Cost Function
Cost Function
Costs Geometry o
October 5, 2009
Cost Minimization Second Order Conditions Conditional factor demand functions The cost function Average and Marginal Costs Geometry o
Difficulties
2-input case
Recall the Cramer’s Rule, we can use it to solve for ∂xi /∂w1 †
0
0 −f2
−f
1 −1 −λf21
∂ x1 −f2 0 −λf22
∂ w1 = 0
−f1 −f2
−f
1 −λf11 −λf21
−f2 −λf12 −λf22
∂x2
Similarly, you can use Cramer’s rule to solve for ∂w1 ,
0
−f1 0
−f1 −λf11 −1
∂ x2 −f2 −λf12 0
∂ w1 = 0
−f1 −f2
−f −λf11 −λf21
1
−f2 −λf12 −λf22
n-input case
1
We omitted y as an argument as it is fixed.
Cost Minimization Second Order Conditions Conditional factor demand functions The cost function Average and Marginal Costs Geometry o
Proof †:
Non-decreasing
Homogeneous of Degree 1
Concave
Continuous
Intuition for concavity of the cost function †
Cost Minimization Second Order Conditions Conditional factor demand functions The cost function Average and Marginal Costs Geometry o
Proof †:
Non-decreasing
Homogeneous of Degree 1
Concave
Continuous
Intuition for concavity of the cost function †
Cost Minimization Second Order Conditions Conditional factor demand functions The cost function Average and Marginal Costs Geometry o
Proof †:
Non-decreasing
Homogeneous of Degree 1
Concave
Continuous
Intuition for concavity of the cost function †
Cost Minimization Second Order Conditions Conditional factor demand functions The cost function Average and Marginal Costs Geometry o
Proof †:
Non-decreasing
Homogeneous of Degree 1
Concave
Continuous
Intuition for concavity of the cost function †
Cost Minimization Second Order Conditions Conditional factor demand functions The cost function Average and Marginal Costs Geometry o
Proof †:
Non-decreasing
Homogeneous of Degree 1
Concave
Continuous
Intuition for concavity of the cost function †
Cost Minimization Second Order Conditions Conditional factor demand functions The cost function Average and Marginal Costs Geometry o
Shepard’s Lemma
dM(a)
The envelope theorem says that da is equal to
∂g(x1 ,x2 ,a)
dM(a)
da = ∂a |x=x(a) − λ ∂h(x∂a
1 ,x2 ,a)
|x=x(a)
In the case of cost minimization, the envelope theorem implies
∂c(x,w) ∂L
∂wi = ∂wi = xi |xi =xi (w,y) = xi (w, y)
∂c(x,y) ∂L
∂y = ∂y =λ
The second implication follows also from the envelope theorem
and just means that (at the optimum), the lagrange multiplier of
the minimization cost is exactly the marginal cost.
Cost Minimization Second Order Conditions Conditional factor demand functions The cost function Average and Marginal Costs Geometry o
For the first unit produced, marginal cost equals average cost
Long run cost is always lower than short run cost
Short run marginal cost should be equal to the long run marginal
costs at the optimum (application of the envelope theorem). If
c(y) ≡ c(y, z(y) and let z∗ be an optimal choice given y∗ †
Differentiation with respect to y yields,
dc(y∗ ,z(y∗ )) ∂c(y∗ ,z∗ ) ∂c(y∗ ,z∗ ) ∂z(y∗ ) ∂c(y∗ ,z∗ )
dy = ∂y + ∂z ∂y = ∂y
Where the last inequality follows from FOC of the minimization
∗ ∗
problem with respect to z ( ∂c(y∂z,z ) = 0)