This Content Downloaded From 197.156.73.170 On Sun, 20 Mar 2022 15:12:18 UTC
This Content Downloaded From 197.156.73.170 On Sun, 20 Mar 2022 15:12:18 UTC
This Content Downloaded From 197.156.73.170 On Sun, 20 Mar 2022 15:12:18 UTC
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/650660?seq=1&cid=pdf-
reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
and Oxford University Press are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to Past & Present
* Versions of this paper have been presented to the African Studies Seminar, McGi
University, January 1976, to the annual meeting of the African Studies Association
Boston, November 1976, and to a symposium on "Cultivator and the State in I're
Colonial Africa", Urbana, May 1977. I am particularly grateful to Donald Ievine and
John M. Cohen for their careful and challenging readings.
1 For example, Arnauld d'Abbadie, Douze ans dans la Haute-Ethiopie (Paris
I 868); C. Conti Rossini, Principi di diritto consuetudinario dell'Eritrea (Rome, I 916
E. Cerulli, "Punti di vista sulla storia dell'Etiopia", in Atti del convegno inter
nazionale di studi etiopici (Rome, 1960); P. Gilkes, The Dying Lion: Feudalism an
Modernization in Ethiopia (London, 1975). John Markakis has been more hesitan
than most: J. Markakis, Ethiopia: The Anatomy of a Polity (Oxford, 1974), p. 4; and
Gene Ellis has registered the most vigorous dissent: G. Ellis, "The Feudal Paradigm
a Hindrance to Understanding Ethiopia", Jl. Mod. African Studies, xiv (1976), p
275-95.
2 Eshetu Chole, "The Mode of Production in Ethiopia and the Realities Thereof",
Challenge: Jl. Ethiopian Students Union in North America, xii (197 1), pp. 3-28; Addis
Hiwet, Ethiopia from Autocracy to Revolution (London, 1975); Provisional Military
Administrative Council [Ethiopia], The Ethiopian Revolution ... FirstAnniversary of
the Ethiopian Revolution (Addis Ababa, 1975).
3 A. Hoben, Land Tenure among the Amhara of Ethiopia: The Dynamics of Cog-
natic Descent (Chicago, 1973); W. Weissleder, "The Political Ecology of Amhara
Domination" (Univ. of Chicago Ph.D. thesis, 1965); D. N. Levine, Wax and Gold
(Chicago, I965); D. N. Levine, Greater Ethiopia: The Evolution of a Multiethnic
Society (Chicago, 1974), ch. 8. See also F. C. Gamst, "Peasantries and Elites without
Urbanism: The Civilization of Ethiopia", Comparative Studies in Society and Hist.,
xii (I970), pp. 373-92.
4 M. Bloch, Feudal Society, 2nd edn., 2 vols. (London, I962).
Io
Language Area
I Tegrenni
Amharic
ever, the very inadequate literature on them does not suggest that
those of Wag and Lasta differ in any respects other than language from
their Semitic-speaking neighbours. They have been entirely integrated
into the Abyssinian polity at least since the twelfth and thirteenth cen-
turies when they ruled it. The basic reality to which I want to call at-
tention here is that at least since the thirteenth century the Abyssinian
state has rested upon and drawn its support from a coherent plough-
cultivating peasantry, whose density and size of population far exceeds
that of any other group over a very wide area (excluding only the lower
Nile valley), and which despite some linguistic differentiation (princi-
pally into Amharic and Tegreinnia) was integrated by a high degree of
common culture and custom.'4 Attempts to explain the state or the
social order from which it arose by reference to one group alone are
bound to fail. Attempts to explain or describe the state without refer-
ence to its relations with the peasantry are equally bound to be inade-
quate.
The period to which my remarks are intended to apply is a very
rough one: from the seventeenth century to the earlier twentieth cen-
tury. Since about 1935 a money economy spread rapidly and a central-
ized bureaucracy and administration grew up, technically distinct
from and independent of local power structures. Interlocked with these
developments was a striking expansion of the communications infra-
structure and a slow growth of capitalist enterprise.'5 The extent to
which these developments altered the Abyssinian social order is as yet
unresolved, but for analytical purposes it is convenient to exclude
them. Throughout the bulk of the period under review the Ethiopian
region had only the meagerest contacts with the evolving capitalist
system of world trade; Ethiopia's external commercial linkages lying
rather towards the north end of the Red Sea.
The starting-point requires some justification. The sixteenth cen-
tury saw a number of upheavals, the full social import of which has yet
to be assessed. From I529 to 1543 the country was racked by war, fol-
lowing which it came under at least half a century of pressure from im-
migrating bands called Galla. Then, for the first quarter of the seven-
teenth century it went through internal strife which became compli-
cated by the intervention of Jesuit missionaries. The status of the peas-
antry through all this is obscure. However, at the apex of the social
14 D. N. Levine has discussed significant ways in which the Solomonic story consti-
tuted a social and cultural myth, as distinct from a purely dynastic one: D. N. Levine,
"Menilek and Oedipus: Further Observations on the Ethiopian National Epic", in
H. G. Marcus (ed.), Proceedings of the First United States Conference on Ethiopian
Studies, I973 (East Lansing, Mich., 1975), pp. 11-23; Levine, Greater Ethiopia, ch. 7.
15 Markakis, Ethiopia, esp. ch. 12; P. Gilkes, The Dying Lion: Feudalism and
Modernization in Ethiopia (London, 1975), ch. 3; C. Clapham, Haile Sellassie's
Government (London, I 969); P. Koehn and John M. Cohen, "Local Government in
Ethiopia: Independence and Variability in a Deconcentrated System", Quart. Jl.
Administration, ix (1975), pp. 369-86.
16 Taddesse Tamrat, Church and State in Ethiopia, 1270-1527 (Oxford, 1972), pp.
89-94; Merid W. Aregay, "Southern Ethiopia and the Christian Kingdom, 1508-1708,
with Special Reference to the Galla Migrations and their Consequences" (Univ. of
London Ph.D. thesis, 197 ).
17 Merid W. Aregay, "Southern Ethiopia and the Christian Kingdom, 1508- 708",
ch. 4; LaVerle B. Berry, "The Solomonic Monarchy at Gondar, i630-1755: An Insti-
tutional Analysis of Kingship in the Christian Kingdom of Ethiopia" (Boston Univ.
Ph.D. thesis, 1976), pp. lvii, 25 -2, 293-6.
18 Girmah Beshah and Merid W. Aregay, The Question of the Union of the
Churches in Luso-Ethiopian Relations, I500-I632 (Lisbon, 1964), p. 73.
19 Stimulating questions about this period are raised in A. Bartnicki and J. Mantel-
Niecko, "The Role and Significance of the Religious Conflicts and People's Move-
ments in the Political Life of Ethiopia in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries",
Rassegna di studi etiopici, xxiv (1969-70), pp. 5-39.
20 Merid W. Aregay, "Southern Ethiopia and the Christian Kingdom, 1508-1708",
pp. 581-2; Berry, "The Solomonic Monarchy at Gondar, 1630-1755", pp. 293-6.
21 Levine, Wax and Gold, p. 156.
The Abyssinian state rested firmly on the peasantry and on the pro-
duce of the land. The Ethiopian cultivator fits virtually all definitions
of a peasant: in no sense, economically, politically, culturally or relig-
iously was he an independent or autonomous figure, but rather was
linked in all these spheres by relationships which ran vertically up a
hierarchical social order, and horizontally over a wide geographical
area.23 Conversely formal kinship organizations, beyond possibly the
family, played no real role in the organization of production or in the
distribution of its results.24 "Clan" and "tribe" are terms manifestly
inapplicable to a description of Abyssinian society in our period.25 The
relationship between cultivators and the state is pithily summed up in
the Amharic apposition: arrasa/naggasa (cultivating/ruling).26 I will
return to the question of subjugation and constraint.
Virtually all commentators have noted the use of fiefs as a major
device for ruling-class support. The generic Abyssinian term is gult,
derived directly from the verb gwallata. Guidi renders gwallata simply
as "assegnare un feudo".27 As terminology varied considerably, in
22 Bloch, Feudal Society, ii, p. 446. For Hoben's application to the Amhara, see
especially his Land Tenure among the Amhara of Ethiopia, pp. 1-2.
23 John M. Cohen has drawn attention to the relevance of Ethiopian cultivators to
the general discussion about peasants in Africa: J. M. Cohen, "Ethiopia: A Survey on
the Existence of a Feudal Peasantry",Jl. Mod. African Studies, xii (1974), pp. 665-72.
The classic statement is by L. Fallers, "Are African Cultivators to be Called 'Peas-
ants'?", Current Anthropology, ii (196I), pp. 108- o, repr. in his Inequality: Social
Stratification Reconsidered (Chicago, 1973), pp. 80-8. For Ethiopia, see also Gamst,
"IPeasantries and Elites without Urbanism"; Levine, Wax and Gold, ch. 3.
24 Hoben's work is fundamental for an understanding of Abyssinian rural society.
In addition to Land Tenure among the Amhara of Ethiopia, see also his "Social
Stratification in Traditional Amhara Society", in A. Tuden and L. Plotnicov (eds.),
Social Stratification in Africa (London, 1970), pp. 187-224; and his "Land Tenure
and Social Mobility among the Damot Amhara", in Proceedings of the Third Inter-
national Conference of Ethiopian Studies, Addis Ababa, 1966, 3 vols. (Addis Ababa,
1970), iii, pp. 69-87.
25 In spite of Shack, The Central Ethiopians.
26 J. Baeteman, Dictionnaire amarigna-francais (Dire Daoua, 1929), col. 524.
27 I. Guidi, Vocabolario amarico-italiano (Rome, 1953 edn.), col. 708.
The nobility have a natural right to rule, are delicate and refined.
Their speech is elegant:
I have the strength of an elephant;
I have the mouth of a noble.
nobility is derived directly from the verb kwannana, which means "to
punish", and which carries an overtone of extortion.97 As I have point-
ed out elsewhere, this brings the term for the nobility close to a generic
term for "oppressor".98
It is not difficult to establish the continuity of class relations through
time. Contrary to certain assertions, some fiefs were hereditary.99
A legal term, resta-gult, existed to cover this situation.100 Weissleder
documented such a case as it existed in I963. Moreover, even where
superordinate land rights were not held strictly to be hereditary, there
was a strong tendency for them to be held successively by close kin.
Hoben shows that, in the area of Daga Damot which he studied,
although father-to-son inheritance of gult office in the twentieth cen-
tury occurred "less than 50 per cent of the time", succession in other
cases generally was to such genetically close relatives as brothers or
uncles.101 However, some of the most distinctive features of the Abys-
sinian situation arise from the nature of the Abyssinian family. As
Hoben and Bauer bring out clearly, the Abyssinian family has no
trans-generational reality. Descent is strongly ambilineal; and succes-
sion and property inheritance tend in the same direction, although
they are frequently biased towards the patriline and to males.102 As a
result legitimate claimants to any office abound; and this provides
ample opportunity for manipulation from above and pressure from
below.
The highest levels of Abyssinian society show marked continuity
over the last two centuries, although the poverty of our documentation
precludes such a demonstration for any lower level of society prior to
the very recent past. Both Gojjam and Tegre present strong cases of
almost dynastic rule, although the administrative level at which this
pertains in Tegre is lower than for Gojjam.103 Again, the descendants
of Ras Ali of Yajju successfully dominated the central axis of Abyssin-
ian territory from the 178os to the 850s, and retained their hold on its
eastern end down to the twentieth century. Wallo saw the emergence of
97 Guidi, Vocabolario amarico-italiano, cols. 542, 547; Baeteman, Dictionnaire
amarigna-francais, cols. 734, 735.
98 Crummey, "Society and Ethnicity in the Politics of Christian Ethiopia", p. 269.
99 J. Doresse, La vie quotidienne des ethiopiens chretiens aux XVII et XVIII siecles
(Paris, I972), p. 89; see also Berhanou Abbebe, Evolution de la proprietefonciere au
Choa, pp. 33-50, 78-92.
100 Berhanou Abbebe, Evolution de la propriete fonciere au Choa, pp. 28-9. Resta-
gult had rather a special meaning in Daga Damot: Hoben, Land Tenure among the
Amhara of Ethiopia, p. 188.
101 Hoben, Land Tenure among the Amhara of Ethiopia, p. I88; Hoben, "Land
Tenure and Social Mobility among the Damot Amhara", pp. 73-8, 80- . Hoben argues
that continuity would be greater in times of peace like the twentieth century; but he
begs the question of who was being unruly in times of unruliness.
102 For patrilineal male bias, see Conti Rossini, Principi di diritto consuetudinario
dell'Eritrea, pp. 3 I0-4; Weissleder, "The Political Ecology of Amhara Domination".
103 Fantahun Birhane, "Gojjam, 8oo-i 855", ch. i, and table 4 of the appendix.
keeping the allegiance of its peasantry. Part of the price which the
nobility paid was the weakness of its own felt identity.
Feudal concepts are useful in an analysis of Abyssinian society. At
the least they raise a range of questions the discussion of which ought
to illuminate significant aspects of social relations in the Abyssinian
past. It is no accident that there has been something of a conjunction
between the liberal and Marxist traditions here. Although the former
has been more concerned with aspects of superstructure, and of style
and flavour, the latter would hold that these are reflective of more
underlying relationships. However, from neither perspective can the
Abyssinian social order be described as feudal without serious qualifi-
cation. From whichever perspective we approach our analysis the
point of departure from the European-derived model may usefully be
explained by reference to the differing levels of class formation in the
two societies. The Abyssinian social formation had two fundamental
classes: cultivators and rulers. Relations between these two were inti-
mate and fluid, uncomplicated either by ethnicity or by legal status.
The rulers supported themselves by means of exactions from the peas-
ants, primarily in the form of tribute rather than rent. The confidence
of these judgements ought not obscure the extent of our ignorance
about historic Abyssinian society, and the various stages of its develop-
ment. Further research is urgently required on the question of property
relations, the sources and exercise of political authority, and the na-
ture of class formation.