Patinkins Real Balance Effect
Patinkins Real Balance Effect
Keywords
Inflation, Interest Rate, Quantity Equation, Phase Diagram
1. Introduction
Generally, problems of inflation are regarded as the relation between price and
currency, and the price and real output. We need to ask the question that
whether currency only has impacts on price or on both price and real output?
Friedman concluded that: “Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phe-
nomenon” [1]. However, since the quantity theory of money cannot explain the
change pattern of price in short-term, people are willing to believe that there is a
certain relation between currency and real output based on Phillips curve [2].
Categorized by the transaction motive, speculative motive and precautionary
motive in Keynesian theory, the demand for money has different models: Di-
amond built up the iterative model based on the storage functionality of money
[3]; Baumol-Tobin model provided the analysis of speculation demand for
money to bonds [4] [5]; McCallum model analyzed how the demand for money
restrained by the transaction cost [6]; models of Patinkin, Whalen, Weinrobe,
Frenkel and Jovanobic, Blanchard and Fischer analyzed the precautionary or
uncertain demand for money from different aspects [7] [8] [9] [10] [11]. Al-
though different models of demand for money have different preconditions, they
all lead to the same conclusion: the demand for money is positively related to the
real income and negatively related to the interest rate.
However, statistical data since 1970s have shown that there is no stable func-
tional relation between currency and output as well as currency and interest rate
[12]. The concept of “demand for money” may be abandoned in the inflation
theory, and it will be easier to find the essence of price changes by analyzing the
relationship between any amount of money and real output.
dM dYr dP
= + , namely M =
Yr + P (3)
M Yr P
In the Equation (3), M can be observed directly from the statistical data, but
only one of Yr and P is from the statistical data, and the other can be calcu-
lated indirectly by the definition Y = PYr . Friedman and Schwartz states in “A
Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960” that there is a fact but not
strict relation between the growth rate of currency and price [13]. As shown in
Figure 2, there are relations between P and M in long-term trend, but fluc-
tuation directions are very different in the short-term.
In order to explain the difference of P and M in the fluctuation, we define
the residual of M and P as V , namely V= Y − M , and observe the direc-
tion of fluctuation of V and M . As Figure 3 shows, V and M change re-
versely in short-term. Since Y includes the change of price index P and that of
real output Yr , unless we have already known the relation between P and V, or
Yr and V, otherwise it is impossible to explain the reverse changing trend of V
and M in short-term.
In fact, V= Y − M equals to d ( ln V ) =d ( ln Y ) − d ( ln M ) =d ln (Y M ) . By
neglecting initial conditions, we can rewrite it as V = Y M . Since Y = PYr ,
then:
MV = PYr , or M + V = P + Yr (4)
The above equation is the famous Fisher equation with different symbols from
the original equation [14], in which V is called the velocity of currency flow. Al-
though there are more variables in Equation (4) compares to that in Equation
(3), it still does not provide more information to analyze the short-term change
of P, unless we clarify the relation between V and other variables. If we assume V
as a constant as Keynes and Friedman did [15] [16], then Equation (4) became
Equation (3), so it is unhelpful for us to explain the change of P in short-term.
From the above derivation process, we can see that Equation (4) is not sacred
by people’s imagination, but is an identity defined by the hypothesis V= Y − M .
( )
Figure 2. Relations between statistical data of P and M M 2 . Calculation and resources:
1) M = M 2 , data of M 2 see Figure 1. 2) The inflation rate=P dP P ≈ ∆P P . The price
index P is calculated by nominal GDP and real GDP, data of nominal and real GDP are
from http://www.bea.gov.
vestment objects on those object whose nominal revenue could reflects the latest
inflation rate. The assumption above indicates that the change of price would
affect the velocity of currency flow. We assume the velocity of currency flow is
the function of inflation rate, namely V = f ( P ) . Since:
df ( P ) dP
= df ( P=
dV ) ⋅ ⋅ P , simplified as df ( P=
) f ′ ( P ) PP
dP P
then
dV df ( P ) Pf
′ ( P )
V =
= =
⋅P (5)
V f ( P ) f ( P )
therefore
M − Yr
P = (6)
f ′ ( P )
1−
⋅P
f ( P )
Equation (6) indicates that the change of P is not only related to ( M − Yr ) ,
but also to f ( P ) and the growth rate of P in short-term. In long-term, the
average value of f ′ ( P ) and P
are equal to 0, otherwise there is a contradic-
tion between Equation (6) and P = M − Y in Equation (3). In that case, we
r
or f ′ ( P ) is equal to 0.
need to verify if the average value of P
Since we do not know the details of the function V = f ( P ) , it is impossible
to verify the average value of f ′ ( P ) . However, we could estimate the average
value of P by observing statistical data of P . As Figure 4 shows, during
1970-2015, the trend line of P is horizontal and it’s the average value in long-
term is 0.01, which approximately equal to 0.
If the average value of M and Y in long-term are the same, then their re-
sidual V should be equal to 0. In short-term, when the direction of fluctuation
of V and P are the same, then we can assume the changing pattern of V is
determined by P . Make θ = Pf ′ ( P ) f ( P ) , and according to Equation (5),
then V = θ P . In Figure 4, we can see that the long-term trend of V and P
is consistent (their trend lines are parallel), and the short-term fluctuation direc-
tion of P is also related. If the range of fluctuation of θ is significantly nar-
rower than that of P in V = θ P
, then we can take θ as a constant.
In fact, the value of θ is not important in the long-term, because as long as the
long-term average of P is 0, there is P
= M − Y according to Equation (6).
r
This is the reason that money is always neutral in long-term, but is not clear in
the medium and short term.
As Figure 4 shows, based on statistical data during 1970-2015, make θ = 0.1,
equals to 0.0010 and its long-term trend is approx-
then the average of 0.1P
imately horizontal. The average of V equals to −0.0040, therefore the average
Figure 4. Relations between P and V . Calculation and resources: 1)= dP P ≈ ∆P P ,
P
=P dP P ≈ ∆P P . Data of P see Figure 2. 2) Theoretically, trend of θ P and V are
consistent in long-term, and the direction of fluctuation and range of fluctuation should
be the same. The difference showed in Figure 4 indicates: θ is not necessarily a constant.
However, it is often regarded as a constant when P changes in a certain rand and the
change of θ is comparatively small compared to that of P .
Equation (7) indicates that the inflation rate P is not only affected by ex-
ogenous variables M and Yr , but also its own change rate P . More impor-
tantly, the variables in Equation (7) have corresponding statistical data in the
United States, so that we can verify the results of the inference. Since the rela-
tionship between P and P can be drawn as a phase diagram, therefore the
change of difference between M and Y determines the change of phase dia-
r
gram P ~ P
.
Figure 5. Time paths of r , rr and P . Calculation and resources: Data of P see Fig-
ure 2. r = r − P , r is the arithmetic mean of annualized earnings of various US Trea-
r
sury bonds, data are from http://www.federalreserve.gov/. See paper “A Kind of neither
Keynesian nor Neoclassical Model (2): the Business Cycle” [17].
Figure 6. Phase diagram P ~ θ P of statistical data. Calculation and resources: θ = 0.1.
When θ P > 0 , then P moves to the right; and when θ P < 0 , P moves to the left.
Therefore the phase diagram P ~ P rotates clockwise.= P dP P ≈ ∆P P =
, P dP P ≈
∆P P , data of P see Figure 2.
(a) (b)
(
gram P ~ P − θ P )
. Notice: In (a), we firstly draw the auxiliary line
P = θ P
. Point a and c in the phase diagram P ~ θ P
correspond to point a
and c in the phase diagram P ~ P − θ P(
) = 0 . Then we can
since θ P
draw other points on the phase diagram based on the composite variable
( P − θ P) . The phase diagram P ~ ( P − θ P ) rotates counterclockwise be-
.
cause there is a negative sign in front of θ P
dK dY dr d α
= − + ,
K Y r α
According to the fundamental equation ∆Y =rY [18],
dY ∆Y rY
= lim= lim = r,
Y ∆Y →0 Y ∆Y →0 Y
r − dr r + dα α . hypothesis dα α = 0 , then
therefore, dK K =
dK dr
K = =r − =r − r.
K r
Compared with Y= r + r , the front of r is a negative sign in K = r − r , so
the rotation of the phase diagram r ~ K is counterclockwise. This causes the
peak of K to fall behind the peak of r in the time path, as shown in Figure 9. If
fluctuation of M is similar to K in short-term, then the peak of M will be
in the second half of a cycle, since the peak of Y is before the peak of r (the
peak of Y is in the first half of a cycle).
As guess from Figure 9, if the peak of Y is in the first half of a cycle, the
peak of M which is similar to K , will be in the second half of a cycle, in other
words the peak of M will follow the peak of Y . The statistical data of Figure
10 can verify this conjecture.
Because the phase diagram rr ~ M rotates counterclockwise, we can overlap
it on the phase diagram rr ~ ( −Yr ) and then get the phase diagram of the com-
posite variable ( M − Y ) . In this way, the phase diagram P ~ ( P − θ P
r
) and
rr ~ ( M − Yr ) can be related according to Equation (7).
Figure 11(a) shows the process to draw the phase diagram rr ~ ( M − Yr ) .
Firstly we draw the phase diagram rr ~ rr rotates clockwise, and draw the phase
diagram rr ~ Yr rotates clockwise based on equation Yr ≈ rr + rr (The reason
for using the symbol ≈ will be explained later in the analysis of the Phillips
curve). Then we can get the phase diagram rr ~ ( −Yr ) which is the mirror im-
age of rr ~ Yr and rotates counterclockwise.
The phase diagram rr ~ M rotates counterclockwise, and the core variable
M is affected by monetary policies and multiple times of the money supply of
Figure 9. Phase diagram and time path of K and r . Drawing method see paper “A
Kind of neither Keynesian nor Neoclassical Model (2): the Business Cycle” [17].
Figure 10. Time paths of M and Yr . Resources: Yr= Y − P . Data of Y see Figure 1,
data of P and M see Figure 2.
central bank. The central bank supplies basic currency, and M comprises of
basic currency and other derived currency created by business banks and finan-
cial market. The bigger of the monetary multiplier of the basic currency and the
derived currency, the higher place on the vertical axis of M . In order to facili-
tate our narration, we assume M is determined by the supply of basic money
under a constant monetary multiplier even though the multiplier might not be a
constant in reality.
P ~ ( P − θ P
) are the same, and points on r ~ ( M − Y ) (as a, b, c, d) are cor-
r r
(a) (b)
rr ~ ( M − Yr ) by overlapping rr ~ M and rr ~ ( −Yr ) . 2) (b), firstly draw the phase di-
, then the corresponding diagram P ~ P − θ P
agram P ~ θ P ( )
. Then adjust the location
0.036 and 0.041 for the period 1970-2015. There are two reasons why the average
value of ( P − θ P
) is slightly smaller than ( M − Y ) . First, the time of the sta-
r
tistical data is not long enough. The impact of money will lag behind for some
time to be reflected in P , especially in the monetary policy of QE (quantitative
easing) over the years. Second, there are leakages of the money, such as part of
the currency flow to other countries and regions.
Theoretical analysis in Figure 11 show that there are four factors affect the
change of macroeconomic price: firstly, the change of M which is closely re-
lated to base money supply; secondly, the periodic change of variable M ; third-
ly, the change of core variable rr which reflects the operating efficiency of the
system; fourthly, the periodic change of rr .
In order to identify all above factors, we call M , r and P as “core va-
r
In this way, we can more clearly understand the factors that affect price
changes, and get some preliminary inference. For example, with an established
phase diagram rr ~ rr , we can analyze the impact of change of exogenous varia-
ble M on P .
As Figure 13 shows, assume the initial state of M as ( M ) , then we can lo-
0
r r ( )
of Figure 11, there is no phase diagrams r ~ Y and rr ~ −Yr . 2) Assume r stay r
unchanged, then the smaller value of M , the further place of the core variable P to-
wards left.
P1 = 0 .
It not only indicates P and M change to the same direction, but also the
central bank could make the core inflation rate P = 0 by controlling M (no-
tice: P = 0 is different from P = 0 ). Since P= P + P , and P fluctuates
around P , the value of P might be less or more than 0.
Even though we know that there is relation between the phase diagram
rr ~ rr and P ~ θ P
in Figure 11, we do not know whether the periodic change
of P is determined by that of r or the periodic change of r is determined
r r
therefore cause the change of P to offset the change of P . The first measure
is usually applied by planned economy, and the second one need to make sure
the change of M would not cause the change of r , otherwise there would be
r
unexpected consequences.
As shown in Figure 14, assume M keep unchanged, we can discuss the im-
pacts of r on P . When r drops from ( r ) to ( r ) , the phase diagram
r r r 0 r 1
rr ~ Yr moves downward along the slash line, and the phase diagram
r ( r )
r ~ M − Y moves from r ~ M − Y
r ( ) ( )
to r ~ M − Y . Correspondingly,
r 0 r r 1
5. Conclusion
5.1. Hypothesis
• The production function: Y = AK α Lβ . A marginal condition:
r= ∂Y ∂K = αY K .
• The quantity equation: M = aY . Identity: Y = PYr .
among them, V =
• Residual: V= Y − M ,= ′ ( P ) f ( P ) P
Pf θ P
, θ = 0.1 .
5.2. Results
• The Inflation equation: P − θ P
= M − Y .
r
5.3. Discussion
• By transforming of the residual V , we use the analysis method of phase di-
agram to explain the short-term and long-term changes of the price in one
equation: in the long-term, the average of P is 0, so P is determined by
M and Yr ; in the short-term, since P
is not 0, P is determined by the
( )
phase diagram of the complex variable M − Yr . Since these conclusions
can be verified by statistical data, so they challenge the traditional theory of
“demand for money”. From the perspective that money is wealth, everyone
wants more money than existing ones. From the perspective that money is
the medium of exchange, with the popularity of non-currency payment,
people realize that their demand for transactions is not a demand for trading
medium (such as currency), but to transfer the real wealth of others into their
own accounts through monetary policy, or to pass on financial crisis to oth-
ers. Therefore, the “demand for money” analysis is difficult to explain the
changes in inflation.
• Although this paper explains the factors that affect inflation, it is not able to
answer whether money will affect real output at the same time as it affects
prices. Omitting the fluctuation factor, if P increases with M increases,
will r also increase. Because the change of P is the result of the change of
r
References
[1] Friedman, M. (1968) Dollars and Deficits: Living with America’s Economic Prob-
lems. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs.
[2] Phillips, A.W. (1958) The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change
of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957. Economica, 25, 283-299.
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.1958.tb00003.x
[3] Diamond, P.A. (1965) National Debt in a Neoclassical Growth Model. American
Economic Review, 55, 1126-1150.
[4] Baumol, W.J. (1952) The Transactions Demand for Cash: An Inventory Theoretic
Approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 66, 545-556.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1882104
[5] Tobin, J. (1965) Money and Economic Growth. Econometrica, 33, 671-684.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1910352
[6] McCallum, B.T. (1983) On Non-Uniqueness in Rational Expectations Models: An
Attempt at Perspective. Journal of Monetary Economics, 11, 139-168.
https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(83)90028-4
[7] Patinkin, D. (1965) Money, Interest and Prices: An Integration of Monetary and
Value Theory. 2nd Edition, Row, Peterson and Co., Evanston, Harper and Row,
New York.
[8] Whalen, E.L. (1966) A Reconsideration of the Precautionary Demand for Cash.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80, 314-324. https://doi.org/10.2307/1880695
[9] Weinrobe, M.D. (1972) A Simple Model of the Precautionary Demand for Money.
Southern Economic Journal, 39, 11-18. https://doi.org/10.2307/1056221
[10] Frenkel, J. and Jovanobic, B. (1980) On Transactions and Precautionary Demand
for Money. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 95, 25-44.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1885347
[11] Blanchard, O.J. and Fischer, S. (1989) Lectures on Macroeconomics. MIT Press,
Cambridge.
[12] Buscher, H. and Frowen, S.F. (1993) The Demand for Money in Japan, the United
Kingdom, West Germany and the USA: An Enpirical Study of the Evidence Since
1973. In: Frowen, S.F., Ed., Monetary Theory and Monetary Policy: New Tracks for
the 1990s, Palgrave Macmillan, New York, 123-164.
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-23096-9_10
[13] Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A.J. (1956) A Monetary History of the United States,
1867-1960. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
[14] Fisher, I. (1911) The Purchasing Power of Money. 2nd Edition, Macmillan Co., New
York.
[15] Keynes, J.M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money.
Macmillan Co., Ltd., London.
[16] Friedman, M. (1956) The Quantity Theory of Money: A Restatement. In: Friedman,
M., Ed., The Optimum Quantity of Money, Aldine Publishing Company, Chicago,
3-41.
[17] Zhan, M.A. and Zhan, Z. (2016) A Kind of Neither Keynesian Nor Neoclassical
Model (2): The Business Cycle. Open Access Library Journal, 3, e3215.
https://doi.org/10.4236/oalib.1103215
[18] Zhan, M.A. and Zhan, Z. (2016) A Kind of Neither Keynesian Nor Neoclassical
Model (1): The Fundamental Equation. Open Access Library Journal, 3, e3207.
https://doi.org/10.4236/oalib.1103207