The Keynesian Cross: Planned Expenditure
The Keynesian Cross: Planned Expenditure
The Keynesian Cross: Planned Expenditure
Now consider the determinants of planned expenditure. Assuming that the economy is closed,
so that net exports are zero, we write planned expenditure PE as the sum of consumption C,
planned investment I, and government purchases G:
We assume that fiscal policy—the levels of government purchases and taxes — is fixed:
Planned expenditure is a function of the level of income. This line slopes upward because
higher income leads to higher consumption and thus higher planned expenditure. The slope of
this line is the marginal propensity to consume, MPC: it shows how much planned expenditure
increases when income rises by $1. This planned-expenditure function is the first piece of the
model called the Keynesian cross.
The Economy in Equilibrium: The next piece of the Keynesian cross is the assumption that
the economy is in equilibrium when actual expenditure equals planned expenditure. This
assumption is based on the idea that when people’s plans have been realized, they have no
reason to change what they are doing. Recalling that Y as GDP equals not only total income
but also total actual expenditure on goods and services, we can write this equilibrium
condition as
Actual Expenditure = Planned Expenditure
SUSHMA
The 45-degree line in Figure below plots the points where this condition holds.
With the addition of the planned-expenditure function, this diagram becomes the Keynesian
cross. The equilibrium of this economy is at point A, where the planned-expenditure function
SUSHMA
How does the economy get to equilibrium? In this model, inventories play an important role
in the adjustment process. Whenever an economy is not in equilibrium, firms experience
unplanned changes in inventories, and this induces them to change production levels.
Changes in production in turn influence total income and expenditure, moving the economy
toward equilibrium.
For example, suppose the economy finds itself with GDP at a level greater than the
equilibrium level, such as the level Y1 in Figure 3. In this case, planned expenditure PE1 is
less than production Y1, so firms are selling less than they are producing. Firms add the
unsold goods to their stock of inventories. This unplanned rise in inventories induces firms to
lay off workers and reduce production; these actions in turn reduce GDP. This process of
unintended inventory accumulation and falling income continues until income Y falls to the
equilibrium level.
Similarly, suppose GDP is at a level lower than the equilibrium level, such as the level Y2 in
Figure 3. In this case, planned expenditure PE2 is greater than production Y2. Firms meet the
high level of sales by drawing down their inventories. But when firms see their stock of
inventories dwindle, they hire more workers and increase production. GDP rises and the
economy approaches the equilibrium.
In summary, the Keynesian cross shows how income Y is determined for given levels of
planned investment I and fiscal policy G and T.
We can use this model to show how income changes when one of these exogenous variables
changes.