Part 1
Part 1
Part 1
Prologue
1 Why Deregulate?
2 What to Deregulate
3 Pricing Power, Energy, and Capacity
4 Power Supply and Demand
5 What Is Competition?
6 Marginal Cost in a Power Market
7 Structure
8 Architecture
9 Designing and Testing Market Rules
Is it a fact–or have I dreamt it—that, by means of electricity, the world of matter has become a
great nerve, vibrating thousands of miles in a breathless point of time? Rather, the round globe
is a vast head, a brain, instinct with intelligence! Or, shall we say, it is itself a thought, nothing
but thought, and no longer the substance that we dreamed it?
Nathaniel Hawthorne
The House Of Seven Gables
1851
3, it does not consider the implications of the network effects described in Part 5.
It can be read directly after Chapters 1-5 and 1-6 if desired. Part 5 begins with more
than enough power engineering to understand losses and congestion pricing which
are its central topics. The theme of Part 5 is that locational loss prices and conges-
tion prices are nothing more than ordinary (bilateral) competitive market prices.
The problem of market design is not to invent clever new prices but to design a
market that will reliably discover the same prices economics has been suggesting
since Adam Smith.
Power markets deviate from standard economics in two ways: the demand sides
are largely disconnected from the market and the details of supply costs violate
the assumptions of competitive economics. Part 2 focuses on the demand-side flaws
which require a regulatory intervention for a few hours per year to ensure reliability
and efficient investment. Until these flaws are sufficiently reduced they will remain
a great danger to power markets that are poorly designed. Part 2, while basic,
contains the most important new material in the book.
While the aggregate market supply function is perfectly normal, the details of
generation costs violate a basic competitive assumption. Because the violations
are small relative to the size of the market, they may require only a slight adjustment
to power exchange bids. Alternatively, a complex and opaque power pool may be
needed. The contribution of Part 3 is to present this problem in an accessible manner
and to highlight crucial questions that still need answers.
The book tells its story largely through examples. These are highly simplified
but designed to capture important phenomena and display their essential natures.
The key conclusions drawn from the examples are summarized in “Results” and
“Fallacies” which are listed after the table of contents. “Result” is not the best of
terms, but Fallacy has no acceptable antonym. Results are not theorems because
they are not stated rigorously. They are rarely new; most are standard economic
wisdom applied to power markets. They are simply the key points that should be
understood in each area. The Results distill much theory that is not presented, but
the examples reveal the mechanisms at work behind the Results. Fallacies are
treated explicitly to help dispel the handful of popular misconceptions that continu-
ally cause confusion.
1. Introduction (untitled)
2. Chapter Summary
3. Section Summaries
4. Sections
5. Technical Supplement (for some chapters)
Use the chapter summary of 50 to 200 words to determine if a chapter covers a
topic of interest and to learn its most essential points. For a complete overview of
the chapter’s content, read the Section Summaries. For the importance and context
of the chapter’s focus, read the introduction.
When reading an entire Part, the chapter and section summaries can be skipped,
though they may still provide a useful orientation. The technical supplement usually
contains more difficult mathematics but never more than easy calculus.
produced and the cost to produce the next unit. The marginal-cost range is defined
as the set of values from left-hand to right-hand marginal cost. See page 65.
Variable Cost. Because marginal cost is not defined at full output for a generator
with a standard right-angle supply function, the constant marginal cost before full
output is called the generator’s variable cost. This remains defined even when
marginal cost is not, as it is a property of the supply curve and not dependent on
the generator’s level of output. See page 69.
Scarcity Rent. “Scarcity rent” is not defined in economics texts, yet it is a term
commonly used in power economics. Popular usage attempts to distinguish between
rents earned when supply of all generation is scarce and those earned when only
some types are scarce. This book avoids the ambiguity inherent in such definitions
by defining scarcity rent as equal to the more conventional economic term,
inframarginal rent, which is the area below the market price and above the competi-
tive supply curve. See page 70.
Aggregate Price Spike. The aggregate price spike is defined as the upper portion
of the price duration curve, specifically the region in which price is above the
variable cost of the most-expensive investment-grade peaker (not an old, inefficient
peaker). This cut-off value is well defined only in simple models, but it still provides
some intuition about real markets. Revenue associated with this spike is called the
price-spike revenue and is similar to the popular meaning of scarcity rent. See page
127.
The propensity to truck, barter, and exchange one thing for another
. . . is common to all men.
Adam Smith
The Wealth of Nations
1776
3. See Joskow (2000b, 16) for a similar view of the unimportance of “the demise of natural monopoly
characteristics at the generation level” and the importance of the expansion of the grid, and Ruff (1999)
for an alternative view of the role of the grid and transmission pricing.
ments for and against deregulation may help explain why such mixed results might
be expected.
Chapter Summary 1-1 : Improvements in transmission, rather than changes
in generation technology, have removed the natural monopoly character of the
wholesale power market in most locations. This makes possible the replacement
of regulated generation monopolies with deregulated wholesale power markets.
In principle these can be more efficient than the old-style regulation. In practice,
California has proven bad deregulation to be worse than mediocre regulation, and
England has demonstrated that mediocre deregulation can bring cost-saving
efficiencies to a badly regulated generation monopoly.
In the short run, power-market problems tend to be more dramatic than the
benefits. The problems are primarily the result of two demand-side flaws: the almost
complete failure of customers to respond to relevant price fluctuations, and the
customer’s ability to take power from the grid without a contract. As fundamental
as these are, it is possible to design a workable market around them, but it does
require design as well as extensive and clever regulation. Recent U.S. history has
shown that there are three impediments to such progress: politics, special interests,
and overconfidence. The last is largely due to a dramatic underestimation of the
problem.
Section 1: Conditions for Deregulation. Deregulation requires the market
not be a strong natural monopoly. One view holds that small efficient gas turbines
have overturned the natural monopoly of large coal plants. Yet today’s competitive
suppliers are far larger than any coal plant, so if the size of a large coal plant were
problematic for competition, today’s markets would be uncompetitive.
Section 2: Problems with Regulation. Regulation can provide strong cost-
minimizing incentives and can hold prices down, but it must trade off one against
the other. Competition can do both at once. In practice, regulators hold prices down
near long-run average costs but leave cost-minimizing incentives too weak. The
result is high costs and high prices.
Section 3: The Benefits of Wholesale Competition. Competition provides
full strength cost-minimizing incentives and, at the same time, forces average prices
down toward their minimum. It may also encourage efficient retail prices.
Section 4: The Benefits of Real-time Pricing. Competition may induce real-
time pricing, which will reduce consumption during periods of peak demand. This
will reduce the need for installed capacity and, if extensively adopted, should
provide a net savings of about 2% of retail price. Although this could be achieved
easily under regulation, competition will provide some additional incentives, but
their consequences are still unclear.
Section 5: Problems with Deregulating Electricity. Contemporary electricity
markets have inadequate metering. Consequently it does not make sense for load
to respond to price fluctuations, and bilateral contracts cannot be physically
enforced in real time. As a result demand can and sometimes does exceed supply,
and competitive pricing is impossible at crucial times. These flaws result in high
prices that must be limited, and they provide ideal conditions for the exercise of
market power. Electricity markets are also extremely complex and prone to prob-
lems with local market power due to the inadequacies of the transmission system.
4. See Joskow and Schmalensee (1983, 54) for a discussion of firm-level economies of scale.
power plant was approaching 1000 MW, and new technologies have made 100-MW
plants almost as efficient.
If this argument were correct, then an 1000-MW supplier must in some sense
be a monopolist, and the market must need suppliers that have capacities smaller
than 1000 MW to be competitive. But in this case, deregulation must certainly have
failed in the United States because every market contains suppliers with capacities
exceeding 1000 MW. Yet no one who suggests small efficient plants are a necessary
condition for competition seems worried by the presence of huge suppliers in the
new markets.
The beliefs that the most efficient size power plant must be quite small, and
that competitive suppliers can own many such plants are contradictory. Most likely
the former is incorrect, at least in markets with peak loads of over 5000 MW.
Fortunately, vast transmission grids have made such large markets the norm. When
small efficient plants are necessary for competition, suppliers with total generating
capacity greater than the most efficient size plant should be prohibited. Greater
threats of natural monopoly conditions come from the economies of multiplant
companies and weaknesses in the power grid that effectively isolate “load pockets”
during peak load conditions.
5. Suppliers having better information than the regulators is at the root of the regulatory trade-off problem
which, though fundamental, is too complex to discuss here.
6. In reality, cost-of-service regulation does provide incentives in two ways: regulatory lag (see Joskow
2000b) which is discussed shortly, and the threat of disallowed costs.
7. For instance, yardstick regulation compares the performance of one regulated firm with other similar
firms, thus giving the regulator some of the benefit of the other firms’ knowledge without requiring the
regulator to know details (see Tirole 1997).
Regulation in Practice
Competition can hold average prices down to long-run costs while putting full
strength pressure on cost minimization. At best, regulation does a decent job of
both but does neither quite as well as competition. But how does regulation work
in practice?
Regulation tends to err in the direction of driving prices down toward cost. In
fact, most regulators believe this is their entire job and would implement pure COS
regulation if they could. Fortunately, it’s just too much bother to re-adjust rates
continuously, so the result is roughly a price cap that gets reset about every three
years. This inadvertent “regulatory lag” is a major factor in saving COS regulation
from providing no incentive at all. It provides some incentive for cost minimization,
but less than would be provided with an optimal trade-off. Even that is too little
by the standard of a competitive market. In practice, regulation has typically done
a passable job in the United States and could do much better if the effort spent
deregulating were spent improving regulation.
8. For a comparison of demand-charges and real-time rates and an explanation of why real-time rates are
crucial for reducing market power, see Borenstein (2001b).
Peak transmission use often occurs during shoulder hours, not peak hours, so
there is no easy proof of a transmission cost savings. But for simplicity assume
that this savings is 1'3 as great as the saving in generation. That brings total savings
to 3%.
9. Significant savings in transmission and distribution should not be expected because transmission lines
are typically used most heavily during off-peak hours, and both have very large fixed-cost components that
will be unaffected by deregulation.
10. More kinetic energy is stored in rotating generators, much more potential energy can be stored by
pumping water up hill and vastly more energy is stored in local fuel supplies, but all of these stores of
energy must be converted to electrical energy by the process of generation before they can be delivered.
11. See Jaffe and Felder (1996), Kahn et al. (2001), and Green (1998).
that eventually price spikes will be low enough to need no caps. This change in
market structure should be encouraged from the start. A responsible deregulation
of electricity would first fix the demand-side flaws and then start the market—they
are cheaper to fix than the problems they have already caused.
Thomas Carlyle
(1795-1881)
for significant efficiency improvements. If restructuring gets this much right, it will
reap most of the benefits presently available from deregulation of electricity.
Markets for reserves may be the next most sensible targets for deregulation
because they are so closely tied to the bulk power market. Reserves are provided
by the same generators that provide power. These markets can only be deregulated
on the supply side, and they are quite complicated to design. Retail deregulation
is easier to design, and retailing can be more fully deregulated, but there is much
less to gain. Retail costs are at most 5% of total costs, and the potential savings
are less obvious than in generation because most of the traditional retail services
are irrelevant. This is also the one area in which competition can be expected to
add a significant cost—the cost of marketing.
Section 1: Ancillary Services and the System Operator. The system
operator must keep the system in balance by keeping supply equal to demand. As
many as five markets may be required to accomplish this: one for “regulation”
which works minute by minute, and four to handle larger deviations and emergen-
cies. Collectively, these services, together with a few others, are known as ancillary
services.
Ancillary services benefit the entire market and are either public goods or have
large external effects. Consequently, all of the markets have a fully regulated
demand side, but some can be deregulated on the supply side. The system operator
service, which coordinates these markets and provides the regulated demand for
ancillary services, is a natural monopoly service and can be provided by a nonprofit
or a for-profit entity.
Section 2: Unit Commitment and Congestion Management. Traditionally
(before restructuring), system operators provided two more coordination services:
unit commitment and transmission-congestion management. Unit commitment can
be left to the generators themselves, though this may result in a small decrease in
efficiency. Transmission congestion must be managed, at least in part, by the system
operator.
Section 3: Risk Management and Forward Markets. Both generators and
their customers are risk averse and wish to avoid the fluctuating prices of the spot
market. Not only the hour-to-hour and day-to-day price variations but also the year-
to-year variations in the spot market’s average price are problematic. Forward
energy trading can hedge these risks and needs no more regulation than other
commodity markets.
Section 4: Transmission and Distribution. Delivery of electric power
requires a network of high voltage lines. Because duplicate sets of lines are wasteful,
both distribution and transmission appear to be natural monopolies. There has been
1. Markets for transmission rights that cover the cost of congestion already exist but not competitive
markets for transmission lines. Australia and Argentina are experimenting with for-profit transmission
lines. A market for monopoly transco franchises is another possibility (Wilson 1997).
2. Frequency is very precisely maintained as indicated by the following report (NERC 2000, 32). “In late
July 1999 . . . system frequency on the Eastern Interconnection dipped to one of its lowest levels in history
(59.93 Hertz).”
by the system operator. There seems to have been no cost-benefit analysis, but
balancing the system with some accuracy is absolutely necessary.
System frequency is exactly the same for all customers in an interconnection.
For example, Quebec and Florida have exactly the same frequency. As long as any
system operator maintains its frequency, every other system in the Eastern Intercon-
nection will also have exactly the right frequency. As a result, no one has much
interest in trying to maintain frequency. Economics calls this a “free-rider” problem.
It is costly to maintain the system balance, and everyone would prefer to let the
others take care of it. Consequently, some regulatory body must decide to purchase
balancing services and must charge (tax) some market participants to pay for them.
There is no alternative; with a pure free market approach, the system frequency
would be unacceptably unstable. This means the demand for balancing services
must be regulated, but they still can be supplied by a competitive market. Every
system operator must meet a balancing standard set by the North American Electric
Reliability Council (NERC), so it purchases enough balancing services to meet
this standard. Because many different generators can supply the services, there is
a good chance the market will be competitive. But it is not automatic; it depends
on the details of the market.
Self-Provision of Reserves. There are two approaches to the supply of balancing
services. The system operator can purchase the necessary services in a market and
assign the cost to either loads or generators on a pro rata basis, or it can assign each
supplier a fraction of the physical requirement. The latter approach is called “self-
providing” and is often described as a less regulated approach.3 As an example,
consider spinning reserves (spin), a key source of balancing services. Not every
generator will want to provide spin, so if physical requirements are imposed on
suppliers, a market for spin will develop. Those who find it expensive to provide
will buy from those who can provide it more cheaply, and some generators will
“self-provide.”
What is the practical difference between the physical “self-provision” approach
and the financial approach? Imagine that a supplier has been told to supply 100
MWh of spin as part of its contribution to balancing services, and that it “self-
supplies.” If the system operator had instead purchased spin directly and had
charged the supplier for 100 MWh of spin, would the supplier have been worse
off? No. It would have sold its 100 MWh of spin to the market at the spin-market
price, P, for a revenue of 100 × P, and then the system operator would have charged
it 100 × P for its share of the spin requirement. The result is the same. In both cases
the generator provides 100 MWh of spin. In neither case does it have any net cost.
So why the agitation to “self-provide?” There are several possible answers. First,
some may not understand the concept. Others may believe they can more easily
supply poor quality spin when they self-provide. Still others may not be interested
in their own requirement but may wish to provide part of the system-operator
service. In other words, they may want to be the market maker for spin and take
this business away from the system operator. If they can do it more efficiently and
with less gaming than the system operator, then they should be allowed to take over
this service.
The problem with “self-providing” is that the services are not provided to the
suppliers themselves but to the system operator. The term is deceptive. There still
must be a physical transaction between the supplier and the system operator. It is
this physical transaction, the verification of the provided reserves, that is difficult.
“Self-provision” is not a way to avoid the regulated nature of the demand side of
the ancillary service market, and it does not make the supply side more competitive.
pricing” debate. Professor William Hogan of Harvard has put forward the nodal-
pricing model which has now been accepted by PJM and the New York, and New
England ISOs. California, Australia, Alberta, and England have rejected it in favor
of a less centralized approach.
Hogan (1992, 1995, 1998) specifies a system operator that provides both unit
commitment and congestion management services.4 These two are linked together
more because of historical system operator practice or by choice than by logic. In
fact, the system operator could easily provide only congestion management and
balancing, but not unit commitment.
4. More recently Hogan (2001b) has explicitly suggested designs that make the unit commitment service
optional.
5. No-load costs, which are greater than startup costs, also cause the production cost function to be
nonconvex, but they apparently cause less trouble.
Transmission-Congestion Management
Congestion management is one of the toughest problems in electricity market
design. Although the costs imposed by congestion in an efficiently run system are
quite low, badly designed congestion pricing can make the system unmanageable.
This was demonstrated by PJM just before the official opening of its market when
it instituted a form of average-cost congestion pricing that resulted in massive
gaming of the pricing rules (Hogan 1999).
Any efficient method of congestion management will charge for the use of
congested lines. If the price charged is set correctly, the demand for the use of the
line will equal its capacity unless the price is zero, and it will be zero only if at zero
price the line is still not fully utilized. Pricing ensures that those who value the line
most get to use it and that the line’s capacity is not wasted. This is the only efficient
way to manage congestion.
Although there is only one set of efficient congestion prices (the prices set by
the “nodal pricing” approach), there are many other approaches that would in theory
give these same prices, or a good approximation of them. Wu and Varaiya proposed
the most extreme alternative to nodal pricing. In their “multi-lateral” approach (Wu
and Varaiya 1995; Varaiya 1996), the system operator would have no knowledge
of the congestion prices. It would simply assign certain parties the right to use lines
in a “reasonable but arbitrary way” that would prevent overuse of the lines. These
parties would then either exercise their rights by using the lines or would sell their
rights to those who valued the lines more. If it worked efficiently as a competitive
market should, the market would then produce the exact same prices for the use
of congested lines as the system operator would compute under nodal pricing.
Congestion prices make money by charging transmission users for a scarce
resource. The revenues collected are called the congestion rent. Because congestion
prices are the same under any efficient system, so is the congestion rent. Under
nodal pricing, the system operator collects the congestion rent. Under other systems,
such as the multi-lateral approach, some private party will collect these rents. This
is at the heart of a controversy. When generators ask to “self-manage” their conges-
tion, they are really asking to “self-collect” as much of the transmission rent as
possible.
Any system of allocating transmission rights can be thought of as selling or
giving away transmission rights. In either case the rights originate with the system
operator and are specified in such a way that the transmission lines are protected
from overuse. The supply of transmission rights must always be regulated.
There is a fundamental choice to be made: should the system operator sell the
transmission rights and use the revenues (congestion rents) to help pay for the cost
of the wires, or should the system operator give the rights away and let private
parties pocket the congestion rents?6 Where physical rights have been purchased
in the past or been acquired by paying for lines or upgrades, grandfathering these
rights, and perhaps converting them to financial rights provides regulatory continuity
6. If the system operator sells transmission rights and collects the congestion rent, it can sell the rights on
a daily or hourly basis in the form of nodal pricing, or it can sell yearly or monthly transmission rights in
periodic auctions, or these can be combined or supplemented with other approaches.
and enhances regulatory credibility. Other schemes for giving away new rights are
usually obscure and arbitrary. Except when there is clear ownership of rights to
begin with, it is preferable for the system operator to create transmission rights,
sell them, and use the resulting revenues to pay for present or future transmission
lines.
an ISO build them. Another way is to grant one company, a transco, the monopoly
right to all lines in some large geographical area. Like any monopoly of an essential
product, the transco will need regulation.
Several problems need to be considered. Transmission lines can act as both
a substitute for and a complement to generation. New transmission lines increase
competition between suppliers who may therefore oppose them, but they are a
public good because they reduce market power. The siting of a new transmission
line is a highly regulated and contentious process. It is also difficult to assign
individual physical or financial rights to the power grid in such a way that investors
make the appropriate return on their investment.
These complexities make deregulation of the market for transmission lines
impossible. The distribution system seems even more difficult to deregulate, and
so far there have been few, if any, proposals to do so.
provided quite easily under regulation, but it wasn’t, so the green choice may be
a benefit of retail competition. It allows customers to pay a premium for their energy
and then makes sure some of that premium finds its way to generators that use
renewable energy sources.
One disadvantage of retail competition is that it makes verifying the reality of
this product much more difficult. Physically, green power is identical in all respects
to coal power. The consumer cannot verify the product without the help of some
third party to audit the suppliers. The source of power is more difficult to monitor
when there are many competitive green and semi-green private companies instead
of just one regulated utility.
Another choice, often suggested but so far not implemented, is the choice of
reliability level. Clearly, some customers have a much greater need for reliability,
and this is the one way in which electricity service can differ between customers.
It is not possible to provide a more stable frequency or better voltage support on
a customer by customer basis, but some reliability (avoidance of some blackouts)
can be provided individually. This would require installing remotely controlled
individual circuit breakers. Unfortunately this is currently quite impractical. Part
of the problem is that those with a strong financial interest in this service are those
who want more reliability. This cannot be provided by installing a breaker for them;
it must be provided by installing breakers for a great many others who would be
sacrificed in an emergency to provide reliability for those who would pay for it.
Innovative Products
One view holds that competition in retail electricity will spawn innovative new
electrical products the way competition in telecommunications has spawned new
types of phones and phone services.8 But so far AC power has shown no prospects
of becoming wireless. Power engineering went through a period of rapid innovation
between 1870 and 1910 that was similar to the current innovation in telecommunica-
tions, and someday it may again. Technology has a life of its own. Competition
may spur some development of new generating technologies, but the basic AC outlet
will be around for a while.
Those who promised dramatic new physical innovations in retail power five
years ago have now shifted their focus from new kinds of electricity meters and
smart appliances to innovative billing systems. Would they have held telecommuni-
cations up as an example of the benefits of deregulation if the last fifteen years had
produced only more complex phone bills while telephones remained rotary dial?
The argument for the value of billing innovations is a curious one. In England,
electricity deregulation has brought some of the same aggravation to electricity
shopping that U.S. customers experience in shopping for phone service. Littlechild
argues that the fact that customers spend so much effort comparing rates proves
they must benefit from doing so.9 Perhaps customers draw a different conclusion
8. Though competition has spurred innovation in telecom, if competition had arrived forty years earlier,
we would not have had vacuum-tube cell phones in the 1950s. Much of what is taken to be the miracle of
telecom competition is just normal technological progress.
9. See Littlechild (2000, 11).
than economists because they understand their efforts are as much to avoid bad
rates that were previously not a danger as to find good rates that were previously
not available.10 In any case, other than real-time pricing, it is hard to imagine how
better electricity bills can bring much improvement to the life of the average
customer.
Price Competition
The latest rationale for retail competition is the benefit of price competition. Even
if customers don’t think fancy electric bills are as useful as cell phones, cheaper
bills would certainly prove popular. Littlechild (2000, p. 9) pushes price competition
as the major benefit of retail competition and lists two ways this can happen, first,
by “reducing the costs of retailing.” Unfortunately, as already noted, the costs of
retailing electricity under regulation are exceptionally small. Even with massive
improvements in efficiency, customers will probably not notice a difference, and
it is quite possible that marketing costs will more than offset any efficiency gains.
Littlechild also mentions a reduction in wholesale costs caused by “improving
wholesale power procurement.” Where does this savings come from: better genera-
tors, better operation, or a reduction in market power? With or without retail
competition, generators still keep every dollar they save, no more and no less, so
retail competition cannot possibly improve the cost-minimizing incentives of
generators. With costs the same, the only room for savings is a reduction in profit.
Because the industry cannot survive on below normal profits, this can only come
about if there is some excess profit at the outset.
So retail competition can only lower wholesale costs by reducing the market
power of wholesalers. But market power on the supply side of the wholesale market
would normally be reduced by an increase in competition on the supply side, not
by increased competition on the buyer’s (retailer’s) side. In fact more competition
on the buyers’ side means less monopsony power to counteract the monopoly power
of the suppliers.
There appears to be only one small chance for retail competition to inhibit
wholesale market power. If retailers sign long-term contracts with wholesalers,
the contracts will inhibit the wholesalers’ market power in the spot market. Unfortu-
nately, competitive retailers have a more, not less, difficult time signing long-term
contracts than the monopoly utility-distribution companies (UDCs) because their
customer base is less stable. The customers of the UDC can’t leave if there is no
retail competition, but customers of competitive retailers generally can leave on
fairly short notice and will leave if they do not like the current price. This makes
it difficult for competitive retailers to sign long-term power contracts, especially
for the supply of residential customers. If the retailer buys its power with a long-
term contract and sells it to customers under short-term contracts, it takes an
enormous risk. If the market price goes down in the future, the retailer must either
10. Recently, and long after this section was written, this phenomenon was documented in the PJM market
by Michael Rothkopf, who was the recipient of an offer to pay 38% above the going rate with only extra
cancellation penalties as compensation. In California deceptive practices similar to those found in phone-
rate competition were quickly spotted in the retail power market.
sell at a loss to its residential customers or lose them and resell its power at a loss
to someone else.
The net result seems to be that retail competition offers no benefits in reducing
wholesale market power. As it will not bring down the costs of generation, it seems
to hold little promise of improving wholesale performance. The slim hope that price
competition will save more on billing costs than it spends on marketing is a flimsy
basis for such a large experiment.
It is not too much to expect that our children will enjoy in their homes
electricity too cheap to meter.
Lewis L. Strauss
Chairman, Atomic Energy Commission
1954
costs in dollars per megawatt-hour ($/MWh). The remainder of the book confirms
this by working every example in these units.
Chapter Summary 1-3 : Energy is measured in MWh, while power and capacity
are measured in MW. All three are priced in $/MWh, as are fixed and variable costs.
Other units with the same dimensions (money divided by energy) may be used,
but this book will use only $/MWh. Screening curves plot average cost as a function
of capacity factor. The slope of the curve is variable cost, and the intercept is fixed
cost. The average cost (ACK) plotted in these graphs is not the average cost of using
a megawatt-hour of energy produced at a certain capacity factor but rather the
average cost of a megawatt-hour of generating capacity. Because the equation for
a screening curve is used through the book, understanding this distinction is crucial.
Section 1: Measuring Power and Energy. Power
Working Summary is the flow of energy and is measured in watts (W),
Readers wishing to gain only a working knowledge kilowatts (kW), megawatts (MW), or gigawatts (GW).
of measurement units for use in later chapters
should understand the following. Energy is an accumulation of power over a period of
Quantity Quantity units Price Units time. For instance, a kilowatt flowing for one hour
Energy MWh $/MWh delivers a kilowatt-hour (kWh) of energy. The price
Power MW $/MWh of both energy and power is expressed in $/MWh. It
Capacity MW $/MWh can also be expressed in “mills,” short for “milli-dol-
lars per kilowatt hour,” with 1 mill equal to $1/MWh.
Cost Symbol Cost Units
Fixed FC $/MWh Section 2: Measuring Capacity. Capacity is the
Variable VC $/MWh
potential to deliver power and is measured in mega-
watts. Like power, it is a flow.
Average ACK = FC + cf × VC $/MWh
Average ACE = FC ' cf + VC $/MWh Section 3: Pricing Capacity. “Overnight” capacity
costs are measured in $/kW and so cannot be added
Ratio Symbol Units
to or averaged with variable costs to find which gener-
Capacity factor cf none
ator could more cheaply serve load of a specific dura-
Duration D none tion. Screening curves plot the annual revenue require-
Notes: Energy is a static amount while power and ment (ARR) of a generator as a function of the genera-
capacity are rates of flow. The average cost of using
capacity, ACK, depends on the capacity factor, cf ,
tion’s capacity factor. Fixed cost (FC) is the value of
which is the fraction of time the capacity is used. The ARR for a capacity factor of zero. Since ARR is mea-
average cost of energy, ACE, produced by a specific sured in $/kWy, the same must be true of fixed cost.
generator also depends on cf . Dividing FC by 8.76 converts it to $/MWh, a more
convenient set of units. Considering the rental cost of
capacity makes these units seem more natural.
To avoid confusion when using screening curves and their associated algebra,
the distinction between the average cost of capacity (ACK ) and the average cost
of energy (ACE ) should be kept in mind. Traditional screening curves graph ACK.
2. Watts per hour has units of watts divided by hours and has no use in the present context.
3. Average revenue per kilowatt hour to ultimate residential consumers was 8.06¢/kWh, according to DOE
(2001c, Table 53).
4. The flow of available capacity is interrupted during generator outages, but the flow of installed capacity
is continuous. This chapter ignores the difference and assumes that the flow of capacity from a generator
is continuous and constant.
purposes the coal plant is the more inexpensive choice. Fuel costs must always
be taken into account when evaluating the choice of generators. Coal plants are
built because their cost of fuel per unit of energy output is less. Assume coal costs
only $10/MWh of energy produced, while the cost of fuel for a GT comes to
$35/MWh. Now which plant is cheaper?
More information is needed. The comparison depends on how much the plant
will be used, and that depends on the load it will serve. For concreteness, assume
that the load has a duration of 25% (2190 hours/year) so the plant serving it will
have a capacity factor of 25%. Now, which plant is cheaper?
Focusing on only the basics, the problem seems workable. The overnight cost
captures the fixed cost of generation, and the fuel cost per unit of output captures
the variable cost. Duration gives a sufficient description of the load. But the
problem is still impossible to solve because the fixed cost of capacity has been
measured in the wrong units. Overnight costs measured in $/kW cannot be added
to fuel costs measured in $/kWh. This would produce nonsense.
Fallacy 1-3.1 Fixed and Variable Costs Are Measured in Different Units
Because capacity is usually paid all at once, while fuel is paid for over time,
variable costs but not fixed costs should include a time dimension.
When units have the same “dimensions,” they differ only by a scale factor (a
pure number). Different quantities having units of the same dimension can be added.
For example, 1 MWh can be added to 100 kWh to get 1100 kWh (or 1.1 MWh).
But quantities whose units have different dimensions cannot be added. This is the
meaning of the famous saying, “you can’t add apples and oranges.” For example,
1 MW cannot be added to 1 MWh. Engineers and physicists pay close attention
to mismatched units because they always signal deeper trouble. Any calculation
that involves adding MW and MWh simply does not make sense.
5. Duration is measured as a percentage (see Chapter 1-4), so if all load served has the same duration, the
capacity factor equals load duration. If the load has a range of durations, these must be averaged.
6. For simplicity, this assumes that fuel is the only variable cost. Operation and maintenance include an
additional variable cost component which should be expressed in $/kWy.
Figure 1-3.1
Use of screening curves
to select a generator.
to find the variable component for any particular cf , these must be multiplied by
cf , 25% in the case of the present example.
The overnight cost of capacity is more problematic. A coal plant with an
overnight cost of $1,000/kW does not cost $1,000/kWy. This would imply a plant
life-time of one year and a discount rate of zero. The correct fixed-cost component
of ARR is the overnight cost amortized (“levelized”) over the life of the plant. This
is equivalent to computing home mortgage payments based on a mortgage that lasts
the life of the house. Obviously a discount rate (interest rate) is involved. The
formula for amortization is
r ⋅ OC r ⋅ OC
FC = − rT
≈ (1-3.1)
1− e 1 − 1 / (1 + r ) T
Notice that fixed cost (FC ) depends only on overnight cost (OC ), the discount rate
(r, in % per year) and the life of the plant (T, in years).7
Table 1-3.1 Technology Costs
VC VC OC FC FC
Corrected in Technology
( /MWh) ( /kWy) ( /kW) ( /kWy) ( /MWh)
published version. Gas turbine $35 $87.60 $350 $109.96 $12.21
Coal $10 $306.60 $1050 $40.48 $4.62
Fixed-costs are based on r = 0.1 and on T = 20 for gas turbines and 40 for coal plants. Equation 1-3.1
gives fixed costs in $/kWh which are then converted to $/MWh by dividing by 8.76.
FC is a constant flow of cost that when added to VC gives ARR, the annual
revenue requirement per kW of generation capacity. Of course this assumes a
capacity factor of 1. If cf is less, VC will be reduced proportionally, but FC is
unaffected because capacity must be paid for whether used or not. That is why FC
is termed the fixed cost. The formula for ARR is
Screening Curve: ARR = FC + cf × VC
7. Using monthly instead of annual compounding in the second formula greatly improves its accuracy as
an approximation. To do this, change r to r ' 12 in the denominator and T to 12 T.
for ARR to be valued in $/kWy, both FC and cf × VC must also be valued in $/kWy.
As these are the traditional units for ARR, the traditional units for fixed cost must
also be $/kWy. These units have the same dimension as $/MWh and any quantity
expressed in $/kWy can be converted to $/MWh by dividing by 8.76.
Variable cost is naturally expressed in $/MWh, so capacity factor, cf , must be
a pure number (dimensionless), otherwise, cf × VC would not have the same units
as ARR. This is correct; a capacity factor is just the fraction of a generator’s potential
output that is actually produced. It is actual energy output divided by potential
energy output, so the energy units cancel.
Figure 1-3.2
Capacity-cost based and
energy-cost based
screening curves.
With the price of energy always expressed as an hourly cost, it is more conve-
nient to divide the annual cost, in $/kWy, by 8.76 and arrive at an average cost per
hour for the year expressed in $/MWh. Like the annual cost, this hourly average
cost is still not a cost of energy produced but the cost of using capacity. This book
will always report capacity, energy and power costs in $/MWh for ease of compari-
son and to make addition of costs and cost averaging possible.
Although screening curves plot the average cost of capacity use, the average
cost of energy produced is also interesting and could be used to construct hyperbolic
screening curves. A pair of these is shown on the right side of Figure 1-3.2; they
are nonlinear (hyperbolic), but they still intersect at exactly the capacity factor at
which one plant becomes more economical than the other. The equations for the
linear and hyperbolic screening curves are closely related and are shown in Figure
1-3.2.
The average cost of capacity (ACK) used with capacity factor cf is the fixed cost
of using that capacity, plus cf times the variable cost of producing energy. If
cf = 1'3 , then one third of the variable cost of maximum potential energy output
must be added to the constant fixed cost which increases the average cost per unit
of capacity by cf × VC.
The average cost of energy (ACE) when the genera-
Screening Curves tor runs with capacity factor cf is the variable cost of
A traditional screening curve plots average cost as producing that energy, plus the fixed cost of the capac-
a function of capacity factor. When using the screen- ity divided by cf . If cf = '3 , then fixed costs must be
1
ing curve equation, this average cost can be con- spread over only '3 of the total possible energy output,
1
fused with the average cost of the energy produced so they are multiplied by 3 (divided by cf ) before being
by a certain type of generator. Instead, it is the added to VC.
average cost of using a unit of capacity. A load slice is a horizontal strip cut from a load-
Screening curves could have been defined using duration curve (see Chapter 1-4.1). Depending on its
the average cost of energy. Then as the capacity
average duration it will be served by some particular
factor approached zero the average cost would
approach infinity. The average-energy-cost equation
technology, baseload, midload, or peaking. Any given
is used to analyze market equilibria in later chapters, load slice is defined by a capacity, Kslice, which is the
but nonstandard screening curves are never used. height of the slice, and an average duration, D. It also
has a total energy requirement, E = D × Kslice. To serve
this load, generation capacity of Kslice must be installed and must run with a capacity
factor of cf = D. Having selected a technology, one can compute the average cost
per MW-of-capacity of serving the load, ACK, and the average cost per MWh-of-
energy of serving the load, ACE. The total cost of serving load is then given by both
Kslice × ACK and E × ACE. Because Kslice and E are both fixed, choosing the technol-
ogy that minimizes either ACK or ACE will minimize the total cost of energy. This
is why either the traditional or the hyperbolic screening curves can be used.
These relationships can be summarized as follows. For a particular load slice
served by generators with fixed cost, FC, and variable cost, VC, the average cost
of capacity and energy can be found as follows:
Capacity: ACK = FC + cf × VC = FC + D × VC (1-3.1)
Energy: ACE = FC ' cf + VC = FC ' D + VC (1-3.2)
The capacity factor of the generator, cf , equals the average duration of the load, D.
No one uses hyperbolic screening curves, but when an average cost is computed
for a specific technology, say by DOE, a value for ACE (not ACK) is always com-
puted. Typically, DOE might report the overnight cost (OC), some information
about fuel costs, and a value for ACE based on technical capacity factor (cf ).8 In
other words, DOE reports some technologically determined value on the technol-
ogy’s hyperbolic screening curve.
ACK is used to determine the optimal durations of various generation technolo-
gies, and from these durations the optimal investment in these technologies. Since
competitive markets optimize technology, ACK is also used to determine competitive
outcomes. Either ACE or ACK may be used to compare the cost of peak energy with
the value of lost load, depending on whether peaker costs are equated to the value
of lost load or the average hourly cost of lost load (see Chapter 2-2 and 2-3). ACE
is also well suited to DOE’s interest in alternative technologies—nuclear, wind,
solar, and so on. These have in common capacity factors which, even in a market
environment, are not affected by normal variations in market structure but are
instead technologically determined because their variable costs are almost always
below the market price. They run whenever they are physically able, so their
capacity factor is determined by their technical capability. The economics of an
alternative technology can be assessed by comparing its ACE with the market’s
average price.
Standard technology generators have capacity factors determined by the market
and not just by their technology. In this case, the duration of the load they serve,
which determines their capacity factor, needs to be determined from their fixed
and variable costs along with those of other technologies. This is done with screen-
ing curve analysis, or with algebra based on screening curves. Traditional linear
screening curves prove simplest. These curves and their associated algebra will
be used throughout the book, as is the formula for ACE.
8. See DOE (1998a) Tables 14–17. In a table of cost characteristics of new generating technologies (DOE
2001a, Table 43) OC is given, but not FC. In a slide labeled “Electricity Generation Costs,” DOE (2001b)
reports the capital costs in mills/kWh. As the title indicates, these are FC ' cf , for cf determined by
technology-based capacity factors, and so are components of ACK, as advertised in the title and thus points
on the hyperbolic screening function.
And when the Rain has wet the Kite and Twine, so that it can conduct the Electric Fire freely,
you will find it stream out plentifully from the Key on the Approach of your Knuckle.
Benjamin Franklin
1752
Figure 1-4.1
A load-duration curve.
Load-Duration Curves
A load-duration curve can be constructed for a given region (or for any collection
of loads) by measuring the total load at hourly intervals for each of the 8760 hours
in a year, sorting them, and graphing them starting with the highest load. The result
is a curve that slopes downward from the maximum load in the peak hour, hour
1, to the minimum load, baseload, in the most off-peak hour, hour 8760 (see Figure
1-4.1).
Duration is traditionally measured in hours per year, but both hours and years
are measures of time, so duration is dimensionless, which means it can be expressed
as a pure number, a ratio, or percentage. To convert from units of hours per year
(h/year) to a pure number, simply multiply by 1 in the form (1 year) ' (8760 h).
Duration has a natural interpretation as the probability that load will be at or above
a certain level. To use this interpretation pick a load level, say 35 GW, and using
the load-duration curve, find the corresponding duration, 20% in this case. This
1. Service industries such as restaurants and airlines often have demand fluctuations which cause similar
problem because their output is not storable, but they tend to use the same technology on and off peak.
indicates that load is 35 GW or greater 20% of the time. Put another way, the
probability of load being 35 GW or greater in a randomly selected hour is 20%.
This interpretation is most convenient.
2. There is no natural definition of short- and long-run demand elasticity, which can be defined usefully
over any time horizon from five minutes to twenty years. This text will use short-run elasticity to mean
something on the order of one day and long-run to mean about five years.
Figure 1-4.2
The effect of price
elasticity on load
duration.
Figure 1-4.3
Using screening curves
to find the optimal mix of
technologies.
includes the effect of price on demand. When it is used along with the screening
curves of the available technologies, the traditional method should predict the mix
of technologies observed in the market if the market is in long-run equilibrium.
In practice many complications must be overcome.
Losses
In real networks, a few percent of the power consumed is consumed by the network.
This consumption should be considered part of demand even though it serves no
end used. With this convention, the system can be viewed as maintaining a perfect
balance between supply and consumption (including losses) at all times and between
supply and demand whenever customers are getting the power they want.
3. More precisely, the amount stored is minuscule and cannot be utilized for trade.
just that. At substations, where very high transmission voltages are reduced to the
lower, but still high, distribution voltage, there are automatically controlled trans-
formers. These adjust so that the distribution voltage remains relatively constant
even when the transmission voltage drops. Because of these devices, more of the
power flow adjustment that accompanies the loss of a generator is accomplished
through frequency reduction than through voltage reduction. Nonetheless both can
and do happen.
4. If the frequency difference between Maine and Florida were 0.001 Hz, for one minute, it would cause
an accumulated phase change between the two states of 22 degrees. This would lead to dramatic changes
in power flow. Thus while the frequency lock between utilities is not exact, it is extremely tight, and there
can be no persistent frequency difference. One utility cannot have a problem unless they all do.
generally unwanted because appliances are built and operated on the assumption
that power will be delivered at a frequency of 60 Hz.
Because frequency indicates the discrepancies between supply and demand,
frequency is the right guide for interconnection-wide price adjustment. When
frequency is high, price should be reduced; when frequency is low, price should
be raised. This is the classic adjustment process for keeping supply equal to demand.
Definition Demand
The demand for power is the amount of power that would be consumed if system
frequency and voltage were equal to their target values for all consumers. Note
that shed load is included as part of demand. This is an economic definition and
contradicts the engineering definition provided by North American Electric
Reliability Council (NERC). (Often “load” is used to mean demand.)
Result 1-4.1 Supply Equals Consumption but May Not Equal Demand
As in all markets, demand is the amount customers would buy at the market price
were supply available. If voltage or frequency is low, customers consume less
power than they would like so supply is less than demand.
As always, the real world adds one more layer of complexity. The frequency
in every power market in an interconnection is exactly the same. Thus frequency
reveals nothing about the supply and demand conditions in any particular market
but only about the aggregate supply and demand conditions of the entire intercon-
nection. Consequently individual markets cannot rely on the frequency alone to
determine their price adjustments.
NERC defines another control variable that takes account of both frequency
and the net excess flow out of a trading region (the net interchange). The net excess
outflow is the actual outflow minus the scheduled outflow. An excess outflow is
a strong signal that supply is greater than demand in the trading region. If the
frequency is high in the interconnection this is a weak signal of excess supply in
any particular market. These two signals are combined to form a single indicator
of excess supply for each market. The indicator is called the area control error, or
ACE. Control areas are required to keep their ACE near zero, and they do. ACE
is the main indicator of the supply–demand balance in every control area in the
United States and when there is a market, it is the signal that determines whether
the price will be increased or decreased by the system operator.
The rich, . . . in spite of their natural selfishness and rapacity, . . . though the sole end which they
propose . . . be the gratification of their own vain and insatiable desires, they divide with the poor
the produce of all their improvements. They are led by an invisible hand to make nearly the same
distribution of the necessaries of life, which would have been made, had the earth been divided
into equal portions among all its inhabitants, and thus without intending it, without knowing
it, advance the interest of the society.
Adam Smith
The Theory of Moral Sentiments
1759
1. Under the special and uncommon conditions of Bertrand competition, two competitors are enough.
Short-Run Competition
The Efficient-Competition Result has limitations. It does not mean that every free
market is efficient, or even that every free market in which suppliers are price takers
is efficient. Because of these limitations, economics has carefully defined both
competition and efficiency and has added two more concepts: well-behaved cost
functions and good information. The modern Efficient-Competition Result can
be summarized as follows:
find the competitive equilibrium which consists of an optimal set of trades. (Prob-
lems with ill-behaved, nonconvex, costs and lack of information are discussed in
Chapter 3-8.)
Long-Run Competition
A short-run competitive equilibrium is (short-run) efficient; it makes the best use
of presently available productive resources. A long-run competitive equilibrium
guarantees that the right investments in productive capacity have been made but
requires that the three short-run conditions be met and adds two new ones. Produc-
tion costs must not possess the conditions for a natural monopoly (see Section 1-
1.1), and competitors must be able to enter the market freely.5 With free entry,
if there are above-normal profits to be made, new suppliers will enter which will
reduce the level of profits. In this way free entry ensures that profits will not be
above normal. A normal profit level is the key characteristic of a long-run competi-
tive equilibrium. Barriers to entry is the term used to describe market characteris-
tics that prevent free entry.
Efficiency and Total Surplus
Almost every proposed market design is declared efficient, but in economics the
term has a specific meaning. The simplest meaning applies to productive efficiency
which means that what is being produced is being produced at the least possible
cost. Minimizing cost is often the most difficult part of the market designer’s
problem, so this meaning is generally sufficient.
When not qualified as productive efficiency, efficiency includes both the supply
and demand sides of the market.6 Efficiency means (1) the output is produced by
the cheapest suppliers, (2) it is consumed by those most willing to pay for it, and
(3) the right amount is produced. These three can be combined into a single criterion
by using the concept of consumer surplus.
Figure 1-5.2
Total surplus equals the
area between the demand
curve and the marginal
cost curve.
A consumer’s demand curve measures how much the consumer would pay for
the first kilowatt-hour consumed, and the second, and so on. Generally the more
consumed, the less would be paid for the next kilowatt-hour. Because the initial
kilowatt-hours are so valuable, the total value of consumption is generally much
greater than the amount paid. The difference between the maximum a consumer
would pay as revealed by the consumer’s demand curve and what the consumer
actually does pay is the consumer’s surplus.
Profit is analogous to consumer surplus and is often called producer surplus.
It is total revenue minus total cost, while consumer surplus is total value to consum-
ers, V, minus total consumer cost, CC. (V is sometimes called gross consumer
surplus, and is the area under the demand curve for all consumption.) Both V and
CC are measured in dollars. If the sum of profit and consumer surplus is maximized,
the market is efficient, and all three of the above criteria follow.
When profit (R ! C ) and consumer surplus (V ! CC ) are added, the consumer
costs (CC ) and producer revenue (R ) cancel because they are the same. The result
is total surplus (V ! C ), consumer value minus producer cost. Consequently
efficiency is the same as maximizing total surplus.
The Efficient-Competition Result
Result 1-5.1 Competitive Prices Are Short- and Long-Run Efficient
If productions costs are well behaved so competitive prices exist, these prices will
induce short-run (dispatch) efficiency and long-run (investment) efficiency.
Note that the Efficient-Competition Result does not say that a market’s prices will
be competitive if costs are well behaved. That conclusion requires the lack of market
power and good information. The Efficient-Competition Result says that if market
prices are competitive then supply and demand will be efficient. Assuring competi-
tive prices is the main problem addressed by this book.
7. Demand-side management concerns itself primarily with information problems on the demand side of
the market. These problems also deserve attention.
8. For a more complete treatment of the microeconomics of competition presented with power markets
in mind, see Rothwell and Gomez (2002).
Quantity Adjustment. A price taking supplier will increase output if its marginal
cost, MC, is less than the market price, P, and will decrease its output if MC > P.
Its profit increases by (P ! MC ) for every unit produced when P is higher than MC
and decreases by (MC ! P ) when P is lower.
Price Adjustment. Whenever demand exceeds supply, suppliers raise their prices,
and whenever supply exceeds demand, they lower prices.
Equilibrium. The quantity adjustment dynamic causes the marginal cost to equal
the market price in a competitive market. The price adjustment dynamic causes
the quantity supplied to equal the quantity demanded. When supply equals demand,
the market is said to have cleared, and the price that accomplishes this is called
the market-clearing price, or the equilibrium price, or, for a competitive market,
the competitive price. Together the two adjustment mechanisms bring a competitive
market to a competitive equilibrium.
If the expected market price is so low that a supplier cannot enter the market
and cover all costs, no supplier will enter. More specifically, if a new generation
unit cannot cover all costs, no new units will be built. The result will be a gradually
diminishing supply of generation (due to retirements of old plants) in the face of
gradually increasing demand. This tightening of the market will cause the price
to rise, and eventually price will be high enough to cover all costs.
Similarly, if price is so high that costs are more than covered, suppliers will
build new generating units. This will increase supply and cause the price to fall.
The result of this long-run dynamic is that the profit in any competitive market
returns to the normal level of profit (zero) in the long-run competitive equilibrium.
The trouble with the world is not that people know too little,
but that they know so many things that ain't so.
Mark Twain
(1835–1910)
Section 1: The Role of Marginal Cost. Marginal costs play a key role in cost-
based power auctions because they help determine the competitive price. They also
play a key role in analyzing market power and gain their importance by defining
the competitive supply curve for individual generators. To find the market (aggre-
gate) supply curve, individual supply curves are summed horizontally.
Section 2: Marginal-Cost Fallacies. In power-market analysis, marginal cost
is often defined as the cost of the last unit produced, but this definition is found
in no economics text. A second fallacy asserts that when marginal cost is ambigu-
ous, the competitive price is ambiguous. Together these lead to a variety of errone-
ous conclusions, such as “the competitive price is above marginal cost,” and “the
competitive price is ambiguous.”
Section 3: The Definition of Marginal Cost. When a marginal-cost curve
is discontinuous (has a sudden jump), marginal cost can be specified only within
a range at the points of discontinuity. This range extends from the left-hand to the
right-hand marginal cost at the point under consideration. For all points where the
curve is continuous, the range is a single point equal to the standard marginal cost.
Section 4: Marginal Cost Results. The competitive price is within the
marginal-cost range of every competitive generator and within the marginal-cost
range of the market. If even one supplier has a supply curve that is continuous at
the market price, the market supply curve is continuous at that price and the
competitive price is equal to the standard marginal cost which is well defined. In
any case, the competitive price is the price at which the supply and demand curves
intersect.
Section 5: Working with Marginal Costs. This book assumes that supply
curves have extremely large but finite slopes rather than the infinite slopes fre-
quently assumed. This is a more realistic assumption and has no practical conse-
quences, but it has the simplifying property of making marginal cost well defined
and the marginal cost of all operating competitive generators equal to the market
price.
Section 6: Scarcity Rent. Scarcity rent is revenue less variable cost and is
needed to cover startup and fixed costs. Economics refers to this as “inframarginal
rent,” and has no separate definition of a scarcity rent. A folk-definition defines
scarcity rent as actual revenue minus the maximum revenue that is collected just
before the system runs completely out of capacity. Used with a stylized model, this
definition has some appeal, but when applied to real systems it is highly ambiguous
and misleading.
Figure 1-6.1
Adding individual supply
curves horizontally to
find the market supply
curve. If B is continuous,
A + B is also.
Fallacies
Two basic fallacies underlie a series of misconceptions surrounding competitive
pricing and market power. These are (1) the Marginal-Cost Fallacy and (2) the
Ambiguous-Price Fallacy. Both of these will be illustrated using Figure 1-6.2, which
shows a normal demand curve and a supply curve that is constant at $30/MWh
up to an output of 10 GW, the capacity limit of all available generation.
The Marginal-Cost Fallacy takes two forms. The simple form asserts that
marginal cost at Q = 10,000 MW is $30/MWh in Figure 1-6.2. The subtle form
asserts that nothing can be said about the marginal cost at this output level. Some
of the conclusions drawn from these assertions are as follows:
1. The competitive price is $30/MWh, and the market should be designed to
hold prices down to this level.
2. The competitive price is $30/MWh, and this is too low to cover fixed costs,
so marginal-cost prices are inappropriate for power markets.
3. Scarcity rents are needed to raise prices above marginal-cost-based prices.
4. Market power is necessary to raise prices to an appropriate level.
5. The competitive price cannot be determined.
Figure 1-6.2
A normal market
equilibrium for an
abnormal supply curve.
All of these conclusions assume that there is some problem with standard
economics caused by the supply curve coming to an abrupt end instead of turning
up smoothly as it does in undergraduate texts. In fact, economic theory has no
difficulty with this example, and all of the above conclusions are false. Consider
a competitive market, with many suppliers and many customers, described by the
curves in Figure 1-6.2. What if the price in this market were $30/MWh? At this
price, the demand curve shows an excess demand of about 4 GW. Some customers
trying to buy more power are willing to pay up to $70/MWh for another MW of
supply. They will find a supplier and offer to pay considerably more than $30, and
the supplier will accept. This shows that the competitive price is above $30/MWh.
The story will be repeated many times, with different values, until the market price
reaches $70/MWh. At that price every supplier will produce at full output, so the
supply will be 10 GW, and demand will be 10 GW. At any higher price demand
would fall short of supply, so the price would fall, and at any lower price, demand
would exceed supply, so the price would rise. There is nothing unusual about this
equilibrium; it is the classic story of how price clears a market by equating supply
and demand.
The Marginal-Cost Fallacy
Fallacy 1-6.1 Marginal Cost Equals the Cost of the Last Unit Produced
Marginal cost equals the savings from producing less even when this is different
from the cost of producing more.
(Subtle Version)
Nothing can be said about marginal cost at the point where a supply curve ends
or jumps from one level to another.
But shouldn’t price equal marginal cost? In this example, all that can be said
is that marginal cost is greater than $30/MWh. So there is no contradiction between
price and marginal cost, but they cannot be proven to be equal. The desire to pin
down marginal cost precisely seems to arise from a belief that competitive suppliers
should set price equal to marginal cost and thereby determine the market price.
But this logic is backwards. As explained in Section 1-5.3, suppliers set price to
clear the market and set quantity to bring marginal cost in line with price. In this
example, the market-clearing forces of supply and demand determine price unam-
biguously, and although marginal cost is ambiguous, it is greater than $30/MWh
which is enough to determine supply unambiguously. Everything of practical
importance is precisely determined.
Having analyzed the example, the preceding list of incorrect conclusions can
be restated in their.
1. The competitive price is not $30/MWh, and the market design should not
hold price to this level.
2. The competitive price is high enough to contribute significantly to fixed
cost recovery.
3. No mysterious “scarcity rent” need be added to the marginal cost of physical
production.
4. Market power is not needed if the market is allowed to clear.
5. The competitive price is $70/MWh.
Figure 1-6.3
Right- and left-hand
marginal costs.
Result 1-6.1 Competitive Suppliers Set Output so MCLH <– P <– MCRH
A competitive producer sets output to a level at which its marginal-cost range,
MCR, contains the market price, P, whether or not that is the competitive price.
First, a price-taking supplier will decrease output as long as P < MCLH because
producing one less unit will save MCLH and cost only P in lost revenues. Thus, the
savings is greater than the cost. Similarly, if MCRH < P, the supplier will increase
output. Thus whenever P lies outside the range between left- and right-hand
marginal costs, the supplier will adjust output. When the range is below P, output
is increased, which raises the range and vice versa when MCR is above P. As a
result, the marginal-cost range will end up encompassing P.
This means that in a competitive market, price will never exceed marginal cost;
this would violate basic economics. Technically, P > MC can never be proven true
in a competitive market.1 Competitive price will always be less than or equal to
left-hand marginal cost, and there is no need for it exceed this value for fixed cost
recovery.2
1. Even those who best understand these concepts sometimes add to the confusion. “Thus in the absence
of market power by any seller in the market, price may still exceed the marginal production costs of all
facilities producing output in the market at that time.” (Borenstein 1999, 3) “. . . the price of electricity
has to rise above its short-run marginal cost from time to time, or peaking capacity would never cover its
fixed costs.” (Green 1998, 4).
2. Part 3 discusses “nonconvex costs,” complexities of the production cost function that require deviations
from marginal cost. Essentially this means that startup costs and other short-run, avoidable costs must be
covered by price.
Figure 1-6.4
The smallest possible
change in the supply
curve of Figure 1-6.2
restores all normal
economic properties.
This result can be extended from a single producer to the whole market. The
MCRH of the market is the least cost of producing one more unit, so it is the mini-
mum of the individual marginal-cost ranges. Similarly, the market MCLH is the
maximum individual MCLH. In a competitive market, every supplier is a price taker
and adjusts its output until P is within its marginal-cost range. Thus P is less than
or equal to every individual MCRH, so it is less than or equal to the MCRH of the
supplier with the lowest MCRH, which is the MCRH of the market. Similarly, P is
greater than or equal to the MCLH of the market.
The range from the market MCLH to the market MCRH is contained within the
marginal-cost ranges of each individual supplier. If even one supplier in the market
has MCLH = MCRH, the market will also have this property. In other words, if even
one supplier has a well defined-marginal cost at the market price, then the market
itself has a well-defined marginal cost.
As shown in Figure 1-6.4, giving the marginal cost curve a nearly, but not perfectly,
vertical slope makes no noticeable difference to any economic result. And this is
how it should be. Economics should not and does not depend on splitting hairs.
Notice that in the finitely-sloped model, price really does equal marginal cost at
the intersection of the two curves. The price and quantity dynamics of a market
with the vertical supply curve will be essentially the same as those of the continuous
market. In this example, at a price different from $70 and a quantity different from
10 GW, the markets have essentially identical gaps between supply and demand
and between price and marginal cost. So they adjust price and quantity in the same
way.
This demonstrates that the standard method of finding the competitive equilib-
rium works even when the marginal cost curves have infinite slopes. Of course
if the slope is infinite at the intersection of supply and demand, marginal cost will
be technically undefined. Yet pretending that the true marginal cost is determined
by this simple short cut will never give the wrong answer to any real-world question.
an emergency operating range in their bids and the total capacity available in this
range is 1,900 MW out of a total installed capacity of about 60,000 MW.3 As long
as there is one such generator in a market, the market’s marginal cost curve is
continuous. Real markets always have well-defined marginal costs and the competi-
tive price equals that marginal cost. The difficulties resolved in this chapter only
matter for the “simplified” diagrams used by power-market analysts.
This book also will use the same simplified diagrams but without taking the
vertical segments literally. Such supply curves will have constant marginal costs
up to the nominal “maximum” output level, but above that marginal costs will
increase rapidly. If the supply curve is flat at $30 but the market price is $50, the
generator’s marginal cost will be $50 and it will produce on the steeply sloped
segment. When referring to such a generator, it is both wrong and confusing to say
its marginal cost is $30 as is the custom. To avoid this confusion, the marginal cost
of a generator’s supply curve to the left of the “maximum” output level will be
termed its variable cost. This is not entirely standard, but it is in keeping with the
term’s normal usage which refers to all costs that vary with the output level.
3. Personal communication from Joe Bowring, head of PJM’s Market Monitoring Unit, January 7, 2002.
4. Samuelson (1973, 623) comes close to using the term when he says “Competitively determined rents
are the results of a natural scarcity.” His definition of such rents is the long-run analog of the short-run
definition of scarcity rent given here.
5. This is greater than short-run profit by the amount of startup costs and no-load costs which will be
ignored until Part 3.
Figure 1-6.5
Folk-definition of
scarcity rent.
Say there are only ten types of generators on the market, and call the one with
the highest variable cost the peaker. Next assume that there are no out-of-date
generators with higher variable costs installed in the system. Finally assume that
no installed generator has an emergency operating range in which its marginal
costs increase dramatically as it increases its output beyond its normal rating. With
these assumptions, peakers will earn enough to cover more than variable cost only
when the system runs out of capacity. In other words, peakers can cover their fixed
costs only from scarcity rents but not from any nonscarcity inframarginal rents.
All other generators cover their fixed costs from a combination of scarcity and
nonscarcity rents. The left half of Figure 1-6.5 illustrates this property of an ideal-
ized supply curve.
The folk definition has the advantage of allowing the following types of state-
ments which seem designed to segregate scarcity conditions from the normal
operating conditions of the market.
1. Scarcity rents pay capital costs of units that run infrequently.
2. In the long-run competitive equilibrium, scarcity rents are just high enough
to cover the fixed costs of peakers.
3. Scarcity rents are paid only infrequently.
This appears to ratify the view that power markets are qualitatively different in their
cost structure and consequently cannot be analyzed with the standard marginal-cost
apparatus.
In the idealized model, these statements are true, although they give the impres-
sion that scarcity rents are mainly or wholly associated with peakers. In fact, under
the folk definition, every type of generator receives the same amount of scarcity
rent per MWh. In addition, the average scarcity rent in $/MWh does not equal the
fixed cost of peakers but is greater by a factor of one over the duration of the
peaker’s use, something that is not easily determined.
Two problems with this definition make it unworkable in a real market. First,
there are likely to be old generators on the system with variable costs greater than
the most expensive new generator that would be built (the peaker). In this case
scarcity will not set in until the old generator is at full output. This will expand the
nonscarcity rents and shrink the scarcity rents to the point where they no longer
cover the fixed costs of a peaker. Second, there will be some (probably many)
generators with marginal cost curves that continue on up to some very high but
ill-defined value. This will reduce scarcity rents to some negligible and indetermin-
able value. Proving scarcity rents exist requires proving price is above the point
where the supply curve becomes absolutely vertical; absolutes are notoriously hard
to prove.
Because of these shortcomings and the limited usefulness of the folk definition,
this book will use only the definition given above that coincides with “inframarginal
rents,” a term that has proven itself useful in economics. This is in keeping with
the chapter’s general view that generation cost functions present no new problems
of consequence and require only a minimal expansion of the definition of marginal
cost and then only to deal with the stylized mathematics of discontinuous cost
functions.
A Marginal-Cost Example
* MCLH is the savings from producing one unit less. MCRH is the cost of producing
one unit more and is considered arbitrarily high, or infinite, if another unit cannot
be produced.
The work I have set before me is this . . . how to get rid of the evils of competition while retaining
its advantages.
Alfred Marshall
(1842-1924)
1. When considering the wholesale market, retail billing is part of structure. When considering the retail
market it is simply a market outcome.
low operating reserves are. This links concerns about reliability with the incentive
to invest.
The high prices paid by the system operator to meet reliability requirements
control all high prices in the power market. Customers can choose between forward
purchases and letting the system operator buy power for them in real time, and they
choose the cheaper alternative. This holds the price in all forward markets down
to the price that the system operator charges for real-time purchases, and it charges
only as much as it pays. So the price paid by the system operator sets a limit on
the price paid in all markets.3 During the intervals when its requirements for
operating reserves are not met, the system operator’s pricing policy controls the
price spikes and high forward prices that induce investment.
Structure vs. Architecture of the Balancing Market. The balancing market
keeps supply and demand in balance until the system operator is forced to balance
the system by shedding load. This market must be administered by the system
operator, but it may include a sizable bilateral component. It may be integrated with
the markets for operating reserves, or these may be separate. These are questions
of market architecture. At a more detailed level, there are innumerable choices
concerning market rules.
The market rules and architecture do not determine the height and duration of
real-time price spikes, nor how closely voltage and frequency will be maintained,
nor the chance that the system will not recover from an unexpected generation
failure.4 These fundamentals are determined by the structure of the balancing
market. The rules and architecture determine how efficiently trades are organized,
who gets their transaction terminated when reliability is threatened, and how closely
prices approximate the competitive level.
The structure of the balancing market is in part determined by the interconnec-
tion’s reliability authority (NERC) and in part by local design. It is also influenced
by the regional regulatory authority (FERC) when it caps real-time prices. The
accuracy of balancing and short-term reliability are largely determined by the
structure of the balancing market. Less obviously, price spikes, generation invest-
ment and long-term reliability are also largely determined by the balancing market.
From this perspective, current balancing market structures appear haphazard and
inappropriate. Part 2 examines these problems and presents methods for designing
a better structure.
1-7.2 TRANSMISSION
Market structure includes the arrangement and capacity of power lines. Insufficient
capacity can cause bottlenecks and local market power while additional capacity
can expand the size of the market and reduce market power. The effect of transmis-
sion on market power makes transmission expansion more valuable in a competitive
than in a regulated market.
3. The proposition that a price limit in the real-time market effectively caps the forward markets was well
tested by the California Power Exchange.
4. This assumes that the rules are at least modestly functional.
While this structural component can only be changed slowly, it is one whose
design cannot be ignored. Unless there is a reversal of the 100-year trend, new lines
will be needed for reliability and economy as demand for power continues to grow.
These will be built either at the direction of market designers working for the system
operator or by for-profit transcos whose incentives, determined by regulators,
govern their choice of transmission upgrades.
So far, this structural component has received the most attention, and the design
issues have proven to be complex and contentious. Australia, New Zealand,
Argentina, Alberta, California and Britain have all provided examples of transmis-
sion design issues that have been resolved with only partial success. Alberta’s case
is particularly interesting because it has highlighted the trade-offs between transmis-
sion and generator location. Alberta’s for-profit Transmission Administrator chose
not to upgrade Alberta’s major transmission path and instead offered long-term
incentives to new generation investment in locations that would alleviate the need
for more transmission. This was quite successful, but two years later the TA strongly
favored the now unnecessary upgrade in order to facilitate exports from northern
Alberta to the United States.
Alberta’s transmission issues did not involve the impact of transmission on
market power, but in both Australia and California, this has been a prominent
concern. Due to their historic rivalry, California’s two largest investor-owned
utilities are connected by inefficiently small power lines (Path 15). As a conse-
quence, these frequently inhibit trade, causing increased generation costs and
increased market power. Besides such major bottlenecks, there are dozens of smaller
ones causing infrequent but locally severe market power. Over half of the generators
in California are regulated at times, supposedly because of these transmission
limitations.5 While a must-run classification is sometimes only an excuse for a
profitable regulatory “must-run” contract, many cases reflect real transmission
constraints.
5. “Must-run” generators are paid regulated prices, which are sometimes quite high, when they are
required to run due to transmission constraints.
6. This demand-side flaw was largely responsible for California’s market power problems and blackouts.
This fact is often ignored because the flaw, being structural, is considered akin to a law of nature and thus
automatically exempted from blame.
7. This result is based on the following real-time rates. Let Q(t) be the “base” profile that would be
charged the flat monthly rate. A real-time customer that actually uses R(t) is charged at the flat rate times
[the real-time cost of R(t) divided by the real-time cost of Q(t)].
8. See Borenstein, Bushnell, and Wolak (2000), the California Independent System Operator (2000),
Joskow and Kahn (2001a and 2001b), and Wolak, Nordhaus and Shapiro (2000).
9. The vesting contract should not specify which plants are providing the power, only that the new owner
of the plant will provide the power. This has the desired effect on market power without unnecessarily
restricting plant operation. See Wolak (2000) for the effectiveness of vesting contracts.
Note that the stricter the limit, the less valuable the plants will be. Exercising
market power is more difficult for those with a smaller market share. Because a
lower limit on market share reduces the profitability of generators, it reduces the
price they will fetch when sold. Consequently, the utility required to divest will
oppose any reduction in such a limit. It will argue that economies of scale or scope
require a purchaser to own a large amount of capacity in order to operate a plant
efficiently. These can be important effects, particularly when several plants are
located on a single site, but disinterested expert opinions should be sought on the
extent of such economies. Many suppliers own very little capacity in a market. Most
economies from multiple plant ownership can be achieved by owning plants in
different markets.10
10. Alberta, a relatively small market, has attempted to avoid the conflict between small concentration
ratios and efficiency by selling twenty-year contracts for a plant’s control and output, while leaving the
plant’s operation and ownership in the hands of the utilities. It remains to be seen how well this has
worked.
The whole world may be looked upon as a vast general market made up of diverse special markets
where social wealth is bought and sold. Our task then is to discover the laws to which these
purchases and sales tend to conform automatically. To this end, we shall suppose that the market
is perfectly competitive, just as in pure mechanics we suppose, to start with, that machines are
perfectly frictionless.
Leon Walras
Elements of Pure Economics
1874
once one has been included in the design list. By bringing the entire market into
focus and specifying the market’s architecture, the designer can take account of
linkages between markets and decide on the types of submarkets. The architectural
approach to design helps with understanding interactions and relationships between
submarkets and thus with avoiding the proverbial “Chinese menu” approach.
Linkages are the heart of market architecture, but the science of linkages is not
well developed. Timing, location, and arbitrage are the keys to most naturally arising
(implicit) linkages, while explicit linkages are limited only by the imagination of
the designer. Unfortunately many of these have unpleasant side effects. A careful
examination of the market’s architecture is the best antidote to inappropriately
designed linkages.
Section 1: Listing the Submarkets. The architecture of the entire market
includes the list of both designed and naturally occurring submarkets. Many
controversies surround the questions of which particular submarkets to include.
For example, a day-ahead centralized energy market may or may not be included,
and some suggest that the only designed markets to include are those for transmis-
sion rights and ancillary services.
Besides the designed submarkets, others already exist or will arise naturally.
If these play an important role in the functioning of the entire market, they are part
of its architecture.
Section 2: Market Types: Bilateral Through Pools. Bilateral markets can
be, in order of increasing centralization, search, bulletin-board, or brokered markets,
while mediated markets can be dealer markets, exchanges, or pools. Public central-
ized markets tend to have certain advantages over private markets that are decentral-
ized: lower transaction costs, quicker transactions, greater transparency of price,
and easier monitoring. Decentralized private markets are more flexible while
centralized private markets are similar to their public counterparts.
Energy exchanges accept only bids that, according to their bid-in values, at least
break even. Pools accept some apparently losing bids. Accepted bids that would
otherwise lose money are compensated with a “make-whole” side payment. Ex-
changes do not make side payments. Pools typically use much more complex bids,
though exchanges can also use multipart bids.
Section 3: Market Linkages. Implicit linkages are most often produced by
arbitrage, the most important example being the arbitrage-induced equality between
a forward price for delivery at time T and the expected spot price at that time. The
selection and arrangement of submarkets can take advantage of implicit links as
when ancillary-service markets are sequenced so that excess supply in one spills
into the next. Alternatively, multiproduct markets can be designed with explicit
linkages, sometimes increasing efficiency but also adding complexity.
signed as part of the public design process contemplated here are by definition
public markets and are almost always centralized. Submarkets that play a significant
role in an entire market should be included in the list of markets even if not designed
as part of the current project because they are a vital part of the market’s architec-
ture. Linkages between designed and naturally occurring or pre-existing submarkets
are crucial to the health of the entire market.
While there are no clear-cut rules, several possible motivations should be consid-
ered:
1. Nondiscriminatory access.
2. Completeness (trading of a product not otherwise traded).
3. Reduced trading costs.
4. A publically known price.
5. Transparent operation.
Nondiscriminatory access may be guaranteed by the governance structure of
a public market and is usually of most importance to small consumers and produc-
ers.2 Completeness is most relevant in the case of public goods such as reliability
services. It may also apply to natural-monopoly goods and services such as the unit-
commitment service. A public centralized market, such as an exchange, will
typically have much lower trading costs than a private decentralized market but
not necessarily lower than a private exchange.
A publically known price serves two different purposes. First, it is a required
assumption of the Efficient-Competition Result and is quite helpful to traders in
making efficient trades.3 Second it can be used as a benchmark for other transac-
tions, both regulated and private, such as settling financial futures. Transparent
operation is essential when market power is a potential problem and needs to be
monitored.
There are also drawbacks to public markets, all of which seem related to the
lack of proper incentives for regulators. A public market may offer products that
are not well designed or are too limited, or transactions costs may be higher than
necessary. These possibilities argue both for higher quality public institutions and
for the substitution of private ones.
Entire markets often use a mixture of types. For example, the used car market
is a mixture of direct search, bulletin board, and dealer markets. The New York
Stock Exchange (NYSE) uses an auction, although when the market is thin, it
becomes a dealer market. The term “pool” has a special meaning with regard to
power markets. For years, utilities in some regions have organized their production
in power pools, some of which used a centralized dispatch. In a deregulated market,
a pool is an exchange in which the supply bids are complex, and the system operator
carries out a complex calculation to select and pay the winners.
Some markets work better as one type and some as another. In the heat of debate,
those favoring bilateral markets often imply that exchanges are in some way like
central planning, socialism, or even communism, but these analogies contribute
little. Often the right answer is for an entire market to utilize both approaches side-
by-side. The long-term energy market utilizes a bilateral forward market that trades
individualized forward contracts and centralized futures exchanges that trade
standardized futures contracts. The transaction cost of trading in the forward market
is greater but provides flexibility while trading in the futures market provides no
flexibility in contract form but is inexpensive.
Bilateral markets can be either direct search markets or brokered markets and
can be more or less centralized. If the market is brokered, as is the housing market,
the brokers do not actually buy or sell in the market but are paid a commission for
arranging a trade. Some forward energy markets, thanks to the Internet, are now
organized as bulletin-board markets which are just a partially centralized variety
of a direct-search market.
With the exception of the bulletin-board approach, bilateral markets need little
design. They require an enforcement mechanism for complex contracts, but this
is provided by the pre-existing legal framework.
4. The terms “direct search market,” “brokered market,” “dealer market,” and “auction market” are
defined in Bodie et al. (1996, 24).
exchange interposes itself between buyers and sellers, the two halves of the market
can operate independently, although they are linked by what is called a double
auction. (Auctions are a traditional method of implementing a competitive market
and are discussed in Chapter 1-9.)
An exchange can have a number of advantages over a bilateral market. It can
reduce trading costs, increase competition, and produce a publically observable
price. Depending on design and circumstances, it can also facilitate collusion and
generally provides less flexibility than a bilateral market. Power marketers often
favor bilateral markets because without an exchange there is more room to earn
commissions as brokers and to appropriate the spread when they act as dealers.
Because exchanges are inflexible, they can operate much faster than bilateral
markets. Stock exchanges routinely execute trades in under five minutes while
bilateral markets take hours to weeks. In power markets, speed is crucial. Catastro-
phes can happen in seconds and system operators often need to exercise minute-by-
minute control. Because of their speed, exchanges can operate much nearer to real
time than can bilateral markets. This makes them the obvious choice for the real-
time market. Weeks in advance, bilateral markets and dealer markets may play a
larger role than exchanges. In between, there is much room for disagreement over
which is better.
other bid-in costs. The pool makes up for this be granting accepted bidders, that
would otherwise lose money, a side payment that makes them whole. Because some
apparently losing bids are accepted, losing bidders have no way to verify whether
their bid was correctly rejected. Typically pools utilize very complex bids which
attempt to comprise a complete economic description of the generation process,
but this is not necessary. A pool could be designed with two-part bids.
Although the principle of designing bid formats so that they do not require
“manipulation” is a useful one, it need not be carried to extremes. Another principle
states that, in a competitive market, competitive forces will induce bidders to
represent true costs as accurately as possible within the bid framework. Thus in
the Power Exchange, bidders included in their bids expected startup and no-load
costs as well as their marginal costs. Chapter 3-9 shows that even in an exchange
with one-part bids, where considerable manipulation is necessary, a competitive
market will do a remarkably efficient job of dispatching generation. The “gaming”
exhibited in a competitive market with an inappropriate bid format is largely
beneficial and should probably be described by another name.
Result 1-8.1 The Forward Price Is the Expected Future Spot Price
The price of a future or forward specified for delivery at time T is approximately
equal to the expected spot price at time T.
This relationship is not exact. Both buyers and sellers tend to prefer the certainty
of knowing the futures price. If the buyer’s preference is stronger, FT may be greater
than E(PT), and vice versa. These preferences will depend somewhat on the possibil-
ities for diversifying the risks involved, but altogether these effects are too subtle
and too unpredictable to be of interest to the power-market designer. For practical
design purposes, FT can be expected to equal E(PT).
One immediate consequence is that if the real-time (spot) price is capped at
$500, then the day-ahead price will not rise above $500. Of course if there are
penalties for trading in the spot market, these must be taken into account. This effect
was well documented in California, and it provides a mechanism for capping
markets that are not accessible to the system operator.
Besides being a valuable tool for understanding the implications of system
architecture, this result can provide practical insight. Seeing current high spot market
prices and low future prices, i.e., FT < P0, many concluded that it was nearly always
much cheaper to buy forwards than to wait for the inevitable high spot price. In
contradiction of Result 1-8.1, they concluded that FT < E(PT), and probably much
less. This was one of two factors which led to California’s huge purchases of
forwards in the spring of 2001. It now appears that purchasing all of California’s
power requirements for 2004 from an extremely thin market during a power
shortage, was not a sure bet. Pre-announcing a determination to buy no matter what
and using inexperienced traders compounded the problem. Most likely, California
did manage to create a temporary exception to the forward arbitrage linkage,
FT = E(PT), but in the opposite direction from what motivated the purchases: FT
was probably much greater in California during the spring of 2001 than a rational
expectation of future spot prices.
Cascading Markets
Generators can provide energy or they can provide reserves, an option to buy energy
when more is needed. Various qualities of reserves are graded by the quickness
and sureness of their response. This classification provides an unambiguous
ordering by value with the best quality of reserve always preferred to the second
best, and so on. Suppose there are three such products called R1 (best), R2, and
R3, and the system operator requires a certain amount of each.
If no linkage is made between the markets for R1, R2, and R3, they will take
place simultaneously but separately. In this case any excess capacity in one market
cannot flow into the others to help lower the price in those markets, so the markets
should be linked, at least by conducting them in sequence. If the R3 market were
conducted first, any excess of R2 might not be bid into the R3 market because it
would not yet be known that it was in excess. To achieve a cascade, the markets
should be cleared starting with the highest quality. Any surplus R1 reserves could
bid into the R2 market and so on. This increases the efficiency of the markets
relative to the absence of a cascade or one set up in reverse. Even with a forward
cascade these markets will not perform optimally. If there is a shortage in the market
for R3 and in total, but not for the first two markets, the price in the R3 market could
exceed the other two prices. In this case high-quality reserve units would hold out
for a chance at the third market, which could result in an inefficient use of reserves.
5. This is explained in 3-1.3 and can be proven from that facts that in general PAB = !PBA and
PAB + PBC = PAC .
If Edison had a needle to find in a haystack he would proceed . . . to examine straw after straw.
A little theory and calculation would have saved him ninety percent of his labor.
Nikola Tesla
New York Times
1931
1. One of several design flaws that produced this outcome was prohibiting the California ISO from
substituting a cheaper better product for a more expensive poorer product (Wolak, 1999). Also see Brien
(1999).
That testing is the key to successful design is well understood by engineers until
they design markets instead of equipment. It is not well understood by policy makers
or economists, and the results are predictable. Rigorous testing, though worthwhile,
is expensive so a simple “bottom-line” test should always be conducted first. This
only requires building the simplest relevant model computing the cheapest possible
production costs, and then computing the costs under the proposed design. If these
are much different, reject the design. This test cannot prove a design will work,
but it can save the cost of a rigorous test or a real-world failure.
Section 1: Design for Competitive Prices. Competitive prices sometimes
include a scarcity rent much greater than needed to cover the concurrent fixed cost
payment. Frequently this inspires attempts, such as FERC’s advocacy of pay-as-bid
auctions, to redesign the market to pay a price below the competitive level. If such
a scheme were to succeed, it would cause reduced and distorted investment.
Fortunately most such schemes are largely subverted by market forces.
Section 2: Design to Prevent Gaming. Rules that induce truth telling are
called “incentive compatible” and often provide good market designs. Some bidding
rules force suppliers to submit bids that do not reflect their true costs; such rules
induce gaming. The pay-as-bid auction design is an example. Gaming usually causes
inefficiency, the importance of which needs to be evaluated on a case-by-case basis.
Section 3: Auctions. Exchanges and pools use auctions to determine market-
clearing prices. The four main auction types all produce the same revenue when
bidders are buying for their own use or selling their own product. There is a slight
efficiency advantage for a “second-price” auction which is incentive compatible.
Recent work in auction theory shows that these results do not generalize to the
multi-unit auctions with elastic and uncertain demand characteristic of power
markets. In this setting, results are ambiguous, but pay-as-bid auctions tend to inhibit
market power, sometimes at the cost of reducing welfare.
Section 4: Testing Market Rules. Every market design should undergo at
least minimal testing before use. A minimal “bottom-line” test consists of three
steps: (1) model the market with and without the design in enough detail to compute
the design’s impact on production costs, (2) find the minimum possible cost of
delivered power, and (3) find the cost of delivered power when the market operates
under the proposed rules. If the design raises costs significantly, it fails the test.
Such a test cannot prove that the design will work well in the real world, but it often
shows it will fail under even ideal conditions, a useful, if disappointing, result.
Section 5: Technical Supplement—Example of a “Bottom-Line” Test.
A proposed charge for transmission access is tested and found to induce generation
investment in a pattern that increases the total cost of delivered energy. Since the
proposed design fails to perform under even the simplest network conditions, it
could have been rejected without expensive testing.
Scarcity Rent
If a competitive generator sells 10,000 MWh for $500,000 and its variable operating
costs are $100,000, then its scarcity rent is $400,000 which is not an unlikely
outcome for a low-variable-cost coal plant when the market price is set by the
marginal cost of a high cost gas turbine. Scarcity rents are necessary for suppliers
to cover their fixed costs, which, as explained in Chapter 1-3, can be thought of
as a constant flow of cost equivalent to the cost of renting the power plant. During
the period in which the plant produced its 10,000 MWh, its fixed costs might have
been $200,000. In this case the scarcity rent was twice what was needed to cover
fixed costs during that period of operation. Such discrepancies are common, and
they convince many that competitive prices are often too high.
This conclusion ignores the fact that in power markets, scarcity rents fluctuate
dramatically. If they are to equal fixed costs on average, they must be higher
sometimes and lower other times. Typically they are lower most of the time but
are occasionally much higher. Ignoring this leads to a fallacy which states that
paying a low-variable-cost plant the marginal cost of an expensive plant is unfair.
This was succinctly expressed by former FERC Chairman Curt Hébert.3
2. The Blue Ribbon Panel that examined this scheme for California’s Power Exchange concluded: “In
sum, our response is that the expectation behind the proposal to shift from uniform to as-bid pricing—that
it would provide purchasers of electric power substantial relief from the soaring prices of the electric
power, such as they have recently experienced—is simply mistaken. . . . In our view it would do
consumers more harm than good." (Kahn et al., 2001, 17)
3. From p. 4 of his concurrence with FERC (2000b).
at why the New York Stock Exchange does not follow Chairman Hébert’s prefer-
ence “that sellers ... be paid what they bid ... rather than the market-clearing price.”4
4. “My preference is that sellers in California be paid what they bid, regardless of what that bid is, rather
than the market-clearing price.” From p. 4 of his concurrence with FERC (2000b).
5. Another possibility is to match buyers and sellers by price so the $50 supplier sells to the $50 buyer,
and so on. Applying the concept of total surplus from Section 1-5.2 demonstrates that this yields no total
surplus, while using a market-clearing price gives a total surplus of $20.
unpopular. In this case a less efficient design will usually need to be adopted, but
it is generally useful to look for the efficient design first.
1-9.3 AUCTIONS
In the last forty years, economics has developed an extensive theory of auctions.
Perhaps because auctioning electricity is a rather new idea, some have suspected
that auctions are an invention of theoretical economics. In fact, the Babylonians
used them in 500 BC, and Buddhists employed them in the seventh century.
Sotheby’s was established in 1744, some time before Adam Smith gave economics
its start.6
William Vickrey, who won the 1996 “Nobel Prize” in economics largely for
his work on auctions, classified one-sided auctions into four types.
1. English: Buyers start bidding at a low price. The highest bidder wins and
pays the last price bid.
2. Vickrey (second-price): Buyers submit sealed bids, and the winner pays
the price of the highest losing bid. This is also confusingly called a Dutch
auction.
3. Dutch: The auctioneer starts very high and calls out progressively lower
prices. The first buyer to accept the price wins and pays that price.
4. Sealed-Bid (first-price): Buyers submit sealed bids, and the winner pays
the price that is bid.
These four types of auction can all be used in reverse to buy a product instead
of sell it. For example, in a reversed English auction, sellers can call out progres-
sively lower prices until there are no more bids. The lowest bid wins, and the seller
sells at that price. Consequently everything said about auctions to sell, holds for
auctions to buy, but in reverse.
There are two motives for buying: for a buyer’s own use or for resale. In the
first case the value of the purchased good is the private value placed on it by the
6. See Klemperer (1999; 2000a; 2000b) for surveys of auction theory and literature. The first is the most
accessible.
buyer. In the second case, the value is the price for which it can be resold. If the
purchase is for resale, then all potential purchasers will find the value to be the
same, i.e., the market price upon resale. This is called the common value.
Assume the bids in each were $100, $200, and $300 by A, B, and C respectively.
In each auction, C wins, but in the Vickrey auction, C would pay only $200 while
in the first-price auction, C would pay $300. This makes it seem that the revenue
of the first-price auction is clearly greater by $100.
The explanation of revenue equivalence involves the fundamental principle
of rule design, Result 1-9.1. Changing the rules changes the behavior of the bidders.
To analyze these behaviors assume that the bidders have private values correspond-
ing to the above bids. First, consider bidder behavior under a Vickrey auction. C
will bid $300 because he knows that if A and B have bid less he will win and get
the best possible price, the price of the next-highest bidder. If C loses, say to a bid
of $305, he will be glad he lost, for winning would mean paying $305 for something
he values at only $300. If a bidder bids less than her valuation, she increases the
chance of losing when she should win and saves no money. If a bidder bids above
her private value her only extra wins from biding higher will be in auctions she
would rather lose. So all bidders bid their true values, and this design is incentive
compatible. Bidder C will win and pay the second price of $200.
“efficient outcomes.” Unfortunately, when such designs are tested against even
the most well-behaved hypothetical situations, they do not always live up to their
claims.
A moderately rigorous test would involve a laboratory simulation of the market
design. While this is recommended, especially when gambling with sums that can
run into the billions of dollars, a more modest course of testing is presented here.
No design should be implemented without this minimal level of testing, which is
called the “bottom-line test” because it tests the effect of a market design on the
total cost of supply. It does not provide a cookbook procedure, but it provides a
structure that is often missing, and it sets a minimum standard. The test procedure
can be broken into three steps.
If consumer response to price (demand elasticity) is important for the rules being
tested, then the bottom-line test must be modified by examining the decrease in
total surplus caused by the design instead of the increase in cost. Fortunately, most
market rules can be tested adequately under the assumption of completely inelastic
demand. Then consumer benefit is unaffected by market rules and drops out of
the test procedure. Occasionally, adding demand elasticity can simplify a model
by removing “knife-edge” discontinuities in behavior. In this case the net-benefit
test should be used.
Lack of demand elasticity confers market power on suppliers, and most designs
are not efficient in the presence of market power. The bottom-line test is only
intended to test designs for competitive markets, so to counteract the effects of
inelastic demand, suppliers should simply be assumed to behave competitively.
7. This might be termed an absolute impacted megawatt-mile approach and is a design that has been
proposed and inappropriately tested.
matter which way it sends power over the line. This completes the description of
the design in question; these two rules are sufficient to compute the transmission
access charge for every generator. In all other respects the market is assumed to
be perfectly competitive.
The stated purpose of the design focuses only on the linkage between this market
and the market for generation plants, and it ignores linkages to the energy market.
Although these linkages deserve testing, for simplicity, the example will test only
the effect of the rules on the location of new power plants.
These rules were “tested” by constructing a model of all the power flows in
the state of California and computing them for every hour on every wire for a given
year. Graphs were made showing how much power flowed on wires operating at
various voltages. It was claimed that since most of the power flowed on high-voltage
lines, and those were the ones being charged for, the market design would “send
the right signals.” As a consequence of sending the right signals, investors would
build plants in the right locations, and the market would operate efficiently. But
such “testing” misses the point.
Notice that although some costs may have been calculated, no total minimum
cost was calculated (step 2), and no total cost under the proposed design (step 3)
was contemplated. The test did not rule out the possibility that generation costs
would be double the economic minimum under the proposed market design. The
central economic question of cost minimization was simply not considered. These
oversights are now remedied by applying the bottom-line test.
should be accepted for a more complex or less precise answer although it may be
useful to test several variations of the model (each will have its own one-number
result for step 2).
Interpretation
The result of this example can be summarized as a $14,000 (4%) increase in cost
caused by the proposed rules. This might be tolerable, but a qualitative inspection
of the model raises more concerns. The rules cause all of the generation in the
system to locate at the load center and consequently cause an eight-fold increase
in the cost of transmission. This is unreasonable, and the rules should clearly be
rejected because they have failed such a simple and reasonable test.
The benefit of the bottom-line test is dramatic. By applying it first, the expense
of a complex study can be saved. Additionally, it provides an intuitive understanding
of the design’s flaws that would be difficult to extract from a more complex
simulation. The following subsection builds the model and uses it to compute the
costs for steps 2 and 3, as well as to develop the intuition of the interpretation.
Step 1: Building the Model and Computing Costs. Assume there are two
cities in the market, and they are connected by a transmission line as shown in
Figure 1-9.1. Assume for simplicity that generation can be located near either city,
and the cost is the same: $10/MWh for capacity and $20/MWh for energy. Assume
peak load on the system is 16,000 MW with 12,000 MW located at city A and 4000
MW located at city B. Assume the average hourly load is 10,000 MW, assume that
line capacity costs $4/MWh, and for reliability purposes assume the minimal line
capacity is 500 MW. This is a sufficient model of the relevant costs.
Step 2: Finding the Minimum Cost. Because the above model assumes that
generators cost the same at either location, the cheapest arrangement is to locate
them where they are needed, that is 12,000 MW of generation at A and 4000 MW
of generation at B. In this case, no power line is needed to facilitate trade. The total
long-run cost of power in this model is found by summing three components as
follows:
Figure 1-9.1
Minimum cost locations
with flows calculated
using proposed Rule 2.