Real GDP, Technological Progress, and The Price of Computers
Real GDP, Technological Progress, and The Price of Computers
FOCUS
A tough problem in computing real GDP is how to deal with new computers this year have a speed of 3 GHz compared
changes in quality of existing goods. One of the most dif- to a speed of 2 GHz for new computers last year. And sup-
ficult cases is computers. It would clearly be absurd to as- pose the dollar price of new computers this year is the
sume that a personal computer in 2010 is the same good as same as the dollar price of new computers last year. Then
a personal computer produced in 1981 (the year in which economists in charge of computing the adjusted price of
the IBM PC was introduced): The same amount of money computers will conclude that new computers are in fact
can clearly buy much more computing in 2010 than it could 10% cheaper than last year.
in 1981. But how much more? Does a 2010 computer pro- This approach, which treats goods as providing a col-
vide 10 times, 100 times, or 1,000 times the computing serv- lection of characteristics—for computers, speed, mem-
ices of a 1981 computer? How should we take into account ory, and so on—each with an implicit price, is called
the improvements in internal speed, the size of the random hedonic pricing (“hedone” means “pleasure” in Greek).
access memory (RAM) or of the hard disk, the fact that com- It is used by the Department of Commerce—which con-
puters can access the Internet, and so on? structs real GDP—to estimate changes in the price of
The approach used by economists to adjust for these complex and fast changing goods, such as automobiles
improvements is to look at the market for computers and and computers. Using this approach, the Department of
how it values computers with different characteristics in Commerce estimates that, for a given price, the quality of
a given year. Example: Suppose the evidence from prices new computers has increased on average by 18% a year
of different models on the market shows that people are since 1981. Put another way, a typical personal computer
willing to pay 10% more for a computer with a speed of 3 in 2010 delivers 1.1829 ⴝ 121 times the computing serv-
GHz (3,000 megahertz) rather than 2 GHz. (The first edi- ices a typical personal computer delivered in 1981.
tion of this book, published in 1996, compared two com- Not only do computers deliver more services, they have
puters, with speeds of 50 and 16 megaherz, respectively. become cheaper as well: Their dollar price has declined by
This change is a good indication of technological progress. about 10% a year since 1981. Putting this together with the
A further indication of technological progress is that, for information in the previous paragraph, this implies that
the past few years, progress has not been made by increas- their quality–adjusted price has fallen at an average rate
ing the speed of processors, but rather by using multicore of 18% ⴙ 10% ⴝ 28% per year. Put another way, a dol-
processors. We shall leave this aspect aside here, but peo- lar spent on a computer today buys 1.2829 ⴝ 1,285 times
ple in charge of national income accounts cannot; they more computing services than a dollar spent on a computer
have to take this change into account as well.) Suppose in 1981.
reserved.
The unemployment rate is the ratio of the number of people who are unemployed
to the number of people in the labor force:
U
u =
L
unemployment rate = unemployment>labor force
Constructing the unemployment rate is less obvious than you might have thought.
The cartoon above not withstanding, determining whether somebody is employed
is straightforward. Determining whether somebody is unemployed is harder. Recall
from the definition that, to be classified as unemployed, a person must meet two
conditions: that he or she does not have a job, and he or she is looking for one; this
second condition is harder to assess.
Until the 1940s in the United States, and until more recently in most other
countries, the only available source of data on unemployment was the number of
people registered at unemployment offices, and so only those workers who were
registered in unemployment offices were counted as unemployed. This system
led to a poor measure of unemployment. How many of those looking for jobs ac-
tually registered at the unemployment office varied both across countries and
across time. Those who had no incentive to register—for example, those who had
exhausted their unemployment benefits—were unlikely to take the time to come to
the unemployment office, so they were not counted. Countries with less generous
benefit systems were likely to have fewer unemployed registering, and therefore
smaller measured unemployment rates.
Today, most rich countries rely on large surveys of households to compute the
unemployment rate. In the United States, this survey is called the Current Population
Survey (CPS). It relies on interviews of 50,000 households every month. The survey
classifies a person as employed if he or she has a job at the time of the interview; it clas-
sifies a person as unemployed if he or she does not have a job and has been looking for
a job in the last four weeks. Most other countries use a similar definition of unemploy-
ment. In the United States, estimates based on the CPS show that, during 2010, an aver-
age of 139.0 million people were employed, and 14.8 million people were unemployed,
so the unemployment rate was 14.8>1139.0 + 14.8 2 = 9.6%.
Note that only those looking for a job are counted as unemployed; those who do
not have a job and are not looking for one are counted as not in the labor force. When
unemployment is high, some of the unemployed give up looking for a job and therefore
are no longer counted as unemployed. These people are known as discouraged workers.
Take an extreme example: If all workers without a job gave up looking for one, the
3
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
unemployment rate would equal zero. This would make the unemployment rate a very
poor indicator of what is happening in the labor market. This example is too extreme; in At the start of economic re-
practice, when the economy slows down, we typically observe both an increase in un- form in Eastern Europe in the
early 1990s, unemployment
employment and an increase in the number of people who drop out of the labor force. increased dramatically. But
Equivalently, a higher unemployment rate is typically associated with a lower participa- equally dramatic was the fall
tion rate, defined as the ratio of the labor force to the total population of working age. in the participation rate. In
Figure 2-3 shows the evolution of unemployment in the United States since 1970. Poland in 1990, 70% of the
Since 1960, the U.S. unemployment rate has fluctuated between 3 and 10%, going up decrease in employment was
reflected in early retirements—
during recessions and down during expansions. Again, you can see the effect of the by people dropping out of the
crisis, with the unemployment rate reaching a peak at nearly 10% in 2010, the highest labor force rather than becom-
such rate since the 1980s. ing unemployed.
Second, economists also care about the unemployment rate because it provides
a signal that the economy may not be using some of its resources efficiently. Many
workers who want to work do not find jobs; the economy is not utilizing its human
It is probably because of resources efficiently. From this viewpoint, can very low unemployment also be a prob-
statements like this that eco- lem? The answer is yes. Like an engine running at too high a speed, an economy in
nomics is known as the “dis- which unemployment is very low may be overutilizing its resources and run into labor
mal science.”
shortages. How low is “too low”? This is a difficult question, a question we will take up
at more length later in the book. The question came up in 2000 in the United States. At
the end of 2000, some economists worried that the unemployment rate, 4% at the time,
was indeed too low. So, while they did not advocate triggering a recession, they favored
lower (but positive) output growth for some time, so as to allow the unemployment
rate to increase to a somewhat higher level. It turned out that they got more than they
had asked for: a recession rather than a slowdown.
–2
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
represent the consumption basket of a typical urban consumer and is updated roughly
only once every 10 years.
Each month, Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) employees visit stores to find out
what has happened to the price of the goods on the list; prices are collected in 87 cit-
ies, from about 23,000 retail stores, car dealerships, gas stations, hospitals, and so on.
These prices are then used to construct the Consumer Price Index.
Like the GDP deflator (the price level associated with aggregate output, GDP), the CPI
is an index. It is set equal to 100 in the period chosen as the base period and so its level has
no particular significance. The current base period is 1982 to 1984, so the average for the
Do not ask why such a strange
period 1982 to 1984 is equal to 100. In 2010, the CPI was 222.8; thus, it cost more than twice
base period was chosen. as much in dollars to purchase the same consumption basket than in 1982–1984.
Nobody seems to remember. You may wonder how the rate of inflation differs depending on whether the GDP
deflator or the CPI is used to measure it. The answer is given in Figure 2-4, which plots
the two inflation rates since 1960 for the United States. The figure yields two conclusions:
■ The CPI and the GDP deflator move together most of the time. In most years, the
two inflation rates differ by less than 1%.
■ But there are clear exceptions. In 1979 and 1980, the increase in the CPI was signifi-
cantly larger than the increase in the GDP deflator. The reason is not hard to find. Re-
call that the GDP deflator is the price of goods produced in the United States, whereas
the CPI is the price of goods consumed in the United States. That means when the
price of imported goods increases relative to the price of goods produced in the United
You may wonder why the effect
States, the CPI increases faster than the GDP deflator. This is precisely what happened
of the increases in the price of in 1979 and 1980. The price of oil doubled. And although the United States is a pro-
oil since 1999 is much less vis- ducer of oil, it produces much less than it consumes: It was and still is a major oil im-
ible in the figure. The answer: porter. The result was a large increase in the CPI compared to the GDP deflator.
The increases have taken place
more slowly over time, and In what follows, we shall typically assume that the two indexes move together so we
other factors have worked in do not need to distinguish between them. we shall simply talk about the price level and
the opposite direction. denote it by Pt, without indicating whether we have the CPI or the GDP deflator in mind.
If inflation is so bad, does this imply that deflation (negative inflation) is good? Newspapers sometimes con-
The answer is no. First, high deflation (a large negative rate of inflation) would create fuse deflation and recession.
many of the same problems as high inflation, from distortions to increased uncertainty. Sec- They may happen together but
they are not the same. Deflation
ond, as we shall see later in the book, even a low rate of deflation limits the ability of monetary is a decrease in the price level.
policy to affect output. So what is the “best” rate of inflation? Most macroeconomists believe A recession is a decrease in
that the best rate of inflation is a low and stable rate of inflation, somewhere between 1 and real output.
4%. We shall look at the pros and cons of different rates of inflation later in the book.
Okun’s Law
Intuition suggests that if output growth is high, unemployment will decrease, and this is
indeed true. This relation was first examined by American economist Arthur Okun and
for this reason has become known as Okun’s law. Figure 2-5 plots the change in the un- Arthur Okun was an adviser
employment rate on the vertical axis against the rate of growth of output on the horizon- t o P re s i d e n t K e n n e d y i n
tal axis for the United States since 1960. It also draws the line that best fits the cloud of the 1960s. Okun’s law is, of
course, not a law, but an em-
points in the figure. Looking at the figure and the line suggests two conclusions: pirical regularity.
■ The line is downward sloping and fits the cloud of points quite well. Put in eco-
nomic terms: There is a tight relation between the two variables: Higher output
Changes in the
(percentage points)
Output growth that is higher
than usual is associated with 1
a reduction in the unemploy-
ment rate; output growth that 0
is lower than usual is associ-
ated with an increase in the
–1
unemployment rate.
–3
–4 –2 0 2 4 6 8
Output growth (percent)
Such a graph, plotting one growth leads to a decrease in unemployment. The slope of the line is -0.4. This
variable against another, is
implies that, on average, an increase in the growth rate of 1% decreases the unem-
called a scatterplot. The line
is called a regression line. For ployment rate by roughly -0.4%. This is why unemployment goes up in recessions
more on regressions, see Ap- and down in expansions. This relation has a simple but important implication: The
pendix 3. key to decreasing unemployment is a high enough rate of growth.
■ This vertical line crosses the horizontal axis at the point where output growth is
roughly equal to 3%. In economic terms: It takes a growth rate of about 3% to keep
unemployment constant. This is for two reasons. The first is that population, and
thus the labor force, increases over time, so employment must grow over time just to
keep the unemployment rate constant. The second is that output per worker is also
increasing with time, which implies that output growth is higher than employment
growth. Suppose, for example, that the labor force grows at 1% and that output per
worker grows at 2%. Then output growth must be equal to 3% 11% + 2%2 just to
keep the unemployment rate constant.
–6
3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Unemployment (percent)
■ The line crosses the horizontal axis at the point where the unemployment rate is
roughly equal to 6%. In economic terms: When unemployment has been below 6%,
inflation has typically increased, suggesting that the economy was overheating, oper-
ating above its potential. When unemployment has been above 6%, inflation has typi-
cally decreased, suggesting that the economy was operating below potential. But, again
here, the relation is not tight enough that the unemployment rate at which the econ-
omy overheats can be pinned down very precisely. This explains why some economists
believe that we should try to maintain a lower unemployment rate, say 4 or 5%, and oth-
ers believe that it may be dangerous, leading to overheating and increasing inflation.
Clearly, a successful economy is an economy that combines high output growth, low
unemployment, and low inflation. Can all these objectives be achieved simultane-
ously? Is low unemployment compatible with low and stable inflation? Do policy mak-
ers have the tools to sustain growth, to achieve low unemployment while maintaining
low inflation? These are the questions we shall take up as we go through the book. The
next two sections give you the road map.