Hotel Management Deficiencies
Hotel Management Deficiencies
Hotel Management Deficiencies
A review of the findings of prior empirical research concerning hotel management con-
tracts between owners and operators is undertaken. It is noted that management con-
tracts have become increasingly commonplace in the international hotel sector and that
gross revenue and gross operating profit are the most extensively used determinants of
operator incentive fee remuneration. These findings present a platform for examining
how revenue and gross operating profit are deficient in promoting owner–operator goal
congruency. In light of this, return on investment (ROI) and residual income (RI) are
examined as potential alternative determinants of operator reimbursement. Although it
is appears that both ROI and RI as determinants of hotel operator fees would represent
an advance in promoting owner–operator goal congruency, a rationale outlining how RI
is preferable to ROI is outlined.
Collier and Gregory (1995a) feel that capital budgeting research is particu-
larly warranted in hotels because of their dual role of property and guest man-
agement and because of their high proportion of capital intensive assets.
Furthermore, hotels are vibrant organizations characterized by complex build-
ings that are costly to maintain (Chan, Lee, & Burnett, 2001). The importance
of these assets underscores the view that the most important budget in a hotel is
the capital budget (Condon, Blaney, & Harrington, 1996; Lynch, 2002).
Guilding (2003, 2006) notes heightened capital budgeting complexity in
hotels operating with a management contract, because the capital outlay decision
must traverse organizational boundaries in satisfying investment criteria of both
Authors’ Note: The authors would like to acknowledge helpful suggestions provided by attendees
at the Performance Measurement Association Conference in Dunedin, New Zealand (April 14-17,
2009), and also the detailed commentaries provided by three reviewers that have resulted in the
article being strengthened.
Journal of Hospitality & Tourism Research, Vol. 34, No. 4, November 2010, 478-511
DOI: 10.1177/1096348010370855
© 2010 International Council on Hotel, Restaurant and Institutional Education
owner and operator. Given the high incidence of owner–operator hotel manage-
ment contracts and the particular governance challenges arising, Field (1995)
expresses surprise at the minimal academic research directed toward furthering
our appreciation of this idiosyncratic governance arrangement.
Although there is a large literature concerning capital budgeting practice in
hotels (e.g., Brander-Brown, 1995; Collier & Gregory, 1995a, 1995b; Damitio
& Schmidgall, 2002; DeFranco, 1997; Eder & Umbreit, 1987; Eyster & Geller,
1981; Field, 1995; Guilding, 2003, 2006; Guilding & Hargreaves, 2003;
Guilding & Lamminmaki, 2007; T. Jones, 1998; Schmidgall & Damitio, 1990;
Schmidgall & Ninemeier, 1987), few studies have investigated the particular
capital budgeting issues arising in hotels governed by a management contract
(Field, 1995; Guilding, 2003, 2006). This is surprising as Beals and Denton
(2005) contend that expectations concerning operators’ appropriate expenditure
of owners’ money have been severely undermined by field observations and law
court judgments. This beckons a fundamental examination of this critical aspect
of the owner–operator relationship.
These factors provide the contextual motivation for this study. The study’s
objective is twofold. First, it seeks to provide an examination of management
contract provisions pertaining to hotel operator remuneration and explicate
shortcomings of these provisions in promoting owner–operator capital expendi-
ture goal congruency. Second, it examines the relative merits of alternative
determinants of hotel operator fees, such as return on investment (ROI) and
residual income (RI). The importance of remunerating a hotel operator in a
manner consistent with promoting owner–operator capital expenditure goal
congruence becomes particularly evident when we recognize that it is the hotel
operator that generally initiates capital expenditure proposals (Guilding, 2006).
Should capital expenditure goal congruency be deficient, operators may fail to
share with owners capital expenditure ideas that significantly serve owner inter-
ests but are minimally aligned to their interests.
By exploring hotel owner–operator contractual relations, this study contrib-
utes to agency theory, as it focuses on exposing contractual problems arising
when an agent (hotel operator) has the capacity to act in a self-interested manner
that is inconsistent with the principal’s (hotel owner) interests (Berle & Means,
1962; Jensen & Meckling, 1976). The agency model has been employed in a
wide variety of business settings concerned with a range of issues, for example,
vertical integration (Walker & Weber, 1984), executive compensation (Baker,
Jensen, & Murphy, 1988), and tender offers (Cotter & Zenner, 1994). It has also
been applied in a range of disciplinary contexts, for example, accounting
(Demski & Feltham, 1978), marketing (Basu, Lai, Srinivasan, & Staelin, 1985),
and organizational behavior (Eisenhardt, 1988)). This study concerns the
owner–manager agency relationship that has been the dominant focus in agency
theory-based studies (Eisenhardt, 1989; Walsh & Seward, 1990).
The authors are not aware of any prior academic work that provides a sys-
tematically conducted expose of the relative merits of hotel operator incentives
used widely in hotel management contracts. We are also not aware of any prior
Downloaded from jht.sagepub.com by guest on May 10, 2016
480 JOURNAL OF HOSPITALITY & TOURISM RESEARCH
consideration given to the extent to which ROI and RI may represent preferable
bases on which to base hotel operators’ fees. This article’s primary contribution
is to provide a systematic examination of the shortcomings of conventional
performance measures used to determine hotel operator fees and to advance the
case that ROI and RI represent alternative performance bases that would result
in heightened levels of owner–operator goal alignment. The rationale provided
offers considerable potential to stimulate further debate into hotel owner–operator
contracting and to change the structure of operator fee incentive terms widely
used in hotel management contracting. The article can also be seen as represent-
ing a particular contribution to the application of agency theory in the hotel
management context.
The remainder of the article is structured as follows. The next section sum-
marizes findings of prior research suggesting increasing use of hotel manage-
ment contracts. This is followed by an examination of the widespread use of
operator fee determinants and also termination clause performance measures
that undermine owner–operator capital expenditure goal congruency. An exam-
ination of the relative merits of ROI and RI as alternative operator fee incentive
bases is then provided. The final section provides a concluding discussion and
some suggestions for further research designed to extend insights concerning
the dynamics of hotel management contracting provided herein.
Regardless of how a hotel’s assets are owned, hotel owners face a number of
choices regarding their operating structure. In many cases, the party that owns
a hotel does not operate the hotel (Hayes & Ninemeier, 2004). Considered inter-
nationally, the three main hotel operational methods are the owner–operator,
franchise agreement, and management contract (Gannon & Johnson, 1997).
Hotel owners that choose to operate their hotel avoid any loss of control over
day-to-day operations (Field, 1995). The use of the owner–operator hotel own-
ership structure is, however, dwindling in many developed Western markets,
such as the United States, Europe, Australia, and New Zealand (Gross-Turner,
1999; Ingram & Baum, 1997; P. Jones, 1996; Phillips, 2003; Slattery, 1992).
Furthermore, there is little use of the hotel owner–operator structure in the bur-
geoning economies of India, China, and other parts of Asia (Haast et al., 2006).
As a result, usually only “flagship” properties remain independently owned and
operated (Gannon & Johnson, 1997).
Garcia-Falcon and Medina-Munoz (1999) define hotel franchising as an
arrangement where:
For a fee, an independent hotel [i.e., owner–operator] adopts the franchiser’s name
and trademarks and receives services in return, including the preparatory steps of
feasibility, site selection, financing, design, and planning. Almost all the advan-
tages of the chain are available for the franchisee: mass purchasing, management
consultation, wide advertising, central reservations, and systems designs. (p. 106)
Table 1
Percentage Distribution of Hotel Operating Modal Types
by Major Geographical Region
Despite relatively high franchising fees, studies show that in both developed
and emerging markets, conditions are more supportive of franchising arrange-
ments than owner–operator structures (see, e.g., Fladmoe-Lindquist & Laurent,
1995; Huszagh, Huszagh, & McIntyre, 1992; Kedia, Ackerman, Bush, & Justis,
1994; Shane, 1996).
Despite the well-established franchising model, recent surveys show that the
third main hotel operational approach, the management contract, has become
the most popular of the three options. The separation between ownership and
management through the use of a hotel management contract is now widespread
(Beals & Denton, 2005; Corgel, 2007; Panvisavas & Taylor, 2006) and is one
of the driving mechanisms for the rapid internationalization of hotels (Beattie,
1991; Dave, 1984; Dunning & McQween, 1981; Eyster, 1997; Litteljohn, 1991;
Litteljohn & Beattie, 1992). Table 1 highlights the predominance of the man-
agement contract across North America, Europe, and Asia in the late 1990s.
Furthermore, Slattery (1996) noted 75% of listed Asian hotels operating under
a management contract. Contractor and Kundu (1998) found 41% of U.S. hotels
had a management contract, whereas Smith Travel Research (2003) noted an
increase to 55%. Beals and Denton (2005), Panvisavas and Taylor (2006), and
Corgel (2007) have provided further recent testimony to the increasing popular-
ity of management contracts.
A management contract is essentially a written agreement between an owner
and operator where the operator is appointed to operate and manage the hotel in
the name of, on behalf of, and for the account of the owner. The contract includes
a description of the operator’s remuneration fee determination (Schlup, 2004). It
enables a hotel owner to retain legal ownership of the hotel site, building, plant
and equipment, furnishings and inventories, whereas the operator assumes
responsibility for managing the hotel’s day-to-day business (Guilding, 2003).
Management contracts do suffer, however, from some drawbacks. A funda-
mental problem concerns agency challenges, as the divorce of ownership and
operation can create a volatile mix of economics and power manifested because
of differing owner–operator time horizons (Beals, 1995; Beals & Denton,
2005). It is generally held that operators focus on short-term cash flows,
whereas owners have more of a long-term orientation (Guilding, Kennedy, &
Downloaded from jht.sagepub.com by guest on May 10, 2016
482 JOURNAL OF HOSPITALITY & TOURISM RESEARCH
McManus, 2001; Lynch, 2002). This tension is widely referred to as the “horizon
problem” (Dechow & Sloan, 1991; Ittner, Larker, & Rajan, 1997; B. Johnson,
1987; Smith & Watts, 1982) and can lead agents to promote low net present
value (NPV) projects yielding relatively high short-term accounting earnings at
the expense of higher NPV projects that yield lower short-term accounting earn-
ings (Baber, Kang, & Kumar, 1998). Operators also tend to focus on maximizing
their brand values and the longevity of their management contracts to increase
the room stock under their management (Beals & Denton, 2005; Haast et al.,
2006; Schiff, 2006). With regard to the brand value maximization incentive, it
is notable that a large proportion of a hotel company’s assets are made up of
goodwill associated with their brand name (Dev, Morgan, & Shoemaker, 1995).
The importance of hotel brand value signifies that operators have an incentive
to support capital expenditures that are consistent with projecting a favorable
brand image, even though the expenditure may provide limited equity value
enhancement for the hotel owner. Consider, for example, a proposed hotel
lobby refurbishment. On incremental cash flow grounds, the refurbishment
expenditure may not be viable. However, in terms of improved brand alignment
for the operating company, the proposed lobby refurbishment may be highly
desirable. These examples of conflicting interests underscore the fact that man-
agement contracts are frequently associated with owner–operator agency con-
flict (Dimou, Chen, & Archer, 2003).
Table 2
Prior Research Into the Calculation of Hotel Operator Base Management Fees
(continued)
Table 2 (continued)
concerned with ascertaining how hotel operator base fees are determined. It is
evident from this table that internationally, the majority of management contract
base fees are determined by gross revenue.
The continued widespread popularity of revenue-determined operator base fees
appears somewhat surprising given Feldman’s (1995) comment that they provide
an incentive for operators to “blithely recommend expenditures that increase top-
line revenues that never drop to the bottom line” (p. 43). Two further noteworthy
implications arise from remunerating operators based on hotel revenue:
486
Prior Research Into the Calculation of Hotel Operator Incentive Management Fees
Contracts Percentage of
Author Geographic Focus Analyzed Incidence Determinant of incentive fee and typical amount
(continued)
Table 3 (continued)
Contracts Percentage of
Author Geographic Focus Analyzed Incidence Determinant of incentive fee and typical amount
Eyster (1993) United States 17 29.4 GOP (5% to 15%)
17.6 Cash flow after debt service (10% to 28%)
11.8 Improvement in GOP (10% to 30%)
5.9 Adjusted GOP (8% to 20%; adjustment not specified)
5.9 Cash flow after debt service and return on equity charge (18% to 30%)
5.9 Appreciated value of property (10%)
23.5 No incentive fee
Sangree and Hathaway United States 32 Most common Percentage increase in GOP compared with a predetermined figure
(1996) (14.0% mean)
Common GOP (7.9% mean)
Common Percentage beyond an owner’s priority return (17.1% mean)
Less common Percentage of GOP that exceeds a base fee amount (did not specify)
Less common Percentage of NOP over a fixed amount (did not specify)
Less common Percentage of the amount by which cumulative cash flow exceeds
cumulative set-aside amount (did not specify)
Eyster (1997) United States 18 27.8 Cash flow after debt service (0% to 32%)
(continued)
487
Table 3 (continued)
488
Contracts Percentage of
Author Geographic Focus Analyzed Incidence Determinant of incentive fee and typical amount
K. Johnson (1999) United States 50 76.0 GOP less property taxes, FF&E reserve allocation, debt service, and
owner’s priority return (21% mean)
12.0 GOP less property taxes and FF&E reserve allocation (did not specify)
8.0 GOP less property taxes, FF&E reserve allocation, and debt service
(did not specify)
4.0 GOP less property taxes (did not specify)
4.0 No incentive fee
Barge and Jacobs Asia-Pacific 50 42.0 GOP (8% mean)
(2001) (Australia 40.0 GOP sliding scale (5% to 10%; most popular range)
included) 10.0 Unspecified
8.0 No incentive fee
Europe 24 54.2 GOP (6.9% mean)
41.7 GOP sliding scale (5% to 15%; most popular range)
4.2 No incentive fee
Americas 28 21.4 Percentage of the difference between an adjusted GOP (by deducting
the base management fee) and a specified percentage of the
purchase price of the hotel (25% to 80% of the difference)
21.4 Percentage of NOP over a certain threshold (unspecified)
(continued)
Table 3 (continued)
Contracts Percentage of
Author Geographic Focus Analyzed Incidence Determinant of incentive fee and typical amount
Haast, Dickson, Asia-Pacific 28 39.3 GOP (11.2% mean)
and Braham (2005) (Australia 35.7 GOP sliding scale (5% to 10%; most popular range)
included) 10.7 Other (not specified)
14.3 No incentive fee
Europe 29 31.0 Adjusted GOP by deducting the base management fee (9.2% mean)
27.6 Profit share, which can include
NOP thresholds
Owner’s priority return deducted from GOP
GOP targets
20.7 GOP sliding scale (5% to 10%; most popular range)
17.2 Other sliding scales (unspecified)
3.4 No incentive fee
Americas 28 21.4 NOP after payout of owner’s priority return (20%)
17.9 GOP (7.6% mean)
Note: GOP = gross operating profit; FF&E = furniture, fittings, and equipment; NOP = net operating profit.
489
490 JOURNAL OF HOSPITALITY & TOURISM RESEARCH
revenue, then an additional $30 (3% of $1,000) will be allocated to the FF&E
reserve and deducted from the profit basis used for determining the incentive
payment. Say that 10% of the adjusted profit is being provided to the operator
as their incentive fee, the result of the $1,000 increased revenue on the incentive
fee paid is a reduction of only $3 ($1,000 × 3% × 10%).2 This worked example
highlights the extent to which deducting FF&E reserve allocations from GOP
used in determining operator incentive fee payments contributes minimally to
greater owner–operator capital expenditure goal congruency. Furthermore, it is
notable that the amount allocated to FF&E reserve does not represent a good
proxy for FF&E capital expenditure, as it is widely noted that FF&E reserve
contributions fall some way short of the average annual capital expenditure
required to maintain FF&E (Barge & Jacobs, 2001; Brooke & Denton, 2007;
Eyster, 1988, 1997; Ferguson & Selling, 1985; Haast, Dickson, & Braham,
2005; Mellen, Nylen, & Pastorino, 2000; Ransley & Ingram, 2001; Reichardt &
Lennhoff, 2003; Turner & Guilding, 2010).3
Of the asset-related deductions from GOP that are noted in Table 3, making
a charge for debt service and return on equity both appear to lay the basis for
greater owner–operator capital expenditure goal congruency relative to an
FF&E reserve allocation–linked deduction. This is because they both represent
an explicit charge for the full cost of any capital outlays made, signifying an
operator incentive to minimize an owner’s capital outlay.4
A second dimension of the management contract drawing on accounting
metrics to promote owner–operator goal alignment concerns performance stan-
dards that, if not met, can be invoked by an owner as grounds for contract termi-
nation (Dutta, 2003; Haktanir & Harris, 2005). This aspect of contracting can be
a source of significant owner–operator conflict (Beals & Denton, 2005). Despite
this, the deployment of minimum performance standards in hotel management
contracting is expected to increase commensurate with rising hotel operator
competition levels (Goddard & Standish-Wilkinson, 2002; Harris & Mongiello,
2001; Rainsford, 1994). It is widely noted, however, that exclusive use of per-
formance measures is unlikely to curb potential dysfunctional operator behavior,
because owners have limited capacity to extract all private information pertain-
ing to performance (Baiman, 1990; Baiman, Evans, & Noel, 1987; Magee, 1980).
The findings of prior empirical research appraising the nature and incidence of
operator performance measures are summarized in Table 4.
The only measures documented in Table 4 that have not already been con-
sidered are occupancy and revenue per available room (RevPAR). The relative
merits of each are outlined in the hospitality management accounting normative
literature (e.g., Jagels, 2007; Schmidgall, 2006). With respect to their implica-
tions for capital expenditure decision making, consistent with the rationale
already outlined, occupancy and RevPAR both suffer from no recognition of
capital outlay. If appraised on RevPAR and occupancy, an operator would have
an inducement to rank a $50,000 capital expenditure opportunity that results in
a 2% increase in occupancy and $5 increase in RevPAR behind a $1,000,000
outlay that results in a 3% increase in occupancy and $6 increase in RevPAR.
Although the first option can from
Downloaded bejht.sagepub.com
expectedbytoguestprovide the higher ROI, it yields
on May 10, 2016
Table 4
Management Contract Termination: Incidence and Nature of Operator Performance Thresholds
Eyster (1988) United States 77 36% of chain operators GOP Actual GOP is compared against the
(58 contracts) that have no equity invested (most common) performance of other competitive
and international 18% of chain operators properties
(19 contracts) with equity invested Cash flow after Suitability of measure determined with
14% of international debt service reference to a comparison of projected
operators (common) and actual inflation rates for the period
under consideration
Cash flow after Suitability of measure determined with
debt service and reference to a comparison of projected
return on equity and actual inflation rates for the period
(less common) under consideration
Occupancy Actual occupancy percentage is
percentage compared against the performance of
(seldom) other competitive properties
Eyster (1993) United States 17 37% of chain operators GOP Agreed-on 3- to 5-year annual budgeted
32% independent operators projections of GOP compared with
491
(continued)
Table 4 (continued)
492
Proportion of Hotels Identifying
Geographic Contracts Criteria For Management Performance
Author Focus Analyzed Contract Termination Measure Performance Threshold Requirement
(continued)
Table 4 (continued)
Haast, Dickson, and Asia-Pacific 28 57.1% GOP Agreed-on annual projections of budgeted
Braham (2005) (Australia (most common) GOP compared with actual GOP each
included) year (actual GOP must typically be 80%
or more of budgeted GOP for
performance to be deemed satisfactory)
RevPAR RevPAR is typically relative to a
(less common) competitive set, market, or even a
particular property, which is often a hotel
managed by the same hotel operator
Europe 29 50+% GOP Agreed-on annual projections of budgeted
GOP compared with actual GOP each
year (actual GOP must typically be 80%
or more of budgeted GOP for
performance to be deemed satisfactory)
RevPAR RevPAR is typically relative to the
average of a competitive set
Americas 28 92.9% RevPAR No further details given
493
Note: GOP = gross operating profit; NOP = net operating profit; RevPAR = revenue per available room.
494 JOURNAL OF HOSPITALITY & TOURISM RESEARCH
the lower occupancy and RevPAR. It should also be noted that emphasis on
occupancy and RevPAR performance measures would likely raise the priority
attached by an operator to accommodation-related capital expenditures relative
to expenditure on other hotel activities such as restaurant and bar.
Where an operator is performing poorly, the only other termination option
for an owner is to invoke termination without a cause provisions. Prior research
findings concerned with appraising the incidence and nature of such provisions
are summarized in Table 5, which highlights that around one third of manage-
ment contracts include termination without a cause provisions. Consistent with
the challenge of activating operator performance measures, termination without
a cause provisions are becoming increasingly difficult to invoke because of their
extensive qualifications and caveats (Dickson, 2007). This underscores the
importance of ensuring that a negotiated management contract is conducive to
a high degree of owner–operator goal alignment. Management contract termina-
tion impediments in combination with deficient owner–operator goal congru-
ence signify a high propensity for protracted hotel operational decision making
that is inconsistent with owner interests.
(continued)
495
496
Table 5 (continued)
It can be seen from these formulae that ROI constitutes a ratio, not an absolute
dollar amount. It has become commonplace for normative expositions of ROI
in the management accounting literature (e.g., Anthony & Govindarajan, 2007;
Horngren, Datar, & Foster, 2007) and the hospitality management accounting
literature (e.g., Guilding, 2009) to demonstrate how ROI can be dissected into
two underlying components: profit margin (profit ÷ sales) and sales turnover
(sales ÷ assets). It is evident that there is some convergence between the profit
margin element of ROI and conventional hotel operator incentives, because of
the latter’s emphasis on sales and profit. The element that is completely lacking,
however, is the incentive to maximize sales for a given level of investment, as
conventional operator incentives lack a measure that taps into the investment
construct. RI is calculated as profit minus an imputed charge for capital employed.
The imputed charge is generally linked to the cost of capital (Langfield-Smith
et al., 2003).
The major benefit of ROI is that the agent is discouraged from excessive
investment in assets.7 Further advantages of ROI include the following: (a) it
reflects anything that affects the financial statements; (b) it is easy to calculate,
simple to understand, and is meaningful in an absolute sense; (c) it can be applied
to any unit within an organization responsible for profitability, regardless of the
size or type of the business; and (d) as ROI data is typically available for com-
petitors, it can be used as a basis for comparison (Anthony & Govindarajan,
2007).8 A major disadvantage of ROI is that it can encourage agents to defer
asset replacement and also discourage agents from investing in some capital
projects that are viable from an owner’s perspective, as will be seen below (this
is sometimes referred to as an “underinvestment problem”). A second disadvan-
tage is that managers evaluated on the basis of ROI may be dissuaded from
investing in some positive NPV projects. This is because such projects may
have low levels of profit and ROI in the early years of their useful lives.
Consistent with most other accounting measures, a third disadvantage of ROI is
that it does not represent an economic rate of return on capital, because account-
ing profit excludes many value increases such as land appreciation prior to sale,
as well as intangible asset growth such as increases in brand value.
RI has been widely promoted as a measure that averts some of ROI’s short-
comings (see Anthony & Govindarajan, 2007; Christensen, Feltham, & Wu,
2002; Dutta & Reichelstein, 2002; Langfield-Smith et al., 2003). RI’s improve-
ment over ROI stems from its formula containing an important datum that is
absent from the ROI formula, that is, the organization’s required rate of return
on invested capital (Langfield-Smith et al., 2003).9 Despite the theoretical
strength of RI, Drury, Braund, Osborne, and Tayles (1993) note that surveys
(e.g., Reece & Cool, 1978; Scapens, Sale, & Tikkas, 1982; Skinner, 1990) have
indicated that practitioners show a strong preference for ROI because: (a) as a
ratio, it can be used for comparisons within or between divisions, (b) ROI can
be compared with other organizations or within an organization’s divisions, and
(c) ROI is generally considered a measure of overall profitability and is there-
fore used more by outsiders.
Downloaded from jht.sagepub.com by guest on May 10, 2016
498 JOURNAL OF HOSPITALITY & TOURISM RESEARCH
Table 6
Illustration of the Merit of RI Versus ROI
Hotel A Hotel B
Current scenario
Investment in assets $500,000 $500,000
Operating profit $20,000 $90,000
ROI (Profit ÷ Assets) 4% 18%
RI ((Profit − (Cost of capital × Assets)) −$30,000 $40,000
Additional opportunity
Purchase asset $200,000
Sell asset $180,000
Change in profit +$18,000 −$21,600
ROI associated with asset purchase or sale 9% 12%
ROI subsequent to asset purchase or sale
Assets $700,000 $320,000
Operating profit $38,000 $68,400
New ROI 5.4% 21.4%
RI subsequent to asset purchase or sale
Assets $700,000 $320,000
Operating profit $38,000 $68,400
RI −$32,000 $36,400
managers to maximize profits from the resources that they have at their disposal
and to only invest in additional resources when the investment will produce an
adequate return (Anthony & Govindarajan, 2007). The appendix presents a
simulated exercise that demonstrates how RI represents a performance measure-
ment basis that promotes a higher degree of owner–operator capital expenditure
goal congruency compared with traditional hotel operator fee bases that are tied
to revenue and profit.
It was noted above that finance practice holds that the preferred investment
appraisal criterion is NPV. It is noteworthy, therefore, to recognize that RI,
considered over the long term, approximates to NPV. Using RI to evaluate
management performance can be expected to promote goal congruency, because
the information that is required for NPV and IRR converges (considered over
the long term, accruals-based differences between cash flows used in NPV cal-
culations and profit used in RI calculations disappear). We can thus conclude
that maximizing RI over time approximates to maximizing firm value.
Analysis of hotel management contracts in the United States provides some
support for the view that RI represents a preferred basis for determining hotel
operator remuneration. Eyster’s (1993) study cites examples of contracts where
the basis for the remuneration fee is GOP (or cash flow) adjusted for items such
as debt service and return on equity. Adjusting profit for debt service can be seen
as a “partial RI” measure, for, although it embodies a charge for debt capital, no
charge is made for equity funding. For the 5.9% of contracts examined by
Eyster, where the operator remuneration is based on cash flow after debt service
and return on equity, we have a closer approximation to RI. This is because the
measure involves a charge made for all long-term capital funding (i.e., equity
and debt). Although this signifies the existence of some management contracts
promoting a better alignment of owner–operator capital expenditure interests,
this improved alignment will be largely negated if this type of incentive fee is
combined with a base fee determined by gross revenue (the most common base
fee noted in Table 2). More recent hotel management contract surveys (e.g.,
Barge & Jacobs, 2001; Goddard & Standish-Wilkinson, 2002; Haast et al., 2005;
K. Johnson, 1999; Panvisavas & Taylor, 2006) have failed to identify any incen-
tive fees tied to cash flow after debt service and return on equity.
With respect to the adoption of RI as a generic performance measure,
Balachandran (2006) conducted an analysis of Compustat firms’ RI usage.
Table 7 provides an industry sector classification of Balachandran’s RI adoption
findings. The proportion of firms using RI measures ranged from 34.8% of
durable goods firms to 0% of real estate firms. Considered holistically, these
findings suggest limited application of RI across a range of industrial settings.
Although this study promotes using RI as a basis for determining operator
fees, it should be noted that it is not devoid of shortcomings. RI is a financially
denominated measure that is calculated from accrual accounting numbers.
Performance measures that are based on accounting numbers are widely criti-
cized for instilling a short-termist outlook (Ezzamel, 1992; Ezzamel & Hart,
1989; Rappaport, 1986). In light of this, many commentators suggest combining
Downloaded from jht.sagepub.com by guest on May 10, 2016
500 JOURNAL OF HOSPITALITY & TOURISM RESEARCH
Table 7
RI Adoption by Sector
however. Several studies support Healy’s hypothesis (see Bernard & Skinner,
1996; Dechow, Sloan, & Sweeney, 1995; Holthausen, Larcher, & Sloan, 1995;
J. Jones, 1991; Kaplan, 1985; McNichols & Wilson, 1988; Schipper, 1989).
Research providing conflicting evidence includes DeFond and Park (1997) and
Gaver, Gaver, and Austin (1995).
Although the discussion in this section has been conducted in the context of
seeking improved bases of hotel operator fee determination, it is also pertinent
to identify appropriate performance measure thresholds that can be invoked by
an owner as grounds for contract termination. Based on the rationale outlined,
it would appear to be in owners’ interests to require operators to meet perfor-
mance thresholds stated in terms of ROI or RI.
APPENDIX
Simulation of Operator Management Fees:
Comparison of Traditional Management Fee
Basis With Residual Income Fee Basis
Project A Project B
Based on a typical traditional fee incentive of 3% of gross revenue and 10% of GOP,
we find that the operator would prefer Project B as it would result in an increase in the
operator fee revenue of $56,000 (3% of $800,000 + 10% of $320,000) per annum for the
5 years of Project B’s life. This is more than the $35,000 (3% of $500,000 + 10% of
$200,000) projected incremental fee revenue that would result if Project A were pursued.
On an ROI and RI basis, it can be seen than project A provides the higher return, however.
Project A provides an ROI of 20% ($200,000 ÷ $1,000,000 × 100) per annum, and Project B
provides an ROI of 8% ($320,000 ÷ $4,000,000 × 100) per annum. If the hotel owner imputes
a 10% required rate of return (based on its cost of capital) charge when calculating RI, we see
that Project A has a positive RI of $100,000 ($200,000 (0.1 × $1,000,000)) per annum, and
Project B has a negative RI of $80,000 ($320,000 − (0.1 $4,000,000)) per annum.
If the operator were to be paid an incentive that is set at (say) 40% of RI, pursuit of
Project A would result in an increase in the operator’s fee revenue of $40,000 (40% of
$100,000) per annum and pursuit of Project B would result in a decrease in the operator’s
fee revenue of $32,000 (40% of −$80,000) per annum.
A comparison of the projected ROIs for the two projects and the fact that Project B
fails to satisfy the owner’s 10% required rate of return provides a persuasive case that
the hotel owner would prefer to take Project A. Capital expenditure goal congruency is
promoted if the operator is remunerated based on RI (Project A has the higher RI), but
it is not promoted if the operator is remunerated based on a revenue and profit incentive,
as the operator would have an incentive to promote Project B.
NOTES
REFERENCES
Brooke, J., & Denton, G. A. (2007). CapEx 2007: A study of capital expenditures in the
hotel industry. Naples, FL: International Society of Hospitality Consultants.
Butler, R., Davis, L., Pike, R., & Sharp, J. (1993). Strategic investment decisions:
Theory, practice, and process. London, England: Routledge.
Chan, K. T., Lee, R. H. K., & Burnett, J. (2001). Maintenance performance: A case study
of hospitality engineering systems. Facilities, 19, 494-504.
Chen, S., & Dodd, J. L. (1997). Usefulness of operating income, residual income, and
EVA: A value-relevance perspective (Working Paper). Rochester, NY: Social
Science Research Network.
Christensen, P., Feltham, G. A., & Wu, M. (2002). Cost of capital in residual income for
performance evaluation. Accounting Review, 77(1), 1-23.
Collier, P., & Gregory, A. (1995a). Investment appraisal in service industries: A field study
analysis of the U.K. hotels sector. Management Accounting Research, 6(1), 33-57.
Collier, P., & Gregory, A. (1995b). The practice of management accounting in hotel
groups. In P. J. Harris (Ed.), Accounting and finance for the international hospitality
industry (pp. 137-160). Oxford, England: Butterworth-Heinemann.
Condon, D. T., Blaney, T., & Harrington, D. J. (1996). How to finance capital expendi-
tures: Capital spending decisions are a key to a club’s future. The Bottom Line,
11(7), 6-7.
Contractor, F. J., & Kundu, S. K. (1998). Modal choice in a world of alliances: Analyzing
organizational forms in the international hotel sector. Journal of International
Business Studies, 29(2), 325-358.
Corgel, J. (2007). Technological change as reflected in hotel property prices. Journal of
Real Estate Finance and Economics, 34, 257-279.
Cotter, J. F., & Zenner, M. (1994). How managerial wealth affects the tender offer process.
Journal of Financial Economics, 35, 63-97.
Crandell, C., Dickinson, K., & Kanter, G. I. (2004). Negotiating the hotel management
contract. In P. Beals & G. A. Denton (Eds.), Hotel asset management: Principles &
Practices (pp. 87-106). East Lansing, MI: University of Denver and American Hotel
& Lodging Educational Institute.
Damitio, J. W., & Schmidgall, R. S. (2002). Capital budgeting of major lodging chains.
FIU Hospitality Review, Spring, 34-41.
Dave, U. (1984). US multinational involvement in the international hotel sector—An
analysis. Services Industries Journal, 4, 48-63.
Dechow, P. M., & Sloan, R. G. (1991). Executive incentives and the horizon problem:
An empirical investigation. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 14, 51-89.
Dechow, P. M., Sloan, R. G., & Sweeney, A. P. (1995). Detecting earnings management.
Accounting Review, April, 193-225.
DeFond, M. L., & Park, C. W. (1997). Smoothing income in anticipation of future earn-
ings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 17, 115-139.
DeFranco, A. (1997). The importance and use of financial forecasting and budgeting at
the department level as perceived by hotel controllers. Hospitality Research Journal,
20(3), 99-110.
Demski, J., & Feltham, G. A. (1978). Economic incentives in budgetary control systems.
Accounting Review, 53, 336-359.
Dev, C. S., Morgan, M. S., & Shoemaker, S. (1995). A positioning analysis of hotel brands—
Based on travel-manager perceptions. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant Administration
Quarterly, 36(6), 48-55.
Dickson, G. (2007). Ten hot management agreement issues in Asia. Hotels, Resorts &
Tourism Newsletter, June, 1-11. Retrieved from http://www.bakernet.com/NR/
rdonlyres/86BE8EF9-2715-4591-8697-7E25966CFD58/42504/HRTNewsletter
July2007.pdf
Dickson, G., & Williams, R. (2006). What’s hot and what’s not with management agree-
ments? Hotels, Resorts & Tourism Newsletter, April, 1-10. Retrieved from http://
www.bakernet.com/NR/rdonlyres/85BD956A-42E9-40E1-A5BA
-93A3F9E72D65/39800/SYDDMS388712v1HRT_Newsletter_April_2005final.pdf
Dimou, I., Chen, J., & Archer, S. (2003). The choice between management contracts and
franchise agreements in the corporate development of international hotel firms.
Journal of Marketing Channels, 10, 33-39.
Drury, C., Braund, S., Osborne, P., & Tayles, M. (1993). A survey of management
accounting practices in UK manufacturing companies. London, England: Certified
Accountants Educational Trust.
Dunning, J. H., & McQween, M. (1981). The eclectic theory of multinational production:
A case study of the international hotel industry. Managerial and Decision Economics,
2, 197-210.
Dutta, S. (2003). Capital budgeting and managerial compensation: Incentive and retention
effects. Accounting Review, 78(1), 71-94.
Dutta, S., & Reichelstein, S. (2002). Controlling investment decisions: Depreciation and
capital charges. Review of Accounting Studies, 7, 253-281.
Eder, R. W., & Umbreit, W. T. (1987). Measures of management effectiveness in the
hotel industry. Hospitality Education and Research Journal, 13, 333-341.
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1988). Agency and institutional explanations of compensation in
retail sales. Academy of Management Journal, 31, 488-511.
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management
Review, 14, 57-74.
Eyster, J. J. (1988). The negotiation and administration of hotel and restaurant manage-
ment contracts (3rd ed.). Ithaca, NY: School of Hotel Administration, Cornell
University.
Eyster, J. J. (1993). The revolution in domestic hotel management contracts. Cornell
Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 34(1), 16-26.
Eyster, J. J. (1997). Hotel management contracts in the U.S.: Twelve areas of concern.
Cornell Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 38(3), 21-34.
Eyster, J. J., & Geller, A. N. (1981). The capital investment decision: Techniques used
in the hospitality industry. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly,
22(1), 69-73.
Ezzamel, M. (1992). Business unit and divisional performance measurement. London,
England: Academic Press.
Ezzamel, M., & Hart, M. (1989). Advanced management accounting: An organisational
emphasis. London, England: Cassell.
Feldman, D. S. (1995). Asset management: Here to stay. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant
Administration Quarterly, 36(5), 36-52.
Ferguson, D. H., & Selling, T. I. (1985). Probability analysis: A system for making
better decisions. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 26(2),
35-43.
Field, H. M. (1995). Financial management implications of hotel management contracts:
A UK perspective. In P. J. Harris (Ed.), Accounting and finance for the international
hospitality industry (pp. 261-277). Oxford, England: Butterworth-Heinemann.
Downloaded from jht.sagepub.com by guest on May 10, 2016
508 JOURNAL OF HOSPITALITY & TOURISM RESEARCH
Holthausen, R. W., Larcher, D. F., & Sloan, R. G. (1995). Annual bonus schemes and
the manipulation of earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 19, 29-74.
Horngren, C. T., Datar, S. M., & Foster, G. (2007). Cost accounting: A managerial
emphasis. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Horwath. (2006). Hotel, leisure and tourism—Consulting services brochure. Sydney,
New South Wales, Australia: Horwath Asia Pacific.
Huszagh, S. M., Huszagh, F. W., & McIntyre, F. S. (1992). International franchising in
the context of competitive strategy and the theory of the firm. International Marketing
Review, 9(5), 5-18.
Ingram, P., & Baum, J. (1997). Chain affiliation and the failure of Manhattan hotels,
1898-1980. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42(1), 68-103.
Ittner, C., Larker, D. F., & Rajan, R. (1997). The choice of performance measures in
annual bonus contracts. Accounting Review, 72, 231-255.
Jagels, M. G. (2007). Hospitality management accounting (9th ed.). New York, NY:
John Wiley.
Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency
costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305-360.
Johnson, B. (1987). Discussion of management compensation contracts and merger-
induced abnormal returns. Journal of Accounting Research, 25(Suppl.), 77-84.
Johnson, K. (1999). Hotel management contract terms: Still in flux. Cornell Hotel and
Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 40(2), 34-40.
Johnstone, D. T., & Duni, J. A. (1995). Asset management issues. In L. E. Raleigh &
R. J. Roginsky (Eds.), Hotel investments: Issues & perspectives (pp. 109-124). East
Lansing, MI: American Hotel & Motel Association.
Jones, J. (1991). Earnings management during import relief investigations. Journal of
Accounting Research, 29, 193-228.
Jones, P. (1996). Introduction to hospitality operations. London, England: Cassell.
Jones, T. (1998). UK hotel operators use of budgetary procedures. International Journal
of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 10(3), 96-100.
Kakati, M., & Dhar, U. R. (1991). Investment justification in flexible manufacturing
systems. Engineering Costs and Production Economics, 21, 203-209.
Kaplan, R. S. (1985). Comments on Paul Healy. Journal of Accounting and Economics,
7, 109-113.
Kedia, B. L., Ackerman, D., Bush, D. E., & Justis, R. T. (1994). Determinants of inter-
nationalization of franchising operations by U.S. franchisors. International Marketing
Review, 11(4), 56-68.
Langfield-Smith, K., Thorne, H., & Hilton, R. W. (2003). Management accounting: An
Australian perspective (3rd ed.). Roseville, Australia: McGraw-Hill.
Litteljohn, D. (1991). Towards an economic analysis of trans/multinational hotel compa-
nies. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 4(4), 157-165.
Litteljohn, D., & Beattie, R. (1992). The European hotel industry: Corporate structures
and expansion strategies. Tourism Management, 13, 27-33.
Lynch, B. (2002). Maximising FM’s contribution to shareholder value. Part 1: Can the
capital expenditure process for fixed assets be improved? Journal of Facilities
Management, 1(1), 48-56.
Magee, R. P. (1980). Equilibria in budget participation. Journal of Accounting Research,
18, 551-573.
McNichols, M., & Wilson, G. P. (1988). Evidence of earnings management from the
provision for bad debts. Journal of Accounting Research, 26, 1-31.
Downloaded from jht.sagepub.com by guest on May 10, 2016
510 JOURNAL OF HOSPITALITY & TOURISM RESEARCH
Mellen, S., Nylen, K., & Pastorino, R. (2000). Capex 2000: A study of capital expenditures
in the U.S. hotel industry. Naples, FL: International Society of Hospitality Consultants.
Morishima, M. (1982). Why has Japan succeeded. Cambridge, England: Cambridge
University Press.
Ohlson, J. A. (1995). Earnings, book value, and dividends in security valuation.
Contemporary Accounting Research, 11, 661-687.
P. F. Chang’s China Bistro Inc. (2008). 10K-report. Scottsdale, AZ: Author.
Panvisavas, V., & Taylor, J. S. (2006). The use of management contracts by international
hotel firms in Thailand. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality
Management, 18, 231-245.
Payne, J. D., Carrington-Heath, W., & Gale, L. R. (1999). Comparative financial practice
in the US and Canada: Capital budgeting and risk assessment techniques. Financial
Practice and Education, 9(1), 16-24.
Phillips, P. (2003). Capital expenditure in hotel chains: Implications for corporate struc-
ture. Guildford, England: University of Surrey School of Management.
Prestowitz, C. V. (1988). Trading places. New York, NY: Free Press.
Rainsford, P. (1994). Selecting and monitoring hotel-management companies. Cornell
Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 35(2), 30-35.
Ransley, J., & Ingram, H. (2001). What is “good” hotel design? Facilities, 19, 79-90.
Rappaport, A. (1986). Creating shareholder value. New York, NY: Free Press.
Reece, J. S., & Cool, W. R. (1978). Measuring investment centre performance. Harvard
Business Review, 55, 29-49.
Reichardt, H. J., & Lennhoff, D. C. (2003). Hotel asset allocation: Separating the tan-
gible personality. Assessment Journal, 10(1), 25-32.
Rushmore, S. (2002). Hotel investments handbook. Retrieved from http://www.hospitali-
tynet.org/news/4021216.search?query=chapter+20+hotel+management+contracts+pdf
Sangree, D. J., & Hathaway, P. P. (1996). Trends in hotel management contracts. Cornell
Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 37(5), 26-38.
Saunders, J., & Wong, V. (1985). In search of excellence in the UK. Journal of
Marketing Management, 1(2), 119-137.
Scapens, R. W., Sale, J. T., & Tikkas, P. A. (1982). Financial control of divisional
capital investment. London, England: Institute of Cost and Management Accountants.
Schiff, C. (2006). What’s next for better decision-making? DM Review, 16(12), 30-32.
Schipper, K. (1989). Commentary on earnings management. Accounting Horizons, 13,
91-102.
Schlup, R. (2004). Hotel management agreements: Balancing the interests of owners and
operators. Journal of Retail & Leisure Property, 3, 331-343.
Schmidgall, R. S. (2006). Hospitality industry managerial accounting (6th ed.). East
Lansing, MI: Educational Institute of the American Hotel & Motel Association.
Schmidgall, R. S., & Damitio, J. (1990). Current capital budgeting practices of major
lodging chains. Real Estate Review, 20(3), 40-45.
Schmidgall, R. S., Damitio, J. W., & Singh, A. J. (1997). What is capital expenditure?
How lodging-industry financial executives decide. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant
Administration Quarterly, 38(4), 28-33.
Schmidgall, R. S., & Ninemeier, J. D. (1987). Budgeting in hotel chains: Coordination
and control. Cornell Hotel and Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 28(1), 78-84.
Shane, S. A. (1996). Hybrid organizational arrangements and their implications for firm
growth and survival: A study of new franchisors. Academy of Management Journal,
39, 216-234.
Downloaded from jht.sagepub.com by guest on May 10, 2016
Turner, Guilding / HOTEL MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS AND DEFICIENCIES 511
Skinner, R. C. (1990). The role of profitability in divisional decision making and perfor-
mance. Accounting and Business Research, 20, 135-141.
Slagmulder, R., & Bruggeman, W. (1992). Justification of strategic investments in flexible
manufacturing technology. Integrated Manufacturing Systems, 3(3), 4-15.
Slattery, P. (1992). Unaffiliated hotels in the UK. Travel and Tourism Analyst, 1, 90-102.
Slattery, P. (1996). International development of hotel chains. In R. Kotas, R. Teare,
J. Logie, C. Jayawardena, & J. Bowen (Eds.), The international hospitality business
(pp. 30-35). London, England: Cassell.
Smith, C. W., & Watts, R. L. (1982). Incentive and tax effects of executive compensation
plans. Australian Journal of Management, 7, 139-157.
Smith Travel Research. (2003). Property and portfolio research. Hotel & Motel Management,
218(7), 24.
Tsuruni, Y. (1984). Multinational management: Business strategy and government policy.
Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Press.
Turner, M. J., & Guilding, C. (2010). Accounting for the furniture, fittings & equipment
reserve in hotels. Accounting and Finance, Published Online First: March 12, 2010.
DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-629X.2010.00347.x
Van Wolferen, K. (1989). The enigma of Japanese power. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Walker, G., & Weber, D. (1984). A transaction cost approach to make or buy decisions.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 29, 373-391.
Wallace, J. (1997). Adopting residual income-based compensation plans: Do you get
what you pay for? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24, 275-300.
Walsh, J. P., & Seward, J. K. (1990). On the efficiency of internal and external corporate
control mechanisms. Academy of Management Review, 15, 421-458.