑈
𝑑𝑈 = 𝑑𝑥 + 𝑑𝑦
𝜕𝑥 𝜕𝑦
• On a given indifference curve, 𝑑𝑈 = 0
Marginal rate of
𝜕𝑈/𝜕𝑋 𝑀𝑈𝑥 substitution (MRS)
𝑑𝑦/𝑑𝑥 = − =−
𝜕𝑈/𝜕𝑌 𝑀𝑈𝑦
SPECIAL CASES
In (a), Bob views orange juice and In (b), Jane views left shoes and
apple juice as perfect substitutes: right shoes as perfect complements:
He is always indifferent between a An additional left shoe gives her no
glass of one and a glass of the extra satisfaction unless she also
other. obtains the matching right shoe.
SPECIAL CASES
Jon is always willing to trade one can of Coke for one can of Sprite, or one can of Sprite for one
can of Coke.
a. What can you say about Jon’s marginal rate of substitution?
Solution:
Jon’s marginal rate of substitution can be defined as the number of cans of Coke he would be
willing to give up in exchange for a can of Sprite. Since he is always willing to trade one for one, his
MRS is equal to 1.
a. Joe has convex preferences and dislikes both hamburgers and soft drinks.
b. Jane loves hamburgers and dislikes soft drinks. If she is served a soft drink, she will pour it
down the drain rather than drink it.
c. Bob loves hamburgers and dislikes soft drinks. If he is served a soft drink, he will drink it to be
polite.
d. Molly loves hamburgers and soft drinks, but insists on consuming exactly one soft drink for
every two hamburgers that she eats.
e. Bill likes hamburgers, but neither likes nor dislikes soft drinks.
f. Mary always gets twice as much satisfaction from an extra hamburger as she does from an
extra soft drink.
SESSION 10: BUDGET CONSTRAINT
Chhavi Tiwari
THE BUDGET CONSTRAINT:
WHAT THE CONSUMER CAN AFFORD
Sachin divides his income (M) between two goods (X and Y):
food (Good X) and clothes (Good Y).
• A “consumption bundle” is a particular combination of the goods, e.g., 40
food & 300 clothes.
• Budget constraint: the limit on the consumption bundles that a consumer
can afford
• Budget line: All combinations of goods for which the total amount of
money spent is equal to income
𝑃𝑋 𝑋 + 𝑃𝑌 𝑌 = 𝑀
BUDGET CONSTRAINT
Quantity of
From C to D, Clothes The slope of the
“rise” = M/ 𝑃𝑌 budget constraint
–200 clothes equals the relative
“run” = price of the good
+50 food on the X axis.
Slope = – 4 C
Sachin must
give up D
4 units of cloth
to get one unit of food.
The slope of the budget line:
𝑃𝑋
=−
𝑃𝑌
M/ 𝑃𝑋
Quantity
of Food
FACTORS THAT CAN IMPACT BUDGET LINES
Antonio buys five new college textbooks during his first year at school at a cost of $80 each. Used books cost
only $50 each. When the bookstore announces that there will be a 10% increase in the price of new books
and a 5% increase in the price of used books, Antonio’s father offers him $40 extra.
a. What happens to Antonio’s budget line? Illustrate the change with new books on the vertical axis.
Equilibrium condition
marginal
price of
value of
food (in
food(in
terms of
terms of 150 300 Quantity
clothes)
clothes) of Food
CH 3. EXERCISE 12
Ben allocates his lunch budget between two goods, pizza and burritos.
a. Illustrate Ben’s optimal bundle on a graph with pizza on the horizontal axis.
b. Suppose now that pizza is taxed, causing the price to increase by 20%. Illustrate Ben’s new
optimal bundle.
c. Suppose instead that pizza is rationed at a quantity less than Ben’s desired quantity. Illustrate
Ben’s new optimal bundle.
CH 3. EXERCISE 16
Julio receives utility from consuming food (F) and clothing (C) as given by the utility function U(F, C) =
FC. In addition, the price of food is $2 per unit, the price of clothing is $10 per unit, and Julio’s weekly
income is $50.
a. What is Julio’s marginal rate of substitution of food for clothing when utility is maximized? Explain.
Find the optimal bundle.
Solution:
Julio’s utility is maximized when his MRS (of food for clothing) equals PF/PC, the price ratio. The price
ratio is 2/10 = 0.2, so Julio’s MRS will equal 0.2 when his utility is maximized.
b. Suppose instead that Julio is consuming a bundle with more food and less clothing than his utility-
maximizing bundle. Would his marginal rate of substitution of food for clothing be greater than or less
than your answer in part a? Explain.
In absolute value terms, the slope of his indifference curve at this non-optimal bundle is less than the
slope of his budget line, because the indifference curve is flatter than the budget line. Therefore, his MRS
is less than the answer in part a.
CH 3. EXERCISE 16
Chhavi Tiwari
CH 3. EXERCISE 16
Julio receives utility from consuming food (F) and clothing (C) as given by the utility function U(F, C) =
FC. In addition, the price of food is $2 per unit, the price of clothing is $10 per unit, and Julio’s weekly
income is $50.
a. What is Julio’s marginal rate of substitution of food for clothing when utility is maximized? Explain.
Find the optimal bundle.
Solution:
Julio’s utility is maximized when his MRS (of food for clothing) equals PF/PC, the price ratio. The price
ratio is 2/10 = 0.2, so Julio’s MRS will equal 0.2 when his utility is maximized.
b. Suppose instead that Julio is consuming a bundle with more food and less clothing than his utility-
maximizing bundle. Would his marginal rate of substitution of food for clothing be greater than or less
than your answer in part a? Explain.
In absolute value terms, the slope of his indifference curve at this non-optimal bundle is less than the
slope of his budget line, because the indifference curve is flatter than the budget line. Therefore, his MRS
is less than the answer in part a.
CH 3. EXERCISE 16
Corner solution: Situation in which the marginal rate of substitution of one good for another in a chosen market
basket is not equal to the slope of the budget line.
Connie has a monthly income of $200 that she allocates among two goods: meat and potatoes.
a. Suppose meat costs $4 per pound and potatoes $2 per pound. Draw her budget constraint.
Solution:
Let M = meat and P = potatoes. Connie’s budget constraint is 4M + 2P = 200, or M = 50 − 0.5P.
Slope of the budget line : if meat is plotted on the x axis; 𝑃𝑀 Τ𝑃𝑃 = 4/2 = 2
b. Suppose also that her utility function is given by the equation U(M, P) = 2M + P. What combination of meat and potatoes
should she buy to maximize her utility?
Solution:
𝑴𝑼𝑴 = 𝟐, 𝑴𝑼𝑷 = 𝟏
Slope of the indifference curve= 2
Slope of the IC= Slope of the Budget line
The indifference curve coincides with her budget constraint. Any combination of meat and potatoes along this line will
provide her with maximum utility.
PROBLEM: CH. 3 PROB. 14
c. Connie’s supermarket has a special promotion. If she buys 20 pounds of potatoes (at $2 per pound), she gets the
next 10 pounds for free. This offer applies only to the first 20 pounds she buys. All potatoes in excess of the first 20
pounds (excluding bonus potatoes) are still $2 per pound. Draw her budget constraint.
Solution: Connie’s budget constraint has a slope of -1/2 until Connie has purchased 20 pounds of potatoes. Then her
budget line is flat from 20 to 30 pounds of potatoes, because the next 10 pounds of potatoes are free, and she does
not have to give up any meat to get these extra potatoes. After 30 pounds of potatoes, the slope of her budget line
becomes -1/2 again until it intercepts the potato axis at 110.
PROBLEM: CH. 3 PROB. 14
d. An outbreak of potato rot raises the price of potatoes to $4 per pound. The supermarket ends its promotion.
What does her budget constraint look like now? What combination of meat and potatoes maximizes her utility?
Solution: New Budget Constraint
4M + 4P = 200
𝑃𝑀 Τ𝑃𝑃 = 1
Connie may buy either 50 pounds of meat or 50 pounds of potatoes, or any combination in between.
Slope of the indifference curve= 2
Slope of the Budget Line = 1
Corner solution at 50 pounds of meat.
Session 12: Production
Chhavi Tiwari
Production Theory
𝑄 = 𝑓(𝐿, 𝐾)
• Variable input
• An input for which the level of usage may be changed quite readily
• Fixed input
• An input for which the level of usage cannot readily be changed,
and which must be paid even if no output is produced
Basic concepts of Production Theory
• Short run
• At least one input is fixed
• All changes in output achieved by changing usage of variable
inputs
• Long run
• All inputs are variable
• Output changed by varying usage of all inputs
Short Run Production with one variable input
• As the company adds workers, the average worker has less capital to
work with and will be less productive.
limiting. Panel B
L1 L2
Marginal
product
Exercise 1, Chapter 6
The menu at Joe’s coffee shop consists of a variety of coffee drinks,
pastries, and sandwiches. The marginal product of an additional worker
can be defined as the number of customers who can be served by that
worker in a given time period. Joe has been employing one worker, but
is considering hiring a second and a third. Explain why the marginal
product of the second and third workers might be higher than the first.
Why might you expect the marginal product of additional workers to
diminish eventually?
Session 13: Long run
Production
Chhavi Tiwari
Long run Production Function
• In the long run, all inputs are variable & isoquants are used to
study production decisions
• The MRTS is the slope of an isoquant & measures the rate at which the
two inputs can be substituted for one another while maintaining a
constant level of output
K
MRTS = −
L
• The MRTS can also be expressed as the ratio of two marginal products:
MPL
MRTS =
MPK
Slope of the Isoquant
𝑄 = 𝑓(𝐿, 𝐾)
Taking total differential,
𝜕𝑄 𝜕𝑄
𝑑𝑄 = . 𝑑𝐿 + . 𝑑𝐾
𝜕𝐿 𝜕𝐾
On a given isoquant, 𝑑𝑄 = 0,
𝜕𝑄ൗ
𝑑𝐾 𝜕𝐿 = − 𝑀𝑃𝐿
=−
𝑑𝐿 𝜕𝑄ൗ 𝑀𝑃𝐾
𝜕𝐾
𝑀𝑃𝐿
𝑀𝑅𝑇𝑆𝐿𝐾 =−
𝑀𝑃𝐾
Two special cases of Isoquants
Perfect complements or fixed proportion Inputs are perfect substitute. 𝑄 = 𝑎𝐿 + 𝑏𝐾, 𝑎 >
𝐿 𝐾
production function. 𝑄 = min ,
𝑎 𝑏
, 𝑎 > 0, 𝑏 > 0, 𝑏 > 0.
0
Problem: Chapter 6, Exercise 7
50 1
=
𝑀𝑃𝐾 4
𝐶 𝑤
𝐾= − 𝐿
𝑟 𝑟
𝐶
• Intercept represents amount of capital that may be purchased if zero labor is purchased.
𝑟
𝑤
• Slope of an Isocost curve is the negative of the input price −( 𝑟 ), which is the ratio of the wage
• Equilibrium condition
• Two slopes are equal in equilibrium
• Implies marginal product per rupee spent on last unit of each input is
the same.
• In short-run, cost of
production may not
be minimized.
Problem 16. Ch.7
Suppose that a paving company produces paved parking spaces (q) using a fixed quantity of land (T) and
variable quantities of cement C and labor (L). The firm is currently paving 1000 parking spaces. The
firm’s cost of cement is $4,000 per acre covered and its cost of labor is $12/hour. For the quantities of C
and L that the firm has chosen MPC = 50 and MPL = 4.
a. Is this firm minimizing its cost of producing parking spaces? How do you know?
Solution: To minimize its cost of production, the firm should produce where 𝑀𝑃𝐶 /𝑃𝐶 = 𝑀𝑃𝐿 /𝑃𝐿 . For this
firm, 𝑀𝑃𝐶 /𝑃𝐶 = 50/4000 = 0.0125 and 𝑀𝑃𝐿 /𝑃𝐿 = 4/12 = 0.333. Since 𝑀𝑃𝐶 /𝑃𝐶 is not equal to 𝑀𝑃𝐿 /𝑃𝐿 , the
firm is not minimizing its cost of producing parking spaces.
b. If the firm is not cost-minimizing, how must it alter its choices of C and L in order to decrease cost?
Solution: Since 𝑀𝑃𝐿 /𝑃𝐿 is much greater than 𝑀𝑃𝐶 /𝑃𝐶 , the additional output per dollar is much greater for
labor than for cement, so the firm should use relatively more L and less C in its production process.
Session 14: Theory of
costs
Chhavi Tiwari
A recap of theory of production
Costs: Explicit vs. Implicit
• Explicit costs require an outlay of money,
e.g., paying wages to workers.
• Implicit costs do not require a cash outlay,
e.g., the opportunity cost of the owner’s time.
• This is true whether the costs are implicit or explicit. Both matter for
firms’ decisions.
Opportunity Cost
Cost of best alternative. Whatever
must be given to obtain something
Examples:
The opportunity cost of…
…going to college for a year is
not just the tuition, books,
and fees, but also the
foregone wages.
…seeing a movie is not just the
price of the ticket,
but the value of the time you
spend in the theater.
Economic cost vs. Accounting cost
• Fixed costs (FC) do not vary with the quantity of output produced.
• For our example, FC = 1000 for renting plants
• Other examples:
cost of equipment, loan payments, rent
• Fixed cost versus Sunk Cost?
• Sunk cost: Expenditure that has been made and cannot be recovered.
• Variable costs (VC) vary with the quantity produced.
• For our example, VC = cost of material
• Short run total cost = Total fixed cost +Total variable cost
Costs
2 100 120 220
$ 400
3 100 160 260
$ 300
4 100 210 310
$ 200
5 100 280 380
$ 100
6 100 380 480
$0
7 100 520 620 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Q
Average Costs
• Marginal Cost (MC) is the increase in Total Cost from producing one more unit:
Δ𝑇𝐶
𝑀𝐶 =
Δ𝑄
EXAMPLE : Marginal Cost
Q TC MC Recall,
$200 Marginal Cost (MC)
is the
$175change in total cost from
0 $100
$70 producing one more unit:
$150
1 170
50 $125
∆TC
MC =
Costs
2 220 ∆Q
40 $100
3 260 Usually, MC rises as Q rises, due
50 $75
to diminishing marginal product.
4 310 $50
70 Sometimes (as here), MC falls
5 380 $25
100 before rising.
6 480 $0
140 (In other0examples,
1 2 3 MC 4 may
5 be
6 7
7 620 constant.) Q
Why MC is important?
Costs
AVC
$100
AFC
MC $75
$50
$25
$0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Q
Why ATC Is Usually U-Shaped
As Q rises: $200
Initially, $175
falling AFC $150
pulls ATC down. $125
Costs
Eventually, $100
rising AVC $75
pulls ATC up.
$50
Efficient scale: $25
The quantity that
$0
minimizes ATC. 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Q
ATC and MC
When MC < ATC, $200 ATC
ATC is falling. MC
$175
When MC > ATC, $150
ATC is rising. $125
Costs
The MC curve $100
crosses the $75
ATC curve at $50
the ATC curve’s
$25
minimum.
$0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Q
Session 15: Long run
costs
Chhavi Tiwari
True or False
• If the owner of a business pays himself no salary, then the accounting
cost is zero, but the economic cost is positive.
• A firm that has positive accounting profit does not necessarily have
positive economic profit.
• If a firm hires a currently unemployed worker, the opportunity cost of
utilizing the worker’s services is zero.
Short Run Average & Marginal Cost Curves
Because many decisions are fixed in the short run but variable in the long run, a firm’s long-run cost
curves differ from its short-run cost curves.
Costs in the long run
• Long-run total cost (LTC) for a given level of output is given by:
• 𝑳𝑻𝑪 = 𝒘𝑳 + 𝒓𝑲
• Where w & r are prices of labor & capital, respectively, & (L*, K*) is the input combination on the
expansion path that minimizes the total cost of producing that output
• Long-run average cost (LAC) measures the cost per unit of output when production can be adjusted so that
the optimal amount of each input is employed
• LAC is U-shaped
• Falling LAC indicates economies of scale
• Rising LAC indicates diseconomies of scale
𝐿𝑇𝐶
𝐿𝐴𝐶 =
𝑄
Long-Run Marginal Cost
• Long-run marginal cost (LMC) measures the rate of change in long-run total cost
as output changes along expansion path
• LMC is U-shaped
• LMC lies below LAC when LAC is falling
• LMC lies above LAC when LAC is rising
• LMC = LAC at the minimum value of LAC
∆𝐿𝑇𝐶
𝐿𝑀𝐶 =
∆𝑄
Derivation of a Long-Run Cost Schedule
Least-cost
combination of
Short-run
Long-run
Shut-down (if not covering Oligopoly Monopoly
VC) Entry (Profit) versus Exit
(Losses)
versus continue
Pricing Decisions
Chhavi Tiwari
Scenario
• Three years after graduating, you run your own business.
• You have forecasted your costs. Fixed and variable costs for the
next five years.
• Now you are wondering how much output you should produce in
the first year. How much price to charge?
• What factors should affect these decisions?
Your costs?
How much competition you face?
Type of Competition
Perfectly competitive markets
1. Many buyers and many sellers.
2. The goods offered for sale are largely the same. (Homogeneous products)
TR
• Average revenue (AR) AR = =P
Q
Price (Rupees)
Price (Rupees)
P0 P0
D = MR
0 Q0 0
Quantity Quantity
TotalProfit
revenue =$36 -x $11,400
= $21,600 600
==$21,600
$10,200
Profit cost
Total = $.3,150
= $17-x$5,100
300
= -1,950
= $5,100
TotalProfit
revenue =$36 -x $11,400
= $21,600 600
==$21,600
$10,200
Profit cost
Total = $.3,150
= $17-x$5,100
300
= -1,950
= $5,100
• Shut-Down Rule: The firm should shut down if the price of the product is
less than the average variable cost of production at the profit-maximizing
output.
• Cost of shutting down: revenue loss = TR
• Benefit of shutting down: cost savings = VC
(firm must still pay FC, FC becomes sunk cost in short-run)
• So, shut down if TR < VC
• Divide both sides by Q: TR/Q < VC/Q
• So, firm’s decision rule is:
• = ( P − ATC )Q
A Competitive Firm’s Short-run Supply Curve
The firm’s supply curve is the portion of the marginal cost curve for which marginal cost
is greater than average variable cost.
S2
Profit ATC B
P2 P2
A C
P1 P1
D2
D1
Q Q
Over time, profits induce entry, (firm) Q1 Q2 Q3 (market)
shifting S to the right, reducing P… …driving profits to zero
and restoring long-run eq’m.
The Zero-Profit Condition
• Long-run equilibrium:
The process of entry or exit is complete—
remaining firms earn zero economic profit.
• Zero economic profit occurs when P = ATC.
• Since firms produce where P = MR = MC,
the zero-profit condition is P = MC = ATC.
• Recall that MC intersects ATC at minimum ATC.
• Hence, in the long run, P = minimum ATC.
Why Do Firms Stay in Business
if Profit = 0?
• Recall, economic profit is revenue minus all costs, including implicit costs like
the opportunity cost of the owner’s time and money.
Assume that all firms are identical, and that the market is characterized by perfect
competition.
a. Find the equilibrium price, the equilibrium quantity, the output supplied by the
firm, and the profit of each firm.
Solution: Solve for equilibrium Price and quantity, P = $5, Q= 6000.
Individual firm output, P=MC, 5= 2q/200 so q= 500.
q2 5002
Profit is Total Revenue- Total Cost = = Pq − 722 + = 5(500) − 722 + = $528
200 200
since the total output in the market is 6000, and each firm’s output is 500, there must
be 6000/500 = 12 firms in the industry.
Exercise 10, Ch.8
b. Would you expect to see entry into or exit from the industry in the long run? Explain. What
effect will entry or exit have on market equilibrium?
c. What is the lowest price at which each firm would sell its output in the long run? Is profit
positive, negative, or zero at this price? Explain.
Solution: In the long run profit falls to zero, which means price falls to the minimum value of AC.
To find the minimum average cost, set marginal cost equal to average cost and solve for q:
2q 722 q
= +
200 q 200
q 722
=
200 q
q 2 = 722(200)
q = 380
AC (q = 380) = 3.8.
Therefore, the firm will not sell for any price less than $3.80 in the long run. The long-run
equilibrium price is therefore $3.80, and at a price of $3.80, each firm sells 380 units and earns
an economic profit of zero because P = AC.
Exercise 10, Ch.8
d. What is the lowest price at which each firm would sell its output in the
short run? Is profit positive, negative, or zero at this price? Explain.
• The firm will sell its output at any price above zero in the short run, because
marginal cost is above average variable cost (MC = q/100 > AVC = q/200) for all
positive prices. Profit is negative if price is just above zero.