Maria Cucagna
Maria Cucagna
Maria Cucagna
BY
THESIS
Urbana, Illinois
a
Adviser:
Global agricultural markets reflect the increasing complexity of modern consumer demand for
food safety and quality. This demand has triggered changes throughout the food industry, and
led to greater opportunities for product differentiation and the potential to add value to raw
differentiation and value adding have in turn dramatically changed the price spread or
marketing bill between the farm value of products and the retail value during the past 18 years.
Thus a significantly greater percentage of the final price paid by consumers is garnered down
chain rather than up chain. This apparent shifting of value creation, as measured by the
marketing margin, has invigorated empirical questions as to where and how much value is
created along the agri-food value chain. Using a regression model with a ten-year panel data of
financial information taken from 454 agri-food companies worldwide, this paper empirically
analyzes value creation in the agri-food value chain. The agri-food value chain can be split into
four main stages: input, production, processing and retailer. The main purpose of this study is
to analyze the differences in stages within the agri-food value chain by identifying which firms
and nodes excel or underperform in the value creation process. For the purpose of this paper,
we estimate the Economic Value Added (EVA) metric for each firm. We validate our findings
by creating and employing three additional value creation measures—the modified economic
value added, the percentage of companies that create value and the persistent value creation—
which improve the robustness of our findings and allow this study to find measures that are not
biased by company size. The results indicate that agricultural producers—the most
commoditized sector—contribute the least amount of value to the chain, while further
ii
TABLE OF CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION.................................................................................................................... 1
DATA ...................................................................................................................................... 23
RESULTS ............................................................................................................................... 44
DISCUSSION ......................................................................................................................... 53
CONCLUSION ...................................................................................................................... 58
REFERENCES....................................................................................................................... 62
iii
INTRODUCTION
consumer demand, the development of complex food standards mainly related to food safety
and food quality, advances of technology, and changes in the industry structure along the value
chain (Goldsmith et al., 2002; Humphrey and Memedovic, 2006). These changes have led to
greater opportunities for product differentiation and the potential for adding value to raw
In recent years, value creation in agriculture and its management has emerged as a
business survival strategy (Kampen, 2011). In the past, firms may not necessarily have needed
scarcity of resources to produce (Doyle, 2000; Lindgreen et al., 2012). Historically, the
agribusiness sector has been a commodity-oriented industry, with strong focus on maximum
efficiency, homogenous products and economies of scale (Grunert et al, 2005). Although agri-
food markets have been efficient at converting raw commodities into homogeneous products,
the evolution of consumer demand for safe, high quality, and convenient products,
technological advances and increased competition are changing the agribusiness sector. New
agribusiness markets are characterized by companies that need to focus on value added
activities that allow them to meet the expectations of consumers by offering high quality and
differentiated products (Streeter, 1991; Alexander and Goodhue, 1999; Coltrain et al., 2000).
In response, companies’ survival relies on their ability to satisfy the end consumer demand
with differentiated and value added products while achieving high profits that capture the
1
During the past 18 years, greater differentiation and value adding along the value chain
have in turn dramatically changed the price spread or marketing bill between the farm gate and
the retail sector (Fig.1). The average farm value of food has been 16.1 percent since 1993,
while the other 83.9 percent came from post-farm activities of the value chain stages. Thus, a
significantly greater percentage of the final price paid by consumers is garnered down chain as
opposed to up chain. This change in the farm and marketing bill share suggests a dramatic shift
As a result, the main objective of business has been to continuously create value
(Conner, 1991; Sirmon et al., 2007). In order to achieve this goal, understanding the concept
of value creation and the way to add value has attracted the interest of researchers and managers
during the past decade (Wilson and Jantrania, 1994; Anderson, 1995; Parasuraman, 1997;
Bowman and Ambrosini, 2000; Mittal and Sheth, 2001; Payne and Holt, 2001; Walter et al.,
2001; Anderson et al., 2006; Möller, 2006; Lepak et al., 2007; Sirmon et al., 2007; Smith and
Colgate, 2007; Ambrosini and Bowman, 2009; O' Cass and Ngo, 2011). Therefore, the idea of
indicates that value creation is a “dynamic and multi-stage process involving different users of
value” (O'Cass and Ngo, 2011), and many studies find a variety of benefits for firms,
stockholders and customers that can be traced to value creation (Anderson and Narus, 1998;
Lindgreen and Wynstra, 2005). These benefits include an increase in customer loyalty, an
upsurge in value to stockholders and rising profits (Srivastava et al., 1998; Zeithaml, 2000;
surprising that managers and even academics “often do not know how to define value, or how
to measure it” (Anderson and Narus, 1998, Lindgreen et al., 2012). Furthermore, there is no
study on a worldwide basis that has analyzed or compared the role of members of the agri-food
2
value chain in the value creation process. How can value creation be achieved in agribusiness?
Which chain members are creating the most value? How can this be measured? Are any of the
stages of the agri-food value chain “more” responsible for the value creation process?
This paper aims to answer these questions and clarify this gap in the literature. The
current study focuses on analyzing the differences in stages within the agri-food value chain
by identifying which stage nodes excel or underperform in the value creation process. For the
purpose of this paper, we estimate the Economic Value Added (EVA) metric for each firm. We
validate our findings by creating and employing three additional value creation measures—the
modified economic value added, the create value metric and the persistent value creation —
which improve the robustness of the findings by using a measure that it is not biased by
company size. Additionally, the impact of the drivers of value creation is evaluated in terms of
firm size, product differentiation, intangible assets and research and development (R&D)
expenditures on our value creation metrics. We use a regression model with a ten-year panel
data of financial information for 454 agri-food companies worldwide. We conduct an empirical
analysis within the entire agri-food value chain by examining and comparing the contribution
of each value chain member to the value creation process. Finally, this study will contribute
additional understanding of value creation in the agri-food industry and will identify the factors
approach used in this study in Section 4. Section 5 follows with analysis of the results and
Section 6 present a discussion of the main findings. Concluding remarks and research
3
LITERATURE REVIEW
The popularity of the concept of value creation has increased since the 1990s, and its
processes have been widely studied in the business discipline (Wilson and Jantrania, 1994;
Anderson, 1995; Parasuraman, 1997; Walter et al., 2001). In this context, Coltrain et al. (2000)
suggest that the concept of value creation is widely used when analyzing the potential
profitability of agriculture. However, the majority of value creation literature fails to provide a
deep and complete definition of value creation. As a result, the concept of value creation is still
poorly understood by managers and academics. Most of the literature defines value creation in
agribusiness as “to economically add value to a product by changing its current place, time,
and form characteristics to characteristics more preferred in the marketplace” (Coltrain et al.,
2000; Anderson and Hanselka, 2009). Coltrain et al. (2000) gives a more specific definition by
giving an example of value adding in agriculture: “to economically add value to an agricultural
product (such as wheat) by processing it into a product (such as flour) desired by customers
(such as bread bakers)”. The 2002 Farm Bill (Farm Security and Rural Investment Act of 2002)
also defines value creation in agriculture as a change in the physical state of any agricultural
commodity or product is produced or segregated. The end result of changing value expands the
customer base for the product or makes available a greater portion of revenue derived from the
achieved by the producer (Farm Security and Rural Investment Act of 2002).
Amanor-Boadu (2003) attempts to clarify the concept of value creation by using the
USDA concept and by distinguishing between the economic metric of value-added and the
descriptive concept of value-added. There are two conditions that a value creation activity must
4
satisfy in order to qualify as value adding “(1) if one is rewarded for performing an activity
that traditionally has been performed at another stage farther down the value chain, or (2) if
one is rewarded for performing an activity that has never been performed in the value chain”
(Amanor-Boadu, 2003; Evans 2006), (Table 1). This definition focuses on the reward that a
company’s output/benefit obtains for a given value creation activity. The reward may be
“higher prices, increased market share and/or increased market access,” and this reward must
“be large enough to increase the total profitability of the performing organization.” “The size
of this reward is directly proportional to the level of customer satisfaction engendered by the
activity and not by the work or effort on the part of the performing organization.” “If the total
profitability of the performing organization is not increased by the value-added activity, then
the activity cannot be deemed to have contributed any value to the value chain or to customers,
must focus on their customers’ perception of value. Customer value reflects the relationship
between the benefits customers receive from a product, and the price they pay for it. The price
of a particular product may be high, but if the associated benefits are high as well, customers
perceive the product as valuable. The marketing discipline defines product as “a bundle of
benefits, and the more benefits there are, the more customers will perceive the product as
having value” (Anderson and Hanselka, 2009). The uniqueness of a product or service (the
value you add) is what ultimately attracts customers (Anderson and Hanselka, 2009).
Although these definitions are the closest terms to what we refer to value creation, most
practitioners still lack a deeply understood definition of value added. For instance it is still not
clear how one can measure customer benefits. Furthermore, the definitions of value creation
provided by previous research are only a weak description of what value creation really means
since these definitions focus solely on the process and product levels and do not take into
5
account two essential aspects of the value creation process: the firm structure capital needed to
perform a value creation activity, and the level of efficiency of companies in using their capital
(Table 1). This study aims to fill this gap in the literature by adding clarity to the term ‘value
creation’. This manuscript strives to provide a novel and complete definition of the term ‘value
creation’ and to consistently measure value creation across the agri-food value chain and
The value chain framework emerges as a key aspect for value creation and has been
recognized as a crucial field for business success (Matopoulos et al., 2007). A value chain is
composed of a number of stages, namely, input seller, processor, distributor, and end consumer.
It is a system of firms that work together to positively impact one another’s performance
(Bigliardi and Bottani, 2010). For the purpose of this study, following Humphrey and
Memedovic (2006), agri-food value chain is split into four main stages: inputs, production,
processing and delivery to consumers. Agri-food firms are classified into these four stages
based on a firm’s main activity (Fig. 2). A description of each stage of these activities is
outlined below.
Stage 1- Inputs
animal breeding and farm equipment companies. Firms in this sector are suppliers of
agricultural products and services such as seeds, agricultural nutrients and farm machinery.
Firms on this stage focus on farmers, who are its primary customers.
6
Stage 2- Production
This stage includes all of the activities involved in the production of raw food materials.
In particular, crop production, beef cattle, poultry, and hog and milk production are included,
among others. The customers for these firms are food manufacturers, the next node of the chain.
Stage 3- Processing
wineries and packaged food companies. Companies within this node are engaged in the
production of meat, dairy and food products. Specifically, soft drink firms produce, market and
distribute nonalcoholic beverages such as sodas, energy drinks, still and sparkling waters,
juices and juice drinks, sports drinks, and ready-to-drink teas. Brewer companies are involved
in the production, marketing, and distribution of beer. Winery firms make and sell branded
alcoholic beverages such as spirits, wines and various categories of beer. Finally, packaged
food companies process, distribute and market food products. Processing firms convert raw
materials into food products, as either brand or unbranded products, which are in turn sent to
the retail market (the last stage) for distribution and sale to consumers.
The main activity of this stage is the distribution, sale and marketing of food products
to the end customer, the consumer. In the last stage of the agri-food value chain we include
firms concerned with food distribution, grocery chains, and restaurants. This category contains
firms that wholesale and/or retail food products, from convenience stores to supermarket
Chikán (1997) and Martin and Jagadish (2006) describe the value chain as a “series of
value adding processes which flows across many companies and creates products and services
7
which are suitable to fulfill the needs of customers” (Vanyi, 2012). The aim of each value chain
actor is to meet customer desires while collaborating in the value creation process (Vanyi,
2012). Today, as members of a value chain, companies fulfill and satisfy costumers’ needs by
collaborating and working together in coordinated activities rather than individually competing
with one another in the market. According to Opara (2003), each step in the chain, from basic
inputs to final outputs, is defined as a link in the value chain. Within this context, the main
objective of firms within each stage is to offer maximum value to the customer and to improve
company performance while obtaining a competitive advantage from being part of the value
chain (Ketchen et al., 2008; Bourlakis et al., 2012). Consequently, value creation does not occur
in isolation but rather within a value chain framework where companies can operate most
efficiently as members of the chain. In this position, a company can more easily establish
collaborative relationships based on trust, commitment, and cooperation among the chain’s
members, which helps to improve all the companies’ performance and thus create value
(Lindgreen et al., 2012; Vanyi, 2012). That is why it is paramount to evaluate and measure
value creation in agri-business within a value chain context. Despite the remarkable number of
studies analyzing the need for collaboration among value chains and measuring the benefits of
collaboration among the value chain, little attention has been paid to measuring value creation
in the agri-food value chain context. In this study a value creation analysis is performed within
the context of the value chain to show which actors excel in the value creation process.
Marketing bill
Changes in consumer demand toward more high-quality, ready-to-eat, safe and healthy
food products have increased the price spread in the food marketing system. Price spreads are
based on food price differences along the agri-food value chain as measured at the farm,
wholesale, and retail nodes (Coltrain et al., 2000; Hahn, 2004; MacDonald, 2011). During the
8
past 18 years, the spread between the farm value of products and their retail value, often called
the marketing bill, has increased (Fig. 1). Food retail sales can be split into two components of
market value—the farm value and the marketing bill (USDA, 2013). Farm value is a measure
of the compensation received by farmers for the raw materials they produce, as a proportion of
the food purchase by end customers (Elitzak, 1999; Oswald, 2011). Farm value can be
estimated to be the retail price minus the spread, which implies that “higher price spreads cause
lower farm prices” (Hahn, 2004). Price spreads can be reduced if farm prices raise and/or retail
On the other hand, the marketing share can be calculated as food dollar expenditures
minus farm share commodity sales (Canning, 2011). The farm share in 1993 was 18.4, while
in 2011 the farm share was 15.5 cents for each food dollar expenditure (“a food dollar
At the same time, the marketing share was 81.6 in 1993 and 84.5 cents in 2011 (Fig. 1). The
marketing bill represents a calculation of the value created by the value chain for farm products.
Rising marketing costs affect either farm or retail prices (Oswald, 2011). Changes in the farm
and marketing share over time suggest that not all stages in the value chain are capable of
creating value at the same levels. The price spreads show that value creation distribution in the
agri-food value chain is changing, giving a more important role to the last stages of the value
chain.
The number of value creation activities designed to meet customer needs is expected to
increase in the coming years (Coltrain, 2000). This may present an opportunity for farmers up-
chain to engage in value adding activities that directly benefit consumers and earn higher
economic benefits. The question that arises is: which member of the agri-food chain is
contributing more to the value produced along the value chain? Given that price spreads are
increasing, the level of value creation is thought to increase as we move downward along the
9
agri-food value chain. A higher spread and share by retail indicates that more value is being
created down chain. But price spreads do not connote value creation. Therefore, we explicitly
tackle this empirical problem by measuring the value created at various stages of the value
chain. . By analyzing and measuring value creation in a value chain framework, we expect to
find different levels of value creation among actors due to the characteristics and opportunities
Hypothesis I: Value creation levels differ across stages. Each stage contributes
Hypothesis II: Value creation levels will be higher as we move downward along the
There are two main drivers of value creation activities: innovation and coordination
(Coltrain et al., 2000; Amanor-Boadu, 2003). “An innovation is an idea, practice, or material
artefact perceived to be new by the relevant adoption unit” (Zaltman et al., 1973). This is
similar to Luecke and Katz (2003), who wrote ‘‘Innovation is generally understood as the
(Sawang and Unsworth, 2011). According to Coltrain et al. (2000), agri-food innovation is
refers to the ability and capacity to produce or create something unique, valuable and hard to
imitate by performing a series of activities such as new processes or modified old processes.
Within this framework, innovation associated with value creation activities refers to the
performance of activities that enhance “existing processes, procedures, products, and services
10
or creating new ones” using organizational structures (Amanor-Boadu, 2003). In the agri-food
industry there are a variety of agro-industrial innovative processes such as producing ethanol
from corn, biodiesel from soybeans, and particleboard from straw; adding value through the
production of enhanced grain crops such as, non-GMO, organic, Nutridense® maize, and low
Value creation can also be achieved through coordination activities. Peterson and
Wysocke (1997) explains that “coordination focuses on arrangements among those that
produce and market farm products. Horizontal coordination involves pooling or consolidation
among individuals or companies at the same node of the food value chain. Vertical coordination
multiple market stages in different levels of the food chain” (Peterson and Wysocki, 1997;
Coltrain et al., 2000). The value chain framework provides numerous opportunities to obtain
significant rewards and create value along the chain by strengthening the coordination of
products, services, and information. Coordination value creation activities emphasize the
vertical and horizontal relationships among value chain actors (Barkema and Drabenstott,
1996; Coltrain et al., 2000). From a reward perspective, for a coordination or innovation
activity to be part of the value creation process, the activity should provide the performer with
a net positive benefit as reward for the effort of performing the specific activity (Amanor-
Boadu, 2003).
Firms employ a number of activities to create value along the agri-food value chain
(Table 2).
Stage 1- Inputs companies: Empirical evidence suggests that the increase in private
investment in agricultural research has been driven by the establishment and strengthening of
intellectual property (Moschini and Lapan, 1997; Goldsmith, 2001; Fulton and Giannakas,
11
2002). Effective intellectual property development in seed and equipment markets, for
differentiated products. Horizontal mergers through acquisition allows seed firms to achieve
significant research and development, marketing, and production economies, in part due to
enhanced coordination. This in turn has led to the development of new products such as
enhanced grains, insect and herbicide resistance crops, and higher yielding varieties and
hybrids.
As member of the agri-food value chain, the inputs stage is positioned in a relative weak
position, as it supplies products to the least profit-making member, the production stage.
Farmers as well as seed companies benefit from using GM technologies (Goldsmith, 2001;
Demont et al., 2007). As a general rule, within the context of GM development, inputs
companies obtain one third of the benefits, while two thirds of the rewards are occur down
chain. A value chain perspective is vital for becoming sustainable within this stage.
Consequently, success and value creation are conditioned to the ability to develop strategic
relationships with other members of the chain in order to provide high-quality products to the
Hypothesis III a: Agricultural inputs is expected to be a high value creator node given
the evidence of branding and agricultural research as well as the evidence of horizontal
Stage 2- This node can be described as the most commoditized sector of the value chain.
indistinguishable from others, often produced in large quantities and sold inexpensively
(Carlson, 2004; Phillips et al., 2007). Thus, this stage is characterized by having low margins,
12
high price dependence and a low level of product differentiation. Companies often operate
within competitive markets and strive to compete on cost management and economies of scale.
In recent years, an increasing number of structural changes have taken place within this
stage, showing a decline in the number the firms but an increase in those firms’ overall size.
Large firms that have been able to obtain the benefits of large-scale business may be
responsible for making this stage profitable (Lobao and Meyer, 2001; Humphrey and
Memedovic, 2006).
Firms within this stage may focus on performing value added activities that permit them
to capture a greater proportion of the consumer dollar (Born and Bachmann, 2006; Kampen,
2011). Previous literature shows that vertical coordination, such as contractual arrangements,
or vertical integration, contribute to achieving efficiency and to creating more value (Hendrikse
and Bijman, 2002; Sporleder, 2006). Contracts, as a form of vertical integration, allow
agreements between buyers and sellers such as prices, quality and time to take place
(Humphrey and Memedovic, 2006). But spot transactions are still common in production
agriculture in the form of active commodity markets like the majority of U.S grain and oilseed
markets (Goldsmith and Bender, 2004; Goldsmith and Silva, 2006). Thus if producers and
processors are increasingly using contracts to operate (Collins, 2001; USDA, 2013b). One
would expect higher levels of value creation rather than lower, since producers are more closely
The main opportunities for producers to innovate rely on their ability to enhance and
add value to their products by moving down chain and capturing part of the higher benefits of
post-producer stages (Coltrain et al., 2000). Producers that are able to create value by producing
what consumers desire rather than offering solely commodities will be able to obtain a larger
share of the food dollar (Coltrain et al., 2000). For example, value added grains are enhanced
13
quality crops with herbicide tolerance and resistance to particular insect pests or with changed
oil composition. These value-added crop products are distinguished from standard
commodities in that they can help improve contractual links among seed firms, farmers,
logistics companies and end customers. The shift from commodity grain to differentiated
grain/oilseed allows producers to create and capture added value (Hayenga and
Kalaitzandonakes, 1999; Goldsmith and Silva, 2006). “Value is created and premiums are paid
because the grain is doing more for someone along the value chain” (Goldsmith and Silva,
2006). This suggests that the value creation generated in one stage of the agri-food value chain
impacts the benefits garnered at other stages. Innovation creation and benefit sharing present
an agri-food value chain as a value creation system of complementarities where firms and nodes
undifferentiated products as well as the condition of price taker make the production
exhibit low levels of innovation and thus, low levels of value creation.
Stage 3- The process of turning raw agricultural outputs into food and beverage
products ‘adds value’ to raw commodities in an economic sense, but these activities may also
significantly alter the appearance, storage life, nutritional value, and content of the raw
materials (Gopinath et al., 1996). A processor’s main activity is to transform commodities into
food products, a process that adds economic value to the products. However, to qualify as a
value creation activity these actions should create products that satisfy consumer demand by
modifying products’ “appearance, storage life, nutritional value, and content of the raw
14
Increasingly, consumer demand for high quality and premium food products with
accompanying services along with the technological characteristics of the modern market are
making innovation crucial for the food processing node of the value chain. Innovation not only
enables firms to reduce cost but also to successfully adapt to the expectations of the end
and thus create value (Omidvar, 2006, USDA). Oustapassidis and Vlachvei (1999) also
discusses advertising as one of the strategies to create value in the manufacturing sector. In this
context, product differentiation of new and unique products, in addition to advertising, can be
advantage. Since processing is the most innovation-oriented node, food manufacturers acquire
low cost inputs from the production sector, giving them a greater opportunity to add value to
farm products.
Stage 4- The last stage of the agri-food value chain focuses on addressing the dynamics
of consumer expectations. One of the main drivers of innovation in this stage for food retailers
are differentiation through service and retail brands to better meet consumer demand (Burch
and Lawrence, 2005; Humphrey and Memedovic, 2006). Retailers offering food services such
as training their personnel to assist the consumer and designing a convenient shopping
(Rintamäki et al., 2007). Another source of value creation for food retailers is the development
15
of supermarkets’ own brands to increase their share of the food and beverage market (Burch
and Lawrence, 2005). This upstream integration into retail brands and private label products
changes the relationship between food manufacturing and retail in order to leverage “close
There is evidence of increasing market power at the retail end of the agri-food value
al., 1995; Humphrey and Memedovic, 2006). The influence of retailers over processors,
manufacturing and also the consumer is allowing the retailer sector to obtain a competitive
advantage (Burch and Lawrence, 2005). This is because first, the growing market power of
downstream members may limit up-chain firms from moving to high-value-added activities
such as distribution, marketing and retailing (Farfan, 2005; Niemi and Xing, 2011). Greater
market power down chain allows for greater control over information flows and the resulting
innovation (Farfan, 2005; Humphrey and Memedovic, 2006). Second, the dominant position
of retailers along the value chain, because of their market power, affects the interlinkages
among the four nodes and allows retailers to depress farm prices and low input costs as well as
to establish the best possible terms and standards with suppliers (buyer power), thus extracting
additional value from agri-food commodities (Burch and Lawrence, 2005). Furthermore,
supermarkets, as owners of ‘critical value chain assets’ such as supermarket shelf space, are
due to their strategic position along the value chain as well as the evidence of innovation
16
R&D expenditures (Meisel and Lin, 1983; Cohen, 1996; Artz et al., 2010; Damanpour,
2010; Zona et al., 2013) and goodwill and intangible assets (Kramer et al., 2011) are key factors
value creation and firm success. The level of product differentiation can be measured as sales
over cost of goods sold (COGS) (Kotha and Nair, 1995; Goldsmith and Sporleder, 1998;
Berman et al, 1999; Nair and Filer, 2003; Balsam et al., 2011). Although several researchers
have identified different categories and activities that determine firm-level value creation (see
Kalafut and Low, 2001; Kale et al., 2001; Zéghal and Maaloul, 2010), there has been little
empirical research on how firms along the agri-food value chain successfully use these
activities to create value. This research aims to fill this gap in the literature by providing
evidence for how expenditures in R&D and the level of intangible assets affect value creation
in the context of the agri-food value chain. This study also measures the effect of the degree of
potential product differentiation on the level of value creation. As the body of literature
suggests, the expectation is that expenditures in R&D, intangible assets and product
Hypothesis IV: Innovation is a critical factor that positively affects firms and industry
value creation. An increase in the level of innovation will lead to an increase of the
Hypothesis IV a: Firms with higher levels of intangible capital will have higher levels
of value creation.
17
Hypothesis V: Firms with higher degrees of product differentiation will have higher
levels of value creation. The greater the ratio of sales over cost of goods sold, the lower
Firm size
Previous studies suggest that firm size is a relevant characteristic that influences the
intensity of firm innovation (Damanpour, 2010; Hecker and Ganter, 2013; Zona et al., 2013).
Several studies provide evidence of a positive relationship between firm size and innovation.
Further, firm size —that is, large firms—is found to be related with the level of innovation
(Aiken and Hage, 1971; Moch et al., 1977; Kimberly and Evanisko, 1981; Ettlie et al. 1984;
Dewar and Dutton, 1986; Damanpour 1992; Sullivan and Jikyeong, 1999; Camisón-Zornoza,
2004; Damanpour, 2010; Zona et al., 2013). Large firms are more innovative because of the
well as knowledge capability and economies of scope. Furthermore, large firms have a greater
capability to afford the cost of innovation as well as to manage the risk of unsuccessful efforts
(Nord and Tucker, 1987; Hitt, et al., 1990; Chandy and Tellis, 2000; Damanpour, 2010;;
Camison-Zornoza et al., 2004; Hecker and Ganter, 2013). Among the benefits related to size,
Vorley (2001) explains that large firms, in spite of having a cost advantage, are in a strong
position to invest in R&D and to access information that can benefit firm performance.
This theory suggests that firm size is one of the determinants of a firm’s level of
innovation and thus of value creation. As a result, large firms within the industry are capable
of creating cost advantages. Additionally, they have access to and control of the most valuable
intellectual property and can procure capital with which to innovate. It is important to account
18
for firm size when estimating value creation across the value chain to avoid possible
confounding effects of differing firm size across the four nodes of the value chain.
Hypothesis VI: There is a positive relationship between firm size and value creation.
A critical component of the agri-food value chain value creation question involves how
one measures value creation. While firms have become more focused on value creation, there
has been a growing concern about the use of value creation measures based on traditional
accounting information such as Return on Equity (ROE), Earning per Shares (EPS), Net
Operating Profit After Taxes (NOPAT) and Return on Investment (ROI) (Ibendahl and
Fleming, 2003). Although widely used, these measures fail both to capture a firm’s value
creation that results from management actions, and to account for the full cost of capital
(Sharma and Kumar, 2010). That is, accounting income is not a good estimator of true value
creation, and value creation efficiency (Sharma and Kumar, 2010). From an economic
perspective, to create value a company must produce higher benefits than its cost of capital. An
accurate measure of financial performance, economic value added (EVA), explains how well
a company produces operating benefits, given the amount of working capital invested
measure the value created by each business unit, since this measure provides better information
than traditional measures (Geyser and Liebenberg, 2003; Ibendahl and Fleming, 2003).
The EVA of a company is defined as “a measure of the incremental return that the
investment earns over the market rate of return” (Sharma and Kumar, 2010). According to
Stewart (1991), this manner of calculating value creation comprises a unified financial
19
framework that includes “financial accounting, management accounting and business
valuation” (O'Hanlon and Peasnell, 1998). The formula for determining EVA is as follows:
AdjNOPAT
EVA = ( − Cost of Capital) ∗ NOA (1)
NOA
Where,
AdjNOPAT is the adjusted net operating profit after taxes. EVA measures the value created by
the operating activities of the company and thus involves an adjusted NOPAT that does not
include non-operating revenues and expenses. These would include such factors as training
made to the accounting measure of NOPAT (Ibendahl and Fleming, 2003; Chmelíková, 2008).
Net Operating Assets (NOA) represents the working capital invested or the total capital
employed by a firm via its main business activities. NOA involves an adjustment similar to that
of NOPAT and removes accounting items that are not used to generate an operating profit of
the core business, such as non-operating fixed assets. Other such factors might include
investment in R&D that may be activated, since this type of expenditure is considered a source
of value creation, and non-operating current assets that are not employed in operating activities
The cost of capital is the weighted average of debt and equity cost. This study calculates
the cost of capital of each firm using the weighted average cost of capital (WACC).
The estimation of EVA measures the true economic profits which is different form
accounting profits in a variety of ways. The EVA takes into account the cost of capital that
20
managers must pay for the capital they employed. Under traditional accounting ratios, a firm
may seem to be profitable when in reality they are not, therefore, the cost of capital is one of
the most relevant component of the EVA estimation as it allow managers to determine the true
value generated by the capital employed (Anderson et al., 2004; Sharma et al., 2010).
According to Walbert (1994), businesses are no longer driven by making higher profits, but
focus on earning a return of capital over the cost of opportunity of the capital. Furthermore, the
EVA metric adjusts accounting information to combine operating efficiency and asset
Much of the previous research uses EVA as a comparative metric to stock price to test
market efficiency hypotheses rather than to explore levels and determinants of value creation,
which is our objective (Turvey et al., 2000; Keef and Roush, 2003; Sparling and Turvey, 2003).
Furthermore, previous studies measure EVA at the firm level, leaving open the opportunity for
The EVA metric is a dollar scaled metric and thus is highly correlated with firm size.
Previous studies suggest that large companies could create more value than smaller companies
despite not using their assets as efficiently because the EVA metric is sensitive to size bias
(Ibendahl and Fleming 2003; Anderson et al., 2004). That is, larger firms, ceteris paribus, create
more nominal value. To understand how firm size affects the EVA metric, suppose that Firm
A has a zero cost of capital, net operating assets of 100 dollars and an AdjNOPAT of 10 dollars.
Calculating the EVA for this firm shows that Company A has an EVA value of 10 dollars.
Then, suppose that a smaller Firm B also has a cost of capital equal to zero and only 10 dollars
of net operating assets but has an adjNOPAT of 1 dollar. The EVA value for Firm B will be 1
dollar. Comparing these firms one in terms of EVA would incorrectly conclude that Firm A is
creating more value than Firm B. The rate at which both companies create value is exactly the
same, which means that both companies are using their capital equally efficiently. In other
21
words, the ratio adjNOPAT/NOA is equal to 0.1 for both companies, but since Firm A is
employing more capital, the EVA value for Firm A is higher than for Firm B. Our interest,
though, focuses more on real and relative value creation and those firms that are efficient or
inefficient users of capital when creating or destroying value. We develop and employ a second
value creation metric, the MEVA, which is scale neutral, is expressed as a percentage, and is
defined as follows:
𝐴𝑑𝑗𝑁𝑂𝑃𝐴𝑇
𝑀𝐸𝑉𝐴 = ( − 𝐶𝑜𝑠𝑡 𝑜𝑓 𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙) ∗ 100 (2)
𝑁𝑂𝐴
A NOA weighted MEVA is estimated for each of the value chain nodes. Both the EVA
and MEVA may be positive, a net creator of value, or negative, a net destroyer of value. EVA
has no range limits while the MEVA ranges between -100% and 100%.
A positive EVA or MEVA indicates that the firm or value chain node creates value
because the operating assets or working capital employed generate a return sufficient to cover
the capital costs of those assets. On the contrary, a negative EVA or MEVA indicates that a
company is destroying value because the returns from its net operating assets fall short of the
returns required to capitalize the company. EVA and MEVA, as value creation metrics, are not
income may actually destroy value because the assets of the firm may have a higher and better
use. The measures show how efficiently the operating assets are being employed to generate a
22
DATA
worldwide is analyzed. The data originate from income statement and balance sheets for each
of the firms collected from Morningstar Inc. Included are agri-food companies from 25
countries (64% are U.S. companies, 3.26% United Kingdom, 3.89% Japan, 3.36 % China, and
2.86% from Mexico and others). The data selected to conduct this study includes all the firms
packaged food, farm construction, restaurants, food distribution, farm-products and grocery
industries. The agri-food value chain is divided into four stages, inputs, production, processing,
and delivery to consumers, and the companies are then reclassified into these four stages
according to the main activity of each. Table 3 provides a brief description of this database,
including a description of the main activities of each stage, as well as the number of companies
at each stage. This includes 97 companies in the input stage, 65 firms belonging to the
production stage, 156 companies within the processing stage, and 136 companies in the
retailer’s stage. The data represent firms that conduct activities that are part of the agri-food
value chain. Firms may conduct activities involving more than one sage along the value chain.
In such cases we follow the classification made by Morningstar Inc. identifying the main
activity of the each company. This main activity then tags the firm to a particular value chain
node. A number of quantitative measures and statistical tests are used to verify the differences
The Morningstar data reported is expressed in the local currency of each firm’s country.
All the observations are converted into U.S dollar units based on the World Bank’s official
exchange rate. The official exchange rate refers to the exchange rate determined by national
23
authorities, or the rate determined in the legally sanctioned exchange market. It is calculated as
an annual average based on monthly averages (local currency units relative to U. S dollars).
Using this financial data, the EVA and MEVA metrics are calculated for each firm for
each year. The following formulas are used to compute the value creation measures:
𝐴𝑑𝑗𝑁𝑂𝑃𝐴𝑇 (3)
𝐸𝑉𝐴 = ( − 𝐶𝑜𝑠𝑡 𝑜𝑓 𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙) ∗ NOA
𝑁𝑂𝐴
𝐴𝑑𝑗𝑁𝑂𝑃𝐴𝑇
𝑀𝐸𝑉𝐴 = ( − 𝐶𝑜𝑠𝑡 𝑜𝑓 𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙) ∗ 100 (4)
𝑁𝑂𝐴
expenses, R&D expenditures, restructuring, and merger and acquisition costs) are summarized
in Table 4. Table 5 presents the adjustments made to total assets. This table provides a brief
description of the adjustments made to total assets to calculate the NOA variable.
The cost of capital is the weighted average of debt and equity cost. To calculate the cost
of capital of each firm at each time period the weighted average cost of capital (WACC) is
used. This method considers the opportunity cost of each source of capital (debt and equity).
Formally,
𝐷 𝐸
𝑟𝑘 = 𝑟𝑑 (1 − 𝑡) ( ) + 𝑟𝑒 ( ) (3)
𝐷+𝐸 𝐷+𝐸
24
Cost of debt is the average cost of the debt for each firm (Equation 4). It is estimated
using,
𝐼𝑛𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑒𝑠𝑡 𝐸𝑥𝑝𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑒𝑠
𝑟𝑑 = (4)
𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑙𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑖𝑒𝑠
The variable tax (t) is used as the official corporate tax rate of each country. Weights
To estimate the cost of equity, the capital-asset pricing model (CAPM) is used
(Equation 5).
𝑟𝑒 = 𝑅𝑓 + 𝛽(𝑅𝑚 − 𝑅𝑓 ) (5)
where,
𝑅𝑓 = Risk-free bond
risk-free bonds (𝑅𝑓 ), the stock’s equity beta (𝛽 = 1.0 is average risk) and the market risk
premium (𝑅𝑚 − 𝑅𝑓 ) needed to attract investors to hold onto the market portfolio of risky assets
(Bruner et al., 1998; Sharma and Kumar, 2010). To calculate the risk-free rate of return a 10-
year Treasury bond return obtained from the Federal Reserve database is used. The long-term
bond yield carefully accounts for the default-free holding period return available and
consequently most closely represent companies’ investments (Bruner et al., 1998). The market
risk premium is calculated from the average of the last 25 years as the difference between the
return of the Standard & Poor’s 500 and the risk-free return. Since this database includes
25
companies from developing countries, the country risk premium to the cost of capital is
included. The country risk premium is the increased return that investors have to pay to invest
in a country that is deemed risky for investment. Risk premium estimates are based on the
country ratings assigned by Moodys. This premium measures a given country’s default risk.
Finally, the beta of each firm is estimated using the unleveraged beta by industry. The
unleveraged betas are estimated using the average market debt/equity ratio by industrial sector.
The betas are then leveraged using each company’s debt/equity ratio
This study also calculates a dummy variable called ‘create value’ (CEVA) which takes
value 1 when MEVA>0 and, 0 otherwise. This variable accounts for the proportion of
companies that have positive MEVA within a particular stage. Furthermore, a ‘persistent value
creation’ (PEVA) variable is calculated to identify the companies that have, in each node,
positive value creation levels for a period of at least five years. This variable is a dummy
variable that takes value equal to 1 if the firm uses its capital efficiently for at least 5 years, and
0, otherwise. This variable identifies and evaluates the characteristics of firms that are
sustainable in the efficient use of their capital. The objective of this analysis is to evaluate the
performance of the companies across time and to identify certain characteristics and patterns
of companies that use their capital efficiently and those that do not.
The analysis of the data also includes firms’ financial characteristics, such as firm size,
Firm size: Previous literature uses different proxies for firm size. Generally, firm size
is measured by using the total sales (Arundel and Kabla, 1998), total assets (Gopalakrishnan
26
and Damanpour, 2000; Zehri et al., 2012) or number of employees (Ettlie et al., 1987; Sawang
and Unsworth, 2011; Zona et al., 2013). For the purpose of this study, the term ‘total assets’ is
used as a proxy for firm size (Goldsmith and Sporleder, 1998; Gopalakrishnan and Damanpour,
2000; Camisón-Zornoza et al., 2004; Damanpour, 2010). From total assets the amount of
intangibles and goodwill is subtracted to avoid counting them twice and to allow them to be
Leverage: In the process of value creation, capital structure is significant. One crucial
aspect is the proper usage of debt or leverage (Houle, 2008). Positive effects are associated
with increasing the leverage of a company in that it saves taxes, cures the risk of unproductively
reinvesting surplus cash flow, creates an urgency to perform well, and forces the sale of
from Finance and Accounting literature generally suggests that financial leverage is a risk
factor (Ely, 1995). This implies that firms with higher levels of financial leverage are riskier
than firms with lower levels of debt (Hua and Templeton, 2010). The interpretation of the
leverage variable is as follows: “the higher the ratio, the more debt a company uses in its capital
structure” (Morningstar). Defined as total assets divided by total shareholders' equity, financial
leverage is included in our analysis to measure the implications of capital structure on value
COGS: Cost of goods sold is the cost a company incurs to process, create, and/or sell a
goods or services including the price of the inputs as well as the costs of transforming it into a
final food product (Morningstar). Cost of goods sold is expressed as a percentage of revenue.
Since a high level of COGS will decrease firms’ revenues, it may negatively impacts the value
creation levels.
27
Innovation: Following previous studies, this variable is composed of R&D
expenditures (Zona et al., 2013), goodwill (Degryse et al., 2012) and intangible assets (Kramer
2011). This study measures innovation in three variables. ‘Innovation 1’ is composed of the
three components described above; it is the sum of R&D expenditures, goodwill and intangible
assets. The study proceeds to separately evaluate the different sources of innovation to
determine whether there are differences in the source of value creation among the four nodes.
‘Innovation 2’ is composed of capital assets (intangible assets and goodwill) and ‘Innovation
3’ is composed of R&D expenditures. These variables are included to measure the impact of
Summary statistics
This section includes the main characteristics of the data while presenting the definition,
means and standard deviation of the main variables (Table 6a) used in this study for each stage
of the agri-food value chain. Mean tests are calculated to determine whether the value outcomes
for each stage are statistically different from each other. Furthermore, a mean test is performed
to determine whether the outcomes of various stages are altogether different from the average
value outcome of the whole food value chain. In this way, this research provides insights
regarding the statistical differences in mean value outcomes among the various stages, and
between individual stages and the mean value outcomes of the whole value chain. Table 6b
illustrates the results from the mean test analysis and provides the p-values of those tests.
28
Value creation analysis
The EVA metric measures, in dollar terms, how well the firms are using their operating
capital to produce operating profits. In other words, the EVA value shows the net value created
by a firm after accounting for the cost of capital. The EVA metric of each stage is calculated
by taking the average EVA of the firms comprising each stage. Analysis shows that in terms
of EVA, agricultural inputs is the node that creates the most value, having, on average, an
added economic value of 264 million dollars per firm, which is 40% higher than the average
EVA of the whole value chain. Stage 3 has an average mean EVA value of 257 million dollars
per firm, which, in dollar terms, makes it the second highest contributor to the agri-food value
creation process. Stage 4 has a mean EVA value of 107 million dollars, having on average a
value creation level 43% below the value creation level of the whole agri-food value chain.
The production stage creates, on average, 43 million dollars, which represents 23% of the
average mean EVA value for the whole chain. The mean tests conducted to show whether
stages are statistically different in terms of the EVA variable do not allow a conclusion that
Stage 1 and Stage 3 are statistically different from each other. Similarly, the null hypothesis
The EVA value for chain members is determined by the level of net operating assets
and the adjusted NOPAT, as well as the cost of capital. Net operating assets differ across value
chain members. In Stage 1, the mean value of NOA is 5,979 million dollars per firm, which is
only 1% lower than average net operating assets per firm in Stage 3, in which the average NOA
is equal to 6,053 million dollars. Stage 1 and Stage 3 have, on average, net operating asset
values 34% and 36% higher than the mean operating assets of the value chain. The mean tests
conducted to measure differences among stages show that Stage 1 and Stage 3 are not
statistically different from each other in terms of NOA. Similarly, for Stage 2 and Stage 4 the
null hypothesis cannot be rejected for significant differences among them; thus, these two
29
stages are not shown to be different in terms of NOA. The average net operating assets for
Stage 4 total 2,200 million dollars, 12% lower than for Stage 2.
Likewise, this study does not find significant differences between Stage 1 and Stage 3
dollars, and Stage 3 generates net operating profits of 639 million dollars, on average, per firm.
Similarly, this study cannot state that Stage 2 and Stage 4 are different in terms of AdjNOPAT.
Stage 2 has an average AdjNOPAT of 210 million dollars, which is 14% lower than the average
net operating profits for Stage 4, which produces 245 million dollars. The rejection of the null
hypotheses of the mean tests for the variables described above, for Stages 1 and 3, and Stages
2 and 4, can be attributed to the differences in size among firms within those respective stages.
Firm size
The various nodes differ significantly in size across the value chain (Fig. 3). To measure
firm size, this study used adjusted total assets. Firm total assets are adjusted by intangible assets
and goodwill to avoid double accounting the intangible capital in the regression model. Stage
1 is significantly larger than Stage 3, Stage 2 and Stage 4, being composed of firms 1.5 times
larger than the average value chain. This fact gives an insight into the need for companies
within this stage to obtain benefits related to large-scale business to create value. This stage
has a coefficient of variability of 1.79 in size, an average 15% less variability than the overall
value chain, implying that in terms of size, Stage 1 is the most homogeneous node. Companies
in Stage 3 have, on average, total assets valuing 4,207 million dollars per firm—the second
largest stage within the agri-food value chain. Interestingly, Stage 3, which is smaller than
Stage 1, generates the same amount of EVA, suggesting that firms in Stage 3 are using their
capital more efficiently than those in Stage 1. In Stage 2, the average firm has 3,067 million
30
dollars in adjusted total assets, and Stage 4 firms have, on average, 3,444 million dollars per
firm and the highest coefficient of variation, making Stage 4 the most heterogeneous node in
terms of adjusted total assets. Stage 2 is a chain member composed of smaller firms within the
overall value chain (mean size of 3,067 million dollars). According to the mean test, this study
cannot affirm that, in terms of size, Stage 2 and Stage 4 are on average statistically different
Although the EVA metric is widely used by managers and academics because it has
better capabilities for measuring the firm value creation level in comparison with traditional
accounting measures, for the purpose of this study the EVA is a weak metric for comparing
value creation across the agri-food value chain. The statistical analysis of the mean EVA value
by stages supports this; the EVA metric is not an accurate measure for comparing value creation
levels among firms or stages because it is affected by the size of the companies. For this reason
it is not appropriate to conduct an analysis and evaluation of the differences in value creation
Across the agri-food value chain, each stage is composed of firms of different sizes.
This study analyzes the relationship between a company’s EVA and a company’s NOA to
understand bias toward the EVA by firm size. A company’s NOA variable is measured by the
average NOA per firm over a period of years. Similarly, a company’s EVA variable is created
to measure the average EVA per firm over a period of years. There is a positive relationship
between the size of the company and its level of value creation (Fig. 4). Meanwhile, there is a
positive correlation (0.77) between a firm’s size and the level of value creation measured by
EVA. This provides evidence that small firms may produce low levels of EVA, and large firms
31
may generate high levels of EVA. The differences in the EVA value can be due to differences
in firm size and not necessarily because of differences in the efficient use of firms’ operating
capital.
MEVA
For evidence of value creation, this study aims to evaluate how efficiently companies
among the agri-food nodes are using their capital. An accurate understanding of a firm’s value
creation requires that company size be controlled to avoid firm size bias. The best metric of
value creation to compare and correctly analyze the value creation of a stage composed of firms
of different sizes is the MEVA metric. This metric removes the distortion caused by firm size
and measures a comparable value creation level in terms of the rate at which each company is
creating value. The MEVA variable measures the standardized/normalized value creation.
Technically, the modified EVA is the EVA metric divided (normalized) by the capital
Down-chain is where the most value is created in terms of MEVA. On average, Stage
3 and Stage 4 are creating additional operating capital at the rate of 0.83% and 3.43 % per year
respectively, while upstream the average rate of value creation is negative. Down-chain there
is also less variability in terms of MEVA, suggesting that Stage 3 and Stage 4 are more
homogeneous in the rate at which companies create value than is the case with up-chain
members. Delivery to consumer is the node that uses its capital most efficiently, having a mean
value MEVA of 196% higher than the mean MEVA value of the overall chain. The average
firm in Stage 4 creates value at a rate 3.43% of net operating assets, in excess of the cost of
capital. This stage is composed of 136 companies, of which 71 have persistent positive levels
of value creation (52% of the firms have persistent positive MEVA value). This stage is
32
characterized by having the smallest percentage of negative MEVA observations and the
largest level of value creation rate (Fig. 5). The distribution of MEVA in Stage 4 is farther to
the right in comparison with other stages. In comparison with other nodes, Stage 4 is composed
of small firms with high a level of value creation. Taking into account the average NOA and
multiplying it by the average MEVA, Stage 4 is creating, on average, 7,555 million dollars of
net operating assets. Stage 3 has a mean MEVA value of 0.833%, being the second-highest
chain node contributor to the value creation process. In dollar terms, the average company in
this stage generates net operating total assets of 5,042 million dollars (if we take into account
the average NOA of the stage). In this stage 58% of companies create value across time and
represent the greatest proportion of persistent value creation companies. Firms that persistently
use capital efficiently have, on average, a value creation rate of 4.6% in Stage 3, while in Stage
4 persistent value creation companies create value at the average rate of 7.48% of net operating
assets.
On the other hand, up-chain is, on average, destroying value. Stage 1 is destroying value
at an average rate of 0.195% while Stage 2 is destroying value at an average rate of 0.806%.
On average, companies within these stages do not generate enough operating profit to cover
the cost of opportunity for their capital. Stage 2 is destroying value at the highest average rate
in the agri-food value chain. The production sector has 68% of its firms persistently destroying
value. It is the chain node with the highest number of firms having negative value creation
levels across time. This implies that, on average, the business nature of this stage is making
firms to create low value. This stage is the most commoditized sector of the value chain,
wherein a low level of product differentiation takes place, and the strategic advantage over
competitors is limited to achieving low cost and economies of scale and scope. In particular,
low-scale companies have a significantly lower value of MEVA in comparison with large-scale
companies within this stage (Fig 5). Persistent value-destroying companies are characterized
33
by having net operating assets 3 times smaller and an adjusted NOPAT 5 times smaller than
persistent value creation companies. Firms in the production sector are not persistent in value
creation. The main differences between observations with positive MEVA and negative MEVA
are that the positive ones rely on the level of net operating profits. Positive MEVA observations
have, on average, 21.6% more net operating assets than negative MEVA observations, but 3
times higher AdjNOPAT. Companies need to focus on obtaining higher levels of net operating
profits to create value. Furthermore, positive MEVA observations have COGS 12% lower than
those that destroy value. Overall, this stage is characterized by small firms that create low rates
of value.
Agricultural inputs companies destroy value at the average rate of 0.194%. This Stage
which is 507% higher than the coefficient of variation of the entire value chain. This means
that companies within Stage 1 create value at significantly different rates. The size of the firms
in this stage is crucial for creating value. Small firms have extremely low values of MEVA,
which increases the variability of the average MEVA for this stage (Fig 5). An analysis of the
data shows evidence of a strong relationship between size and the rate at which firms create
value (Fig. 4). In particular, 25% of agricultural inputs companies with the lowest MEVA
within the stage have net operating assets of 2,125 million dollars on average, and the range of
the MEVA value for these companies goes from -83% to -3%. The other 75% of companies
included in this stage have a positive value of MEVA (ranging from 2% to 34%) and a mean
NOA of 7,251 million dollars, which is 3.4 times higher than the mean NOA for the other 25%.
Therefore, Stage 1 is characterized by two main features. First, there is evidence of high
heterogeneity in the rate at which companies create value in terms of MEVA. Second, this
study finds that firms with a low value of MEVA have, on average, low values of net operating
assets.
34
The distribution of MEVA differs across the four stages (Fig. 5). The mean test shows
statistically significant differences among the MEVA value for all chain members. In all stages,
small firms have lower rates of value creation in comparison with large ones, which implies
that value creation is, in part, a function of size. Despite the differences in value creation rates
among stages, large firms tend to have a positive value of MEVA. In other words, the benefits
associated with large business units are helping companies to create value. The nature of the
business of each stage seems to be playing an important role in determining the level of value
creation. Furthermore, the variability within stages in terms of MEVA decreases down-chain,
implying that down-chain companies are using capital more efficiently, but the down-chain
The objective of this variable is to measure the number of observations in each stage
that create value. Technically, it is a dummy variable that takes value equal to 1 if the
observation has a positive value creation level and zero otherwise. So, this variable measures
whether a firm’s operating assets are being efficiently used in a particular year, but it does not
account for how well the capital is used. This metric is calculated as a manner of validating
results. The value member containing the highest number of observations with a positive value
creation level is Stage 4 with 67% of its observations demonstrating efficient use of operating
capital. With 8 % fewer number of observations creating value, Stage 3 is the second highest
chain member in this category, composed of 62% observations with positive value creation
levels, followed by Stage 1 with 60% of the firms creating value. Agricultural inputs has only
52% of its observations creating value, and therefore is the chain member with the least
proportion of observations creating value, having 16% fewer created value observations than
35
the overall value chain. In accordance with the MEVA analysis, the down-chain stages show a
The mean test performed to reflect differences among the stages in terms of MEVA
shows statistical differences among all the nodes except for Stage 1 and Stage 3. For these two
stages the null hypothesis cannot be rejected. This variable only identifies whether a firm
capital is being used efficiently or not (without accounting for how much value is created, either
in percentage or in dollar terms). The ‘CEVA’ variable analysis shows that except for Stage 2,
more than 60% of the observations have positive value creation levels. However, the MEVA
calculation shows that from those observations that created value, the rate at which companies
add value varies across stages. Overall, this analysis of value creation definitely gives an insight
that down-chain is where most of value is being created. Furthermore, the three measures of
value creation evaluated in this section support the conclusion that agricultural producers are
Innovation
Innovation is considered one of the drivers of value creation. The innovation variable
is composed of the sum of R&D, goodwill and intangible assets. Since firm innovation level is
related to firm size, it is more accurate to analyze the mean value as a percentage of total assets.
Stage 3 is the most innovative chain member, investing 66% of the average adjusted total assets
in innovative activities, and Stage 3 is the second stage that where the most value is produced,
in terms of EVA, MEVA and CEVA. Nevertheless, Stage 3 has the greater coefficient of
variation, suggesting heterogeneity in terms of innovation capital among firms. Stage 4 is the
36
second most innovative value chain actor, investing 21% of adjusted total assets in innovation
activities, which is one-third the level of Stage 4. Stage 1 invests in innovation 4.4 times less
than Stage 3, assigning 15% of the adjusted total assets to innovative activities. As the most
commoditized node, it is not surprising that Stage 2 is the least innovative chain member,
investing on average 9% of total assets in innovative activities. According to the mean test, the
mean value of innovation is significantly different among the chain actors in, except for Stage
1 and Stage 4, as well as Stage 2 and Stage 4, since the null hypothesis for the mean test
conducted to test differences in innovation cannot be rejected for these particular stages.
Down-chain is where most of the value chain value is being created, but also where
innovation and value creation level. The distribution of the innovation variable varies across
stages (Fig. 6). Stage 3 has a higher level of investment in innovation capital but also greater
dispersion, suggesting that within this stage the level of innovation among firms differs.
Not only the level but also the source of innovation varies across the four nodes. In the
following paragraph, this study separately analyzes each component of the innovation variable:
‘Innovation 2’ variable is composed by intangible capital (intangible assets plus goodwill), and
‘Innovation 3’ is composed by R&D expenditures. This study also reports the proportion of
The analysis of ‘Innovation 2’ shows that the main source of innovation in all the
stages—except for agricultural inputs—is intangible capital. For Stages 2, 3 and 4, the
innovation level is a function of intangible capital and not of R&D expenditures, as 99% of
innovation investments involve goodwill and intangible assets for the three nodes. In Stage 1,
intangible capital represents 86% of the total amount of innovation, and provides the main
source of innovation for this node. However, Stage 1 is where the greater investment in R&D
takes place. From the total investment in innovation, 16% is assigned to R&D expenditures,
37
which represents, on average, 141 million dollars (34% of the average net income). This is
eight times more than spent in Stage 3, the next highest member in R&D investment, Stage 3
average net income for this stage. The significantly higher level of investment in R&D in Stage
1 can be explained by the progressively higher need for product differentiation at earlier
production stages, and by the business nature of this member, which needs to be engaged in
The analysis of innovation variables shows that down-chain is where the highest
proportion of total assets is assigned to intangible capital and also where the most value is
created. Consistent with the previous evaluation, Stage 2 having the lowest level of innovation
is the node that creates the least value. This suggests a positive relationship between innovation
COGS
The analysis of COGS focuses on identifying key relationships between buyers and
sellers to determine if there exists any type of complementarities in terms of costs and prices
among stages. Furthermore, this study aims to identify the implications of cost in the value
creation process. Cost of goods sold includes the inputs cost paid to the up-chain member plus
the cost of value-added activities performed to make the product ready for the next stage—and
not including indirect costs such as selling, general and administrative costs.
The distribution of COGS varies across chain members (Fig. 7). Consistent with the
MEVA analysis, down-chain is where the gross margin is higher than that of up-chain
members. Stage 4 is the only node that has COGS below 100%; the other stages have
companies with COGS above 100%. In particular, Stage 2 has the greatest proportion of
companies with COGS above 100% (3.5%), which can be traced to the nature of its productive
38
cycle. Production companies experience high uncertainty with selling prices. This risk is
increased by the timing between receptions of input to the moment when the product is ready
On average, Stage 2 pays the highest cost in terms of revenues. Agricultural producers
spend, on average, 78% of their revenues on inputs costs. This can also be related to the fact
that product differentiation allows Stage 1 to force higher prices for products since companies
are offering unique products such as patented, high performance seeds. Stage 2 may offer low-
cost products to processors because they sell undifferentiated materials such as raw
commodities. This stage pays high inputs prices, having a gross margin of only 22% of its
revenues, and then sells to processors at low prices. Stage 3 is the chain member that pays the
lowest input prices (in comparison with all chain members), but it is the actor that adds the
most value to the products in gross terms. Specifically, 35% of its revenues represent the cost
of the value-added activities, and it pays 65% of its revenues in cost, having on average the
lowest rate of COGS in terms of revenue. In the previous analysis, this study finds that Stage
3 is the most intangible capital-oriented one, and clearly, Stage 3 is the chain member with
most opportunities for differentiating products and adding value to products through branding,
developing new products and new markets, and offering high-quality and ready-to-eat
products. The last stage of the agri-food value chain spends 71% of its revenues in cost of
goods sold, having one of the highest margin of the chain members. That can be attributed to
the fact that deliver to consumer sells its products to the consumer markets giving a key and
Buying and selling activities are related among members of the agri-food value chain,
and this study finds a negative relationship between COGS and MEVA outcomes (Fig. 8).
Consistent with previous analysis, down-chain is where companies create more value and also
pay the lowest input prices. In particular, processors can be seen as being in the strongest
39
position in terms of COSG, since companies within this stage buy at the lowest prices from the
least value-adding node and perform value-adding activities which allow them to obtain higher
margins. Furthermore, this analysis gives the insight that market power in down-chain stages
Financial leverage
this variable measures the proportion of equity and debt the company uses to finance the firm’s
assets. This analysis shows that there is no difference among stages in the level of financial
leverage. The mean test indicates that the mean leverage levels for each stage are not different
from one another. Additional investigation of the implications of financial leverage in the value
In order to deeply understand the distribution of the variables, the present study
evaluates the standard deviations of our main variables to identify whether the source of the
variance is due to differences across time or across firms. Each stage of the agri-food value
chain is composed of heterogeneous groups of firms. In other words, the variability among
firms within each stage is what explains the standard deviation. Firms across years seem not to
be experiencing significant variations regarding the main variables analyzed in this study.
40
EMPIRICAL MODEL
To test our hypotheses and to identify which actors in the value chain are the highest
contributors to the value adding process we use an econometric model. This model essentially
consists of measuring the effect of inputs, production, processors and delivery to consumer
stages in the value creation process. It next determines the impact of firm size, firm capital
structure, and expenditures in innovation and COGS on stage value creation. The dependent
variables of the models are the value creation measures described in the previous sections:
EVA, MEVA, CEVA, PEVA variables. Formally, the models are as follows:
Explicative Variables
41
Stage 1 is a dummy variable that takes value equal to one if the firm belongs to Stage
1, and zero otherwise. Stage 2 is a dummy variable that takes value equal to one if the firm
belongs to Stage 2 and zero otherwise, and Stage 3 is a dummy variable that takes value equal
to one if the firm belong to Stage 3 and zero otherwise. To avoid the dummy variable trap we
drop the Stage 2 variable. This theory suggests that Stage 2 (agricultural production) is the
more commoditized stage; therefore we drop the dummy variable for the second stage to
compare all the results against a stage that has a lesser probability of creating value. These
dummy variables are included to measure the contribution of each stage in the value creation
There are three main sources of bias in the present study. These are factors related to
each particular country, year or company. In order to avoid the endogeneity problem due to
unobservables in the error term, country-fixed effects (CountryFE) and year-fixed effects
(yearFE) are included. All country-fixed effects control for the unobservables in each country
that may affect the value creation process. In the same way, the year-fixed effects control for
shocks that affect all companies’ value creation process for each particular year. Since the
variables of interest are the stage dummy variables that changes at company levels, company-
fixed effects cannot be included. For this reason company characteristics are included instead
of company fixed effects such as size, leverage, goodwill and intangible capital, R&D
Firm characteristic variables are included in the regression model. The first is firm size,
measured as the logarithm of adjusted total assets to quantify the impact of firm size on the
value creation process. The second is firm leverage, measured as total current liabilities over
total equity, which is included in the model to measure the effect of the financial capabilities
of each firm with regard to the create value variables. This study includes two measures of
innovation: ‘Inn2’ that reports the value of intangible capital (intangible and goodwill assets),
42
and ‘Inn3’ that reports the value of R&D expenditures. Furthermore, the variable COGS is
To validate the results and provide reliable findings, a t-test is performed to determine
whether stages are statistically different from one another after controlling for value creation
drivers. The primary interest relies on verification that the regression results of EVA, MEVA,
43
RESULTS
This study estimates the effect of being part of the different stages of the value chain in
EVA, MEVA, CEVA and PEVA variables. The four models are designed to test Hypothesis I
that states that each stage contributes differently to the value creation process and to estimate
the contribution of each stage in the value adding process. In this section, the results of our
regression models are presented (Table 7). Only three dummy variables, Stage 1, Stage 3 and
Stage 4 are included in order to avoid the dummy variable trap, making Stage 2 the baseline
against which to compare. The test for significant differences across stages is also reported.
The four value creation metrics are calculated using each firm’s net operating profits
after taxes (NOPAT). The data used in the present study is comprised by firm from different
countries. Therefore, one interesting question that may arise is how local tax rates and policies
affect the NOPAT variable and the EVA estimation. For validation purposes we estimate the
value creation metrics using the net operating profits before taxes. The results are robust
showing no change in the EVA coefficient estimates. Additionally, the four regression models
control for the country fixed effects, which in part address differences in tax policies.
The EVA metric calculates the value creation level, weighted by the capital invested in
productive activity. In terms of EVA, Stage 3 is the largest contributor to the agri-food value
creation process. On average, this stage creates 40 more millions of dollars per year than Stage
2, ceteris paribus. The coefficient estimate is significant at the 0.1 level. Processors are
followed by Stage 4, delivery to consumers, which creates 39 million more dollars per year in
terms of EVA than Stage 2—independent of the country in which the company was located,
44
the year of each observation, and the individual characteristics of each firm. The coefficient
estimates are significant at the 0.05 level. Stage 1, agricultural inputs, destroys 15 million more
dollars per year in terms of EVA than Stage 2, independent of the country in which the company
was located, the year of each observation, and the individual characteristics of each firm;
however, the coefficient estimates are not statistically significant. Stage 2 (the constant) has an
estimated coefficient of -8 and it is not statistically significant, meaning that it cannot be stated
that the EVA level for this stage is statistically different from zero. The superiority of the value
contemporary agribusiness literature that suggests that Stage 2 is the most commoditized stage,
for which possibilities for product differentiation are low and products offered by these
business units are characterized by being undifferentiated, homogeneous, and are a low level
of value-added goods.
Comparing the statistical differences for the dummy variables of each stage, results
show that the effect of being in Stage 3 cannot be statistically distinguished from the effect of
being in Stage 4. Additionally, the effect of being in either Stage 3 or Stage 4 is statistically
better than the effect of being in Stage 1 (t-test). To conclude, in terms of EVA, Stage 3 is the
sector that creates the most value in dollar terms, but in terms of EVA metric we cannot
statistically affirm that it is different from Stage 4, which follows Stage 3 in the chain. These
two nodes have a higher value creation level (measured as EVA) than Stage 2, which is not
statistically different from zero and Stage 1, showing that capital is being used more efficiently
by down-chain members.
45
MEVA as measure of value creation
In order to validate our results with a different measure of value creation, this research
estimates the MEVA metric that accounts for the standardized value creation level without
taking into account the capital invested in the productive process (see column 2 of Table 7).
In terms of MEVA, the value creation of the average company in Stage 3 or in Stage 4
increases to 1.59% and 4.71% per year respectively, in comparison with Stage 2, independent
of where the company is located, the year in which each observation took place, and the
individual characteristics of each firm. The coefficient estimates for Stage 1 is 0.60%, but not
statistically significant. For Stage 2, the coefficient estimate is negative but not statistically
significant. This is in accordance with the EVA results from Stage 2 that show that the
production sector is a poor contributor to the value creation process. The p-values for the t-
tests were performed to show whether stages are statistically different in term of MEVA.
Results show that there are statistically significant differences among the four nodes. Thus,
delivery to consumer is the value chain member that creates value at the highest rate in terms
of MEVA, followed by processors as the stage that contributes second most to the value
creation process. As hypothesized, the results show differences in the level of value creation
across the nodes and point out that down-chain nodes are the chain members that most
CEVA is s a dummy variable that takes value equal to 1 if the observation has a positive
value creation level, and zero, otherwise. This variable was analyzed to validate the results and
46
In particular, retailers have a highly significant coefficient estimate of 14.7%,
representing the chain member with the highest probability of creating value in comparison
with Stage 2. Stage 3 has a coefficient estimate of 8.8%, which is statistically significant at the
0.01 level, meaning that there is an 8.8% higher probability of having a positive value creation
level in Stage 3 than in Stage 2, ceteris paribus. The coefficient estimate for agricultural inputs
is 5.5% and is statistically significant at 0.01 level, which means that the probability of creating
value in Stage 1 is 5.5% higher when compared to Stage 2, which has a significant coefficient
value of 58.9%. In all cases, the CEVA variable is estimated independently of the country in
which company is located, the year of each observation, and the individual characteristics of
each firm.
The p-values for the t-test were calculated to show whether stages are statistically
different in terms of the CEVA variable. The results show statistical differences among the
four nodes except for Stage 1 and Stage 3, for which the null hypothesis for differences among
these stages cannot be rejected. In accordance with previous findings, Stage 2 has the least
probability of creating value in comparison with the other chain nodes. This result can be linked
with the nature of the business. Stage 4 is consistently one of the most efficient users of its
capital and captures the highest share of value-added. This can be linked to the fact that retailers
are controlling the flow of technology and knowledge along the chain—a finding that supports
previous research.
sustainable each stage may be in the generation of value. PEVA is a dummy variable that that
takes value equal to 1 if a company uses its capital efficiently for at least five years (half of the
47
period covered by the database), and zero otherwise. This variable identifies the proportion of
companies that persistently create value within each stage. Stage 4 has a coefficient estimate
of 2.18%, meaning that the probability of a persistent create value in Stage 4 is 2.18% higher
than in in Stage 2. The coefficient estimate for Stage 3 is 2.16% and for Stage 1, 1.58%. The
probability of creating persistent value for Stage 2 is negative, showing the inability of the most
commoditized stage to create value in a sustainable way. Finally, all the coefficient estimates
for each stage dummy are statistically different at the 0.1 level, again showing that the down-
The p-values for the t-test were calculated to show whether stages are statistically
different in terms of the PEVA variable. The results show statistical differences among the four
nodes except for Stage 3 and Stage 4, for which the null hypothesis for differences among these
The four regression models were designed to test Hypothesis III a, Hypothesis III b,
Hypothesis III c, Hypothesis III d that predict the level of value creation at each stage.
Hypothesis III argues that agricultural inputs is a high value creation node. Although this study
finds statistically significant results for the CEVA and PEVA models, there is no significant
results for EVA and MEVA variables. Thus, this research cannot affirm that the conditional
mean of the value created by companies in this stage is different from zero. Therefore, there is
mixed evidence and thus no strong support for Hypothesis III a. According to Hypothesis III
b, Stage 2 is expected to exhibit low levels of value creation. In all the regression results, this
study finds that the production sector is the least contributor in the value adding process.
Therefore, the estimation results validate Hypothesis III b. Although the differences in the
conditional mean for EVA and MEVA metrics between Stages 1 and 2 are not statistically
significant, this study shows that the dimensions that distinguish companies in Stage 1 and
Stage 2 in terms of EVA are firm size, financial health, innovation levels, COGS, year fixed
48
and country fixed effects. The present analysis also finds no statistically significant differences
between Stage 1 and Stage 2 regarding the conditional and unconditional mean MEVA. One
explanation for this is that both stages have average low rates of value creation. For instance,
the conditional mean is -0.194 and -0.806 for Stage 1 and Stage 2 respectively, which are rates
very close to zero if one takes into account that the MEVA range is -100 to 100. Companies
within these stages show this type of pattern over the years of analysis, making the conditional
mean of EVA and the MEVA undistinguishable between these two stages.
Hypothesis III c and Hypothesis III d states that Stage 3 and Stage 4 are high value
creation members. The empirical analysis conducted shows that Stage 4 is the chain node that
most efficiently uses its capital, being the greater contributor to the value creation process. The
four regression models validate these results. Processors is found to be the second most
contributor chain member in the value adding process. Therefore, these results provide strong
support for Hypothesis III c and Hypothesis III d as well as for Hypothesis II which states that
In the four regression models this study includes four control variables, as well as
variables at the company level that can determine the value creation of each company such as
firm size, leverage, goodwill and intangible capital, R&D expenditures and COGS.
The logarithm of adjusted total assets as a measure of firm size has a positive and
statistically significant coefficient estimate (at the 0.01 level) in all the regression models,
meaning that size is a significant determinant of value creation. An increase of one percent in
size increases the EVA level by 40 million dollars. According to the MEVA variable, an
49
increase of one percent in the size of a firm increases the rate of value creation by 2.5 percentage
points. The probability of creating value (MEVA) is increased by 0.059% for the average
company when the firm size is increased by one percent. Finally, the probability of persistently
created value increases by 0.088% when firm size is increased by one percent. These results
are consistent with previous literature which states that larger companies are more innovative
because of their better availability of resources, economies of scale and scope to spread the
risk—all in contrast to small companies. Furthermore, large firms are associated with higher
innovation, having higher R&D intensity, and taking advantage of economies of scale. These
results confirm the Hypothesis VI and provides evidence of a positive relationship between size
Leverage is measured as total liabilities over total equity. This variable measures the
source of capital within a company. For all these models the coefficient estimates are positive;
however only the EVA model (at the 0.1 level) is statistically significant. For the EVA model,
the coefficient estimate is 3.645, meaning that increasing firm leverage by one unit increases
All the regression models include two measures of innovation. The two measures of
innovation are included to test Hypothesis IV which states that innovation positive affects value
creation. Specifically, firms that have higher level intangible capital (Hypothesis IV a) or higher
level of R&D expenditures (Hypothesis IV b) may have higher levels of value creation.
Therefore, Intangible and goodwill assets (measured by ‘Inn 2’ variable) and R&D
expenditures (measured by ‘Inn 3’ variable) have been hypothesized as being key drivers of
innovation, and thus of value creation. The results of investment in R&D, differ depending on
the dependent variable. The coefficient estimate for the EVA model is 1.464 and is significant
at the 0.01 level, meaning that an increase of one million dollars in expenditures in R&D
50
increases a firm’s EVA by 1.4 million dollars. Furthermore, the coefficient estimate for the
CEVA model is 0.001 and is significant at the 0.01 level, meaning that the effect of increasing
expenditures in R&D by one million dollars increases, on average, the probability of creating
value by 0.1%, ceteris paribus. The coefficient estimates for R&D expenditures for the MEVA
and PEVA models are both 0.001; surprisingly, these are not statistically significant at 0.1
level. However, the coefficient estimates for the MEVA and PEVA models are significant at
0.2 level. Overall, these results are in accordance with Hypothesis V b and with previous
The second innovation variable is intangible capital, measured as the sum of goodwill
and intangible assets. As hypothesized, the regression results shows that intangible capital
positively affects value creation. For the first regression, the coefficient estimate is 0.045 and
is statistically significant at the 0.001 level, meaning that an increase in intangible capital of
one million dollars generates an increase of $45,000 dollars in a firm’s EVA. According to the
regression results for the MEVA model, an increase of one million dollars of intangible capital
increases the rate of value creation by 0.001. The coefficient estimate for intangible capital in
the CEVA model is 0.001, meaning that an increase of one million dollars in intangible capital
increases the probability of create value by 0.1 %. For the persistently create value model the
coefficient estimate is positive but not statistically significant. Therefore, the regression results
provide evidence of a positive relationship between innovation and value creation supporting
Hypothesis IV a.
Cost of goods sold is the ratio between cost and sales. The larger this ratio, the smaller
is the gross margin for the producer. Since this variable is the inverse of the gross margin of
the company, it is also an indirect measure of the level of product differentiation. This variable,
included in the four models to test Hypothesis V predicts a negative relationship between the
COGS ratio and the level of value creation. Increasing the ratio of COGS by one unit reduces
51
the firm’s EVA by $27.6 million dollars. The coefficient estimate is significant at the 0.05
level. Similarly, the probability of creating value decreases by 0.036 when COGS is increased
by one unit. The coefficient estimate is significant at the 0.01 level. For the MEVA and PEVA
models, the regression results are negative but not statistically significant. Since the variable
COGS can be interpreted as an inverse variable of product differentiation, the regression results
for the four models show a positive relationship between product differentiation and value
creation. In particular, the results show that firms producing more “commodity-like” products
have lower levels of value creation for the EVA and CEVA models providing support for
Hypothesis VI. Similarly, firms offering greater differentiation have a higher probability of
creating value. However, the results for the MEVA and PEVA does not provide strong support
for Hypothesis VI. Therefore, the results show a mixed evidence regarding the relationship
52
DISCUSSION
This paper offers insights and implications for managers, shareholders and investors.
The results serve as a benchmark for designing and implementing business strategies aiming
to accomplish an efficient use of capital and thus, obtain higher value creation outcomes.
This study shows significant differences in the value creation levels of four stages in
the agri-food value chain. For example, up-chain members contribute least to the value adding
process. Stage 1 is the homogeneous in terms of size in comparison with other chain nodes, but
has significant variability in MEVA values. Agricultural inputs is an inefficient user of capital.
Stage 1 is the chain node with the highest level of investment in R&D expenditures (on average,
34% of net income is invested in R&D) but has relatively low returns in terms of MEVA.
Although Stage 1 is the chain node with the highest EVA mean value, it is characterized by
low rates of value creation (62% of the observations have an MEVA value below the mean
MEVA of the stage) but high amounts of capital invested, since it is composed, on average, of
the largest firms in the overall value chain. Stage 1 represents low value creation because of
the nature of the business, which provides agricultural inputs such as farm machinery,
genetically modified seeds and fertilizer, among others. Naturally, these activities require high
capital intensity and installed capacity to gain scale and thus reduce costs.
The analysis of previous sections shows that 53% of the agricultural input companies
have positive PEVA outcomes, being a persistent but low value creation member. However,
these companies have experienced a high variability in value creation outcomes over the ten
years of study. For example, although Alamo Group Inc. (AGL), that manufactures and sells
creation, it has also experienced negative value creation levels in other years (Fig. 9). On
average, AGL destroyed 4.5 million dollars at the average rate of -1.12% (average MEVA).
53
Effective value creation appears unsustainable with respect to Alamo Group Inc. as even
though there are six non negative years of value creation, there are four years of highly negative
of significant capital destruction (Fig. 9). Like in this company, firms in this stage are
destroying value (on average, 40%), but they have periods of successful performance. This
example also shows the relevance of analyzing value creation across time. Managers should
take into account the importance of having persistent value creation business units, but they
should also be aware that new practices are needed to identify negative shocks and to mitigate
However, Stage 1 is comprised also by high value creating firms such as Monsanto.
Monsanto is a company that provides agricultural products for farmers such us seeds,
biotechnology trait products, and herbicides. Monsanto products are designed to improve
farmer’s productivity, reduce the costs of farming and produce better foods. Monsanto belongs
to Stage 1 in the agri-food value chain. The firm is a significant value creator over the 10 years
under analysis, having on average an EVA of $1,165 million dollars and the average annual
rate of value creation (MEVA) of 7.6%. Monsanto is a highly innovative company investing
10% of sales in R&D expenditures and maintaining 30% of the adjusted total assets in goodwill
and intangible assets. The firm is also a persistent value creator having positive MEVA value
outcomes in all the years under analysis. Furthermore, Monsanto attains an average COGS of
49.06% which is 24% lower than the average firm in the input stage. This firm as a high value
creator demonstrates that there are companies that are efficient users of capital and significant
value creators even in low value creation stages of the food and agribusiness value chain.
The production stage is characterized by being a poor value creator because it has the
lowest outcome in the four metrics of value creation analyzed in this study. The main distinctive
characteristic of this node is the inability to produce higher operating returns on capital. In
other words, companies intensely use capital but yet produce low returns. On average the
54
production stage annually produces 5 cents per each dollar invested in NOA, the lowest rate in
comparison with the other chain members. However, not all the companies in this stage are
underperforming in the value creation process. Successful firms are characterized by key
features. Analysis of the data shows that large companies have positive and persistent value
creation rates. Clearly, size plays a key role for production companies to create value. In other
words, companies that take advantage of the economies of scale in this stage perform better
than those that do not take advantage of size features. Furthermore, one of the main
characteristics of big firms is that they generate greater revenue per dollar invested in NOA (12
cents per dollar invested in NOA). In addition, these companies are more likely to invest in
intangible and goodwill assets. Small companies face more difficulties creating value,
especially when measuring the persistence of value creation outcomes. The small firms that
perform better are involved in value creation activities. For example, China Green Ltd, is a
vertically integrated, relatively small company (size: 82% less than the average size of the
stage) engaged in the cultivation, production and logistical activities of food products. The
firm uses its capital efficiently and produces 19 cents per each dollar invested in NOA (280%
higher than the average operating revenue of the stage). The company has an average MEVA
of 1.24% and an average EVA of 33 million dollars per years over the ten years under analysis.
Its average COGS is 49%, which is 36% lower than the average COGS for the stage, suggesting
that the company is adding more value than the average company in the sector. The company
As this example clearly shows, there are opportunities in the production sector to obtain
higher returns and create more value. There are companies in this stage that are efficient users
of capital. However, most of the companies are unsustainable value creators. Furthermore, the
regression results show that the probability of creating persistent value for companies within
this stage is negative. Managers should be aware of that and need to focus on managing firms
55
assets more efficiently. The main weakness of this stage could be the product firms are offering.
Commodity production, which dominates Stage 2, is a low margin business, where price setting
products may allow companies some pricing power and the ability to obtain higher margins
that lead to higher operating profits and value creation outcomes. Overall, the efficient use of
capital is being poorly achieved within this sector, a fact related to the commoditization of
products offered. Thus, the companies in this stage can only compete in price reduction with
As this study has already noted, up-chain nodes are the least contributor in the value
adding process along the agri-food value chain. To improve performance, a low value creator
might change the focus of its business strategies and aim to imitate the practices of down-chain,
high value-creating members. The implementation of new business strategies may be needed
to capture part of the value that is being produced down-chain. Undoubtedly, the products being
offered play a significant role. Although there may be other possible drivers of value creation,
results suggest that companies in the production sector need to move from the production of
undifferentiated products to differentiated ones in order to change their price orientation to one
more focused on value orientation. According to the results of the present study, investment in
innovation could dramatically help to improve firm performance and the creation of value.
Importantly, our findings also demonstrate that capturing some of the benefits related to size
could allow firms to create higher value outcomes. This finding may guide managers to
This study finds that down-chain is where the most value is created. Food
manufacturing and delivery-to consumer-nodes use operating capital efficiently and make a
strong contribution to the value adding process of the entire value chain. Both stages have
56
positive and high value outcomes in the four measures of value creation used in this research.
Furthermore, Stage 3 and Stage 4 are associated with a strong focus on innovation and product
implications about the relationship between innovation and value creation. Supporting previous
studies, this research shows that investment in innovation positively affects value creation. For
example, processors that excel in value creation outcomes invest on average 66% of the
Managers need to first understand the meaning of value creation in business. In this
sense, the present study contributes by providing a clear definition of value creation.
Additionally, this paper uses the well-known EVA metric but also introduces new financial
tools such as MEVA, CEVA and PEVA metrics to measure and analyze value creation.
Although these metrics are used at the stage level from a value chain perspective, they can also
be used to measure value creation at the business unit level. These metrics successfully measure
the value generated by a business unit after accounting for the cost of opportunity. Furthermore,
PEVA is a metric that allows measurement of value creation across time and gives an insight
Our findings may also help managers to understand how each stage excels or
underperforms in the value creation process along the agri-food value chain. This information
may be useful for managers and practitioners, since knowing about the performance of the
stage to which a particular firm belongs and how other nodes succeed or fail in the value
creation process could help managers to design more productive business strategies.
57
CONCLUSION
This study evaluated the value creation process among the key stages of the agri-food
value chain. The main purpose of this manuscript was to analyze the differences in stages
within the agri-food value chain by identifying which nodes excel or underperform in the value
creation process. Furthermore, this research measured the effect of the drivers of value creation
in the contexts of value chain and agribusiness. An estimation of four value creation metrics
was conducted for each firm and each stage: the Economic Value Added (EVA) metric, the
Modified Economic Value Added (MEVA), the create value variable (CEVA) and the
persistent value creation (PEVA) variable. These four metrics were employed to improve the
The analysis of value creation among the stages provides evidence that capital is not
being used equally efficiently across the four nodes. As hypothesized, each stage contributes
differently to the value creation process, according to the statistically significant regression
The findings provide evidence that the production stage—the most commoditized
node— contributes the least amount of value to the chain, while additional processing and
retailing contribute significantly greater levels of value. Measuring value creation as MEVA
or CEVA, Stage 4 is the chain node that most efficiently uses its capital, being the greater
contributor to the value creation process. However, when value creation is measured using the
EVA metric, and accounting for the working capital invested, processors excel in creating
value. In all cases, down-chain is where most of the value is being created. The evidence shows
that the down-chain nodes create value more persistently than that found in the up-chain nodes.
regression results provide evidence of a positive relationship between innovation and value
58
creation. Analysis of the data also reveals significantly greater levels of innovation down-chain,
where capital is being used more efficiently, implying that innovative firms have higher levels
of value added. Two types of innovation were measured in this study: intangible capital and
R&D spending. The source of innovation was found to vary across stages. The main source of
innovation for all the stages is intangible capital, but the levels of investment in intangible
capital varies across nodes. However, agricultural input companies are more focused on R&D
This analysis also provides evidence that size is a significant determinant of value
creation, showing that firm size has a positive effect on the four value creation variables. In all
the regression models, firm size was found to be positive and significant, thereby affecting the
three value creation metrics as expected. Product differentiation was also found to positively
products provide a lesser level of value creation. A firm’s degree of product differentiation also
One of the objectives of this paper was to clarify the term “value creation.” The present
study of value creation in agri-business, using the EVA concept as the base measure of firm
value added, allowed the researcher to conclude that to create value, firms must perform a
value-added activity that could consist of an innovation (which refers to the introduction of a
new method or the modification of an existing one), or they must perform an activity that was
previously performed by another member of the chain. Furthermore, business units could focus
on coordination as a method for creating value. In this case, investing in horizontal or vertical
coordination, as well as seeking collaboration among other firms, might be another effective
way to increase company value. But in either of these cases, to qualify as a value-added activity,
such an action must be capable of providing the company with a positive net benefit after
59
The regression results show that there are still differences in the value creation levels among
the stages, even when controlling for widely considered drivers of value creation. This provides
the insight that there may be other critical factors at play, or, it may be the nature of the business
that explains differences in value creation levels among the four nodes. This study is restricted
insofar as it only uses financial data. Among the drivers of value creation enumerated in
previous sections, financial data only permit a measurement of innovation as driver of value
source of innovation, can account for the different outcomes obtained for each stage. So, an
area for further research would be an analysis of the impact of coordination (horizontal and
vertical) on value creation. Coordination among value chain actors implies complementarities
among the activities of different chain members. According to Hendrikse et al. (2001), vertical
coordination of production, distribution, and marketing among firms in a value chain may have
an impact on the investment decisions of each firm individually. Investments by a firm of the
chain must be coordinated with investments by other firms to obtain optimal chain
with “ higher inventory costs, longer delivery times, higher transportation costs, higher levels
of loss and damage, and lowered customer service” (Lee et al., 1997; Simatupang et al., 2002).
Lee (2004) explains that a value chain to attain a competitive advantage not only need to be
cost effective and high speed but also need to develop three specific talents which are to be
adaptable, aligned and agile. Among the literature, it is widely agree that activities and
decisions making in one stage of the agri-food value chain impacts and benefits other stages,
implying that there exist intra-stages linkages and business relationships that make the agri-
food value chain a value creation system. Additional information would be needed to measure
coordination and the degree of collaboration among agri-food members and how interlink ages
60
among firms are contributing to the value creation process. To quantify this effect, a survey
61
REFERENCES
Aiken, M., & Hage, J. (1971). The organic organization and innovation. Sociology, 5(1), 63-
82.
Alexander, C., & Goodhue, R. E. (1999). Production system competition and the pricing of
innovations: An application to biotechnology and seed corn. American Agricultural
Economics Association.
Amanor-Boadu, V. (2003). A conversation about value-added agriculture. Value-Added
Business Development Program. Department of Agricultural Economics. Kansas State
University.
Ambrosini, V., & Bowman, C. (2009). What are dynamic capabilities and are they a useful
construct in strategic management? International Journal of Management
Reviews, 11(1), 29-49.
Anderson, A. M., Bey, R. P., & Weaver, S. C. (2005). Economic value added adjustments:
much to do about nothing. WP-Lehigh University.
Anderson, D. P., & Hanselka, D. (2009). Adding Value to Agricultural Products. Retrieved
from from http://hdl. handle. net/1969, 1, 86940.
Anderson, J. C. (1995). Relationships in business markets: exchange episodes, value creation,
and their empirical assessment. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 23(4), 346-
350.
Anderson, J. C., & Narus, J. A. (1998). Business marketing: understand what customers
value. Harvard business review, 76, 53-67.
Anderson, J. C., Narus, J. A., & Van Rossum, W. (2006). Customer value propositions in
business markets. Harvard business review, 84(3), 90.
Arundel, A., & Kabla, I. (1998). What percentage of innovations are patented? Empirical
estimates for European firms. Research policy, 27(2), 127-141.
Balsam, S., Fernando, G. D., & Tripathy, A. (2011). The impact of firm strategy on
performance measures used in executive compensation. Journal of Business
Research, 64(2), 187-193.
Barkema, A., & Drabenstott, M. (1996). Consolidation and change in heartland
agriculture. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Economic Forces Shaping the Rural
Heartland.
Berman, S. L., Wicks, A. C., Kotha, S., & Jones, T. M. (1999). Does stakeholder orientation
matter? The relationship between stakeholder management models and firm financial
performance. Academy of Management journal, 42(5), 488-506.
Bigliardi, B., & Bottani, E. (2010). Performance measurement in the food supply chain: a
balanced scorecard approach. Facilities, 28(5/6), 249-260.
Born, H., & Bachmann, J. (2006). Adding value to farm products: an overview. National
Center For Appropriate Technology.
62
Bourlakis, M., Maglaras, G., & Fotopoulos, C. (2012). Creating a “best value supply chain”?
Empirical evidence from the Greek food chain. International Journal of Logistics
Management, The, 23(3), 360-382. 3.
Bowman, C., & Ambrosini, V. (2000). Value creation versus value capture: towards a coherent
definition of value in strategy. British Journal of Management, 11(1), 1-15.
Bruner, R. F., Eades, K. M., Harris, R. S., & Higgins, R. C. (1998). Best practices in estimating
the cost of capital: survey and synthesis. Financial Practice and Education, 8, 13-28.
Burch, D., & Lawrence, G. (2005). Supermarket own brands, supply chains and the
transformation of the agri-food system. International Journal of Sociology of Agriculture
and Food, 13(1), 1-18.
Camisón-Zornoza, C., Lapiedra-Alcamí, R., Segarra-Ciprés, M., & Boronat-Navarro, M.
(2004). A meta-analysis of innovation and organizational size. Organization
Studies, 25(3), 331-361.
Canning, P. N. (2011). A revised and expanded food dollar series: a better understanding of
our food costs. US Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service.
Capitanio, F., Coppola, A., & Pascucci, S. (2009). Indications for drivers of innovation in the
food sector. British Food Journal, 111(8), 820-838.
Carlson, W. (2004). Don’t produce a commodity. Greenhouse Grower, 22(12), 20-23.
Chandy, R. K., & Tellis, G. J. (2000). The incumbent's curse? Incumbency, size, and radical
product innovation. The Journal of Marketing, 1-17.
Chikan, A. (1997): Vállalatgazdaságtan, Aula Kiadó Kft
Chmelikova, G. (2008). Economic Value Added versus Traditional Performance Metrics in the
Czech Food-Processing Sector. Editorial Staff, 11(4), 49.
Collins, K. (2001). Statement of Keith Collins, Chief Economist, US Department of
Agriculture before the US Senate Committee on Appropriations, Subcommittee on
Agriculture, Rural Development, and Related Agencies: Economic Issues Related to
Biofuels. Unknown www. usda. gov/documents/Farmbill07energy. doc, 1-8.
Coltrain, D., Barton, D., & Boland, M. (2000). Value Added: Opportunities and Strategies.
Retrieved October 20, 2003.
Congress, U. S. (2002, May). Farm security and rural investment act of 2002. In107th
Congress, 2nd Session. Public Law (No. 107-171).
63
Damanpour, F. (2010). An integration of research findings of effects of firm size and market
competition on product and process innovations. British Journal of Management, 21(4),
996-1010.
Degryse, H., de Goeij, P., & Kappert, P. (2012). The impact of firm and industry characteristics
on small firms’ capital structure. Small Business Economics, 38(4), 431-447.
Demont, M., Dillen, K., Mathijs, E., & Tollens, E. (2007). GM Crops in Europe: How Much
Value and for Whom? Les cultures génétiquement modifiées en Europe: quels avantages
et pour qui? Genetisch veränderte Feldfrüchte in Europa: Welcher Wert und für
wen?. EuroChoices, 6(3), 46-53.
Dewar, R. D., & Dutton, J. E. (1986). The adoption of radical and incremental innovations: an
empirical analysis. Management science, 32(11), 1422-1433.
Doyle, P. (2000). Value-based marketing. Journal of Strategic Marketing, 8(4), 299-311.
Elitzak, H. (1999). Food Cost Review, 1950-97 (No. 34053). United States Department of
Agriculture, Economic Research Service.
Ely, K. M. (1995). Operating lease accounting and the market's assessment of equity
risk. Journal of Accounting Research, 397-415.
Ettlie, J. E., Bridges, W. P., & O'keefe, R. D. (1984). Organization strategy and structural
differences for radical versus incremental innovation. Management science, 30(6), 682-
695.
Evans, E. (2006). Value Added Agriculture: Is It Right for Me? EDIS document FE638, Florida
Cooperative Extension Service, Institute of Food and Agricultural Sciences, University
of Florida, Gainesville, FL. Published.
Farfan, O. (2005). Understanding and escaping commodity-dependency: a global value chain
perspective. documento preparado para la Corporación Financiera Internacional,
Washington, DC, Banco Mundial.
Fulton, M., & Giannakas, K. (2002). Agricultural biotechnology and industry structure.
Geyser, M., & Liebenberg, I. E. (2003). Creating a new valuation tool for South African
agricultural co-operatives. Agrekon, 42(2), 106-115.
Goldsmith, P. D. (2001). Innovation, Supply Chain Control, and the Welfare of Farmers: The
Economics of Genetically Modified Seeds. American Behavioral Scientist, 44(8), 1302-
1326.
Goldsmith, P. D., & Silva, C. (2006). Specialty Soybean and Corn Survey. National Soybean
Reseach Laboratory.
Goldsmith, P. D., & Sporleder, T. L. (1998). Analyzing Foreign Direct Investment Decisions
by Food and beverage Firms: An Empirical Model of Transaction Theory. Canadian
Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie, 46(3), 329-346.
Goldsmith, P., & Bender, K. (2004). Ten conversations about identity preservation. Journal on
Chain and Network Science, 4(2), 111-123.
64
Goldsmith, P., Salvador, A., Knipe, D., & Kendall, E. (2002). Structural change or logical
incrementalism? Turbulence in the global meat system. Journal on Chain and Network
Science, 2(2), 101-115.
Gopalakrishnan, S., & Damanpour, F. (2000). The impact of organizational context on
innovation adoption in commercial banks. Engineering Management, IEEE Transactions
on, 47(1), 14-25.
Gopinath, M., Roe, T. L., & Shane, M. D. (1996). Competitiveness of US food processing:
benefits from primary agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 78(4),
1044-1055.
Grunert, K. G., Jeppesen, L. F., Jespersen, K. R., Sonne, A. M., Hansen, K., Trondsen, T., &
Young, J. A. (2005). Market orientation of value chains: A conceptual framework based
on four case studies from the food industry. European Journal of Marketing, 39(5/6),
428-455.
Hahn, W. F. (2004). Beef and pork values and price spreads explained. USDA Economic
Research Service.
Hayenga, M., & Kalaitzandonakes, N. (1999, May). Structure and Coordination System
Changes in the US Biotech Seed and Valueadded Grain Market. In Prepared for
presentation at the 1999 World Food and Agribusiness Congress. Florence, Italy:
International Food and Agribusiness Management Association.
Hecker, A., & Ganter, A. (2013). The Influence of Product Market Competition on
Technological and Management Innovation: Firm‐Level Evidence from a Large‐Scale
Survey. European Management Review, 10(1), 17-33.
Hendrikse, G., & Bijman, J. (2002). Ownership structure in agrifood chains: the marketing
cooperative. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 84(1), 104-119.
Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E., & Ireland, R. D. (1990). Mergers and acquisitions and managerial
commitment to innovation in M-form firms. Strategic Management Journal, 11(4), 29-
48.
Houle, M. D. (2008). Economic Value Added. Senior Honors Papers, 38.
Hua, N., & Templeton, A. (2010). Forces driving the growth of the restaurant industry in the
USA. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 22(1), 56-68
Humphrey, J., & Memedovic, O. (2006). Global value chains in the agrifood sector (Working
paper). Retrieved from United Nations Industrial Development Organization website:
http://www.unido.org/fileadmin/user_media/Publications/Pub_free/Global_value_chain
s_in_the_agrifood_sector.pdf
Ibendahl, G. A., & Fleming, R. A. (2003). Using Economic Value Added (EVA) to Examine
Farm Businesses. In Annual Meeting of the Southern Agricultural Economics
Association. Mobile, Alabama. February.
Kalafut, P. C., & Low, J. (2001). The value creation index: quantifying intangible
value. Strategy & Leadership, 29(5), 9-15.
65
Kale, P., Dyer, J., & Singh, H. (2001). Value creation and success in strategic alliances:
alliancing skills and the role of alliance structure and systems. European Management
Journal, 19(5), 463-471.
Kampen, K. (2011). Financial analysis of three value-added dairy enterprises in Vermont,
Wisconsin, and New York (Doctoral dissertation, California Polytechnic State
University).
Keef, S. P., & Roush, M. L. (2003). The relationship between economic value added and stock
market performance: A theoretical analysis. Agribusiness,19(2), 245-253.
Ketchen Jr, D. J., Rebarick, W., Hult, G. T. M., & Meyer, D. (2008). Best value supply chains:
A key competitive weapon for the 21st century. Business Horizons, 51(3), 235-243.
Kimberly, J. R., & Evanisko, M. J. (1981). Organizational innovation: The influence of
individual, organizational, and contextual factors on hospital adoption of technological
and administrative innovations. Academy of management journal, 24(4), 689-713.
Kotha, S., & Nair, A. (1995). Strategy and environment as determinants of performance:
evidence from the Japanese machine tool industry. Strategic management journal, 16(7),
497-518.
Kramer, J. P., Marinelli, E., Iammarino, S., & Diez, J. R. (2011). Intangible assets as drivers
of innovation: Empirical evidence on multinational enterprises in German and UK
regional systems of innovation. Technovation, 31(9), 447-458.
Lepak, D. P., Smith, K. G., & Taylor, M. S. (2007). Value creation and value capture: a
multilevel perspective. Academy of management review, 32(1), 180-194.
Lindgreen, A., & Wynstra, F. (2005). Value in business markets: what do we know? Where
are we going?. Industrial Marketing Management, 34(7), 732-748.
Lindgreen, A., Hingley, M. K., Grant, D. B., & Morgan, R. E. (2012). Value in business and
industrial marketing: Past, present, and future. Industrial Marketing Management, 41(1),
207-214.
Lobao, L., & Meyer, K. (2001). The great agricultural transition: crisis, change, and social
consequences of twentieth century US farming. Annual review of sociology, 103-124.
Luecke, R., & Katz, R. (2003). Harvard business essentials: managing creativity and
innovation. Harvard Business School Press.
MacDonald, J. M. (2011). Agricultural contracting update: Contracts in 2008. DIANE
Publishing.
Martin, S. K., & Jagadish, A. (2006). Agricultural marketing and agribusiness supply chain
issues in developing economies: the case of fresh produce in Papua New Guinea.
Matopoulos, A., Vlachopoulou, M., Manthou, V., & Manos, B. (2007). A conceptual
framework for supply chain collaboration: empirical evidence from the agri-food
industry. Supply Chain Management: an international journal,12(3), 177-186.
Mittal, B. and J. N. Sheth (2001). Value Space: Winning the Battle for Market Leadership.
New York: McGraw-Hill.
66
Moch, M. K., & Morse, E. V. (1977). Size, centralization and organizational adoption of
innovations. American Sociological Review, 716-725.
Möller, K. (2006). Role of competences in creating customer value: A value-creation logic
approach. Industrial Marketing Management, 35(8), 913-924.
Morningstar (2014). Morningstar Inc. Retrived from http://www.morningstar.com/
Moschini, G., & Lapan, H. (1997). Intellectual property rights and the welfare effects of
agricultural R&D. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 79(4), 1229-1242.
Nair, A., & Filer, L. (2003). Cointegration of firm strategies within groups: a long‐run analysis
of firm behavior in the Japanese steel industry. Strategic Management Journal, 24(2),
145-159.
Niemi, J., & Xing, L. (2011). Market power in the retail food industry: Evidence from Finland.
In The 21st Annual IFAMA World Symposium.
Nord, W. R., & Tucker, S. (1987). Implementing routine and radical innovations. Lexington,
MA: Lexington Books.
O'Cass, A., & Ngo, L. V. (2011). Examining the firm's value creation process: a managerial
perspective of the firm's value offering strategy and performance. British Journal of
Management, 22(4), 646-671.
O'Hanlon, J., & Peasnell, K. (1998). Wall Street's contribution to management accounting: the
Stern Stewart EVA< sup>®</sup> financial management system. Management
Accounting Research, 9(4), 421-444.
Omidvar, V., Brewin, D. G., & Carlberg, J. G. (2006, February). Meat Processing in North
America: Successes, Failures and Opportunities. In Southern Agricultural Economics
Association Annual Meeting. Orlando, Florida.
Opara, L. U. (2003). Traceability in agriculture and food supply chain: a review of basic
concepts, technological implications, and future prospects. Journal of Food Agriculture
and Environment, 1, 101-106.
Oswald, D. J. (2011). Economic analysis of the US Department of Agriculture’s value-added
producer grants program (Doctoral dissertation, Kansas State University).
Oustapassidis, K., & Vlachvei, A. (1999). Profitability and product differentiation in Greek
food industries. Applied economics, 31(10), 1293-1298.
Parasuraman, A. (1997). Reflections on gaining competitive advantage through customer
value. Journal of the Academy of marketing Science, 25(2), 154-161.
Payne, A., & Holt, S. (2001). Diagnosing customer value: integrating the value process and
relationship marketing. British Journal of management, 12(2), 159-182.
Peterson, H. C., & Wysocki, A. F. (1997). The vertical coordination continuum and the
determinants of firm-level coordination strategy (No. 11817). Michigan State University,
Department of Agricultural, Food, and Resource Economics.
67
Phillips, J., Holcomb, E. J., & Kelley, K. (2007). Determining Interest in Value-added Planters:
Consumer Preference and Current Grower and Retailer
Perceptions. HortTechnology, 17(2), 238-246.
Priem, R. L. (2007). A consumer perspective on value creation. Academy of Management
Review, 32(1), 219-235.
Rintamäki, T., Kuusela, H., & Mitronen, L. (2007). Identifying competitive customer value
propositions in retailing. Managing service quality, 17(6), 621-634.
Sáenz, J., & Aramburu, N. (2010). Towards a New Approach for Measuring Innovation: The
Innovation-Value Path. Identifying, Measuring, and Valuing Knowledge-based
Intangible Assets: New Perspectives, 87.
Sawang, S., & Unsworth, K. L. (2011). Why adopt now? Multiple case studies and survey
studies comparing small, medium and large firms. Technovation,31(10), 554-559.
Sharma, A. K., & Kumar, S. (2010). Economic Value Added (EVA)-Literature Review and
Relevant Issues. International Journal of Economics & Finance,2(2).
Sirmon, D. G., Hitt, M. A., & Ireland, R. D. (2007). Managing firm resources in dynamic
environments to create value: Looking inside the black box. Academy of management
review, 32(1), 273-292.
Smith, J. B., & Colgate, M. (2007). Customer value creation: a practical framework. The
journal of marketing theory and practice, 15(1), 7-23.
Sparling, D., & Turvey, C. G. (2003). Further thoughts on the relationship between economic
value added and stock market performance. Agribusiness,19(2), 255-267.
Sporleder, T. (2006). Strategic alliances and networks in supply chains: knowledge
management, learning and performance measurement. Quantifying the Agri-Food Supply
Chain, 161-171.
Srivastava, R. K., Shervani, T. A., & Fahey, L. (1998). Market-based assets and shareholder
value: a framework for analysis. The Journal of Marketing, 2-18.
Stewart, G., 199 1. The Quest for Value, New York, Harper Business.
Streeter, D. H., Sonka, S. T., & Hudson, M. A. (1991). Information technology, coordination,
and competitiveness in the food and agribusiness sector. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics, 73(5), 1465-1471.
Sullivan, P. & Jikyeong K. (1999). Quick response adoption in the apparel manufacturing
industry :Competitive advantage of innovation. Journal of Small Business Management
37: 1–13.
Turvey, C. G., Lake, L., Van Duren, E., & Sparling, D. (2000). The relationship between
economic value added and the stock market performance of agribusiness
firms. Agribusiness, 16(4), 399-416.
U.S Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service. (2013, March).Food Dollar
Series.. Retrieved from http://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/food-dollar-
series/documentation.aspx#.U45uMvldWSo
68
USDA (2013)a. Economic Research Service. [ONLINE] Available
at: http://www.ers.usda.gov/. [Last Accessed 1/11/2014].
USDA (2013)b. Farm Structure and Organization. [ONLINE] Available at:
http://www.ers.usda.gov/topics/farm-economy/farm-structure-and-
organization.aspx#.UtGYrvRDuSo. [Last Accessed 1/11/2014].
Vanyi, N. (2012). Members Of A Supply Chain And Their Relationships. APSTRACT: Applied
Studies in Agribusiness and Commerce, 6(5).
Viaene, J., & Gellynck, X. (1995). Structure, conduct and performance of the European food
sector. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 22(3), 282-295.
Vorley, B. (2001). The chains of agriculture: sustainability and the restructuring of agri-food
markets.
Walbert, L. (1994). The Stern Stewart Performance 1000: Using Eva™ To Build Market
Value. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 6(4), 109-112.
Walter, A., Ritter, T., & Gemünden, H. G. (2001). Value creation in buyer–seller relationships:
Theoretical considerations and empirical results from a supplier's perspective. Industrial
Marketing Management, 30(4), 365-377.
Wilson, D. T., & Jantrania, S. (1994). Understanding the value of a relationship.Asia-Australia
Marketing Journal, 2(1), 55-66.
Zaltman, G., Duncan, R., & Holbek, J. (1973). Innovations and organizations.
Zéghal, D., & Maaloul, A. (2010). Analysing value added as an indicator of intellectual capital
and its consequences on company performance. Journal of Intellectual capital, 11(1), 39-
60.
Zehri, C., AbdelBaki, A., & BouAbdellah, N. (2012). How Intellectual Capital Affects a Firm's
Performance. Australian Journal of Business and Management Research, 2(08), 24-31.
Zeithaml, V. A. (2000). Service quality, profitability, and the economic worth of customers:
what we know and what we need to learn. Journal of the Academy of Marketing
Science, 28(1), 67-85.
Zona, F., Zattoni, A., & Minichilli, A. (2012). A Contingency Model of Boards of Directors
and Firm Innovation: The Moderating Role of Firm Size. British Journal of Management.
69
FIGURES AND TABLES
Value creation firms are those engaged in value -Efficiency: Increase -Optimal capital use
add activities that uses capital efficiently. return with lowest (debt and equity)
In other words, value creation companies are level of capital
Our definition
those that produce goods or services efficiently employed -Maintaining
obtaining a benefit higher than the cost of efficiency
producing them, including the cost of capital -Sustainability over the time
70
Table 2 – Value creation activities
71
Table 3- Agri-food value chain description
Number
Stages Sectors Description of
companies
Chemicals Biotechnology firms
Supplier of fertilizer,
1 Inputs Agricultural Inputs 97
insecticides and farm
Farm- Construction equipment
Soft drinks
Produces, markets, and
Brewers
3 Processing distributes beverages and 156
Wineries food products.
Packaged food
Food Distribution
Delivery to Distribution and sale of food
4 Grocery 136
Consumer products to end consumer
Restaurant
72
Table 4 -Adjustment made to NOPAT
73
Table 5- Adjustment Made to Total Assets to Calculate NOA
74
Table 6a- Summary statistics
Notes: Values are expressed in USD in million dollars. Standard deviation is in parentheses (SE). CV is the coefficient of
variation. % AdjTA is the variable expressed as a percentage of Adjusted Total Assets. % Net income is the variable expressed
as a percentage of Net Income. Inn2/Inn1 is Innovation 2 divided by Innovation 1. Inn3/Inn1 is Innovation 3 divided by
Innovation 1. MEVA is a variable measure in percentage. CEVA is a binary variable that takes value equal to 1 if the MEVA
is greater to one and zero, otherwise. PEVA is a binary variable that takes value equal to 1 if MEVA>0 for at least 5 years and
zero, otherwise. COGS is a percentage variable that measure the cost as a percentage of the revenues.
75
Table 6b- Mean tests
Null Hypothesis
All
S1 = S2 S1 = S3 S1 = S4 S2 = S3 S2 = S4 S3 = S4
Variable equal
NOA 0.00 0.88 0.00 0.00 0.62 0.00 0.00
Notes: The table shows the p-values of the mean tests calculated to determine whether the value
outcomes for each stage are statistically different from each other for each variable of interest.
‘S1’ means Stage 1, ‘S2’ means Stage 2, ‘S3’ means Stage 3 and ‘S4’ means Stage 4. The null
hypothesis is that the mean of particular variable are equal between two stages. Rejecting the
null hypothesis means that there are statistically significant differences between two particular
stages (Rejecting the null are shown in italics)
76
Table 7 – Regression results
77
Figure 1- Marketing bill and farm share of the U.S. real food dollar, 1993 to 2011
Avg. 1993 to 2011
Marketing
83.9
Share
78
Figure 2- Simplified Agribusiness Value Chain Diagram
79
Figure 3- Firm Size per Stage
80,000
Firm Size (USD million dollars)
60,000
40,000
20,000
0
1 2 3 4
Stage
Notes: The graph shows the distribution of firm size per stage. Firm size is measured as
adjusted Total Assets. It is expressed in million dollars.
80
Figure 4-Relationship between Firm EVA and Firm NOA
10,000
6,000
4,000
2,000
0
0 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000
Firm NOA (USD million dollars)
Notes: The graph shows the positive relationship between firm EVA and Net Operating
Assets (NOA). Firm EVA is calculated as the average EVA for each firm across the
years. Firm NOA is calculated as the average NOA for each firm across the years. The
variables are expressed in million dollars.
81
Figure 5- MEVA Distribution by Stages
f f
ccccc f
Notes: The graphs show the distribution estimation of MEVA for each stage. Small Firms are those firms that have
a MEVA value below the mean MEVA of the stage. Large Firms are those firms that have a MEVA value above the
mean MEVA of the Stage.
82
Figure 6- Innovation Level per Stage
80,000
Innovation 1 (USD million dollars)
60,000
40,000
20,000
0
1 2 3 4
Stage
Notes: The graph shows the level of innovation for each observation in each stage.
‘Innovation’ 1 is composed of goodwill, intangible assets and R&D expenditures. It is
measured in million dollars
83
Figure 7- COGS Distribution per Stage
0.04
0.03
Density (%)
0.02
0.01
0
0 50 100 150
COGS (%)
Notes: The graph shows the distribution of Cost of Goods Sold (COGS) for each
stage. COGS is expressed as a percentage of sales.
84
Figure 8- Relationship Between COGS and MEVA
150
100
COGS (%)
50
0
-100 -50 0 50 100
MEVA (%)
Notes: The graph shows the positive relationship between Cost of Goods Sold (COGS)
and MEVA variables. Fitted values show the correlation between the variables. The
variable COGS is expressed as a percentage of revenues. MEVA is expressed in
percentage.
85
Figure 9- Alamo Value Creation levels 2003-2012
86