0% found this document useful (0 votes)
310 views19 pages

Competitive Analysis of The Global Oil and Gas Industry Using Porters Five Forces Model

Porter’s Five Forces Model for Oil and Gas Industry

Uploaded by

Afnan Aldarwish
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
310 views19 pages

Competitive Analysis of The Global Oil and Gas Industry Using Porters Five Forces Model

Porter’s Five Forces Model for Oil and Gas Industry

Uploaded by

Afnan Aldarwish
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 19

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/332632145

Competitive Analysis of the Global Oil and Gas Industry using Porters Five
Forces Model

Conference Paper · June 2018

CITATION READS

1 16,942

1 author:

Tarig Malik
Heriot-Watt University
1 PUBLICATION   1 CITATION   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Strategic Analysis Article View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Tarig Malik on 25 April 2019.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


The 7th Annual Conference of Economic Forum of Entrepreneurship & International Business: ISBN:
978-1-988081-05-2: Library & Archive Canada
© ECO-ENA: Economics & ECO-Engineering Associate, Inc. ®, Canada
Venue: Hughes Hall, Cambridge University, Cambridge, United Kingdom
Date: June 28th, 2018

Competitive Analysis of the Global Oil and Gas Industry using Porters Five
Forces Model

Tarig Mohamed Ali Malik Taha


[email protected]
BSc Econometrics, MBA, University of Khartoum-Sudan
MSc IFA, Newcastle University Business School, UK

1.0 Abstract:

The Structure Conduct Performance (SCP) model suggests that the structure of an industry has

more bearing on the performance of firms operating in an industry (Mason, 1939, 1949; Bain, 1951

as cited in Lipczynsk et al 2013, p. 6; Bain 1956; Bain 1968). In view of the SCP model this study

investigates the fundamental competitive drivers, that function within the global oil and gas

industry -more specifically Exploration and Production (E&P) segment1- using Porter’s (1979)

Five Forces model, the study also attempts to assess the likely impact of these fundamental drivers

on the profit potential of the industry. The results showed that, while customers bargaining power

appears to be low, the power of suppliers might be of moderate strength and that the threat

substitute products is still, far off, and less credible in the short run, it is also observed that the

industry has high barriers to entry, Finally, the study revealed that there are both intensive rivalry

and evidence for collaboration among existing players in the oil and gas industry.

Key words: Competitive Structure, Oil and Gas Industry, Porter’s Five Forces, Profit Potential.

1 For
the purpose of this study the terms E&P industry and or oil and gas industry shall be used
interchangeably to mean the global E&P sector of the industry.

1
2.0 Introduction:

In agreement with SCP advocates, Barney and Zajac (1994) strongly believed that, the market in

which a company operate is a key factor that determine its profitability. If one accept this widely

held view, competitive analysis would therefore expected to uncover a set of contextual

underpinnings that act to inform companies strategic positioning based on an enlightened view of

the external forces operating within the industry, to this, certainly, oil and gas industry is no

exception. Caves and Porter (1977) (Porter, 1979; Porter, 2008) have strongly supported this SCP

nation.

Therefore, this study is set to examine critically the market dynamics within the oil and gas

industry and, to assess the profit potential of the industry in light of various competitive drivers.

On the basis of the overall objectives of the study five major issues will be addressed: To begin

with, an assessment of whether there are threats of new firms entering the oil and gas industry will

be investigated. Secondly, the study will try and review the seriousness of various attempts of

substituting petroleum products with other alternative energy sources. Furthermore, is there a

threat of buyer’s ability to negotiate lower prices? Similarly, are suppliers able to dictate own terms

and conditions on oil and gas producers? The intense of rivalry among existing major players in

the industry will be examined as well. Essentially, the study will try and highlight likely impact of

each of these forces on the oil and gas industry profit potential.

3.0 Research Methodology:

Porter produced his pioneering (1979) Five Forces model to be used for industry structure analysis

using five generic factors: Threat of new entrants, threat of substitutes, bargaining power of buyers,

bargaining power of suppliers, and intensity of rivalry among existing firms (See figure-1 below).

2
It worth noting that, after almost three decades, in which the Five Forces model have been used

widely by academics and practitioners alike, Porter stated that “Industry structure drives

competition and profitability, not whether an industry is emerging or mature, high tech or low tech,

regulated or unregulated” (Porter, 2008: 30). This model is still operational as a generic framework

for competitive analysis of any industry, thanks to the degree of business image clarity provided

by the model across the value chain (Brandenburger, 2002) and, the emphasis that the analysis

results can be used for positioning the company in order to gain competitive advantage (Aktouf

et., al, 2005).

Figure-01: Competitive Forces that Shape Strategy :

Threat of new entrants’ means that there is a risk that new companies could enter the industry and

compete with incumbents by gaining some share of the market, which may negatively impact on

industry profit potential (Porter, 2008). However, barriers to entry could prevent new entrants from

3
entering the industry. Barrier to entry includes: high capital requirements (Bain, 1956; Porter,

1979), high sunk costs and experience curve (Porter, 1979).

Porter (1979) rightly pointed out that substitute products as a competitive force has more strategic

bearing, and should be taken more seriously in industries that are characterized by high profit rates

and or when substitute products are experiencing positive trend in their price-performance ratio.

Bargaining power of suppliers is low when the suppliers’ financial viability is dependent on the

industry they are serving. The relative size of suppliers and their monopoly power compared to

industry clients is another factor to be considered (Grant, 1991).

Similar to bargaining power of buyers, various factors come into play when sizing the bargaining

power of suppliers. As identified by Porter (1979) if buyers are organized in groups they could

demand lower prices for products or services. Another factor is the size of the buyers and volume

of their purchase. The availability of close substitutes and low degree of product differentiation

could also make switching from one product to another much easier for buyers, which might

increase the bargaining power of customers and hence dilute industry profitability (Peteraf, 1993).

Porter (2008) cited various factors for signaling the degree of rivalry among incumbents,

comprising: barriers to exit, high assets specificity and high fixed and snuck costs, this is

particularly so when profitability is declining or when firms are making losses. The Degree of

commitment of the incumbents and the prevalence of other non-profit making objectives tend to

intensify the competition as well.

4.0 Results and Discussion

This section shows the resultant analysis from the application of the underline generic five forces

of Porter to the oil and gas industry.

4
4.1 Threat of new entrants:

Oil and gas industry have various characteristics in regards to barriers to entry. For instance, this

industry is highly costly and technical. As presented in figure-2 below, the breakeven price for

deep-water Gulf of Mexico oil projects are higher than $60/barrel (U.S. EIA, 2016) whereas, the

weighted average crude oil spot price of Brent, Dubai and West Texas Intermediate was

$42.8/barrel in 2016 (Index Mundi, 2016). This indicates that given the current state of technology,

event some of the most entrenched companies are making losses which could obviously deter

aspirants.

Crude oil spot price Break-Even Price


70

60
US Dollars Per Barrel

50

40

30

20

10

0
Jan-16 Feb-16 Mar-16 Apr-16 May-16 Jun-16 Jul-16 Aug-16 Sep-16 Oct-16 Nov-16 Dec-16

Source: Indexmundi.com and US EIA

Figure-2: Crude oil average spot price (2016) vs breakeven price for a deep-water Gulf of Mexico oil project

In the technical side, the possession of advance technology in the part of existing players can boost

productivity while reducing costs (Santos et al. 1999 as cited in Hokron, 2014), making it more

difficult for new contestants to operate at the same cost curve.

Moreover, for firms to enter into this industry they need to have strong ability to raise funds, which

becomes rather difficult, in the presence of substantial sunk costs and high assets specificity

5
(Worthington, 1995). Another barrier to entry in the extractive oil and gas business is high exit

costs. By way of illustration, Campbell and Smith (2013) reported that in the UK it costs around

$10 million to plug and abandon a semisubmersible platform. These high exit costs may increase

the incumbent commitment to fight, thus, deter the potential entrants from entering the industry.

There are many evidences to suggest that learning curve in oil and gas wells drilling is a source of

competitive advantage that is hard to overcome by new entrants (Chi, 1978: and Bondy, 2015).

Figure-3, illustrates that while it could take an operator with zero learning up to 20 years to

breakeven, it might only take on average 5 years for an experienced operator to do, which is almost

4 folds advantage, this again another entry deterrence factors, emerging from the very unique

characteristic of the oil and gas industry.

25
Years of Breakeven

20

15

10

0
0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3
Learning Rate
Source: www.palantirsolutions.com

Figure-3: Oil drilling projects breakeven time and learning rate

First move, is another source of competitive advantage that incumbents enjoy over potential rivals.

For instance, the majority of the most preferable and lucrative oil and gas fields might have already

been occupied by major oil and gas players. Quigley (2014) report implied that these oil majors

are holding on these strategic assets quite tightly.

6
The above mentioned factors represent massive barriers to entry to oil and gas industry, which

may limit the pool of likely entrants. Consequently, making it possible for firms already operating

in the industry to generate economic profit other things being equal.

4.2 Threat of substitutes:

As depicted in figure-4, the consumption of oil and gas alternative sources, such as wind, solar and

geothermal are increasing at an increasing rate over time for the period from 2000- 2015 (BP

Statistical Review, 2016). However, their expansion to the degree of significant substitution is

faced by various challenges, a possible explanation for this might be that renewable energy

production is linked with weather conditions. For example, sun light availability and limited dust

are necessary for optimal solar energy production, this make alternative energy sources more of a

locational specific.

500000
Cumulative installed power

400000 Geothemal Solar Wind

300000
capacity

200000

100000

Source: BP Statistical Review of World Energy June 2016

Figure-4: Historical trend of renewable energy sources

Non-hydro renewable electric energy might be cited as another potential substitute product to oil

and gas. Davis and Owens (2003) using real options calculated that, the current annual funding for

US non-hydro electric energy R&D program was only $300 million, whereas the program requires

around $1.2 billion per year. Their study concluded that;

7
‘The optimal policy is to delay deploying RE and continue R&D funding until RE
technologies become more competitive, which will take about 25 years according
to the DCF model’ (Davis and Owens, 2003: 18).

This could possibly implies that, the US research and development program for non-hydro

renewable electric energy was still in its early stages.

In terms of marketability, Sayigh (1999) claimed that renewable energy products penetration rate

of the energy market have beaten expectations, and may represent around 10-15% energy of

consumption by the year 2020. Conversely, McVeigh et. al (2000) found that these energy source

have not been successful in achieving the expected US energy market penetration rate, although

their production costs were cheaper than expected. The later point has been supported by Varma

(2016), who argued that the price performance-ratio of various substitute products is improving,

Nevertheless, switching costs from fossil to non-fossil fuel could be high, since the current

machinery were predominately designed to operate on the earlier.

That being said, the challenges of threats of substitute products although highly likely in the longer

terms seems to be less credible at least in the short to medium terms.

4.3 Bargaining Power of buyers:

The barraging power of buyers depends to a large extend on the degree to which buyers are

concentrated on organized groups. Although buyers of hydrocarbons are generally powerful

countries such as the Chinese, American and Japanese governments which imports 18.6%, 15.9%

and 7.3% of world crude oil respectively (Workman, 2018), this represents a massive 41% of the

global oil market. However, despite their big size, the lack of a unified formation for oil buyers,

could possibly, reduce the degree of hassles caused to producers. As pointed in the earlier

discussion, the lack of credible substitutes to oil and gas products and the actuality of high

switching costs to other alternatives, the bargaining power of customers might be low.

8
On top of this, the producers of oil and gas are big multinational companies (see table-1), this

might at least, expectedly, restrain the ability of buyers to bargain and force prices down.

Table-1: Top 10 Oil and Gas Producers


2017 Revenue in $billion
Company Nationality
(as a proxy of size)
Saudi Aramco 455 Saudi Arabia
Sinopec 488 China
China National Petroleum 428 China
ExxonMobil 268 USA
Royal Dutch Shell 265 Netherlands/UK
Kuwait Petroleum Corporation 251 Kuwait
Eni 131 Italy
Chevron Corporation 129 USA
BP 222 UK
Total 212 France
Adapted from (Oil & Gas IQ.com)

But, sellers’ ability to charge higher prices could still be low, because all products are homogenous

with slight quality variations. Nevertheless, a group of the largest sellers of crude oil have

organized themselves into the ‘Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries’ (OPEC),

which could again weight down the ability of buyers to negotiate lower prices, and at the same

time enable OPEC members to limit the chances of price collapse, primarily, through the

determination of production quota. However, Dichristopher (2016) pointed out that OPEC

members fight for market share among themselves, which is expected behaviour in any cartel,

because there is tendency from some members to maximize own interests at the expenses of other

members.

It follows then, neither buyers nor sellers have sufficient bargaining power to be forced upon each

other. Overall, the prices of products sold by firms operating in this industry can be claimed to be

largely determined by the interplay of supply and demand.

9
4.4 Bargaining Power of Supplier:

In the oil and gas industry some supplier are well established firms such as Schlumberger,

Weatherford International, or China Oilfield Services Ltd, which suggests an ability to bargain. In

a recent study Naumov and Toews (2016) found a strong relationship between oil prices and

upstream capital costs (See figure-5).

Source: VOXeu.org

Figure-5: Growth in three-year moving average of the real oil price and drilling costs (2005-2012)

The positive correlation between growth in oil prices and growth in drilling costs over the period

from (2005 to 2012) could indicate that oil and gas service companies are very flexible, as they

adjust their costing system to match oil prices fluctuations. This entails suppliers’ ability to

negotiate higher prices when economic conditions are good. On the other hand, and despite the

high E&Ps dependence on their suppliers for execution of key operational activities across the oil

and gas value chain, services companies are forced to lower their prices, in the environment of low

oil prices (Marcel, et al. 2016). Further, Marcel et al. (2016) claimed that having their margin

squeezed, the services companies are forced to move towards more integrative, collaborative and

10
partnership operational models with their clients, sharing both risks and rewards with E&Ps, which

means oil and gas companies are giving up part of the industry profit to top suppliers.

On balance, the bargaining power of suppliers is not strong to the degree that it affects firms’

performance in a significant way. Nevertheless, the new trend of supplier-client partnership

operational model may means that part of the profit pie might cross the E&P industry boundaries.

4.5 Intensity of competition:

There are some evidences to suggest that rivalry in the oil and gas industry is very intensive,

because the incentives to fight are rather high. By way of exmaple, Quigley (2014) reported that,

in 2012 the Chinese oil giant Sinopec have facilitated an extension of $7.5 billion credit line to

Angola in which it was producing more than 1.7 million barrels per day with projection to reach

2.0 million barrel per day starting 2014. In the same year Sinopec have paid $2.5 billion to acquire

20% of OML 138 field in Nigeria. These are multibillion dollar projects, with huge future cash

flow expectations, which have clearly incentivize Sinopec to try and cement its presence in West

African region. Let alone other political motives for these multi-nationals.

It is also observed, the industry sales and residual income are very sensitive to economic situation.

As demonstrated in figure (6 and 7) below, ExxonMobil and Chevron sales growth rate and

residual income are negative for the period from (2013-2015). The negative growth in sales volume

and the inability to generate economic rent by major players such as these, coupled with the high

sunk costs and exist barriers in the industry- see section 4.1- represents entry barriers, but may also

signal a pre-commitment strategy, therefore, leading firms to compete more fiercely to recover

these costs, in a somewhat harsh economic environment.

11
25,000 Figure-6: Residual Income at 10% level of Equity Figure-7: Sales Growth Rate for ExxonMobil and
Charge for ExxonMobil and Chevron (2011-2015) Chevron (2011-2015)
40.0%
15,000
30.0%

5,000 20.0%

10.0%
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
-5,000
0.0%
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
-10.0%
-15,000
-20.0%

-25,000 -30.0%
ExxonMobil Chevron -40.0% ExxonMobil Chevron-Corp

However, Hokron (2014) and Brogan et. al (2015) reported that oil and gas companies have

various reasons to collaborate and operate jointly, in the form of joint venture for instance, this

collaboration is driven by desire to share risks, get access to capital and technological capabilities

and gain more market power.

Although, there is intense competition among rivals in the oil and gas industry, which might not

be good for the industry profitability, there is tendency for oil and gas giants to collude, may

somehow dilute the adverse effect of zero sum competition.

Conclusion:

The competitive analysis of the oil and gas industry has revealed that; this industry is hard to enter,

possibly because of high capital requirement, high sunk costs and incumbents competitive

advantage. Substitutes products started to penetrate the energy market with an increasing rate, but

might only affect profitability of the industry in the distant future. The barraging power of buyers

seems to be limited, primarily due to the relatively big size of producers and the organization of

them in a cartel, and the fact that buyers are not organized in groups. Suppliers’ bargaining power

12
seems to be moderate, although there are evidences of high dependence on them by E&P

companies, thus posing some risk on industry profitability. The study found signs of intensive

rivalry among existing players, because there are political interests and the desire to protect and

control of rich oil and gas assets, yet there is scope for collaboration driven by (high risk-high

costs) nature of the oil and gas business. Finally, although, most oil majors are making accounting

profit, the economic profit was negative for some of these companies at least in the last 3 to 5

years.

Despite the insights provided by Porter’s 5-Forces model about the oil and gas industry

competitive landscape, the analysis ignores the characteristics of individual firms operating in the

industry, a limitation inherited from the model used. In reality, however, along with market

structure what equally matters for companies’ success is the possession of distinctive capabilities

that help in creating and sustaining competitive advantage Wernerfel (1948).

13
5.0 References:

Aktouf, O. et, al (2005) ‘The False Expectations of Michael Porter's Strategic management

Framework’. Problems and Perspectives in Management, 3(4), [Online] Available at:

https://businessperspectives.org/images/pdf/applications/publishing/templates/article/

assets/785/PPM_EN_2005_04_Aktouf.pdf [Accessed 30 December 2018].

Baaziz, A. and Quoniam, L. (2013) ‘How to Use Big Data Technologies to Optimize Operations

in Upstream Petroleum Industry’. International Journal of Innovation 1(1) pp 19-25.

Bain, J. (eds) (1956) Barriers to New Competition: Their Character and Consequences in

Manufacturing Industries, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Bain, J. (1968) Industrial Organization, 2nd Edition. New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Bondy. J. (2015) ‘Unconventional: The Power of the Learning Curve’ Palantir Solutions [Online]

Available at:

http://www.palantirsolutions.com/blog-research/blog/2015/july/27/unconventionals-power-

learning-curve [Accessed 28 June 2016].

BP (2016) ‘Statistical Review of World Energy’ 20 June, [Online] Available at:

http://www.bp.com/en/global/corporate/energy-economics/statistical-review-of-

world-energy.html [Accessed 09 July 2016].

Brandenburger, A. (2002) Porter’s added Value: High Indeed!’. Academy of Management

Executive 16(2) pp 58-60.

Brogan, A. et al (2015) ‘Navigating joint ventures in oil and gas’. Ernst and Young [Online]

Available at: http://www.ey.com/Publication/vwLUAssets/EY-navigating-joint-

14
ventures-in-oil-and-gas/$FILE/EY-navigating-joint-ventures-in-oil-and-gas.pdf

[Accessed 8 July 2016].

Campbell, K., and Smith, R., (2013) ‘Permanent Well Abandonment’. Society of Petroleum

Engineers [Online] Available at: https://www.spe.org/en/twa/twa-article-

detail/?art=554 [Accessed 28 June 2016].

Caves, R. and Porter, M. (1977) ‘from entry barriers to mobility barriers: conjectural decisions

and contrived deterrence to new competition’. The Quarterly Journal of Economics

91(2) pp 241–261.

Chi. U., (1978) ‘Application of learning curve to the oil and Gas well drilling’ the SOCI of

Petroleum Engineers [Online] Available at:

https://www.onepetro.org/download/conference-paper/SPE-7119-MS?id=conference-

paper%2FSPE-7119-MS [Accessed 28 June 2016].

Davis, G. and Owens, B. (2003 ‘optimizing the level of renewable electric R&D expenditures

using real options analyses. Energy Policy, 31(15) pp 1589-1608.

Grant, R. (1991) ‘the resource - based theory of competitive advantage: implications for strategy

formulation’. California Management Review 33(3) pp 114 – 135.

Hokron, M. (2014) ‘An Analysis of the oil and gas industry’s competitiveness using porter’s Five

Forces Framework’. Global Journal of Commerce & Management perspective 3(2) pp

76-82.

Hotelling, H. (1929) ‘Stability in competition’. The Economic Journal 39(153) pp 41–57.

Marcel, V. et al. (2016) ‘ Using workhorses of the oil industry- Oil services companies’ KPMG,

01 March 2016 [Online] Available at:

15
https://home.kpmg/xx/en/home/insights/2016/03/oilfield-services-companies-unsung-

workhorses-oil-industry.html [Accessed 30 December 2018].

Lipczynski, J. et al. (ed.) (2013) Industrial Organization, Competition, Strategy and Policy,

Edinburgh: Pearson Education Limited.

McVeigh et. al (2000) ‘Winner, loser, or innocent victim? Has renewable energy performed as

expected?’. Solar Energy 68(3) pp 237-255.

Musprat, A. (2018) ‘The Top 10 Oil & Gas Companies in the World: 2018: who are the biggest

oil companies by revenue in 2018?’. Oil and Gas IQ 08 October 2018 [Online]

Available at: https://www.oilandgasiq.com/strategy-management-and-

information/articles/oil-and-gas-companies [Accessed 30 December 2018].

Naumov, N. and Toews, G. (2016) ‘Revisiting the relationship between oil prices and costs in the

upstream industry’ 22 February 2016 [Online] Available at:

https://voxeu.org/article/oil-prices-and-costs-upstream-industry [Accessed 30

December 2018].

Peteraf, M. (1993) ‘the cornerstones of competitive advantage: a resource -based view’. Strategic

Management Journal 14(3) pp 179 -192.

Porter, M. (1979) ‘How Competitive Forces Shape Strategy’. Harvard Business Review 57, 2, pp

137-145. [Online] Available at:

https://www.hbs.edu/faculty/Pages/item.aspx?num=10692 [Accessed 22 June 2016].

Porter, M. (2008) ‘The five competitive forces that shape strategy’. Harvard Business Review,

86, 1, pp.25–40. [Online] Available at:

http://www.business.uwm.edu/gdrive/Goranova_M/Readings_712/Porter%205%20forces.pdf

16
[Accessed 22 June 2016].

Quigley, S. (2014) ‘Chinese Oil Acquisitions in Nigeria and Angola’. American University in

Cairo, 01 June [Online] Available at:

http://schools.aucegypt.edu/huss/pols/khamasin/Pages/article.aspx?eid=14. [Accessed 20 June

2016].

Sayigh, A. (1999) ‘Renewable energy — the way forward’. Applied Energy 64(1-4) pp 15-30.

Schendel, D. (1994) ‘Competitive organizational behavior: toward an organizationally: based

theory of competitive advantages’. Strategic Management Journal 15(15) pp 5-7.

Index mundi (2018) [Online] Available at:

https://www.indexmundi.com/commodities/?commodity=crude-oil&months=180 [Accessed 30

December 2018].

U.S. Energy Information Administration (2016) Trends in U.S. Oil and Natural Gas Upstream

Costs, [Online] Available at:

https://www.eia.gov/analysis/studies/drilling/pdf/upstream.pdf [Accessed 16 July

2016].

Wernerfelt, B. (1984) ‘Resource-Based View of the Firm’. Strategic Management Journal 5(2)

pp 171-180.

Workman, D. (2018) ‘Crude Oil Imports by Country’. World top exporters, 11 May 2018 [Online]

Available at: http://www.worldstopexports.com/crude-oil-imports-by-country/

[Accessed 27 July 2018].

Worthington, P. (1995) ‘Investment, Cash Flow, and Sunk Costs’. The Journal of Industrial

Economics 43(1) pp 49-61.

17
Varma, S. (2016) ‘Indian Petroleum Industry: Some Insights Using Porter’s Model’. Journal of

Energy and Management, [Online] Available at:

http://www.pdpu.ac.in/downloads/3.%20indian_petroleum_industry.pdf [Accessed 30

December 2018].

18

View publication stats

You might also like