Space-Time Budgets and Activity Studies in Urban Geography and Planning T
Space-Time Budgets and Activity Studies in Urban Geography and Planning T
J Anderson
Department of Planning and Urban Design, Architectural Association School of Architecture, London
Received 17 May 1971
Abstract. This paper attempts to provide a general perspective on the potentialities and limitations
of research into individual activity patterns. The most common types of activity study and data-
collecting device are briefly described, and problems of data collection and analysis are outlined.
The main focus is on the value of 'space-time budgets' in household surveys, assessed with respect
to two contrasting aims: (1) deriving 'behavioural' postulates on which geographic theories of
spatial structure might be based, and (2) planning spatial structures to suit the behaviour patterns
and aspirations of different types of individuals and households. Activities occur in a 'space-time'
continuum', and there are temporal regularities inherent in spatial patterns. It is argued that
studying activity patterns in terms of 'space-time locations' can throw light on pressing socio-
spatial problems.
1 Introduction
A time-budget is a systematic record of a person's use of time over a given period.
It describes the sequence, timing, and duration of the person's activities, typically for
a short period ranging from a single day to a week. As a logical extension of this
type of record, a space-time budget includes the spatial coordinates of activity
locations.
Studies using these devices do not constitute a unified research field. The purposes
of such studies vary widely. In the English-speaking world, time-budgets have been
used mainly in market-research for the mass media and in non-spatial sociological
studies of life-styles and leisure (Converse, 1968). Mead's (1958) paper on seasonal
variations in rural life in Finland was one of very few instances of time-budgets being
used in geographic research prior to 1960. More recently, however, work by Meier
(1962), Chapin (1965), and Hagerstrand (1970a) has given greater impetus to
spatially-oriented research on daily activity patterns. Space-time as well as time-
budgets are now being used, and mainly in urban rather than in rural studies. The
use of a related device, the travel diary, by Marble (1959, 1967, 1970) and by
Nystuen (1959, 1967) also contributed to the growing interest in relationships
between uses of space and time.
There is considerable variation in the underlying methodology and purposes
associated with the use of activity records, even within the field of urban spatial
research. Meier, for instance, sees their potential, in practical rather than theoretical
terms, as a means of gauging the general quality of urban life and overall efficiency of
urban systems. Chapin, taking a more microscopic approach, sees activities as the
outcome of choices which reflect people's values, while Hagerstrand, in contrast,
emphasizes the constraints imposed by urban environments. He is mainly concerned
with how people's activities are 'canalized' through urban space-time, for example,
with how city size affects daily patterns of life. As significant as their differences,
however, is the fact that for all three, urban planning is a central consideration.
t This paper was presented in a shortened version at the Institute of British Geographers' meeting
on 'Space-Time Budgets in Urban Analysis', at Cambridge University, 7 November 1970, and
published as Discussion Paper 40 in the London.School of Economics Geography Department series.
354 J Anderson
Policy considerations are also central to the transportation economists' work on the
value of time, and trade-offs between alternative travel modes (for example, Foster
and Beesley, 1963; Quarmby, 1967); in order that transport investment and pricing
can be related to travel-/7rae savings, time is evaluated in monetary terms.
This cash-conversion procedure is perhaps peripheral to more comprehensive studies
of the spatial organization of diverse activities and activity-sequences. Time is itself a
quantitative measure highly appropriate in studying social organization. As a
pervasively awkward scarcity, it is perhaps the main rival to money in our society
(Moore, 1963); in many situations 'time is money'. It is not simply a quantity to be
'spent', 'saved', or 'wasted'; we also have to 'keep time', meet deadlines, and order
our activities in particular sequences, simultaneously taking account of the amounts of
time required to get from place to place. Time is a 'one-directional dimension' to
which we refer in organizing our activities, and it can serve as a scale on which most,
if not all, activities and their interrelationships can, in principle, be measured. It can
be used to create typologies of activities, people, institutions, and environments,
which are directly appropriate to studies of accessibility and spatial behaviour
(Carlstein et al., 1968). For comparative purposes, time (unlike money) has the
advantage that everyone who remains alive during a given period has exactly the same
amount to 'allocate'. This is not to disparage monetary units (either for spending or
in studying behaviour)—lack of cash is a major constraint on time allocation—rather
it is to suggest that temporal units have considerable potential in spatial studies,
without being converted to cash terms. Indeed, economists have recently begun to
consider all time (non-work as well as work hours) as a 'scarce resource' (Burenstam
Linder, 1970); and attempts by them (for example, Burenstam Linder, 1970;
Becker, 1965) to develop a general theory of time allocation may eventually prove
useful in constructing deductive spatial theories. The concept of trade-offs between
time uses is, at least potentially, very relevant to spatial study. However (as is argued
in Sections 5 to 7 below) while being alive to such theoretical implications, it is
perhaps more realistic at present to consider time—and the space-time budget device
—as primarily of use in descriptive or 'inductive' studies of spatial behaviour.
When a device or technique is the focus of attention there may be difficulties in
going beyond purely technical considerations. Formidable problems of data collection
and analysis are the most immediately obvious common element in time-budget
studies. However, these problems will be discussed only in general terms (Section 4),
and the main types of activity study and the most usual devices for collecting data
will merely be outlined (Section 3). The emphasis is on the value of activity studies
in human geography, the potential of space-time budgets in such studies, and the
relevance of this type of study to urban planning (Sections 2, 4 to 8).
programming, but the focus has most frequently been on general leisure and life-
styles (for example, Lundberg et al., 1934; Sorokin and Berger, 1939), an emphasis
continued in the present UNESCO sponsored cross-cultural time-budget study
involving over ten countries (Szalai, 1966; Converse, 1968). Much of this work
gives, at best, only partial treatment to spatial locations (see Anderson, 1970).
The French sociologist, Chombart de Lauwe (1960), has used time-budgets to show
the effects of locations and differential journeys to work on family life and welfare,
and in architecture, activity studies have provided a basis for designing interior
layouts. In anthropology, time allocations have served as indicators of cultural
change, and production time has been taken as a measure of cost-value in non-
monetary economies (Firth, 1967). In 'mainstream' economics it is only recently
that all time (that is, 'free' or non-work as well as work-time) has been considered
explicitly as a scarce resource; according to Burenstam Linder (1970), economists
have traditionally made the implicit assumption that consumption, in contrast to
production, was atemporal, whereas, in fact, like production, it has to be
accommodated in a time-table. In modern production-oriented 'consumer society'
temporal scarcity seems to be increasing (see Anderson, 1971).
Modern citizens organise their daily lives by reference to clock and calendar, and
in accordance with deadlines over which they often have little control. Conceptions
of time vary for different activities and social groups (Gurvich, 1964); and Quarmby
(1967) in discussing the monetary value of travel time suggests that waiting time may
have to be costed at three times the rate for time spent actually moving. In peasant
societies, personal time indicators (for example, the 'biological clocks' of hunger and
tiredness) may have more relevance than impersonal clock-time; in Greek peasant
tradition "to hurry is to forfeit freedom", the peasant is "intent on passing the time,
not on budgeting it" (Mead, 1954). We too are guided by 'biological clocks', but
these are frequently overruled by mechanical clock-time (and not without danger to
health and welfare—see Wilkins, 1968). If the variable natures of time are taken into
account, it loses some of its convenience for activity-study purposes; considering its
paramount importance in industrial societies, clock-time may provide an adequately
'objective' standard. Mumford (1934) chose the clock rather than the steam-engine
as the 'key machine' of the industrial age. The increased specialisations, spatial
separations (for example, of home and work) and interdependencies, which are a
general feature of industrial growth, require more precise time scheduling and tend to
reduce flexibility in time allocation (Anderson, 1961). Space, distance, and
accessibilities acquire new meanings as the importance attached to time increases.
Human behaviour, although highly variable, does display some marked temporal
regularities, because of physiological, physical and social constraints. Activities occur
in a space-time continuum: there are temporal regularities inherent in spatial
regularities, and temporal r h y t h m s obviously vary over space. The c o m m o n practice
in geography of collapsing the time dimension may simplify spatial analysis, but in so
doing we may ignore what Nystuen (1963) has called 'space-time tensions': "When
time is short, space is conserved. When an activity has a deadline associated with it,
congestion in space is likely." Urban rush-hour congestion is ample proof of the
latter point; and distance minimization can often be expressed realistically as time
minimization. For the individual, residential location, spatial mobility, accessibility
levels, and time-use patterns form a complicated tangle of interrelationships. If
geographers are to untangle some of these, without unduly distorting them,
questionnaire surveys combined with activity records seem essential (see Section 7
below).
356 J Anderson
activities which occur irregularly or follow a longer cycle than the activity record
period, although seasonal variability presents difficulties. The willingness of
respondents to record activities falls off fairly rapidly, whether or not payment is
involved—about three days seems a critical level for relatively comprehensive diary
records. However, a short activity record period facilitates comprehensive treatment
of important daily and weekly rhythms.
Research design and sampling are particularly important because of these problems.
The activity classifications in sociological studies are typically 3-digit and very
detailed. For spatial studies a simpler and more flexible classification system may be
more suitable—for example, the first digit might specify the 'station' (home,
workplace, shop, other person's home, and so on) while the second (and third)
describes the nature of the activity (working, purchasing, travelling, and so on);
behaviour can be analysed in terms of each component separately and in terms of the
whole classification system. Recorded addresses must be translated (laboriously) into
suitable locational terms, such as a grid system reference, perhaps with a variable grid
size depending on the use made of different parts of the overall activity space.
Standardized 'time blocks' are also problematical, especially at the recording stage
where they are likely to impose extraneous 'structure' on the time pattern of
activities.
Space-time activity patterns may be influenced by a wide range of factors, some of
which (for example, age, occupation, household composition, or residential location)
must a priori initially be taken as particularly important and used in sample
stratification. To ascertain the influence of one variable, such as home location, a
whole range of other factors should ideally by held constant. Thus households who
intend moving to new residences might be surveyed before and after they move
(Blight, 1970) although observed activity changes might be due partly to additional
factors, for example, premeditated choice, decreased knowledge of the 'environment',
or both (see Section 8 below). This implies an important point: to be really useful,
activity analysis should be linked to other types of analysis (such as attitudes to
environment and accessibilities) and this demands careful integration of diary and
questionnaire designs.
Problems of analysis are probably solved less easily than those involved in data
collection (Hurst, 1969). They can perhaps be clarified by distinguishing between a
substance language and a space-time language. The latter—a locational coordinate
system of four dimensions (or three, if the vertical axis of space is ignored)—is
associated with the so-called 'physicalists', who advocated the unification of science
through use of the language of physics (Neurath, 1944). The non-spatial substance
language describes characteristics or properties (occupations, types of activities) of
respondents or other individuals, while their locations or positions are described in
terms of a space-time language. Writing in a non-geographical context, Wilson (1955)
points out that individuation requires the use of space-time coordinates; if
individuals are defined only in substance terms they "lose part of their essence".
This part is particularly essential to geographic study. Harvey (1969, p.217) writes
that the ordering of geographic data "amounts to the difficult logical problem of
working with two different language systems in the same context"—a problem
increased by the fact that geographers usually deal with both discrete and continuous
data. He cites regionalization as a case where different languages have been mixed up
to produce confusion and controversy.
The problem of using both languages together lies at the heart of space-time
budget analysis. The substance language is itself multi-dimensional (for example,
different types of respondents, activities, non-locational constraints, attitudes), and
adding the temporal dimension to the two spatial dimensions introduces further
358 J Anderson
and biological analogy. Daily life patterns as well as firms and institutions may be
studied in terms of linkages, systems, and organization (Hagerstrand, 1968). Ecology
and, more recently, ethology are other sources of inspiration. Baker (1969), Eyles
(1970), and others have related concepts of animal behaviour, such as territoriality,
to human geography. However, within geography there has been relatively little
testing of such analogies, and hence there is considerable scope for divergent opinions.
[For example, Doherty's (1969) countering of Webber's (1964) suggestion that
territoriality is important for the working class but not for the more mobile
'intellectual elites'; the more mobile may have strong attachments to particular
spaces, that is, to a spatially discontinuous territory.] As far as human behaviour is
concerned, ethological analogies have been most fruitful in small group ecology on a
very limited spatial scale, for example, Sommer's (1969) study of behaviour inside
rooms and its implications for better interior design. Analogous leaps from this scale, or
direct from animal behaviour, to the spatial scale of the neighbourhood or city can be
dangerously misleading. Calhoun's famous rats and mice do not actually tell us
anything about high-density urban living, though their behaviour might suggest
fruitful lines for empirical research into human behaviour (see Calhoun, 1963).
Spatial scale is an important factor in the relative success of ethologically inspired
ecology studies of small-groups. Human behaviour can be directly observed for
continuous periods, and room environments can be experimentally controlled.
[Anthropologists have also used direct observation, but again only for small g r o u p s -
see, Lewis (1959).] For behavioural processes at the neighbourhood or city scales, in
which geographers are more interested, direct and continuous observation is usually
impractical, if not impossible. It has been used by Carlstein et al (1968) to construct
peoples' activity patterns for part of a day, but the study area was a small village and
a well-organized team of observers was required. It was used in a small research
project in Notting Hill, London, but the focus was on the use made of streets at
particular times of the day and week, and information on those observed was lacking
(Arias and Diaz, 1970).
The main quality of space-time diaries is perhaps that they record behaviour
patterns which are not directly observable because of their spatial and temporal
extent. Equally important is the fact that the identity of individuals over time is
preserved—they are not 'commuters' or 'shoppers', or 'leisure-seekers' in isolation
from their other roles. While particular activities may be singled out for analysis, they
can be treated in the context of the respondents' time and space uses throughout the
record period. In a questionnaire study of over 500 households, Clarke (1968) found
that less than half his sample went to the nearest available shops to their home. He
concluded that regression models were not very helpful in explaining consumer
behaviour because of multi-purpose trips and because people visit shops from bases
other than their place of residence. Space-time budgets provide detailed information
on this type of activity organization; they provide an overall behaviour context
within which particular activities can be viewed realistically.
Nystuen (1963) identifies distance, direction, and connection as the three
'fundamental spatial concepts'. Using space-time budgets, distance can readily be
expressed in terms of time, which is often the way people perceive urban distances,
and connection can be given more comprehensive treatment than is perhaps usual in
geography. Haggett (1968) has labelled this emphasis in the study of cities as contact
structures', the emphasis has shifted from distance to contacts, from Euclidean
geometry to graph theory and topology; there has been increased interest in
discontinuous and anisotropic properties of urban space (as measured in terms of
time, costs, or perceptions), and a corresponding dissatisfaction with the assumptions
of classical location theory. It seems highly debatable, however, whether behavioural
360 J Anderson
geography, and in particular the use of space-time budgets, can directly contribute to
improving location theory—as opposed to underlining its already obvious
shortcomings.
structure, for historical, institutional, and other reasons, is rarely a direct response to
the types of activity patterns currently displayed by urban residents. Nor, unless we
disregard significant political and economic forces, can it be argued that urban
structures are 'self-adjusting' and in the long run achieve 'equilibrium' with respect to
the activity patterns and preferences of urban households. As Keynes said, "In the
long run we are all dead"; and equilibrium theories (see Robinson, 1964, pp.65-80)
have severe limitations where locational changes through time are concerned,
particularly so if we agree with Harvey (1971) that modern cities are in a continuous
condition of 'differential ^equilibrium' (see below). Making urban structure more
responsive to the activity patterns of urban residents should indeed be one of the
fundamental and continuing tasks of planning. Therefore, rather than emphasize
their formative influence on spatial structure, it may be more useful to study how
activity patterns are themselves shaped by existing environments. According to
Meier (1962), time-budgets will not 'make or break' existing urban theories, but they
are likely to be increasingly useful in helping "to redress certain market value biases"
in urban decision-making.
mobile, and narrower for the poor, the old, those with young children, those without
a car, and so on. The 'options' in many situations are few (especially for the latter
group) or they may be reduced to 'Hobson's choice'.
Constraints are implicit in 'choice', but, depending on the relative emphasis given to
'positive' and 'negative' determinants (see Section 4 above), we may make a crude
distinction between 'choice' and 'constraint' oriented approaches to behaviour (Pahl,
1970). If psychological motivations of spatial behaviour (such as the 'rules' of
spatial choice, see Section 6 above) are sought, observed behaviour must be seen in
terms of choices between alternative courses of action. However, there is the danger
that important constraints may be underestimated or ignored, at least in the more
extreme forms of 'choice' approach. Observed behaviour can be thought of as
reflecting the actors' values and motivations, but it also reflects the constraints of
environment and personal circumstances. If highly constrained situations are not
recognized as such, observed behaviour may be interpreted misleadingly as what
people 'choose' rather than 'are forced' to do. With the prevailing emphasis on
'choice', situations where actors do not have effective choice may be neglected (for
example, the public housing sector in residential location and mobility studies, and
obligatory as opposed to leisure activities in time-budget studies); or, in the absence
of effective choice, people may be asked to decide between hypothetical alternatives
which in reality they have little hope of achieving.
The less common preoccupation with 'negative' determinants is exemplified in the
similar constraint orientations adopted by Pahl (1970) and Hagerstrand (1970a). In
attempting to redefine urban sociology, Pahl advocates studying "the pattern of
spatial and social constraints which operates differentially in given localities" and
which fundamentally affects people's 'life chances'—a framework with implications
for at least a partial re focusing of social geography. His argument is basically that
there are fundamental spatial (time, cost, distance) and social constraints on access to
scarce urban resources and facilities. The social constraints reflect the distribution of
wealth and power in society, they include bureaucratic rules and procedures, and the
actions of 'social gatekeepers' (such as local government officials, landlords,
employers) who help regulate the quality and accessibility of opportunities (for
example, education, employment, housing). Conflicts of interest in this socio-spatial
system are inevitable, and the greater the scarcity of valued opportunities the greater
the conflict. Pahl sees populations limited in their access to facilities as 'dependant
variables', while the 'gatekeepers' are the 'independant variables'. Noting that the
current emphasis on 'diversity and choice' in physical planning implies that access to
facilities is an 'independant' variable, in contrast to being, in his opinion, dependant
on allocation by 'gatekeepers', he suggests that there are ideological differences
underlying the variation between choice and constraint orientations (for example,
differing attitudes to 'free market' mechanisms).
The interrelationships between space and time uses have perhaps been worked out
most clearly by Hagerstrand and his colleagues (Carlstein et al, 1968). Influenced by
the 'physicalists', they focus on what Hagerstrand calls "the space-time mechanics of
constraints". Three interacting groups are identified: (1) capability constraints
include physiological regulators (such as sleep and age), and ability to move around in
physical space; (2) coupling constraints, operating within the first set of constraints,
include activity commitments, and the need for timing and synchronizing activities in
space; and (3) authority constraints refer to limitations and control of access—they
occur at different levels to produce hierarchies of 'space-time domains' (for example,
immigration control, domicile requirements, legal shop opening hours, and parking
restrictions). Particular space-time environments in the form of detailed computer
models, are evaluated on this conceptual basis (Hagerstrand, 1970a, 1970b) for the
364 J Anderson
8 Conclusions
Space-time budgets provide a comprehensive description of activity routines which are
not directly observable because of their spatial and temporal extent. Although the
recorded period is usually of necessity short, fundamental daily and weekly activity
rhythms can be studied, and people's identity over time (during the recorded period)
is preserved. The organization of their activity patterns can be treated as a 'system',
with explicit recognition of the fact that particular activities effect and constrain each
other, while the institutions to which people belong (such as households) and with
which they interact (shops, schools, recreation places) can be treated in a similar way.
Thus a particular type of activity, for example, shopping, might be analysed in the
context of the overall space and time uses of the shoppers and their households in
relation to shop locations and business-hours.
A set of activity records provides a wealth of data which may be used for a variety
of purposes. They are expensive to collect, however, and because of this, collection
might best be undertaken by public authorities and large planning agencies (as, for
example, in Hungary). They are also difficult to analyse adequately. In particular,
obtaining adequate summary measures of a person's overall space-time behaviour
remains a major problem. Faced with a wealth of information on diverse activities,
their attributes, and space-time locations, the usual procedure has been to abstract
from the data-set, collapse the temporal or the spatial dimensions, and carry out one
or more partial analyses. In this respect, Hagerstrand's computer modelling of space-
time environments is an outstanding exception. The analysis of space-time uses,
albeit partial analysis, in order to be most useful, should ideally be linked (via
questionnaire and other data) to the study of less tangible 'covert' behaviour (for
example, environment perception, attitudes, motives), and/or to the analysis of
environmental constraints (socio-economic and spatial accessibilities). Studies of the
Space-time budgets and activity studies 365
Burton, T. L., Noad, P. A., 1968, Recreation Research Methods: A Review of Recent Studies,
Centre for Urban and Regional Studies, Occasional Paper 3, University of Birmingham, England.
Calhoun, J. B., 1963, "Population density and social pathology", in The Urban Condition,
Ed. L. Duhl (Basic Books, New York).
Carlstein, T., Lenntorp, B., Martensson, S., 1968, "Individers dygnsbanor i nagra hushallstyper",
Urbaniserings Processen, 17, Department of Geography, University of Lund, Lund, Sweden.
Chapin, F. S., 1965, Urban Land Use Planning (University of Illinois Press, Urbana).
Chapin, F. S., 1968, "Activity systems and urban structure: a working schema", Journal of the
American Institute of Planners, 34, 11-18.
Chapin, F. S., Hightower, H. C , 1965, "Household activity patterns and land use", Journal of the
American Institute of Planners, 31, 222-231.
Chapin, F. S., Hightower, H. C , 1966, "Household activity systems—a pilot investigation"
(University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill).
Chapin, F. S., Logan, T. H., 1969, "Patterns of time and space use", in The Quality of the Urban
Environment, Ed. H. S. Perloff (Resources for the Future, Inc., Washington, D.C.).
Chombart de Lauwe, P. H., 1960, Famille et Habitation, Volume 2, Centre National de la Recherche
Scientifique, Paris.
Chombart de Lauwe, P. H., 1963, "The social sciences, urbanism and planning", International
Journal of Comparative Sociology, 4, 19-30.
Clarke, W. A. V., 1968, "Consumer travel patterns and the concept of range", Annals of the
Association of American Geographers, 58, 386-396.
Converse, P. E., 1968, "Time budgets", in International Encylopedia of Social Science (Macmillan,
New York).
Cox, K. R., Golledge, R. G. (Eds.), 1969, "Behavioural models in geography", in Behavioural
Problems in Geography, Studies in Geography, 17, pp.1-13, Northwestern University.
Cullen, I., 1970, "Algorithmic approaches to the recognition of activity patterns", Seminar Paper 19,
Joint Unit for Planning Research, University of London.
Curry, L., 1967a, "Quantitative geography, 1967", Canadian Geographer, 11, 265-279.
Curry, L., 1967b, "Central places in the random spatial economy", Journal of Regional Science,
7 (Supplement), 217-238.
Darke, R., Darke, Jane, 1969, "Suburban housing estates: social composition and characteristics",
CES-WP-40, Centre for Environmental Studies, London.
Doherty, J. M., 1969, "Developments in behavioural geography", London School of Economics and
Political Science, Graduate Discussion Paper 35, London.
Engels, F., 1892, The Condition of the Working-class in England (1844) (Panther, London).
Eyles, J., 1970, "Space, territory and conflict", Geographical Paper 1, University of Reading,
Reading, England.
Firth, R. (Ed.), 1967, "Themes in economic anthropology", Association of Social Anthropologists
Monograph, London.
Foster, C. D., Beesley, M. E., 1963, "Estimating the social benefit of constructing an underground
railway in London", Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A, 126, 46-92.
Gans, H. J., 1967, The Levittowners: Anatomy of Suburbia (Pantheon, New York).
Gould, P. R., 1969, "Methodological developments since the fifties", in Progress in Geography, 1,
Eds. C. Board, R. J. Chorley, P. Haggett, D. R. Stoddart (Edward Arnold, London).
Gurvich, G., 1964, The Spectrum of Social Time (Reidel, Dordrecht).
Hagerstrand, T., 1968, "Methods and new techniques in current urban and regional research in
Sweden", Plan, 22, 3 - 1 1 .
Hagerstrand, T., 1970a, "What about people in regional science?", Presidential Address European
Regional Science Association, Copenhagen, August; Papers of the Regional Science Association,
24,7-21.
Hagerstrand, T., 1970b, "Tidsanvandning och omgivningsstrukture", in Urbaniseringen i Sverige:
en geografish samhallsanalys, Stockholm.
Haggett, P., 1968, "The spatial structure of city regions", Social Science Research Council/Centre
for Environmental Studies Joint Conference, "The future of the city region", CES-WP-6,
Volume 2, Centre for Environmental Studies, London.
Harvey, D., 1969, Explanation in Geography (Edward Arnold, London).
Harvey, D., 1971, "Social processes, spatial form and the redistribution of reaLincome in an urban
system", in Proceedings, 22nd Colston Research Society Symposium, Eds. M.Chisholm, A. Frey,
P. Haggett (Butterworths, London).
Hemmens, G. C , 1966, "The structure of urban activity linkages" (University of North Carolina,
Chapel Hill).
Space-time budgets and activity studies 367
Hurst, M. E. E., 1969, "The structure of movement and household travel behaviour", Urban Studies,
6, 70-82.
King, L. J., 1969, "The analysis of spatial form and its relation to geographic theory", Annals of
the Association of American Geographers, 59, 573-595.
Lenntorp, B., 1970, "PESASP—en modell for berakning av alternativa banor", Urbaniserings
Processen, 38, Department of Geography, University of Lund, Lund, Sweden.
Lewis, O., 1959, Five Families: Mexican, Case Studies in the Culture of Poverty (Basic Books, New
York).
London Traffic Survey, 1964, 1966, 2 volumes (Greater London Council, London).
Lundberg, G. A., Komarowsky, M., Mclnerny, Mary Alice, 1934, Leisure, A Suburban Study
(Columbia University Press, New York).
Marble, D. F., 1959, Section 3 of Studies of Highway Development and Geographic Change,
Ed. W. L. Garrison (University of Washington Press, Seattle).
Marble, D. F., 1967, "A theoretical exploration of individual travel behaviour", Quantitative
Geography, 1, Studies in Geography, 13, (Northwestern University), pp.33-53.
Marble, D. F., 1970, "Travel diaries—problems of data collection and analysis", Paper presented at
the Cambridge meeting, Institute of British Geographers, London.
Martensson, S., 1970, "Tidsgeografisk beskrivning av stationsstrukture", Urbaniserings Processen, 39,
Department of Geography, University of Lund, Lund, Sweden.
Maw, R., 1969, "Construction of a leisure model", Official Architecture and Planning, August,
924-935.
Mead, Margaret (Ed.), 1954, Cultural Patterns and Technical Change (UNESCO, New York).
Mead, W. R., 1958, "The seasonal round:- a study of adjustment on Finland's pioneer fringe",
Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie, 49, 157-161.
Meier, R. L., 1962, A Communications Theory of Urban Growth (MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.).
Milstein, D. N., 1961, "An economic approach to leisure analysis", Social Problems, 9, 17-31.
Moore, E. G., 1970, "Some spatial properties of urban contact fields", Geographical Analysis, 2,
376-386.
Moore, W. E., 1963, Man, Time and Society (John Wiley, New York).
Morrill, R. L., Pitts, F. R., 1967, "Marriage, migration, and the mean information field: a study in
uniqueness and generality", Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 57, 401 -422.
Mumford, L., 1934, Technics and Civilization (Harcourt, Brace & Co., New York).
Neurath, O., 1944, "Foundations of the social sciences", International Encyclopedia of Unified
Science, 2, 1-51, University of Chicago, Chicago.
Nichols, Vida, 1969, "An institution in metropolis", Seminar Paper 12, Joint Unit for Planning
Research, University of London.
Nystuen, J. D., 1959, Section 4 of Studies of Highway Development and Geographic Change,
Ed. W. L. Garrison (University of Washington Press, Seattle).
Nystuen, J. D., 1963, "Identification of some fundamental spatial concepts", in Spatial Analysis,
Eds. B. J. L. Berry, D. F. Marble (Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, N.J.), pp.35-41.
Nystuen, J. D., 1967, "A theory and simulation of intra-urban travel", Quantitative Geography, 1,
Studies in Geography, 13, Northwestern University, Evanston, Illinois, pp.54-83.
Pahl, R. E., 1970, Whose City? And Other Essays on Sociology and Planning (Chapter 13)
(Longmans, Green, London).
Quarmby, D. A., 1967, "Choice of travel mode for the journey to work: some findings", Journal
of Transport Economics and Policy, 1, 273-314.
Robinson, Joan, 1964, Economic Philosophy (Penguin Books, Harmondsworth).
Rushton, G., 1969, "Analysis of spatial behaviour by revealed space preference", Annals of the
Association of American Geographers, 59, 391-400.
Sommer, R., 1969, Personal Space: The Behavioural Basis of Design (Prentice-Hall, Englewood
Cliffs, N.J.).
Sorokin, P. A., Berger, C. Q., 1939, Time-budgets of Human Behaviour (Harvard University Press,
Cambridge, Mass.).
Stegman, M. A., 1969, "Accessibility models and residential location", Journal of the American
Institute of Planners, 35, 22-29.
Szalai, A., 1966, "The multinational comparative time budget research project", American
Behavioural Scientist, 10, 1-4.
Thompson, W., 1967, "Urban economics", Chapter 4 of Taming Megalopolis, Volume 1,
Ed. H. W. Eldredge (Anchor Books, New York).
Webber, M. M., 1964, "Culture, territoriality and the elastic mile", Papers of the Regional Science
Association, 13, 59-69.
368 J Anderson
Wheeler, J. O., 1970, "Transport inputs and residential rent theory. An empirical analysis",
Geographical A nalysis, 2 , 4 3 - 5 4 .
Wilkins, M. B., 1968, "Biological clocks", Advancement of Science, 24, 273-283.
Willmott, P., 1967, "Social research and new communities", Journal of the American Institute of
Planners, 33, 387-398.
Wilson, N. L., 1955, "Space, time and individuals", Journal of Philosophy, 52, 589-598.
Wolpert, J., 1965, "Behavioural aspects of the decision to migrate", Papers of the Regional Science
Association, 15, 159-169.