The Implementation of Trade Liberalization in Indonesia: Dewa K. S. Swastika and Sri Nuryanti
The Implementation of Trade Liberalization in Indonesia: Dewa K. S. Swastika and Sri Nuryanti
The Implementation of Trade Liberalization in Indonesia: Dewa K. S. Swastika and Sri Nuryanti
IN INDONESIA
INTRODUCTION
258
with the rates of 0-10 percent; about 15 percent in the range of 15-20 percent;
about 0.5 percent with the range of 15-30 percent; and only 1 percent have the rate
above 30 percent.
Indonesia imposed specific tariff for rice and sugar at a very low rate
compared to bounded tariff. Although Indonesia did not apply for specific tariff on
AoA-WTO, however, it is much easier to implement in order to prevent the
country from rice smuggling. Among other agricultural products, over quantity
and untimely import of soybeans as well as domestic price deterioration have got
high attentions of many institutions, mainly the government of Indonesia.
Simatupang (2004) and Sawit et al. (2005), have proposed Indonesian soybeans to
be grouped into special product (SP) and special safeguard mechanism (SSM),
together with rice, sugar, and maize. This proposal was aimed to enable Indonesia
to temporary protect its farmers against over quantity and untimely imports of
soybeans. Import monopoly of soybeans and soybean meal given to Bulog
followed by high tariff in 1980s, for example, have successfully stabilized
domestic prices of soybeans, soybeans meal, and feed, thus livestock industry was
well developed with the low risk (Ismet et al., 1996).
Since the end of 1980s, many deregulations were launched by the
government of Indonesia. Many trade barriers were gradually reduced, even some
were eliminated. Import monopoly on soybeans for Bulog was phased out in 1991.
Some private companies were allowed to import soybeans and soybeans meal with
the tariffs of 5 percent and 40 percent, respectively. This policy indicated that
Indonesia has liberalized the trade of agricultural products.
As generally happen in most of developing countries, Indonesia applied
tariffs much lower than what were bounded in the AoA-WTO agreement. For
example, the applied specific tariffs for rice and sugar were Rp 430/kg and Rp
700/kg, respectively, which were about 30 percent and 60 percent of ad-valorem
bounded tariffs. Meanwhile, the tariffs for other commodities were much lower
than these two commodities. Soybeans and milk bounded tariffs were 27 percent
and 210 percent in terms of ad-valorem, while their implementation were only 0
percent and 5 percent, respectively (Sawit, 2005). Therefore, Indonesia often
called as the most open country for agricultural products (Mageira, 2002 cited by
Sawit, 2005). Table 1 shows the bounded and implementation of tariffs for some
agricultural products for the last ten years period.
As shown in Table 1, that the applied tariffs of almost all agricultural
products were much lower than what were bounded in the AoA-WTO. Even some
commodities have no tariff. The low tariff policy has encouraged the high flow of
agricultural products from other countries to Indonesia. As a result, the prices of
imported agricultural commodities mostly lower than what they supposed to be.
Another impact is that the prices of imported commodities were lower than the
domestic one. It implies that the competitiveness of domestically produced
agricultural products will be relatively lower.
THE IMPLEMENTATION OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION IN INDONESIA Dewa K.S. Swastika dan Sri
Nuryanti
259
Table 1. The Bounded and Applied Tariffs of Agricultural Products in Indonesia, 1994-
2004
260
Amber Box is any subsidy that could make market distortion, and
therefore hamper international trade. In this category, there should be a reduction
in subsidy, including the difference between domestic and world price, and direct
payment to producers. But the exemption of subsidy should not more than 10
percent, so called de minimis. In other words, Indonesia is allowed to provide
subsidy in terms of price support, fertilizer subsidy, or seed subsidy, as long as
those subsidies are not exceed 10 percent of the product value per year.
Export subsidy is dealing with export subsidy reduction and ban. Because
this policy will definitely create world market distortion, except for the
commodities that included in the list of commitment. For the commodities that are
listed in the commitment, the country should reduce budget for subsidy and the
number of subsidized export commodities. The developed countries agree to
reduce the number of subsidized export commodities by 24 percent within 6 years,
while the developing countries by 14 percent within 10 years (Solagral, 2001).
During the 6 years implementation of tariff reduction commitment, the developing
countries, for certain condition, are allowed to use their subsidy to reduce export
cost. The reduction of export cost is an important strategy of developing countries
to create an international trade balance between developed and developing
countries in the global market.
The changes in the three pillars of AoA-WTO will affect the international
trade and domestic trade of agricultural products, in terms of production,
processing, marketing and consumption. A broader market access is actually a
better opportunity for Indonesia to increase the export of agricultural products.
However, this opportunity is not optimally utilized, due to many constraints.
The progress is that developed countries have utilized the three pillars of
AoA-WTO to legalize some forms of subsidies for their rich farmers. These
domestic supports and export subsidy given by developed countries have made
worse the competitiveness of the same commodities produced by developing
countries. The situation became worse, since the developed countries provided
some protections in terms of market access, such as tariff escalation, and some
non-tariff barriers. The developed countries make use these supports to expand the
marketing of their agricultural products, thus it created an unbalance international
trade.
The developed countries who are members of Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD), provided some forms of domestic
supports, and tended to increase annually. There are at least three indicators of
domestic support given by OECD to their farmers, namely: (i) Nominal Protection
Coefficient for Producer (NPCp); (ii) Nominal Assistance Coefficient for Producer
(NACp); and (iii) Producer Support Estimate (PSE).
The NPCp is the ratio between actual price received by producer (farm
gate price) and import parity price (border price evaluated at farm gate). The
greater the coefficient the greater is the difference between domestic and world
THE IMPLEMENTATION OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION IN INDONESIA Dewa K.S. Swastika dan Sri
Nuryanti
261
prices. The NACp is the ratio between actual output values received by farmers
(included support) and output value at the world price (without support). On the
other hands, PSE reflects the protection rate given to farmers, relative to actual
value of products at farm level. PSE is commonly used as an indicator of
protection comparison inter-countries, inter-commodities, and inter-temporal.
Table 2, Table 3, and Table 4, show the examples of NPCp, NACp, and PSE on
soybeans in some OECD countries.
Table 2. The Nominal Protection Coefficient for Producer (Soybeans Case) in some
OECD countries, 1986 – 2004
Switzerland and South Korea had NPCp higher than that of aggregate
OECD in both period. Before AoA-WTO, Switzerland gave the highest protection,
while after AoA-WTO South Korea gave the highest protection to their soybeans
farmers. The interesting case was that after AoA-WTO, soybeans farmers in
Slovakia got 20 percent protection from their government.
Analisis Kebijakan Pertanian. Volume 4 No. 4, Desember 2006 : 257-267
262
The Nominal Assistance Coefficient to Producer (Soybeans Case)
The aggregate NACp of OECD countries for soybeans farmers slightly
increased from 2.19 before AoA-WTO to 2.33 after AoA-WTO, meaning that
farmers in these countries got revenue from soybeans 119 percent and 133 percent
higher than its parity, respectively, before and after AoA-WTO. Before AoA-
WTO, four countries (Switzerland, South Korea, European Union, and Japan) had
NACp higher than that of aggregate OECD, while after AoA-WTO, only
Switzerland and South Korea had NACp higher than that of aggregate OECD.
Before AoA-WTO, soybeans farmers in Poland got revenue from
soybeans 46 percent less that its parity, while after AoA-WTO, they got 16 percent
higher than its parity. In contrast, Slovakia got assistance 39 percent before AoA-
WTO and -4 percent after AoA-WTO, as presented in Table 3.
Table 3. The Nominal Assistance Coefficient for Producer (Soybeans Case) in some
OECD countries, 1986 – 2004
The trade liberalization in agriculture, that has been design in the form of
AoA-WTO, was initially aimed to accelerate the economic development of
developing countries through international trade of agricultural products.
However, the fact is that the imports of agricultural products from developed
countries to developing countries were steadily increasing. On the other hands, the
exports of agricultural products from developing countries were declining. This
situation has made worse the economic development of developing countries.
Poverty and hunger in developing countries remain unchanged, even in some
countries are increasing. At the same time, budget constraints along with
increasing foreign debts have worsen the efforts of poverty alleviation, food
security programs, and rural development in developing countries. This negative
impact of trade liberalization and foreign debts was also happen in Indonesia
(Sawit and Rusastra, 2005).
264
Due to protection and subsidy given by developed countries to their
agricultural products, they sold their agricultural products (about 80% food) to
world market at a low price, so that the price of food in the world market remain
distorted, and tended to decline, especially rice, maize, soybeans, sugar, wheat,
and meat. The faster is price declining the higher is support given by developed
countries to their farmers. This support had a negative impact on the poor farmers
who produce food, since they could not compete in both international and
domestic markets.
The following discussion describes the growths of wholesaler real prices
of five food commodities in Indonesia during the period of 1998-2005. As
presented in Table 5, the growths of real prices of three food commodities were
negative. The real prices of soybeans, rice and milk grew at the rates of -1.87
percent, -2.18 percent, and -0.94 percent, respectively.
Table 5. The Trend of Wholesalers Real Prices of Five Food Commodities, 1998-2004
Agricultural Products
Year
Soybeans Maize Rice Sugar Milk
1998 1,703 395 814 957 5,905
1999 1,229 526 992 1,025 6,108
2000 1,084 493 807 1,098 5,642
2001 1,042 504 779 1,246 5,198
2002 991 499 844 1,071 4,926
2003 1,080 551 900 1,327 5,349
2004 1,012 486 699 1,049 4,332
Growth
-1.87 2.58 -2.18 2.73 -0.94
(%/year)
*) Real price = nominal price deflated by CPI 1996.
Source: Wholesalers Price Statistics, 1996-2005 (CAS).
THE IMPLEMENTATION OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION IN INDONESIA Dewa K.S. Swastika dan Sri
Nuryanti
265
Husein Sawit and Rusastra (2005) suggested some strategic policies, such
as: (a) Increasing the frontier of production through development and promotion
of new high yielding varieties; (b) Improvement of farm management through
empowerment of extension services; (c) Improvement of global trade policy with
more orientation to the need of developing countries; (d) Improvement of policy
on domestic marketing system for food commodity through improvement of
institution and infrastructure facilities. The implementation of these policies are
expected to have a significant impact on the willingness of farmers to adopt new
technology. Finally the adoption of new technology is expected to be able to
increase productivity and farmers income.
CONCLUDING REMARKS
REFERENCES
Directorate General of Customs and Excise (DGCE). 2004. Indonesian Customs Tariff
Book: Based on AHTN. Ministry of Finance. Jakarta.
266
Ismet, M, C. Silitonga dan M. Husein Sawit. 1996. “Industri Bungkil dan Minyak
Kedelai”, dalam Amang, B. dkk (Eds). Ekonomi Kedelai di Indonesia. IPB Press.
Bogor.
OECD. 2005a. Producer and Consumer Support Estimates, OECD Database 1986-2004.
www.oecd.org/oecd pse full zip/. 14 April 2006.
OECD. 2005b. Producer and Consumer Support EstimatesOECD Database 1986-2004
User’s Guide. www.oecd.org/EDPuserguide05/. 11 April 2006.
Sawit, M.H. 2005. Perum Bulog dalam Perjanjian Pertanian WTO: Apa, Mengapa, dan
Bagaimana. (Edisi ke-2) Puslitbang Bulog.. Jakarta.
Sawit, M.H. dan I. W. Rusastra. 2005. “Globalisasi dan Ketahanan Pangan di Indonesia”.
Laporan akhir dari bagian laporan penelitian Road Map Memperkuat Kembali
Ketahanan Pangan. LPEM UI, Jakarta.
Sawit, M.H., A.Setiyanto, H.J.Purba dan Supriati. 2005. “Penyaringan SP (Special
Product) Pertanian di WTO: sebuah modalitas dari Indonesia”, Jurnal Ekonomi &
Bisnis Indonesia, 20 (4), FE UGM: Yogyakarta
Simatupang, P. 2004. “Justifikasi dan Metoda Penetapan Komoditas Strategis” dalam
Edisi Rudi Wibowo dkk. Rekontruksi dan Restrukturisasi Ekonomi Pertanian,
PERHEPI: Jakarta.
Solagral. 2001. The Agreement on Agriculture: The End of Exceptions?. Agriculture in
Developing Countries and WTO. Papers To Understand, Anticipate, and Debate.
TPRM. 2003. Trade Policy Review: Indonesia. “Trade policies by sector”.
WT/TPR/S/117. http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/tpr_e/tp216_e.htm. 6 June
2005.
THE IMPLEMENTATION OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION IN INDONESIA Dewa K.S. Swastika dan Sri
Nuryanti
267