How The World Became Rich - The Historical Origins of Economic Growth (2022)
How The World Became Rich - The Historical Origins of Economic Growth (2022)
How The World Became Rich - The Historical Origins of Economic Growth (2022)
1. Cover
2. Dedication
3. Title Page
4. Copyright
5. Preface
6. 1 Why, When, and How Did the World Become Rich?
1. What Is Economic Growth?
2. Measuring the Past
3. What Will You Learn from This Book?
4. What This Book Does Not Do
7. Part I Theories of How the World Became Rich
1. 2 Did Some Societies Win the Geography Lottery?
1. Geography and Modern Development
2. Mountains, Coasts, and Climate
3. Geography and Transport Infrastructure
4. Geography and Industrialization
5. Chapter Summary
2. 3 Is It All Just Institutions?
1. What Are Institutions?
2. Property Rights
3. The Legal System
4. Political Institutions
5. More Equal Rights for All
6. Institutions and the Commercial Revolution
7. Between the State and the Market: Guilds
8. Parliaments and Limited Government
9. War and State Finances
10. Chapter Summary
3. 4 Did Culture Make Some Rich and Others Poor?
1. What Is Culture and Why Does It Matter?
2. Can Culture Explain the European Take-off?
3. Does Religion Affect Economic Growth?
4. The Protestant Work Ethic and the “Spirit” of Capitalism
5. If Not a Work Ethic, Why Did Protestant Countries Grow
Faster?
6. The Reformation and Religion as a Source of Political
Legitimacy
7. Is Islam the Cause of Middle Eastern Economic Stagnation?
8. The Long-Term Persistence of Culture
9. The North–South Italy Divide
10. The Persistence of Trust Norms
11. Gender Norms
12. Chapter Summary
4. 5 Fewer Babies?
1. Malthusian Pressures
2. The Black Death
3. Household Formation and the European Marriage Pattern
4. Did the EMP Spur Economic Growth?
5. Reasons for Skepticism
6. Demographic Change and the Transition to Modern
Economic Growth
7. Chapter Summary
5. 6 Was It Just a Matter of Colonization and Exploitation?
1. How Did the Colonizers Benefit?
2. The Slave Trades
3. The Resource Grab
4. Some Silver Linings of Colonialism?
5. Public Goods and Education
6. Missionaries
7. Chapter Summary
8. Part II Why Some Parts of the World Became Rich First, Why Other
Parts Followed, and Why Some Are Not There Yet
1. 7 Why Did Northwestern Europe Become Rich First?
1. How Geography Shaped Institutional Development
2. Why Was There No Medieval European Take-off?
3. Divergence within Europe Just before the Take-off
4. Parliaments and the Rise of Limited, Representative
Government
5. Chapter Summary
2. 8 Britain’s Industrial Revolution
1. A Consumer Revolution
2. Capitalist Agriculture
3. Do Political Institutions Explain Britain’s Industrialization?
4. Mercantilism and Empire
5. Does the Transatlantic Slave Trade Explain Britain’s
Industrialization?
6. Was It Cotton?
7. Was It Market Size?
8. How About State Capacity?
9. Maybe It Was Skilled Mechanical Workers?
10. An Innovative Economy
11. High Wages and Induced Innovation
12. An Enlightened Economy
13. Chapter Summary
3. 9 The Rise of the Modern Economy
1. The Fruits of Industrialization
2. The Second Industrial Revolution
3. The Demographic Transition
4. The Uneven Diffusion of Modern Economic Growth
5. How the US Became Rich
6. The Soviet Detour
7. Chapter Summary
4. 10 Industrialization and the World It Created
1. Delayed Catch-up: The Shadow of Colonization (and Other
Factors)
2. How Japan Became Rich
3. How the East Asian Tigers Became Rich
4. How China Is Becoming Rich
5. Chapter Summary
5. 11 The World Is Rich
9. References
10. Index
11. End User License Agreement
List of Tables
1. Chapter 4
1. Table 4.1 Most populous cities in Western Eurasia, 800 CE
2. Chapter 5
1. Table 5.1 Black Death mortality by country
3. Chapter 6
1. Table 6.1 English crop yields, 18th century
4. Chapter 7
1. Table 7.1 British borrowing and interest rates, 1693–1739
5. Chapter 8
1. Table 8.1 Most populous English cities excluding London (with
populations of at least 10,0…
6. Chapter 9
1. Table 9.1 Major inventions of the Second Industrial Revolution
List of Illustrations
1. Chapter 1
1. Figure 1.1 Countries that were richer in 2018 (annual per capita
income) than the US in 190…
2. Figure 1.2 Countries that were richer in 2018 (annual per capita
income) than Great Britain…
3. Figure 1.3 People living in extreme poverty, 1820–2015
4. Figure 1.4 Year that per capita GDP exceeded $10 per day (2018
USD)
5. Figure 1.5 Yearly per capita income for selected regions, 1 CE–
present
6. Figure 1.6 US GDP per capita, 1720–2018 (2018 USD)
7. Figure 1.7 Ruggedness and income in African and non-African
countries
8. Figure 1.8 The reversal of fortunes within formerly colonized
nations, 1500–1995
2. Chapter 2
1. Figure 2.1 Coastlines of African countries
2. Figure 2.2 Africa’s “malaria belt”
3. Figure 2.3 Verticality and horizontality of the continents
4. Figure 2.4 Technology adoption levels in 1500 (% of frontier
technologies adopted)
5. Figure 2.5 Temperature deviations across Europe, 1100–1800
6. Figure 2.6 The Roman road network
7. Figure 2.7 The increase in turnpikes in England and Wales: 1680–
1830
8. Figure 2.8 Changes in US market access, 1870–90
9. Figure 2.9 Location of cities in England and France in the Roman
and medieval periods
10. Figure 2.10 The price of energy in the early 1700s
3. Chapter 3
1. Figure 3.1 Rule of law vs. per capita GDP
2. Figure 3.2 Night lights on the Korean Peninsula
3. Figure 3.3 Rule of law index, 2017
4. Figure 3.4 The first(?) formal legal system: the Code of
Hammurabi
5. Figure 3.5 Legal origins throughout the world
6. Figure 3.6 Polity score, 2017
7. Figure 3.7 Democracy score, 2017
8. Figure 3.8 Parliamentary activity in Europe, 1100–1800
9. Figure 3.9 Tax revenues per capita for six European powers,
1500–1900
10. Figure 3.10 Interest rates in city-states and territorial states, 1200–
1800
4. Chapter 4
1. Figure 4.1 Subcultures of the US
2. Figure 4.2 Percentage Protestant, Catholic, and Muslim vs. per
capita GDP
3. Figure 4.3 Percentage of Protestants vs. school enrollment rate in
early 19th-century Pruss…
4. Figure 4.4 Ruler duration in Western Europe and the Islamic
world
5. Figure 4.5 The north–south Italy divide: cousin marriage, trust,
and judicial efficiency
6. Figure 4.6 The relationship between trust and per capita GDP
7. Figure 4.7 Traditional plow use, female labor force participation,
and female firm ownershi…
5. Chapter 5
1. Figure 5.1 Life expectancy around the world, 2015
2. Figure 5.2 The Malthusian model
3. Figure 5.3 The Malthusian model: illustrating the effects of
reducing the birth rate
4. Figure 5.4 Black Death mortality rates (%) in 1347–52
5. Figure 5.5 Population and wages in England, 1209–1750
6. Figure 5.6 Fertility and female age of marriage in England,
1590s–1830s
6. Chapter 6
1. Figure 6.1 Countries colonized by Great Britain, France, Spain,
Portugal, the Netherlands, …
2. Figure 6.2 Number of slaves in the transatlantic slave trade by
carrier
3. Figure 6.3 Number of slaves taken in the slave trades
4. Figure 6.4 The relationship between slaves exported and
economic indicators
5. Figure 6.5 Africa’s ethnic boundaries prior to colonization
6. Figure 6.6 Settler mortality, institutions, and long-run
development
7. Figure 6.7 Agricultural investment in India
8. Figure 6.8 Ethnic partitioning and the “scramble for Africa”
9. Figure 6.9 The Indian railroad network, 1930
10. Figure 6.10 Modern literacy and proximity to Jesuit missions in
Argentina, Brazil, and Parag…
7. Chapter 7
1. Figure 7.1 The steppe and state formation in China and Europe
2. Figure 7.2 Real per capita GDP, 1450–1700, select countries
8. Chapter 8
1. Figure 8.1 GDP, GDP per capita, and population in
England/Britain, 1270–1870 (1700 = 100)
2. Figure 8.2 England and its largest cities, 1520–1801
3. Figure 8.3 The spinning jenny
4. Figure 8.4 Arkwright’s water frame
5. Figure 8.5 Crompton’s spinning mule
6. Figure 8.6 Schematic of the Newcomen steam engine
7. Figure 8.7 The Watt steam engine
8. Figure 8.8 Number of letters in Voltaire’s correspondence in the
Republic of Letters…
9. Chapter 9
1. Figure 9.1 GDP per capita and real wages in England/Great
Britain, 1270–1870 (1700 = 100)
2. Figure 9.2 Fertility and mortality in England, 1541–1839
3. Figure 9.3 Children born per woman in Western Europe and the
US, 1800–2000
4. Figure 9.4 Human capital and the demographic transition in
England, 1730–1890
5. Figure 9.5 Shares of world industrial output, 1750–1938
6. Figure 9.6 US population and immigrant share, 1850–2010
10. Chapter 10
1. Figure 10.1 Per capita GDP in select Asian countries, 1960–2019
2. Figure 10.2 Percentage of Indians living in extreme poverty,
1977–2011
3. Figure 10.3 Per capita GDP in England/Great Britain and Japan,
1280–1850
4. Figure 10.4 Per capita GDP in South Korea and Nigeria, 1960–
2019
5. Figure 10.5 Per capita GDP in various parts of the world, 1960–
2019
6. Figure 10.6 Chinese per capita GDP, 1960–2019
Dedication
Mark: For Desiree.
Jared: To my father, Thom, and the memory of my mother, Linda.
How the World Became Rich
The Historical Origins of Economic Growth
Mark Koyama
Jared Rubin
polity
Copyright © Mark Koyama and Jared Rubin 2022
The right of Mark Koyama and Jared Rubin to be identified as Author of this Work has been asserted
in accordance with the UK Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.
First published in 2022 by Polity Press
Polity Press
65 Bridge Street
Cambridge CB2 1UR, UK
Polity Press
101 Station Landing
Suite 300
Medford, MA 02155, USA
All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purpose of criticism and review,
no part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted, in any form
or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior
permission of the publisher.
ISBN-13: 978-1-5095-4024-2
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library.
Library of Congress Control Number: 2021944393
The publisher has used its best endeavours to ensure that the URLs for external websites referred to in
this book are correct and active at the time of going to press. However, the publisher has no
responsibility for the websites and can make no guarantee that a site will remain live or that the
content is or will remain appropriate.
Every effort has been made to trace all copyright holders, but if any have been overlooked the
publisher will be pleased to include any necessary credits in any subsequent reprint or edition.
For further information on Polity, visit our website:
politybooks.com
Preface
The world is rich, although it may not always seem like it. Poverty is still all
too prevalent. Approximately one billion people around the world barely
have enough to survive. The fate of millions of people living in poverty and
violence in places like Venezuela, Syria, Burundi, or the Democratic
Republic of Congo is deplorable. Even in the developed world, poverty is
far, far too common.
Yet, by historical standards, the world is very rich. Most people are much
better off than their ancestors were. In fact, most people living right now are
better off than almost every person who ever lived prior to two centuries ago
(save a very small fraction of elites who lived in luxury … or what was
considered luxury at the time). As the world has become richer in the 20th
and 21st centuries, more and more people have been lifted out of poverty.
And there is good reason to hope that, within our lifetimes, a significant
fraction of the remaining poverty around the world will be eliminated.
How did the world become rich? This is the question this book attempts to
answer. It is by no means easy to do so. In fact, there is almost certainly no
one correct answer! Yet, it remains perhaps the biggest question in the social
sciences. A proper understanding of why certain parts of the world have
become rich – and others have not (yet) – can help us tackle some of the
biggest problems facing us in the present. As you read this book, it will soon
become clear that there is no panacea to lift a country into riches. However,
there are many factors that historically tend to be present alongside sustained
economic growth. It is our goal to both highlight these factors and provide
insight into when they do and do not contribute to growth.
Throughout this book, we draw on an immense and fast-growing scholarship
in global economic history. The first half of our book is mostly meant to be
an overview of what we consider to be the leading theories for how the
world became rich. Our debts to this scholarship are evident throughout.
Naturally, as this book is addressed to a broad audience, we have not been
able to cite every piece of specialist research. We apologize in advance for
any omissions. We do, however, direct the reader towards the relevant
literature wherever possible.
Many people helped us along the way. We cannot possibly thank everyone
without this Preface taking up half the book. Sascha Becker, Desiree
Desierto, Anton Howes, Nathan Nunn, Tuan-Hwee Sng, Felipe Valencia
Caicedo, and John Wallis read parts (or all!) of the book. Their insightful
comments helped us significantly improve the manuscript. Our editor at
Polity, George Owers, gave excellent guidance at each step of the process.
Dan Bogart, Dave Donaldson, Erik Hornung, Noel Johnson, and Jonathan
Schulz shared their data files so that we could produce some of the figures in
this book. Mark thanks his many coauthors, from whom he has learned a
tremendous amount over the years. Jared will always be indebted to Avner
Greif, Timur Kuran, Larry Iannaccone, and Ran Abramitzky – the best
mentors, coauthors, and friends he could hope for.
Much of this book was written while we were quarantined on opposite coasts
of the US due to COVID-19. We would like to thank the people who helped
us get through that time – without them, this book would not be possible.
For Mark, these include his wife and frequent collaborator Desiree, his
parents Ninette and Noboru, and his brother Jonathan. For Jared, these
include his family – Thom, Debbie, and Tyler Rubin and Samantha and Ryan
Sully – and friends Rob Ainsley, Ted Chang, Doug Haney, Matt Menefee,
Travis Menefee, Scott Shumate, and JJ Singh. Most of all, Jared is indebted
to his amazing wife Tina and their two beautiful children, Nadia and Sasha.
1
Why, When, and How Did the World
Become Rich?
The world is rich. Certainly, some parts of the world are richer than others,
and many millions still live in poverty. But the world is richer than it has
ever been, and it continues to grow richer with each passing day.
Don’t believe us? Let’s compare income around the world today to some of
the wealthiest countries in the past. Figure 1.1 maps all of the countries with
greater per capita income in 2018 than the wealthiest country in the world in
1900: the United States. The average income in much of the world is now
greater than the average income in the world’s richest country just over a
century ago. The startling level of modern wealth comes into even clearer
focus when compared to the wealthiest country in 1800: Great Britain (see
Figure 1.2). Almost every nation in the world, with some exceptions, mostly
in sub-Saharan Africa, has a greater average income than the world’s leading
economy just two centuries ago.
Modern wealth of course extends well beyond average incomes. Even in
many of the poorest parts of the world, we have luxuries that our ancestors
could have only dreamed of. Forget about smartphones and flat-screen TVs
– even our richest ancestors would have been jealous of our indoor
plumbing, electricity, vaccinations, low child mortality, and long life
expectancy.
Figure 1.1 Countries that were richer in 2018 (annual per capita income)
than the US in 1900
Data source: Bolt and van Zanden (2020). Average income in the US in 1900 was $8,970 in
2011 USD.
Figure 1.2 Countries that were richer in 2018 (annual per capita income)
than Great Britain in 1800
Data source: Bolt and van Zanden (2020). Average income in Great Britain in 1800 was $3,731
in 2011 USD.
Think about it: would you trade your current life for the life of a wealthy
English baron in, say, 1200? Sure, you would have servants, and you’d have
the social and political benefits that come with being a member of the upper
crust. But you would also live in a drafty, uncomfortable castle, and you
would likely have multiple children die in infancy. And let’s hope you didn’t
get a bad bout of diarrhea (you probably wouldn’t survive). If you didn’t die
young on the battlefield, odds are you would die of some now-curable
disease such as dysentery (which killed English kings John [r. 1199–1216]
and Henry V [r. 1413–22]), smallpox (which killed French king Louis XV [r.
1715–74] and English queen Mary II [r. 1689–94]), or plague. Some of us
might trade our current lot for that of the baron, but many of us (including
the authors of this book) would not.
We are not heartless. There is still a tremendous amount of extreme poverty
in the world. We appreciate that the entire world is not actually “rich” by
current or historical standards. But the fact of the matter is that extreme
poverty is in rapid decline. This decline began two centuries ago and it has
accelerated in recent decades. The trends, summarized in Figure 1.3, are
striking. Just two centuries ago, 94% of the world lived on less than $2 a day
(in 2016 prices), and 84% lived on less than $1 a day. By 2015, less than
10% of the world lived on less than $1.90 a day, and that number continues
to decline. To be clear, 10% of the world is still a lot of people. But as the
world continues to become richer, that number will dwindle all the more.
It’s not just that there has been a reduction in absolute poverty as the world
has grown wealthier. More and more of the world has moved further from
the edge of subsistence in the last century. Take, for instance, the relatively
arbitrary milestone of $10 per day in 2018 USD. This is not much: $3,650
per year is hardly a king’s ransom. However, in most economies it is more
than enough to afford the basics of life (food, shelter, clothing, etc.). This is
even more true in relatively poor countries, where modest housing and food
can be had cheaply. Figure 1.4 shows when each country reached this
milestone. It represents a level of security unknown throughout most of
human history.
Figure 1.3 People living in extreme poverty, 1820–2015
Data source: Roser (2021c). For the sake of this figure, extreme poverty is defined as less than
$1.90 per day.
How did the world become rich? Why are some so rich and others so poor?
This book provides some answers to these questions. The answers are by no
means obvious, and they are the subject of much debate among economists,
historians, and other academics. This is reflective of just how important the
questions are. To alleviate poverty, we must understand wealth. We still do
not have all the answers, but enough strides have been made that we can
dedicate a book to answering the question: “What do we know about how
the world became rich?”
What Is Economic Growth?
Throughout most of world history, a vast majority of the world’s population
– well above 90% – was poor. Whether your ancestors are from China, India,
Africa, Europe, the Middle East, or elsewhere, the odds are very high that
most of them lived on little more than a few dollars a day. That is clearly no
longer the case. As shown in Figure 1.3, the proportion of the world’s
population living in extreme poverty has dropped precipitously in the last
two centuries. Most of the readers of this book likely live in some level of
comfort, and even our poorest readers would be the envy of their ancestors.
After all, they can read! How did the world get to this point?
Figure 1.4 Year that per capita GDP exceeded $10 per day (2018 USD)
Data source: Bolt and van Zanden (2020). Italy reached $10/day sporadically in the 15th
century.
On the surface, the answer to this question is simple: the last two centuries
have seen more economic growth than the rest of human history combined.
Economic growth refers to a sustained increase in economic prosperity as
measured by the total goods and services produced in the economy
(commonly referred to as gross domestic product, or GDP). We care about
economic growth not because it is an end in itself, but because it is the key
to alleviating the type of poverty experienced by almost everyone who lived
prior to 1800, and that still plagues way too large of a share of the world’s
population today.
Our focus on economic growth does not mean that we don’t value other
aspects of human development. Leisure time, long life, good health, literacy,
education, female empowerment, and rights and protections for the
vulnerable are all central to having a happy and fair society. That said, we
hope to convince you by the end of this book that all of these features are
made possible by economic growth. It is no coincidence that the last 200
years have seen dramatic strides in those very aspects of human
development. Even though there is clearly a long way to go to achieve the
type of society that most of us want, economic growth will be a key part of
the solution.
Economic growth on its own is not necessarily a panacea. It can be
accompanied by environmental degradation, increased inequality, or
worsening health outcomes. For instance, air quality declined and life
expectancy fell during the British Industrial Revolution. Today, issues such
as climate change and social polarization are among the most important
challenges that policy-makers face. The point that deserves emphasis here is
that economic growth makes available the resources and the new
technologies needed to tackle these important challenges. Of course,
humanity actually needs to employ these resources to address these
challenges. But in the absence of economic growth, we may not have such
an opportunity.
It is a mistake to think that we necessarily have to choose between economic
growth and other values (such as preserving the environment). For example,
a more unstable climate poses potentially catastrophic risks to our society.
Yet, we’ve seen in recent years that measures to reduce carbon emissions can
be accompanied by economic growth. The UK, for example, saw carbon
emissions fall by 38% between 1990 and 2017, from 600 million tonnes to
367 million tonnes (Hausfather, 2019). Meanwhile, total GDP (adjusted for
inflation) increased by over 60% in the same period.
Nor do we necessarily have to choose between economic growth and a fairer
society. In fact, a lack of economic growth has serious moral downsides.
Historically, it is in stagnant or declining economies that one observes the
worst episodes of violence, intolerance, and political polarization. On the
other hand, social mobility and greater equality of opportunity are much
more likely in an economy that is growing. As Friedman (2005, p. 86) puts
it, stagnant economies “do not breed support for economic mobility, or for
openness of opportunity more generally.”
So, how has the world economy grown over time? Figure 1.5 gives some
rough estimates of per capita GDP in the world’s most populous regions
since the birth of Christ. While these numbers are admittedly speculative –
and likely more volatile prior to the 18th century than the figure suggests –
the pattern is clear (and uncontroversial). Prior to the 19th century, the
wealthiest region in the world never reached more than $4 a day average (in
2011 USD). Throughout most of world history, $2–3 a day was the norm.
Yes, there were fabulously wealthy people, and these societies produced
some of the greatest art, architecture, and literature the world has known
(pursuits not generally associated with people on the brink of starvation).
These artists and authors are the people from the past you may be the most
familiar with, since they are the ones who generally fill our history books.
But this was not the lot of almost the entirety of humanity prior to the 19th
century. The fact is that most people who ever lived – at least, prior to the
20th century – lived in conditions very similar to those of the very poorest in
the world today. The economic growth of the last two centuries has
alleviated a vast majority of this poverty, although the job is clearly not
finished.
Figure 1.5 Yearly per capita income for selected regions, 1 CE–present
Data source: Bolt, Inklaar, de Jong, and van Zanden (2018).
In the final chapters, we assess the relative strengths and weaknesses of the
major arguments and lay out the ones we find the most convincing. Our
focus shifts to Britain, the home of the Industrial Revolution, and ultimately
the first country to achieve modern, sustained economic growth. We ask,
“What were the preconditions that made sustained economic growth possible
in northwestern Europe?” We then address the flip-side of this question:
“Why did sustained economic growth not first happen elsewhere?” Next we
delve into the Industrial Revolution itself, as well as its connection to
sustained economic growth. We explore what we find to be the most
convincing explanations of its causes, linking these back to the broader
sources of sustained, long-run economic growth.
The first set of explanations that we prefer – both for the onset of
industrialization and for modern economic growth – emphasize the link
between economic and political development. Such explanations touch on
topics like institutional change, the growth of state capacity, and the rule of
law. In our reading of the literature and of history, we find it difficult to tell a
compelling story of long-run economic growth while ignoring the role that
political institutions played in encouraging or (more often than not)
dampening economic growth.
The second set of explanations that we find convincing are those that
highlight the role of culture. To be clear, we do not mean the type of
Eurocentric explanations popular in the early 20th century that made claims
regarding the supremacy of some aspect of European culture. We mean
culture in the way cultural anthropologists use the term: those heuristics
employed by people to interpret the complex world around them (Cavalli-
Sforza and Feldman, 1981; Boyd and Richerson, 1985; Henrich, 2015).
Recent scholarship demonstrates that culture is amenable to serious social
scientific study. Several insights can be gleaned from this line of research.
First, cultural values can be extremely persistent (Guiso, Sapienza, and
Zingales, 2006; Nunn, 2012). Second, cultural values interact with
institutional development (Greif, 1994, 2006; Alesina and Giuliano, 2015;
Bisin and Verdier, 2017).
In the penultimate chapter, we consider the “Great Convergence” between
the many parts of the rest of the world and the West. One of the great stories
of the last half-century is the billions of people pulled out of abject poverty.
China has been a huge source of this economic progress, but so have many
parts of South Asia, Southeast Asia, and Latin America. As we write this
book, another half a billion or so people in India seem on the brink of
escaping absolute poverty. In fact, the last twenty years have been
characterized by faster economic growth in poor countries than in rich
countries (Patel, Sandefur, and Subramanian, 2021). The time horizon might
be a little longer for sub-Saharan Africa and the poorest countries in Latin
America and Central Asia, but there is reason to be optimistic that we will
experience a further dramatic eradication of poverty in those regions in our
lifetime. All of this would be impossible without economic growth.
Just because we find some explanations for how the world became rich more
compelling than others does not mean that the other theories have little
merit. In fact, we believe there are important insights in all of the theories
outlined in this book. In the end, we need to remember that an issue as wide-
ranging as “how the world became rich” almost certainly has many causes.
Intelligent people can and will disagree on what weight to put on each of
these causes. What matters most is understanding the conditions under
which certain causes are important and the conditions under which they are
not. It is our hope that this book will provide a better understanding of these
conditions.
What This Book Does Not Do
For all we are attempting to accomplish with this book, we want to be clear
about a few things we will not do. First, our goal is to present all of the
major arguments on “how the world got rich” in a fair-minded fashion. This
means that, when initially presenting the theories, we will do our best to not
let our own biases creep in. We certainly have views on the various issues
presented in the book, and we do think that some views are more convincing
than others. The later chapters of the book lay out the reasons we believe
some of the proposed causes in the literature have greater explanatory power
than others. However, we aim to give each of the main explanations a fair
shake and present them, to the best of our ability, the way that the authors of
the theories would want them presented.
This book is thematic and conceptual. We elucidate the major themes
running through the academic literature and contextualize them in a
digestible manner. As such, we won’t present a comprehensive economic
history of specific countries. Such histories can be extremely valuable. In
some cases, they shed light on important aspects of the origins of economic
growth. We pay particular attention to developments in Great Britain in the
18th and 19th centuries. But this is simply due to the fact that we are seeking
to understand the origins of modern, sustained growth, and Great Britain was
the locus of the first modern economy. We also pay attention to places that
failed to be the center of the first modern economy – despite a head start
relative to Western Europe – such as China and the Middle East. We do not
provide a deep dive into the specifics of the economic histories of these
regions. Instead, we selectively choose various aspects of their histories to
help substantiate theories espoused in the literature.
Finally, we do not spend much time discussing the drawbacks to economic
growth such as pollution, climate change, and the capacity to create deadly
weapons. We are by no means denying the importance of these topics, but
these issues are simply outside the scope of this book. We have written a
book on the origins of modern economic growth. While we believe
economic growth in general to be a good thing, the focus here is on what
caused economic growth, not its consequences.
Part I
Theories of How the World Became
Rich
2
Did Some Societies Win the Geography
Lottery?
Does geography determine the fate of nations? Is the key to unlocking riches
preordained by factors like climate, natural resources, soil quality, and
access to the ocean? Geographic explanations have long been a favorite of
thinkers looking for reasons why their society pulled ahead. According to the
Muslim Andalusian thinker Abū al-Qāsim Sā’id (1068): “The exceeding
distance [of Northern Europeans] from the sun thickens the air making their
dispositions cold, their natures rude, their skin color white and their hair
straight. Thus … dullness and ignorance overpower them” (quoted in
Chaney, 2008, p. 2). On the other hand, in Book XIV of The Spirit of the
Laws, the French philosopher Montesquieu made a similar argument but
drew an opposite conclusion:
People are … more vigorous in cold climates…. The inhabitants of
warm countries are, like old men, timorous; the people in cold countries
are, like young men, brave. If we reflect on the late wars … we shall
find that the northern people, transplanted into southern regions, did not
perform such exploits as their countrymen who, fighting in their own
climate, possessed their full vigor and courage. (Montesquieu,
1748/1989, p. 317)
Modern scholars have also argued that geography and climate play a crucial
role in explaining patterns of economic development. Perhaps the most well-
known insights are those of Diamond (1997), who argues that factors like
the relative length of continental axis, the disease environment, proximity to
the equator, and access to coasts and rivers had a tremendous influence on
long-run economic prosperity. We discuss Diamond’s influential hypothesis
in depth in this chapter.
But is geography fate? Are locations with “good” characteristics destined to
be more developed? Davis and Weinstein’s (2002) seminal study of Japanese
urban development in the aftermath of World War II provides evidence for
the importance of geographic fundamentals. The authors examined what
happened to the distribution of urban centers after the destruction of
Hiroshima and Nagasaki by the atomic bomb. They show that after
experiencing complete destruction, both Hiroshima and Nagasaki returned to
the same relative positions in Japan’s distribution of cities within twenty
years. This suggests that a major shock to the distribution of population was
insufficient to overcome the intrinsic geographic advantages of these two
locations. Whether such findings are generalizable is something we will
discuss throughout the book.
What about the Industrial Revolution? Britain’s position as a large island off
the coast of Europe, endowed with a moderate climate, numerous rivers, and
a long coastline, helped shape the formation of its political institutions.
Abundant coal resources played an important role in its early
industrialization. It is worth asking: could this be why Britain industrialized
first?
Geography and Modern Development
Geography matters for economic development today, especially in the
poorest parts of the world. For instance, many countries in sub-Saharan
Africa are landlocked, and most others have only a small amount of coast
(see Figure 2.1). Without coastlines, they are unable to directly ship goods to
other countries. They also have to rely on expensive and hard-to-maintain
road and rail networks which can easily be blocked or cut off by their
neighbors.
Figure 2.1 Coastlines of African countries
Coast length data from: CIA (2019).
Figure 2.2 Africa’s “malaria belt”
Data source: Hay, Guerra, Gething, Patil, Tatem, Noor, et al. (2009).
Another important geographic factor is disease burden. Countries in the
“malaria belt” in sub-Saharan Africa continue to be underdeveloped (see
Figure 2.2). Malaria has probably killed more human beings over the course
of human history than any other disease. But the burden of malaria is also
economic. All else being equal, countries where a high proportion of the
population are infected with malaria had growth rates that were around 1.3%
lower than other countries (Sachs and Malaney, 2002). They also have
higher infant mortality and lower investment in physical and human capital.
Other diseases are also endemic in sub-Saharan Africa. One particularly
potent disease is sleeping sickness, which the tsetse fly transmits via
parasites. The effects of the tsetse fly are not limited to humans. The same
parasite causes nagnana, which is deadly to livestock. Livestock played a
crucial role in agricultural development in other parts of the world. People in
regions affected by the tsetse fly were historically much less likely to
domesticate livestock. Alsan (2015) documents how in these parts of sub-
Saharan Africa, intensive agriculture was less likely to develop, the plow
was less likely to be employed, and large domesticated animals were rarer.
These patterns of economic underdevelopment also had political
consequences, as they made it less likely for centralized states to develop.
These examples point to the attractions and limitations of arguments based
on geography. On the one hand, geography-based arguments are simple and
geography has the advantage of being largely exogenous. This means that it
is not affected by other variables of interest. As such, we don’t have to worry
about geography being the result of other factors that are also important for
economic growth, such as culture or institutions. Hence, geographic
explanations can potentially provide a straightforward explanation of
economic growth and poverty.
The big problem with geographic explanations, however, is that geography
is largely unchanging. Geography is not completely static, of course. For
instance, fisheries can be over-fished, and this encourages societies to adapt
accordingly (Ostrom, 1990; Dalgaard, Knudsen, and Selaya, 2020). And
natural resources are generally not just there for the taking – finding them
requires exploration and the capacity to extract (David and Wright, 1997).
But geography is much less malleable than other societal features such as
demography, institutions, or culture. This can be a problem for explanations
linking geography to long-run economic growth, because many of the
differences in incomes that we observe across the world today have changed
dramatically over time. In 1750, the richest country in the world (per capita)
was probably the Dutch Republic. Yet, it was only at most four times richer
than the poorest countries in the world. Today the richest countries in the
world are between one hundred and two hundred times richer in terms of
measured GDP per capita. More perplexing still, geography has a difficult
time explaining economic reversals. As it is mostly fixed, it cannot easily
explain why the Middle East was much more developed in 1000 than
Western Europe yet by 1800 Western Europe was far ahead of the Middle
East.
Guns, Germs, and Steel
In his Pulitzer Prize-winning book Guns, Germs, and Steel, Diamond (1997)
asked why it was that Europeans were able to conquer the New World so
easily. How was it that they had not only superior weapons and technology
but also more deadly germs than the native inhabitants of the Americas? His
answer was geography. To explain why Eurasian societies were more
technologically advanced, he drew on the work of Crosby (1986), who
argued that the relative height and length of the Eurasian, African, and
American continents had a deep impact on long-run development. Vertically
aligned continents contain numerous microclimates, which limit the spread
of crops, domesticated animals, and people. After all, crops suitable for rain
forests are unlikely to grow in the savannah or mountains. So, the
domesticated plants and animals of Mesoamerica did not spread to Peru or
the Amazon basin. Perhaps more importantly, technology and knowledge
spread more easily horizontally than vertically, since climatic characteristics
vary less. The “verticality” of the Americas and Africa south of the Sahara
(see Figure 2.3) may have therefore imposed huge hurdles to long-run
economic growth.
Figure 2.3 Verticality and horizontality of the continents
Reproduced using map in Diamond (1997). Gall-Peters map projection.
This, according to Diamond, was why the Near East was the birthplace of
human civilization. It was in the Near East that wheat, barley, and the pea
were first cultivated. The rich fertile plains between the Tigris and Euphrates
rivers were surrounded on several sides by so-called “hilly flanks.” Goats
and sheep were first domesticated 11,000 years ago in the hills of northern
Syria and northern Mesopotamia. Pigs and cattle followed soon afterwards
and spread throughout the Fertile Crescent. In total, thirty-three of the
world’s fifty-six heaviest wild grasses originated in either Europe, the Near
East, or North Africa. The majority of these crops were first domesticated in
the Fertile Crescent. Moderate climatic differences between Europe and the
Middle East ensured that agricultural techniques could spread between the
two.
Of the fourteen species of large domesticable animals, only one, and perhaps
the least useful – the llama – originated in the New World. Nine of the
world’s fourteen large domesticable herbivores originated in Eurasia. This
left inhabitants of the New World at a decided economic disadvantage.
Livestock are a tremendous source of both animal power and protein. But
domesticated animals are also a source of epidemic disease. The absence of
large domesticable animals left New Worlders particularly vulnerable to new
diseases. Because interactions between humans and animals are a major
source of epidemic disease, human populations which have a long history of
exposure to these diseases are more likely to acquire immunity. This is why
contact with Europeans was so deadly for Native Americans. Recent
estimates suggest there was a 95–98% drop in the Native American
population between its pre-1492 peak and 1900 (Mann, 2005).
Figure 2.4 Technology adoption levels in 1500 (% of frontier technologies
adopted)
Data source: Pavlik and Young (2019).
The downturn in the climate that occurred in the late Middle Ages had real
economic consequences. For one, it impacted city growth rates (Waldinger,
2019). Worsening climatic conditions generated political instability across
Eurasia (Parker, 2014). The climate downturn also made minority
communities like Jews more vulnerable to persecution. As entrenched
antisemitic attitudes were common across Europe, Jews were frequently
scapegoated for economic ills and political crises. Unusually cold weather
increased the probability that a city would persecute its Jewish community
by as much as 50% (Anderson, Johnson, and Koyama, 2017).
Colder weather associated with the Little Ice Age affected war and conflict
more generally. Using geo-coded battle locations, Iyigun, Nunn, and Qian
(2017) find that colder weather was associated with more conflict between
1400 and 1900. These effects were stronger in areas with worse-quality soil
and regions that were already cold in 1400. Nevertheless, despite colder
weather, it was in these centuries that the seeds of modern economic growth
were sown. This raises the question: how can geographic and climatic
constraints be overcome?
Geography and Transport Infrastructure
Can investment in transport infrastructure overcome the curse of geography?
It seems possible. The Trans-Siberian Railway brought harsh terrain in
contact with markets and goods to a degree previously unimaginable. But
can transport infrastructure fully overcome the curse of bad geography or
just ameliorate it?
Infrastructure projects can be financed by private individuals or by the state.
But why do some institutional arrangements facilitate private investment in
infrastructure while others deter it? Why do some states invest and others do
not? When are states even capable of undertaking such projects in the first
place? These questions suggest that overcoming “bad” geography may
require institutions capable of diverting resources to infrastructure. Although
we will return to this issue in Chapter 7, we outline here some of the ways
that investments in transport infrastructure affected historical economic
development.
The Roman Empire invested in a road system. By the reign of the Emperor
Trajan (r. 97–117 CE), the road network comprised 80,000 km (see Figure
2.6). It was complemented by massive inland waterways that crisscrossed
the empire and connected landlocked cities with the Roman lake that was the
Mediterranean Sea. The Roman road system was built for military reasons.
But once established, it played a crucial role in knitting the empire together
economically and culturally. The suppression of Mediterranean piracy and
the establishment of safe sea-lanes was also critical in lowering transport
costs, which enabled inter-regional trade and specialization. Archaeological
evidence attests to the fact that manufactured goods such as amphorae
(pottery) were mass produced and transported over long distances.
Figure 2.6 The Roman road network
Map provided by Erik Hornung from Flückiger, Hornung, Larch, Ludwig, and Mees
(forthcoming). Grey lines symbolize roads, solid black lines navigable river sections, and
dashed lines coastal shipping routes.
Building on this argument, Wrigley (1989, 2010) argues that without coal
there would have been no Industrial Revolution. Specifically, he
distinguishes between an organic economy (in which energy is extracted
from human or animal muscle or from wood) from a mineral economy (in
which energy stored up over millions of years becomes available for human
use). Productivity is always bound to be low in an organic economy. Coal
permitted Britain to escape from the constraints of an organic economy.
Wrigley acknowledges that the presence of coal alone did not guarantee that
it would be exploited. But without coal, industrialization would have been
impossible.
In his now famous contribution to the Great Divergence debate, Pomeranz
(2000) argued that British industrialization relied crucially on the proximity
of coal deposits to the new industrial centers and on resources from the
Americas. Traditional forms of energy such as timber were land-intensive. In
comparison, coal yielded more power per unit of land. New crops from the
Americas, notably the potato, increased the productivity of land in
northwestern Europe. Natural resources shifted Britain and northwestern
Europe from a labor-intensive path of economic development into an
energy-intensive and innovative development path. For Pomeranz, access to
the New World (and slavery)
offered what an expanding home market could not have: ways in which
manufactured goods created without much use of British labour could
be turned into ever-increasing amounts of land-intensive food and fiber
(and later timber) at reasonable and even falling prices. Precious metals
enabled Europeans to trade with Asia. Without silver it is difficult to
imagine another European good being exported as much.
This argument has been challenged. After all, China had abundant coal
deposits. So did the Ruhr Valley in Germany. The question of whether they
were located close to industrial centers is perhaps the wrong one to ask. In
Britain, industrial towns grew where coal was plentiful and energy cheap. It
was also possible to transport coal cheaply by sea from Newcastle to fuel
London’s demand for energy.
Mokyr (1990) argues that coal was unlikely to have been decisive, for a
variety of reasons. First, the Industrial Revolution was broader than steam
power, and even steam power did not absolutely require coal. Water power
was an important substitute. Had coal been more expensive, innovators
would have had an incentive to economize on it and develop alternative
energy sources. The supply of coal was highly elastic (Clark and Jacks,
2007). This implies that coal production expanded as demand for coal
increased with industrialization. By this account, the expansion of coal
output could have occurred in earlier decades had there been demand. In
other words, had Britain had no coal, this would not have prevented
industrialization. Coal would simply have been imported from Ireland,
France, or elsewhere in Northern Europe. This would have been costly, but
the additional costs were unlikely to have been decisive for Britain’s
industrialization. This speaks against Pomeranz’s claim that the supply of
coal was a binding constraint for industrialization to take place.
Chapter Summary
One can hardly deny the power of geography in explaining many patterns in
the pre-industrial world. Geographic characteristics were critical in the
emergence of agricultural and urban life in the Fertile Crescent. Geographic
features such as access to rivers and coasts and high-quality agricultural land
also help explain many patterns of comparative development prior to
industrialization.
But this does not mean that geography can provide a full answer for the
puzzle of comparative economic development. Before 1800, better-endowed
lands were not much richer in per capita terms than were less well-endowed
lands. They just tended to be more densely populated. Moreover, while
geographic characteristics can explain much of the variation in the location
of economic activity, they do not provide the full story. Firms benefit from
being near each other. So do workers. Economies of scale and the network
effects associated with close proximity (known in economics as
agglomeration effects), rather than geographic fundamentals, often explain
why certain cities outperform others. Most importantly, geography on its
own cannot account for the timing of the Industrial Revolution, the onset of
modern, sustained economic growth in the 19th century, or the various
reversals of fortune that we observe in the historical record.
Where does this leave us? Is there a role for geography in explaining why
the world became rich? Hopefully, this chapter has convinced you that
geography has played an important role in determining certain outcomes that
differ between societies, but that it cannot explain everything. If it could
explain everything, our fate would have been written thousands of years ago
with little room for human agency. In the remaining chapters, we will show
that human actions have played a significant role in determining the
economic trajectories of societies. These decisions range from the most
intimate (how many babies to have) to the type of legal and political systems
societies have. Yet, even though human actions have played a key role in
determining the world’s economic distribution, geography likely played
some role in these decisions. To some degree, geography has helped shape
societies’ institutions (the subject of Chapter 3), culture (the subject of
Chapter 4), demography (the subject of Chapter 5), and colonization (the
subject of Chapter 6). We will keep these interactions in mind as we proceed
through the first half of the book.
3
Is It All Just Institutions?
In Afghanistan, justice is mostly provided at the tribal level. Whether you
win your case or not depends in part on its merit. But it also depends on who
you are, which tribe you belong to, and who is overseeing your case
(Murtazashvili, 2016). In the Ottoman Empire, a well-functioning court
system existed. But it was biased: it favored men, Muslims, and elites,
regardless of the merits of their cases (Kuran and Rubin, 2018). These
systems of justice differ considerably from those found in the wealthier parts
of the contemporary world. True, the rich can buy better lawyers, and justice
is hardly color-blind, especially in the US. But the fact is that the
disadvantaged can, and frequently do, win cases when the facts are in their
favor. The relative impartiality of courts, in turn, encourages economic
activity. When people know they have legal recourse should their partner
cheat them, they are more likely to engage in exchange. Might these
differences in legal systems have played some role in determining which
parts of the world have become rich?
Differences across societies are hardly relegated to the legal sphere. At a
higher level, differences in political systems can play an important role in
economic decision-making. Where autocrats rule, violence often follows. In
North Korea, those on the wrong side of the regime tend not to last long. In
Stalin’s Soviet Union, anyone remotely expected of having anti-regime
sentiments ended up in a gulag or executed (as well as many who had no
such sentiments).
Political systems affect more than just violence. They affect whether you
have to pay bribes to do business, whether you have the right to sell and use
your property as you please, and whether you have the freedom to move
when the economic opportunity presents itself. The degree to which a
society enables – or restricts – people in this fashion is of first-order
importance in determining its economic potential.
These political, legal, religious, and economic organizations are a society’s
institutions. In this chapter, we examine the literature on institutions. We
begin by explaining what institutions are and why they impact economic
development. We then show why different institutions in different parts of
the world have placed societies on different economic trajectories.
What Are Institutions?
Until recently, textbook accounts of economic growth focused on investment
in physical capital and technological change as the key determinants of
growth. Such an approach is natural for economists interested in creating
mathematical models of economic growth. However, it is of limited value in
understanding the historical origins of economic growth. There are simply
too many examples of societies not investing in capital or technology to boil
it down to investment decisions. This is as true of the past as it is today.
Investment is relatively sparse in places like Afghanistan, Haiti, and Niger.
The marginal return to capital in these countries is likely very high. Why,
then, do individuals in these societies forgo what is more or less a free
lunch? What are the constraints people face in these societies? And how do
these constraints evolve over time?
These questions were posed by North and Thomas (1973). They argued that
the factors on which economists focused – investment in capital machinery,
factories, and schooling – were not independent causes of economic growth.
They were economic growth. To understand the causes of growth, one has to
study the incentives that led individuals in some societies to build factories
and invest, to go to school, and to acquire new skills. One must also study
why individuals in other societies were not incentivized to do these things.
North and his co-authors called the aspects of society that formed these
incentives institutions and they proposed reorienting the study of economic
growth around the study of them.
For North, institutions are the rules of the game. For example, in a game of
football (soccer), the rules determine the nature of the game and thus
structure the incentives facing the players. If we want to explain the different
behavior of players in football compared to a game of rugby, the best
explanation may reside not in differences in the individuals playing the two
games but in the different rules, and hence incentives, they face.
North’s thinking about institutions evolved over the course of his career.
Initially, North and Thomas (1973) supposed that institutions had a tendency
to evolve towards efficiency. Over time, inefficient institutions would be
weeded out and more efficient institutions would be promoted in the same
manner as market competition weeds out less efficient firms in favor of their
more efficient competitors.
Later, North (1981) came to the view that there is no process analogous to
the competitive market process to “select” the most efficient institutions.
The incentives in the political sphere differ from those in the marketplace.
Hence, inefficient institutions can persist for decades or even centuries. Such
inefficient institutions can be a source of lasting poverty. They may even be
a leading cause of why some countries are rich and others are poor.
Building on North’s insights, Greif (2006) developed an alternative
definition of institutions. His framework incorporates the critical role
cultural beliefs play in enforcing, and indeed constituting, institutions. For
Greif, institutions are not only the “rules of the game,” but also comprise the
beliefs and social norms that uphold these rules. Beliefs and social norms,
like institutions, can be hard to change. This is true even when there are clear
economic benefits from doing so. One of Greif’s key insights is that cultural
beliefs and institutions can reinforce each other. When one strengthens the
other, both are all the harder to change. Greif proposes this as a key reason
why some economies fail to grow while others prosper. We discuss these
insights further in Chapter 4.
One key component of institutions is the degree to which they permit
economic freedom. The more economic freedom a society has, the more
individuals are free to allocate their resources as they see fit. Economic
freedom is closely associated with the rule of law. When a society follows
the rule of law, laws are applied equally and all types of rights are protected.
This of course includes economic rights. Economic freedom is strongly
correlated with per capita income (Gwartney, Lawson, and Holcombe, 1999;
Gwartney, Lawson, Hall, and Murphy, 2019). Rodrik, Subramanian, and
Trebbi (2004) show that raising the degree to which a society follows the
rule of law one standard deviation – roughly corresponding to the difference
in institutions between Bolivia and South Korea – is associated with a 6.4-
fold difference in per capita income (see Figure 3.1). Incidentally, this is
about the income gap between Bolivia and South Korea. This finding should
not be taken as gospel, however. There are major challenges in estimating
the importance of institutions when relying solely on variation across
countries. This is because countries differ across so many dimensions it is
hard to isolate the specific effects of institutional quality.
Figure 3.1 Rule of law vs. per capita GDP
Data sources: World Justice Project (2020) for rule of law, Bolt and van Zanden (2020) for per
capita GDP.
For this reason, one of the most persuasive examples illustrating the
importance of institutions is the comparison between North and South Korea
(Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson, 2005a). For centuries, North and South
Korea were part of a single country, with the same language, culture, and
religious traditions. To the extent that there were major regional differences,
the north of the country was more industrialized and developed. Then, in
1948, the Communists took over the North. Ever since the war that followed,
the economic story between the two nations has been one of divergence. The
contrast between the prosperity of the South and the poverty of the North
reveals the importance of their different institutions: market-based in the
South versus Communist in the North. These differences are immediately
visible in Figure 3.2, which is a photograph taken from space of the two
countries at night. Night lights are a measure of economic prosperity because
they reveal economic activity and electrification. One can clearly see the
South Korean border and its many economic hubs. North Korea is almost
entirely pitch black.
We rarely have examples as clean-cut as North and South Korea, however.
In their absence, institutional arguments can be difficult to test. One critique
is that “good institutions” is simply a label for all things a particular author
approves of (Clark, 2007, pp. 145–65). The problem is that a label of
approbation has little explanatory value. It cannot be operationalized or used
to discriminate between points of view.
There are two ways around this problem. One is that pioneered by Greif and
his co-authors. Greif developed carefully specified theoretical models of
how specific economic institutions functioned. These models have two
virtues: the assumptions are transparent and they are capable of generating
novel predictions.
Figure 3.2 Night lights on the Korean Peninsula
Source: https://visibleearth.nasa.gov/view.php?id=83182.
For property to be put to its most efficient use, there must also be a way of
rearranging property rights when it is productive to do so. Different systems
of property rights have different consequences for economic development. In
17th- and 18th-century England, property rights had to be reordered in order
to make the best use of new investment opportunities in areas such as mining
(Bogart and Richardson, 2011). For this to happen, there needs to be a way
that property rights can be renegotiated and reallocated if it is beneficial to
do so. This was made possible only when political institutions also changed.
As Cox (2016) points out, the crucial advantage that England had by the
18th century was that in Parliament it had a centralized forum where these
claims could be adjudicated. Local veto players could be, and often were,
overruled if the gains to reallocating property rights were large enough. The
problem facing rulers who were not constrained by institutions like
Parliament is that they could not credibly commit to not using these powers
to reallocate property rights in their favor. In France, the monarchy could not
be trusted to refrain from abusing this power. Landlords therefore insisted on
retaining local veto power on any adjustments in land use. All of this
suggests that property rights cannot be viewed in isolation from the legal
system as a whole.
Van Bavel, Buringh, and Dijkman (2018) present a fascinating case of weak
property rights discouraging investment. They study investments in the
major labor-saving capital goods of the late medieval period: water mills,
windmills, and cranes. These were expensive to build, but offered an
immense return on investment. Because of their cost, they were precisely the
type of capital goods that were only likely to be invested in when property
rights were secure. Van Bavel, Buringh, and Dijkman find that, over the
period 900–1600, their use increased over time in Western Europe but
diminished over time in the Middle East. The decline in Middle Eastern
capital investments coincided precisely with a decline in the security of
property rights.
It is not just the security of property rights that matters. How rights are
assigned is also crucial. In particular, overlapping property rights, in which
multiple parties are able to claim rights to the same good, generate holdup
problems and impede investment (Lamoreaux, 2011). A holdup problem
occurs when one party has an incentive to strategically delay or impede the
investment in order to extract a larger share of the resulting profits
(Williamson, 1985). For example, in France prior to the Revolution,
complex and rigid overlapping property rights prevented landowners from
investing in irrigation or in drainage projects (Rosenthal, 1992). If anything,
these property rights were “too secure.”
It is also possible for property rights to sow the seeds of an economy’s
demise. Van Bavel (2016) shows that the rise and fall of Abbasid Iraq (750–
1258), medieval northern Italy, and the early modern Dutch Republic all
followed a similar pattern. In each case, there was a feedback loop in which
secure property rights in factor markets allowed underutilized resources to
become more productively used. This led to specialization and division of
labor, which led to economic growth, which resulted in greater use of factor
markets, and so on. However, with factor market growth came political and
economic inequality. Those who owned the factors of production gained
more political power. They used it to dominate the markets for land, labor,
and capital, as well as financial markets, making these markets less free in
the process. These vested interests squeezed the little remaining productive
power out of the economy, leaving little for the rest of society.
The Legal System
The legal system is the meta-institution that spells out the formal rules of the
game and the manner in which they are enforced. Legal systems vary
tremendously across societies. Many small-scale societies rely on informal
and decentralized legal systems based around ostracism and feuding. These
legal systems differ considerably from those of large-scale agrarian states, let
alone highly commercialized, market-oriented societies.
Small-scale societies rely on repeated interactions and social sanctions to
enforce order. In small-scale, closely knit societies, these mechanisms are
powerful in enforcing cooperation. Individuals in these societies expect to
interact with each other again in the future. They thus have an incentive to
develop a reputation for fair dealing. It is the threat of missing out on future
rewards that induces them to refrain from violence or theft in the present
(Kandori, 1992; Dixit, 2004).
However, mechanisms dependent on the logic of repeated dealings may be
unable to support cooperation in large-scale societies, where people are
unlikely to interact consistently. As societies become more complex,
therefore, formal legal systems tend to emerge. A formal legal system
prescribes rules that outline licit and illicit behavior and specify punishments
for those who disobey the law. The first such legal system that we have a
record of is the Code of Hammurabi, dated to 1754 BCE (see Figure 3.4).
Legal systems structure the incentives that individuals face. For example, the
Code of Hammurabi prescribed numerous harsh punishments. A son who hit
his father was to have his hands chopped off, while lovers who conspired to
murder a husband were to be impaled. The Code of Hammurabi specified
harsher punishment for lower-status individuals and for crimes directed
against one’s social betters. For instance, “if a man knocks out the teeth of
his equal, his teeth shall be knocked out,” while knocking out the teeth of a
social inferior only resulted in a fine. The Code of Hammurabi thus
reinforced existing power structures and a hierarchical social system.
Figure 3.4 The first(?) formal legal system: the Code of Hammurabi
Source: https://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/0/06/Prologue_code_Lipit-
Ishtar_AO_5473.jpg.
In other words, the Code of Hammurabi was a set of laws based on identity
rules rather than impersonal rules (Johnson and Koyama, 2019). The kind of
punishment varied according to the social identity of the parties involved.
Such identity rules tend to entrench the power of existing elites. There are
many historical examples of identity rules. Medieval European Jews faced
their own set of laws, including what they could wear and where they could
live. Many medieval European cities had sumptuary laws, specifying which
clothes individuals could wear based on their social class (Desierto and
Koyama, 2020).
In contrast, a society structured around impersonal rules is committed to
treating individuals the same regardless of their social identity. Impersonal
rules are often more consistent with the protection of property than are
identity rules. They enable impersonal rather than personal exchange and
hence are more likely to promote investment and economic growth.
The distinction between identity rules and impersonal rules is one of the key
differences between rule by law and the rule of law. In a “rule by law”
society, laws exist but are not necessarily applied to everyone. The ruling
elites tend to be above the law. In these societies, the dictum “rules for thee
but not for me” applies. As we noted earlier in this chapter, moving away
from such a society to one in which rulers are constrained by the law was
key to economic growth (Greif and Rubin, 2021).
Societies that have a strong rule of law tend to be richer (see Figure 3.1).
What is it about the rule of law that leads to positive economic outcomes?
Fuller (1969) argued that the rule of law requires (1) a concept of legal
equality – that is, all individuals from the ruler downwards are equally
subject to the law; (2) that laws should be prospective, open, and clear; (3)
that laws should be stable over time; (4) that the making of laws should be
open and guided by impersonal rules; (5) that the judiciary should be
politically independent; (6) that legal institutions such as courts should be
accessible to all; and (7) that rules should be general and apply uniformly.
These are all conditions that decrease uncertainty, and hence increase
investment and incentivize exchange.
Importantly, the rule of law depends on a nexus of different institutions. It
depends on a political system that is bound by rules that constrain the power
of the executive. It also depends on a standardized legal system in which
individuals know what to expect and in which there are clearly defined
standards that cannot be subverted through corruption or patronage.
Many scholars have argued that the rule of law played a critical role in the
rise of Western Europe. It provided a check on the power of government,
guaranteed each individual their own private sphere of non-interference, and
offered a platform of institutional stability conducive to long-run economic
growth (Hayek, 1960; Cooter, 1997; Weingast, 1997). The idea is that rule of
law, rather than rule by men, provides the stability and certainty that enables
individuals to truck, barter, and exchange their way to prosperity (Dicey,
1908, pp. 198–9). The question is: how do societies develop impersonal
rules? Where does the rule of law come from?
In Law and Revolution, Harold Berman (1983) attributed particular
significance to the emergence of the Western legal tradition during the
Middle Ages. This legal tradition has its origins in ancient Rome. As the
Roman economy was commercialized and market-oriented, Roman legal
scholars developed a theory of contracts and property (Arruñada, 2016).
Roman law was largely lost in Western Europe following the collapse of the
Western Roman Empire. During this period, Germanic or customary legal
codes dominated. These laws were based on identity rules and better suited
to governing small-scale societies rather than providing a framework for
impersonal trade. Beginning in the 11th and 12th centuries, however, Roman
law was rediscovered and the principles underlying the Roman law of
contracts began to be studied by lawyers of canon law in universities like
that of Bologna (Fernández-Villaverde, 2022). While customary laws
remained in place for centuries, the principles of Roman law would
eventually form the basis for both the French and Germanic legal systems.
At roughly the same time, a different legal system was emerging when
Germanic and local legal systems were unified into common law during the
12th and 13th centuries. English common law was influenced by Roman
law, but only indirectly via canon law. Numerous scholars, including the
great legal scholars Pollack and Maitland (1895) and Dicey (1908), saw
English common law as it evolved in the Middle Ages as playing a critical
role in enshrining and protecting property rights. They reasoned that
common law provided a set of stable but adaptive principles that in later
centuries enabled more complex organizational forms to emerge.
Building on this tradition, La Porta, de Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998)
argued that the English common law tradition is associated with better
protection of property rights, less onerous regulations, and a more favorable
environment for markets than systems based on Roman Law (such as the
French or German legal systems). In particular, La Porta et al. argued that
protection for investors was systematically stronger in common law
countries. Common law countries tend to give both shareholders and
creditors the strongest rights, regardless of GDP. This is important for
financial development because it limits the extent to which corporate
insiders can expropriate investors. Other research has found that within a
country such as France, which had both civil and common law traditions
prior to the Revolution, there is little evidence that civil law was worse for
economic development (Le Bris, 2019). Particularly problematic for the
legal origins argument is the finding that financial development varies
greatly over time, and that in 1913 France’s stock market capitalization, as a
proportion of the economy, was almost twice that of the US (Rajan and
Zingales, 2003).
Nevertheless, the type of law that countries have is one of the important
relics of the colonial era. Countries that were colonized by Europeans –
which, as we will see in Chapter 6, was much of the world – tended to get
their legal institutions (see Figure 3.5). Some speculate that this is why
English colonies, steeped as they were in English common law, tended to do
better than other European colonies. Other scholarship suggests that what
matters is how different legal traditions were transplanted to the colonies
(Berkowitz, Pistor, and Richard, 2003). In particular, Oto-Peralías and
Romero-Ávila (2014) argue that whether or not the British introduced
common law to a colony hinged on initial levels of population density,
which determined how costly it would be to enforce a new legal code. We
leave the discussion of the long-run effects of colonization to Chapter 6.
Figure 3.5 Legal origins throughout the world
Data source: Shleifer, de Silanes, and Porta (2008).
But does the type of government one lives under matter for economic
growth? If so, why does it matter? What can governments do – or not do – to
facilitate growth?
Institutional economists argue that political institutions matter for growth
because they ultimately shape the incentives that exist in society. In an
unconstrained autocracy, the rule of law cannot function because it does not
apply to the ruler, who can use the legal system to favor his cronies and
harm his opponents. Autocratic regimes are often more corrupt than non-
autocratic regimes. Liberal democracies – those which secure basic rights
and liberties for their citizens – tend to have less corruption. Yet, the
evidence for whether (liberal) democracy promotes economic growth, or is
itself a product of economic growth, is mixed. There are examples of
democracies outperforming autocracies and vice versa. As we discuss in
more depth in Chapter 10, China has outperformed India since the 1980s
despite similar initial levels of development. The Chinese government is
autocratic while India is the world’s largest democracy.
Whether a country is democratic or not is not all that matters for economic
growth. Whether or not state power is limited is likely more important, as we
shall discuss below. Moreover, among nondemocratic states it matters how
broad the ruling coalition is and whether it represents the interests of
merchants and owners of capital. In what follows, we discuss some of the
additional factors that connect political institutions to economic
development.
More Equal Rights for All
Which are more important for a society’s long-run growth: economic
institutions or political institutions? Political institutions determine who has
power in society. However, political institutions tend to depend on economic
resources and hence past economic institutions. Those who control political
institutions can use them to increase their control of economic resources,
thereby increasing their political power (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2006).
This is one reason why institutions can be a source of lasting poverty. In
societies where the political system is in the hands of a narrow elite, this
elite can use their power to construct economic institutions that benefit
themselves but impoverish the rest of society.
There is therefore a feedback between economic institutions and political
institutions. The economic institutions of a society are a function of its
political institutions, while political institutions help dictate the economic
incentives people face. But in what ways do they do so? Are some political
institutions “good” for growth and others “bad”?
Acemoglu and Robinson (2012b) argue that whether political institutions are
good or bad for growth hinges on whether they are inclusive or extractive.
Inclusive institutions create broad-based economic incentives and
opportunities. They tend to be characterized by a broad distribution of
political power. They bring people from varying socio-economic classes,
ethnicities, and cultures to the political bargaining table. This makes it tough
for one group to transgress the rights of another. Democratic institutions are
often seen as relatively inclusive. In a well-functioning democracy, office
holders can be challenged, anyone that meets certain qualifications (age,
citizenship) can run, and unpopular officials can be voted out.
On the other end of the spectrum are extractive economic and political
institutions. These institutions do not create broad-based incentives. Instead,
power is held by a small group of powerful elites who are subject to few
constraints from the rest of society. When power is held narrowly or the state
is too weak to be effective, the conditions are ripe for some individuals or
groups to extract from each other. Long-lasting economic development is
rarely achieved in such an environment. One need look no further than
modern-day autocracies for examples of extractive political institutions. In
North Korea, Eritrea, and Turkmenistan, the political elite live in luxury
while much of the population barely gets by. Funds that could be used for
the public good line the pockets of the elite. There is little incentive for
either domestic or foreign investment, since the proceeds of such investment
are insecure. These economies tend to stagnate over time.
But what institutions count as “inclusive” as opposed to “extractive”? One
problem with this taxonomy is that institutions that are inclusive for some
can also be extractive for others. The Athenian democracy was a very
inclusive system for adult male Athenians (Ober, 2018). Yet it behaved in a
highly extractive manner to its large slave population – many of whom
labored in the silver mines of Laurion in horrific conditions – and to the
members of its alliance or empire who had to pay tribute in order to maintain
the fleet. Was the Athenian democracy more inclusive and less extractive
than later societies that did not practice democracy but also did not have
slaves or an empire? A similar insight applies to Republican Florence, which
granted its citizens civil and political rights but imposed extractive
institutions on neighboring towns and cities (Epstein, 2000). To take a more
recent example, since the 17th century, political institutions in North
America have been more open and equal – for white males – than in almost
any other part of the world. At the same time, even after the abolition of the
slavery, the US suppressed the voting (and many other) rights of African-
Americans until the 1960s.
Acemoglu and Robinson (2019) introduced the concept of a “narrow
corridor to liberty” to resolve this apparent paradox. They acknowledge that
political development is a process. Inclusive institutions are made possible
by a functioning state – one able to repress powerful interest groups or
corrupt elites. But inclusive institutions will also be upended by an overly
powerful state. Civil society needs to develop alongside the growth of state
power because it is civil society that is capable of limiting state power. When
the state becomes too powerful relative to society, a society can be knocked
out of the corridor, resulting in despotic rule and extractive institutions. But
the state cannot be too weak, either. This is when we get anarchism,
tribalism, and weak public good provision. For Acemoglu and Robinson, the
former situation describes societies like China, while the latter situation
explains the poverty and stagnation of much of sub-Saharan Africa.
A related concept is the distinction between what North, Wallis, and
Weingast (2009) call the “natural state” and the “open-access order.” In the
natural state, which was the only form of political organization more or less
anywhere prior to the 18th century, personal relationships form the basis of
social organization. People are treated differently based on whom they know
and where they stand in the social and economic hierarchy. The law, where it
is applied at all, applies differently depending on one’s standing. Although
growth can happen in the natural state, it is limited. The elite can extract
from the non-elite, and there is little investment in any goods that do not
directly benefit the elite. Nearly every society in history was structured this
way, as are many contemporary societies. Feudal Europe, Shogunate Japan,
and practically every European colony had natural state political institutions.
Today, many states in Africa, the Middle East, and Central Asia are in the
“natural state.”
Key to this argument is the concept of rents. Economic rents are returns
above opportunity cost. Rents can be generated by government policies and
restrictions on economic activity that limit entry. The insight of Tullock
(1967) was that the cost of rents includes all the resources economic actors
expend in pursuit of them. These costs can be very large. The concept of
rent-seeking can be used to explain many institutions that were prevalent in
the past, including restrictions on interest rates (Ekelund, Hebert, Tollison,
Anderson, and Davidson, 1996; Koyama, 2010a), the sale of monopolies
(Ekelund and Tollison, 1997), and government offices. What North, Wallis,
and Weingast (2009) mean when they argue that rents hold a natural state
together is that they bind together individuals with the capacity to use
violence. Rents make it in their interest to adhere to the existing political
order rather than challenge it by resorting to force.
According to North, Wallis, and Weingast (2009), long-run economic
development requires a society to transition to the open-access order. This is
a type of political system similar to what Acemoglu and Robinson (2012b)
call “inclusive.” But the emphasis for North, Wallis, and Weingast is on the
ability of individuals and groups to form long-lasting organizations that are
independent of the state. What matters for sustained economic growth is less
whether or not a country is a formal democracy, but rather how easy it is to
set up a rival political party or establish a large business without getting
favors from political insiders. By this measure, North, Wallis, and Weingast
argue that only a small number of countries today are truly open-access
orders.
The question is: how do societies transition to an open-access order or
inclusive institutions? How do they enter what Acemoglu and Robinson
(2019) call the “narrow corridor”? This is the key question from a
development standpoint. Noting which institutions are necessary is one
thing. Figuring out how we get there is another. For Acemoglu and Robinson
(2012b), there are “critical junctures” in a society’s past that allow it to make
the leap (or not). For North, Wallis, and Weingast (2009), there are a set of
“doorstep conditions” a natural state society needs to achieve in order to be
able to make the leap. But even then the leap is not assured.
In short, there is no general answer to how a society achieves “good”
political institutions. Some societies have done it and others have not. Yet,
this does not mean this literature teaches us nothing. Understanding how the
societies that took off did so is important for teaching us what can work.
Institutions and the Commercial Revolution
Between 1000 and 1300, Europe experienced a period of sustained economic
growth. The population grew, per capita income increased, urbanization rates
increased dramatically, and the volume of trade expanded many times over.
This was not modern economic growth, as we described in Chapter 1,
because it eventually petered out. But it was growth nonetheless. For some
economic historians, it was this growth that set the stage for what was to
come. Southern (1970, p. 34) went so far as to suggest that “that moment of
self-generating expansion, for which economists now look so anxiously in
underdeveloped countries, came to Western Europe in the late eleventh
century.” Cipolla (1976, p. 139) described the rise of cities in Europe in the
10th through 12th centuries as one of the “turning point[s] in the history of
the West – and, for that matter, of the whole world.” These statements may
be exaggerations. But there is no doubt that this was a period of remarkable
economic growth.
The Commercial Revolution was characterized by the revival of long-
distance trade. This trade spanned political borders and jurisdictions. Yet,
there were no political authorities capable of enforcing contracts between
merchants operating in different cities. So how did trade occur? How could a
merchant punish someone who cheated him?
Medieval merchants selling in different jurisdictions faced the following
problem. Say an English merchant has wool valued at £5 in England. He
decides to take the wool to Flanders, where it is valued more. He meets a
Flemish merchant who can sell it for £8. If goods and money can be
exchanged there and then, the trade can take place at a price between £5 and
£8 and both merchants will gain. Trade is mutually beneficial.
But now suppose that there is some delay between either the goods or
payment arriving. Let’s say the Flemish merchant has to pay on credit since
hard specie is in short supply. This delay between purchase and payment
gives the Flemish merchant an opportunity to renege on his promise. The
English merchant cannot therefore know whether the Flemish merchant will
actually deliver the payment. Once the Flemish merchant has the wool, he
has the choice of transferring the money to England or not. But why should
he? The shadow cast by the future will not be sufficiently strong to enforce
cooperation if the two merchants are not expected to regularly trade with
each other in the future. Knowing this, the English merchant will never agree
to trade unless he can be paid up front and immediately. The potential gains
from trade are never realized.
Greif (2000) called this the fundamental problem of exchange. Trade is
limited to cases where either a spot exchange can take place or merchants
trust each other enough to trade on credit. This insight is generalizable: in
the absence of this trust, trade is extremely costly. A lack of information
about the quality of goods could generate similar problems. Manufactured
goods might have suffered from defects that were hard to detect on purchase
but only became apparent later on. Purchasers alone bore the consequences
of defective purchases, because people who purchased defective
merchandise had few remedies (Richardson, 2008). Merchants had an
incentive to pass on defective goods to traders they met anonymously and to
retain quality products for personal exchange.
Greif used game theory to explain how merchant communities in the Middle
Ages attempted to resolve this fundamental problem of exchange. First, he
considered the Maghribi traders – Jewish traders in Muslim North Africa –
who were prominent in Mediterranean trade during the 10th and 11th
centuries (Greif, 1989, 1993, 2006). Conducting long-distance trade in the
absence of a reliable and centralized legal system, these traders faced a
version of the problem of exchange. To conduct their business in different
parts of the Mediterranean, they needed to hire agents. But what guarantee
did a merchant have that the agent would not cheat him?
The key to the Maghribi traders’ success was their ability to utilize a
multilateral punishment strategy. This is a situation in which multiple parties
agree to punish anyone who cheats any individual in the group. The
effectiveness of this punishment hinged upon the nature of their close-knit
community. Greif provides evidence that the Maghribi traders were able to
disseminate information about the behavior of commercial agents among a
coalition of merchants.
In the 11th and 12th centuries, the Maghribi traders were displaced from
Mediterranean trade by Italian merchants. Greif (2002, 2006) documents that
community responsibility enabled these merchants to overcome the problem
of exchange. Community responsibility meant that individual merchants
were made responsible for the behavior of their peers. The goods of a
merchant could be seized simply because another merchant from his town
had refused to repay a loan or had cheated another merchant. Under this
system, the cost of an individual merchant cheating was borne by the
community. This meant that internal community enforcement could be used
to deter domestic merchants from cheating foreigners. The court of the
Flemish merchant had an incentive to uphold complaints from the court of
the English merchant, which in turn only championed genuine complaints.
This allowed borrowers to credibly commit to repaying lenders even though
they might never trade again in future.
Greif’s models help to explain how trade worked without widespread rule of
law. Although these institutions differed over time and place, they had one
common element: they incentivized people to follow through with their
promises. They thus allowed trade to flourish long before states were
capable of providing the rule of law over the entirety of their domains.
Between the State and the Market: Guilds
Not all institutions are formal ones emanating from the state. The rules of the
game come from many facets of life. One important set of institutions that
played a role in the Commercial Revolution were guilds. Various craft and
merchant guilds regulated large swaths of the European economy from the
late Middle Ages to the Industrial Revolution. Indeed, the story of the
medieval economic efflorescence is impossible to tell without some mention
of guild activity.
Craft guilds dominated urban life for much of the period between the 12th
and 16th centuries. To participate in a trade, one generally had to be a
member of a guild. This was true for smiths, tanners, butchers, bakers,
brewers, clerks, and entertainers, among many others. Guild membership
was restricted, and one had to serve a lengthy apprenticeship before
becoming a master. Craft guilds performed a range of different functions,
including regulating goods and labor markets. They also aided local political
authorities in tax collection. They kept their privileges by allying with local
political authorities (Ogilvie, 2019).
Craft guilds have been the subject of considerable controversy. Were guilds
rent-seeking institutions that imposed costs on the wider economy? Or did
they serve an important economic function? In theory, both are possible.
Guilds did restrict entry and hence generate higher profits for members than
they would have otherwise obtained. At the same time, it is possible that
guilds could have helped to resolve coordination problems, protect
merchants from state predation, and resolve market failures.
Richardson (2008) argued that craft guilds helped resolve problems of
asymmetric information such as verifying product quality. Guilds had an
incentive to keep product quality high since they had a “name brand” which
allowed them to sell goods well outside of the city. This is why some goods
are still associated with cities. London’s guild of pewterers made a
particularly high-quality pewter (which we still call London pewter). The
wine-makers of Burgundy made a particularly rich and sought-after red
wine. The cheese-makers of Parma made a very nice cheese.
Craft guilds served other purposes as well. Epstein (1998) argued that the
craft guilds and the apprentice system played a critical role in incentivizing
investment in industry-specific human capital. The work done by master
guild members required extremely high skill, taking years to learn. Epstein
argues that restricting labor via the apprenticeship system was the only way
for masters to recoup the costs of transferring skills. Teaching these skills
entailed upfront costs with little immediate payoff. Masters needed to recoup
costs later to make it worth it. The rents available via the guild system
provided these incentives. They could also have incentivized innovation.
Monopoly rents largely went to inventors, since not just anyone could pick
up a trade. As a result, there were numerous minor improvements made to
techniques and capital in the late medieval period. De la Croix, Doepke, and
Mokyr (2017) show that these novel techniques slowly spread throughout
Europe via journeymen. These master guildsmen would go from town to
town and employ the tacit knowledge of “how to do things” gained in their
previous employment. In this light, guilds may have encouraged innovation
and the diffusion of best-practice techniques.
In contrast, Ogilvie (2019) argues that craft guilds were rent-seeking
organizations that did best by their members but often imposed costs on the
rest of society. Drawing on two databases of guild activities, she provides
evidence that guilds routinely restricted the economic activity of non-guild
members, lobbied governments for privileges, and used a combination of
fines, fees, confiscations, and occasionally violence to enforce these
privileges. They opposed innovations when they threatened guild profits. In
this view, the late medieval economy was held back by guild activity. It is of
course possible that the truth lies somewhere in between these opposing
views.
Merchant guilds, on the other hand, dominated trade throughout most of the
late Middle Ages, especially in the free towns of Northern Europe (Ogilvie,
2011). The most famous of these guilds was the German Hansa. Members of
the Hansa traded with other members in cities throughout modern-day
Germany, Poland, Denmark, Netherlands, Belgium, England, and beyond.
Travel to foreign lands can be dangerous, especially for merchants carrying
valuable cargo. Beyond the physical dangers imposed by outlaws, local
rulers have an incentive to confiscate the wares of foreign merchants. What’s
to stop them? To whom could merchants appeal? According to Greif,
Milgrom, and Weingast (1994), one purpose of the merchant guild was to
serve as a collective voice against rulers who wished to transgress upon their
rights. If a merchant had his rights transgressed, the guild would boycott the
city. This dried up the tax revenue that rulers received from trade, providing
a huge disincentive to transgress merchants’ rights. The guild could do this
while an individual could not because boycotts require collective action.
Any merchant caught trading with a city under boycott – a “scab” in modern
parlance – could be kicked out of the guild, forgoing a lifetime of healthy
earnings.
Once states became larger and able to protect the rights of more of their
citizens, merchant guilds became unnecessary. They imposed a cost on
society through their monopoly privileges (Ogilvie, 2011). In the medieval
context, where state and legal capacity was limited, this cost was worth it,
since it allowed some degree of trade to occur. But how did states gain the
legal capacity to make institutions such as merchant guilds obsolete? It is to
this issue that we turn next.
Parliaments and Limited Government
Among the most important changes in European political institutions in the
build-up to the Industrial Revolution was the rise of limited government. As
the name implies, in a limited government, the powers of the ruling elite are
constrained. There are checks on authority in each part of government. Such
checks help economies grow. They limit the ability of any one group to
extract too much. There are no inclusive political institutions or open-access
orders without some limits on government.
But how do societies get limited government? Throughout history, most
governments were not limited. Small groups of ruling elites held most
power, and the rest of society had relatively little capacity to push back. This
began to change in Europe during the Commercial Revolution. In the 11th
and 12th centuries, self-governing or independent cities emerged in northern
Italy, the Low Countries, and then later in the Rhineland and across
Germany. The absence of a single strong ruler enabled merchants to rise to
political prominence. They implemented reforms that favored their own
interests but were also largely favorable to the overall expansion of trade.
For this reason, independent city-states were pioneers of the revival of trade
during the Commercial Revolution.
The late Middle Ages also saw the rise of parliaments. The term
“parliament” refers to political assemblies that had the ability to limit the
power of the sovereign. They were generally comprised of three types of
elites: churchmen, landed nobles, and the urban bourgeoisie. The first
medieval parliaments, or cortes, emerged in medieval Spain, in León and
Castile, before spreading across Europe in the 12th and 13th centuries (van
Zanden, Buringh, and Bosker, 2012). Parliaments were important because, at
least in theory, they allowed the interests of the broader population to be
represented in a single body. In the ancient world, democracy always meant
direct democracy. In classical Athens, the entire citizen body meeting in the
assembly was sovereign. The limitation to this mode of government was that
it scaled poorly. Individuals who did not reside in Athens could not attend
the assembly. The development of representative institutions like
parliaments made it possible for individuals living in much more extensive
polities to participate, albeit indirectly, in the governing process.
Parliaments emerged out of the councils medieval kings called among their
nobility. In England, the Magna Carta, signed by King John (r. 1199–1216)
and his barons in 1215, played a crucial role in the formation of medieval
parliaments. The Magna Carta arose in response to the abuses of King John
following his defeat by (and the loss of his Norman territories to) the King of
France (Koyama, 2016). To understand why this led to the rise of
representative institutions, one has to understand the feudal system that John
presided over. One way to do this is through the lens of the natural state
framework introduced by North, Wallis, and Weingast (2009).
In their framework, discussed earlier in this chapter, political elites restrict
entry in areas of the economy in order to generate monopoly rents. These
rents are distributed to those with enough coercive power to disrupt the
existing power structure. In medieval England, these were the great barons,
who had purview over significant territory. In such a setting, states cannot
provide rule of law to all precisely because they rely on treating individuals
differently in order to maintain political order. Instead of impersonal rules,
natural states rely on personal enforcement and on identity rules to govern.
This reliance on identity rules meant that individuals received different
treatment depending on their religion, social class, place of birth, or
residency.
In England circa 1200, the authority of the king stemmed from two sources.
First, he was the largest landowner. This was crucial, as most royal revenue
came from land. Second, the king was at the top of the feudal system. All
other lords in the country swore him fealty. He could apportion estates in the
absence of a direct male heir and was endowed with a range of prerogatives,
which included the right to hold court and enforce justice. But these
prerogatives did not include the right to freely impose taxes on his subjects
during times of peace. In theory, he was expected to “live on his own” from
the proceeds of the royal demesne.
To meet the costs of war with France, John exploited all of the revenue
sources available to a feudal ruler. He sold wardships – the right to take
control of the land of minors until they came of age – and sold the right to
marry rich heiresses. Feudal rights such as these were traditionally employed
to cement alliances among the nobility. But John exploited them for
immediate profit. His position as feudal overlord enabled him to exploit his
control over the royal courts to sell justice. And he mercilessly taxed
England’s Jewish community (Koyama, 2010b).
Through these abuses, John alienated the powerful lords who made up the
ruling coalition of 13th-century England. These lords had the military power
to defeat the king if they could coordinate their resistance. In forcing him to
agree to the Magna Carta, they got him to acknowledge certain limits to
royal authority – particularly the right to levy taxes without consent. They
succeeded: the Magna Carta forcefully articulated the position that the king
was subject to the law.
During the reign of John’s successor, Henry III (r. 1216–72), the term
“parliament” emerged to describe meetings between the king and the leading
barons. The initial role of Parliament was judicial. It was employed to hear a
variety of legal cases, and it soon became important in fiscal matters as well.
In the reign of Edward I (r. 1272–1307), Parliament became crucial in
granting the king the right to collect taxes. Importantly, Edward I regularly
called Parliaments in which representatives of the urban bourgeoisie
attended, in addition to the nobility and members of the clergy. For the rest
of the Middle Ages, English kings relied on Parliament to grant them the
taxes they needed, particularly in wartime.
During the Middle Ages, representative institutions flourished across
Europe. However, they did not all become national institutions like the
English Parliament. For example, the parlement of Paris was in origin a
similar body to the English Parliament and it covered the entirety of the
kingdom of France. However, during and after the Hundred Years’ War, the
French king devolved authority to regional parlements such as the those of
Toulouse, Rouen, Guyenne and Gascony, Burgundy, and Provence. These
parlements came to represent local rather than national interests. They
therefore precluded the development of an institution strong enough to
constrain the French monarch. Similarly, the cortes of León and Aragon,
although they remained active, were only able to provide local resistance
against the Spanish monarchies after the unification of the crowns of Aragon
and Castile in 1469.
Unlike today, parliaments were only in session when they were called by the
monarch. And monarchs were only likely to call parliaments when they
needed something – mainly taxes. In return, parliaments could expect to
receive some favorable laws, policies, or rights. Hence, the frequency with
which parliaments were called reflects their power to constrain the crown,
and it can thus be used as an indicator of the degree of limited governance
(van Zanden, Buringh, and Bosker, 2012). Figure 3.8 depicts the frequency
of parliamentary activity in several Western European states. One feature is
immediately clear: parliaments in Southern Europe became less active over
time while parliamentary activity in northwestern Europe rose rapidly in the
16th and 17th centuries. This was just prior to the economic rise of
northwestern Europe.
Is this just a coincidence? The timing suggests not. The parliaments of
northwestern Europe, especially in England and the Netherlands, became
strong around the time when economic growth accelerated. This is precisely
what we would expect to see if limited government played a role in forging
the modern economy. Although it could be a coincidence, the literature
described above suggests that the connection is causal. For this reason, the
rise of limited governance is among the most important issues we will return
to in Chapter 7, when we discuss the preconditions for the rise of the modern
economy.
War and State Finances
How does a society get institutions that provide equal rights for individuals,
enforce property rights, and allow for flourishing factor markets? One
important factor dictating the path of institutional development has been
warfare.
This question was asked by Tilly (1975, 1990). His statement “war made the
state, and the state made war” succinctly summarizes the matter. War was
the main preoccupation of medieval and early modern European states.
Before 1800, states spent most of their revenue on warfare or on paying
interest on debts occurred in previous wars. Nonetheless, though almost all
pre-modern states were preoccupied with war, Tilly (1990) discerned three
paths of state formation: a “coercive-intensive” path, a “capital-intensive”
path, and a mix between the two.
The coercive-intensive path was taken by Prussia and Russia. These states
were built from and for war. The Prussians and Russians did not just tax
their populations. They directly mobilized labor and other resources through
conscription. In the 17th century, Russia was involved in a war on its
western frontier one year out of every two. On its southern and eastern
frontiers, war was essentially continuous (Pipes, 1974). As war machines
became stronger, they were able to exert force over a greater expanse of
people and demand tax revenue from them. This, however, did not lead to
positive long-run economic outcomes. There was little incentive for
individuals to invest in capital in such a regime.
On the other extreme were states on the “capital-intensive” path. This was
taken by many of the city-states of northern Italy, Central Europe, and the
Low Countries. These states expanded as their wealth expanded. Capital-
intensive states were also often involved in warfare. They generally
protected the rights of their citizens, especially those engaged in commerce.
They were thus able to collect tax revenue from the economic elite in return
for protection. These city-states were able to borrow at relatively low rates
precisely because they were run by merchants for merchants (Stasavage,
2011). Merchants had an interest in maintaining the credit-worthiness of the
state, and thus the risk of default was low. This is important: access to credit
is a necessary feature of the modern state. Absent natural resource windfalls,
it is impossible to think of a modern state functioning well without the
capacity to borrow. Yet, as Stasavage (2014) points out, when certain groups
dominate the political scene for too long, vested interests eventually
undermine further growth.
The late medieval Italian city-states provided a particularly important
example of the institutional innovations associated with warfare. Almost
continuously at war, Venice and Florence pioneered institutional innovations
which enabled them to compete with much larger states and raise ever larger
revenues to pay for their mercenary armies. The annual revenue of Florence
in the 14th century varied between 250,000 and 350,000 florins, but
historians estimate the direct cost of the three-year war between Florence
and the Papacy in 1375–8 exceeded 2.5 million florins (Caferro, 2008, p.
177). To meet this shortfall, Italian city-states developed impersonal systems
of public debt and permanent systems of taxation (Epstein, 2000). In these
cities, the holders of capital were represented in government, ensuring that
the promise to repay was credible. Thus, their political institutions allowed
city-states to pay lower interest on their debts than territorial monarchies did
(see Figure 3.10).
Yet, Tilly (1990) argues that the path to the modern economy did not lie in
the purely capital-intensive political institutions of the city-states. Instead, it
lay in those states that employed some hybrid model that combined both
coercion and capital. England is a prototypical example. These states were
able to encourage capital accumulation while also acquiring the capacity to
tax large swaths of their population. And those with capital were willing to
provide taxes in return for protection of their property rights.
Hoffman (2015) presents a modified version of this thesis. Like Tilly, he
focuses on incessant European warfare as a prime mover of European
economic success. But instead of emphasizing its role in state formation, he
stresses the role that warfare played in encouraging innovation in military
technology. These technological advances, especially when combined with
gunpowder, gave Europe the upper hand in colonizing the rest of the world.
But why were European patterns of warfare different? Hoffman argues that a
cultural proclivity to warfare made European military competition more
intense than elsewhere.
Yet another impact of warfare was its effect on the location of economic
activity. Rosenthal and Wong (2011) argue that European warfare
disproportionately affected the countryside because cities tended to be better
fortified. This contrasted with China, where less frequent warfare meant that
urban and rural locations were equally affected by war. The result was that
trade and manufacturing were pushed to urban areas in Europe but not in
China. This in turn meant higher urban wages in Europe, which encouraged
investment in labor-saving technologies. As we will see in Chapter 8, these
were precisely the types of technologies that were key to Europe’s
industrialization.
Figure 3.10 Interest rates in city-states and territorial states, 1200–1800
Data source: Stasavage (2016).
Why might culture help explain how the world became rich? The answer to
this question is often addressed by considering its converse: what aspects of
culture have inhibited economic development? Because the learned norms
and beliefs we acquire through cultural evolution develop slowly – often
more slowly than economic and technological change – cultural beliefs can
become maladapted to their economic environment. In other words, cultural
beliefs that benefited economic growth under one set of circumstances may
hamper it in another. And because cultural norms are slow to change,
societies may not be in a position to take advantage of the new opportunities
afforded to them.
Culture also matters because cultural beliefs can affect how institutions
function. Recall that this was a key insight of Greif’s discussion of
institutions in Chapter 3. From this perspective, cultural beliefs matter
because they explain why people do what they do and therefore why
institutions encourage certain patterns of behavior in some contexts but not
in others. This may explain, for instance, why democracy has had such a
tough time taking hold in the Middle East, even in the wake of the Arab
Spring. If democratic norms of accountability and abiding by the outcomes
of elections are not well established, democratic institutions are unlikely to
function as they are supposed to.
Before we proceed, we want to be clear that, with respect to the effect of
culture on “why the world became rich,” we are not speaking of (and
certainly not endorsing) a “Eurocentric” view of history. This view, common
among historians of the early 20th century, attributes some aspect of Western
culture – such as being hard-working, innovative, or willing to take risks –
as being superior and the cause of much that is good in the modern world.
Not only are many of the views of this ilk offensive, but they are
unsatisfying as social science. Even if we are to believe that such cultural
traits differ between societies, why did such differences arise in the first
place?
Most of the supposed cultural differences pointed to in the early 20th century
may have reflected as much about the cultural norms of Western observers
as about their subjects. For example, in the late 19th century, Westerners in
Japan commented on the indolence and laziness of Japanese workers. Chang
(2008) notes that “in his 1903 book, Evolution of the Japanese, the
American missionary Sidney Gulick observed that many Japanese ‘give an
impression … of being lazy and utterly indifferent to the passage of time.’”
Gulick was no casual observer. He lived in Japan for twenty-five years
(1888–1913), fully mastered the Japanese language, and taught at a Japanese
university. After his return to the US, he campaigned for racial equality on
behalf of Asian-Americans. Nevertheless, he saw ample confirmation of the
cultural stereotype of the Japanese as an “easygoing” and “emotional”
people who possessed qualities like “lightness of heart, freedom from all
anxiety for the future, living chiefly for the present.” But by the late 20th
century, similar observers claimed that the discipline, industriousness, and
punctuality of the Japanese reflected a deep-rooted Confucian culture.
An aversion to such cultural stereotyping understandably led economists of
the late 20th century to dismiss culture as a cause of economic differences
between societies. Yet, going too far in the opposite direction may have been
a mistake. Research over the past twenty-five years has demonstrated the
insights that studying culture offers. In this chapter, we focus on recent
scholarship that has presented a more nuanced view of how and why certain
cultural traits differ across societies and what this means for economic
development. Such cultural traits include those related to trust, family
structure, individualism, and (perhaps most importantly) religion. In none of
these cases are one set of cultural traits “superior” to others, although some
do affect economic growth differently than others.
Can Culture Explain the European Take-off?
Was there something about European culture that allowed it to become
wealthy before the rest of the world? This is a thorny issue. On the one hand,
it invites ethnocentric or racist theorizing: that is, that Europeans have
something about them that is just “better”. These arguments tend to be
flawed upon even casual inspection, and we will not consider them in this
book. On the other hand, this should not dissuade us from asking whether
there are cultural attributes that may have helped propel the European take-
off in the 18th and 19th centuries. Recent research suggests that culture can
play an enormous role in all sorts of economic outcomes. We should not rule
out the possibility that culture played a role in Europe’s rise.
The answer to the question posed in the title of this section depends on one’s
assessment of how and why modern economic growth took place. To the
extent that one views the onset of sustained economic growth as a pan-
European phenomenon, then the cultural factors that we should study will be
ones common to all of Europe, or at least Western Europe. But to the extent
that one views modern economic growth as beginning in northwestern
Europe, specifically in the British Isles, then one should be most interested
in cultural traits that permeated Britain but not the rest of Europe.
Just how important are values to a society’s economic potential? Could a
society take off economically in the absence of values praising hard work,
risk taking, and wealth accumulation? McCloskey (2006, 2010, 2016) argues
that such values were essential for northwestern Europe’s take-off in the
17th and 18th centuries. According to her, one of the primary impediments
to growth in history was the way people thought and talked about work and
profit. For the ancient Greeks and Romans, for example, work of any type
was among the lowest-valued pursuits. Wealth was valued because it brought
freedom and permitted leisure (Finley, 1973). The middling classes – the
bourgeois – had little prestige in ancient society. If you were at all
successful, you were supposed to strive to own a landed estate and live off of
its returns. Indolence was what a Roman social climber strove towards.
A society with such cultural values is unlikely to have sustained economic
growth. As we will see, technological innovation is essential for growth to
persist in the long run. But innovation requires detailed knowledge of
production processes and what can make production more efficient. Any
society that frowns upon hard work will be unlikely to have a robust class of
innovators. Any society that disparages finance will be unlikely to have a
thriving entrepreneurial class or significant investment in capital. Although
the Roman Empire had a sophisticated market economy and, as we saw in
Chapter 2, a developed road network, it did not experience sustained
economic growth.
Cultural values that disparaged hard work persisted through the medieval
period, especially among the European elite. To the extent that the elite were
supposed to get their hands dirty, it was through warfare, not work. Those
lucky few from the lower classes who were able to rise up the economic
ladder were supposed to use their wealth to gain social status, perhaps by
acquiring a noble title. Once acquired, nobles were supposed to live off the
fruits of their land, leaving behind the professions that gave them their
wealth. McCloskey claims these cultural values changed in northwestern
Europe in the 17th and 18th centuries. In the Netherlands, and later in
England, the bourgeois pursuit of profit became lauded, not demonized. The
rhetoric concerning the bourgeois elevated financiers, innovators, and
merchants to a place where people aspired to these professions. Rising up
the economic ladder also placed one higher on the social ladder – it was not
simply a means to social prestige. These cultural changes, in turn,
encouraged the best and brightest to engage in productive pursuits. A class
of well-to-do merchants, financiers, and manufacturers emerged and entered
into the British elite – individuals like Sir Robert Peel (1750–1830), who
made his fortune in the textile industry before entering Parliament and
becoming a baronet, or Joseph Chamberlain (1836–1914), who was a shoe
manufacturer before becoming a politician.
On the flip side is China. For most of the last two millennia, China was the
world’s leader in technology and science. But by 1850 it had unquestionably
fallen behind Europe in technology, science, and engineering. This gave rise
to the famous Needham puzzle, named after the great British chemist and
historian Joseph Needham (1995). How did China go from being the world’s
scientific leader in ancient and medieval times to a technological laggard by
the 19th century?
One prominent answer to this question is culture. Landes (2006, p. 7)
summarized this line of thinking when he noted that China failed to “realize
the economic potential of its scientific expertise involved the larger values of
society.” While Landes does point to institutional factors such as the absence
of political competition, the power of the state, and the lack of institutions
that allowed for free debate, he dwells on cultural differences between China
and Europe. He argues that China lacked “this peculiarly European joy in
discovery…. This pleasure in the new and better…. This cultivation of
invention” (Landes, 2006, p. 9).
Does this explanation hold water? It is hard to square a Chinese cultural
disinclination for invention with the facts. For one, it does not explain the
Needham puzzle. China was the world’s innovation leader for much of the
last two millennia! In any case, the evidence in support of Landes’s assertion
is thin. The primary piece of evidence he brings to bear is the mission of
George Macartney to the Qing Empire in 1793. Qing China restricted trade
with the West and Macartney’s mission was to persuade the Qianlong
emperor of the benefits of more extensive trade with Britain. When
Macartney presented the latest manufactured goods in order to impress the
emperor, Qianlong was notoriously underwhelmed, replying: “Strange and
costly objects do not interest me…. We possess all things. I set no value on
objects strange or ingenious, and have no use for your country’s
manufactures.” As Platt (2018, p. 97) relates, however, this statement need
not represent a negative cultural attitude towards science and innovation:
Privately, … Qianlong was deeply fascinated by Western inventions.
[He] had a cherished collection of seventy intricate English clocks
gathered over the years, and had written poetry on the loveliness of
foreign glass as well as several poems about telescopes. He periodically
addressed edicts to the customs commissioner in Canton asking him to
send European goods or artisans to the capital. He was a patron of the
Catholic missionaries he employed at court as astronomers and
cartographers, and though he allowed them little freedom, he valued the
skills they brought. When James Dinwiddie was assembling the
scientific equipment that Qianlong would so publicly dismiss, he did so
without knowing that the emperor had actually ordered the missionaries
to watch closely what Dinwiddie was doing so they could replicate his
work after he was gone.
The problem with Landes’s argument is not that there is no evidence of a
cultural disinclination towards innovation or new ideas in 18th-century
China. Rather, Landes does not provide a systematic explanation for the
differential incentives facing rulers and intellectuals in China versus Europe.
No European ruler in the 18th century would have acted as the Qianlong
emperor did. But this may be better explained by geopolitics than by culture.
In the late 18th century, China still did not have to fear any serious military
competition. Qianlong’s focus was on maintaining order within his empire.
As a Manchu outsider, it was more important for him to pose as a guarantor
of traditional Confucian culture than it was to acquire technologies from a
foreign power.
Does Religion Affect Economic Growth?
Another cultural feature that can impact economic growth is religion. While
social scientists have largely eschewed simplistic theories stating that certain
religions are the reason some (Protestant) societies are ahead or other
(Muslim) societies are behind, recent research suggests there are more subtle
ways that religion can affect economic growth. These include incentivizing
education, affecting family formation through marriage regulations, and
impacting political development. This section examines the leading theories
tying religion to economic growth.
The Protestant Work Ethic and the “Spirit” of
Capitalism
Perhaps the most famous argument that “culture matters” was made by
Weber (1905/1930) in The Protestant Ethic and the “Spirit” of Capitalism.
According to Weber’s hypothesis, the Calvinist doctrine of predestination –
which stated that one’s eternal fate was decided regardless of one’s actions
on earth – encouraged people to work harder and save more. This is how
they would show that they were one of the “elect” who would enter heaven.
This ideal became secularized in places with Calvinist influence (the US, the
Netherlands) and was the root of a “capitalist spirit” that permeated these
societies. For Weber, people like Benjamin Franklin were the ideal type
exhibiting the capitalist spirit. They were hard-working, organized, frugal,
and always engaged in productive pursuits (never mind that Franklin often
indulged in the luxuries of life).
The inspiration for Weber’s hypothesis came from his home in Germany,
where Protestants seemed to do much better than Catholics. This correlation
extended beyond Germany, though. Since the 16th century, the world’s
leading economy has been Protestant: the Dutch Republic from the late 16th
through early 18th centuries, Great Britain from the 18th through early 20th
centuries, and the US since. More generally, Protestantism is strongly and
positively correlated with modern per capita GDP, while the correlation is
weaker for Catholicism and negative for Islam (see Figure 4.2). But is
Weber’s causal argument correct? Did Protestantism (and specifically
Calvinism) cause economic growth via some capitalist work ethic, or is this
just a case of “correlation does not equal causation”?
Figure 4.2 Percentage Protestant, Catholic, and Muslim vs. per capita GDP
Data sources: Rubin (2017) for religion shares, Bolt and van Zanden (2020) for GDP per
capita. Every country is listed three times, once for each of the religions.
Societies with an individualistic culture are not able to punish cheaters this
way. Instead, they must set up institutions to do this and to facilitate trust.
Such institutions are costly to establish, and they may not be worth it when
the scale of trade is small. However, as more trade opportunities arise, the
benefits of establishing such institutions may be high enough to convince
individualistic societies to adopt them. Once in place, these institutions
permit trade with a much larger set of potential exchange partners.
On the other hand, what was once an advantage in kin-based societies
becomes a disadvantage. Since their networks are kin-based, there is little
incentive to adopt costly, impersonal institutions. Yet, by not doing so, they
limit their trade partners to those within the kin group, forgoing trade with
much of the outside world. The consequences for economic growth are clear.
As inter-regional trade became more widespread and lucrative, those
societies that were able to take advantage of trading with as many partners as
possible grew, while those that remained confined to old (kin-based) trade
networks stagnated.
A similar argument can be applied to China. The clan was the key unit in
China for risk sharing and resource pooling. Clan members supported each
other in time of need and brought resources together for bigger projects. This
was rooted in a Confucian ideology that was centered on clan-based
obligations. This meant that there was little demand for larger financial
markets that could distribute capital more broadly (Chen, Ma, and Sinclair,
forthcoming). Why engage with someone you cannot trust when there are a
bunch of your kin for you to deal with? This was not the case in Western
Europe, where there were no larger family units to provide access to capital.
Eventually, financial markets emerged in Europe to fill this void (Greif and
Tabellini, 2017).
The importance of individualistic culture extends beyond the type of trade
and financial institutions a society has. Individualistic culture rewards
personal achievement. It stands to reason that innovators therefore gain
greater social status in individualistic societies than they do in collectivist
societies. Gorodnichenko and Roland (2011, 2017) find that societies that
are more individualistic have much higher income per worker, and much of
this comes from greater productivity and innovation. This is important: as
we will see in Chapters 7 and 8, innovation is one of the keys to modern,
sustained economic growth.
The Persistence of Trust Norms
Economists have long recognized that trust is an integral part of economic
exchange. Trust is important because most exchange is sequential. One party
gives the other party something, with the expectation that the latter will give
something back in return, possibly at a later date (Greif, 2000). We discussed
this in Chapter 3 in the context of the fundamental problem of exchange.
This is as true today as it was in the past. When you buy something online,
you provide your credit card number, and then money is immediately taken
from your account. The online merchant is then supposed to send you
whatever you purchased over the course of the next few days. But what if
they do not send it to you? They already have your money. Especially if they
never expect to sell to you again, why should they send you the goods?
In the example of the online retailer, it is obvious why they would send the
goods to you. Any company that regularly cheated customers like this would
be sued and made to pay damages. They would also get a bad reputation and
would likely not be in business for long. But court systems and means of
reputation building have not always been available. In their absence, why
would one trust that the entity they are dealing with will fulfill their end of
the bargain?
This is where trust comes in. If I trust that the online merchant is not going
to cheat me – regardless of my ability to sue – then I may go through with
the exchange. Of course, the merchant also needs to be likely to come
through on his or her promises. This is why societies that have high levels of
trust tend to do better economically (Tabellini, 2010). Trust enables mutually
beneficial exchanges that would not otherwise occur. In the words of Arrow
(1972, p. 357): “Virtually every commercial transaction has within itself an
element of trust, certainly any transaction conducted over a period of time. It
can be plausibly argued that much of the economic backwardness in the
world can be explained by the lack of mutual confidence.” Perhaps variation
in trust across countries can help explain why some countries are rich and
others are poor? Social scientists have in fact frequently noted differences in
trust across countries. People in richer countries are both more trusting and
more trustworthy than people in poorer countries (see Figure 4.6).
The question is: why are some societies more trusting than others? Trust
does not come from thin air. People are more trusting in environments that
are safer and when the likelihood of being cheated is lower. So, on the one
hand, levels of trust might reflect institutional quality rather than a separate
and identifiable cultural trait. On the other hand, recent work by economists
and political scientists has also shown that trust norms tend to persist long
after the reason they emerged in the first place. Thus, historical events which
affected trust in the past may help explain economic prosperity today.
Natural experiments can help parse out the role of history in the
development of trust norms as opposed to modern factors like contemporary
institutions. Natural experiments, like the partition of Korea discussed in
Chapter 3, occur when some people in a population are “treated” with some
event and others are not, much like a clinical trial in a medical experiment.
History is full of natural experiments, often due to shifting national borders.
One day, a group is under the dominion of one state, the next day part of the
population is under the dominion of another. If there is reason to believe that
this change might affect trust, we can compare people on opposite sides of
the border to see whether trust was indeed affected by the border change and
whether these differences persisted. For instance, Becker, Boeckh, Hainz,
and Woessmann (2016) find that people who live on the Habsburg side of
the old Habsburg–Ottoman–Russian border trust government officials,
courts, and police more in the present day. In the 18th and 19th centuries, the
Habsburgs provided public services more efficiently than their eastern
neighbors, increasing trust in government. The fact that these trust norms
exist in the present day strongly suggests that cultural norms persist after
their original cause is long gone.
Figure 4.6 The relationship between trust and per capita GDP
Data sources: Inglehart, Haerpfer, Moreno, Welzel, Kizilova, Diez-Medrano, et al. (2018) for
trust data, Bolt and van Zanden (2020) for per capita GDP data. Qatar dropped to make the rest
of the data more visible.
Lowes, Nunn, Robinson, and Weigel (2017) find evidence for the persistence
of cultural norms in a study of rule following by individuals living on
opposite sides of the old borders of the Kuba Kingdom, a state established in
the early 17th century in what is now the Democratic Republic of the Congo.
Contrary to expectations that the presence of a relatively powerful state
might have encouraged and reinforced pro-social norms, they find that Kuba
descendants are less likely to follow rules and more likely to steal. They
reason was that those living under Kuba rule had less need to generate norms
of rule following. Those who did not follow rules could be punished by the
institutions of the kingdom. Again, a key takeaway is that culture persists
long after the institutional and political environment under which it emerged
has changed.
Gender Norms
Most societies in history have had cultural norms that restrict the capacity of
women to work. For this reason, it is possible that women have historically
been the greatest untapped source of potential economic growth. Yet,
although most societies have restricted women in one way or another, some
societies placed greater restrictions than others. Why?
Cultural norms regarding female labor likely date to the Neolithic
Revolution, which saw the spread of settled agriculture. Boserup (1970)
argued that plow agriculture precipitated the emergence of a sharp gender
division of labor. Plows required significant upper body and grip strength,
both of which favored men over women. As a result, men gained significant
bargaining power over women in societies practicing plow agriculture. It is
therefore possible that gender norms favoring men emerged in such
societies.
Alesina, Giuliano, and Nunn (2013) tested this hypothesis. They document
that a social norm arose in societies with plow agriculture whereby men
worked outdoors in the field and women were confined indoors. The sexual
division of labor that arose in plow-dominant agricultural civilizations
proved to be self-reinforcing. In societies where grain provided the majority
of calories and society was organized around agriculture, the fact that
women played a subordinate role in the agrarian economy reinforced their
inferior social status. The evidence provided by Alesina, Giuliano, and Nunn
testifies to the persistence of these norms even today, in societies where the
vast majority of people work outside agriculture. In the 21st century,
societies with more traditional plow use have lower female labor
participation, lower female firm ownership, and less female participation in
politics (see Figure 4.7). Alesina, Giuliano, and Nunn also show that the
children of immigrants living in the US and Europe exhibit more unequal
beliefs about gender if their parents came from a country with a heritage of
plow use. Similarly, Fernández and Fogli (2009) find that the work and
fertility behavior of second-generation American women is affected by
gender cultural norms in the country of their ancestry. Combined, these
results point to a detrimental consequence of social norms that persist long
after the reason they emerged in the first place was relevant.
Cultural attitudes towards female labor can also shift due to economic
change. For instance, Xue (2020) studies the introduction in China of the
treadle-operated spindle wheel, which tripled the productivity of female
cotton spinners beginning in 1300. In cotton textile producing regions,
female incomes rose substantially. Their earning power increased many
times over, to the point where female incomes were comparable to or even
greater than those of men. Consequently, women began to be seen as more
important members of society. Pomeranz (2005) uses the term “economics
of respectability” to describe women’s rising status. For parents, as women
became productive members of the economy in their own right, it became
less financially costly to have a daughter. The prospect of daughters being
self-sufficient lowered the cost of having them. Xue (2020) provides
evidence that cultural attitudes towards women were transformed in the
affected counties. Today, in counties with pre-modern cotton textile
production, sex ratios are less biased against women. Additionally,
individuals in counties with pre-modern cotton textile production are more
likely to disagree with the statement that men are naturally more capable, or
that women should focus on family, and are more likely to have preference
for daughters over sons.
Figure 4.7 Traditional plow use, female labor force participation, and female
firm ownership
Data source: Alesina, Giuliano, and Nunn (2013).
The status of women mattered for economic growth in the past and continues
to do so. The studies cited above show how cultural norms may have been a
channel through which female status affected economic growth. We will
return to a discussion of gender and economic growth in Chapter 5, which
studies demographic trends and investment in human capital.
Chapter Summary
This chapter summarized the growing literature on the role that culture plays
in economic growth. Recent cultural explanations are much more nuanced
than those of the early 20th century, which were Eurocentric at best and
racist at worst. Modern theories tend to think of culture in the way that
anthropologists view culture: it is those aspects of society which forms
people’s worldview. This shapes how people respond to incentives, how they
interact with others, how and whom they marry, how many children they
have, and so on. Modern economic studies of culture focus on things such as
the role of trust, gender norms, and marriage norms in determining
outcomes. Religion may also affect economic development, often through its
effect on politics or law. One key reason that culture can affect long-run
economic development is that it persists. Even after the reasons certain
cultural traits emerged are long a thing of the past, they tend to shape the
outlook of the descendants of those past societies. For this reason, culture
tends to interact with some of the other determinants of long-run economic
development, such as institutions and demography. As we shall see in
Chapter 7, these interactions are at the heart of most societies’ long-run
economic trajectories, for both good and bad.
5
Fewer Babies?
It is January 24, 1700. A cold winter air blows through Westminster Abbey
in the center of London. Even open fires and coal braziers struggle against
the winter chill. Princess Anne, heir to the throne of England, is silently
sobbing into her bedclothes, surrounded by her maids and ladies-in-waiting.
Anne had miscarried again. Though only 33, this was her seventeenth and
last pregnancy. She had not produced a living heir. Of her four live births,
only one outlived early childhood. But Prince William died aged 11 of
pneumonia, having been bled and blistered by his doctors. We do not know
the reasons for Anne’s failed pregnancies. But her own health was fragile.
Historians have suggested that she may have suffered from a host of
ailments including Lupus, diabetes, or Rhesus autoimmunization (Emson,
1992). By her early thirties, she suffered from severe gout, which would
prevent her from walking and ensured she would have to be carried to her
coronation in 1702. Anne would die at 49.
Anne could afford the best medical treatment of her time. But it hardly
availed her and her family. Her mother only lived to 34. Her sister Mary died
at 32 of smallpox. Anne’s tale was not uncommon. Even for the rich, life in
the pre-industrial world was dominated by births, deaths, and disease.
This is clearly no longer the case. Even in the poorest parts of the world, life
expectancy is higher than it was in the wealthiest parts of the world during
Anne’s time. In 1703, average life expectancy in England was 38.5 years
(Roser, 2021c). In 2015, no country in the world had an average life
expectancy less than 51 years (see Figure 5.1). What changed? Might these
changes have affected growth?
For most of human history, families had many children, a few of whom
would make it to adulthood. These conditions led Thomas Malthus
(1798/2007) to famously conclude that this was the permanent condition of
humanity. He reasoned that most people would not be able to eke out much
more than a subsistence living. Malthus wrote in the late 18th century and
was not wrong about the human condition up to that point in time. His ideas
relating demography to economic development explain much about the pre-
industrial economy. But they cannot account for the incredible
transformations in the human condition that have arisen in the last two
centuries. What changed?
In this chapter, we discuss the role that demography played in making some
parts of the world rich. We consider the theories of Malthus and consider the
extent to which the world he envisioned aptly describes the economic
realities of our ancestors. Then we ask: how did some parts of the world first
moderate and then escape the forces Malthus highlighted? What factors
made a transition from a Malthusian world to modern growth possible? In
particular, how did demographic change lead to investments in education
and human capital, and how did these investments foster economic growth?
Malthusian Pressures
The most frequently cited cause of persistent poverty in the pre-industrial
world is population pressure. There were simply too many mouths to feed.
This theory is most commonly attributed to Malthus (1798/2007, p. 13), who
put it succinctly:
That population cannot increase without the means of subsistence is a
proposition so evident that it needs no illustration.
That population does invariably increase where there are the means of
subsistence, the history of every people that have ever existed will
abundantly prove.
And that the superior power of population cannot be checked without
producing misery or vice, the ample portion of these too bitter
ingredients in the cup of human life and the continuance of the physical
causes that seem to have produced them bear too convincing a
testimony.
To explain these principles Malthus proposed a simple model:
Ashraf and Galor (2011) show that a Malthusian framework explains many
features of the world up to 1500. Specifically, they find that countries that
underwent the agricultural transition earlier had more productive land and
higher population densities in 1500. But they did not necessarily have higher
per capita incomes.
Yet, Malthusian forces operated gradually and in conjunction with other
factors. Even in a Malthusian environment there is variation in living
standards and economic growth is possible. As we saw in earlier chapters,
there were periods of relative prosperity in pre-modern Europe. There were
also episodes when per capita income rose well above subsistence in
Classical Greece, the Roman Empire, and Song China.
The fact that the long-run dynamics of the world economy are broadly
consistent with the Malthusian model does not mean that Malthusian
dynamics provide a complete explanation of short- or medium-run growth
fluctuations. The Malthusian feedback mechanism operated gradually and a
given economy could be “out of equilibrium” for many decades or longer.
Other factors such as epidemics of contagious diseases and warfare impacted
pre-industrial populations much more rapidly and with greater effect than
did gradual Malthusian feedback loops. The result was that pre-industrial
societies fluctuated around their Malthusian equilibrium, but sometimes with
significant variation.
The Black Death
How can we test whether the Malthusian model had any bite in the pre-
modern world? One way would be to see what happens following a massive
demographic shock. The most famous – and deadly – example of such a
shock was the Black Death, which ravaged much of the world in the mid-
14th century.
The Black Death was the most deadly pathogen to ever hit Europe and Asia.
Contemporaries estimated that a third of the world’s population died. For
much of the 20th century, historians scoffed at such high figures and
suggested that the overall mortality must have been significantly lower, say
5 or 10%. Recent research, however, confirms the higher previous estimates,
with some historians going as far to argue that as much as 60% of the
population in Western Europe may have died (Benedictow, 2005).
Scientists have identified the bacterium that caused the Black Death as
Yersinia pestis, or bubonic plague. As Europe and the Middle East had been
spared plague outbreaks for centuries, their populations had little or no
immunity to the disease. It was transmitted to Europe from Kaffa in the
modern Crimea, and from there to Italy and Western Europe. The mortality
rate of the disease was not related to pre-existing characteristics. At least as
many died in the countryside as in the cities. Southern Europe and the
Mediterranean were hit especially hard, and so were the British Isles (see
Figure 5.4).
The medieval population of Europe peaked in the early 14th century, several
decades before the Black Death. Between 1315 and 1322, excessive summer
rains led to successive harvest failures. As a result, a terrible famine swept
through much of Northern Europe. Bruce Campbell (2010, p. 287) describes
it as possibly “the single worst subsistence crisis, in terms of relative
mortality, in recorded European history.” It was accompanied by a bovine
plague that wiped out livestock. The population barely had time to recover
before the Black Death struck. As a consequence, the population of England
fell from between 4.5 and 6 million in 1300 to around 2 million by the
middle of the 15th century (Smith, 1991; Campbell, 2010). A similar
population collapse occurred throughout Europe (see Table 5.1) and the
Middle East.
Figure 5.4 Black Death mortality rates (%) in 1347–52
Notes: This map plots the location of all existing cities (i.e. localities ≥ 1,000 inhabitants) in
1300 for which we know their Black Death mortality rate (%) in 1347–52 as well as the modern
boundaries of eighteen Western European countries.
Source: Jedwab, Johnson, and Koyama (2019).
One example of the preventive check was the practice of late marriages. For
women, teenage marriage was common in many parts of the world since the
dawn of the institution of marriage. However, in parts of late medieval
Europe, women tended to marry in their mid-twenties. Hajnal (1965) labeled
this practice the European Marriage Pattern (EMP). This marriage pattern,
which was characteristic of most of Europe in 1900, had its origins in
northwestern Europe several hundred years earlier. Common in Scandinavia,
the British Isles, the Low Countries, Germany, and northern France, it was
less evident in Southern Europe and entirely absent in Eastern Europe. Why
might this marriage pattern matter for economic growth?
Before the modern period, female age at marriage was important in
determining aggregate fertility (see Figure 5.6). Childbirth outside of
marriage was rare. But birth control within marriage was not widely
practiced. Since fertility within marriage remained high, aggregate fertility
was significantly reduced by delayed marriages. Every two years a woman
was not married reduced the number of children she had, on average, by one
child. Malthusian theory therefore suggests that the EMP helped keep per
capita incomes higher than they would have otherwise been. Some scholars
have gone further and argued that the EMP could have played a decisive role
in the transition to modern economic growth. We consider both claims here.
Figure 5.6 Fertility and female age of marriage in England, 1590s–1830s
Data sources: Wrigley, Davies, Oeppen, and Schofield (1997, p. 130) and Galor (2005).
The EMP was associated with small, nuclear households, based on a single
married couple. After marriage, the husband left his parents’ home and
became the head of a new household. Prior to marriage, young people
worked in other households as servants or wage laborers. While working,
“women were not under the control of any male relative. They made
independent decisions about where to live and work and for which
employer” (Hajnal, 1982, p. 475). This contrasts sharply with pre-industrial
societies outside of northwestern Europe. There, joint households,
comprising two or more married couples, were common. These households
were characterized by universal and early marriage and high fertility.
These two systems reacted differently to population pressure. In joint
households, an increase in the population might increase the
underemployment of married adults. In contrast, in northwestern Europe,
population pressure would have simply caused delayed marriages. The
characteristics of the EMP can therefore be summarized as follows:
Many of the costs of the slave trades were not directly economic. The
psychological costs of being enslaved are incalculable. The sociological
costs of what the slave trades did to African communities, as well as the
damage done to slave families torn apart in the New World, may well be
greater than the economic costs of forgone development. Yet, this does not
mean that we should be uninterested in the economic costs of the slave
trades. They play a significant role in Africa’s continued poverty. Nunn
(2008) finds that countries that had high levels of slave “exports” (an
unfortunate term when speaking of human beings) have lower GDP, greater
ethnic fractionalization (which itself is associated with lower income in
numerous economic studies), and worse political institutions (see Figure
6.4). The gap grew following the collapse of European colonial rule.
Between 1950 and 2000, the per capita GDP of high slave export countries
was nearly constant (at a low level of less than $3 a day), while the per
capita GDP of low slave export countries nearly doubled from around $4 to
$8 a day. This suggests that the slave trades might be responsible for both
the relative poverty of sub-Saharan Africa and differences of income within
Africa. But the slave trades have ceased to exist for well over a century. Why
would their residue still be with us?
One reason the slave trades still affects outcomes is that they shaped the
culture of societies damaged by them. As we noted in Chapter 4, culture can
persist long after the original impetus for the cultural trait has disappeared.
One of the most lasting cultural impacts of slavery arose from the way in
which slaves were captured. Some were captured through state-organized
raids and warfare, while many others were kidnapped or tricked into slavery
by people such as close friends or family members. This produced a culture
of mistrust and uncertainty in those regions affected by the slave trades.
Nunn and Wantchekon (2011) found that people whose ancestors belonged
to ethnic groups that were heavily exposed to the slave trades still have
lower trust today of relatives, neighbors, co-ethnics, and local government.
This negatively impacted Africa’s economic development and may explain
some of Nunn’s results cited above linking the slave trades to long-run
economic outcomes. As we noted in Chapter 4, trust is a crucial component
of exchange, especially with previously unknown persons. The dearth of
trust in sub-Saharan Africa, engendered by the slave trades, is therefore an
impediment to the region’s development.
Other consequences of the slave trades abound. Whatley and Gillezeau
(2011) find that places more heavily affected by them have higher ethnic
fractionalization today. That is, there are more ethnic groups living in close
proximity to each other in these regions. Africa does in fact have many
ethnic groups (see Figure 6.5). But what does this have to do with the slave
trades? The logic is straight-forward: where slave raiding was profitable,
local groups would raid each other rather than form larger, cohesive states.
Ties across villages and ethnic groups were weakened. Inter-ethnic alliances
and marriages were less common. This led to more ethnic groups over time.
Figure 6.4 The relationship between slaves exported and economic
indicators
Data sources: Nunn (2008) for slave exports and state development, Bolt and van Zanden
(2020) for GDP.
Figure 6.5 Africa’s ethnic boundaries prior to colonization
Data source: Nunn (2008).
There are many reasons that ethnic fractionalization might be negatively
associated with economic growth. In fractionalized states, some groups rule
over others. This can be disastrous, especially if these groups have a history
of animosity towards each other. In these settings, fractionalization can cause
civil conflict, less public good provision, and lower trust. In fact, Easterly
and Levine (1997) find that ethnic fractionalization is responsible for around
25% of the differences in African and Asian economic growth. As the results
of Whatley and Gillezeau (2011) suggest, this may be a residue of the slave
trades.
The Resource Grab
From the point of view of long-run economic growth, perhaps the most
damaging aspect of colonialism was the institutions the colonizers
established. As we saw in Chapter 3, institutions can be hard to change.
They also tend to stick around well beyond the time their original purpose is
relevant. This can be really bad for economic development if the original
institutions were exploitative in the first place.
European colonizers mostly set up institutions in their colonies to maximize
the amount of resources extracted. Some of these institutions built off of
institutions that were there prior to colonization. Others were completely
new to the environment. Extraction often required forced labor and brutal
means of suppression. In the Belgian Congo, for instance, local chiefs were
given rubber quotas. If coerced laborers failed to meet these quotas, they
could be imprisoned, burned, or murdered (Lowes and Montero,
forthcoming). The Spanish set up similar forced labor institutions in their
South American colonies, where natives were forced to work in silver mines
– most notably in Potosi. These institutions were extractive. Their primary
purpose was to extract resources, most of which went back to the colonizing
country.
Where extractive institutions were established, rights for the native
population were limited (if they existed at all), and investments in public
goods tended to be restricted to those that facilitated extraction (such as
roads leading from mines to ports). Unfortunately, many post-colonial
governments found these extractive institutions useful as well. As a result,
these institutions often persisted after independence. This is one of the
reasons why “bad” governance – in terms of checks and balances and
freedoms secured – is more common in the formerly colonized world than in
Western Europe. However, not all of the former colonies got bad institutions.
For instance, Australia, New Zealand, Canada, and the US all have
institutions that place limits on the extractive ability of the state. Why did
some colonies end up with “good” institutions and others end up with “bad”
ones?
Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001) were among the first to offer a
comprehensive answer for the large variation in contemporary institutional
quality and economic outcomes in the former colonies. They argue that
colonizers set up different types of institutions depending on how frequently
settlers died in the colonies. In places with climates poorly suited for
European settlement – such as Africa’s “malaria belt,” where European
mortality rates were extremely high – the incentive for Europeans was to
extract as much as they could. There was little reason to set up European-
style institutions, since this would limit their capacity to exploit the native
populations. On the other hand, in more temperate climates similar to those
found in Europe – such as the US or the east coast of Australia – there was
more incentive for Europeans to settle. As more Europeans came over, they
brought with them the type of legal, political, and religious institutions that
were so vital to their continent’s economic growth. The analysis conducted
by Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson supports these relationships. They
find that places with higher settler mortality still have worse institutions
today, and those places with worse institutions are also poorer (see Figure
6.6). This might also be responsible for the “reversal of fortunes” that they
found in a follow-up study (Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson, 2002:
discussed in Chapter 1, see Figure 1.8). Those places that were the
wealthiest in the world in 1500 were among the poorest by the end of the
20th century. It was precisely those places with easily exploitable natural
resources that got the bad colonial institutions associated with poor long-run
economic development.
Figure 6.6 Settler mortality, institutions, and long-run development
Data source: Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001) for settler mortality and expropriation
risk, Bolt and van Zanden (2020) for GDP.
Sokoloff and Engerman (2000) argue that the reversal of fortunes was
especially pronounced in the Americas, where places with good agricultural
suitability – the Caribbean, large parts of Latin America, and the southern
US – got institutions that strongly favored a small landholding elite. These
institutions brought wealth to the elite, but also caused tremendous
inequality, much of which is still present today. On the other hand, the more
marginal farming lands of the northern US and Canada were poorly suited
for growing cash crops. Instead of relying on the exploitation of the native
population, these colonies relied on laborers of European descent with
relatively high levels of human capital. Institutions favoring local enterprise,
rather than cash crops and labor exploitation, arose in these areas and have
largely persisted to the present day. Bruhn and Gallego (2012) provide a
slightly alternative view, arguing that labor-exploiting institutions in the
Americas are associated with a lack of political representation in the present.
Areas exploited in the past still have less political voice today. This enables
more rent-seeking by the plutocratic class and lower overall economic
development.
The resource grab was the dominant theme of Spanish colonization in South
America. Its mines provided a large share of the world’s precious metals in
the 16th and 17th centuries. Mining is a dangerous, labor-intensive
enterprise, hence, the Spanish forced natives to do this work. One of the
most pernicious institutions that facilitated this forced labor was the mita, a
system that required indigenous communities to send one-seventh of their
adult male populations to work in the mines. Dell (2010) found that those
living within the old mita boundaries have less consumption and worse
health today, despite the fact that the mita was abolished in 1812. This is
likely due to the type of colonial institutions set up in mita areas. There was
less education provided, less connection to the system of roads, and
increased subsistence farming. All of these persist in some form to the
present day and continue to hold back the economic potential of former mita
regions.
Another example comes from the Belgian Congo. Belgian King Leopold II
(r. 1865–1909) set up one of the most extractive colonies of the entire
colonial period. As discussed above, local chiefs were given rubber quotas,
and violence was likely if the quotas were not met. Ultimately, this meant
that the chiefs who were most prone to enforce rubber quotas by
transgressing the rights of their people stayed in power. This is a prototypical
“bad” institutional design. Its effects are still present today. Lowes and
Montero (forthcoming) find that places that were in the rubber concession
zone have much worse education, wealth, and health outcomes than those
that were not. The most likely reason is that village chiefs in these regions –
many of whose positions are hereditary – are still less likely to provide local
public goods like road maintenance and conflict arbitration.
Colonial institutions were established not only to extract natural resources,
but also to tax the local populations. How these taxation systems worked
was important. Some gave significant power to local authorities in return for
tax collection. This tended to be bad for long-run economic development.
Local power brokers wanted to keep their rents flowing after independence,
and thus extractive institutions tended to persist. Banerjee and Iyer (2005)
studied these taxation institutions in colonial India. They found that, even
decades after independence, places in which rights were given to local
landlords continued to have greater inequality, lower agricultural
productivity, and less investment in health and education. These differences
were mostly due to differences in government spending. Places where
landlords dominated in the past tend to irrigate and fertilize less in the
present, leading to lower crop yields (see Figure 6.7).
India provides a fertile testing ground for examining the effects of colonial
rule. Not only was it by far the most populous of the European colonies
(colonial India also included modern-day Pakistan and Bangladesh), but only
parts of it were ruled by the British. The rest of the subcontinent, known as
the “Princely States” because they were ruled by local princes, maintained
some degree of political autonomy. Iyer (2010) found that areas that were
formerly under British rule have much less access to schools, health centers,
and roads. They are also no better off in terms of agricultural productivity or
investment. One explanation for these results is that local princes funneled
less tax revenue into their own pockets than did the British, instead spending
more on public goods. Another reason is that the British removed the worst
princes in the colonial period. This gave an incentive for princes to be
relatively good rulers. It is not clear if this result extends beyond India,
however. Lange (2004), on the other hand, finds that former British colonies
that were under direct rule (that is, they were ruled by the British
administrative apparatus) tend to have more political stability, bureaucratic
effectiveness, rule of law, and freedom from government corruption than do
those that were under indirect rule (like the Princely States).
Another set of negative consequences from colonization stemmed from poor
political design. Colonial powers sought to rule groups of people they knew
relatively little about. This led to some disastrous decisions. In the US,
Native Americans were placed on reservations at the tribal level. However,
most Native American political decisions were historically determined at the
sub-tribal level. Dippel (2014) studied the impact of this forced coexistence
on Native American tribes and found that reservations that combined
multiple sub-tribal bands are around 30% poorer today than those that did
not. The primary explanation is poor local governance. These reservations
have more political corruption and internal conflict, while having less
certainty about the contracting environment and less investment by local
government.
Michalopoulos and Papaioannou (2016) find further evidence of poor
colonial political design in the “scramble for Africa.” In the late 19th
century, much of sub-Saharan Africa remained among the last places on
earth that had not come under some type of colonial rule. The European
powers sought to change this. Meeting in a board-room in Berlin (the Berlin
Conference of 1884–5), they partitioned Africa among Great Britain, France,
Germany, Italy, Belgium, Portugal, and Spain. The people in charge of
dividing Africa into spheres of influence had little knowledge of the
continent. The consequences were disastrous. The colonial powers gave little
thought to pre-existing ethnic divisions. They just wanted to maximize their
own share of the pie. This meant that rival ethnic groups were placed in the
same states – a situation that continued after independence as these colonial
borders largely remained. Michalopoulos and Papaioannou find that these
partitions (which affected many ethnic groups throughout Africa: see Figure
6.8) triggered political violence, political instability, discrimination, and
ethnic wars. This was bound to happen in an environment where some ethnic
groups rule over others, especially when there is a long history of animosity
between them. Michalopoulos and Papaioannou also find that ethnically
partitioned groups are worse off on a host of economic outcomes, including
education and wealth.
Figure 6.7 Agricultural investment in India
Data source: Banerjee and Iyer (2005).
On the other end of Eurasia, the Western European city most exposed to the
steppe (Vienna) is as far from the steppe as the least exposed major city in
China (Guangzhou). The “steppe threat” was therefore not nearly as potent
in Western Europe. But this did not relieve Europe from invasion. On the
contrary, settled people in post-Roman Europe could be invaded from
multiple directions. And indeed they were: Huns, Avars, Magyars, Arabs,
Moors, and Vikings invaded Europe for centuries from nearly every
direction. Any prospective empire builder in Europe would thus face a
multidimensional threat that would strain his resources. This is one reason
why attempts to build a large centralized state in Europe failed after the fall
of the Roman Empire.
Why did Europe’s persistent political fragmentation matter? From the point
of view of Smithian economic growth, introduced in Chapter 2, empires
could be good news. The Roman Empire was able to create a fairly unified
market economy that spanned the Mediterranean. It suppressed piracy,
limited internal trade duties, and introduced a standardized monetary system
(Temin, 2006). Similarly, the “Pax Islamica” and the “Pax Mongolica”
allowed trade to thrive in the Middle East and Central Asia for centuries.
Chinese dynasties also invested in transport infrastructure, as we saw in
Chapter 2. From estimates for the mid-18th century, we know that levels of
price integration in China were relatively high (Shiue and Keller, 2007;
though it declined quite sharply in the late 18th century – see Bernhofen, Li,
Eberhardt, and Morgan, 2020). In contrast, Europe’s endemic fragmentation
was accompanied by frequent warfare which often disrupted inter-regional
trade.
But European fragmentation also had positive and unforeseeable
consequences. Scholars dating back to Montesquieu (1748/1989) and Hume
(1762) have argued that the most important consequences of Europe’s
fragmentation were institutional. As we saw in Chapter 3, Scheidel (2019)
argued that the failure of European rulers to rebuild a continent-wide empire
after the fall of Rome resulted in a period of economic decline and military
weakness – the so-called “Dark Ages” – but it also laid the foundations for
long-run economic growth.
The polities that succeeded the Roman Empire in Western Europe were
weak. They lacked the ability to tax their populations or provide basic goods.
As a consequence, political power became unbundled from economic and
military power. Ideological power became the near-monopoly of the
Catholic Church. The separation of sovereignty between rulers, the Church,
and the nobility was an important precondition for the emergence of
parliaments, independent cities, and other representative institutions that we
discussed in Chapter 3. These dispersed pockets of power were unique to
Europe in the medieval period. Ironically enough, it was the very weakness
of European rulers that allowed these alternative sources of power to arise.
Within states, it meant that rulers had to cede more to elites to stay in power
(Blaydes and Chaney, 2013; Salter and Young, 2019). It also meant that
there was more interstate competition, which gave impetus to economic,
political, scientific, and technological breakthroughs (Hoffman, 2015;
Mokyr, 2016; Scheidel, 2019; Kitamura and Lagerlöf, 2020). As we shall
discuss below, these were important preconditions for future economic
growth.
Why Was There No Medieval European Take-off?
During the 11th and 12th centuries, self-governing or independent cities
emerged on the edges of what had been the Carolingian Empire – in northern
Italy, the Low Countries and then later in the Rhineland and northern
Germany. As we saw in Chapter 3, the absence of a single strong ruler
enabled merchants to rise to political prominence. They implemented
reforms that favored their own interests but also, by and large, were
favorable to the overall expansion of trade. This made possible the European
Commercial Revolution. The new cities were manufacturing centers and
trade entrepôts. Trading networks based on the market economy emerged in
the absence of a central authority. These cities were characterized by what
McCloskey (2006) calls “bourgeois values.”
Unlike in either the Byzantine Empire, the Islamic world, or China, Europe’s
political polycentricity allowed for multiple sources of power. In addition to
merchants, the Catholic Church took on an unprecedented political role. This
had important intellectual and cultural consequences. For instance,
Fukuyama (2011) notes the role the Church played in undermining the
claims of clans and extended families. Focusing on the emergence of the
individual, Siedentop (2014) sees Christianity as critical to the emergence of
liberal societies. The research we touched on in Chapter 4 by Schulz,
Bahramni-Rad, Beauchamp, and Henrich (2019), Henrich (2020), and
Schulz (2020) provides empirical support for the specific claim that the
Church undermined traditional kinship networks. They link the Church’s
prohibition on cousin marriage to the formation of medieval communes. It
was precisely in these communes that the great medieval city-states were
born. These were the political units that relieved Europe of its post-Roman
economic doldrums. It is difficult to see how such independent, free cities
could have emerged under the thumb of the type of strong ruler who ruled
over much of the rest of Eurasia.
If the preconditions for sustained economic growth emerged in the medieval
period, why didn’t Europe take off then? Medieval Europe did experience
several centuries of growth during the Commercial Revolution. Could these
developments have led to sustained economic growth in the Middle Ages?
What was holding the medieval European economy back?
Answering these questions with certainty is impossible. In history, we lack
controlled experiments. For example, we do not know how the European
economy would have developed had Europe not been hit by the Black Death
(as discussed in Chapter 5). The Black Death may have had positive
institutional implications in the long run, but its immediate impact on trade
and the medieval economy as a whole was devastating. In any case, it is
possible that the medieval economy was already on the verge of crisis prior
to the Black Death. Many medieval historians have long thought that an
economic crisis was all but inevitable even before the Black Death struck
(Postan, 1973).
Economic growth did occur in the Middle Ages. But it was not sustained,
and it was prone to reversals. To see why, we need to consider how medieval
economic growth occurred. Trade and the expansion of markets were an
important source of economic growth during the Commercial Revolution.
Van Zanden and Prak (2006) argue that medieval city-states were able to
successfully create political communities based on trust and cooperation.
City-states were able to overcome free-rider and other agency problems and
to elicit high contributions in money and time from their populations through
a concept of active citizenship. They enforced property rights and supplied
market-supporting public goods.
But was this enough? Medieval city-states such as Florence, Genoa, and
Venice saw rapid economic growth in the 12th and 13th centuries. But even
before the Black Death, there is evidence that the economic dynamism of
these cities was on the wane. These city-states may have grown, but they did
not develop. Their growth was subject to reversals. Stasavage (2014) finds
that autonomous city-states grew more rapidly than non-autonomous cities
in the initial years of independence but more slowly thereafter. Growth was
not sustained. The primary reason was that merchant oligarchs tended to put
in place barriers to entry in order to consolidate their own positions and the
positions and fortunes of their heirs. In other words, they did not transition to
a fully open-access social order.
In this respect, medieval city-states contained the seeds of their own ruin.
Florence illustrates this. Although it remained a center for international trade
and banking in the 15th century, its prowess as a manufacturing center
peaked a century earlier. Florence manipulated and restricted market access
to maintain its regional primacy within Tuscany at the cost of impeding
regional economic integration (Epstein, 1991, 2000). It also imposed large
and distortionary taxes on its peasantry. The financial services offered by
Florentine bankers became increasingly monopolized in the hands of a few
banking families, of whom the Medici were the most powerful. In the 15th
century, Florence’s competitive political institutions were subverted by the
Medici (Belloc, Drago, Fochesato, and Galbiati, 2021). All of these were
consequences of a rent-seeking ruling elite.
Another example comes from the city-state of Venice. Venice eventually
built an empire on the basis of its commercial success. From the 10th and
11th centuries onwards, the prosperity associated with trade gave rise to a
new Venetian merchant class. These merchants became powerful enough to
influence and shape the political system. Trade promoted social mobility.
Puga and Trefler (2014) show that there was increasing movement of
families into and out of the Great Council (a ruling body) before 1297,
suggesting a fluid and competitive political elite. However, more open
access to politics also threatened the profits the elites earned as a result of
their control over Venice’s foreign trade. The reaction of existing elites led to
a period known as the Serrata (“closure”) in the early 14th century. During
the Serrata, established merchants used their power in the Council to pass
laws to restrict access to trade. First was a law in 1297 restricting new
entrance into the Council. Then another law in 1323 restricted entrance into
long-distance trade. As a result, Council seats became fully hereditary
among the nobility. The nobility then used state power to monopolize
international trade by collectivizing control of the galleys, which were
previously privately owned. The rights to use these ships were auctioned off
among the nobles.
These accounts suggest that prosperous Italian city-states became
increasingly restrictive and exclusive after around 1300. Rent-seeking
among commercial elites increased. Economic growth began to decline.
Incidentally, the cultural flowering of Renaissance Italy occurred perhaps a
century and a half after its economic peak.
The technological base of the medieval economy was also limited. There
was some innovation in the late Middle Ages, notably in clock-making,
spectacles, and later printing. Navigational techniques also improved, paving
the way for the voyages of discovery that would begin in Portugal and Spain
in the 15th century. But the rate of innovation remained too slow to
overwhelm demographic and other retarding factors (Mokyr, 1990, chs. 3,
8). An important reason for this was that the costs of reproducing knowledge
remained high prior to the invention of movable-type printing (Buringh and
van Zanden, 2009).
In short, many of the preconditions for Europe’s eventual economic rise
emerged in the medieval period. The multiple centers of power that
characterized medieval European life set the stage for the continent’s
eventual economic rise. But this rise was by no means pre-ordained, and it
took centuries to come to fruition. Nor was it certain by the end of the
medieval period that Europe would eventually take this path. History is not
deterministic. Had a few things gone differently, modern economic growth
might not have begun in Europe. Indeed, many of the wealthiest parts of
Europe at the end of the medieval period, such as northern Italy and Spain,
did not experience modern economic growth until the 20th century.
But this does not mean that the history is impossible to understand or that
some events are just as likely to happen in one place as another. As we will
argue below, the political conditions characterizing Europe at the end of the
medieval period did indeed matter for subsequent events. Even if these
events were not pre-ordained, they are difficult to imagine without the
medieval heritage. But how and why did this heritage matter? What
happened in the early modern period (roughly 1500–1750)? Understanding
what happened in this period is probably even more important for
understanding why northwestern Europe was the first part of the world to
become rich. It is this period we turn to next.
Divergence within Europe Just before the Take-off
By the end of the medieval period, Europe was no longer obviously behind
the rest of the world. The medieval European resurgence was led by the
trading and manufacturing centers of northern Italy: Venice, Genoa,
Florence, Milan, and many others. Yet, over the course of the 16th and 17th
centuries, the economic center of Europe moved away from the
Mediterranean. By 1800, the Italian city-states had long lost their
independence and prosperity, and Italy was among the most economically
backward areas in Western Europe. The reversal of fortunes became clear
during the 17th century, when the Italians were driven out of textile
production by the English and Dutch. Historians have debated over whether
or not this decline resulted in an absolute decline in living standards or
merely a relative decline (Braudel, 1949/1973; Cipolla, 1952). The real wage
and per capita GDP estimates compiled by Malanima (2003, 2005, 2007)
suggest that this decline was absolute.
One dramatic event was the discovery of the Americas and the Cape Route
around Africa. This shaped the economies of both Europe and the Middle
East. The old trade routes between Asia and Europe lost much of their value,
leading to a decline in the economic fortunes of cities in Central Asia and the
Middle East as well as in Italy (Blaydes and Paik, 2021). In the 16th and
17th centuries, the Atlantic economy rose to prominence. This was true
relative both to Europe and to the rest of the world. It was this shift that
ultimately set the stage for the modern economy. What can explain this
transformation in economic fortunes?
One factor often cited in explaining this mini-divergence within Europe was
demography. Chapter 5 considered the role of late and voluntary marriage –
the European Marriage Pattern (EMP) – in European development. While
this demographic pattern may have deep roots in European history, it appears
to have become prominent after the Black Death.
The labor scarcity that resulted from that catastrophe encouraged women to
enter the workforce and helped produce active markets for agricultural labor.
The high wages that followed should have resulted in a rapid population
recovery. But the practice of late and voluntary marriage and small, nuclear
families moderated this recovery. It dampened Malthusian pressures and
enabled wages to remain higher than would otherwise have been the case.
Europe’s particular demography is clearly part of the reason why its real
wages were higher than those recorded for Asian countries like China, India,
and Japan as far back as the Middle Ages.
Demographic factors help explain why real wages tended to be higher in
Northern Europe, where the EMP was strongest, than in Southern Europe.
But it is also evident that demographic factors were not sufficient by
themselves for sustained economic growth. Otherwise, the Industrial
Revolution would have happened in northern Germany, which was
economically stagnant. It is also difficult to reconcile the timing of the
emergence of modern economic growth with purely demography-based
explanations. The EMP preceded industrialization and sustained economic
growth by at least four centuries.
But this does not mean that demography was unimportant for the eventual
emergence of sustained economic growth. Indeed, it may be a key reason
why industrialization did not immediately lead to a rise in incomes. We will
return to this issue in Chapter 8.
Many explanations for Europe’s economic rise focus on the opening of the
Atlantic. And with good reason. This was one of the key economic and
political events of the three centuries preceding the onset of sustained
economic growth. It makes sense to start with the simple fact that an entirely
new world opened up to Europe, and those with access to the Atlantic had a
natural advantage in accessing it. But not everyone benefited equally. Nor
was the opening of the Atlantic a uniformly good thing for European
economies. One of the most easily visible effects of the discovery of the
Americas was on the monetary base. Inflows of gold and silver from
American mines enriched the Habsburg rulers of Spain and funded wars
across Europe. This is not why the Atlantic economies pulled ahead,
however. These inflows of precious metals ultimately led to higher prices
and not higher levels of output. Inflation reached levels not known to
Europeans for at least a millennium. This so-called “price revolution” led by
Spain was, if anything, detrimental to the economic fortunes of the region.
The decline of Spain is an interesting case. It tells us much about what was
important for the long-run economic development of Europe. Along with
Portugal, Spain was the first European nation to benefit from the opening of
the Atlantic. By the dawn of the 16th century, Spain had a worldwide
empire, and Ferdinand and Isabella were bestowed the prestigious titles of
the “Catholic King and Queen” by Pope Alexander VI. Through inheritance
and marriage, the Spanish Habsburgs would add the wealthy Low Countries
to their empire. Throughout most of the 16th century, Spain was probably
the most powerful nation in Europe, and among the wealthiest. Meanwhile,
England was emerging from a bloody civil war (the Wars of the Roses) and
was far from the European economic frontier.
Yet, it was in the 16th century that the seeds for reversal were sown. By the
end of the century, England and Spain were no longer so far apart
economically (even if it did take an English stroke of luck to keep the
Spanish Armada out of its harbors). Within another century (by 1700 or so),
Spain was clearly behind the economic leaders of Europe. England and the
Dutch Republic, the latter recently liberated from Spanish rule, pulled far
ahead. By the 18th century, Spain was at best a second-rate power in Europe.
What happened?
Ironically enough, the decline of Spain was closely tied to the discovery of
the Americas. The new trade routes opened up a new world to European
manufacturing and trade. But not everyone was able to take advantage of
these opportunities. How countries responded depended on their institutions.
Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2005b) argue that where the profits from
Atlantic trade were controlled by the crown, access to the Atlantic led to a
strengthening of autocratic power. Rulers like the Spanish Habsburgs,
especially Charles I (r. 1516–56) and Philip II (r. 1556–98), used Atlantic
profits to fund wars and consolidate power. The “royal fifth” – 20% of all
precious metals and other commodities coming in from the Americas – went
straight into royal coffers. These riches strengthened the Spanish crown
relative to its parliaments.
The inflows of precious metals (largely silver) were massive. Between 1500
and 1600, precious metals imported from the Americans dwarfed Europe’s
stock of precious metals in 1492 almost ten-fold (Palma, forthcoming). The
immediate effect of the gold and silver extracted from mines in the Americas
was both to enrich the Spanish crown and to give a boost to the European
economy, where specie was in short supply. In the medium and long run,
however, the effect was inflation.
North (1981, 1990) attributed the decline of Spain to political institutions
that encouraged the Habsburg monarchs to pursue economically inefficient
policies such as granting monopoly rights to guilds, failing to tax the
nobility, defaulting on debts, and confiscating property. These extractive
political institutions undermined the foundations of commerce: the “structure
of property rights that evolved in response to the fiscal policies of the
government simply discouraged individuals from undertaking many
productive activities and instead encouraged socially less productive
activities that were sheltered from the reach of the state” (North, 1981, pp.
151–2).
In Spain, the crown held a monopoly on colonial trade. The monopoly rents
associated with colonial trading routes were enormous. For example, the
cargo of the Manila galleons that took Asian goods from the Philippines to
Mexico amounted to around 2% of the GDP of the entire Spanish Empire
(Arteaga, Desierto, & Koyama, 2020). The costs associated with these
monopolies was vast. Spanish trade was tightly restricted for the benefit of a
relatively small number of elites. As Adam Smith (1776/1976) – a fierce
critic of colonial empires and monopoly trading regimes – understood, this
led to a severe misallocation of resources.
Recent research demonstrates that the Habsburg monarchs of Spain were
hardly all-powerful. In particular, they were limited in their ability to raise
taxes. But institutional explanations for the decline of Spain remain
persuasive. Drelichman and Voth (2008) argue that the resource curse
associated with large inflows of American silver afflicted the Spanish
economy by increasing the returns to rent-seeking and undermining the
institutions that limited the power of the monarch, nobility, and clerical
establishment. Resources also undermined efforts to standardize or
centralize a fragmented and inefficient fiscal system. This fiscal
fragmentation was accompanied by institutional, legal, and economic
fragmentation (Grafe, 2012).
Yet, institutional weaknesses in Spain are only part of the story of
divergence. A compelling explanation must also account for why England
and the Dutch Republic pulled ahead in the early modern period. The Dutch
Republic became the world’s dominant economy beginning in the late 16th
century. The English economy was primed for industrialization by the 18th
century. What changed in these economies? Why was the modern economy
born there and not elsewhere?
Parliaments and the Rise of Limited,
Representative Government
In Chapter 3, we discussed the role of institutions. One important set of
institutions we discussed were parliaments. These assemblages of important
people – nobility, clerics, and urban elite – constrained rulers and their worst
whims. But parliaments were more powerful in some places than in others.
As noted above, the Spanish cortes were relatively hapless when it came to
preventing abuses by the Habsburg crown. This ended up not being the case
in England and the Dutch Republic. There, parliaments grew in strength over
time and ultimately were able to place significant constraints on central
authorities. The period after 1600 saw the rise of representative political
institutions first in the Dutch Republic and then in England. Meanwhile, in
Southern Europe, monarchical power was consolidated. But why did this
matter? Any why did limited governance arise in northwestern Europe but
not in Southern Europe?
It is worth revisiting some of the relevant history. The most successful
economy of the 17th century was the Dutch Republic. The cities of the Low
Countries (modern-day Belgium and the Netherlands) became prosperous in
the late Middle Ages. In the 15th century, the cities of the northern
Netherlands prospered due to the wool trade and their control over Baltic
trade routes. The wealth of their urban bourgeoisie is evident in the oil
paintings of the era. As a result of a series of dynastic marriages and
accidents, these rich cities came into the possession of the Habsburg
Emperor Charles V (r. 1516–56) and they were passed down to his son
Philip II, ruler of Spain (r. 1556–98). Tax revenues from these towns and
cities helped to fund Habsburg expansion and warfare against the Ottomans.
The rich burghers of the Dutch cities resented paying taxes to a distant
Habsburg monarch. At first, there was little they could do. The Habsburgs
were powerful and had a legitimate claim on Dutch rule. But in the 1540s
and 1550s, Protestant ideas began to spread throughout the Low Countries.
This gave those looking to throw off the Spanish yoke an opportunity to do
so. The heavy-handed Habsburg response – as many as 2,000 Protestants
were burned alive as heretics – helped galvanize resistance from among the
Dutch nobility and city leaders. The Reformation therefore helped kick-start
a wider political rebellion. It resulted in the establishment of an independent
Dutch Republic in the northern Netherlands and an eighty-year war with
Spain.
This is precisely what we mean when we say that culture and institutions are
often inseparable. It is difficult to imagine how the Dutch Revolt could have
succeeded without the spread of Protestant (Calvinist) ideas. These
motivated and legitimated the rebellion against Habsburg rule – binding the
rebels together in a way that mere shared economic interests were unlikely
to. Meanwhile, it is difficult to imagine how a religious movement like the
Reformation could have succeeded without the political and institutional
changes that secured Dutch independence from the fiercely Catholic
Habsburgs.
The polity that arose as a result of the Dutch Revolt was a federal republic.
William, Prince of Orange, was the most influential noble to lead the
rebellion. He might have become the sovereign of an independent
Netherlands, but he was assassinated. The position of sovereign was also
offered to Queen Elizabeth of England. Only after these options were
exhausted did the Dutch parliament (States General) assume full sovereignty.
The result of the Dutch Revolt was therefore a religiously divided Republic
in which merchants and commercial interests held political power (de Vries
and van der Woude, 1997).
The Dutch Republic created institutions that benefited members of the
economic elite. As a result, despite an ongoing war with Spain, it
experienced rapid economic growth in the century following 1580. This
growth was the result of structural changes to the Dutch economy. In other
words, this was a period of Dutch economic development. Benefiting in part
from the destruction of Antwerp by Spanish forces in 1576, Amsterdam
became Europe’s financial capital. Real wages grew faster than in the rest of
Europe, despite a doubling of the Dutch population. Urbanization increased
rapidly. Large-scale investments in canals and other inland transport helped
ignite a trade boom. Dutch shipping dominated the Baltic. The United East
India Company was founded in 1603 and soon helped win the Dutch an
empire in Southeast Asia. Throughout the 17th and 18th centuries, Dutch
real wages and per capita income were the highest in the world (see Figure
7.2).
Dutch economic success was a direct result of institutional change. The rise
of limited, representative governance was one of the key driving forces
behind the Dutch economic expansion. There was no centralized authority to
extract resources, trample over property rights, or infringe on personal
liberties. This is not to say the Dutch States General was perfect. It could –
and did – favor some interests over others, and it wasn’t exactly in favor of
religious freedom once its preferred religion won the day. It was also not a
modern democracy. Each of the seven provinces retained considerable
power.
While the rise of limited government was an important precondition for
long-run economic growth, it was not enough on its own. The Dutch ended
up being relatively late to the industrialization game, although they remained
among the world’s leading economies. Why, then, do we place so much
emphasis on limited, representative government? For one, it allowed the
Dutch to become the world’s leading economy for over a century. But it was
also a precondition for Britain’s rise.
Figure 7.2 Real per capita GDP, 1450–1700, select countries
Data source: Broadberry, Guan, and Li (2018): 2021 international dollars converted from 1990
international dollars at rate of $2.03:1.
In the 18th century, the locus of economic growth moved from the Dutch
Republic to England, or, as it became known after 1707, Great Britain. Even
prior to the Industrial Revolution, Great Britain had emerged as one of the
world’s leading economies. Institutional change was critical in this
development.
Changes in labor market institutions played a role in unleashing the domestic
economy. While the medieval economy was dominated by craft and
merchant guilds that regulated entry, by 1700 the power of English guilds
had greatly diminished. Britain was, along with the Netherlands, quite
different from much of continental Europe, where guild power remained
entrenched. This hampered economic development by allowing insiders to
block competition and innovation (Ogilvie, 2019).
The centuries leading up to modern economic growth saw the emergence of
Parliament as the dominant legal and political force in England. Chapter 3
examined how Parliament emerged in 13th-century England following the
Magna Carta. A particularly important development – one solidified in the
reign of Edward I (r. 1272–1307) – was that Parliament came to represent
urban interests and not just the nobility. As shown in Figure 3.8, the English
Parliament met frequently during the Middle Ages. This was largely a
reflection of how often the crown was at war. When the crown did not need
additional revenues, it did not have to call Parliament. Strong medieval kings
typically had the ability to dominate Parliament. When there were major
challenges to royal authority, they usually came from the nobility, who still
maintained their own private armies, rather than from Parliament.
This institutional arrangement began to change in the late 15th century.
Following the Wars of the Roses (1455–85), the first Tudor, Henry VII (r.
1485–1509), came to the throne. Henry won the crown on the battlefield and
had a very weak claim to the throne. Greif and Rubin (2021) argue that to
bolster his legitimacy, he turned to Parliament, ruling by acts of Parliament
much more than his predecessors. Henry also weakened the power of the
noble families, particularly those whose blood might make them potential
challengers (Penn, 2011). His son, Henry VIII (r. 1509–47), relied on
Parliament even more frequently, especially after the Reformation further
weakened one of the crown’s key sources of legitimacy, the Catholic
Church. Although the crown continued to employ religion as a source of
legitimacy, the new Anglican Church was under its thumb. It therefore could
not legitimate rule like the Catholic Church could. These factors were also
present under Henry VIII’s three Tudor successors, Edward VI (r. 1547–53),
Mary I (r. 1553–8), and Elizabeth I (r. 1558–1603). They all came to the
throne with low legitimacy. Mary and Elizabeth were the first two female
monarchs in English history and had both been declared bastards. They
therefore relied heavily on Parliament. As Parliament’s power increased, so
did its willingness and ability to limit the crown. This set the stage for the
tumultuous events of the 17th century, in which Parliament twice deposed a
Stuart king whom they believed transgressed their rights.
As recent research confirms, it was in the 17th century that England’s
political institutions diverged from those of continental Europe (Henriques
and Palma, 2020). The first key event of the 17th century was the English
Civil Wars (1642–51). The Civil Wars pitted Parliamentarians against
supporters of King Charles I (r. 1625–49). A vast body of scholarship
considers the causes of these civil wars from a variety of perspectives. For
our purposes, one can view the conflict as primarily over the proper
institutional structure of English governance (Greif and Rubin, 2021). Did a
king have the legitimate right to rule without Parliament (as Charles I had
tried to do in the decade preceding the Civil Wars)? Or was following the
law, as created by Acts of Parliament, essential to being a legitimate king?
Under the Tudors, England had increasingly moved to the latter
arrangement. This was not by design – both Henry VII and Henry VIII had
autocratic aspirations. It occurred partly because of Henry VIII’s need for
Parliamentary support for his break with Rome and particularly because
historical accident landed England with a minor and two women as his
successors. Conflict between crown and Parliament came to a head after
James I (r. 1603–25) and his successor Charles I sought to subordinate
Parliament to the crown. This conflict was in large part over how powerful
the monarchy should be. In the end, the Parliamentarians won and Charles I
was executed.
The English Civil Wars were an important turning point. They brought about
a change in the ruling coalition. Jha (2015) explores how emerging overseas
economic opportunities helped the formation of a coalition in favor of
constraining the crown. Many of the landed elite purchased shares in
overseas trading companies, aligning their interests with the merchant class.
Ownership of shares in overseas trade shifted the views of non-merchants,
helping to consolidate support for reformers in Parliament. They therefore
had an interest in fighting with Parliament against the king. This aligned the
interests of the economic elite with a broad set of powerful people, which, in
turn, gave them a central seat at the political bargaining table.
The Civil Wars sharply accelerated the ultimate pre-eminence of limited
governance. Such institutional changes were important for the rise of the
modern economy. However, even though the Parliamentarians won the day,
this did not mean that limited governance immediately followed. The
conflict between Parliament and the Stuart kings was not permanently
resolved by the Civil Wars. It resulted in another conflict a generation later,
between Charles I’s son James II (r. 1685–8), a Catholic who aspired to
create a more autocratic monarchy along French lines, and his opponents in
Parliament. In 1688, a Parliamentary faction invited William of Orange and
his wife, Mary (the daughter of the king), to overthrow James. James fled
and William and Mary (r. 1689–1702) came to the throne with little
bloodshed (at least in England; it was quite different in Scotland and
Ireland). This capped off the so-called Glorious Revolution. In the process,
William and Mary accepted a Bill of Rights whereby they relinquished
numerous rights and agreed to limit the power of the crown. This was a
major turning point in the history of limited governance.
The change in English government was part of a broader global and
expensive war against France. The settlement following the Glorious
Revolution helped fund this war. Because Parliament now had power over
the English purse-strings, creditors were more willing to believe they would
be paid back (North and Weingast, 1989). William of Orange brought with
him Dutch advisors and knowledge of Dutch fiscal and financial practices
(Hart, 1991). A critical event was the establishment of the Bank of England
in 1694, which helped fund the war effort. Over time, it led to a substantial
drop in borrowing costs (see Table 7.1). This enabled an enormous growth in
state power that would become a theme of the 18th century and beyond.
By making England (after 1707, Britain) a constitutional monarchy, the
Glorious Revolution laid the foundations of the party system and cabinet
government (Stasavage, 2002, 2003; Pincus and Robinson, 2014; Cox,
2016). These developments did not all take place immediately after 1688. It
took several decades for the implications of the Glorious Revolution to fully
take shape. But they provided the political and institutional stability that was
important for Britain’s subsequent economic growth.
North and Weingast (1989) argued that the credibility of the English
monarchy to repay its debts after 1688 translated into more secure property
rights in general. While this claim has not survived subsequent scrutiny, in
other respects there was an improvement in institutional quality after 1688.
Rather than securing property rights, these changes made it easier to reorder
property rights in order to exploit new investment opportunities.
In other words, what mattered was less the “security” of property rights in
the abstract than the ability to rearrange residual claimancy as new economic
opportunities emerged. Feudal property rights were secure but they were
designed to support feudal society and not to maximize productivity. Land
rights in 17th-century England were complex and constrained. The
ownership of land came with feudal entails which meant that potential heirs
could veto anything that could be claimed to detract from the future capital
value of the land (such as cutting down a forest or draining a lake).
Table 7.1 British borrowing and interest rates, 1693–1739
Data source: North and Weingast (1989, Table 4).
Date Amount (£) Interest (%)
Jan. 1693 723,394 14.0
Mar. 1694 1,000,000 14.0
Mar. 1694 1,200,000 8.0
Apr. 1697 1,400,000 6.3
July 1698 2,000,000 8.0
Mar. 1707 1,155,000 6.25
July 1721 500,000 5.0
Mar. 1728 1,750,000 4.0
May 1731 800,000 3.0
June 1739 300,000 3.0
Prior to the Glorious Revolution, estate bills often failed due to political
conflict. However, as a result of changes brought on by the Glorious
Revolution, Parliament became a forum where land could be reallocated
towards more productive uses (Bogart and Richardson, 2009, 2011). As a
consequence, investment in road and river transport dramatically improved,
with important consequences for subsequent economic growth (Bogart and
Richardson, 2011). Parliamentary regulation helped keep internal trade
relatively unimpeded, especially in comparison to the Holy Roman Empire
or France (Bogart, 2012). Parliament played a crucial role in regulating the
tolls that maintained England’s road and canal network. Tolls were kept low,
in part by Parliamentary regulation and in part by market competition. Toll
roads were funded by users and in competition with river and canal routes.
This was not a move towards greater democracy. Only a small proportion of
adult males could vote. And after 1715, elections became less frequent (held
only every seven years). In many ways, the power of the rich was entrenched
and historians have often viewed the 18th-century British state as designed
to favor the propertied classes. Certainly it ruthlessly enforced Enclosure
Acts and penal laws against the poor (Hay, Linebaugh, Rule, Thompson, and
Winslow, 1975). For the most part, early 18th-century Parliaments were
characterized by unabashed rent-seeking. Parliament passed many acts that
benefited specific interests – most notably the Calico Act of 1721, which
banned the importation of most cotton textiles – at the expense of the larger
public. None of this shocked contemporaries. Members of Parliament were
expected to look out for their own material interests and to pursue what to
modern eyes looks like venality (Root, 1991). This changed over the course
of the 18th century. Mokyr and Nye (2007, p. 58) note that “[p]urely
redistributional actions … began losing their appeal. Many special interest
groups’ legislated privileges, monopolies, exclusions, limitations on labor
mobility, occupational choice, and technological innovation found
themselves on the defensive as the 18th century wore on.”
In other words, if we are to discern the distinctive features of the British
political system on the eve of the Industrial Revolution, it is less useful to
focus on features such as its corruption or lack of democratic representation.
These were features that it shared with almost all pre-modern states. More
insight is gained from considering which factors were critical in allowing it
to attain a high degree of political stability and prosperity.
In this respect, the British system was successful in constraining the
independent power of the monarchy, while balancing the interests of
landowning elites with those of mercantile and financial elites. It was able to
mobilize tremendous resources for warfare without crushing the domestic
economy. It was not a democracy, as it limited political representation to
those with property. But it did provide scope for “voice” through regular
elections. It also provided greater freedom for religious minorities than did
its competitors in Europe (with the exception of the Dutch Republic) while
also prohibiting Catholics and religious dissenters from positions of political
power (Johnson and Koyama, 2019, pp. 179–83).
Chapter Summary
By around 1700, northwestern Europe had many of the necessary
preconditions for sustained economic growth. Per capita incomes and real
wages were high by pre-industrial standards. Markets were relatively well
developed and extensive. The institutional framework was conducive to the
expansion of internal trade. State institutions were strong enough to provide
a measure of law and internal peace. But these factors alone were unlikely to
have been enough for modern economic growth.
This is demonstrated by the example of the Dutch Republic. Though the
Dutch Republic has been hailed as “the first modern economy” (de Vries and
van der Woude, 1997), the Dutch pattern of commercial, Smithian, trade-
driven growth more closely resembled earlier episodes of temporary growth
than it did the sustained economic growth that characterized Western Europe
and North America after 1800. As Goldstone (2002, p. 340) writes: “[W]hile
Golden Age Holland did indeed experience an ‘efflorescence’ of innovation,
intensification and productivity growth in agriculture, and stable per capita
incomes despite substantial population growth, such a pattern is neither
uniquely Dutch nor ‘modern’ by global standards.”
In the 18th century, the Dutch Republic remained rich but its economy did
not experience further rapid growth (de Vries and van der Woude, 1997).
There were many factors responsible for this stagnation. Inequality rose and
merchant elites based in Amsterdam were able to entrench their political
power (van Bavel, 2016). Institutions like the Dutch East India Company
(VOC) benefited a relative small number of shareholders. The Dutch
Republic thus followed a similar pattern to Italian city-states like Florence
and Venice that grew rich on the back of trade before eventually stagnating.
Another factor was the high taxes and high levels of government debt
incurred fighting numerous wars for survival against the French. Moreover,
the mercantilist policies of the British and the comparative failure of the
Dutch to invest further in fiscal capacity also contributed to their relative
decline (O’Brien, 2000). Overall, the Dutch were not able to achieve a
dramatic and sustained increase in living standards. This would not happen
until the Great Enrichment that began after 1800, and it was driven by
developments in Britain.
The Dutch Republic was at the forefront of the Scientific Revolution.
Christiaan Huygens made important contributions to astronomy and
mathematics. Antonie van Leeuwenhoek pioneered the field of
microbiology. There were also important Dutch developments in
engineering, especially hydraulic engineering. Yet, the Dutch did not
experience the combination of growth of industry and structural change that
characterized Britain’s Industrial Revolution.
Britain did experience this combination in the 18th and 19th centuries. The
result was the first modern economy – one in which economic growth was
sustained without reversal. Why did this happen first in Britain? We began
this explanation in this chapter, noting that Britain had some of the important
institutional preconditions. Most importantly, it had a (relatively) limited and
representative government. But this was clearly not enough. If it were, the
Dutch would have had the first modern economy. What else was needed for
Britain to prosper? We turn to this question in the next chapter.
8
Britain’s Industrial Revolution
We are now in a position to address the question “How did the world
become rich?” The answer to this question begins with Britain’s Industrial
Revolution. Britain’s industrialization set in motion a series of events that
ultimately resulted in modern, sustained economic growth. Since the first
few decades of the 19th century, the world has become richer and billions
have been lifted out of poverty. This was due to sustained economic growth.
This is why we care so deeply about it.
Figure 8.1 reports the growth of total GDP, population, and GDP per capita
in England from 1270 to 1700 and then for Britain from 1700 to 1870.
Between 1700 and 1870, the size of the total economy increased by a factor
of 10. Population also grew roughly four-fold. Per capita GDP more than
doubled. Such an economic transformation defied the logic of the
Malthusian economy. By the middle of the 19th century, the British
economy began to exhibit modern, sustained economic growth. Per capita
GDP grew in a continuous fashion even as the population also continued to
expand. Perhaps most importantly, despite the ups and downs of wars and
business cycles, there were no serious growth reversals.
The first seven chapters have laid out various theories that give insight into
why modern, sustained economic growth was likely to happen in some
places but not others. In this chapter we go further. Answering the question
“How did the world become rich?” means establishing the reasons for both
the location of modern economic growth and its timing.
We begin this pursuit by exploring the causes of the Industrial Revolution. It
began in Britain some time in the second half of the 18th century. This part
is uncontroversial. What is more controversial is why it began when and
where it did. Having outlined some of the institutional prerequisites for
growth in Chapter 7, in this chapter we consider the development of the
British economy more generally in the 18th and 19th centuries. We also
consider what made the Industrial Revolution a “revolution.” It was not the
rate of economic growth, which remained modest. It was that growth was
sustained thereafter.
Figure 8.1 GDP, GDP per capita, and population in England/Britain, 1270–
1870 (1700 = 100)
Data source: Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton, and van Leeuwen (2015).
Above all else, the major revolutionary change during the Industrial
Revolution was an increase in the rate of innovation. The acceleration in
innovation ensured that economic growth continued and did not peter out.
New and important technologies emerged at a rapid pace in late 18th- and
early 19th-century Britain. Why? Any answer must account for how British
society became particularly innovative.
We first consider the British economy on the eve of the Industrial
Revolution, paying particular attention to several important preconditions.
These include the rise of a market-oriented society and its implications for
labor supply and consumption patterns, the size of the domestic economy,
commercial agriculture, culture and social norms, and the increasing
significance of the Atlantic economy. Many of these features were also
shared by the Dutch Republic.
But the Industrial Revolution did not begin in the Dutch Republic. We
therefore turn our attention to factors that may have distinguished Britain
from its rivals. These include its high level of state capacity and its dominant
role in the transatlantic slave trade. While these factors played a role in
Britain’s economic success, however, neither provides a full accounting of
why this success led to industrialization. To answer the question “Why
Britain?” we therefore focus on two important arguments. First, we consider
Allen’s (2009a) argument that innovation was a response to high wages and
cheap capital and energy. Second, we consider Mokyr’s (2009, 2016)
argument that cultural and intellectual developments within British and
European society, along with increased human capital and skills, were
responsible for Britain’s industrialization. But first we provide some
background on Britain’s economy on the eve of industrialization.
A Consumer Revolution
To identify the relevant preconditions for industrialization, we must know
something about British society and its economy in the century or so prior to
industrialization. There was peace (in England, though not yet Scotland)
following the Civil Wars (1642–51). The domestic economy can be
described as a market economy. That is, although problems with silver
coinage meant that monetarization was far from universal, economic
activities were oriented around market exchange. All large-scale societies
rely on markets to some extent. Even in Soviet Russia there was market
exchange, both legal and on the black market. Nevertheless, many societies
that allow markets to play an important role in the allocation of final goods
rely on non-market systems for allocating factors of production (land,
capital, and labor).
By 1700, Britain had a fully developed market economy. The expansion and
improved integration of domestic markets can account for much of the
relative prosperity the country enjoyed in the 18th century. As we reviewed
in Chapter 2, the integration of what was a comparatively large domestic
market rested on a domestic road and canal network that was greatly
improved in the 18th century (Bogart, 2014). Allen (2009a, p. 106) observes
that “cities grew, London’s wages were high, agriculture improved, and
manufacturing spread across the countryside.” Another characteristic of a
market society emerged in this period: the rise of the consumer. Historians
have called this period the Consumer Revolution. Put simply, households
became more oriented towards the market (McKendrick, Brewer, and
Plumb, 1982; Brewer and Porter, 1993).
The Consumer Revolution was a move away from within-household
production and consumption to market-oriented production and
consumption. It was a sea change in how people consumed goods and
services. Late medieval households, while not completely self-sufficient,
produced many products within the household. They might, for instance,
make their own clothes from yarn or cloth purchased from a whole-seller, or
they might brew their own beer. This changed in the 17th and 18th centuries.
Retail shops emerged, which enabled customers to purchase goods
immediately. It became possible to purchase ready-made textiles as opposed
to buying them wholesale and taking them to a dressmaker or making one’s
clothes at home (Mui and Mui, 1989).
British consumption habits changed as a result. Weatherill (1988) found that
the number of households owning durable goods in the inventories of the
London’s Orphans’ Court increased significantly between 1675 and 1725.
The frequency of goods such as saucepans, cutlery, clocks, china, pewter,
and earthenware increased dramatically. Utensils for hot drinks were almost
completely absent from 17th-century inventories but they were found in 80%
of inventories by 1725. Lemire notes that even servants could save up the
“six or seven shillings needed to purchase sufficient cotton cloth to make a
gown, or the eight shillings for a ready-made gown.” This created “a
potentially vast market among working-women, for whom these prices
meant perhaps one week’s wages or less” (Lemire, 1991, p. 97).
Scholars have linked this Consumer Revolution to the growing prosperity of
this period. De Vries (1993, 2008) in particular argues that new consumption
opportunities created by the expansion and development of markets gave rise
to an “industrious revolution.” By this, he means that as households became
more active participants in the market economy, they had to work harder to
earn the wages to buy all of these new and affordable goods. New
consumption opportunities meant that fewer goods were produced within the
household economy. Households began to purchase goods that had no
domestic substitute. Instead of consuming their surplus income as leisure,
they spent it on an increasingly wide range of consumption goods (Koyama,
2012). The “industrious revolution” can thus be viewed as the other side of
the Consumer Revolution.
According to de Vries, this “industrious revolution” originated in the
Netherlands in the 17th century and spread to England and other parts of the
Atlantic economy over the course of the late 17th and early 18th centuries.
But why was it an important predecessor to the Industrial Revolution?
Improvements in GDP per capita can either come from increased labor
inputs, greater capital investment, or improvements in efficiency (often
equated with innovation). Part of the growth in GDP per capita that took
place during the 17th and early 18th centuries was due to an increase in labor
inputs, both working hours and the number of days worked. The reason,
according to de Vries, was a new “industriousness.” Workers worked harder
because they wanted additional income to engage in new consumption
opportunities.
Increased industriousness helps resolve another puzzle involving wages and
industrialization. The 19th century did not witness a dramatic rise in English
real wages. Contrast this with the period following the Black Death, which
saw real wages rise precipitously (see Chapter 5). Yet, following the Black
Death, GDP per capita did not rise as much as real wages. And the post-
Black Death rise in wages was not sustained in the long run. There were two
key differences between the two periods. First, labor markets were thin in
the late Middle Ages. Even though measured wages were high, this did not
mean that workers could find reliable work at those wages. Second, even
when wage laborers did find work, they often “consumed” their higher
incomes in the form of increased leisure. So, even though daily wages were
higher for some time following the Black Death, yearly incomes rose much
less rapidly (Humphries and Weisdorf, 2019).
This changed between 1500 and 1700. In the Netherlands, de Vries and van
der Woude (1997) find that the average number of working days increased
for day laborers by 25% between 1550 and 1650. In England, Voth (2001)
finds evidence of a particularly dramatic increase in the working day after
1750. While these estimates are sensitive to assumptions and to the
particular data employed, there is little doubt that there was an increase in
the total labor inputs in this period (Allen and Weisdorf, 2011). This
increased willingness to work longer hours for the wages required to
purchase new consumer goods can be seen as a precondition for the rise of
the factory system (Clark, 1994). As we will discuss below, factories
required large investments in fixed capital. These were only worthwhile if
there was a willing workforce that could man the factories, and if necessary
work long and exhausting hours.
Capitalist Agriculture
In the century preceding the Industrial Revolution, English agriculture was
highly commercialized relative to the rest of Europe. Production was geared
towards the market. The majority of workers were wage laborers. And farms
were large compared to continental Europe, allowing them to exploit
economies of scale. By the mid-18th century, England was a major exporter
of food. Many historians have viewed this distinctive “capitalist” agriculture
as an important precondition for the Industrial Revolution.
It is evident that labor productivity in English agriculture was comparatively
high prior to the Industrial Revolution. Output per worker in England was
similar to that in Italy and France in 1500. By 1750, it was higher in England
and in the Low Countries than elsewhere in Europe. What was responsible
for this increase in productivity?
In medieval England, the dominant form of farming was small-scale
agriculture, organized around open fields and commons. Peasants farmed
small, scattered plots located across the manor. These open fields enabled
farmers to share risk. An individual farmer who owned several small plots of
land scattered around the village was insured against idiosyncratic risk – say
a hailstorm, a flood, or crop blight (McCloskey, 1976). This open-field
system limited the harm that could arise from local shocks. There were
downsides to this system, however. It was costly and time-consuming to
move between different plots of land. Small, disjoint, and irregular plots
often made it unprofitable to introduce new crop types or equipment.
We saw in Chapter 5 that the Black Death shock depopulated the countryside
across Western Europe. Changing factor prices and changing patterns of
demand led to a shift in land use. Land, particularly in the north and west of
the country, was given over to pastoral agriculture. As a result, landowners
sought to consolidate many patches of land. They did this through the
process of enclosure. Many medieval enclosures occurred through private
negotiation: farmers who wished to enclose the land had to buy out those
who did not. It was also possible to petition Parliament for an Enclosure Act.
These acts would pass if somewhere between three-quarters to four-fifths of
landowners (by value) supported it. The holdouts would receive
compensation. By 1500, 45% of farmland in England was enclosed (Allen,
1994, p. 99).
The trend towards larger farms, what historians like Brenner (1976) term
“capitalist agriculture,” accelerated after 1500. While economic historians
used to think in terms of a distinct Agricultural Revolution directly
preceding the Industrial Revolution, more recent evidence from labor
productivity data suggests a general increase taking place over several
centuries. Farms became larger and more capital-intensive. The pace of
enclosures increased in the 18th century, driven by Parliamentary legislation.
These enclosures had long been the subject of intense controversy. Their
supporters among contemporaries and later historians saw them as
contributing greatly to increased yields. They also made possible the
eventual mechanization of agriculture in the 19th century with machines
such as threshers. Their critics, including Karl Marx, saw them as acts of
class warfare. Poor smallholders were forced off their land by rapacious,
richer farmers, with scant compensation. Looking at the South Midlands,
moreover, Allen (1992) finds little evidence that the late 18th-century
enclosures actually improved yields.
There is evidence, however, that they led to more land being reclaimed and
in the growth of larger farms and more capital-intensive agriculture. The
gains from these changes, Allen contends, were largely captured by rich
landlords. More recently, Heldring, Robinson, and Vollmer (2021) have
studied the impact of enclosures across the whole of England. Their
estimates suggest that enclosures led to an improvement in productivity.
They also find that infrastructure improvements were associated with
enclosures.
This rise in agricultural productivity between 1500 and 1700 in northwestern
Europe was important. It helped to banish the specter of famine. It also
helped sustain a dramatic rise in the proportion of the population living in
cities. After all, urban development is only possible when there is a large
enough agricultural surplus to feed all those city-dwellers. Improved yields
and commercial agriculture may have laid the foundations of Britain’s
relative prosperity from 1600 onwards. But they were certainly not sufficient
for sustained economic growth after 1800. When Britain did industrialize,
the increase in agricultural production was not sufficient to keep up with
population growth, and the agrarian economy did not offer a large market for
manufactured goods. Indeed, Britain became a net food importer during the
Industrial Revolution.
Do Political Institutions Explain Britain’s
Industrialization?
Now that we have a better understanding of some of the key features of the
British economy on the eve of industrialization, we can circle back to the
discussion in Chapter 7 regarding the preconditions for growth. We ended
that chapter noting that the political environment in Britain and the Dutch
Republic was more conducive to economic growth than the rest of Europe
(and the rest of the world). Both countries had some degree of limited,
representative governance. In the British Isles, political institutions provided
a measure of stability after 1688. This had both political and economic
consequences. In the political realm, it allowed government borrowing to
increase dramatically. It also resulted in greater fiscal and military power.
Political stability enabled Smithian growth. But this is not what made Britain
unique.
Political institutions alone cannot explain why Britain industrialized first.
Traditionally, historians have argued that what made the Industrial
Revolution a “revolution” was the wave of innovations that consumed
Britain beginning in the latter half of the 18th century. Although British
political stability and protection of property rights were important, they
cannot fully account for this development. Britain did have intellectual
property rights. A patent system existed and could be used to protect
innovation. Yet, while it was ruthlessly employed by some of the Industrial
Revolution’s most famous innovators (like James Watt), patents were neither
necessary nor sufficient to account for the wave of innovations that Britain
experienced in this period. The innovator responsible for coke pig iron,
Abraham Darby, for example, did not take out a patent (Mokyr, 2009). Many
inventions required too much knowledge of how they worked to be copied.
Other innovators kept their inventions secret or selectively revealed them to
the public. None of these strategies required intellectual property rights.
Where does this leave us? There are many possibilities to consider. First, just
because institutions do not fully explain why Britain industrialized, they can
explain why other parts of the world did not. By the mid-18th century,
British citizens could feel relatively secure that their property, innovations,
and industrial output would not be seized by the prying hands of the
government or anyone else with coercive power. Even though British
political institutions were far from perfect and certainly corrupt to modern
eyes, there was enough constraint on executive power that the majority of
the population was reasonably well protected from infringements on
property rights. This was not the case in other parts of the world, especially
those with autocratic governance. The Ottoman and Qing Empires, for
example, regularly infringed on the rights of their people, especially the
economic elite (Balla and Johnson, 2009; Kuran, 2011; Ma and Rubin,
2019). Even within Europe, the Spanish crown was more than willing to
transgress property rights, especially those of its merchants. For instance, the
16th-century kings Charles V and Philip II regularly reneged on their debts
and confiscated treasure coming in from the Atlantic trade (Drelichman,
2005; Drelichman and Voth, 2011). They gave foreign merchants privileges
(for a price) over domestic merchants. They trampled over the rights of
religious minorities. None of this encouraged domestic production on the
type of scale that would come to typify Britain.
Mercantilism and Empire
Economic policy throughout the century or so leading up to industrialization
was unabashedly mercantilist. Mercantilism is the label used to describe
economic policies that favored exports rather than imports. Mercantilist
policies often favored domestic market integration. When it came to
international trade, they supported the use of tariffs, subsidies, and
monopolies for special interests to obtain a favorable balance of trade.
Mercantilist economic policies were therefore embroiled with the dynastic
and violent conflicts that characterized European international relations for
much of the 17th and 18th centuries.
The Atlantic economy that emerged in the 18th century was the product of
British success in a series of wars with France and Spain. Its origins lay in
the mid-17th century, including the capture of Jamaica in 1655. After this,
the Atlantic economy began to boom. It centered on the rich agricultural
economy of the Caribbean. In the 18th century, the British state defeated its
main rivals at sea and secured the lion’s share of trade routes between the
Americas, Europe, and West Africa.
The rise of the Atlantic economy changed Britain’s economic landscape. The
new westward orientation of international trade that came with it altered the
structure and geography of the British economy. Ports like London, Bristol,
and Liverpool expanded operations as Britain’s growing Atlantic empire
offered new opportunities. With the exception of London (which exploded,
becoming the largest city in the world by 1800), the economic geography of
Britain shifted to the Northwest (see Figure 8.2). Table 8.1 shows the largest
English cities (excluding London) between 1520 and 1801. In 1520,
Norwich was the largest city outside London. This was due to its
prominence in the wool trade and proximity to the Low Countries. The only
other cities with populations larger than 10,000 were York, the historical
capital of the north, and Bristol, a major port. By 1801, this urban hierarchy
had been transformed. The industrial center Manchester, which ranked as
only the 82nd largest town in England in the 17th century with a population
of around 2,000, numbered 94,876 inhabitants by 1801. By 1841, it had a
population of 311,269. The only city that grew faster was Liverpool, which
rose from being the 233rd most populated British city to the third most
populous by 1801.
The shift of the British economy and population towards the Northwest
reflects two processes. First, the rise of Atlantic trade favored ports,
particularly those on the west coast. This is why cities like Liverpool grew
so rapidly. Second, as manufacturing began to expand in the 18th century, it
was centered in Yorkshire, Lancashire, or areas abundant with coal such as
Newcastle.
Areas like the West Midlands came to specialize in metallurgy. Liverpool
became the center of the watch trade (Kelly and Ó Gráda, 2016). Other
centers of manufacturing arose such as Sheffield (associated with the steel
industry) and Birmingham (associated with the gun trade, clocks, locks, and
toys) (Kelly, Mokyr, and Ó Gráda, 2020). These manufacturing centers
required many highly skilled workers to produce their goods. As we will see
shortly, the agglomeration of these highly skilled workers in urban centers
may have been one of the factors that set Britain apart.
Figure 8.2 England and its largest cities, 1520–1801
Table 8.1 Most populous English cities excluding London (with populations
of at least 10,000)
Data source: Clark (2001).
The shift to the Atlantic also helped fuel the Consumer Revolution. New,
exotic, addictive products were introduced to Europe by the Atlantic trade,
particularly tea, tobacco, and sugar. These goods were initially luxuries, but
they soon became accessible to the population at large. As Berg (2004, p.
365) describes the process: “The history of these colonial groceries is one of
the transformation of exotic luxuries into necessities.” In the 17th century,
tea was a luxury consumed by the rich. By 1800, it had become a staple of
working-class diets. Tea was consumed with sugar, which the Atlantic
economy made cheaply and widely available. In fact, by the end of the 18th
century, sugar was the single most important import into the British
economy (de Vries, 2003, pp. 151–8).
Many of these goods were produced by slave labor. Harvesting tropical
goods, especially sugar, is a dangerous and laborious task. Indentured
servants tended to avoid the Caribbean, even though it offered a shorter term
of servitude. The high profits made from slave labor reflected both the
exploitation of the labor force and the high demand for the goods slaves
produced. The Atlantic-facing British cities associated with the slave trade
became important in their own right. But how crucial was slavery for
Britain’s industrialization? This is a heated debate. In the next section, we
will discuss this debate and the extent to which the sugar–slavery nexus was
a crucial ingredient for British industrialization.
Does the Transatlantic Slave Trade Explain
Britain’s Industrialization?
Numerous scholars have linked European colonization with the British
Industrial Revolution. Two of the most powerful arguments come from
Williams (1944) and Inikori (2002).
Williams (1944) first popularized the link between the slave trade and
commercial and financial development in 18th-century Britain in his classic
Capitalism and Slavery. He argued that the profits of the slave trade helped
fuel the Industrial Revolution. He drew attention to the trade nexus that
linked British manufactured exports with the slave trade in West Africa and
the sugar, tobacco, and cotton plantations in the Americas. As Solow (1987,
p. 732) describes the period before the Industrial Revolution:
Total trade increased greatly, and the Atlantic was crisscrossed by
British ships carrying manufactured goods to Africa, the West Indies,
Brazil, Portugal, and British North America.
The Atlantic islands were exporting wine, Africa slaves, Brazil gold,
and the West Indies sugar and molasses. Some of the British North
American colonies were sending rice and tobacco to Britain; others
were sending fish, lumber, horses, and flour to the West Indies and were
buying British manufactures with the proceeds. Every one of these
flows depended on the product of slave labor.
Slavery was at the center of this trade. Conditions on sugar plantations were
exceptionally harsh. As a consequence, it proved difficult to attract free
workers to settle. Initially settled by white laborers, often as indentured
servants, by the 18th century the West Indies had become slave economies.
Of course, slaves have no say in working conditions. Slavery enabled
plantation owners to extract the entire surplus generated by forced labor in a
hot and harsh climate (Wright, 2020). Given the centrality of sugar (and to a
lesser extent tobacco), the 18th-century Atlantic economy was inseparable
from the enslavement and exploitation of Africans.
These facts were often neglected in traditional accounts of the British
economy in the 18th century. Williams’s argument about the profits from the
slave trade fueling industrialization established an important correlation. But
was it causal?
Scholars following Williams have not established a link from the investors
and landowners who benefited from exploiting slave labor in the Caribbean
to the innovative developments taking place in the north of England. There
are two reasons for this. First, the entrepreneurs, factory owners, and
inventors who were key to the Industrial Revolution funded their firms from
profits and their own savings and were not well integrated with London-
based capital markets. While slavery was crucial to certain industries and
made many British families rich, it was not directly linked with the more
innovative manufacturing sector. Indeed, sugar was less connected to the
overall economy than were coal, iron, and textiles (Eltis and Engerman,
2000, p. 140). Second, economic historians have pointed out that super-
normal profits were not made in the long run due to competition, and the
sugar industry was small relative to the British economy as a whole (Eltis
and Engerman, 2000). The direct contribution of slavery to the British
economy was small as a matter of simple accounting.
Nevertheless, perhaps the slave trade played an outsized role because of its
strategic importance in the British economy? Scholars including Solow
(1987) have suggested numerous other connections between slavery and the
wider British economy. The slave trade ensured an elastic supply of sugar
and tea, goods that helped fuel an “industrious revolution.” Derenoncourt
(2019) finds that cities linked with the transatlantic slave trade grew faster
than other cities between 1600 and 1850. More generally, slavery raised the
return on investment across the empire. This may have enabled faster
structural change and industrial growth. Inikori (2002) focuses on the role
played by sugar and slavery in the rise of overseas trade in the late 17th and
early 18th centuries. It was this expansion in overseas trade, he claims, that
drove initial increases in productivity. Technological progress built on this
initial increase in productivity. To assess these arguments, however, one has
to go beyond simply establishing plausible empirical linkages. What is
required is a method of assessing the quantitative economic significance of
these linkages.
The theoretical frameworks that Inikori (2002) and Darity (1992) propose
stress the existence of linkages between overseas trade and domestic
manufacturing. Slavery, by being so vital to British overseas trade, was at
the heart of these linkages. However, the evidence for such important
connections has not yet been provided. Hence, modern assessments do not
greatly depart from Solow’s (1987, p. 733) view that “[t]o argue that slavery
was important for British economic growth is not to claim that slavery
caused the Industrial Revolution.” Eltis and Engerman (2000, p. 138) make
the simple point that no industry was indispensable to the Industrial
Revolution. Atlantic slavery was nonetheless a background condition tied to
Britain’s rise to both economic and military prominence in the 18th century.
Was It Cotton?
Williams and Inikori focused on the role played by slavery in the Caribbean
economy of the 18th century. More recently, Beckert (2014) focused on
cotton’s role in creating the modern economic system in the 19th century.
This argument has risen to prominence as part of the new “History of
Capitalism.”
Hobsbawm (1968) declared that, for all intents and purposes, cotton was the
Industrial Revolution. Beckert’s argument builds on this claim. Certainly
cotton textile production was one of the most dynamic sectors of the
industrializing economy. The outward supply shift in cotton textiles induced
an 85% decrease in the price of cotton cloth between 1780 and 1850 (Mokyr,
1990). Once a luxury only for the rich, cheaper cotton goods were a
tremendous boon for consumers of all classes. Almost every Brit could now
afford lightweight, easily washable garments for the first time.
But how did Britain build a world-leading cotton textiles industry? Beckert’s
answer lies in the policies of aggressive colonialism overseas and state
intervention, regulation, and coercion against the labor force at home. Thus,
for him: “Slavery, colonialism, and forced labor, among other forms of
violence, were not aberrations in the history of capitalism, but were at its
very core” (Beckert 2014, p. 441).
One problem with this argument is that it reduces the Industrial Revolution
to cotton textiles. Though cotton textiles were among the most dynamic
industries in Britain during the Industrial Revolution, economic historians
like Mokyr (2009, p. 296) argue that one cannot reduce the Industrial
Revolution to one industry: “If there had been no cotton, there still would
have been an Industrial Revolution, even if its exact shape would have
differed.”
So what was the link between exports and economic growth? McCloskey
(2010, p. 222) observes that “[p]eople innocent of economics … believe that
trade just is growth.” But there is no reason to privilege trade with a
foreigner above trade with one’s fellow citizen. Historians like Beckert focus
on export industries, as these are commonly seen as key drivers of economic
growth. But exports are the price we pay for imports. Harley (2004, p. 192)
notes that “a person or nation fully employed … yearns to acquire goods, not
to get rid of them. Exports are an unfortunate sacrifice that people or nations
must make to acquire imports for consumption.”
Harley further notes that the share and prominence of international trade in
national income accounts is a poor indication of its economic significance.
To assess the economic significance of international trade, he presents
counter-factual estimates of the importance of trade to the British economy.
He finds that:
Self-sufficiency in 1860 … would have cost Britain only (50 per cent) *
(0.125) or about 6 per cent of national income. Six per cent of national
income – or even, if, improbably, the terms of trade effect were twice as
great, 12 per cent – looks small beside bold metaphors of Britain’s
“dependence” on foreign trade. (Harley, 2004, p. 194)
These calculations suggest that the importance of trade to the British
Industrial Revolution was sizable but not so significant to warrant being
described as critical or essential.
Was It Market Size?
While certain types of institutions may have prevented other parts of the
world from experiencing sustained growth, they do not fully explain why
Britain did experience such growth. The same applies to other preconditions
such as access to international markets and a large domestic market
relatively free from internal taxation. Britain had both. This was in no small
part due to the evolution of British political institutions, which (as we
discussed in the previous chapter) increasingly favored the interests of the
economic elite. We noted previously how the rise in the Atlantic trade
contributed to Britain’s rise as an economic power. Equally significant were
the large domestic markets in which British producers could offload their
goods. Important improvements in transport networks in the 18th century
(see Chapter 2) lowered the cost of domestic shipping. Meanwhile, the
British state was committed to free internal trade. This was no doubt due, in
part, to the pre-eminence of economic elites in Parliament. This contrasted
with fractured states like the Holy Roman Empire and France. In those
states, internal tariffs stifled domestic trade. Along the River Rhine,
merchants faced a new tariff in each of the many territories they would pass
on a routine trip between cities (Johnson and Koyama, 2017, pp. 9–10). It
was not until the formation of the Zollverein trade customs union in the mid-
19th century that domestic trade was freed of tariffs and domestic markets
became relatively integrated (Shiue, 2005).
Some economists have theorized that Britain’s market size played a crucial
role in providing incentives for innovation and bringing about sustained
growth. This idea goes back to Adam Smith (1776/1976), who argued that
the size of the market determined the extent of the market. This in turn
determined both the productivity of labor and capital and the incentives for
investment and innovation. Building on this insight, Desmet and Parente
(2012) link increasing market size with increasing firm size and argue that
these two interlinked developments were critical in accounting for the
Industrial Revolution. The size of markets, particularly urban markets,
expanded considerably in 17th-and 18th-century England. This played an
important role in enabling regional specialization and promoting Smithian
growth. Areas with poor-quality land like the Northwest and Midlands
developed their comparative advantage as centers of manufacturing (Kelly,
Mokyr, and Ó Gráda 2020). But this was not enough by itself.
One reason why institutions and markets were not enough is that they were
not unique to Britain. Numerous studies have found comparatively high
levels of market integration in parts of pre-industrial Europe (Bateman,
2011, 2012). Even in England, markets were already highly integrated by the
late Middle Ages (Federico, Schulze, and Volckart, 2021). Bouts of market
integration also occurred previously and in other parts of the world without
inducing a sustained increase in innovative activity. For instance, under the
Qing dynasty, China achieved comparatively high levels of integration
(Bernhofen, Li, Eberhardt, and Morgan, 2020). Moreover, the Dutch had
reasonably secure property rights and access to large international markets.
Why didn’t the Dutch have an Industrial Revolution? Why didn’t they end
up turning their trade networks, physical capital, and human capital into
sustained growth and innovation?
How About State Capacity?
All of the preconditions we have discussed so far either have not been
unique to Britain or were not directly related to innovation. This does not
make them unimportant. They were all part of the bigger story of why
Britain industrialized in the 18th century. But they leave some pieces
missing. One of these missing pieces is that Britain’s state capacity was
second to none in Europe.
In particular, simply because it governed a much larger territory, Britain’s
state capacity was much greater than that of the Netherlands. The Dutch
Republic was the leading economy of the 17th century. But it had to expend
tremendous resources to fend off French invasions in 1672–8, 1688–97, and
1701–14. It is a testament to the resilience of the Dutch economy that it did
not collapse from the fiscal challenges it faced in fighting the French. The
costs were huge. De Vries and van der Woude (1997, p. 681) estimate that,
in the mid-18th century, 7% of total Dutch GDP was spent on debt
financing. Interest payments constituted 70% of tax receipts. The Dutch
Republic remained rich – its per capita GDP exceeded that of Britain’s until
after 1820 – but it lacked the capacity for rapid, sustained growth.
Throughout the 18th century, the Dutch controlled a large share of world
trade. Amsterdam remained a financial capital. But the large debts incurred
during the French Wars had to be financed and this meant high taxes. When
a renewed crisis came in the 1780s, the Dutch Republic was unable to
respond. The Republic was eventually brought to an end by the French
invasion of 1795.
In contrast, Britain was able to finance numerous wars with France during
what historians have come to call the “Second Hundred Years’ War”
between 1688 and 1815. Like the Dutch Republic, the British state took on a
tremendous amount of public debt (Vries, 2015). Debt as a portion of GDP
soared to 250% by 1815. But unlike the Dutch Republic, the British state
was able to support this debt without resorting to draconian levels of
taxation. British taxes were higher than in France (about 12% of national
income compared to 6–7% in France), but they were not so high so as to
impede growth. As Brewer (1988) demonstrated, the bulk of taxes were
raised through indirect taxation, particularly on goods like beer.
This suggests the possibility that despite having many of the prerequisites
for modern economic growth, in a world characterized by interstate violence,
the Dutch Republic was simply too small to support the type of economic
growth that characterized industrializing Britain. The British could engage in
dynastic and commercial wars with their well-funded rivals without
destroying their economy. The Dutch could not. Of course, the Dutch could
have tried to avoid warfare, but this was difficult in this period. Any nation
that did not have a robust military, such as Poland-Lithuania, tended to be
gobbled up by its rivals. Yet, state capacity merely gives us one reason why
industrialization did not begin in the Dutch Republic. It does little to tell us
why the British were so innovative beginning in the latter half of the 18th
century. This requires knowing something more about the British people
themselves.
Maybe It Was Skilled Mechanical Workers?
Another important factor unique to Britain was its large supply of highly
skilled workers. These included craftsmen, printers, watch-makers,
carpenters, and engineers (Kelly, Mokyr, and Ó Gráda, 2014, 2020). Britain
also had a large supply of wrights, who were highly skilled mechanical
craftsmen (Mokyr, Sarid, and van der Beek, 2020). These craftsmen
specialized in water-powered machinery, which gave Britain an edge until
well into the 19th century, when steam power finally replaced water power.
One thing tying all of these workers together was fine mechanical skills.
These were the types of workers who would eventually create many of the
innovations of the Industrial Revolution. They would also be the ones who
would produce and repair these innovations at scale. Metal machines
requiring precise measurement and engineering acumen were the hallmarks
of the Industrial Revolution. It was these workers who made it possible
(Kelly, Mokyr, and Ó Gráda, 2020). The Dutch Republic, with its strong
focus on merchant activity and international trade, did not have an
equivalent workforce. As we will see later in this chapter, such skilled
workers were crucial to Britain’s industrialization. The Dutch Republic’s
relative paucity in this respect likely inhibited any possibility of an industrial
revolution there.
One critical factor that supported the existence of a highly skilled workforce
was the system of apprenticeships. In Britain, the contract between the
apprentice and a master was a private one, and hence voluntarily enforced
(Humphries, 2010). But it was regulated by municipal authorities. These
contracts were a way of overcoming a fundamental problem in the market
for human capital. How can talented but poor individuals acquire training in
a profession if they lack the means to pay for it? The apprentice contract
sought to overcome this problem by locking an apprentice in for a certain
number of years, usually seven, during which time he would provide labor
services for the master in return for bed, board, education, and training. As
the apprentice became more skilled, his labor would become much more
valuable than his costs of upkeep and training, allowing the master to recoup
the outlay of the earlier years.
Apprenticeship was not unique to Britain, but it was not tied to the guilds as
it was in the rest of Europe. Wallis (2008, p. 854) notes that apprenticeships
in early modern England “thrived despite, not because of, the guilds.” In
practice, apprentices often left their contracts early (Minns and Wallis,
2012). Journeymen would take their skills from one town to another. This
was important because the type of skills they transferred were best
transferred in person (de la Croix, Doepke, and Mokyr, 2017). As a result of
the movement of labor and a fluid and mobile labor market for apprentices
in London, craft skills were diffused widely both in London and beyond.
This can help explain Britain’s relatively high level of human capital. It can
also help explain why the difference in wages between skilled and unskilled
workers was relatively low (van Zanden, 2009).
In short, Britain had many of the prerequisites for industrial expansion – at
least, those prerequisites we can now see with the benefit of hindsight. It had
political institutions that protected property rights, while also allowing their
adjustment and renegotiation. It was open to innovation and invention
(despite the downsides associated with too rigorous an enforcement of
intellectual property). It had access to the Atlantic and its slave economies,
while avoiding the perils of the resource curse. Its political elites, while
mercantilist, encouraged domestic trade and, despite tariffs and other
restrictions, did not repress international trade. It had labor market
institutions that avoided the costs associated with guild privileges, but
provided skills and training on a large enough scale.
Britain was not the only place with at least one of these traits. The free cities
of the Holy Roman Empire had many of the best-skilled laborers on the
continent. The Dutch had secure property rights and access to international
markets. The Spanish and Portuguese had worldwide colonial empires.
Perhaps the difference was that the British had all of these factors? Take any
one away and it is unlikely that Britain would have industrialized the way it
did. But how did Britain industrialize? We turn to this crucial issue next.
An Innovative Economy
The Industrial Revolution saw a range of innovations concentrated in certain
sectors of the British economy. To illustrate the cumulative nature of the
major breakthroughs, we focus on one of those sectors: the cotton textile
industry.
For centuries, the productivity of spinners had been constrained by the use of
a single spinning wheel. In 14th-century China, there were experiments with
multiple spindles. In Europe, this development did not occur until the mid-
18th century. The first successful machine using this technique was the
spinning jenny, invented by James Hargreaves in 1764 or 1765 (see Figure
8.3). Prior to Hargreaves’s invention, spinning was a labor-intensive activity,
usually performed by women working from their own homes. In both
Europe and Asia, spinning was produced through a decentralized system of
household production, often in the countryside. Merchants or “putter-outers”
would distribute raw cotton fiber to spinners and then return a week or so
later to collect the spun cotton thread. Weaving – also a labor-intensive
activity – tended to be the prerogative of men and was typically better paid
than spinning.
Figure 8.3 The spinning jenny
Source: Figure in the public domain, available at
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Spinning_jenny#/media/File:Spinning_Jenny_improved_203_Mar
sden.png.
Cheap energy is another part of Allen’s story. Cheap energy was partly the
result of prior developments. The coal industry developed in England in
response to a shortage of timber in the 16th century. In particular, the growth
of London exhausted nearby sources of timber and induced a switch to coal-
burning. This was a drawn-out process that required innovations like
improvements to the chimney. It also provided incentives for the expansion
of the mining industry. Cheap coal was a particularly important spur to the
development of steam engines (see Figure 2.10).
Allen’s argument has come under critical scrutiny. First, technological
change does not always economize on the most expensive factor. For profit-
maximizing entrepreneurs, all costs are economized. The conditions under
which directed technological change seeks to economize on the most
expensive factor depend on the degree of substitutability between labor and
capital. We do not yet have a good estimate of whether these conditions were
met in Industrial Revolution Britain.
Second, more detailed studies have refined Allen’s account in the specific
context of the Lancashire cotton industry in the mid-18th century. Styles
(2021), for instance, argues that it was not the overall level of wages in the
British economy that mattered for the incentive to adopt a new technology. It
was the specific cost of labor in regional textile centers like Lancashire.
Humphries and Schneider (2019) provide counter-evidence suggesting that
female spinners did not in fact earn as high wages as Allen claimed.
Third, Allen infers that labor was expensive in Britain because wages were
high. However, high real wages reflected high levels of human capital and
not just the cost of labor. British workers were better fed, taller, capable of
working longer, and more skilled and numerate than their equivalents
elsewhere (Kelly and Ó Gráda, 2014). The higher wages they commanded
may therefore not be an accurate measure of labor costs.
Finally, Allen’s explanation does not address one key aspect of Britain’s
industrialization: its large supply of highly skilled workers. It was these
workers who drove the Industrial Revolution. Allen’s explanation also does
not account for the role that scientific advancements played in
revolutionizing many key industries. Sure, science was not important for
some of the advances in cotton textile machinery. But it was for the steam
engine and metallurgy. A satisfying explanation of the Industrial Revolution
needs to account for these factors while also accounting for why it began in
Britain. We turn next to such an explanation.
An Enlightened Economy
Thus far, we have noted numerous preconditions for industrialization. All
were apparent in Britain on the eve of industrialization. These include a
large supply of highly skilled workers, a large domestic economy, limited
and stable governance, and access to the growing Atlantic economy. Yet,
none of these explanations can account for why British innovators were so
adept at taking advantage of recent advances in science. This is the last part
of the puzzle in need of explanation.
Mokyr (2009, 2016) offers a theory addressing precisely this puzzle. He
emphasizes the role that cultural elites of the Enlightenment played in
propelling European – and particularly British – technological innovation.
Specifically, Mokyr (2016) emphasizes the role played by the Republic of
Letters in producing a culture that rewarded and encouraged innovation. The
Republic of Letters was a Europe-wide forum in which Enlightenment elites
disseminated and disputed the cutting-edge scientific findings and
philosophical insights of the day. It provided a setting for ideas to be tested
and norms of good behavior and scientific standards to develop. In previous
eras and in other societies, innovators were often siloed. Brilliant individuals
often worked in isolation (like Renaissance polymath Leonardo de Vinci).
Or they were dependent on the patronage of a single individual, often a
monarch whom they might offend or displease. But individual genius was
not enough to produce a culture of innovation. And the patronage systems of
most pre-modern societies were not conducive to the pursuit of innovative
new ideas.
The Republic of Letters crossed national and religious borders and followed
strict rules of intellectual engagement. Networks of elite minds were formed
that would have been impossible without this forum. For instance, the
famous French philosopher Voltaire corresponded with cultural elites far
away from his home in Paris – in England, Spain, Italy, Portugal, Germany,
the Netherlands, and beyond (see Figure 8.8). The Republic of Letters was
remarkably open to new scholars advancing ideas that overturned existing
orthodoxies, while also succeeding at vetting for quacks and charlatans.
Participants in the Republic of Letters created a hierarchy of merit wherein
individuals were judged on the basis of their ideas and not their social
pedigree. The Republic of Letters was successful because it weeded out bad
ideas and enabled good ideas to diffuse and spread.
Malthus turned out to be wrong. In particular, he did not fully anticipate the
extent to which married couples would seek to limit their number of
children. This demographic transition was a critical turning point in
economic history. Families began to deliberately choose family size within
marriage. It began in France in the late 18th and early 19th centuries before
spreading across Northern Europe and the US in the late 19th century during
the second Industrial Revolution (see Figure 9.3). Prior to this transition,
married women might have eight or more births (Guinnane, 2011). Whether
or not a society was close to the feasible maximum birth rate of around forty
to fifty births per 1,000 people largely depended on practices that limited
marriage or involved infanticide.
The timing and nature of the fertility transition remain subject to debate.
Certain populations began restricting fertility earlier, including Jews in
Western and Central (though not Eastern) Europe. The first country to
experience the demographic transition was France (see Figure 9.3), where
the birth rate began falling even before the Revolution. The reasons for this
decline are not well understood. Spolaore and Wacziarg (2021) view the
demographic transition as being spread by cultural contact. They note that
specific parts of France experienced the demographic transition first, and
that it only spread to more culturally remote regions such as Brittany more
slowly. One point emphasized by Spolaore and Wacziarg is that modern
fertility norms diffused from France, the originator of European cultural
modernity, and not from England, the source of economic modernity.
Figure 9.3 Children born per woman in Western Europe and the US, 1800–
2000
Data source: Roser (2021a).
The rise of cotton impacted not only the economy of the US but also its
political economy. Demand for slaves rose. The booming cotton trade drove
the center of slavery south and west, away from Virginia and North Carolina
towards the “black belt” of Louisiana, Mississippi, and Alabama.
Slave-produced cotton was highly profitable and it made the fortunes of
many a planter in the South. It was an utterly brutal system, and it played a
central role in Southern society. Nevertheless, it is important to recognize
that cotton exports represented less than 6% of the economy. While this is
far from a trivial number, exaggerated claims have been made of the pivotal
importance of slavery and cotton to American economic growth.
In fact, the existence of slavery slowed Southern industrialization and
urbanization. Southern elites held their wealth primarily in the form of
slaves. Investing in slaves was profitable, and it took resources away from
other, industrial, pursuits (Ransom and Sutch, 1988). This limited local
market size, making industrial production all the less attractive. As
Majewski (2009, p. 17) notes, “[S]lavery severely limited the size of markets
for southern manufacturers. Cities such as Richmond, Norfolk, and
Charleston, serving sparsely populated hinterlands, lagged behind northern
rivals. The southern economy certainly generated substantial profits for the
region’s many planters and farmers, but the slower growth of cities, industry,
and population created a sense of relative decline.”
In any case, removing slavery did not mean no cotton. Absent slavery, cotton
manufacturers would have had to purchase cotton from non-slave sources.
And in the medium-run, cotton production could have expanded through
small-scale farming (Wright, 2020). Southern elites certainly would have
been poorer without slavery. Cotton prices would have been higher in the
absence of coerced slave labor. But there is little reason to suppose that this
would have been more than a temporary disruption to textile production.
Clegg (2015, p. 296) notes that when “Britain was briefly cut off from
American cotton imports by the War of 1812, the price of cotton rose less
than it did in the 1860s, suggesting less dependence in this earlier period.”
The other important development was in the Northeast, where the
technologies of the First Industrial Revolution spread earliest. The growth of
industrial production expanded 100-fold between 1790 and 1850. Factors
identified by both Allen and Mokyr in Chapter 8 help explain these
developments. Initially, the rapid spread of new ideas from Britain was
facilitated by a shared Anglo culture that linked Britain with the newly
independent US. “Culture” was clearly not the only cause of New England’s
industrialization, but it helped. Those cultural attributes emphasized by
Mokyr as crucial for Britain’s rise did not exist in many parts of the world.
This was a hurdle that likely delayed industrialization. This hurdle was
minimal in New England, given its shared heritage with Britain.
Moreover, Allen’s argument (centered on relative factor prices) has bite for
the US. Real wages were high in America prior to the Revolution – by some
estimates higher than in Britain (Lindert and Williamson, 2016). Energy was
cheap. Water power and other natural resources such as timber were
abundant. This created a strong incentive for labor-saving innovation.
Examples include the first automatic flour mill invented by Oliver Evans in
1782 and Whitney’s cotton gin. Allen (2011a, p. 83) writes: “[T]he success
of the American economy depended on the application of inventive
engineering across the full spectrum of industries. The incentive to
mechanize was provided by the high cost of labour. The successful response
required a large pool of potential inventors. The interplay between challenge
and response made the USA the world’s productivity leader.” Until 1880, the
relative price of unskilled labor compared to energy and capital was not
higher in the US than in Britain. However, after 1880, “the incentives to
invent higher productivity technology led to an American lead. The
incentives to use more power per worker in America increased significantly
in this period – without a corresponding change in Britain” (Allen, 2014, p.
332).
Another precondition highlighted in Chapter 7 was limited and
representative government. Like Britain, the US had this, although not for
everyone. In Britain, this mattered for public good provision, particularly
transport networks. This was also the case in the US, even if the
circumstances were different. Of particular importance was the Interstate
Commerce Clause, which prevented individual states from passing laws that
impeded inter-regional trade and prohibited the granting of transport
monopolies. For instance, this clause struck down New York State’s attempt
in 1824 to grant a steamboat monopoly to Robert Fulton.
Improvements in transport infrastructure began in earnest in the early 19th
century. Probably the most famous improvement was the Erie Canal,
completed in 1825, which connected New York City to the Great Lakes.
Improvements like this helped knit together different regions and different
markets. Inter-regional trade resulted, permitting greater specialization and
the rise of an integrated domestic market for manufactured goods (North,
1966). Such large domestic markets were another precondition found in
Chapter 7. Only after the US was connected was such a market available.
The largest investments were in railroads, which were funded with both
public and private funds. Chapter 2 reviewed the debate over the importance
of the railroads. Recent findings suggest that they had an enormous impact
on US economic growth, mainly because they improved market access
(Donaldson and Hornbeck, 2016). By 1890, US aggregate productivity
would have been some 25% lower had there been no railroads (Hornbeck
and Rotemberg, 2021). In short, the railroad contributed to integrating the
US into a large and homogeneous market, one of the preconditions for the
rise of American manufacturing.
A second way in which US political institutions played an important role
was through investment in education. Unlike Britain, whose human capital
advantage was based primarily on mechanical skills, the US invested in
formal public education. Most of this investment was at the local, municipal
level. Engerman and Sokoloff (2012) claim this was a consequence of its
political institutions. Local government in Colonial America was highly
decentralized, egalitarian, and democratic, particularly in the Northeast.
Meanwhile, in the South, large-scale landlords had incentive to keep their
labor force uneducated. Literacy was of little value in farming. Keeping the
masses (both slaves and poor whites) uneducated limited their outside
options, allowing the elite to keep wages low (Galor, Moav, and Vollrath,
2009). This was not the case in the North, where industrialists could gain
from a more productive workforce. As a result, Northern states had
relatively high literacy rates and basic education.
Literacy rates stagnated in the mid-19th century with industrialization and
rapid immigration. However, in the early 20th century, the high school
movement brought a dramatic expansion in secondary education (Goldin and
Katz, 2008). This rise in human capital was so central to American growth in
the 20th century that Goldin (2001) calls it the “human capital century.”
Other factors were distinct to the American experience. Some were
important for why the US became rich, others not. For instance, the US
employed protective tariffs. Proponents of tariffs saw them as protecting
“infant industries” from foreign competition. But was the tariff essential for
American industrialization? The answer given by most economic historians
is a qualified no. The tariff did speed the growth of manufacturing,
particularly in the New England textile industry (Harley, 1992a, 1992b;
Rosenbloom, 2004), but tariffs likely just sped up a process that would have
happened anyway (Irwin, 2000, 2002).
American culture was also unique. But it is hard to discern which aspects of
American culture were important for the acceleration of economic growth
that occurred in the 19th century. Recall our discussion of the Weber
hypothesis in Chapter 4. For Weber, the archetypical example of how
Calvinism could mutate into a set of values suitable for economic growth
was an American: Benjamin Franklin. But as we also saw in that chapter, the
evidence for a specific Protestant work ethic – independent of the effects that
operated via education and human capital – is weak. Perhaps more important
than Calvinism per se was the general attitude that commerce was a means
to social advancement (Appleby, 2010). As the US lacked a hereditary
aristocracy, it lacked the inhibiting social norms that penalized commerce
and encouraged successful merchants and entrepreneurs from buying land
and entering the nobility.
A long tradition, dating at least back to Frederick Jackson Turner (1893),
locates a unique American individualism in the frontier. While American
individualism has had a significant effect on the country’s politics, taxation,
and welfare state (Bazzi, Fiszbein, and Gebresilasse, 2020), it is unclear
whether this frontier culture played an important role in its industrialization.
Early industrialization tended to be far from the frontier: first in the
Northeast and later in the Midwest. Rather, it is more likely that the
willingness of Americans to move to the frontier – something that was
commented upon by 19th-century European observers such as Alexis de
Tocqueville (1958) – reflected a broader American cultural belief in the
possibility of economic improvement.
Another important feature of America’s growth experience was immigration.
The population of the US grew from less than 4 million in 1790 to more than
76 million by 1900. While much of this was due to natural growth (that is,
births exceeding deaths), immigration played a key role (see Figure 9.6).
This had multiple implications for economic growth and industrialization.
First, it contributed to the growth of domestic markets. Even by the 1850s,
outside experts commented on America’s large and deep domestic market
for manufactured goods. Second, it provided the large workforce needed for
the US to become a major manufacturing center. Third, immigrants brought
with them human capital. This contributed to American inventiveness – a
large share of US inventors were immigrants or second-generation
immigrants. In fact, counties with more immigration in this period had more
and larger manufacturing establishments, greater agricultural productivity,
and higher rates of innovation (Sequeira, Nunn, and Qian, 2020). Those
counties that had high levels of historical immigration still have significantly
higher incomes, less poverty, less unemployment, more urbanization, and
higher educational attainment today.
Figure 9.6 US population and immigrant share, 1850–2010
Data sources: Various US Censuses and Migration Policy Institute
(https://www.migrationpolicy.org/programs/data-hub/charts/immigrant-population-over-time).
The Soviet Detour
Another path to industrialization was pioneered in Russia. This path was
based on command and control rather than on markets. Why did this take
place? And why did it ultimately result in failure?
Recent empirical research has overturned conventional views about the pre-
Soviet Russian economy. In the mid-19th century, Imperial Russia was a
closed, backwards agrarian economy. But following a series of modernizing
reforms by the end of the 19th century, Russia had, with Meiji Japan, joined
the group of late industrializing economies. By the early 20th century, it was
one of the fastest growing economies in the world (Gregory, 1994).
Despite its rapid growth, Russia remained agrarian. Agriculture made up
almost 60% of the economy in 1913 (Gregory, 2004b, p. 185). Inefficient
serf-based agriculture had been a major drag on productivity in the Russian
economy during much of the 19th century, even after the formal abolition of
serfdom in 1861 (Markevich and Zhuravskaya, 2018). But agrarian reforms,
notably the Stolypin Reforms of 1906 and 1911, made peasants residual
claimants. This had the potential to unlock agricultural productivity
(Castañeda Dower and Markevich, 2018). This period of rapid growth,
however, ended with the collapse of the Russian economy following World
War I (1914–18), the Russian Revolution (1917), and the onset of the
Russian Civil War (1917–22).
In the midst of this, Lenin imposed a policy of War Communism. This
effectively abolished markets and private property and produced famine and
destitution. We lack the space to provide a full account of the Communist
era. Nonetheless, the following bare-bones outline is important for the story
of modern economic growth. From this catastrophic low point in the early
1920s, the Soviet economy began to recover under Lenin’s New Economic
Policy, which enabled a revival of market activity. Marxist theory had
assumed that the first socialist revolution would occur in a heavily
industrialized economy. The Russian economy, however, even though it had
been rapidly growing prior to World War I, was not industrialized. Stalin’s
“achievement” was to rapidly accelerate the process of industrialization
through the collectivization of agriculture and a series of Five-Year Plans.
This came at a catastrophic human cost. Collectivization saw agricultural
yields plummet and forced requisitioning produced mass famine. Between
5.5 and 10.8 million died of starvation, with the majority of them in Ukraine
(Markevich, Naumenko, and Qian, 2021; Naumenko, 2021).
The rapid pace of Soviet industrialization provided an alternative path to
other developing countries, particularly in the immediate post-war period.
The Soviet state succeeded in providing many basic public goods, most
notably excellent technical education and essential healthcare. The Soviet
Union also eradicated smallpox and other diseases earlier than the US
(Troesken, 2015).
This accelerated pace of industrialization could not be sustained, however.
Even during the early phase of rapid growth, inefficiencies and wastage were
legendary (Gregory and Harrison, 2005). Many problems were initially
disguised by the sheer amount of labor (much of it slave labor), physical
capital, and natural resources the Soviet economy could mobilize.
Ultimately, though, the centralization of all economic decisions in the hands
of a dictator produced chaos. Stalin spent his time making seemingly trivial
decisions, including setting the price of metro tickets and making detailed
managerial appointments (Gregory, 2004a, pp. 112–14). Corruption and
rent-seeking were endemic (Anderson and Boettke, 1997; Boettke, 2001).
There were reforms after the death of Stalin, but as the Soviet economy
developed in the 1950s and 1960s, it struggled to provide basic consumer
goods that people wished to purchase.
Economic growth is ultimately about producing economic value. Here, the
Soviet economy failed. Soviet elites had access to special stores where
Western products were available but to which ordinary Soviet citizens were
denied access. The Soviet economy came to depend more and more heavily
on exports of oil and natural gas. When the price of oil collapsed in the
1980s, pressure to reform the Soviet economy became impossible to stop.
And when Mikhail Gorbachev began the process of reform, this soon led to
the collapse of the Soviet economy and the Communist system (Boettke,
1993).
The story of Soviet industrialization has two lessons. First, Communism is
incompatible with long-run growth. The Soviet Union was unable to
implement its original economic blueprint. The actual Soviet economy relied
on black markets and was unable to suppress the profit motive. Over time, it
became more and more sclerotic. A second lesson is that autocratic
government can stifle growth in the long run. This certainly does not mean
that economic growth cannot happen under autocracy – we will discuss
recent Chinese economic growth in the next chapter. Nor is limited
governance sufficient to bring about modern, sustained growth. Yet, the
Soviet case remains an important reminder of the potentially devastating
economic consequences of unchecked political power.
Chapter Summary
While the modern economy first arose in Britain, it was not confined there.
We have seen in this chapter how it spread to parts of Western Europe and to
the US.
The US had several advantages in this respect. It shared a common language
and culture with Great Britain so that intellectual developments in one
country were rapidly transmitted to the other, even after the Revolutionary
War. It had high wages, abundant land, and natural resources. This made it
well suited to adopt labor-saving technologies. Similarly, while Britain had a
comparatively large internal market for a pre-industrial economy, the US had
a huge domestic market. This was particularly true as its population
expanded and spread west and its internal transport networks improved. All
of these factors worked in favor of the US becoming an industrial giant by
the late 19th century. Although many other factors contributed to the
continued economic growth of the US in the 20th century, that is material for
another book.
But what about the rest of the world? In the 20th century, the fruits of the
modern economy expanded well beyond Western Europe and its offshoots.
How did this happen? Were the factors highlighted in previous chapters
crucial? We turn to these issues next.
10
Industrialization and the World It
Created
This book is titled “How the World Became Rich.” So far, we have
discussed why parts of Western Europe and the US became rich. But that is
only around 10–15% of the world’s population! To understand how the
world became rich, we need to understand how parts of the rest of the world
obtained the fruits of the modern economy.
Before proceeding, let us circle back to something we said in the first
chapter. We are well aware that the entire world is not actually rich. Over a
billion people still live in abject poverty. Eradicating such poverty should be
among the chief goals of civilization. We believe humanity is well on the
way to achieving this daunting task.
The world as a whole has certainly become much richer in the last 200 years.
In the last century or so, the fruits of these riches have finally spread well
beyond Europe and the US. They have also spread well beyond small groups
of elites. This is seen most starkly in Asia. As recently as 1960, most of the
continent was extremely poor – though no poorer than most civilizations
have been in world history (see Figure 10.1). After all, the condition for
nearly every human being living before 1800 was poverty or near-poverty.
This changed over the course of the 20th century, and it continues to change
in the present. Asia is becoming richer, and as such the world is becoming
richer. This chapter is dedicated to how this happened.
Sure, there is a long way to go. And sure, the path is even more fraught in
sub-Saharan Africa, parts of Latin America, and parts of Central and South
Asia. But this is real, tangible progress. The world is becoming richer.
Delayed Catch-up: The Shadow of Colonization
(and Other Factors)
One important reason that some countries have taken so long to catch up is
the shadow cast by colonization. It is highly unlikely, as we discussed in
Chapter 6, that colonization explains why the colonized world did not
industrialize first. However, in many parts of the world, colonization
undoubtedly played a role in delayed convergence.
Figure 10.1 Per capita GDP in select Asian countries, 1960–2019
Data source: World Bank (2019).
Why did the East Asian Tigers become rich? Their success was not predicted
by many economists ahead of time. In 1961, Paul Rosenstein-Rodan
published a series of forecasts about growth in developing countries. He
envisioned that countries in South Asia and sub-Saharan Africa would grow
much faster than their East Asian counterparts. He particularly
underestimated the growth of Taiwan and South Korea, predicting average
growth rates of 0.96% and 1.4%, respectively, between 1961 and 1976 as
compared to actual average growth rates of 4.8% and 7.3% (Acemoglu and
Robinson, 2012a). Why was this success story so hard to foretell?
Like Japan, these countries did not need to reinvent the wheel. Countries that
are poor and far from the technological frontier should in theory be able to
achieve rapid economic growth by importing new ideas and technologies. As
technology advances in rich countries, the catch-up potential of poor
countries should be even greater (Parente and Prescott, 2002). In one sense,
this economic “catch-up” helps explain much of the rise of the four East
Asian Tigers. In another sense, it simply pushes back the puzzle and raises a
further question: why were these countries able to catch up while many other
parts of the world remained poor? We will address this shortly. We first need
a better understanding of why some countries have the prerequisites for
catch-up growth.
In general, “catch-up” is not simply a matter of poor countries importing
technologies from rich countries. This of course does happen to some extent.
Cellular phones and later smartphones spread rapidly across the developing
world in the early 2000s. But in many cases, this is insufficient to ensure
catch-up growth. Pritchett (1997) characterized the dominant trend between
1950 and the 1990s as “divergence big time” between the wealthy and poor
world.
Given the dominant themes of this book, it should come as no surprise that
catch-up is not simply a matter of importing technology. Institutions matter.
So does culture. So do geography, demography, and a society’s colonial past.
Which of these were important in allowing East Asia to buck the trend?
In many respects, the geography of East Asia was not promising for modern
economic growth. Taiwan, Singapore, and South Korea lack natural
resources, especially oil and gas. But as we discussed in Chapter 2, it is often
economic geography that matters more than the presence of natural
resources. By economic geography we mean the presence of manmade
economic hubs and agglomerations. One of the most robust findings in
economics is that countries close to one another are more likely to trade with
one another (the so-called “gravity model” of trade).
Geographic features were hardly the only critical factors. But the emergence
of a cluster of densely populated manufacturing and consumption hubs in
East Asia was an important precondition for both the initial and continuing
successes of the economies of the region. Had Taiwan been located off the
coast of West Africa, it is hard to imagine it being as successful.
As we just saw, Japan was the first country to industrialize in Asia. South
Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, and Hong Kong are not only geographically
proximate to Japan, but had also been ruled or occupied by it (the former
two for a substantial period of time earlier in the 20th century). As a result,
these East Asian economies were well placed to follow the path pioneered
by Japan. Moreover, as the East Asian economies began their rapid growth
later than Japan, they were further from the economic frontier and had a
larger “backlog” of modern technologies to import. This gave them greater
potential for rapid growth.
Geography mattered in another way. The East Asian economies were all
relatively small. They were therefore forced to rely on international markets.
They did not fall into the trap that many larger developing countries did of
relying on protective tariffs and subsidies to support domestic manufacturing
firms. It also helped that the world moved towards freer trade after 1945
with the establishment of GATT (the General Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade). Protective tariffs and subsidies appeared plausible in countries with
large domestic markets like Brazil and India. Such policies could work (as in
19th-century America), but in practice they often freed domestic
manufacturers from the threat of international competition and encouraged
rent-seeking and corruption.
The poster child for these failures was Hindustan Motors, based in Kolkata,
India. From 1957 onwards, protected by a complex system of import permits
and government subsidies, Hindustan Motors produced the Ambassador
motor car. There was nothing wrong per se with this car. Yet, trade
protections allowed Hindustan Motors to keep producing and selling the
same, largely unchanged, vehicle for decades. It was not until the
liberalization of the Indian economy in the 1980s, which allowed Japanese
cars to be sold in India, that it became evident how far behind Indian
automobiles had fallen. Small and medium-sized countries like Hong Kong,
Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan were insulated from making such
mistakes. Simply by virtue of their size, they had to rely on international
markets.
What role did institutions play in East Asian development? In Chapters 3
and 9, we noted that institutions which constrain executive power have been
important in the story of economic growth. In Western Europe, the US,
Canada, and Australia, constraints on executive power tended to come
through democratic institutions. Yet, the East Asian Tigers were not initially
democratic. South Korea and Taiwan remained dictatorships until the 1980s.
Democratization followed economic growth rather than preceding it. Does
this speak against the “preconditions” we highlighted in earlier chapters?
As we discussed in Chapter 3, institutions are context-specific. A range of
different institutional arrangements can evolve to constrain rulers, solve
collective action problems, or enable credible commitments. Democracy is
one solution. Others exist. As Haggard (2004, p. 53) writes, “[T]he search
for a single institutional ‘taproot’ of growth is likely to be a misguided
exercise.” In fact, there was no single set of policies pursued by all of the
tiger economies, nor did they share the same institutions.
As each country had different political constituencies to satisfy and different
traditions and histories, they pursued a range of different policies. Hong
Kong, as a British colony, was the most reliant on markets and the most open
to trade – though even here there was a substantial role for government in
the provision of public housing. Singapore, also an ex-British colony, relied
on a pragmatic combination of the market and government.
In South Korea, formal constraints on executive power were weak at best in
the early years of industrialization. As a result, industrial policy was more
heavily directed by the government. But the South Korean economy was
also subject to discipline by worldwide markets. The key players were
chaebols, large industrial conglomerates that obtained government support
and guaranteed bank loans. The success of the chaebols rested ultimately on
their ability to enter export markets. The South Korean economy at the time
was simply too small and poor to provide a sufficiently large consumer base
to support large-scale manufacturing. These factors allowed South Korean
industrialization to succeed, perhaps in spite of the heavy role played by the
state. Export reliance provided much-needed market discipline and mitigated
some of the problems of corruption and non-transparency that otherwise
afflicted large firms. Reliance on exports is thus one feature that unifies the
experiences of the four Asian tiger economies.
In the absence of democratic institutions, the East Asian Tigers found ways
to constrain executive power. They did this by working in conjunction with
business elites in the private sector. In the post-war period, Haggard (2004,
p. 60) notes that “political leaderships in all of these countries faced the
problem of how to mobilize resources under political circumstances that
were highly uncertain.” Institutions like chaebols can be viewed as resolving
commitment problems between the state and the private sector. These
institutions diverged from those in the West and opened the tiger economies
up to charges of cronyism and corruption. But they also served an important
function by restraining predatory instincts of rulers.
To appreciate the importance of institutions in the East Asian success story,
it is informative to contrast it with the ultimate failure of the Eastern Bloc
economies in the same period. Eastern Bloc economies were able to achieve
fairly rapid growth initially. The state played a key role in mobilizing
resources; it forced savings to rise rapidly and encouraged industrialization.
The problems began once this initial period of recovery from World War II
passed (Eichengreen, 2007). Without a developed market, producers lacked
the incentives to produce goods that consumers wanted to buy. Inefficiencies
within the system accumulated. Incentive problems within firms’
bureaucracies grew worse over time, creating more opportunities for rent-
seeking.
Other factors mattered as well. In East Asia, cultural norms influenced by
the Chinese Confucian ideal of an educated ruling class favored investment
in human capital. Demographic factors also mattered. As they invested
heavily in human capital, East Asian societies rapidly underwent a
demographic transition. Average annual population growth in South Korea
slowed from 2.6% in the 1960s to 1.1% in the 1980s. In Hong Kong it fell
from 2.5% to 1.4% in the same period. This gave a one-off boost to recorded
growth rates – though it also means that these societies may run into adverse
demographic headwinds in the future. Meanwhile, population growth was
stable in South America and growing rapidly in sub-Saharan Africa. In the
Asian tiger economies, family sizes shrank as households moved from large
families to small households with highly educated children.
To what extent is the East Asian Tigers’ success replicable? China was able
to replicate many aspects of the East Asian economic model after its
disastrous experience with Communism, albeit on a much larger scale.
However, for countries in other parts of the world with different histories,
cultures, and geographies, the lessons from the East Asian miracle may be
more limited.
How China Is Becoming Rich
One enduring puzzle in the history of economic growth is why China did not
industrialize first. During the height of the Song dynasty (960–1279), China
was much richer than even the wealthiest parts of Europe. Yet by 1850,
Chinese per capita GDP was one-fifth that of England (Broadberry, Guan,
and Li, 2018). This gap would greatly expand over the subsequent century.
What happened? Why did China not undergo an Industrial Revolution first?
These are not the only questions that must be answered. In the past forty
years, the Chinese economy has grown at a break-neck speed. After decades
of mismanagement, famine, and persecution by Communist rule produced
mass impoverishment, the growth of the last four decades has lifted around
one billion Chinese citizens out of dire poverty. As recently as 1990, 66.2%
of Chinese were earning less than $1.90 per day, and 98.3% of the
population made less than $5.50 per day (World Bank, 2020b). In a country
of around 1.5 billion people, these numbers are staggering.
China has become much wealthier in the last few decades. As of 2016, only
0.5% of the population made less than $1.90 per day and 23.9% made less
than $5.50 per day (World Bank, 2020b). Per capita GDP has risen from $71
in 1962 (around $0.20 per day) to $10,262 in 2019 (see Figure 10.6). This is
one of the great human triumphs of our lifetime. Over one billion people
have been lifted out of the most extreme poverty in China alone. There is
still work to be done, of course. But this should not make us lose sight of
what an achievement this is. How did it happen?
First, we need to tackle the mystery of why China did not become rich first.
While there is much evidence that the economic peak of the pre-modern
Chinese empire was in the Song dynasty, recent scholarship focuses on the
last imperial Chinese dynasty – the Qing dynasty – who ruled China from
1644 to 1912. During the first 150 years of Qing rule, China reached its
greatest geographic extent and experienced a remarkable boom in
population. According to Glahn (2016, p. 322) this “boom of the eighteenth
century rested on a foundation of steady growth in population and
agricultural output” and represented “the maturation of the market
economy.”
Figure 10.6 Chinese per capita GDP, 1960–2019
Data source: World Bank (2020b).
Pomeranz (2000) suggested that around 1750 there was little to distinguish
the economy of Europe from that of China. According to this argument, the
divergence between China and the West has to be explained in terms of
factors that became relevant after 1750. Subsequent scholarship does not
support this claim, as we shall see, but it was indeed the case that in many
respects Qing China had institutions that looked favorable for economic
growth.
Consider Adam Smith’s statement that little else is required for economic
growth “but peace, easy taxes, and a tolerable administration of justice; all
the rest being brought about by the natural course of things” (Stewart,
1793/1980, p. 322). China in the 18th century certainly had the first two
ingredients for growth and arguably had the third ingredient too.
First, China was a large unified state. Though it has been divided on many
occasions, its longevity as a centralized state is in fact unique (Ko and Sng,
2013; Ko, Koyama, and Sng, 2018). From 1683 to 1796, Qing China
enjoyed a long period of internal peace. The only wars were on the frontiers
against nomadic peoples. In contrast, European states were frequently at war,
as we discussed in Chapter 3. The sheer size of China and high degree of
political centralization also facilitated market integration. As we noted in
Chapter 2, Northern and Southern China were connected via the Grand
Canal over 1,000 years ago. This connected markets for grain and other
goods. By the 18th century, the Grand Canal was supplying Beijing with
almost 1 million tonnes of rice annually (Glahn, 2016, p. 332). And as we
saw in Chapter 8, China and parts of Western Europe had comparable levels
of market integration around 1750 (Shiue and Keller, 2007), although
Chinese market integration appears to have declined thereafter (Bernhofen,
Li, Eberhardt, and Morgan, 2020).
Second, taxes were low in Qing China. In contrast to Europe, which saw a
dramatic rise in fiscal extractions by the state between 1500 and 1800, in
China the tax burden fell over time. The Qing imposed lower taxes than
previous Chinese dynasties, and the per capita tax rate fell further during the
18th century (Sng, 2014). The central state did not regulate the economy.
Merchants, organized through guilds, regulated commercial affairs at a local
level.
On Smith’s final point (the importance of a tolerable administration of
justice), China was governed by a large, meritocratic bureaucracy.
Contemporaries in 18th- and early 19th-century Europe saw this institution
as ensuring fair and impartial government. They contrasted it to European
governments, which were staffed with individuals appointed through
patronage or through the sale of offices. Voltaire, for instance, celebrated the
examination system as a form of impartial and benign government (yü Têng,
1943). In fact, the Chinese examination system was the model for the
introduction of professional bureaucracies in England and later the US.
Overall, the Chinese state provided more public goods and was less intrusive
than its European counterparts (Wong, 1997, 2012). Certainly, by pre-
modern standards, Chinese institutions provided something approximating a
tolerable administration of justice. Over time, however, there is evidence of
increasing corruption (Sng, 2014).
Despite these apparent advantages, rather than experiencing sustained
economic growth after 1750, China went into decline. A series of peasant
rebellions, culminating in the Taiping Rebellion of 1850–64, left millions
dead. Defeated by Britain in the Opium Wars (1839–42 and 1856–60), China
was forced to cede Hong Kong and to allow Western colonial powers to
establish trading posts within the empire.
There are numerous proximate causes of this collapse. These include
political failure by Qing elites and a Malthusian crisis brought about by a
rapidly growing population and limited ecological resources. But the deeper
cause was the absence of sustained innovation. The reasons for this were
institutional and cultural. As documented by Needham (1995), China had
been the most technologically innovative part of the world for centuries prior
to 1500. But this was no longer the case by the 18th century.
One reason for this was China’s political institutions. The emperor was
relatively unconstrained in contrast to Western Europe, where cities had
autonomy and parliaments contested the sovereign’s rule. More important
still was Europe’s fragmentation. Although it meant costly barriers to trade
and frequent conflict, fragmentation ensured that there was a considerable
degree of competition in the system (Scheidel, 2019). As we discussed in
Chapter 8, it was this fragmentation that allowed goods and people to
relocate to more favorable environments. Such freedoms were absent in
imperial China.
Moreover, while the imperial bureaucracy was meritocratic, it was subject to
imperial discretion (Brandt, Ma, and Rawski, 2014, p. 74). This meant that
bureaucratic agents were disincentivized to do their jobs “too well.” If they
did, the central government could crack down on them at any moment. It
would be all the more likely to do so if the bureaucrat were wealthy or
independent (Ma and Rubin, 2019). China was governed by a centralized,
hierarchical, hub-and-spoke network with the emperor at the center. This
hub-and-spoke structure was an efficient way of organizing a large and far-
flung empire, but it impeded the flow of information between different
nodes, discouraged innovation, and made the entire empire vulnerable to
system-wide collapse (Root, 2020).
These centralizing and autocratic tendencies were strengthened in the 17th
and 18th centuries, at a time when representative institutions were on the rise
in Western Europe. Unsure of their own political legitimacy, the Qing rulers
of China governed more autocratically. One particularly pernicious set of
policies they implemented were the “literary inquisitions,” which cracked
down on possible sources of dissent while promoting a narrow and
traditional understanding of China’s intellectual history (Xue, 2021).
For these reasons, the Qing institutional and cultural environment was not
conducive to innovation. While the imperial examination system encouraged
investment in human capital, it tended to reproduce existing knowledge. The
brightest students had an incentive to pursue Confucian education, which
had little practical application to science or technology (Huff, 1993; Lin,
1995). Such cultural norms may not have been as big of an issue under the
Song, who actively encouraged innovation, but they became a binding
constraint under the Qing dynasty. The importance of these norms meant that
even when the central government attempted reforms akin to the Meiji
Reforms – the so-called Self-Strengthening Movement (1860–94) – they did
so in a Confucian context. Practical education was largely eschewed in favor
of the old classics. This is summarized by the famous formula: “Chinese
learning as the basis; Western learning for practical use” (Wright, 1957, p.
1).
The lack of competition or a forum that encouraged innovation ultimately
impeded anything like the Scientific Revolution or Enlightenment from
occurring in China. As Mokyr (2016, p. 318) puts it, despite being highly
centralized and sharing a single written language and literary culture, “China
paradoxically lacked a single unifying coordinating mechanism such as a
competitive market in which new ideas were tested.” Hence, a combination
of centralized political institutions and a culture favoring the Confucian
classics over what Mokyr (2002) calls “useful knowledge” were jointly
responsible for stifling Chinese innovation in the centuries prior to the
Industrial Revolution. Nevertheless, to speak of a Chinese failure here is
misguided. As Mokyr (2016, p. 338) notes, “[W]hat is exceptional, indeed
unique, is what happened in eighteenth-century Europe.”
It is important to recognize that these factors did not act in isolation. They
interacted with one another. For instance, consider the clan-based nature of
Chinese families. As we discussed in Chapter 4, kin-based cultures have
certain advantages and disadvantages over individualistic cultures. On the
one hand, kin-based cultures have a larger safety net. The “clan” tends to
provide such insurance. However, this comes at the cost of institutional
development. In medieval Western Europe, societies were forced to form
corporations that provided mutual aid. These included guilds, communes,
and business associations. Such institutions were unnecessary in China,
where the clan provided mutual aid (Greif and Tabellini, 2017). A similar
logic explains why banking and finance first emerged in the West. In the
absence of the clan, there was a greater need for interpersonal risk sharing
and resource pooling. Such needs were much less pronounced in China,
since the clan mitigated these risks. As a result, there was less need for
banking and finance (Chen, Ma, and Sinclair, forthcoming).
The clan-based nature of Chinese families also played a role in the country’s
demography. Until the one-child policy was introduced in 1979, China had a
high birth rate. Early marriage and a multi-generational family system in
which newly married couples moved into the paternal home allowed women
to marry early and kept fertility rates high. Much of Chinese history is
consistent with a Malthusian perspective, as discussed in Chapter 5. The
dominant features were high birth rates, high death rates, and little long-run
change in per capita income. This framework helps explain why China
remained poor despite being a world technological leader for most of the
medieval period. All of those advancements resulted in more people, not
more wealth per person. For instance, while the total amount of cultivated
land more than tripled between 1400 and 1913, the total population more
than quintupled from 65 to 80 million in 1400 to 430 million in 1913
(Brandt, Ma, and Rawski, 2014, p. 52).
If institutions, culture, and demography are in part responsible for China
never fulfilling its technological promise, what role did these factors play in
explaining why the country has been able to grow rapidly in the past four
decades? It is this important question we turn to next. The Chinese miracle is
remarkable: nearly one billion people have been taken out of extreme
poverty within the span of our lifetime. How did this happen? Do the factors
highlighted in this book shed any light on China’s rise?
China has remained an autocracy despite the vicissitudes that it experienced
following its defeat in the Opium Wars and the fall of the Qing dynasty. The
Republican period (1912–49) saw the first sustained local efforts at state-
building and industrialization. Between 1912 and 1936, Chinese industrial
output grew at a faster rate than Japan, India, or Russia/the USSR (Brandt,
Ma, and Rawski, 2017, p. 198). One achievement of the Communist period
(1949– ) was to build on this and to successfully construct a modern
centralized state. But this came at a tremendous human cost. The Communist
period saw forced collectivization of agriculture and a series of Five-Year
Plans culminating in the disastrous Great Leap Forward (1958–62). The
resulting famine was the direct consequence of Communist policies.
What happened next illustrates one of the costs of moving away from a
market economy. In a market economy, the pace of industrialization was
constrained by the productivity of agriculture. If too many workers were
drawn into the cities to work in factories, demand for foodstuffs would
increase and grain in the fields would go unharvested. The scissors of supply
and demand would drive prices up, slowing the pace of industrialization.
Mao and his advisors believed they could accelerate this process by
bypassing the market mechanism. Specifically, they thought that peasants
were inefficiently cultivating small plots of land or not using the latest
fertilizers. They also suspected that peasants were hoarding grain in the hope
of profit. Collectivization was thus seen as a means both to greatly increase
production and to render the resulting food surplus legible to the state, which
could easily collect and transport it to feed the urban population. The Great
Leap Forward was thus a misguided attempt to jump-start industrialization.
Regardless of the personal culpability of Mao, it was the broader political
system, one characterized by a lack of checks and balances, that was crucial
in magnifying the scale of the tragedy. At the heart of the famine were
overoptimistic estimates of grain production. This was in large part due to
local bureaucrats having a systematic incentive to inflate estimates. On top
of this, highly inflexible procurement and an unwillingness of political elites
to recognize the problem led to disaster. Local cadres used extreme violence
to enforce their quotas. Peasants accused of hiding food or of shirking were
beaten and sometimes killed. Collectivization saw productivity plummet as
the tacit knowledge peasant farmers had of their local soils was lost when
they were herded into collective farms. In fact, the famine was most severe
in areas where agricultural productivity had been the highest (Meng, Qian,
and Yared, 2015). Meanwhile, news of mass starvation was covered up. The
numbers who died during the Great Famine are debated. Plausible estimates
range from around 15 to 45 million (Ó Gráda, 2015, pp. 130–73). Even at
the more conservative estimates of 20–30 million dead, this manmade
famine ranks among the most destructive episodes in human history.
An important lesson of this book is that political institutions are a key reason
why economically beneficial policies are often ignored while economically
destructive policies are pursued. The fact that China was ruled by an
autocratic and highly centralized state made these policy disasters not only
possible but also likely. The disasters of the Great Leap Forward and the
Great Famine were followed by the Cultural Revolution, during which
(according to conservative estimates) 750,000–1,500,000 people died. While
the Chinese Communist Party had been successful in unifying the country
and investing in basic education and healthcare, the result of the Great Leap
Forward and the Great Famine was that by the 1970s China was one of the
poorest places on the earth. Yet, the autocratic and highly centralized nature
of Communist rule also enabled the country to successfully reverse course
under Deng Xiaoping, the Chinese leader who initiated market-oriented
reforms in 1979.
We have highlighted in this book the importance of constraints on executive
power in promoting growth. In the case of the East Asian Tigers, constraints
were not formally part of the political system. The Tigers benefited from
being small. This meant that private enterprise was able to constrain the
government’s autocratic tendencies. But this was not the case for China. The
Chinese central government remained exceedingly powerful relative to other
important organizations and people. Yet, China still modernized its economy
and escaped poverty. Can the features we have highlighted in this book
account for this feat?
Much like Japan and the East Asian Tigers, China did not need to reinvent
the wheel of industrialization or the modern economy. It could borrow
industrial inputs and managerial know-how from abroad via opening up to
foreign direct investment. Tremendous under-utilized economic potential
had clearly been there for decades prior to the reforms of the late 1970s.
With over one billion people languishing in subsistence farming, China was
an obvious source of low-wage labor. But a large labor force was hardly the
only or most important factor in Chinese growth. After all, such a labor force
existed prior to the 1980s, and surplus labor has long been a characteristic of
developing economies.
China’s economic reforms can be divided into two periods: early reforms
between 1978 and 1995 and post-1995 reforms (Brandt, Ma, and Rawski,
2017). The first set of reforms dismantled many aspects of the command
economy. Agriculture had been gravely damaged by collectivization and the
misguided attempt to industrialize rural areas. In the late 1970s, these
policies began to be reversed. Among the first reforms was the revival of
household farming. Grain output rose by nearly one-third between 1978 and
1984 (Brandt, Ma, and Rawski, 2014, p. 96). Importantly, these increases in
agricultural productivity freed up hundreds of millions of workers to move
into industrial labor.
The post-1995 reforms involved widespread privatization. The state’s share
of industrial output declined from almost 50% in 1995 to 24% in 2008.
There was also an expansion in legal protection for private enterprise. There
was no rule of law in pre-reform China. As a market economy was
introduced, a corresponding legal system had to be developed. One
important development was the adoption of elements of German civil law
such as the right for private citizens to sue the government (Fukuyama,
2014, p. 364). Despite Communist opposition to private property rights,
reforms were able to create
a set of usufructuary (usage) rights that could be bought, sold,
mortgaged, or transferred, in which the state nonetheless retained
formal ownership. Thus, in China’s booming real estate market, no one
technically “owns” an apartment or house. One owns the equivalent of
a lease whose term extends up to seventy years, which is acquired in
exchange for land-use fees. (Fukuyama, 2014, p. 366)
China did not adopt Western institutions wholesale. Rather, relatively minor
moves towards greater rule of law were sufficient to induce a radical
transformation of its economy and society.
As with other East Asian economies, another aspect of China’s rise was its
increased openness to global trade. The establishment of economic zones
encouraged foreign direct investment into the country. Given how far behind
China was from the world’s economic frontier and how low its wages were,
there were tremendous opportunities for catch-up growth. Once China
rejoined the global economy, its trade ratio rose from 9.7% to 31.9%
between 1978 and 1993 (Brandt, Ma, and Rawski, 2014, p. 98). Foreign
investment poured in and state enterprises were made more efficient. Growth
accelerated in the 1990s and 2000s, driven by reforms that restructured the
bloated public sector. Chinese growth has slowed since the early 2000s
(when growth was around 10% per year; it is now around 6–7%), but this is
precisely what a model of catch-up growth would predict.
That is what happened. But how did it happen? How did such rapid growth
occur under an autocratic government? Two features of China’s history are
important for understanding its modern growth. The first is institutional.
Although the Chinese emperor historically faced few constraints, one
difference between the way that the Chinese and Europeans legitimated
political rule was that, for the Chinese, good rule meant legitimate rule. A
good Chinese emperor was viewed as having the “Mandate of Heaven.” If
he were overthrown or responded poorly to a crisis, it was a sign that he did
not have the Mandate.
This principle continues to hold influence for legitimating Communist rule
today, even if in a different guise. After the death of Mao in 1976, whose
legitimacy was tied to his role as the founding father of the People’s
Republic of China, the Chinese leadership faced a legitimacy deficit. Not
only did none of the potential successors to Mao have a personal history like
his, but there was internal turmoil over who would lead. Given this
legitimacy deficit, Deng Xiaoping, who led China from 1978 to 1989, turned
to “good rule means legitimate rule.” This helped solve many of the issues
associated with unconstrained governance. Even though the state could have
infringed on the rights of its citizens at any time – and it certainly did, and
continues to today, especially its ethnic and religious minorities – doing so in
a way that would have undermined economic growth would have also
undermined the legitimacy of the ruling Communist Party. As China has
remained highly centralized and autocratic, there is always a possibility of
the current economic policies being reversed. And indeed, under Xi
Jinping’s presidency since 2013 there has been both a strengthening of
autocracy and a move away from the market. China has not escaped from the
“bad emperor problem.”
Another historical feature that has contributed to China’s growth has to do
with its culture. Like Japan and other East Asian countries, literacy was
relatively high in pre-modern China. This was a product of a culture that
viewed education as a means of rising economically and socially. Although
historically education was confined to the Confucian classics, this type of
education became less important after the dismantling of the old Chinese
bureaucracy in 1905. But the emphasis on education remained, especially in
those places where it was important in the past. In fact, places that produced
more top-level bureaucrats in the imperial period still have much higher
levels of educational attainment today (Chen, Kung, and Ma, 2020). This
legacy of high educational attainment is likely one reason that Chinese
economic success has not petered out (Brandt, Ma, and Rawski, 2014).
This section glosses over numerous aspects of Chinese history and its recent
rise. Yet, much like the other cases considered in this chapter, it reveals both
the potential and the limits of using lessons from history to understand why
poor parts of the world can become rich. China has become relatively rich
without having many of the attributes of 18th-century England or the 19th-
century US. Above all, it has had few constraints on governance. Yet, those
histories point us to what might matter for economic growth to occur.
Institutions are of critical importance. But we also are limited in our
knowledge of which institutions matter. When China abandoned command
and control, it also defied the policy consensus of the 1990s (known as the
Washington Consensus) which emphasized privatization and deregulation
(Weber, 2021). Yet, China’s pace of economic growth was faster than those
countries that adopted what were perceived to be best-practice policies.
The appropriate institutional reforms will always be context-dependent and
politically constrained. This is one of the key takeaways from this book.
What worked to make some parts of the world rich worked in a certain
cultural, historical, and institutional context. We can learn from this past, but
we should not be wedded to it.
Chapter Summary
The advent of modern economic growth created tremendous opportunities
for catch-up growth. But these opportunities were difficult to grasp. Not all
societies were able to benefit from them.
Some were colonies and hence unable to implement independent economic
policies. Others had factor endowments that were unsuited for the labor-
saving, capital-intensive technologies produced by countries on the
technological frontier. Still others had institutions that repressed
entrepreneurship and markets. The kinds of political institutions that had for
centuries governed the agrarian empires of Eurasia were not suited for the
new environment in which rapid technological change was possible.
For these reasons, while the global economy greatly expanded after 1800
and technological innovations diffused across the world, the pace of growth
was uneven. India and much of Africa remained Malthusian economies.
Total GDP increased tremendously in these countries, but it was almost all
absorbed into population growth. Per capita income remained close to
subsistence.
Outside Europe or settler colonies like Argentina, Australia, and New
Zealand that were land- and resource-abundant and underpopulated, in the
middle of the 19th century there was little sign of sustained growth in per
capita income. The first non-Western country to achieve rapid economic
growth was Japan. This was predicated on a change in political institutions
and, in the absence of natural resources or abundant farmland, was initially
based on Japan’s successful entry into international textile markets. Later,
Japanese firms moved into iron, steel, and manufacturing. The path
pioneered by Japan could be followed by other East Asian countries with
similar factor endowments such as South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, and
Hong Kong. Later, following an experiment with Communist central
planning, a version of it could implemented on a much larger scale (and with
a much greater role of government and state-owned firms) by China.
In many respects, these developments have contributed more to the world
becoming rich than anything that happened in England or the US. The
countries that became rich first hold a relatively small share of the world’s
population. For the world to become rich, it was necessary for those riches to
spread to more populated places. First and foremost this meant Asia, which
holds around 60% of the world’s population. There is still a long way to go.
But the developments summarized in this chapter give reason for optimism
that soon the whole world will indeed be rich.
11
The World Is Rich
The world is richer than it has ever been. It is likely to continue to become
richer for the foreseeable future. The world becoming richer means that
more and more of humanity can be lifted from dire poverty. Riches free
human minds to concentrate on pursuits besides acquiring the basic
necessities of life. Riches allow us to live longer and healthier lives and
provide us with material comforts that our ancestors could have only
dreamed of. In the 2020s, we will reach a point where basic comforts are
available to a large fraction of the world’s population – although certainly
not everyone. This achievement deserves to both be celebrated and
understood.
We still have a long way to go. While over a billion people have been lifted
out of poverty just in our lifetime, around a billion people still live in abject
poverty. Many of these people live in sub-Saharan Africa, although many
others live in Latin America, Central Asia, South Asia, and Southeast Asia.
Lifting these people out of poverty is one of the most important things the
next generation of humans can do. But how can this be achieved?
Understanding where wealth comes from helps us lift more people out of
poverty. This is why we wrote this book. The literature in economics and
economic history has provided many answers to these questions in recent
years, but until now there has not been one place where interested readers
could go to get an understanding of these various theories. Nor do most
existing accounts seriously consider the interactions between their proposed
explanation and other theories. The goal of this book is to do both. In the
first part of the book, we provided an overview of the primary explanations
for “how the world became rich.” We discussed theories focusing on
geography, institutions, culture, demography, and colonization. As we were
writing these chapters, we realized just how hard it is to discuss these
theories in isolation. How do you talk about institutions without considering
the effect of culture, or how they are shaped by geography? Is demography
really independent of institutions? Can we really silo off colonization as if it
existed independent of the various attributes of the colonizing and colonized
countries?
This is why, in the second part of the book, we drew these theories together
to explain why the first place to achieve sustained economic growth –
Britain – did so. Of course, this required explaining some of the peculiarities
of British history. But we were also able to use this history to understand
what preconditions mattered for Britain’s industrialization and why they
mattered. Both of these are important. The “what” matters because it
provides insights into the preconditions that might generally be necessary for
sustained economic growth. The “why” matters because it gives insight into
what might have been particular about Britain and thus not necessary in
other contexts.
Going beyond Britain, as we do in Chapters 9 and 10, has led us to a few key
insights. Once the initial breakthrough to sustained economic growth had
taken place, the path was open for other countries to achieve catch-up
growth. Certain institutions, particularly those that encouraged innovation
and entrepreneurship and allowed for the free-flowing of ideas, may have
been less important for countries catching up to the frontier (as opposed to
those on the frontier).
Markets are also crucial for sustained economic growth. Textbook
economics often focuses on the efficiency properties of markets: the
principle that in a competitive market, prices will be bid down to marginal
cost so that there is no deadweight loss. But from a long-run perspective,
what matters more is that markets provide incentives for innovation. Growth
episodes like the Industrial Revolution were not planned by policy-makers.
They resulted from an untold number of decisions by private individuals to
experiment with new production methods or to build new factories or to
mechanize production. Command economies are also capable of growth. In
the short run, they can grow faster than market economies because policy-
makers can use coercion to mobilize resources. This occurred in the Soviet
Union under Stalin and in Eastern Europe after World War II. But sheer
labor power and investment eventually run into diminishing returns if there
is no innovation and there are no markets to coordinate investment decisions.
And while command economies like the Soviet Union excelled at military
innovation, they were abysmal at providing new goods that consumers
actually wanted to buy.
Market do not operate in a vacuum. As Adam Smith understood, the
proposition that self-interest or market forces have beneficial outcomes is
conditional on the appropriate institutional environment. For this reason, we
have placed considerable emphasis on institutions throughout this book. But
institutions cannot be viewed in isolation. A society’s institutional
environment interacts with other variables. This means that the outcomes
associated with certain institutional environments will be context-specific.
For example, the institutional reforms that led China to escape extreme
poverty in the 1980s were quite minor: they involved restoring private
production in agriculture, the creation of special economic zones, and the
abandonment of central planning. At no time did the Chinese Communist
Party contemplate the introduction of genuine representative institutions or
formal constraints on the state. The important point is that this liberalization
occurred at a point in time when rapid convergence to the economic frontier
was possible. Even relatively minor institutional changes had huge payoffs
as China was able to become the world’s low-cost producer of manufactured
goods.
Institutions also interact with culture. By culture, recall that we mean the
conceptual lens or heuristics individuals in a society use to interpret the
world. Sustained economic growth may have been possible in the ancient
world. Certainly, the Roman Empire at its height had an integrated and
sophisticated market economy. Yet, one reason it never achieved anything
close to an “industrial revolution” appears to have been cultural. Successful
individuals in the Roman Empire aspired to a life of leisure. In contrast,
consider the case of Britain that we surveyed in Chapters 7 and 8. Britain
had many of the institutional prerequisites needed for take-off by the mid-
18th century: relatively limited government, an apprenticeship system that
honed the skills of craftsmen, and institutions favoring investment in public
goods. But it also had cultural attributes that complemented these
institutions. Hard work did not place someone at the bottom of the social
scale. Among the intellectual elite, the idea of continued progress seemed
like a realistic and worthwhile goal. These cultural attributes were not
unique to Britain. They were shared with parts of continental Europe, and
many non-European societies had some of these attributes at some point in
their history. But no society, at least prior to the mid-18th century, had the
combination of these cultural attributes and institutional characteristics.
Once the key elements of sustained growth emerged, first during Britain’s
Industrial Revolution, and then more decisively after 1850, elements of the
blueprint provided by the early developers could be used elsewhere, even if
it looked a bit different depending on the location. In Chapter 10, we showed
how different parts of the world took pieces of that blueprint and adapted
them to their own institutional and cultural characteristics. In some cases,
such as Meiji Japan, this required a wholesale institutional change. In other
cases, such as late 20th-century China, pieces of the blueprint were adapted
to the local institutional and cultural context.
This is what makes the problem of economic development in the poorest
parts of the world so vexing. There is no silver bullet. We know what has
worked in various historical contexts. But merely transplanting what worked
elsewhere to poverty-stricken societies isn’t the solution. Context matters.
Culture and the historical past matter. So do demography and geography.
Of course, this does not mean that bringing wealth to the world’s poorest is a
lost cause. Knowing what did work and why it worked matters precisely
because it allows us to build a cumulative body of knowledge. This, in turn,
helps provide a framework for understanding what economic policies are
likely to succeed. It will take substantial local knowledge to know how to
apply this framework to a given society. Which parts can be used and which
can be discarded? While the answer is always “it depends,” this knowledge
is still vital to even know where to begin.
Although this book has almost exclusively focused on the positive side of
the world becoming rich (with the obvious exception of colonization), we
are aware of the downsides. Foremost among these is climate change.
Industrialization saw a massive rise in the use of fossil fuels, which polluted
many parts of the world and contributed to the heating of the earth. If the
current pace of global warming continues (or even continues to rise at a
slower pace), all of the economic advancements highlighted in this book
might have been for naught. We cannot enjoy the fruits of prosperity if we
have killed the ecosystems necessary for human life on earth.
But there is reason for hope on this front too, and it is related to global
prosperity. On the one hand, as countries industrialize and consumption
rises, they initially tend to pollute more. Not only do these countries have
more factories, but people drive more automobiles and eat more meat (which
contributes much more to environmental degradation than plant agriculture).
On the other hand, they also have more resources to combat deforestation
and to invest in mitigation. Many of the richest countries today have reduced
their levels of pollution in recent decades.
Moreover, if humanity is going to survive a changing climate, the answer
will likely lie in technological progress. Whether this means technologies
that allow for clean energy production, carbon capture, or something else,
we cannot say. And it is not just that we are not experts. In reality, it is likely
that nobody knows what yet-to-be discovered technologies will help
alleviate climate change. But this is one of the most important reasons why
prosperity is so important. When human brain power can be used for solving
the most pressing issues of the day rather than focusing on where one’s next
meal is coming from, the odds of technological progress are much greater.
Freeing up a few billion minds to help solve these problems is probably our
best hope. So, while modern economic growth may have been a leading
cause of climate change, it is also at the center of the solution.
We hope this book has given you some insight into how the world became
rich. We also hope it gives you a better appreciation of just how important
understanding history is for modern problems. It is not so much that history
repeats itself. It is that we can learn so much from history – what worked,
why it worked, and in what context it worked. The blueprints of the past
contain much valuable information. While it is not always obvious how to
use that information – if it can be used at all – it is one of the most valuable
resources we have for making the world a better place.
References
Acemoglu,
1. Daron, Davide Cantoni, Simon Johnson, and James A.
Robinson. 2011. “The Consequences of Radical Reform: The French
Revolution.” American Economic Review 101(7): 3286–307.
Acemoglu,
2. Daron and Simon Johnson. 2007. “Disease and
Development: The Effect of Life Expectancy on Economic Growth.”
Journal of Political Economy 115(6): 925–85.
Acemoglu,
3. Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2001. “The
Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical
Investigation.” American Economic Review 91(5): 1369–401.
Acemoglu,
4. Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2002.
“Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of
the Modern World Income Distribution.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 117(4): 1231–94.
Acemoglu,
5. Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2005a.
“Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-run Growth.” In
Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1, ed. Philippe Aghion and
Steven Durlauf. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 385–472.
Acemoglu,
6. Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2005b.
“The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and
Economic Growth.” American Economic Review 95(3): 546–79.
Acemoglu,
7. Daron and James A. Robinson. 2006. The Economic
Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Acemoglu,
8. Daron and James A. Robinson. 2012a. “The Big Mis-
forecast.” http://whynationsfail.com/blog/2012/4/6/the-big-mis-
forecast.html.
Acemoglu,
9. Daron and James A. Robinson. 2012b. Why Nations Fail.
New York: Crown Business.
10.
Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson. 2019. The Narrow Corridor:
States, Society, and the Fate of Liberty. New York: Penguin.
11.
Acemoglu, Daron and Alexander Wolitzky. 2011. “The Economics of
Labor Coercion.” Econometrica 79(2): 555–601.
12.
Akçomak, İ Semih, Dinand Webbink, and Bas ter Weel. 2016. “Why
did the Netherlands Develop So Early? The Legacy of the Brethren
of the Common Life.” Economic Journal 126(593): 821–60.
13.
Alesina, Alberto and Paola Giuliano. 2015. “Culture and Institutions.”
Journal of Economic Literature 53(4): 898–944.
14.
Alesina, Alberto, Paola Giuliano, and Nathan Nunn. 2013. “On the
Origins of Gender Roles: Women and the Plough.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 128(2): 469–530.
15.
Allen, Robert C. 1992. Enclosure and the Yeoman. Oxford: Clarendon
Press.
16.
Allen, Robert C. 1994. “Agriculture during the Industrial Revolution.”
In The Economic History of Britain since 1700, ed. Roderick Floud
and Donald McCloskey. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
pp. 96–122.
17.
Allen, Robert C. 2001. “The Great Divergence in European Wages and
Prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War.” Explorations in
Economic History 38(4): 411–47.
18.
Allen, Robert C. 2009a. The British Industrial Revolution in Global
Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
19.
Allen, Robert C. 2009b. “Engels’ Pause: Technical Change, Capital
Accumulation, and Inequality in the British Industrial Revolution.”
Explorations in Economic History 46(4): 418–35.
20.
Allen, Robert C. 2011a. Global Economic History: A Very Short
Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
21.
Allen, Robert C. 2011b. “Why the Industrial Revolution Was British:
Commerce, Induced Invention, and the Scientific Revolution.”
Economic History Review 64(2): 357–84.
22.
Allen, Robert C. 2014. “American Exceptionalism as a Problem in
Global History.” Journal of Economic History 74(2): 309–50.
23.
Allen, Robert C., Jean-Pascal Bassino, Debin Ma, Christine Moll-
Murata, and Jan Luiten van Zanden. 2011. “Wages, Prices, and
Living Standards in China, 1738–1925: In Comparison with Europe,
Japan, and India.” Economic History Review 64(1): 8–38.
24.
Allen, Robert C. and Jacob Louis Weisdorf. 2011. “Was There an
‘Industrious Revolution’ before the Industrial Revolution? An
Empirical Exercise for England, c. 1300–1830.” Economic History
Review 64(3): 715–29.
25.
Alsan, Marcella. 2015. “The Effect of the TseTse Fly on African
Development.” American Economic Review 105(1): 382–410.
26.
Andersen, Thomas Barnebeck, Jeanet Bentzen, Carl-Johan Dalgaard,
and Paul Sharp. 2017. “Pre-Reformation Roots of the Protestant
Ethic.” Economic Journal 127(604): 1756–93.
27.
Anderson, Gary M. and Peter J. Boettke. 1997. “Soviet Venality: A
Rent-seeking Model of the Communist State.” Public Choice 93(1–
2): 37–53.
28.
Anderson, R. Warren, Noel D. Johnson, and Mark Koyama. 2017.
“Jewish Persecutions and Weather Shocks, 1100–1800.” Economic
Journal 127(602): 924–58.
29.
Appleby, Joyce. 2010. The Relentless Revolution: A History of
Capitalism. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.
30.
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1972. “Gifts and Exchanges.” Philosophy and Public
Affairs 1(4): 343–62.
31.
Arruñada, Benito. 2016. “How Rome Enabled Impersonal Markets.”
Explorations in Economic History 61(1): 68–84.
32.
Arteaga, Fernando, Desiree A. Desierto, and Mark Koyama. 2020.
“Shipwrecked by Rents.” CEPR Discussion Paper 15300.
33.
Ashraf, Quamrul and Oded Galor. 2011. “Dynamics and Stagnation in
the Malthusian Epoch.” American Economic Review 101(5): 2003–
41.
34.
Bai, Ying and James Kai-sing Kung. 2011. “Climate Shocks and Sino-
nomadic Conflict.” Review of Economics and Statistics 93(3): 970–
81.
35.
Bai, Ying and James Kai-sing Kung. 2015. “Diffusing Knowledge
while Spreading God’s Message: Protestantism and Economic
Prosperity in China, 1840–1920.” Journal of the European Economic
Association 13(4): 669–98.
36.
Bailey, Mark. 2014. The Decline of Serfdom in Late Medieval England:
From Bondage to Freedom. Woodbridge: Boydell & Brewer.
37.
Ball, Philip. 2017. The Water Kingdom: A Secret History of China.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
38.
Balla, Eliana and Noel D. Johnson. 2009. “Fiscal Crisis and
Institutional Change in the Ottoman Empire and France.” Journal of
Economic History 69(3): 809–45.
39.
Banerjee, Abhijit and Lakshmi Iyer. 2005. “History, Institutions, and
Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure
Systems in India.” American Economic Review 95(4): 1190–213.
40.
Banfield, Edward C. 1958. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society.
New York: Free Press.
41.
Bateman, Victoria N. 2011. “The Evolution of Markets in Early Modern
Europe, 1350–1800: A Study of Wheat Prices.” Economic History
Review 64(2): 447–71.
42.
Bateman, Victoria N. 2012. Markets and Growth in Early Modern
Europe. London: Pickering & Chatto.
43.
Bates, Robert H. 1981. Markets and States in Tropical Africa. Berkeley:
University of California Press.
44.
Bazzi, Samuel, Martin Fiszbein, and Mesay Gebresilasse. 2020.
“Frontier Culture: The Roots and Persistence of ‘Rugged
Individualism’ in the United States.” Econometrica 88(6): 2329–68.
45.
Becker, Gary S. and H. Gregg Lewis. 1973. “On the Interaction
between the Quantity and Quality of Children.” Journal of Political
Economy 81(2, Part 2): S279–88.
46.
Becker, Gary S., Tomas J. Philipson, and Rodrigo R. Soares. 2005.
“The Quantity and Quality of Life and the Evolution of World
Inequality.” American Economic Review 95(1): 277–91.
47.
Becker, Sascha O., Katrin Boeckh, Christa Hainz, and Ludger
Woessmann. 2016. “The Empire Is Dead, Long Live the Empire!
Long-run Persistence of Trust and Corruption in the Bureaucracy.”
Economic Journal 126(590): 40–74.
48.
Becker, Sascha O., Erik Hornung, and Ludger Woessmann. 2011.
“Education and Catch-up in the Industrial Revolution.” American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3(3): 92–126.
49.
Becker, Sascha O. and Ludger Woessmann. 2008. “Luther and the
Girls: Religious Denomination and the Female Education Gap in
Nineteenth-century Prussia.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics
110(4): 777–805.
50.
Becker, Sascha O. and Ludger Woessmann. 2009. “Was Weber Wrong?
A Human Capital Theory of Protestant Economic History.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(2): 531–96.
51.
Beckert, Sven. 2014. Empire of Cotton: A Global History. New York:
Vintage Books.
52.
Belloc, Marianna, Francesco Drago, Mattia Fochesato, and Roberto
Galbiati. 2021. “Wealth Accumulation and Institutional Capture: The
Rise of the Medici and the Fall of the Florentine Republic.”
Unpublished manuscript.
53.
Benedictow, Ole J. 2005. The Black Death 1346–1353: The Complete
History. Woodbridge: The Boydell Press.
54.
Berg, Maxine. 1980. The Machinery Question and the Making of
Political Economy, 1815–1848. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
55.
Berg, Maxine. 2004. “Consumption in Eighteenth- and Early
Nineteenth-century Britain.” In Cambridge Economic History of
Modern Britain, Vol. 1, Industrialisation, 1700–1860, ed. Roderick
Floud and Paul Johnson. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
pp. 357–87.
56.
Berkowitz, Daniel, Katharina Pistor, and Jean-François Richard. 2003.
“Economic Development, Legality, and the Transplant Effect.”
European Economic Review 47(1): 165–95.
57.
Berman, Harold J. 1983. Law and Revolution: The Formation of the
Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
58.
Berman, Harold J. 2003. Law and Revolution, II: The Impact of the
Protestant Reformations on the Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
59.
Bernhofen, Daniel M. and John C. Brown. 2005. “An Empirical
Assessment of the Comparative Advantage Gains from Trade:
Evidence from Japan.” American Economic Review 95(1): 208–25.
60.
Bernhofen, Daniel M., Jianan Li, Markus Eberhardt, and Stephen L.
Morgan. 2020. “The Secular Decline of Market Integration during
Qing China’s Golden Age.” Working Paper.
61.
Besley, Timothy and Maitreesh Ghatak. 2010. “Property Rights and
Economic Development.” In Handbook of Development Economics,
Vol. 5, ed. Dani Rodrik and Mark Rosenzweig. Amsterdam: Elsevier,
pp. 4525–95.
62.
Bisin, Alberto and Thierry Verdier. 2017. “On the Joint Evolution of
Culture and Institutions.” NBER Working Paper 23375.
63.
Blaydes, Lisa and Eric Chaney. 2013. “The Feudal Revolution and
Europe’s Rise: Political Divergence of the Christian West and the
Muslim World before 1500 CE.” American Political Science Review
107(1): 16–34.
64.
Blaydes, Lisa and Christopher Paik. 2021. “Muslim Trade and City
Growth before the Nineteenth Century: Comparative Urbanization in
Europe, the Middle East and Central Asia.” British Journal of
Political Science 51(2): 845–68.
65.
Boettke, Peter. 1993. Why Perestroika Failed: The Politics and
Economics of Socialist Transformation. London: Routledge.
66.
Boettke, Peter. 2001. Calculation and Coordination. London:
Routledge.
67.
Bogart, Dan. 2012. “A Small Price to Pay: A Historical Perspective on
Infrastructure Regulation during Britain’s Industrialization.” Mimeo.
68.
Bogart, Dan. 2014. “The Transport Revolution in Industrialising
Britain.” In The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain
(new edn.), Vol. 1, 1700–1870, ed. Roderick Floud, Jane Humphries,
and Paul Johnson. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 368–
91.
69.
Bogart, Dan, Eduard J. Alvarez-Palau, Oliver Dunn, Max Satchell, and
Leigh Shaw Taylor. 2017. “Market Access and Urban Growth in
England and Wales during the Pre-steam Era.” Working Paper.
70.
Bogart, Dan and Gary Richardson. 2009. “Making Property Productive:
Reorganizing Rights to Real and Equitable Estates in Britain, 1660–
1830.” European Review of Economic History 13(1): 3–30.
71.
Bogart, Dan and Gary Richardson. 2011. “Property Rights and
Parliament in Industrializing Britain.” Journal of Law and
Economics 54(2): 241–74.
72.
Bogart, Dan, Max Satchell, Eduard J. Alvarez-Palau, Xuesheng You,
and Leigh Shaw Taylor. 2017. “Turnpikes, Canals, and Economic
Growth in England and Wales, 1800–1850.” Working Paper.
73.
Bolt, Jutta, Robert Inklaar, Herman de Jong, and Jan Luiten van
Zanden. 2018. “Rebasing ‘Maddison’: New Income Comparisons
and the Shape of Long-run Economic Development.” GGDC
Research Memorandum no. 174.
74.
Bolt, Jutta and Jan Luiten van Zanden. 2020. “Maddison Project
Database, version 2020.” Maddison Style Estimates of the Evolution
of the World Economy: A New 2020 Update.
75.
Boserup, Ester. 1970. Woman’s Role in Economic Development.
London: George Allen and Unwin Ltd.
76.
Bosker, Maarten, Eltjo Buringh, and Jan Luiten van Zanden. 2013.
“From Baghdad to London: Unraveling Urban Development in
Europe, the Middle East, and North Africa, 800–1800.” Review of
Economics and Statistics 95(4): 1418–37.
77.
Botticini, Maristella and Zvi Eckstein. 2012. The Chosen Few: How
Education Shaped Jewish History, 70–1492. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
78.
Boyd, Robert and Peter J. Richerson. 1985. Culture and the
Evolutionary Process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
79.
Brandt, Loren, Debin Ma, and Thomas G. Rawski. 2014. “From
Divergence to Convergence: Reevaluating the History behind
China’s Economic Boom.” Journal of Economic Literature 52(1):
45–123.
80.
Brandt, Loren, Debin Ma, and Thomas G. Rawski. 2017.
“Industrialization in China.” In The Spread of Modern Industry to the
Periphery since 1871, ed. Kevin O’Rourke and Jeffrey Williamson.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 197–228.
81.
Braudel, Fernand. 1949/1973. The Mediterranean, and the
Mediterranean World in the Age of Phillip II, Vol. 2. Translated by
Siân Reynolds. Berkeley: University of California Press.
82.
Brenner, Robert. 1976. “Agrarian Class Structure and Economic
Development in Pre-industrial Europe.” Past & Present 70(1): 30–
75.
83.
Brewer, John. 1988. The Sinews of Power. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
84.
Brewer, John and Roy Porter, eds. 1993. Consumption and the World of
Goods. London: Routledge.
85.
Broadberry, Stephen. 1994. “Comparative Productivity in British and
American Manufacturing during the Nineteenth Century.”
Explorations in Economic History 31(4): 521–48.
86.
Broadberry, Stephen. 1998. “How Did the United States and Germany
Overtake Britain? A Sectoral Analysis of Comparative Productivity
Levels, 1870–1990.” Journal of Economic History 58(2): 375–407.
87.
Broadberry, Stephen, Bruce M.S. Campbell, Alexander Klein, Mark
Overton, and Bas van Leeuwen. 2015. British Economic Growth,
1270–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
88.
Broadberry, Stephen, Johann Custodis, and Bishnupriya Gupta. 2015.
“India and the Great Divergence: An Anglo-Indian Comparison of
GDP per Capita, 1600–1871.” Explorations in Economic History
55(1): 58–75.
89.
Broadberry, Stephen, Hanhui Guan, and David Daokui Li. 2018.
“China, Europe, and the Great Divergence: A Study in Historical
National Accounting, 980–1850.” Journal of Economic History
78(4): 955–1000.
90.
Broadberry, Stephen and Bishnupriya Gupta. 2006. “The Early Modern
Great Divergence: Wages, Prices and Economic Development in
Europe and Asia, 1500–1800.” Economic History Review 59(1): 2–
31.
91.
Broadberry, Stephen and John Joseph Wallis. 2017. “Growing,
Shrinking, and Long-run Economic Performance: Historical
Perspectives on Economic Development.” NBER Working Paper
23343.
92.
Bruhn, Miriam and Francisco A. Gallego. 2012. “Good, Bad, and Ugly
Colonial Activities: Do They Matter for Economic Development?”
Review of Economics and Statistics 94(2): 433–61.
93.
Buringh, Eltjo and Jan Luiten van Zanden. 2009. “Charting the ‘Rise of
the West’: Manuscripts and Printed Books in Europe, a Long-Term
Perspective from the Sixth through Eighteenth Centuries.” Journal of
Economic History 69(2): 409–45.
94.
Caferro, William P. 2008. “Warfare and Economy in Renaissance Italy,
1350–1450.” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 39(2): 167–209.
95.
Cagé, Julia and Valeria Rueda. 2016. “The Long-term Effects of the
Printing Press in sub-Saharan Africa.” American Economic Journal:
Applied Economics 8(3): 69–99.
96.
Cameron, Rondo E. 1993. A Concise Economic History of the World:
From Paleolithic Times to the Present. New York: Oxford University
Press.
97.
Campbell, Bruce M.S. 2010. “Nature as Historical Protagonist.”
Economic History Review 63(2): 281–314.
98.
Campbell, Cameron D., Wang Feng, and James Z. Lee. 2002.
“Pretransitional Fertility in China.” Population and Development
Review 28(4): 735–50.
99.
Cantoni, Davide, Jeremiah Dittmar, and Noam Yuchtman. 2018.
“Religious Competition and Reallocation: The Political Economy of
Secularization in the Protestant Reformation.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 133(4): 2037–96.
100.
Carmichael, Sarah G., Alexandra de Pleijt, Jan Luiten van Zanden, and
Tine de Moor. 2016. “The European Marriage Pattern and Its
Measurement.” Journal of Economic History 76(1): 196–204.
101.
Castañeda Dower, Paul and Andrei Markevich. 2018. “The Stolypin
Reform and Agricultural Productivity in Late Imperial Russia.”
European Review of Economic History 23(3): 241–67.
102.
Cavalli-Sforza, Luigi L. and Marcus W. Feldman. 1981. Cultural
Transmission and Evolution: A Quantitative Approach. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
103.
Centeno, Miguel Angel. 1997. “Blood and Debt: War and Taxation in
Nineteenth-century Latin America.” American Journal of Sociology
102(6): 1565–605.
104.
Cervellati, Matteo and Uwe Sunde. 2005. “Human Capital Formation,
Life Expectancy, and the Process of Development.” American
Economic Review 95(5): 1653–72.
105.
Chaney, Eric. 2008. “Tolerance, Religious Competition and the Rise
and Fall of Muslim Science.” Unpublished paper.
106.
Chaney, Eric. 2016. “Religion and the Rise and Fall of Islamic
Science.” Unpublished paper.
107.
Chang, Ha-Joon. 2008. Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and
the Secret History of Capitalism. London: Bloomsbury Press.
108.
Chaudhary, Latika and James Fenske. 2020. “Did Railways Affect
Literacy? Evidence from India.” CAGE Online Working Paper Series
529.
109.
Chen, Ting, James Kai-sing Kung, and Chicheng Ma. 2020. “Long Live
Keju! The Persistent Effects of China’s Civil Examination System.”
Economic Journal 130(631): 2065–104.
110.
Chen, Zhiwu, Chicheng Ma, and Andrew J. Sinclair. Forthcoming.
“Banking on the Confucian Clan: Why Did China Miss the Financial
Revolution?” Economic Journal. https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/ueab082.
111.
Christian, Cornelius and Liam Elbourne. 2018. “Shocks to Military
Support and Subsequent Assassinations in Ancient Rome.”
Economics Letters 171: 79–82.
112.
CIA. 2019. “CIA World Fact Book.” Data available at:
https://www.cia.gov/the-world-factbook/.
113.
Cipolla, Carlo M. 1952. “The Decline of Italy: The Case of a Fully
Matured Economy.” Economic History Review 5(2): 178–87.
114.
Cipolla, Carol M. 1976. Before the Industrial Revolution. London:
Methuen.
115.
Clark, Gregory. 1994. “Factory Discipline.” Journal of Economic
History 54(1): 128–63.
116.
Clark, Gregory. 2007. A Farewell to Alms. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
117.
Clark, Gregory. 2010. “The Macroeconomic Aggregates for England,
1209–2008.” Research in Economic History 27(1): 51–140.
118.
Clark, Gregory and Neil Cummins. 2015. “Malthus to Modernity:
Wealth, Status, and Fertility in England, 1500–1879.” Journal of
Population Economics 28(1): 3–29.
119.
Clark, Gregory and David Jacks. 2007. “Coal and the Industrial
Revolution, 1700–1869.” European Review of Economic History
11(1): 39–72.
120.
Clark, Peter, ed. 2001. The Cambridge Urban History of Britain, Vol.
II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
121.
Clegg, John J. 2015. “Capitalism and Slavery.” Critical Historical
Studies 2(2): 281–304.
122.
Clingingsmith, David and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 2008.
“Deindustrialization in 18th- and 19th-century India: Mughal
Decline, Climate Shocks and British Industrial Ascent.” Explorations
in Economic History 45(3): 209–234.
123.
Cohn, Samuel. 2007. “After the Black Death: Labour Legislation and
Attitudes towards Labour in Late-Medieval Western Europe.”
Economic History Review 60(3): 457–85.
124.
Cooter, Robert D. 1997. “The Rule of State Law and the Rule-of-law
State: Economic Analysis of the Legal Foundations of
Development.” Annual World Bank Conference on Development
Economics 1996: 191–217.
125.
Coşgel, Metin M., Thomas J. Miceli, and Jared Rubin. 2012. “The
Political Economy of Mass Printing: Legitimacy and Technological
Change in the Ottoman Empire.” Journal of Comparative Economics
40(3): 357–71.
126.
Cox, Gary W. 2016. Marketing Sovereign Promises: Monopoly
Brokerage and the Growth of the English State. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
127.
Crafts, Nicholas. 2011. “Explaining the First Industrial Revolution:
Two Views.” European Review of Economic History 15(1): 153–68.
128.
Crafts, Nicholas. 2018. Forging Ahead, Falling Behind and Fighting
Back: British Economic Growth from the Industrial Revolution to the
Financial Crisis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
129.
Crosby, Alfred W. 1986. Ecological Imperialism: The Biological
Expansion of Europe, 900–1900. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
130.
Dalgaard, Carl-Johan, Anne Sofie B. Knudsen, and Pablo Selaya. 2020.
“The Bounty of the Sea and Long-run Development.” Journal of
Economic Growth 25(3): 259–95.
131.
Darity, William, Jr. 1992. “A Model of ‘Original Sin’: Rise of the West
and Lag of the Rest.” American Economic Review 82(2): 162–7.
132.
David, A. Paul and Gavin Wright. 1997. “Increasing Returns and the
Genesis of American Resource Abundance.” Industrial and
Corporate Change 6(2): 203–45.
133.
Davis, Donald R. and David E. Weinstein. 2002. “Bones, Bombs, and
Break Points: The Geography of Economic Activity.” American
Economic Review 92(5): 1269–89.
134.
de la Croix, David, Matthias Doepke, and Joel Mokyr. 2017. “Clans,
Guilds, and Markets: Apprenticeship Institutions and Growth in the
Preindustrial Economy.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 133(1): 1–
70.
135.
de Moor, Tine and Jan Luiten van Zanden. 2010. “Girl Power: The
European Marriage Pattern and Labour Markets in the North Sea
Region in the Late Medieval and Early Modern Period.” Economic
History Review 63(1): 1–33.
136.
de Vries, Jan. 1993. “Between Purchasing Power and the World of
Goods: Understanding the Household Economy in Early Modern
Europe.” In Consumption and the World of Goods, ed. John Brewer
and Roy Porter. London: Routledge, pp. 85–132.
137.
de Vries, Jan. 2003. “The Industrious Revolution and Economic
Growth, 1650–1830.” In The Economic Future in a Historical
Perspective, ed. Paul A. David and Michael Thomas. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, pp. 43–72.
138.
de Vries, Jan. 2008. The Industrious Revolution. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
139.
de Vries, Jan and Ad van der Woude. 1997. The First Modern
Economy: Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch
Economy, 1500–1815. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
140.
Dell, Melissa. 2010. “The Persistent Effects of Peru’s Mining Mita.”
Econometrica 78(6): 1863–903.
141.
Dell, Melissa and Benjamin A. Olken. 2020. “The Development Effects
of the Extractive Colonial Economy: The Dutch Cultivation System
in Java.” Review of Economic Studies 87(1): 164–203.
142.
Dennison, Tracy and Sheilagh Ogilvie. 2014. “Does the European
Marriage Pattern Explain Economic Growth?” Journal of Economic
History 74(3): 651–93.
143.
Derenoncourt, Ellora. 2019. “Atlantic Slavery’s Impact on European
and British Economic Development.” Working Paper.
144.
Desierto, Desiree A. 2018. “Formal Models of the Political Resource
Curse.” Economics of Governance 19(3): 225–59.
145.
Desierto, Desiree A. and Mark Koyama. 2020. “The Political Economy
of Status Competition: Sumptuary Laws in Preindustrial Europe.”
CEPR Discussion Papers 14407.
146.
Desmet, Klaus and Stephen L. Parente. 2012. “The Evolution of
Markets and the Revolution of Industry: A Unified Theory of
Growth.” Journal of Economic Growth 17(3): 205–34.
147.
Diamond, Jared. 1997. Guns, Germs, and Steel. New York: W.W.
Norton & Company.
148.
Dicey, A.V. 1908. Introduction to the Study of the Law of the
Constitution. London: Macmillan and Co. Ltd.
149.
Dincecco, Mark. 2009. “Fiscal Centralization, Limited Government,
and Public Revenues in Europe, 1650–1913.” Journal of Economic
History 69(1): 48–103.
150.
Dincecco, Mark, James Fenske, Anil Menon, and Shivaji Mukherjee.
2019. “Pre-colonial Warfare and Long-run Development in India.”
University of Warwick Working Paper N. 426.
151.
Dippel, Christian. 2014. “Forced Coexistence and Economic
Development: Evidence from Native American Reservations.”
Econometrica 82(6): 2131–65.
152.
Dittmar, Jeremiah E. and Ralf R. Meisenzahl. 2020. “Public Goods
Institutions, Human Capital, and Growth: Evidence from German
History.” Review of Economic Studies 87(2): 959–96.
153.
Dixit, Avinash. 2004. Lawlessness and Economics. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
154.
Doepke, Matthias and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2008. “Occupational Choice
and the Spirit of Capitalism.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
123(2): 747–93.
155.
Donaldson, Dave. 2018. “Railroads of the Raj: Estimating the Impact of
Transportation Infrastructure.” American Economic Review 108(4–
5): 899–934.
156.
Donaldson, Dave and Richard Hornbeck. 2016. “Railroads and
American Economic Growth: A ‘Market Access’ Approach.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 131(2): 799–858.
157.
Drelichman, Mauricio. 2005. “All That Glitters: Precious Metals, Rent
Seeking and the Decline of Spain.” European Review of Economic
History 9(3): 313–36.
158.
Drelichman, Mauricio and Hans-Joachim Voth. 2008. “Institutions and
the Resource Curse in Early Modern Spain.” In Institutions and
Economic Performance, ed. Ethan Helpman. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press, pp. 120–47.
159.
Drelichman, Mauricio and Hans-Joachim Voth. 2011. “Lending to the
Borrower from Hell: Debt and Default in the Age of Philip II.”
Economic Journal 121(557): 1205–27.
160.
Drelichman, Mauricio and Hans-Joachim Voth. 2016. Lending to the
Borrower from Hell: Debt, Taxes, and Default in the Age of Philip II.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
161.
Dyer, Christopher. 2005. An Age of Transition? Economy and Society in
England in the Later Middle Ages. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
162.
Easterly, William and Ross Levine. 1997. “Africa’s Growth Tragedy:
Policies and Ethnic Divisions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
112(4): 1203–50.
163.
Edelstein, Dan, Maria Comsa, Melanie Conroy, Biliana Kassabova,
Claude Willan, Chloe Edmundson, and Bugei Nyaosi. 2010.
“Voltaire and the Enlightenment.” Mapping the Republic of Letters,
Stanford University.
http://republicofletters.stanford.edu/casestudies/voltaire.html.
164.
Eichengreen, Barry. 2007. The European Economy since 1945:
Coordinated Capitalism and Beyond. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
165.
Ekelund, Robert B., Robert Hébert, Robert Tollison, Gary Anderson,
and Audrey Davidson. 1996. Sacred Trust: The Medieval Church as
an Economic Firm. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
166.
Ekelund, Robert B. and Robert D. Tollison. 1997. Politicized
Economies. College Station, TX: Texas A & M University Press.
167.
Eltis, David and Stanley L. Engerman. 2000. “The Importance of
Slavery and the Slave Trade to Industrializing Britain.” Journal of
Economic History 60(1): 123–44.
168.
Emson, H.E. 1992. “For the Want of an Heir: The Obstetrical History of
Queen Anne.” BMJ: British Medical Journal 304(6838): 1365–6.
169.
Engerman, Stanley L. and Kenneth L. Sokoloff. 2012. Economic
Development in the Americas since 1500. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
170.
Enke, Benjamin. 2019. “Kinship, Cooperation, and the Evolution of
Moral Systems.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 134(2): 953–1019.
171.
Epstein, S.R. 1991. “Cities, Regions and the Late Medieval Crisis:
Sicily and Tuscany Compared.” Past & Present 130: 3–50.
172.
Epstein, S.R. 1998. “Craft Guilds, Apprenticeship, and Technological
Change in Preindustrial Europe.” Journal of Economic History 58(3):
684–713.
173.
Epstein, S.R. 2000. Freedom and Growth: The Rise of States and
Markets in Europe, 1300–1700. London: Routledge.
174.
Federico, Giovanni, Max-Stephan Schulze, and Oliver Volckart. 2021.
“European Goods Market Integration in the Very Long Run: From
the Black Death to the First World War.” Journal of Economic
History 81(1): 276–308.
175.
Feinstein, Charles H. 1998. “Pessimism Perpetuated: Real Wages and
the Standard of Living in Britain during and after the Industrial
Revolution.” Journal of Economic History 58(3): 625–58.
176.
Fernández, Raquel and Alessandra Fogli. 2009. “Culture: An Empirical
Investigation of Beliefs, Work, and Fertility.” American Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics 1(1): 146–77.
177.
Fernández-Armesto, Felipe. 2006. Pathfinders: A Global History of
Exploration. New York: Norton.
178.
Fernández-Villaverde, Jesús. 2022. Global Economic History: Change
and Continuity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
179.
Fernández-Villaverde, Jesús, Mark Koyama, Youhong Lin, and Tuan-
Hwee Sng. 2020. “Fractured-land and Political Fragmentation.”
Working Paper.
180.
Feyrer, James and Bruce Sacerdote. 2009. “Colonialism and Modern
Income: Islands as Natural Experiments.” Review of Economics and
Statistics 91(2): 245–62.
181.
Finley, Moses I. 1973. The Ancient Economy. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
182.
Floud, Roderick, Robert W. Fogel, Bernard Harris, and Sok Chul Hong.
2011. The Changing Body: Health, Nutrition, and Human
Development in the Western World since 1700. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
183.
Flückiger, Matthias, Erik Hornung, Mario Larch, Markus Ludwig, and
Allard Mees. Forthcoming. “Roman Transport Network Connectivity
and Economic Integration.” Review of Economic Studies.
https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdab036.
184.
Fogel, Robert W. 1964. Railroads and American Economic Growth.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
185.
Fogel, Robert W. 2004. The Escape from Hunger and Premature Death,
1700–2000. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
186.
Foreman-Peck, James. 2011. “The Western European Marriage Pattern
and Economic Development.” Explorations in Economic History
48(2): 292–309.
187.
Fouquet, Roger and Stephen Broadberry. 2015. “Seven Centuries of
European Economic Growth and Decline.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 29(4): 227–44.
188.
Frankema, Ewout H.P. 2012. “The Origins of Formal Education in sub-
Saharan Africa: Was British Rule More Benign?” European Review
of Economic History 16(4): 335–55.
189.
Frankema, Ewout H.P. and Marlous van Waijenburg. 2012. “Structural
Impediments to African Growth? New Evidence from Real Wages in
British Africa, 1880–1965.” Journal of Economic History 72(4):
895–926.
190.
Friedman, Benjamin M. 2005. The Moral Consequences of Economic
Growth. New York: Vintage Books.
191.
Fukuyama, Francis. 2011. The Origins of Political Order. London:
Profile Books Ltd. Fukuyama, Francis. 2014. Political Order and
Political Decay. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
192.
Fuller, Lon L. 1969. The Morality of Law. New Haven, CT: Yale
University Press.
193.
Galor, Oded. 2005. “From Stagnation to Growth: Unified Growth
Theory.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1, ed. Philippe
Aghion and Steven Durlauf. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 171–293.
194.
Galor, Oded. 2011. Unified Growth Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
195.
Galor, Oded and Omer Moav. 2006. “Das Human-Kapital: A Theory of
the Demise of the Class Structure.” Review of Economic Studies
73(1): 85–117.
196.
Galor, Oded, Omer Moav, and Dietrich Vollrath. 2009. “Inequality in
Landownership, the Emergence of Human-Capital Promoting
Institutions, and the Great Divergence.” Review of Economic Studies
76(1): 143–79.
197.
Galor, Oded and Andrew Mountford. 2008. “Trading Population for
Productivity: Theory and Evidence.” Review of Economic Studies
75(4): 1143–79.
198.
Galor, Oded and David N. Weil. 2000. “Population, Technology, and
Growth: From Malthusian Stagnation to the Demographic Transition
and Beyond.” American Economic Review 90(4): 806–28.
199.
Gennaioli, Nicola and Hans-Joachim Voth. 2015. “State Capacity and
Military Conflict.” Review of Economic Studies 82(4): 1409–48.
200.
Gerschenkron, Alexander. 1962. Economic Backwardness in Historical
Perspective. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press.
201.
Glahn, Richard von. 2016. The Economic History of China. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
202.
Goldin, Claudia. 2001. “The Human-Capital Century and American
Leadership: Virtues of the Past.” Journal of Economic History 61(2):
263–92.
203.
Goldin, Claudia and Lawrence F. Katz. 1998. “The Origins of
Technology–Skill Complementarity.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 113(3): 693–732.
204.
Goldin, Claudia and Laurence F. Katz. 2008. The Race between
Education and Technology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
205.
Goldstone, Jack A. 2002. “Efflorescences and Economic Growth in
World History: Rethinking the ‘Rise of the West’ and the Industrial
Revolution.” Journal of World History 13(2): 323–89.
206.
Gorodnichenko, Yuriy and Gerard Roland. 2011. “Individualism,
Innovation, and Long-run
207.
Growth.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
108(Supplement 4): 21316–19.
208.
Gorodnichenko, Yuriy and Gerard Roland. 2017. “Culture, Institutions,
and the Wealth of Nations.” Review of Economics and Statistics
99(3): 402–16.
209.
Gottfried, Robert S. 1983. The Black Death: Natural and Human
Disaster in Medieval Europe. New York: The Free Press.
210.
Grafe, Regina. 2012. Distant Tyranny: Markets, Power, and
Backwardness in Spain, 1650–1800. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
211.
Gregory, Paul R. 1994. Before Command: The Russian Economy from
Emancipation to Stalin. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
212.
Gregory, Paul R. 2004a. The Political Economy of Stalinism.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
213.
Gregory, Paul R. 2004b. Russian National Income, 1885–1913.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
214.
Gregory, Paul R. and Mark Harrison. 2005. “Allocation under
Dictatorship: Research in Stalin’s Archives.” Journal of Economic
Literature 43(3): 721–61.
215.
Greif, Avner. 1989. “Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade:
Evidence on the Maghribi Traders.” Journal of Economic History
49(4): 857–82.
216.
Greif, Avner. 1993. “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions
in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders’ Coalition.” American
Economic Review 83(3): 525–48.
217.
Greif, Avner. 1994. “Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society:
A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and
Individualist Societies.” Journal of Political Economy 102(5): 912–
50.
218.
Greif, Avner. 2000. “The Fundamental Problem of Exchange: A
Research Agenda in Historical Institutional Analysis.” European
Review of Economic History 4(3): 251–84.
219.
Greif, Avner. 2002. “Institutions and Impersonal Exchange: From
Communal to Individual Responsibility.” Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics 127(1): 168–204.
220.
Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy:
Lessons from Medieval Trade. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
221.
Greif, Avner, Paul Milgrom, and Barry R. Weingast. 1994.
“Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the
Merchant Guild.” Journal of Political Economy 102(4): 745–76.
222.
Greif, Avner and Jared Rubin. 2021. “Political Legitimacy and the
Institutional Foundations of Constitutional Government: The Case of
England.” Working Paper.
223.
Greif, Avner and Guido Tabellini. 2017. “The Clan and the
Corporation: Sustaining Cooperation in China and Europe.” Journal
of Comparative Economics 45(1): 1–35.
224.
Grier, Robin M. 1999. “Colonial Legacies and Economic Growth.”
Public Choice 98(3–4): 317–35.
225.
Guinnane, Timothy W. 2011. “The Historical Fertility Transition: A
Guide for Economists.” Journal of Economic Literature 49(3): 589–
614.
226.
Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2006. “Does Culture
Affect Economic Outcomes?” Journal of Economic Perspectives
20(2): 23–48.
227.
Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2016. “Long-term
Persistence.” Journal of the European Economic Association 14(6):
1401–36.
228.
Gupta, Bishnupriya. 2019. “Falling Behind and Catching Up: India’s
Transition from a Colonial Economy.” Economic History Review
72(3): 803–27.
229.
Gwartney, James D., Robert A. Lawson, Joshua Hall, and Ryan
Murphy. 2019. Economic Freedom of the World: 2019 Annual
Report. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.
230.
Gwartney, James D., Robert A. Lawson, and Randall G. Holcombe.
1999. “Economic Freedom and the Environment for Economic
Growth.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 155(4):
643–63.
231.
Haggard, Stephan. 2004. “Institutions and Growth in East Asia.”
Studies in Comparative International Development 38(4): 53–81.
232.
Hajnal, John. 1965. “European Marriage Patterns in Perspective.” In
Population in History: Essays in Historical Demography, ed. D.V.
Glass and D.E.C. Eversley. London: Aldine, pp. 101–43.
233.
Hajnal, John. 1982. “Two Kinds of Preindustrial Household Formation
System.” Population and Development Review 8(3): 449–94.
234.
Hanley, Susan B. and Kozo Yamamura. 1977. Economic and
Demographic Change in Preindustrial Japan, 1600–1868. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
235.
Harley, C. Knick. 1992a. “The Antebellum American Tariff: Food
Exports and Manufacturing.” Explorations in Economic History
29(4): 375–400.
236.
Harley, C. Knick. 1992b. “International Competitiveness of the
Antebellum American Cotton Textile Industry.” Journal of Economic
History 52(3): 559–84.
237.
Harley, C. Knick. 2004. “Trade: Discovery, Mercantilism and
Technology.” In The Cambridge Economic History of Modern
Britain, Vol. 2, ed. Roderick Floud and Paul Johnson. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, pp. 175–203.
238.
Harper, Kyle. 2017. The Fate of Rome. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
239.
Hart, Marjolen’T. 1991. “‘The Devil of the Dutch’: Holland’s Impact
on the Financial Revolution in England, 1643–1694.” Parliaments,
Estates, and Representation 11(1): 39–51.
240.
Hausfather, Zeke. 2019. “Analysis: Why the UK’s CO2 Emissions have
Fallen 38% since 1990.” CarbonBrief.
https://www.carbonbrief.org/analysis-why-the-uks-co2-emissions-
have-fallen-38-since-1990.
241.
Hausmann, Ricardo, Lant Pritchett, and Dani Rodrik. 2005. “Growth
Accelerations.” Journal of Economic Growth 10(4): 303–29.
242.
Hay, Douglas, Peter Linebaugh, John G. Rule, E.P. Thompson, and Cal
Winslow, eds. 1975. Albion’s Fatal Tree. London: Allen Lane.
243.
Hay, Simon I., Carlos A. Guerra, Peter W. Gething, Anand P. Patil,
Andrew J. Tatem, Abdisalan M. Noor, et al. 2009. “A World Malaria
Map: Plasmodium falciparum Endemicity in 2007.” PLoS Medicine
6(3): e1000048.
244.
Hayek, F.A. 1960. The Constitution of Liberty. London: Routledge.
245.
Hayek, F.A. 1982. Law, Legislation and Liberty: The Political Order of
a Free People, Vol. III. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
246.
Heldring, Leander, James A. Robinson, and Sebastian Vollmer. 2021.
“The Economic Effects of the English Parliamentary Enclosures.”
Working Paper.
247.
Henrich, Joseph. 2004. “Demography and Cultural Evolution: How
Adaptive Cultural Processes Can Produce Maladaptive Losses: The
Tasmanian Case.” American Antiquity 69(2): 197–214.
248.
Henrich, Joseph. 2015. The Secret of Our Success: How Culture Is
Driving Human Evolution, Domesticating our Species, and Making
Us Smarter. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
249.
Henrich, Joseph. 2020. The WEIRDest People in the World: How the
West Became Psychologically Peculiar and Particularly Prosperous.
New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
250.
Henriques, Antonio and Nuno Palma. 2020. “Comparative European
Institutions and the Little Divergence, 1385–1800.” CEPR
Discussion Paper 14124.
251.
Herbst, Jeffrey. 2000. States and Power in Africa: Comparative Lessons
in Authority and Control. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
252.
Hobsbawm, Eric J. 1968. Industry and Empire. London: Weidenfeld &
Nicolson.
253.
Hoffman, Philip T. 2015. Why Did Europe Conquer the World?
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
254.
Hornbeck, Richard and Martin Rotemberg. 2021. “Railroads, Market
Access, and Aggregate Productivity Growth.” Working Paper.
255.
Howes, Anton. 2017. “The Relevance of Skills to Innovation during the
British Industrial Revolution, 1547–1851.” Working Paper.
256.
Huff, Toby. 1993. The Rise of Early Modern Science. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
257.
Huillery, Elise. 2009. “History Matters: The Long-term Impact of
Colonial Public Investments in French West Africa.” American
Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1(2): 176–215.
258.
Hume, David. 1762. The History of England. Dublin: United Company
of Booksellers.
259.
Humphries, Jane. 2010. Childhood and Child Labour in the British
Industrial Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
260.
Humphries, Jane and Benjamin Schneider. 2019. “Spinning the
Industrial Revolution.” Economic History Review 72(1): 126–55.
261.
Humphries, Jane and Jacob Weisdorf. 2019. “Unreal Wages? Real
Income and Economic Growth in England, 1260–1850.” Economic
Journal 129(623): 2867–87.
262.
Hunter, Janet. 2003. Women and the Labour Market in Japan’s
Industrializing Economy: The Textile Industry before the Pacific War.
London: Routledge.
263.
Inglehart, R., C. Haerpfer, A. Moreno, C. Welzel, K. Kizilova, J. Diez-
Medrano, et al. 2018. World Values Survey: All Rounds – Country-
Pooled Datafile Version. Madrid: JD Systems Institute. Data
available at:
http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/WVSDocumentationWVL.jsp.
264.
Inikori, Joseph E. 2002. Africans and the Industrial Revolution in
England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
265.
Irwin, Douglas A. 2000. “Did Late-nineteenth-century US Tariffs
Promote Infant Industries? Evidence from the Tinplate Industry.”
Journal of Economic History 60(2): 335–60.
266.
Irwin, Douglas A. 2002. “Interpreting the Tariff–Growth Correlation of
the Late 19th Century.” American Economic Review 92(2): 165–9.
267.
Iyer, Lakshmi. 2010. “Direct versus Indirect Colonial Rule in India:
Long-term Consequences.” Review of Economics and Statistics
92(4): 693–713.
268.
Iyigun, Murat, Nathan Nunn, and Nancy Qian. 2017. “Winter Is
Coming: The Long-run Effects of Climate Change on Conflict,
1400–1900.” NBER Working Paper 23033.
269.
Iyigun, Murat, Jared Rubin, and Avner Seror. 2021. “A Theory of
Cultural Revivals.” European Economic Review 135: art. 103734.
270.
Jacks, David S., Christopher M. Meissner, and Dennis Novy. 2011.
“Trade Booms, Trade Busts, and Trade Costs.” Journal of
International Economics 83(2): 185–201.
271.
Jedwab, Rémi, Noel D. Johnson, and Mark Koyama. 2019. “Pandemics,
Places, and Populations: Evidence from the Black Death.” CEPR
Discussion Paper.
272.
Jedwab, Rémi and Alexander Moradi. 2016. “The Permanent Effects of
Transportation Revolutions in Poor Countries: Evidence from
Africa.” Review of Economics and Statistics 98(2): 268–84.
273.
Jha, Saumitra. 2015. “Financial Asset Holdings and Political Attitudes:
Evidence from Revolutionary England.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 130(3): 1485–545.
274.
Johnson, Noel D. and Mark Koyama. 2017. “States and Economic
Growth: Capacity and Constraints.” Explorations in Economic
History 64(1): 1–20.
275.
Johnson, Noel D. and Mark Koyama. 2019. Persecution and
Toleration: The Long Road to Religious Freedom. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
276.
Jones, Eric. 2003. The European Miracle (3rd edn). Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
277.
Kamen, Henry. 1971. The Iron Century: Social Change in Europe
1550–1660. London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson.
278.
Kandori, Michihiro. 1992. “Social Norms and Community
Enforcement.” Review of Economic Studies 59(1): 63–80.
279.
Kanzaka, Junichi. 2019. “The Development of Civil Engineering
Projects and Village Communities in Seventeenth- to Nineteenth-
Century Japan.” In Public Goods Provision in the Early Modern
Economy: Comparative Perspectives from Japan, China, and
Europe, ed. Masayuki Tanimoto and R. Bin Wong. Berkeley:
University of California Press, pp. 150–71.
280.
Karaman, Kivanc and Şevket Pamuk. 2013. “Different Paths to the
Modern State in Europe: The Interaction between Warfare, Economic
Structure and Political Regime.” American Political Science Review
107(3): 603–26.
281.
Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi. 2011. “The
Worldwide Governance Indicators: Methodology and Analytical
Issues.” Hague Journal on the Rule of Law 3(2): 220–46.
282.
Kelly, Morgan, Joel Mokyr, and Cormac Ó Gráda. 2014. “Precocious
Albion: A New Interpretation of the British Industrial Revolution.”
Annual Review of Economics 6(1): 363–89.
283.
Kelly, Morgan, Joel Mokyr, and Cormac Ó Gráda. 2020. “The
Mechanics of the Industrial Revolution.” Working Paper.
284.
Kelly, Morgan and Cormac Ó Gráda. 2014. “Ready for Revolution?
The English Economy before 1800.” Working Paper.
285.
Kelly, Morgan and Cormac Ó Gráda. 2016. “Adam Smith, Watch
Prices, and the Industrial Revolution.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 131(4): 1727–52.
286.
Kennedy, Paul. 1987. The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers, 1500–
1980. New York: Vintatge Books.
287.
Kitamura, Shuhei and Nils-Petter Lagerlöf. 2020. “Geography and State
Fragmentation.” Journal of the European Economic Association
18(4): 1726–69.
288.
Ko, Chiu Yu, Mark Koyama, and Tuan-Hwee Sng. 2018. “Unified
China; Divided Europe.” International Economic Review 59(1): 285–
327.
289.
Ko, Chiu Yu and Tuan-Hwee Sng. 2013. “Regional Dependence and
Political Centralization in Imperial China.” Eurasian Geography and
Economics 54(5–6): 470–83.
290.
Kohli, Atul. 2004. State-directed Development: Political Power and
Industrialization in the Global Periphery. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
291.
Koyama, Mark. 2010a. “Evading the ‘Taint of Usury’: The Usury
Prohibition as a Barrier to Entry.” Explorations in Economic History
47(4): 420–42.
292.
Koyama, Mark. 2010b. “The Political Economy of Expulsion: The
Regulation of Jewish Moneylending in Medieval England.”
Constitutional Political Economy 21(4): 374–406.
293.
Koyama, Mark. 2012. “The Transformation of Labor Supply in the Pre-
industrial World.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
81(2): 505–23.
294.
Koyama, Mark. 2016. “The Long Transition from a Natural State to a
Liberal Economic Order.” International Review of Law and
Economics 47(1): 29–39.
295.
Koyama, Mark, Chiaki Moriguchi, and Tuan-Hwee Sng. 2018.
“Geopolitics and Asia’s Little Divergence: State Building in China
and Japan after 1850.” Journal of Economic Behavior &
Organization 155: 178–204.
296.
Koyama, Noboru. 2004. Japanese Students at Cambridge University in
the Meiji Era, 1868–1912: Pioneers for the Modernization of Japan.
Translated by Ian Ruxton. Morrisville, NC: Lula Press.
297.
Kremer, Michael. 1993. “Population Growth and Technological
Change: One Million BC to 1990.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
108(3): 681–716.
298.
Kuran, Timur. 2011. The Long Divergence: How Islamic Law Held
Back the Middle East. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
299.
Kuran, Timur and Jared Rubin. 2018. “The Financial Power of the
Powerless: Socio-economic Status and Interest Rates under Partial
Rule of Law.” Economic Journal 128(609): 758–96.
300.
Kuru, Ahmet T. 2019. Islam, Authoritarianism, and Underdevelopment:
A Global and Historical Comparison. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
301.
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez de Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and
Robert W. Vishny. 1998. “Law and Finance.” Journal of Political
Economy 106(6): 1113–55.
302.
Lal, Deepak. 2005. The Hindu Equilibrium, India c. 1500 BC–2000
A.D. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
303.
Lamb, H.H. 1982. Climate, History, and the Modern World. London:
Methuen.
304.
Lamoreaux, Naomi R. 2011. “The Mystery of Property Rights: A US
Perspective.” Journal of Economic History 71(2): 275–306.
305.
Lampe, Markus and Paul Sharp. 2018. A Land of Milk and Butter.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
306.
Landes, David S. 1998. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some
Are So Rich and Some So Poor. New York: Norton.
307.
Landes, David S. 2006. “Why Europe and the West? Why Not China?”
Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(2): 3–22.
308.
Lange, Matthew K. 2004. “British Colonial Legacies and Political
Development.” World Development 32(6): 905–22.
309.
Lankina, Tomila and Lullit Getachew. 2012. “Mission or Empire, Word
or Sword? The Human Capital Legacy in Postcolonial Democratic
Development.” American Journal of Political Science 56(2): 465–83.
310.
Le Bris, David. 2019. “Testing Legal Origins Theory within France:
Customary Laws versus Roman Code.” Journal of Comparative
Economics 47(1): 1–30.
311.
Lee, James, Cameron Campbell, and Wang Feng. 2002. “Positive
Check or Chinese Checks?” Journal of Asian Studies 61(2): 591–
607.
312.
Lemire, Beverly. 1991. Fashion’s Favourite: The Cotton Trade and the
Consumer in Britain, 1660–1800. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
313.
Lewis, Bernard. 2002. What Went Wrong? Western Impact and Middle
Eastern Response. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
314.
Lin, Justin Yifu. 1995. “The Needham Puzzle: Why the Industrial
Revolution Did Not Originate in China.” Economic Development and
Cultural Change 43(2): 269–92.
315.
Lindert, Peter H. and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 2016. “American Colonial
Incomes, 1650–1774.” Economic History Review 69(1): 54–77.
316.
Lowes, Sara and Eduardo Montero. Forthcoming. “Concessions,
Violence, and Indirect Rule: Evidence from the Congo Free State.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjab021.
317.
Lowes, Sara, Nathan Nunn, James A. Robinson, and Jonathan L.
Weigel. 2017. “The Evolution of Culture and Institutions: Evidence
from the Kuba Kingdom.” Econometrica 85(4): 1065–91.
318.
Ma, Debin. 2004. “Why Japan, Not China, Was the First to Develop in
East Asia: Lessons from Sericulture, 1850–1937.” Economic
Development and Cultural Change 52(2): 369–94.
319.
Ma, Debin and Jared Rubin. 2019. “The Paradox of Power: Principal–
Agent Problems and Administrative Capacity in Imperial China (and
Other Absolutist Regimes).” Journal of Comparative Economics
47(2): 277–94.
320.
Macaulay, Thomas Babbington. 1830. “Sir Thomas More; or,
Colloquies on the Progress and Prospects of Society by Robert
Southey.” Edinburgh Review 50: 528–65.
321.
Maddison, Angus. 1983. “A Comparison of Levels of GDP per Capita
in Developed and Developing Countries: 1700–1914.” Journal of
Economic History 43(1): 27–41.
322.
Maddison, Angus. 1991. Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development: A
Long-run Comparative View. New York: Oxford University Press.
323.
Maddison, Angus. 2001. The World Economy: A Millennial
Perspective. OECD.
324.
Maddison, Angus. 2007. Contours of the World Economy, 1–2030 AD:
Essays in Macro-economic History. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
325.
Majewski, John. 2009. Modernizing a Slave Economy: The Economic
Vision of the Confederate Nation. Chapel Hill: University of North
Carolina Press.
326.
Malanima, Paolo. 2003. “Measuring the Italian Economy 1300–1861.”
Rivista di Storia Economica 21(1): 265–95.
327.
Malanima, Paolo. 2005. “Urbanisation and the Italian Economy during
the Last Millennium.” European Review of Economic History 9(1):
97–122.
328.
Malanima, Paolo. 2007. “Wages, Productivity and Working Time in
Italy (1270–1913).” Journal of European Economic History 36(1):
127–71.
329.
Malthus, T.R. 1798/2007. An Essay on the Principle of Population.
New York: Dover.
330.
Mann, Charles C. 2005. 1491: New Revelations of the Americas before
Columbus. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.
331.
Manning, Patrick. 1990. Slavery and African Life: Occidental, Oriental,
and African Slave Trades. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
332.
Manning, Sturt. 2013. “The Roman World and Climate: Context,
Relevance of Climate Change, and Some Issues.” In The Ancient
Mediterranean Environment between Science and History, ed. W.V.
Harris. Leiden: Brill, pp. 103–72.
333.
Markevich, Andrei, Natalya Naumenko, and Nancy Qian. 2021. “The
Soviet Great Famine, 1932–1933.” Working Paper.
334.
Markevich, Andrei and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya. 2018. “The Economic
Effects of the Abolition of Serfdom: Evidence from the Russian
Empire.” American Economic Review 108(4–5): 1074–117.
335.
Marshall, Monty G. and Gabrielle Elzinga-Marshall. 2017. Global
Report 2017: Conflict, Governance and State Fragility. Vienna, VA:
Center for Systemic Peace.
336.
Marx, Karl. 1868/1990. Capital, Vol. 1. Translated by Ben Fowkes.
London: Penguin Classics.
337.
McCleary, Rachel M. and Robert J. Barro. 2006. “Religion and
Economy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(2): 49–72.
338.
McCleary, Rachel M. and Robert J. Barro. 2019. The Wealth of
Religions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
339.
McCloskey, Deirdre N. 2006. The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age
of Commerce. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
340.
McCloskey, Deirdre N. 2010. Bourgeois Dignity: Why Economics Can’t
Explain the Modern World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
341.
McCloskey, Deirdre N. 2016. Bourgeois Equality: How Ideas, Not
Capital or Institutions, Enriched the World. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
342.
McCloskey, Donald N. 1976. “English Open Fields as Behavior
towards Risk.” In Research in Economic History: An Annual
Compilation of Research, Vol. 1, ed. Paul Uselding. Greenwich, CT:
JAI Press, pp. 124–70.
343.
McKendrick, Neil, John Brewer, and J.H. Plumb. 1982. The Birth of
Consumer Society: The Commercialization of Eighteenth-century
England. London: Europa.
344.
McLean, Ian W. 2013. Why Australia Prospered: The Shifting Sources
of Economic Growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
345.
Mehlum, Halvor, Karl Moene, and Ragnar Torvik. 2006. “Institutions
and the Resource Curse.” Economic Journal 116(508): 1–20.
346.
Meng, Xin, Nancy Qian, and Pierre Yared. 2015. “The Institutional
Causes of China’s Great Famine, 1959–1961.” Review of Economic
Studies 82(4): 1568–611.
347.
Michaels, Guy and Ferdinand Rauch. 2018. “Resetting the Urban
Network: 117–2012.” Economic Journal 128(608): 378–412.
348.
Michalopoulos, Stelios and Elias Papaioannou. 2016. “The Long-run
Effects of the Scramble for Africa.” American Economic Review
106(7): 1802–48.
349.
Minns, Chris and Patrick Wallis. 2012. “Rules and Reality: Quantifying
the Practice of Apprenticeship in Early Modern England.” Economic
History Review 65(2): 556–79.
350.
Mitch, David. 1999. “The Role of Skill and Human Capital in the
‘British’ Industrial Revolution.” In The British Industrial Revolution:
An Economic Perspective, ed. Joel Mokyr. Boulder, CO: Westview
Press, pp. 241–79.
351.
Mokyr, Joel. 1990. The Lever of Riches. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
352.
Mokyr, Joel. 1998. “The Second Industrial Revolution, 1870–1914.” In
Storia dell’economia Mondiale, ed. Valerio Castronono. Rome:
Laterza, pp. 219–45.
353.
Mokyr, Joel. 2002. The Gift of Athena: Historical Origins of the
Knowledge Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
354.
Mokyr, Joel. 2009. The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of
Britain, 1700–1850. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
355.
Mokyr, Joel. 2016. A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern
Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
356.
Mokyr, Joel and John V.C. Nye. 2007. “Distribution Coalitions, the
Industrial Revolution, and the Origins of Economic Growth in
Britain.” Southern Economic Journal 74(1): 50–70.
357.
Mokyr, Joel, Assaf Sarid, and Karine van der Beek. 2020. “The Wheels
of Change: Technology Adoption, Millwrights, and Persistence in
Britain’s Industrialization.” Working Paper. Montesquieu, Charles de.
1748/1989. The Spirit of the Laws. Translated by Anne M. Cohler,
Basia C. Miller, and Harold S. Stone. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
358.
More, Thomas. 1516/1997. Utopia. New York: Dover.
359.
Morris, Ian. 2005. “Archaeology, Standards of Living, and Greek
Economic History.” In The Ancient Economy, ed. Ian Morris and J.G.
Manning. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, pp. 91–126.
360.
Mui, Hoh-Cheung and Lorna H. Mui. 1989. Shops and Shopkeeping in
Eighteenth-century England. Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University
Press.
361.
Murtazashvili, Jennifer Brick. 2016. Informal Order and the State in
Afghanistan. New York: Cambridge University Press.
362.
Nath, Pratyay. 2018. “Through the Lens of War: Akbar’s Sieges (1567–
69) and Mughal Empire-building in Early Modern North India.”
South Asia: Journal of South Asian Studies 41(2): 245–58.
363.
Naumenko, Natalya. 2021. “The Political Economy of Famine: The
Ukrainian Famine of 1933.” Journal of Economic History 81(1):
156–97.
364.
Needham, Joseph. 1995. Science and Civilisation in China. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
365.
Nef, John U. 1932. The Rise of the English Coal Industry. Vols. 1–2.
London: Routledge.
366.
Nelson, Richard R. and Edmund S. Phelps. 1966. “Investment in
Humans, Technological Diffusion, and Economic Growth.”
American Economic Review 56(1/2): 69–75.
367.
North, Douglass C. 1966. The Economic Growth of the United States
1790–1860. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.
368.
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History.
New York: Norton.
369.
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and
Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
370.
North, Douglass C. and Robert Paul Thomas. 1973. The Rise of the
Western World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
371.
North, Douglass C., John Joseph Wallis, and Barry R. Weingast. 2009.
Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for
Interpreting Recorded Human History. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
372.
North, Douglass C. and Barry Weingast. 1989. “Constitutions and
Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice
in Seventeenth-Century England.” Journal of Economic History
49(4): 803–32.
373.
Nunn, Nathan. 2008. “The Long-term Effects of Africa’s Slave Trades.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 123(1): 139–76.
374.
Nunn, Nathan. 2012. “Culture and the Historical Process.” Economic
History of Developing Regions 27(Supplement 1): S108–26.
375.
Nunn, Nathan and Diego Puga. 2012. “Ruggedness: The Blessing of
Bad Geography in Africa.” Review of Economics and Statistics
94(1): 20–36.
376.
Nunn, Nathan and Nancy Qian. 2010. “The Columbian Exchange: A
History of Disease, Food, and Ideas.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 24(2): 163–88.
377.
Nunn, Nathan and Leonard Wantchekon. 2011. “The Slave Trade and
the Origins of Mistrust in Africa.” American Economic Review
101(7): 3221–52.
378.
Ó Gráda, Cormac. 2015. Eating People Is Wrong and Other Essays.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
379.
Ober, Josiah. 2018. Demopolis: Democracy before Liberalism.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
380.
O’Brien, Patrick. 2000. “Mercantilism and Imperialism in the Rise and
Decline of the Dutch and British Economies 1585–1815.” De
Economist 148(4): 469–501.
381.
Ogilvie, Sheilagh. 2003. A Bitter Living: Women, Markets, and Social
Capital in Early Modern Germany. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
382.
Ogilvie, Sheilagh. 2011. Institutions and European Trade: Merchant
Guilds, 1000–1800. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
383.
Ogilvie, Sheilagh. 2019. The European Guilds: An Economic Analysis.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
384.
O’Rourke, Kevin H. 2007a. “Culture, Conflict and Cooperation: Irish
Dairying before the Great War.” Economic Journal 117(523): 1357–
79.
385.
O’Rourke, Kevin H. 2007b. “Property Rights, Politics and Innovation:
Creamery Diffusion in Pre-1914 Ireland.” European Review of
Economic History 11(3): 395–417.
386.
O’Rourke, Kevin H. and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 1999. Globalization
and History: The Evolution of a Nineteenth-Century Economy.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
387.
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of
Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
388.
Oto-Peralías, Daniel and Diego Romero-Ávila. 2014. “The Distribution
of Legal Traditions around the World: A Contribution to the Legal-
origins Theory.” Journal of Law and Economics 57(3): 561–628.
389.
Palma, Nuno. Forthcoming. “The Real Effects of Monetary
Expansions: Evidence from a Large-scale Historical Experiment.”
Review of Economic Studies.
390.
Palma, Nuno and Jaime Reis. 2019. “From Convergence to Divergence:
Portuguese Economic Growth, 1527–1850.” Journal of Economic
History 79(2): 477–506.
391.
Pamuk, Şevket. 2007. “The Black Death and the Origins of the ‘Great
Divergence’ across Europe, 1300–1600.” European Review of
Economic History 11(3): 289–317.
392.
Parente, Stephen L. and Edward C. Prescott. 2002. Barriers to Riches.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
393.
Parker, Geoffrey. 2014. Imprudent King: A New Life of Philip II. New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
394.
Pascali, Luigi. 2017. “The Wind of Change: Maritime Technology,
Trade, and Economic Development.” American Economic Review
107(9): 2821–54.
395.
Patel, Dev, Justin Sandefur, and Arvind Subramanian. 2021. “The New
Era of Unconditional Convergence.” Journal of Development
Economics 152: art. 102687.
396.
Pavlik, Jamie Bologna and Andrew T. Young. 2019. “Did Technology
Transfer More Rapidly East–West than North–South?” European
Economic Review 119: 216–35.
397.
Penn, Thomas. 2011. The Winter King: Henry VII and the Dawn of
Tudor England. New York: Simon & Schuster.
398.
Perkins, Dwight and John P. Tang. 2017. “East Asian Industrial
Pioneers: Japan, Korea, and Taiwan.” In The Spread of Modern
Industry to the Periphery since 1871, ed. Kevin O’Rourke and
Jeffrey Williamson. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 169–96.
399.
Pincus, Steven C.A. and James A. Robinson. 2014. “What Really
Happened during the Glorious Revolution?” In Institutions, Property
Rights, and Economic Growth: The Legacy of Douglass North. New
York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 192–222.
400.
Pipes, Richard. 1974. Russia under the Old Regime. London: Penguin.
401.
Platt, Brian. 2004. Burning and Building: Schooling and State
Formation in Japan, 1750–1890. Cambridge MA: Harvard
University Press.
402.
Platt, Stephen R. 2018. Imperial Twilight: The Opium War and the End
of China’s Last Golden Age. New York: Knopf.
403.
Platteau, Jean-Philippe. 2017. Islam Instrumentalized. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
404.
Pollack, A.F. and F.W. Maitland. 1895. The History of England Law,
Before the Time of Edward I, Vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
405.
Pomeranz, Kenneth. 2000. The Great Divergence: China, Europe and
the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
406.
Pomeranz, Kenneth. 2005. “Women’s Work and the Economics of
Respectability.” In Gender in Motion: Divisions of Labor and
Cultural Change in Late Imperial and Modern China, ed. Bryna
Goodman and Wendy Larson. Lanham, MD: Rowman and
Littlefield, pp. 239–63.
407.
Postan, M.M. 1973. Medieval Trade and Finance. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
408.
Pritchett, Lant. 1997. “Divergence, Big Time.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 11(3): 3–17.
409.
Pritchett, Lant and Lawrence H. Summers. 1996. “Wealthier Is
Healthier.” Journal of Human Resources 31(4): 841–68.
410.
Puga, Diego and Daniel Trefler. 2014. “International Trade and
Institutional Change: Medieval Venice’s Response to Globalization.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(2): 753–821.
411.
Putnam, Robert D., Robert Leonardi, and Raffaella Y. Nanetti. 1993.
Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
412.
Rajan, Raghuram G. and Luigi Zingales. 2003. “The Great Reversals:
The Politics of Financial Development in the Twentieth Century.”
Journal of Financial Economics 69(1): 5–50.
413.
Ransom, Roger and Richard Sutch. 1988. “Capitalists without Capital:
The Burden of Slavery and the Impact of Emancipation.”
Agricultural History 62(3): 133–60.
414.
Redding, Stephen and Anthony J. Venables. 2004. “Economic
Geography and International Inequality.” Journal of International
Economics 62(1): 53–82.
415.
Reid, Anthony. 2015. A History of Southeast Asia: Critical Crossroads.
Oxford: Wiley Blackwell.
416.
Richardson, Gary. 2008. “Brand Names before the Industrial
Revolution.” NBER Working Paper 13930.
417.
Richerson, Peter J. and Robert Boyd. 2010. “The Evolution of Free
Enterprise Values.” In Moral Markets: The Critical Role of Values in
the Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
418.
Richter, Daniel K. 2011. Before the Revolution: America’s Ancient
Pasts. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
419.
Robinson, James A., Ragnar Torvik, and Thierry Verdier. 2006.
“Political Foundations of the Resource Curse.” Journal of
Development Economics 79(2): 447–68.
420.
Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi. 2004.
“Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and
Integration in Economic Development.” Journal of Economic
Growth 9(2): 131–65.
421.
Root, Hilton L. 1991. “The Redistributive Role of Government:
Economic Regulation in Old Régime France and England.”
Comparative Studies in Society and History 33(2): 338–69.
422.
Root, Hilton L. 2020. Network Origins of the Global Economy: East vs.
West in a Complex Systems Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
423.
Rosenbloom, Joshua. 2004. “Path Dependence and the Origins of the
American Cotton Textile Industry.” In The Fibre that Changed the
World: Cotton Industry in International Perspective, ed. David
Jeremy and Douglas A. Farnie. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp.
365–91.
424.
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 1992. The Fruits of Revolution. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
425.
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent and Roy Bin Wong. 2011. Before and beyond
Divergence. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
426.
Roser, Max. 2021a. “Children Born per Woman.” Our World in Data.
Data available at:
https://web.archive.org/web/20180916202120if_/https://ourworldind
ata.org/grapher/children-born-per-woman.
427.
Roser, Max. 2021b. “The Rise of Basic Schooling since the 19th
Century.” Our World in Data. Data available at:
https://web.archive.org/web/20180921060942mp_/https://ourworldin
data.org/primary-and-secondary-education.
428.
Roser, Max. 2021c. “The Short History of Global Living Conditions
and Why It Matters That We Know It.” Our World in Data. Data
available at: https://ourworldindata.org/a-history-of-global-living-
conditions-in-5-charts.
429.
Ross, Michael L. 2015. “What Have We Learned about the Resource
Curse?” Annual Review of Political Science 18: 239–59.
430.
Rostow, Walt W. 1960. The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-
Communist Manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
431.
Rubin, Jared. 2011. “Institutions, the Rise of Commerce and the
Persistence of Laws: Interest Restrictions in Islam and Christianity.”
Economic Journal 121(557): 1310–39.
432.
Rubin, Jared. 2017. Rulers, Religion, and Riches: Why the West Got
Rich and the Middle East Did Not. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
433.
Sachs, Jeffrey D. and Pia Malaney. 2002. “The Economic and Social
Burden of Malaria.” Nature 415(6872): 680–5.
434.
Sachs, Jeffrey D. and Andrew M. Warner. 2001. “The Curse of Natural
Resources.” European Economic Review 45(4–6): 827–38.
435.
Saito, Osamu. 2005. “Pre-modern Economic Growth Revisited: Japan
and the West.” LSE Working Paper No. 16/05.
436.
Saito, Osamu. 2009. “Land, Labour and Market Forces in Tokugawa
Japan.” Continuity and Change 24(Special Issue 01): 169–96.
437.
Salter, Alexander William and Andrew T. Young. 2019. “Polycentric
Sovereignty: The Medieval Constitution, Governance Quality, and
the Wealth of Nations.” Social Science Quarterly 100(4): 1241–53.
438.
Scheidel, Walter. 2017. The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of
Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-first Century. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
439.
Scheidel, Walter. 2019. Escape from Rome. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
440.
Schulz, Jonathan F. 2020. “Kin Networks and Institutional
Development.” Working Paper.
441.
Schulz, Jonathan F., Duman Bahrami-Rad, Jonathan P. Beauchamp, and
Joseph Henrich. 2019. “The Church, Intensive Kinship, and Global
Psychological Variation.” Science 366(6466).
442.
Sequeira, Sandra, Nathan Nunn, and Nancy Qian. 2020. “Immigrants
and the Making of America.” Review of Economic Studies 87(1):
382–419.
443.
Shiue, Carol H. 2005. “From Political Fragmentation towards a
Customs Union: Border Effects of the German Zollverein, 1815 to
1855.” European Review of Economic History 9(2): 129–62.
444.
Shiue, Carol H. and Wolfgang Keller. 2007. “Markets in China and
Europe on the Eve of the Industrial Revolution.” American Economic
Review 97(4): 1189–216.
445.
Shleifer, Andrei, Florencio Lopez de Silanes, and Rafael La Porta.
2008. “The Economic Consequences of Legal Origins.” Journal of
Economic Literature 46(2): 285–332.
446.
Siedentop, Larry. 2014. Inventing the Individual: The Origins of
Western Liberalism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
447.
Smith, Adam. 1776/1976. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the
Wealth of Nations, ed. R.H. Campbell and A.S. Skinner. Liberty Fund
(reproducing Oxford University Press edition).
https://www.libertyfund.org/books/an-inquiry-into-the-nature-and-
causes-of-the-wealth-of-nations-vol-1/.
448.
Smith, Richard M. 1991. “Demographic Development in Rural
England, 1300–48: A Survey.” In Before the Black Death: Studies in
the “Crisis” of the Early Fourteenth Century, ed. Bruce M.S.
Campbell. Manchester: Manchester University Press, pp. 25–78.
449.
Sng, Tuan-Hwee. 2014. “Size and Dynastic Decline: The Principal–
Agent Problem in Late Imperial China, 1700–1850.” Explorations in
Economic History 54: 107–27.
450.
Sng, Tuan-Hwee and Chiaki Moriguchi. 2014. “Asia’s Little
Divergence: State Capacity in China and Japan before 1850.”
Journal of Economic Growth 19(4): 439–70.
451.
Sokoloff, Kenneth L. and Stanley L. Engerman. 2000. “Institutions,
Factor Endowments, and Paths of Development in the New World.”
Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(3): 217–32.
452.
Solow, Barbara L. 1987. “Capitalism and Slavery in the Exceedingly
Long Run.” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 17(4): 711–37.
453.
Solow, Robert M. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic
Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70(1): 65–94.
454.
Southern, Richard. 1970. Western Society and the Church in the Middle
Ages. New York: Penguin.
455.
Spolaore, Enrico and Romain Wacziarg. 2021. “Fertility and
Modernity.” Economic Journal. https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/ueab066.
456.
Squicciarini, Mara P. and Nico Voigtländer. 2015. “Human Capital and
Industrialization: Evidence from the Age of Enlightenment.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 130(4): 1825–83.
457.
Stasavage, David. 2002. “Credible Commitment in Early Modern
Europe: North and Weingast Revisited.” Journal of Law, Economics,
and Organization 18(1): 155–86.
458.
Stasavage, David. 2003. Public Debt and the Birth of the Democratic
State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
459.
Stasavage, David. 2011. States of Credit. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
460.
Stasavage, David. 2014. “Was Weber Right? The Role of Urban
Autonomy in Europe’s Rise.” American Political Science Review
108(2): 337–54.
461.
Stasavage, David. 2016. “What We Can Learn from the Early History
of Sovereign Debt.” Explorations in Economic History 59: 1–16.
462.
Stasavage, David. 2020. The Decline and Rise of Democracy: A Global
History from Antiquity to Today. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
463.
Steckel, Richard H. 2009. “Heights and Human Welfare: Recent
Developments and New Directions.” Explorations in Economic
History 46(1): 1–23.
464.
Stewart, Dugald. 1793/1980. “Account of the Life and Writings of
Adam Smith LL.D.” In Adam Smith, Essays on Philosophical
Subjects, ed. W.P.D. Wightman and J.C. Bryce. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, pp. 269–352.
465.
Styles, John. 2021. “The Rise and Fall of the Spinning Jenny: Domestic
Mechanisation in Eighteenth-century Cotton Spinning.” Textile
History 51(2): 195–236.
466.
Sugihara, Kaoru. 2004. “The State and the Industrious Revolution in
Tokugawa Japan.” LSE Working Paper.
467.
Tabellini, Guido. 2010. “Culture and Institutions: Economic
Development in the Regions of Europe.” Journal of the European
Economic Association 8(4): 677–716.
468.
Tawney, R.H. 1936. Religion and the Rise of Capitalism. A Historical
Study. London: John Murray.
469.
Taylor, Leigh Shaw and E.A. Wrigley. 2014. Occupational Structure
and Population Change. In The Cambridge Economic History of
Modern Britain (new edn.), Vol. 1: Industrialisation, 1700–1870, ed.
Roderick Floud, Jane Humphries, and Paul Johnson. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press pp. 53–88.
470.
Temin, Peter. 2006. “The Economy of the Early Roman Empire.”
Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(1): 133–51.
471.
Thompson, E.P. 1965. The Making of the English Working Class.
Harmondsworth: Penguin.
472.
Tilly, Charles. 1975. “Reflections on the History of European State-
making.” In The Formation of Nation States in Western Europe, ed.
Charles Tilly. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 3–84.
473.
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990–
1990. Oxford: Blackwell.
474.
Tocqueville, Alexis de. 1958. Journeys to England and Ireland. New
Haven: Yale University Press.
475.
Troesken, Werner. 2015. The Pox of Liberty: How the Constitution Left
Americans Rich, Free, and Prone to Infection. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
476.
Tullock, Gordon. 1967. “The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and
Theft.” Western Economics Journal 5(3): 224–32.
477.
Turner, Frederick Jackson. 1893. “The Significance of the Frontier in
American History.” Proceedings of the State Historical Society of
Wisconsin.
478.
Valencia Caicedo, Felipe. 2018. “The Mission: Human Capital
Transmission, Economic Persistence, and Culture in South America.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 134(1): 507–56.
479.
van Bavel, Bas. 2016. The Invisible Hand? How Market Economies
Have Emerged and Declined since AD 500. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
480.
van Bavel, Bas, Eltjo Buringh, and Jessica Dijkman. 2018. “Mills,
Cranes, and the Great Divergence: The Use of Immovable Capital
Goods in Western Europe and the Middle East, Ninth to Sixteenth
Centuries.” Economic History Review 71(1): 31–54.
481.
van Zanden, Jan Luiten. 2009. The Long Road to the Industrial
Revolution: The European Economy in a Global Perspective, 1000–
1800. Leiden: Brill.
482.
van Zanden, Jan Luiten, Eltjo Buringh, and Maarten Bosker. 2012.
“The Rise and Decline of European Parliaments, 1188–1789.”
Economic History Review 65(3): 835–61.
483.
van Zanden, Jan Luiten and Maarten Prak. 2006. “Towards an
Economic Interpretation of Citizenship: The Dutch Republic between
Medieval Communes and Modern Nation-states.” European Review
of Economic History 10(2): 111–45.
484.
van Zanden, Jan Luiten and Bas van Leeuwen. 2012. “Persistent but
Not Consistent: The Growth of National Income in Holland, 1347–
1807.” Explorations in Economic History 49(2): 119–30.
485.
Voigtländer, Nico and Hans-Joachim Voth. 2006. “Why England?
Demographic Factors, Structural Change and Physical Capital
Accumulation during the Industrial Revolution.” Journal of
Economic Growth 11(4): 319–61.
486.
Voigtländer, Nico and Hans-Joachim Voth. 2013a. “How the West
‘Invented’ Fertility Restriction.” American Economic Review 103(6):
2227–64.
487.
Voigtländer, Nico and Hans-Joachim Voth. 2013b. “The Three
Horsemen of Riches: Plague, War, and Urbanization in Early Modern
Europe.” Review of Economic Studies 80(2): 774–811.
488.
Voth, Hans-Joachim. 2001. “The Longest Years: New Estimates of
Labor Input in England, 1760–1830.” Journal of Economic History
61(4): 1065–82.
489.
Vries, Peer. 2015. State, Economy and the Great Divergence: Great
Britain and China, 1680s–1850s. London: Bloomsbury Publishing.
490.
Vries, Peer. 2020. Averting a Great Divergence. London: Bloomsbury.
491.
Waldinger, Maria. 2017. “The Long-run Effects of Missionary Orders
in Mexico.” Journal of Development Economics 127: 355–78.
492.
Waldinger, Maria. 2019. “The Economic Effects of Long-term Climate
Change: Evidence from the Little Ice Age.” Working Paper.
493.
Wallis, Patrick. 2008. “Apprenticeship and Training in Premodern
England.” Journal of Economic History 68(3): 832–61.
494.
Ward-Perkins, Bryan. 2005. The Fall of Rome, and the End of
Civilization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
495.
Watson, Andrew M. 1983. Agricultural Innovation in the Early Islamic
World: The Diffusion of Crops and Farming Techniques, 700–1100.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
496.
Weatherill, Lorna. 1988. Consumer Behaviour and Material Culture in
Britain, 1660–1700. London: Routledge.
497.
Weber, Isabella M. 2021. How China Escaped Shock Therapy: The
Market Reform Debate. London: Routledge.
498.
Weber, Max. 1905/1930. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of
Capitalism. Translated by Talcott Parsons. London: Allen and
Unwin.
499.
Weber, Max. 1978. Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive
Sociology, Vol. 1. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
500.
Weingast, Barry R. 1997. “The Political Foundations of Democracy and
the Rule of Law.” American Political Science Review 91(2): 245–63.
501.
Whatley, Warren C. 2018. “The Gun–Slave Hypothesis and the 18th
Century British Slave Trade.” Explorations in Economic History 67:
80–104.
502.
Whatley, Warren C. and Rob Gillezeau. 2011. “The Impact of the
Transatlantic Slave Trade on Ethnic Stratification in Africa.”
American Economic Review 101(3): 571–6.
503.
White, Lawrence H. 2012. The Clash of Economic Ideas. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
504.
WHO. 2018. “WHO Global Ambient Air Quality Database.” Data
available at: https://www.who.int/airpollution/data/cities/en/.
505.
Williams, Eric. 1944. Capitalism and Slavery. Chapel Hill, NC:
University of North Carolina Press.
506.
Williamson, Jeffrey G. 2006. Globalization and the Poor Periphery
before 1850. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
507.
Williamson, Oliver. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism.
New York: The Free Press.
508.
Wilson, Andrew. 2011. “City Sizes and Urbanization in the Roman
Empire.” In Settlement, Urbanization, and Population, ed. Alan
Bowman and Andrew Wilson. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp.
161–95.
509.
Wong, R. Bin. 1997. China Transformed: Historical Change and the
Limits of European Experience. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
510.
Wong, R. Bin. 2012. “Taxation and Good Governance in China 1500–
1914.” In The Rise of Fiscal States: A Global History, 1500–1914,
ed. Bartolome Yuan-Casaliia, Patrick K. O’Brien, and Francisco
Comín Comín. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 353–78.
511.
Woodard, Colin. 2011. American Nations: A History of the Eleven Rival
Regional Cultures of North America. New York: Penguin.
512.
Woodberry, Robert D. 2012. “The Missionary Roots of Liberal
Democracy.” American Political Science Review 106(2): 244–74.
513.
Wooton, David. 2015. The Invention of Science. London: Allen Lane.
514.
World Bank. 2019. “World Development Indicators: GDP per Capita
(Current US$).” Data available at:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/ny.gdp.pcap.cd.
515.
World Bank. 2020a. “Total Population Living in Extreme Poverty, by
World Region.” Data available at:
https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/total-population-living-in-
extreme-poverty-by-world-region.
516.
World Bank. 2020b. “World Development Indicators.” Data available
at: https://datacatalog.worldbank.org/dataset/world-development-
indicators.
517.
World Justice Project. 2020. “Rule of Law Index.”
https://worldjusticeproject.org/our-work/research-and-data/wjp-rule-
law-index-2019/current-historical-data.
518.
Wright, Gavin. 2020. “Slavery and Anglo-American Capitalism
Revisited.” Economic History Review 73(2): 353–83.
519.
Wright, Mary C. 1957. The Last Stand of Chinese Conservatism: The
Tung-Chih Restoration, 1862–1874. Stanford, CA: Stanford
University Press.
520.
Wrigley, E.A. 1989. Continuality, Chance and Change: The Character
of the Industrial Revolution in England. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
521.
Wrigley, E.A. 2010. Energy and the English Industrial Revolution.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
522.
Wrigley, E.A, R.S. Davies, J.E. Oeppen, and R.S. Schofield. 1997.
English Population History from Family Reconstitution, 1580–1837.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
523.
Wrigley, E.A. and R.S. Schofield. 1981. The Population History of
England, 1541–1871: A Reconstruction. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
524.
Xue, Melanie Meng. 2020. “High-value Work and the Rise of Women:
The Cotton Revolution and Gender Equality in China.” Working
Paper.
525.
Xue, Melanie Meng. 2021. “Autocratic Rule and Social Capital:
Evidence from Imperial China.” Mimeo.
526.
yü Têng, Ssu. 1943. “Chinese Influence on the Western Examination
System: I. Introduction.” Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 7(4):
267–312.
527.
Ziegler, Philip. 1969. The Black Death. London: Collins.
Index
Page numbers in italics refer to figures and tables.
A
Acemoglu, D.
and Johnson, S., Robinson, J.A. 11, 33, 40, 41, 114, 115, 139
and Robinson, J.A. 50–1, 52, 187, 208
and Wolitzky, A. 95–6
Africa
colonization 108, 114, 116, 117–19, 120, 122–3
and independence 199–200
cultural norms 84–5
geographic factors 20–2
ruggedness of terrain 11, 12
Jewish traders, North Africa 53, 80–2
slave trades 109–13
trust 11, 111
agriculture
Black Death, impact of 93–4, 95–6
capitalism 95, 153–4
China 216–17, 218
climate and geography 25–6
Dutch Cultivation System, Java, Indonesia 121–2
England/Britain
capitalist agriculture 153–4
crop yields (18th century) 107
labor force 177
gender norms 85, 86
India 117, 118
and Malthusian model of population 92
potato, introduction of 107
Soviet Russia 195–6
and technology 6, 22–4
Alesina, A., Giuliano, P., and Nunn, N. 85, 86
Allen, R.C. 8–9, 34, 151, 154, 166, 168–71, 174, 175, 178–9, 192, 206
and Weisdorf, J.L. 153
Americas/New World and European Empires 104–5, 107, 116
Atlantic trade route 32–3, 137–8, 139, 140
amoral familism 79–80
Anderson, R.W., Johnson, N.D., and Koyama, M. 26, 27
Anne of England 88
Appleby, J. 194
apprenticeships 164
Arkwright, R.: water frame 166, 167, 168
Arrow, K.J. 83
Arteaga, F., Desierto. D, and Koyama M. 140
Ashraf, Q. and Galor, O. 92
Asia
East Asian Tigers 207–11
per capita GDP 199
trade routes and colonization 104–5
Athenian democracy 50, 56, 59
Atlantic economy and Industrial Revolution, Britain 156–8
Atlantic trade 32–3, 137–8, 139
slave 108, 109, 110, 158–60
Australia 189
autocracy and democracy 48–9
B
da Gama, V. 104
Darity, W. 160
“Dark Ages” 26, 134
Davis, D.R. and Weinstein, D.E. 19–20
de la Croix, D., Doepke, M., and Mokyr, J. 55
de Vries, J. 152, 158
and van der Woude, A. 147, 152–3, 162–3
death/mortality rates
and birth rates, Malthusian model 90–2
colonial settlers 114, 115
impact of Black Death 92–4, 96
infant 21, 88
Dell, M. 116
and Olken, B.A. 121–2
democracy
Athenian 50, 56, 59
and autocracy 48–9
cultural beliefs and norms 67
education and Protestant missionaries 123
demographic transition 101–2, 183–5
Deng Xiaoping 217, 219
Denmark: butter industry 189
Dennison, T. and Ogilvie, S. 100–1
Derenoncourt, E. 159
Desierto, D. and Koyama, M. 45
Desmet, K. and Parente, S. 162
Diamond, J. 19, 22, 23, 32, 132
Dias, B. 104
Dippel, C. 117
disease
Africa 21, 114
among rich (18th century) 88
animal–human interactions 23–4
Black Death 6, 92–6, 99, 135, 152, 153
Dittmar, J,
and Meisenzahl, R. 74
and Yuchtman, N. 75
Donaldson, D. 32, 120–1
and Hornbeck, R. 31, 193
Drelichman, M. and Voth, H.-J. 60, 140
Dutch Cultivation System, Java, Indonesia 121–2
Dutch Republic/Netherlands 140–3, 147–8, 152–3, 162–3, 164
Protestantism 75–6
Dutch Revolt 141
E
famine
China 216, 217
pre-Black Death 93–4
Soviet Russia 196
Feinstein, C.H. 8, 177
Fernández, R. and Fogli, A. 85
Fernández-Villaverde, J., 46
and Koyama, M., Lin, Y., Sng, T.-H. 132
fertility/birth rates see demographic transition; European Marriage
Pattern (EMP); Malthusian model
Finley, M., 69
fiscal capacity 58–64
Florence, Italy 50, 62, 94, 136
Floud, R. 9
Fogel, R.W. 9, 31
Foreman-Peck, J. 100
“fractured land” hypothesis 132
France
birth rate 184–5
and England 32, 33, 42, 46, 94, 95, 122
legal system 46, 47
parlements 58
property rights 42, 43
Frankema, E.H.P. 122
and van Waijenburg, M. 120
Franklin, B. 71, 194
Friedman, B.M. 5
Fukuyama, F. 134–5, 218
G
Kamen, H. 96
Karaman, K. and Pamuk, S. 61
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., Mastruzzi, M. 41, 42
Kelly, M.
and Mokyr, J., Ó Gráda, C. 156, 162–4, 177
and Ó Gráda, C. 156, 166, 171
kin-/clan-based cultures 79–82, 134–5, 215–16
Ko, C., Koyama, M, and Sng, T.-H. 133
Kohli, A. 200
Koyama, M. 152
and Moriguchi, C., Sng, T.-H. 203–5, 213
Kuba Kingdom, Congo 84–5
Kuran, T. 47, 77, 108, 131
and Rubin, J. 37
L
Ma, D. 206
and Rubin, J. 155
Macartney, G. 70
Macaulay, T. 179–80
McCloskey, D.N. 69, 129, 134, 153, 160
Maddison, A. 8
Magna Carta 56–7
Majewski, J. 191–2
malaria 21, 114
Malthus, T. 88–9, 96–7, 179, 184
Malthusian model 89–92, 96–7, 101–2, 178, 185, 216
and Black Death 92–6
Mann, C. 24
manufacturing see Industrial Revolution, Britain; modern economy, rise
of
Mao Zedong 216–17, 219
market access 31–2, 136, 193
market economy 151–2, 213, 216
market exchange 151
markets
and competition 38, 215, 223
expansion of 28
and geography 24
and growth 223
and immigration 194
and innovation 162, 223
integration of 29, 121, 156, 162, 213
size, Britain: Industrial Revolution 161–2, 191
marriage 80, 81, 135, 183, 184
see also European Marriage Pattern (EMP)
Marshall, M.G. and Elzinga-Marshall, G. 48
Marx, K. 106, 154
and Engels, F. 178–9
McLean, I. 189
measurement of wealth 1–2, 4, 5–6, 7, 8–10
medieval period 134–7
see also Commercial Revolution
mercantilism and Empire, Britain: Industrial Revolution 156–8
merchant guilds 55–6
Michalopoulos, S. and Papaioannou, E. 117–19
Middle East 137
Arab Spring 67
capital investment 42–3
European colonization 108
Islam, influence of 76–9
Mill, J.S. 179
mining
coal 168–9, 170
precious metals 114, 116, 139
missionaries 70, 122–4
modern economy, rise of 9, 129–30
and colonialism 106
demographic transition 101–2, 183–5
East Asian Tigers 207–11
European Marriage Pattern (EMP) 99–100
Industrial Revolution and fruits of 176–80
Japan 202–6
Second Industrial Revolution 180–3
Soviet Russia 195–7
uneven diffusion of modern economic growth 185–90
US 190–4, 195
Mokyr, J. 35, 155, 160, 171–4, 175, 180, 181, 182, 192, 215
and Nye, J.V.C. 146
and Sarid, A., van der Beek, K. 163
monarchy
disease and life expectancy 88
England 143–6
Habsburg 84, 138, 139, 140, 141
and parliaments 56–8, 60–1, 143–7
Montesquieu, C. de 19, 25, 134
mortality see death/mortality rates
mountains 132
coasts, and climate 24–7
ruggedness of terrain 11, 12, 25
N
Ober, J., 50
Ogilvie, S. 55–6, 101
open-access order and natural state systems 51–2, 187
Ottoman Empire 37, 78, 84, 105, 155, 187, 188
P
Pamuk, S. 94
parliaments
and limited government 56–8, 59, 140–7
and Protestantism 75
Pascali, L. 189
patent system, Britain 155
Pavlik, J.B. and Young, A.T. 24
Peel, R. 70, 168
Philip II of Spain 33, 60, 139, 141, 155
plagues see Black Death
Platt, B. 204
Platt, S.R. 70
political fragmentation
and cultural unity, Europe 173, 214
and topography 130, 132, 133–4
political institutions 47–9
Britain: Industrial Revolution 154–5
China 214–15, 217–20
East Asian Tigers 210–11
and catch-up economic growth 187–8
and economic institutions 49–52
Soviet 196–7
US 192–3
see also parliaments
political legitimacy
China 214, 219
Islamic societies 77–9
Protestant societies 75–6, 141, 143–5
Pomeranz, K. 14, 34–5, 85–7, 213
population 88–9, 102–3, 138
Black Death 92–6
change and transition to modern economic growth 101–2, 183–5
China 215–16
East Asian Tigers 211
England 149, 150, 156, 157, 178, 179, 183–4, 186
household formation and European Marriage Pattern (EMP) 96–
101
pre-industrial Malthusian pressure 89–92
US 190, 194, 195
Portugal: colonialism 104, 106, 107, 108, 109
poverty/extreme poverty 198, 201–2, 222
Africa 111, 112
China 212, 216
decline of 2–3, 4, 15
India 201–2
and pre-industrial population pressure 89–92
primitive accumulation and colonization 106
printing presses 78, 123, 136–7, 187
property rights 41–3, 46, 139–40, 145–6, 201, 204
intellectual 155
protectionist policies
India 201, 209–10
US 193–4
Protestantism
education 73–4
missionaries 123, 124
as source of political legitimacy 75–6
Spanish Habsburgs and Dutch Revolt 141
work ethic and capitalism 71–3, 194
Prussia 61, 73–4, 182
public goods and colonization 120–2
Q
railroads
Britain 29
British India 32, 120–1
US 31–2, 193
religion 71–9
missionaries 122–4
see also Catholicism; Islam; Protestantism
rents 51
craft guilds 54, 55
elites 136, 146, 196, 201
monopoly 57, 140
Republic of Letters, Europe 171–4
resources
and colonization 106–7, 113–19
and industrialization 33–5
resource curse 132, 140
“reversal of fortunes”: former colonies 11, 13, 114, 116
Ricardo, D. 179
Richardson, G. 54
Richerson, P.J. and Boyd, R. 66
Roman Climatic Optimum 25–6
Roman Empire 103, 109
elites 69, 105, 224
and post-Roman invasions 133
transport infrastructure, impacts of 27–9, 32, 33
Roman law 46
Rosenthal, J.-L. 43
and Wong, R.B. 62–3
rubber extraction, Belgian Congo 114, 116
Rubin, J. 72, 75–6, 77–8
ruggedness of terrain 11, 12, 25
see also mountains
rule of law 39–40, 41, 42, 54, 57, 65, 218
autocracies vs. democracies 49
vs. rule by law 45
Russia 61, 84
Soviet 195–7, 223
S
wages
Black Death, impact of 94–5, 96, 97, 152
European Marriage Pattern (EMP) 138
Industrial Revolution, Britain 168–71
and prices, historical estimation of wealth 8–9
real, and GDP per capita income 177–9, 203
Wallis, P. 164
war
and climate 27
English Civil Wars 144
and industrial technologies 188
Napoleonic 178, 188
and state finances 58–64
and wages 96
Wars of the Roses 143
World War II 19–20, 206, 211
water frame 166, 167, 168
water transport 24–5
steamships 188–9
Watt, J.: steam engine 169, 170, 179
Weber, M. 71–3, 76, 194
Whatley, W.C. and Gillezeau, R. 111, 113
White, L. 201
William of Orange 141
and Mary 144–5
Williams, E. 108, 158, 159
Williamson, O. 43
Wong, B. 214
Woodberry, R. 123
Wooten, D. 168
World Bank 199, 202, 207, 208, 212
World Bank Governance Index (WBGI) 41, 42
Wrigley, E.A. 34
and Davies, R.S., Oeppen, J.E., Schofield, R.S. 98
and Schofield, R.S. 183, 186
Wright, G. 192
Wright, M. 215
X
Xi Jinping 219
Xue, M.M. 85–7, 214–15
POLITY END USER LICENSE AGREEMENT
Go to www.politybooks.com/eula to access Polity’s ebook EULA.
Table of Contents
Dedication
Title Page
Copyright
Preface
1 Why, When, and How Did the World Become Rich?
What Is Economic Growth?
Measuring the Past
What Will You Learn from This Book?
What This Book Does Not Do
Part I Theories of How the World Became Rich
2 Did Some Societies Win the Geography Lottery?
Geography and Modern Development
Mountains, Coasts, and Climate
Geography and Transport Infrastructure
Geography and Industrialization
Chapter Summary
3 Is It All Just Institutions?
What Are Institutions?
Property Rights
The Legal System
Political Institutions
More Equal Rights for All
Institutions and the Commercial Revolution
Between the State and the Market: Guilds
Parliaments and Limited Government
War and State Finances
Chapter Summary
4 Did Culture Make Some Rich and Others Poor?
What Is Culture and Why Does It Matter?
Can Culture Explain the European Take-off?
Does Religion Affect Economic Growth?
The Protestant Work Ethic and the “Spirit” of
Capitalism
If Not a Work Ethic, Why Did Protestant
Countries Grow Faster?
The Reformation and Religion as a Source of
Political Legitimacy
Is Islam the Cause of Middle Eastern
Economic Stagnation?
The Long-Term Persistence of Culture
The North–South Italy Divide
The Persistence of Trust Norms
Gender Norms
Chapter Summary
5 Fewer Babies?
Malthusian Pressures
The Black Death
Household Formation and the European
Marriage Pattern
Did the EMP Spur Economic Growth?
Reasons for Skepticism
Demographic Change and the Transition to
Modern Economic Growth
Chapter Summary
6 Was It Just a Matter of Colonization and Exploitation?
How Did the Colonizers Benefit?
The Slave Trades
The Resource Grab
Some Silver Linings of Colonialism?
Public Goods and Education
Missionaries
Chapter Summary
Part II Why Some Parts of the World Became Rich First, Why Other Parts
Followed, and Why Some Are Not There Yet
7 Why Did Northwestern Europe Become Rich First?
How Geography Shaped Institutional
Development
Why Was There No Medieval European Take-
off?
Divergence within Europe Just before the
Take-off
Parliaments and the Rise of Limited,
Representative Government
Chapter Summary
8 Britain’s Industrial Revolution
A Consumer Revolution
Capitalist Agriculture
Do Political Institutions Explain Britain’s
Industrialization?
Mercantilism and Empire
Does the Transatlantic Slave Trade Explain
Britain’s Industrialization?
Was It Cotton?
Was It Market Size?
How About State Capacity?
Maybe It Was Skilled Mechanical Workers?
An Innovative Economy
High Wages and Induced Innovation
An Enlightened Economy
Chapter Summary
9 The Rise of the Modern Economy
The Fruits of Industrialization
The Second Industrial Revolution
The Demographic Transition
The Uneven Diffusion of Modern Economic
Growth
How the US Became Rich
The Soviet Detour
Chapter Summary
10 Industrialization and the World It Created
Delayed Catch-up: The Shadow of
Colonization (and Other Factors)
How Japan Became Rich
How the East Asian Tigers Became Rich
How China Is Becoming Rich
Chapter Summary
11 The World Is Rich
References
Index
End User License Agreement