Production Function: Program Example 1
Production Function: Program Example 1
Production is the transformation of inputs into outputs. Inputs are the factors of
production -- land, labor, and capital -- plus raw materials and business services.
But how do these outputs change when the input quantities vary? Let's take a look
at an example of a production function.
In general, we would allow for varying amounts of land, labor and capital.
However, in this example, labor will be the only input, for the sake of simplicity.
Program Example 1
Click here to see the result:
Labor Output
Marginal Productivity
Productivity, by definition, is a ratio of output to labor input. In most statistical
discussions of productivity, we refer to the average productivity of labor:
Let's have a numerical example to illustrate the application of the theory. Suppose
that:
• When 300 labor-days per week are employed the firm produces 2505
units of output per week.
• When 400 labor-days per week are employed the firm produces 3120 units
of output per week.
• It follows that the change in labor input, ミ Labor, is 100.
• It also follows that the change in output, ミ Output, is 615.
• Applying the formula above, we approximate the marginal productivity of
labor by the quotient 615/100 = 6.15.
• We can interpret this result as follows: over the range of 300 to 400 man-
days of labor per week, each additional worker adds approximately 6.15
units to output.
Now let's think a little further about the Law of Diminishing Returns.
The Law of Diminishing Marginal
Productivity
In his discussions of the Law of Diminishing Returns, Malthus did not distinguish
between average and marginal productivity. However, in modern economics, we
think of diminishing returns primarily in terms of marginal, not average,
productivity. Thus, we would state the law this way:
Law of Diminishing Returns (Modern Statement):
When the technology of production and some of the inputs are held constant
and the quantity of a variable input increases continually, the marginal
productivity of the variable input will eventually decline.
The inputs that are held steady are called the "fixed inputs." In these pages we are
treating land and capital as fixed inputs. The inputs that are allowed to vary are
called the "variable inputs." In these pages we are treating labor as the variable
input.
Another way to express the law of diminishing returns, is that, as the variable input
increases, the output also increases, but at a decreasing rate. The marginal
productivity of labor is the rate of increase in output as the labor input increases.
To say that output increases at a decreasing rate when the variable input increases
is another way to say that the marginal productivity declines
Table 1
Average
Labor Output Marginal
Productivity
Productivity
0 0 0
9.45
100 945 9.45
8.35
200 1780 8.90
7.25
300 2505 8.35
6.15
400 3120 7.80
5.05
500 3625 7.25
3.95
600 4020 6.70
2.85
700 4305 6.15
1.75
800 4480 5.60
0.65
900 4545 5.05
-0.45
1000 4500 4.50
Output Diagram
Here is a picture of the relationship between the variable input
and the output in the numerical example in the previous table.
Notice how the slope gets flatter: as the variable input increases,
output increases at a decreasing rate. This is a visualization
of the Law of Diminishing Marginal Productivity.
Here are the average and marginal productivities for the same numerical example
in the page before last. Notice how both average and marginal productivity
decrease as the labor input increases. But the marginal productivity declines faster
than the average productivity, pulling the average productivity down after it. The
downward slope of the marginal productivity line expresses the Law of
Diminishing Returns, and the downward slope of the average productivity is also a
result of the law.
The diagram does not show any values where average productivity is less, but a
more complicated example might, and then we would see the second part of the
relationship visualized.
To understand the relationship, think of it this way: as we add labor input, one unit
after another, we add a bit more to output at each step. When the addition is greater
than the average, it pulls the average up toward it. When the addition is less than
the average, it pulls the average down toward it.
Table 2
0 0 0 0
100 9500 100 12107
Table 3
Allocation of Labor
and Total Output
on Two Fields
total
Labor
Labor on output
on
South in
North
Field bushels
Field
of corn
0 1000 85000
1000 0 50000
We see that the farmer gets his largest output by allocating most, but not all, of his
labor to the south field. Because of the principle of diminishing returns, however,
he shouldn't put all his resources into the one field, but divide the labor resource
(unevenly!) between the two.
But how much should go to the north plot, and how much to the south plot?
It's pretty easy to see where the maximum is in this simple example. But in a more
realistic example, in which there could be many more than just two dimensions, it's
harder to visualize. We need a rule that we can apply in more complex, realistic
examples, a rule that will tell us if we have or don't have an efficient allocation of
resources.
That's where the economist's "marginal approach" comes in. The objective is to get
to the top of the hill. You could call "the marginal approach" the "bug's-eye view."
Think of yourself as a bug climbing up that production hill in the picture. How will
you know when you are at the top?
If you were a farmer with two fields, it's a little more complicated, but the same
principles apply: take it step by step. However much you may be producing, ask
yourself "What would happen if I were to take one worker away from the North
Field and put her to work on the South Field? How much less will the North Field
produce? The answer to that question is the marginal productivity of labor on the
North Field. How much more will the South Field produce? The answer to that
question is the marginal productivity of labor on the South Field. So the move of
labor from the North Field will increase production if the marginal productivity on
the North Field is less than the marginal productivity on the South Field. Like the
bug, you want to keep moving in that direction as long as production keeps getting
greater, that is, as long as the marginal productivity on the North Field is less than
the marginal productivity on the South Field. And you stop when further
movement won't get you any higher on the hill, that is, when the marginal
productivities are equal on the two fields.
So now, let's visualize the marginal productivities for these two fields. But this
time we will do it a slightly different way. We will measure the labor used on the
infertile north field from left to right on the horizontal axis. Then, what's left is
what's available for the north field, so we will measure the labor used on the south
field from left to right -- from 1000 hours down to zero. The marginal product on
the north field is shown with the green line, and the marginal product on the south
field with the vertical-dashed purple line. (Remember, the marginal productivity on
the south field decreases as the labor input on the south field gets bigger, so the
marginal productivity on that field increases as labor used on the field gets smaller,
as it does here). Here it is:
Figure 5: Marginal Productivity and Efficient Allocation
Marginal Productivity
Figure 6 shows the most efficient allocation of resources in this case. It is to
allocate 300 hours of labor to the north field, and 700 hours to the south field, as
shown by the vertical red-orange line. For maximum output, labor is allocated so
that the marginal productivity of labor on the north field is equal to the marginal
productivity of labor on the south field.
To see why this works, think it through in reverse: what happens if the allocation
of labor is not 300 to the north field and 700 to the south field? For example,
suppose 200 hours are allocated to the south field and 800 to the north field. This
puts us to the left of the orange line -- and we read off the diagram that the
marginal productivity of labor on the north field is 80 bushels of corn, while the
marginal productivity on the south field is about 62. Remembering the definition of
marginal productivity, that means: if the farmer spends one additional hour on the
north field, he will gain 80 bushels, while spending one less on the south field will
cost him 62 bushels, leaving a net gain of 18 bushels. What has happened is that
spending 800 hours of labor on the south field has pushed the "diminishing
returns" on that field so far that it is less productive at the margin than the north
field. and that will be true anywhere to the left of the orange line, since, in that
range, the marginal productivity on the north field is always greater than the
marginal productivity on the south field.
Now let's see what happens if the allocation is to the right of the most efficient one
-- for example, suppose the farmer were to allocate 600 hours to the north field and
400 to the south field. Looking at the diagram, we see that the marginal
productivity on the north field is 40 while the marginal productivity on the south
field is 90. Thus, moving an hour of labor from the north field to the south field
will yield a gain of 90-40=fifty bushels of corn. And the farmer will continue to
gain as he moves toward the efficient allocation from the right, because, in that
range, the marginal product on the south field is always bigger than the marginal
product on the north field.
We have seen that the farmer can gain by reallocating his labor from either side
toward the efficient output. Once he has 300 hours of labor on the north field and
700 on the south, the farmer cannot increase his output any further. That is why we
think of it as the "efficient" allocation of resources.