Anteneh Temesgen Agri. Economics. - 2000
Anteneh Temesgen Agri. Economics. - 2000
Anteneh Temesgen Agri. Economics. - 2000
BY
ANTENEH TEMESGEN.
DECEMBER, 2000
ALEMAYA
i
SMALLHOLDER FARMING SYSTEM AND THEIR POTENTIAL FOR OPTIMUM
UTILIZATION OF RESOURCES IN NORTH WOLLO,
ETHIOPIA: A CASE OF MEKET DISTRICT
By
Anteneh Temesgen
December, 2000
Alemaya University
School of Graduate Studies
ii
SMALLHOLDER FARMING SYSTEM AND THEIR POTENTIAL FOR OPTIMUM
UTILIZATION OF RESOURCES IN NORTH WOLLO, ETHIOPIA:
A CASE OF MEKET DISTRICT
By
Anteneh Temesgen
Faculty of Agriculture
Department of Agricultural Economics
______________________________________ _____________
Advisor Signature
______________________________________ ___________
External Examiner Signature
______________________________________ ___________
Internal Examiner Signature
iii
BIOGRAPHY
The researcher Anteneh Temesgen, was born in East Gojjam zone, near Debremarkos town. He attended an
elementary and junior secondary school in Sidamo, Hagereselam town and completed his secondary school
in Deberemarkos comprehensive high school in 1982. Then he joined the Alemaya university of Agriculture
After graduation he was employed by MOA and worked in Amhara regional state of South and North Wollo
administrative zones. Then he Joined the school of graduate studies at Alemaya university in September
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
First and foremost my great appreciation goes to my major advisor Dr. D. K. Grover for his advise and
i
constructive comments in the thesis writing work. I also thank him for facilitating my work by returning the
comments of thesis in time. I greatly appreciate Dr. Wolday Amha for his constructive comments by
sacrificing his valuable short period of time. His contribution is a lot for the improvement of this work. I
thank my former major advisor Dr. Belay Kassa, for his comments and guidance in developing the research
proposal. I want to express my gratitude to Hassen Beshir for his support during data analysis.
My thanks goes to SOS Sahel and SCF (UK) for their financial support in the process of research project. It
is great pleasure to extend my appreciation to Mr. Justin of SOS Sahel and Mr. Ben Foot and Wonduwessen
Bekele of SCF (UK) for their understanding of my problem and their effort to support my research work;
without their kind cooperation my thesis work would have not been so successful. I would also to thank
other staff members of SOS Sahel and SCF (UK) for their valuable support during my work.
It is great pleasure to extend my appreciation to North Wollo Administrative Zone Executive Committee,
Department of Agriculture, as well as Amhara Regional State Executive Committee and Regional Bureau
of Agriculture for their permission to join the M.Sc program. My gratefulness is due to the kind,
commendable and humorous staff members of North Wollo Zone Department of Agriculture. I do not fail
to register the support and respect given by Meket wereda office of agriculture staff members during the
selection of appropriate research study sites and recruiting enumerators among the appropriate staff
members on data collection. I want to tank the enumerators for finishing the tedious data collection work in
time. I am deeply grateful to all people who have assisted me through all stages of the study.
I also want to express my gratitude to my relatives and families: Baye Motebayhon, Moges Shibesh, Solome
Motbaihon, Astede W/kidan, Yeshita Anteneh, Melaku Anteneh and Getachew Anteneh for their
encouragement in successful completion of my graduate study.
TABLE OF CONTENT
BIOGRAPHY .............................................................................................................................................................................................i
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT........................................................................................................................................................................i
ii
TABLE OF CONTENT............................................................................................................................................................................ii
LIST OF TABLES....................................................................................................................................................................................iv
ABSTRACT...............................................................................................................................................................................................ix
1. INTRODUCTION.................................................................................................................................................................................1
1.1. BACKGROUND OF THE STUDY ...............................................................................................................................................................1
1.2. STATEMENT OF THE PROBLEM ..............................................................................................................................................................6
1.3. OBJECTIVES OF THE STUDY ...................................................................................................................................................................9
1.4. SIGNIFICANCE OF THE STUDY ................................................................................................................................................................9
1.5. SCOPE AND LIMITATION OF THE STUDY..............................................................................................................................................10
1.6. HYPOTHESES........................................................................................................................................................................................11
1.7. ORGANIZATION OF THE THESIS ............................................................................................................................................................11
2. REVIEW OF LITERATURE ...........................................................................................................................................................13
2.1. GENERAL .............................................................................................................................................................................................13
2.2. REVIEW OF APPLICATION OF LINEAR PROGRAMMING (LP) MODEL IN AGRICULTURE.....................................................................16
2.3. ADVANTAGES OF LINEAR PROGRAMMING .........................................................................................................................................19
2.4. LIMITATIONS OF LINEAR PROGRAMMING ...........................................................................................................................................20
3. OVERVIEW OF THE STUDY AREA............................................................................................................................................23
3.1. GEOGRAPHICAL SETTING ....................................................................................................................................................................23
3.2. AGROECOLOGY AND CLIMATE............................................................................................................................................................26
3.3. LAND USE............................................................................................................................................................................................26
3.4. LAND TENURE SYSTEM.......................................................................................................................................................................27
3.5. POPULATION AND DEMAND FOR FOOD...............................................................................................................................................28
3.6. ANIMAL HUSBANDRY..........................................................................................................................................................................29
3.7. SOCIO-ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND INFRA STRUCTURAL FACILITIES .........................................................................................30
3.8. THE AGRICULTURAL EXTENSION SYSTEM .........................................................................................................................................31
3.9. SOIL AND WATER CONSERVATION PRACTICE ....................................................................................................................................32
3.10. OFF-FARM ECONOMIC ACTIVITY......................................................................................................................................................33
3.11. INSTITUTIONS OF FARMING COMMUNITY:........................................................................................................................................34
3.11.1. Zone and Wereda Administration:..........................................................................................................................................34
3. 11.2. Agricultural Offices.................................................................................................................................................................35
3. 11.3. Co-operative Offices ...............................................................................................................................................................35
3.11.4. Non-Governmental Institutions:..............................................................................................................................................36
3.11.5. Agricultural Finance................................................................................................................................................................36
4. METHODOLOGY .............................................................................................................................................................................38
4.1. SELECTION OF THE STUDY AREA ........................................................................................................................................................38
4.2. THE SAMPLING METHOD ....................................................................................................................................................................38
4.3. SOURCES AND METHOD OF DATA COLLECTION ................................................................................................................................39
4.4. DATA ANALYSIS AND ANALYTICAL TOOLS........................................................................................................................................40
4.5. STRATIFICATION OF FARM HOUSEHOLDS ...........................................................................................................................................41
4. 6. SPECIFICATION OF THE LP MODEL.....................................................................................................................................................46
4.6.1. The Objective Function..............................................................................................................................................................47
4.6.2. The Activities ..............................................................................................................................................................................48
4.6.3. The Constraints ..........................................................................................................................................................................52
4.6.4. Other Restrictions.......................................................................................................................................................................56
4.6.5. Estimation of Technical Coefficients.........................................................................................................................................59
iii
5. DESCRIPTION OF THE FARMING SYSTEMS IN THE STUDY AREA ............................................................................62
5.1. FAMILY STRUCTURE AND EDUCATIONAL STATUS .............................................................................................................................62
5.1.1. Labor usage................................................................................................................................................................................63
5.1.2. Educational status......................................................................................................................................................................66
5.2. LAND RESOURCE AND USE .................................................................................................................................................................68
5.2.1. Average land size........................................................................................................................................................................68
5.3. THE CROP PRODUCTION......................................................................................................................................................................69
5.3.1. Production pattern .....................................................................................................................................................................70
5.3.2. Land fragmentation....................................................................................................................................................................72
5.3.3. Crop calendar and method of operation...................................................................................................................................73
5.3.4. Seed and fertilizer rate ...............................................................................................................................................................74
5.3.5. Crop and straw productivity......................................................................................................................................................75
5.3.6. Soil management practices........................................................................................................................................................76
5.3.7. Soil conservation practices........................................................................................................................................................78
5.3.8. Crop production problems.........................................................................................................................................................78
5.4. ANIMAL PRODUCTION .........................................................................................................................................................................79
5.4.1. Contribution of livestock to the farming system........................................................................................................................79
5 4.2. Livestock feed. ............................................................................................................................................................................82
5.4.3. Livestock production problem.s.................................................................................................................................................82
5.5. EUCALYPTUS TREE PRODUCTION .......................................................................................................................................................84
5.6. FARM INCOME AND RESOURCE PRODUCTIVITY.................................................................................................................................85
6. LINEAR PROGRAMMING OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS.............................................................................................................90
6.1. BASE MODEL RESULTS .......................................................................................................................................................................90
6.1.1. Production Pattern.....................................................................................................................................................................90
6.1.2. Resource Use under the Base Model ........................................................................................................................................94
6.1. 3. Farm Income and Resource Productivity ................................................................................................................................95
6.1.4. Marginal Value Product of Major Resources ..........................................................................................................................96
6.2. ALTERNATIVE MODEL PLAN RESULTS ...............................................................................................................................................97
6.2.1. Land Use and Cropping Pattern (Alternative Optimum Plan)................................................................................................97
6.2.2. Resource Use under the Alternative Plan.................................................................................................................................99
6.2.3. Farm Income and Resource Productivity (Alternative Plan) ...............................................................................................100
6.2.4. Marginal Value Productivity of Resources (Alternative Plan)..............................................................................................101
6.3. SENSITIVITY TEST ..............................................................................................................................................................................102
6.3.1. Impact of Output Price Reduction...........................................................................................................................................103
6.3.2 Impact of Input Price Variation................................................................................................................................................110
6.3.3 Impact of Output Reduction.....................................................................................................................................................117
7. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION...............................................................................................................................................123
8. REFERENCES ..................................................................................................................................................................................129
9. APPENDICES....................................................................................................................................................................................134
LIST OF TABLES
TABLE 3.1 DISTRIBUTION OF AREAS AND POPULATION OF NORTH WOLLO IN DIFFERENT26AGROECOLOGICAL ZONE 26
TABLE 3.2 LAND SITUATION IN THE ZONE.................................................................................................................................................27
TABLE 3.3 PEOPLE IN NEED OF FOOD AID AND FOOD AID DELIVERED IN N. WOLLO ZONE. (1995-1999) 29
TABLE 3.4 THE LIVESTOCK POPULATION IN THE ZONE AND WEREDA FOR THE YEAR 1997/98................................................................29
iv
TABLE 4.1. SAMPLE PA’S, POPULATION AND FARM FAMILY HEAD (FFH), (NUMBER)............................................................................39
TABLE 4.2 AVERAGE VALUE INDICATORS USED IN THE STUDY FOR CLASSIFICATION OF THE FARMERS. ................................................43
TABLE 4.3 FINAL CLUSTER CENTERS, F-VALUE AND T-VALUE FOR THE MAJOR SELECTED
VARIABLE FOR TWO GROUPS:- .........................................................................................................................................................45
TABLE 5. 1 DISTRIBUTION OF AVERAGE FAMILY MEMBERS BY AGE GROUP SAMPLE FARMERS, 1999/00..............................................62
TABLE 5..2 FAMILY SIZE AND THE LABOR FORCE OF SAMPLED RESPONDENTS, 1999/00.........................................................................63
TABLE 5.3 ESTIMATED FAMILY LABOR AVAILABLE FOR FARM ACTIVITY.................................................................................................66
TABLE 5.4 EDUCATIONAL STATUS OF THE SAMPLED HOUSEHOLD HEADS 1999/00 (NUMBER AND PERCENTAGE) 67
TABLE 5. 5. EDUCATIONAL STATUS OF THE SAMPLED HOUSEHOLD MEMBERS (NUMBER AND PERCENTAGE).......................................67
TABLE 5. 6. AVERAGE LAND USE AND CROPPING PATTERN, SAMPLE HOUSEHOLDS, 1999/00................................................................69
TABLE 5.7 THE CROP CALENDAR FOR MAJOR CROPS IN THE STUDY AREA...............................................................................................74
TABLE 5.8 AVERAGE SEED AND FERTILIZER RATE PER HECTARE USED BY THE FARMERS
IN THE STUDY AREA, 1999/00 ..........................................................................................................................................................75
TABLE 5.9 AVERAGE PRODUCTION OF GRAIN AND STRAW PER HECTAR UNDER NORMAL
AND IMPROVED PRACTICES, 1999/00 ..............................................................................................................................................76
TABLE 5.14 MARGINAL VALUE PRODUCTIVITIES OF VARIOUS RESOURCES ON SAMPLED HOLDINGS (BIRR) .........................................88
TABLE 5.15 TOTAL INCOME FROM DIFFERENT CROPS AND THEIR RELATIVE CONTRIBUTION TO
THE SAMPLED FARMERS. (IN BIRR) .................................................................................................................................................89
TABLE 6.1 EXISTING/OPTIMAL CROPPING PATTERN AND LAND USE ON SAMPLE HOLDINGS, 1999/00....................................................92
TABLE 6.2 LIVESTOCK NUMBER UNDER EXISTING AND OPTIMAL CONDITION, SAMPLE FARMERS, 1999/00...........................................93
TABLE 6.3 LABOR, OXEN POWER AND WORKING CAPITAL USE UNDER THE BASE MODEL.......................................................................94
TABLE 6.4 CHANGE IN FARM INCOME AND RESOURCE PRODUCTIVITY UNDER OPTIMAL BASE MODEL
OVER THE EXISTING ONE, SAMPLE HOLDINGS, 1999/00 .................................................................................................................95
TABLE 6.5 SHADOW PRICES OF LIMITING RESOURCES UNDER BASE MODEL ............................................................................................97
TABLE 6.6 CROPPING PATTERN IN THE ALTERNATIVE PLAN SAMPLE HOLDINGS, 1999/00 ......................................................................98
TABLE 6.7 LIVESTOCK NUMBER UNDER ALTERNATIVE PLAN CONDITION.................................................................................................99
TABLE 6.8 LABOR, OXEN POWER AND WORKING CAPITAL USE UNDER THE ALTERNATIVE PLAN......................................................100
TABLE 6.9 FARM INCOME AND RESOURCE PRODUCTIVITY UNDER THE ALTERNATIVE PLAN ................................................................101
TABLE 6.10 SHADOW PRICES OF LIMITING RESOURCES UNDER ALTERNATIVE PLAN .............................................................................102
TABLE 6.11 IMPACT OF OUTPUT PRICE VARIATION ON THE CROPPING PATTERN UNDER BASE PLAN (1999/00). 104
TABLE 6.12 IMPACT OF OUTPUT PRICE VARIATION ON THE OPTIMUM RESOURCE USE RESOURCE
PRODUCTIVITY AND FARM INCOME UNDER BASE MODEL. ...........................................................................................................105
v
TABLE 6.13 IMPACT OF OUTPUT PRICE VARIATION ON MARGINAL VALUE OF RESOURCES UNDER BASE MODEL 106
TABLE 6.14 IMPACT OF OUTPUT PRICE VARIATIONS ON CROPPING PATTERN IN ALTERNATIVE PLAN ....................................................107
TABLE 6.15 IMPACT OF OUTPUT PRICE VARIATION ON THE OPTIMUM RESOURCE OF LIVESTOCK IN ALTERNATIVE PLAN108
TABLE 6.16 IMPACT OF OUTPUT PRICE VARIATION ON THE FARM INCOME, OPTIMUM RESOURCE USE,
PRODUCTIVITY AND MV OF RESOURCES ON ALTERNATIVE PLAN ................................................................................................110
TABLE 6.17. IMPACT OF INPUT PRICE INCREMENT ON THE CROPPING PATTERN OF BASE MODEL..........................................................112
TABLE 6.18 IMPACT OF INPUT PRICE INCREMENT ON THE LIVESTOCK COMPOSITION OF BASE MODEL. ................................................113
TABLE 6.19 IMPACT OF INPUT PRICE VARIATION ON FARM INCOME, RESOURCE PRODUCTIVITY AND
MV OF PRODUCTS OF BASE MODEL.........................................................................................................................................................114
TABLE 6.20 IMPACT OF INPUT PRICE VARIATION ON CROPPING PATTERNIN ALTERNATIVE PLAN .........................................................115
TABLE 6.21 IMPACT OF INPUT PRICE INCREMENT ON THE OPTIMUM RESOURCE USE, FARM INCOME AND
MV OF RESOURCES UNDER ALTERNATIVE PLAN...........................................................................................................................116
TABLE 6.22 IMPACT OF OUTPUT REDUCTION ON CROPPING PATTERN OF BASE MODEL........................................................................118
TABLE 6.23 IMPACT OF OUTPUT REDUCTION ON THE OPTIMUM RESOURCE USE AND
FARMINCOME UNDER BASE MODEL..........................................................................................................................................................119
TABLE 6.24 IMPACT OF OUTPUT REDUCTION ON CROPPING PATTERN OF ALTERNATIVE PLAN (1999/00) ............................................120
TABLE 6.25 IMPACT OF 10 PER CENT AND 25 PER CENT OUTPUT REDUCTION ON THE OPTIMUM
RESOURCE USE AND FARM INCOME UNDER ALTERNATE PLAN. ...................................................................................................122
LIST OF APPENDICES
APPENDIX 1 CONVERSION FACTORS USED TO STANDARDIZE HOUSEHOLD SIZE IN TERMS OF ADULT EQUIVALENT..............................134
APPENDIX 2 CONVERSION FACTORS USED TO STANDARDIZE HOUSEHOLD SIZE IN TERMS OF MAN EQUIVALENT............................134
vi
APPENDIX 4 PRICE OF LIVESTOCK AND CROPS (BIRR) .............................................................................................................................136
APPENDIX 7 NUMBER OF DAYS, WORKING HOURS, AVAILABLE LABOR FORCE AND OXEN POWER......................................................137
LIST OF MAPS
ABBREVIATION
vii
ACSI Amhara Credit and Saving Institute.
AE Adult Equivalent.
AESE Agricultural Economics Society of Ethiopia.
ANOVA Analysis of variance
ANRS Amhara National Regional State
BPED Bureau of Planning and Economic Development.
CI Cash Income.
CSA Central statistics Office
DA Development Agent
DAP Diammomium phosphate
DD Demand
DOA Department of Agriculture
DOPED Department of Planning and Economic Development.
DODPP Department of Disaster Prevention and Preparedness.
F Female
EPID Extension and Project Implementation Department
FAO Food and agriculture organization.
FFH Farm family head
GDP Gross domestic product.
GM Gross margin.
HIG High income group
Hrs. Hours
ILCA International Livestock Center for Africa.
KA Kebele Administration
Kg Kilogram.
Km Kilo meter
Lab. Labor
LDCs Least developed countries.
LIG Low income group.
LP Linear programming.
Ltd. Limited
LU Livestock unit. viii
M Male
Smallholder farming systems and their potential for optimum utilization of resources in North Wollo,
Ethiopia: A case of Meket district
By
Anteneh Temesgen
Abstract
The main objective of this study is to examine the potential for optimal utilization of resources in North
Wollo, which contributes towards designing appropriate plan and development strategies in the future. The
main aim of this comparative analysis is to investigate whether the existing patterns of production are
optimal or not and indicate ways and means of efficiently using the resources of smallhalders in order to
maximize farm incomes.
The study attempts to identify and characterize the farming systems to determine the constraints of
agricultural production, analyze productivity of different resources as well as the level of the farm income
and develop optimal plan for existing and improved farming system with the available resources.
The study uses primary information through farm survey. 110 farm households from 4 peasant associations
are selected through multistage proportionate random sampling. A cluster analysis is used for the
classification of the households based on land to labor ratio, oxen number, tropical livestock unit (TLU),
crop production, family number, and fertilizer use. The two groups are statistically tested and are found to
be significantly different. Thus, there exists a significant difference in resource endowments, input use,
production pattern and farm income. The overall average land holding size for the sample farmers is 1.03
hectare, with 1.76 hectare for the high income group and 0.78 hectare for the low income group.
The high income group possesses an average land labor ratio of 0.5, 1.9 oxen, 7.41 tropical live stock units,
spends Birr 284 per year for fertilizer, average family size of 6.6 and produces 20.60 quintals of grains per
year. The low income group possesses an average 0.3 unit of land to labor ratio, 0.83 oxen, 3.2 tropical live
ix
stock units (TLU), family size of 5.1, an average of 7.20 quintal of grain production and spent Birr 60.70 per
year for fertilizer.
Shortage of Land, weather variability, soil degradation, pest problem, poor management practice, lack of
improved technology, inappropriate allocation of resources, shortage of inputs etc. are some of the main
problems which hinder farmers` productivity and farm income increment in the study area.
Optimal allocation of resources brings improvement in Gross margin by 9.4 per cent and 8 per cent for high
income group and low income group respectively. This change occurs mainly by shifting the area allocated
to enterprises using improved seeds and fertilizers. In the base optimal plan, the average area for
enterprises using improved wheat and fertilizer production increases by 272 per cent and 1350 per cent for
high income group and low income group respectively.
Furthermore, the analysis of the alternative optimal plans over the base model with allocation of enough
working capital shows a better prospect for increasing more farm income than could be realized from the
re-allocation of existing resources for both groups. As a result there is an increment in gross margin by 22,
2 and 10 per cent for high income group, low income group and overall sampled farmers respectively.
A sensitivity test is conducted to test the stability of the optimal plan. The analysis brings out that
consequent upon increased input price and output reduction by 25 per cent, the optimal solution becomes
infeasible. However, such an increment in input price / output reduction is very common in the study area.
This calls for measures such as facilitating of resettlement programs on voluntary bases, construction of
dams, supplying of various inputs to the farmers at reasonable prices and increasing of non-farm activities
to prevent the occurrence of such risks.
x
1. INTRODUCTION
Ethiopia is one of the poorest and least developed countries in the world. According to FAO (1997), the
country had a real per capita GDP of less than US $100 in 1995, and over 60 per cent of its population live
in absolute poverty. The United Nations Development Program’s (UNDP) human development report of
1997, ranked Ethiopia 170th out of 175 countries in terms of its human development index, which
combines economic factors with other factors, such as education, health nutrition and life expectancy.
According to the Word Bank (1995), the size of the country is about 1.14 million sq. km, two thirds of
which consist of highlands with an altitude range of 1500- 4000 meters above sea level. Ethiopia
encompasses about 50 per cent of the total highland areas in tropical Africa (Gryseels, 1988). The country
is endowed with diversity of natural resources. It is, nonetheless, observed that the natural resources such
as soil and forest are declining over time. Depletion of forests and poor land conservation measures have
led to wide spread land degradation (FAO/WFP, 1997). For instance, forests, which at the turn of the
century covered over 40 per cent of the land area, have been reduced to 4 per cent, as a result of expansion
of agricultural frontiers to feed the rapidly increasing population and to satisfy the growing demand for
Agriculture, being the mainstay of the Ethiopian economy, accounts for about 40 per cent of gross national
product. At present nearly 85 per cent of the total population depend on agriculture for their livelihood at
subsistence level. Agriculture provides basic food supply for the urban population, raw materials for agro-
industries, and exportable surplus of commodities to earn foreign exchange, required for strengthening the
1
industrial base of the economy. It is believed that, agriculture is the base for industrial development and the
The 1997/98 agricultural sample survey results indicate that out of total area of 114 million hectares, 9.06
million hectares were used for different purposes. Out of it 7.01 million hectares (77.37 per cent) were
under temporary crops, 558.21 thousand hectares (6.16 per cent) was covered with permanent crops,
597.21 thousand hectares (6.59 per cent) were used for grazing land, 503.99 thousand hectares (5.56 per
cent) of land was kept as fallow land, 35.30 thousand hectares (0.39 per cent) were used as wood land and
356.70 thousand hectares (3.93 per cent) were used for some other purposes (CSA, 1998).
The land holding of the private peasants varies among regions and according to climatic situation of these
areas. In the highland areas the land holding is comparatively small, whereas in the low lands, it is
relatively bigger. According to CSA (1998) Agriculture sample survey, on land utilization by size of land
holdings were classified in 7 groups: - These are Group I under 0.10 hectare, Group II 0.1-0.5 hectare,
Group III 0.51 - 1 hectare, Group IV 1.01 -2 hectares, Group V 2.01- 5 hectares, Group VI 5.01 -10.00
hectare and Group VII above 10.01 hectares and from this out of the total private holdings under temporary
crop, over one - third (35.85 per cent) of them fall in group IV (1.01 - 2 hectares). On the other hand, most
of the holdings under permanent crops (54.43 per cent) fall in group II (0.1-0.5 hectare). The survey result
also indicated that 37.57 per cent of grazing land holdings and 46.14 per cent of land kept as fallow fall in-
group II. It was also noted that 35.24 per cent of the total land used for wood fall in-group I. The largest
estimate (30.18 per cent) of total area of peasant holdings is found in-group IV. The survey result indicates
the total number of agricultural householders in rural area (excluding nomadic areas) is estimated to be
9.29 million and average land holding per household to be 0.98 hectare (CSA, 1998).
2
The average rural sedentary agricultural household size is 5.20. With regard to the education level of the
farmers, the same source reveals that most of them (72.84 per cent) are illiterate, 15.11 per cent attended
grade 1-3, and 0.52 per cent completed 12 grade. The remaining 11.53 per cent had an educational level
that varies between grade 3 and 11. The average life expectancy is reported to be 49 years for males and 52
Nearly 90 per cent of the total export earnings of the country is derived from the agricultural sector.
However, Ethiopian agriculture is characterized by its subsistence nature where, the quasi-totality of the
production comes from smallholder farmers. Most of small-holders are practicing mixed farming (77.68
per cent) with only 20.31 per cent practice crop production and 2.01 per cent on livestock production
(CSA, 1998). The decomposition analysis of the agricultural sector reveals that about 60 per cent of the
output in value terms comes from crop production, 33 per cent from livestock, and 7 per cent from forestry
(FAO, 1992).
Small-holders are characterized by almost exclusive use of family labor for the production process, direct
dependence on farm produce for subsistence requirements, low level of productivity, absence of farm
mechanization and low degree of specialization. However, they have a considerable capacity for change
and improvement (Ruthernberg 1980). This has been seen practically in the “Sassakawa Global 2000’’
efforts, where farmers were able to achive substantial increments in the yields of various crops by using
improved technologies, i.e. seeds, fertilizers, credit availability, and extension support, etc.
Although Ethiopia is one of the poorest countries of the world, yet, it is endowed with enormous
agricultural potential that remains untapped so far. For instance, of the total 68.5 million hectares of arable
3
land (60 per cent of total available land), less than 15 per cent was put under cultivation (CSA, 1998). A
significant proportion of the Central, Southern and Western parts of the country is endowed with fertile
soil and reliable climatic conditions. The country has also vast and regionally spread water resources that
could be used for agricultural production. Only 0.86 per cent of the three million hectares suitable for
irrigation have so far been developed in the year 1997/98 (CSA, 1998). In terms of livestock population,
Ethiopia stands first in Africa and seventh in the world (FAO, 1990).
Despite the country’s immense agricultural potentials, the capacity of the agricultural sector to meet the
domestic and export requirements has been handicapped by its low productivity. It is paradoxical that a
country with such immense agricultural resources could not feed its population and continues to rely on
The Ethiopian population which is estimated at 61.7 millions has been growing at a rate of 2.9 per cent per
annum and is, expected to reach 77 millions by the year 2010 (NBE,1998). In order to feed this ever-
increasing population, agricultural production should grow at a rate of more than 3 per cent per annum.
Keeping in view the ever-expanding food requirements, on the one hand, and the poor productivity of the
agricultural sector, on the other, it becomes pertinent to make an efficient/optimal utilization of the
available limiting resources. Civil war and recurrent droughts have been among the main bottlenecks that
affected the country’s development effort. Drought has become the most frequent phenomenon beginning
the 1974/75 drought years. For instance, during 1980s, the domestic food production was, on an average
able to cover only 70 per cent of the recommended minimum food intake and it only rose to 76 per cent
when food aid was included (Takele 1996). More specifically, there has been a substantial long term
decline in food self-sufficiency. There is a sharp increase in the gap between production and consumption
4
as indicated by a large increase in commercial food import. The volume of food imports increased from
177.8 tons in 1979 to more than 1 million tons in 1991/92 (Tesfaye and Debebe, 1995). As a result of food
shortage, the number of famine victims has been considerable; between 1983 and 1985 the number of
people who died due to famine was estimated at over 1 million (Joachim, 1990). In recognition of these
problems and challenges, there is increasing emphasis on strategies and mechanisms of institutional and
policy reform aimed at improving agricultural productivity in the face of population growth possesses one
of the greatest challenges in satisfying the increasing demand for food and creating exportable surpluses
Significant growth of agriculture production were registered in the last few years as a result of the new
extension program. The 1997 FAO/WFP crop and food supply assessment mission to Ethiopia, witnessed
that in recent years, the growth rate of the agricultural production tended to keep ahead of population
growth rate but production was reported to be highly variable due to heavy dependence on erratic rainfall.
The Agricultural Sample Survey results of the Central Statistics Authority, revealed that agricultural
production has grown at the rate of 3.4, 14.7, 3.44, -7.6 per cent per year in the period of 1994/95, 1995/96,
1996/97 and 1997/98 respectively. The explanation for the fluctuation in the growth rate of agricultural
production is variation in the amount and distribution of rainfall. For instance, in 1996/97 the country
received a favorable rainfall but in 1997/98 because of the el nino effect, production declined sharply. As
to the total agricultural production, in 1996/97 ‘meher’ season, private peasant producers (sedentary rural
population) produced 96,452.4 thousand quintals of major crops. Of this total production, cereals
accounted for the highest share (89.5 per cent), followed by pulses (8.3 per cent) and other crops like neug,
linseed, rapeseed, fenugreek, sunflower and sesame (2.2 per cent). A comprehensive study undertaken by
the Ministry of Agriculture depicts, that in 1997/98, yield per hectare for cereals was 11.6 quintals (17.5 for
5
Maize, 14.1 for wheat, 11.5 for barley and 7.5 for teff), 8.12 quintals for pulses, 3.77 quintals for nueg and
Of total area under major crops in 1996/97 production season, improved seeds were applied only on 165.4
thousand hectares (2 per cent), pesticides were applied on 624.2 thousand hectares (8 per cent) and
fertilizers were applied on 2,844.9 thousand hectares (35 per cent) respectively (National Bank of Ethiopia,
1999). This indicates that concerted efforts need to be made to familiarize private peasant holdings with
the intensive use of improved agricultural inputs as they are still at low levels of input application.
The crop productivity of small-holder farmers has to be increased considerably and quickly if self-
sufficiency in food production is to be achieved. If the productivity of these farms can be increased to the
level where they could achieve self-sufficiency and have surpluses for sale, then there will be a much
expanded opportunity for improvements in rural welfare and, indirectly for industrial development
powered and led by agricultural surpluses. This has been observed in India after the “green revolution”.
Currently agriculture in India is leading industrial growth by earning foreign exchange through export of
agricultural surpluses, and through capital transfer and demand creation to sustain economic growth
(Rajagoplan, 1981)
In highlands of Ethiopia the demand for land has been increasing significantly in the last three decades.
Available evidence shows that, over the years, the total land holding per household is becoming smaller
and smaller. Given the rapidly growing population and consequent degradation of natural resources, the
opportunity to increase smallholders` productivity through area expansion is limited. The proportion of
cultivated land in potentially productive highlands is perhaps of the order of 50 to 70 per cent of total land
and the remaining land is mostly water logged or steep slope (World Bank, 1984). The reduction of
6
cropping land, due to increasing human population, soil erosion, deforestation and deterioration in fertility
of land is the principal challenging problem observed in the study area. Cropping, grazing and tree
plantation (Eucalyptus tree) etc. are the major competing agents for this limited land in the study area.
Any attempt to improve agricultural productivity requires a detailed study on existing farming systems.
Results of such studies help to look for alternatives to the existing farming systems and there by identify
the effects of various activities (crop and livestock) on farm plans. With respect to the study area, it is
possible to say that only very few of farmers incorporate improved inputs in their farming practice.
However, it is common knowledge that the introduction of new techniques and methods of production
creates a variation in the productivity and farm income, so that selection of high productive, high income
technologies should be expanded. Currently, the Ethiopian Government has accorded high priority to the
dissemination of inputs, credit availability and training of development agents (DAs). to increase
agricultural production.
In fact, the new extension package adopted from “Sassakawa Global 2000” has given more emphasis to
the expansion of the area under major cereals (wheat, teff and maize) with the aim of promoting food self-
sufficiency. This can be made possible only at the expense of other enterprises for it diverts scarce
resources to the production of major cereal crops (Hassen, 1999). Hence, conflicts may emanate from the
farmers` priority of managing multiple enterprises and the Government’s objective of promoting major
cereal production. So that, even though the basic objectives of agricultural policy in the country had always
been food self-sufficiency, generation of export earnings and employment creation, the performance of the
agricultural sector remained very poor. The aforementioned technical problems call for the need to
investigate farmers’ practices in optimally allocating scarce resources among their competing uses.
7
Optimizing production pattern and resource utilization can be defined as to what crop and livestock
activities to undertake, how much land to allocate to each crop activity and what method and combination
of inputs to use on each activity so that farm returns can be maximized. The question of optimum
allocation of resources is one which is answered within a farm as an individual business firm, within a
nation for a distinct society or for producing units of any other magnitude. Moreover, if high level of
efficiency is to be attained in the economy, constant reallocation of resources must be a continuous activity,
based on changes in human wants the kinds and quantities of resources available, and the available
technology (Leftwich and Eckert, 1985). Therefore, to exploit the resources at their disposal, farmers
should be assisted to achieve their objectives by efficiently allocating their resource to the enterprises from
Hence, it is necessary to closely examine the traditional cropping patterns as well as improved practices
and identify optimum plans that could maximize farm income under a given set of constraints, using
available resources and technologies at farmers` level. In actual practice, the optimal plans are designed in
such a way that they capture all possible interactions between food, livestock activities and tree planting, so
that farmers could fulfill their subsistence need from their own resource along with earning maximum
incomes.
This study has been mainly designed to analyze the smallholders` existing farming systems and to explore
their potential for improvement in North Wollo Zone. The specific objectives of the study are:
8
1. To identify and characterize the farming systems and to identify the constraints of agricultural
2. To analyze the productivity of different resources as well as the level of farm income in the
study area.
3. To develop optimal plan for existing and improved farming systems with the available
The task of establishing whole set of new production methods and farming system requires a study on the
nature of constraints within which small farmers operate so as to identify and assess possible changes in
the method of production (Dalton, 1975). Farmers who are operating in different agro-climatic and socio-
economic conditions are confronted with different constraints and thus may not adopt the same
innovations. An understanding of the smallholders` farming systems and their demand for suitable
9
innovations is an essential pre-requisite for the organization of technical research, the design of
development policies and for shaping the direction of action for smallholders` development. In case of
acute land shortage and existing low land productivity, farmers face difficulty to self-sustain on the
existing farming practices. There is a need to assess the ways of increasing productivity by proper
allocation of existing mixed farming practices from the stand-point of the scarcity of resources. There is a
particular need, to improve their resource allocation in order to increase yields, without depleting the
resources upon which they rely. Farm planning should be given more attention to ensure the best use of
This study, therefore, seeks to contribute to a better understanding of the smallholder`s farming system
for performing further research, the design of development policies, and for shaping the direction of
action for smallholders' development. Furthermore, it assists in improving the planning process and
developing the strategy of smallholders optimal allocation of existing limited resources. Thus, study
attempts to provide directions for further planning, research, and extension and development schemes
and for identifying the potential techniques that would benefit farming population.
Due to time and financial constraints, this research has been limited to only one district in North Wollo
zone, with particular topographic and climatic situation, as well as soil type. The study covered only the
major crops grown in the study area. Moreover, the study used a single visit interview technique on 110
farm households. Moreover, the analytical model makes use of inputs measured in stock rather than in
flow. As a result, the analysis may suffer from inaccuracies in some aspects of measurements. Of course,
10
results would be sound if repeated visits of sample households were made throughout a year. Because of
the above limitations the results of this study could hardly be used for inference purposes. However, the
results of this study are expected to be of paramount importance in providing first hand information
1.6. Hypotheses
- Farmers are operating at a sub-optimal level, and there is a possibility of increasing their farm income by
- Different farm households have different resource endowments and are exposed to different farm
problems.
- The productivity of household resources are at low level, and there will be a possibility of increasing
This thesis is organized in eight chapters. Chapter one - introduces the problem and background of
Ethiopian economy, in chapter two - relevant literature has been reviewed. Chapter three describes the
local agro-climatological features of the study area and the socio-economic characteristics of the
households. Chapter four presents the methodology and procedures employed to accomplish the objectives
of the study. Chapter five describes the farming systems and resource endowments. Chapter six presents
11
outputs of the LP model. The last chapter summarizes the major findings and policy recommendations of
the study.
12
2. REVIEW OF LITERATURE
2.1. General
The majority of the rural population in developing countries is small scale farmers or tenant farmers. One
principal characteristic of smallholders is their limited access to farm resources, mainly land and capital. If
“solutions” are to be found to the problem of households, those solutions must involve better use of their
Many countries in sub-Saharan Africa are experiencing rapid population growth, increasing degradation of
the natural resource base, and declining per capita food production (Omiti, 1995). In Ethiopia, eventhough
agriculture is the dominant and most promising sector for dealing with socio-economic problems of the
country, its productivity is very low. Farming, particularly crop and livestock compete for various
resources such as land and labor. However, practicing a mixed farming is complementary to mutually
benefit from their manure and crop residues. Considerable differences exist between households in factor
endowment and farming practices, which lead to complex household decisions on selection of enterprise
combinations and production techniques. In fact such decisions have important implications for farm
incomes and the sustainablity of the farming system(s) (Omiti, 1995). Food self-sufficiency is brought
about by achieving the desired level of production in crops and livestock through proper planning and use
of resources. The more efficient a country′s agriculture is, the better fed its people will be, and the more
resources there will be to satisfy peoples` needs and aspirations beyond the essentials of food and fibres
(Dillon, 1968). The potential of agriculture should be prioritized on improving a nation’s economic
standard. The accumulation of knowledge, the development of structures, and the build-up of capital,
required to give the developing world an adequate and secure food supply in the long term is the major
13
challenge the world faces (Cunningham, 1992). Farm size in peasant agriculture is a main constraint in the
way of efficient production as well as providing adequate living conditions for the households. Those
farmers who cultivate small areas of land have more shortage of oxen, heads of other cattle, low income,
low family expenditure and are forced to buy more grain from the market to supplement subsistence from
their own produce. Problems of production like shortage of capital to buy inputs such as fertilizer, shortage
of land and oxen for crop production and food shortage for the farm family and inability to produce and to
earn enough food and cash both at present and in the future are also found to be more frequently perceived
by the small-sized farmers. The reaction of the smallholder farmers to land shortage, and their adjustment
strategies, show some relation to farm size even within small range of the size differences among the
farmers. Cropping pattern could not be found to be much influenced by farm size. For the smaller sized
farmers yield of major annual crops and, hence, return per hectare of cultivated land are relatively higher
The basic economic problem of “scarcity” provides the need for efficient allocation of limited resources.
The economic rationality of peasant agriculture has been a controversial issue among economists. Many
studies have attempted to examine this issue and came out with two opposing conclusions: - Singh et al.
(1978) showed that in the case of India, under existing cropping pattern, farm resources were not utilized
optimally and the optimal plan resulted in significant increment in farm returns over the existing one. It
was further stressed that even with the limited cash resources at the disposal of the small-scale farmers, a
change in cropping pattern would positively affect the existing farm income.
Solomon (1993) indicated the existence of a substantial potential, of increasing farm income and
employment in Sidamo zone through optimum use of existing resource, by adopting improved technology
14
and with extended supply of labor. Similarly, many research findings (Bezabih et al (1991) Getachew
(1995), Hassen (1999)) in Ethiopia showed the possibility of increasing farm income through efficient
allocation of resources and incorporation of improved farm practices on the existing one.
On the other hand, Schultz (1964) proposed that smallholder farmers do maximize profits and therefore
use their resources efficiently within the limits of traditional technology. He stressed that the allocation
efficiency in most peasant agriculture is generally high in the content of prevailing technical possibilities
and of factors and product cost relationship. Similarly, Solomon (1996) showed there is no significance
deviation in resource allocation between the base model and the current farmer practices.
As a result, there are no clear-cut conclusions on the behavior of smallholders economy with respect to
allocation of resources. The controversies on the issue will continue as far as their dissimilarities among
peasants of various forms with regard to their objectives, motivations and constraints.
Subsistence, smallholder mixed farming systems generally prevail throughout the highlands with crop and
livestock typically produced within the same management unit. There is a high degree of integration
between crop and livestock production systems. The farm integration function refers to all the different
effects of livestock on crop and vice versa on the productivity of the resources engaged in Agriculture.
Mixed farming in smallholder is assumed to be more productive than crop or livestock enterprise alone.
Livestock may provide agricultural inputs, like power, manure and working capital, and render cropping
enterprise more productive and more secure by using residual capacities of production factors with low
opportunity costs like non-arable land, excess labor and child labor, by converting crop residues into high
value animal products, by balancing production and marketing risk, etc. According to Jahnke (1982), a pair
15
of animals used for agriculture work increase the work capacity of a farm two to three folds resulting in an
increase in income.
The poor performance of the peasant agriculture in Ethiopia calls for an investigation of means to improve
the existing situation. One possible way of improving the situation is by reallocating the farm resources
with or without technical innovations. In the study area, where shortage of resources especially shortage of
land is high, farmers need assistance in resource allocation so as to mitigate and eventually overcome the
Linear programming is a mathematical technique based on matrix algebra where by a stated objective is
either maximized or minimized while satisfying various linear constraints. The production possibilities for
the farm, their resource needs, gross margins and the resource constraints are brought together in a tableau
called a matrix from which the optimum plan is produced (Johnson, 1982).
Planning and optimizing techniques (farm budgeting, program planning, linear programming, and recently
project planning) are essential for solving the problem of low farm productivity in peasant agriculture,
through improving the resource productivity available to farm households and measuring net income effect
of recombining their resources and enterprises. Linear programming (LP), as one of the various methods of
farm planning, has become a basic and widely recognized empirical tool particularly in solving problems
related to allocation of resources among alternative lines of production and to identify an optimum
enterprise mix that could maximize income or profit. The technique has already found many important
applications in determining optimum enterprise patterns for maximum profit and in identifying resource
16
constraints. It also serves as an important management aid to farmers in evaluating the merits or demerits
of introducing new techniques. Exploratory researches in application of the LP model to such and other
types of problems reveals its usefulness. The economic significance and strength of LP, especially in
According to Low (1978), Linear programming is a powerful tool to analyze farm management data in
order to determine farm plans that will yield maximum profits under different situations. It is also
important to model the behavior of a group of small-scale farmers with regard to their goals so that
policy-makers can better formulate actions to help them. Further, the strength of the linear programming
model lies in its ability to handle a large number of interrelated variables and to cope with peasant
farming systems which are characterized by a high degree of interdependence between production,
consumption, investment, resource availability, social and cultural constraints. LP is advantageous in that
it allows one to test a wide range of alternative adjustments and to analyze their consequences thoroughly
with a small input of managerial time (Beneke and Winter Boer 1973).
LP has been used as a research tool by agricultural economists to solve various agricultural problems. For
instance, Kahlon et al (1975) in their study of relative profitability of dairy enterprise vis-à-vis crop
cultivation in Punjab India, used linear programming analysis for developing optimal plans. Bogahawatte
(1984), formulated a linear programming model for describing the crop-livestock integrated farming
systems in the Moneragla district of Sirilanka to evaluate the system in terms of maximizing farm incomes
from the different crop and livestock components of the system. Singh et al.(1989) used LP for examining
the resource requirements, their better utilization for the village as a whole and to explore economic
feasibility of co-operative farming in the Haryana state of India. Similarly, many researchers applied LP to
17
African agriculture. The first application was made by Clayton (1961) in his study, on effect of the
constraints on profitability of typical farms in the central province of Kenya. Abalu (1975) used LP to
identify resource constraints of small farmers in Nigeria. R. Emonger and S.C. Mbogoh, (Cited in Sisay
1983), used linear programming model to test the optimal resource allocation and economic
competitiveness of rain-fed rice on smallholder farms in Amkura division, Busia District Kenya. Tibaijuka
(1994) had selected LP model to investigate gender roles on peasant farms in the Kajera Region
(Tanzania).
Woubeshet (1985) used a whole-farm linear programming model to assess the technical and economic
performance of sheep enterprises under smallholder farmers` management conditions around Debreberhan.
Gryseels (1988) adopted linear programming to allow incorporation of cross-bred cows in farm operations
of smallholders around Debreberhan, Ethiopian highlands, where cows were fed a mixture of oats and
vetch, grass hay and straw of cereals. Tesfaye (1989) made use of LP to make economic analysis of co-
operative farming in the highlands of Ethiopia. Debebe (1992) applied LP to assess the impact of
diversification with tobacco in smallholder farms in Awassa zuria aweraja. Bezabih (1992) applied LP to
evaluate the effect of reallocation of resources on the cropping patterns and the associated incomes of the
farmers and to evaluate the effect of improved technologies on the cropping patterns and incomes of the
households in the Hararghe highlands of Ethiopia. Solomon (1993) had indicated a substantial potential in
Sidamo region for increasing farm income and employment through optimum use of existing resources
more so with the adoption of improved technology and with extended supply of labor in the LP
optimization model. Panin and Brokken (1993) applied linear programming to evaluate the economic
efficiency of single ox and cow traction technologies to identify major constraints to increase farm income.
Omiti (1995) employed LP in his study on economic analysis of crop-livestock integration in Ethiopian
18
highlands. Hassen (1999) used LP model in his study on the crop-livestock integration on smallholders`
farms and their potential for improvement in Deberesina and Tehulederie districts of South Wollo zone.
Compared with ordinary farm budgeting and simplified programming, LP has the following advantages
- LP guarantees the optimum solution when there are a wide range of resources which can be used in many
different ways, something which is difficult if not impossible with ordinary budgeting techniques (Reddy,
1999)
- Most LP computer routines make it possible to see the effect of the optimal plan of changing prices,
resources as well as input/ output coefficients (Reddy, 1999). This is laborious to do using ordinary
budgeting techniques and for this reason seldom done by simple budgeting methods.
- LP algorithm is operational on most digital computers, so the major proportion of professional time
investment in farm planning using LP is in data collection, appraisal and model formulation, not in the
- LP provides additional useful economic information about the optimum plan such as shadow prices and
range results. Shadow prices or the marginal value products of scarce resources are useful in indicating
where there will be a payoff to improved technical efficiency. Those scarce resources with relatively higher
marginal value products than the others in the optimal solution, if it increased in supply, will give higher
returns to the gross margin. Range results provide the range of quantities of inputs, outputs and prices to
vary over which the optimal solution would not change (Dillon and Hardaker, 1980). There are several
complex LP options that can be more appropriate and theoretically suitable to smallholders` farm planning.
Some of these models include: dynamic (multi period) and quadratic (stochastic) etc. programming. The
19
main reasons as to why these complex LP models are not used in this study are: Substantial data is required
for these multi-period LP options, requirement of complex computer programming for the realistic model
were unreliable.and Setting up of the models needs too much preparation, time and experience.
The LP model used in this study is a simple computer-based procedure that can be used for smallholders
farm planning, within certain limitations. This simple model determines a mix of activities, which
LP, like most planning techniques, has certain limitations for it was designed to be applicable under a
given set of assumptions. A number of assumptions underlying linear programming restrict its
application and interpretation. The general model of linear programming represents the linear, static
deterministic and non-integer programming model. For this to be effective, various requirements must
be met, including the standard and primary requirements of linearity objective function and every
constraint function, proportionality of activity levels to resources, additivity and divisibility of resources
and activities, and single-valued prices of technical coefficients and resources. The use of linear
The assumption of linear input-output relation overlooks the non-linear rates of substitution between
factors or products that arise from the law of diminishing returns or from scale effects. Taking
diminishing returns into account is troublesome, because more activities must be included in the model.
However, production relations of this type can be handled realistically. Discrete points on the function
can be represented as separate activities in the matrix. For instance, wheat produced with improved
20
seeds can be treated as one activity and wheat produced with local seeds as an another activity. A choice
among any number of different levels can be handled in this way. A similar procedure can be followed
wherever a choice among different levels of inputs is desired provided the amount of output per unit of
Linear programming assumes activities and resources to be additive and divisible. The additivity
assumption causes a problem if activities are complementary. However, this can be tackled by defining
new activities that accommodate these interactions. Divisibility problem can be solved by making minor
adjustments in the solution to bring activities to integral levels. “Rounding off” the answer to the nearest
The assumption of single-valued expectations specifies that resource supplies, input-output coefficients,
and prices are known with certainty. The resulting plan does not take into account the risk preference of
the operator. However, it is possible for the operator to exclude or consider activities to be risky by
eliminating them from the range of activities offered or by restraining their level. Furthermore, Prices
and production coefficients can be raised and “sensitivity analysis” can illustrate the resource allocation
and income impacts of alternative sets of prices and production efficiencies. This information can be
quite useful in evaluating the implication of price or yield variability. Alternative modification of linear
programming, such as stochastic and MOTAD programming procedures can be used to incorporate risk
dimensions in the analysis although they are of additional complexity and data requirements.
Regardless of these limitations, linear programming has been used to solve various types of farm
management problems.
21
The technique has been employed in this study after making some possible adjustments on the problem
formulation so that it could reflect as nearly as possible the actual farming practices and socio-economic
conditions of the study area. In this regard, the necessary modifications that were made on the specification
of the activities and constraints include segregation of family labor by sex, age, and inclusion of minimum
subsistence requirements for the family. In this study LP was used to analyze the production pattern,
productivity of resources and marginal value of resources etc. In addition to these, LP helped to derive
optimum farm plans for two levels of farm technologies i.e. optimization models at current and constraint
released level. Moreover, sensitivity analysis has also been carried out to test the stability of optimal plans.
22
3. OVERVIEW OF THE STUDY AREA.
North Wollo zone is situated in the North Eastern part of the country. It is one of the eleven
administrative zones of Amhara National Regional State (ANRS). It is bounded in the North with
Tigray National Regional State and Wag Hamira zone, in the East with Afar National Regional State, in
the South with South Wollo Administrative zone, in the West with South and North Gonder zones. The
zone is divided into 9 weredas consisting of one town (Woldia) and 8 rural (Gubalafto, Kobo, Habru,
Gidan, Bugina, Meket, Wadela and Delanta) weredas. Meket wereda is the district selected for this
study. It is found in the western part of the North Wollo as is displayed in the figure. The distance from
Addis to Woldia (town of North Wollo zone) is 520 km, and that of Flakit (town of the wereda) is 665
km.
23
3.1 MAP OF NORTH WOLLO ZONE.
24
3.2. Agroecology and Climate
North Wollo zone is divided into different agroecology and climatic conditions. The zone is
mountainous and is situated in the rift valley. There is a great variation in Meket wereda in elevation
25
with lowlands to highlands, ranging between 1500 to 3200 MSL. The distribution of areas and
population of this zone in different agro-ecological sub-zone has been depicted in table 3.1.
Agroecological Zone
Total area Population
Particular (hectares) (number) Dega W/dega Qolla
% % % % % %
pop. area pop. area pop. area
N. Wollo zone 1,070,000 1,490,853 28 28 50 48 22 24
Meket Wereda 182826 227,872 20 36 57 37 23 27
Source :- North Wollo DOA, 2000, Woldia.
Table 3.1 shows that Dega and W/dega account for more than 70 per cent of area and population of the
North Wollo zone and Meket wereda. There are significant climatic variations within the zone. The
rainfall situation is inadequate and erratic in its distribution. There is bimodal rainfall situation in the
zone: the main rainfall season extends from June to September where as the short rainy season starts
from end of January up to end of April. This makes North Wollo as one of the most frequently stricken
zones by recurrent droughts. The occurrence of drought in this area is mainly the result of drastic weather
variability and erratic nature of rainfall in quantity and distribution over time and space. Among these
Since the area is mountainous and inappropriate for plowing, only small portion of the total area is
arable. Out of total 1,070,000 hectares, only 255,163 hectares are useful for plowing which is less than
25 per cent of the total area, for meher, belg and with irrigation. Other areas are inappropriate for
26
plowing because of the mountainous nature of the zone. Some of the areas are plowed twice a year
based on the rainfall distribution. When the belg rainfall condition is high the amount of two-times
plowed land (belg plowed land) per year will increase, on an average a total of up to 262,100 ha of land
is plowed per year for the three farming types in North Wollo zone (DOA, 1997). The average land
holding in the zone is 0.78 hectare, and that of the sampled households is 1.03 hectares. This average
masks differences in land holding among farmers in the study area, which varies between 0.25 to 2.5
hectares. Table 3.2 gives a brief account of the land situation in the zone.
Land as per constitution, is owned by the state and the farmer has a user right but he can not sell and
exchange the land. The land tenure system has been a controversial issue in Ethiopia. Some believe that
the existing land tenure arrangement has contributed towards increased degradation of farmer’s land, i.e.
permanent conservation activities were not done on the land, and the farmer fails to plant or is
discouraged from planting permanent trees on his land. This aggravates the soil erosion problem and
reduces the productivity of various crops. Others believe that, if the farmers are given the right to own
land privately and are allowed to sell, many of the farmers will start selling their land and at the end
become landless. Since, there are very limited non-farm activities available; the farmers will be exposed
to serious economic hardships and evictions. These controversies have to be solved through discussions
27
Starting 1997 the Amhara National State started to distribute the hill sides to individual farmers for
forest land, and this has contributed to conserve the mountainous areas and some forest remnants started
to regenerate because the land was protected and different varieties of forest seedlings were planted on
The population growth level is 2.9 per cent per year; the situation is similar to North Wollo and Meket
wereda. The total number of people in the year 1999/00 was 1,490,853 and 227,872 in North Wollo and
The food requirement in the zone is not fulfilled. In normal season, less than 85 per cent of the food
requirement is fulfilled. In the event of bad weather, the food deficiency reaches up to 50 per cent. This
deficit is mostly fulfilled through aid and by performing non-farm activities. As seen in table 3.3, the
number of food aid dependent people is increasing year after year. This may be attributed to the
inadequate rains received in the belg season during the last four years i.e. from 1995/96 to 1998/99.
Table 3.3 People in need of food aid and food aid delivered in
Since the farming system is mixed, livestock equally play as important role as that of crop production.
The livestock holding per household varies among households. The livestock productivity of the zone
and wereda is generally very low. The livestock population are shown in table 3.4.
Table 3.4 The livestock population in the zone and wereda for the year 1997/98
North Wollo zone is poor by all socio-economic and infra structural indicators.
Education
Similar to the rest of the country, most of people in the zone are illiterate. There are 212 elementary and
6 high schools in the zone. There are 41,812 male and 31,423 female students enrolled in these schools.
There are 7462 male and 6043 female students in Meket wereda.
Health
Access to health facilities is also far from satisfactory. There are only 2 hospitals, 8 health centers, 60
29
clinics and 53 health stations in the zone and 1 health center, 8 clinics and 8 health posts in Meket
wereda.
Roads
There are two main roads connecting North Wollo zone with other regional states and zones. Besides,
these roads are not all-weather roads. During rainy seasons, there is no transport connection with two of
the weredas. Meket wereda is one of the weredas in which the main Woldia-Woreta road crosses and a
new road is under construction that passes through Gashena and Lalibela towns. There are also some
other roads constructed by NGOs (such as Meket-Serko constructed by SOS Sahel) in food for work
Potable water
The available potable water facilities are inadequate for the rural population. Wereda towns and only
few villages near to the main road are getting pure potable water. The water problem is acute,
particularly in the low land areas of the zone and during dry seasons, where people have to travel more
than 10 km to fetch drinking water.
Agricultural extension attempts to change farmers` behavior and increase productivity of their enterprise.
To fulfill the national long-term target of food self-sufficiency and food security, improving the
productivity levels of the rural smallholders is essential. Various extension approaches were developed at
different times. These include: first and second minimum package program (MPP1 and MPP2), the
Extension and Project Implementation Department (EPID), Peasant Agriculture Development and
Extension Project (PADEP) and Training and Visit Program (T and V) etc. But all these extension
approaches could not help much to change living conditions of the rural poor. The prevailing national
30
extension system called Participatory Demonstration and Training Extension System (PADETES) is in the
process of implementing the various extension activities from regional to the smallest grass-root institution
at the peasant associations(PAs) and/or kebele administration (KA) levels. The regional PADETES plans,
have one extension agent or development agent (DA) for one PA/KA comprising 5000 people and/or 1000
farm households, but at present, the number of DAs. has increased while the number of farmers per DA
has declined. Furtherrmore, farmers have formed working teams of 10-20 members to plan and implement
various rural development programs. The efforts made in the country as a whole and at the grass-root level
in order to expand the new extension system has helped farmers to increase farm income and agricultural
productivity.
Some of the extension services rendered for farmers at regional, zonal and wereda levels include: delivery
of different improved seed varieties, inorganic fertilizer, improved poultry breed (Rod Island Red),
improved dairy cows, improved fodder crops, improved ram, improved beehives, credit facilities coupled
The soil fertility problem is one of the serious problems in the study area. It should be addressed
immediately.
There are efforts of soil and water conservation activity in North Wollo zone. Every year more than 25,000
hectares of arable land are being covered with terraces. Other related soil conservation activities performed
in the zone include pond construction, derange ferrous, gully control measures, afforestation practices etc.
The conservation practics are being conducted every year by mobilizing the community basis during slack
31
seasons when farmers are free. During the meher season, farmers perform conservation activities starting
January up to March. The conservation activities are performed on a voluntary basis. Farmers are
organized into groups; each group with a supervisor and a team leader selected from the members of the
group will be trained by the agricultural experts in the wereda`s agricultural office. Then the farmers
formulate their own rules to implement their activities through DAs and kebele leaders.
Though, the soil and water conservation effort of course has many advantages, yet, it has some problems
(1) The conservation activities were not supported by other related practices such as vegetative coverings.
(2) Although the farmers are aware of the advantages of soil conservation practices, they destroy and
distract previous years` terraces and reconstruct new ones above or below the previous terraces in order to
(3) Farmers also complained that terracing takes farming space which would eventually reduce their land
size.
In spite of the above problems, the soil conservation practices are the only remaining main option to reduce
soil degradation in the area. The concerned government officials, NGO`s and the community have to
provide due emphasis to the soil conservation activities by integrating it with other vegetative coverage
practices.
In addition the crop - livestock mixed farming system, there are also off - farm activities in the study area.
Both the high and low income groups participate in off-farm activities. The relatively high income groups
32
participate in petty trading, lending their property including money with high per cent of interest repayment
and hiring mules and horses; where as the low income groups participate in food-for-work activities,
hiring-out family labor, weaveing, pottery-making, black-smithing, local tanning and so on.
Trading activities include the collection of hides and skins from the surrounding area and resale to larger
merchants, bringing factory products from the town for sale to the surrounding people, and the collection
of grains from the neighbouring markets where prices are low (at harvesting season) for resale at relatively
high prices in the lean season. The high income group also lends their money and other property such as
food grain etc., in order to be repaid during harvest time usually at double of the amount they lent. They
lend their money with 10 per cent interest per month and double repayment for the amount of property
such as grain borrowed within a year`s time. Some farmers participate in hiring-out of their mules and
horses for tourists and surrounding merchants in order to transfer goods and human beings from place to
place. Tourists pay a certain amount of Birr per round trip to go to “Abune Aron rock hune church” which
is about 10 km from the study site. The road is extremely difficult to cover on foot because of the
Low income groups hire-out their labor to the surrounding, relatively richer farmers for plowing, weeding,
harvesting and threshing purposes at very low pay. They are paid either in the form of ox for plowing
purpose or grains. Their children are also employed to herd the livestock of the richer farmers. In addition
to food, the payment ranges from 50-100 Birr per year. Poor farmers also participate in food-for-work
activities in the area which includes soil and water conservation activities and nursery activities. The pay
for these activities is 3 kg of wheat and 120 ml. of edible oil per day. This opportunity is only available for
some poor farmers who are selected by considering their poverty status and ability to work. The selection
33
is usually done by DAs and leaders of Kebeles` peasant associations.
In the Amhara National Regional State, there is a strong administrative institutional system which starts
from kebele administration at grass-root level. Above the kebele, we have the wereda and zone. Each
kebele is sub-divided into sub-kebeles and up to 35 family households organized into one group. This
group in the kebele is the starting point for planning and implementing development activities in the
community. These groups participate in mass mobilization activities. The community selects his leaders
so that they will attend and control the average activity in each administrative stratum. All economic,
social and political activities at the grass-root level are performed by these groups. The grass-root level
institutions are aware of all the services provided to the farmers. The kebeles are the main institutions
The hierarchy of MOA exists at all levels. At regional level it is Bureau of Agriculture, at zonal level it
Agricultural Station. These institutions are mainly government structures supportting the farming
system. The grass root-level institutions are responsible for the overall improvement of the farmers`
production and living conditions through extension services. The activities of these institutions involve:
34
- Provision of improved seeds;
- Provision of fertilizer;
- Provision of credit facility or assistance in obtaining financial services from NGOs, government;
- Procuring improved livestock breeds from the breeding centers etc; and
- Regulating and controlling disease, pests, hide and skin defects, forest products etc.
It is an institution that is established to help farmers to tackle their problems together. It helps farmers to
take their products together to the market place and bring factory-products to their surrounding area for
members. There are 91 service co-operatives in North Wollo zone (BPED, 1998). The service co-
operatives in the zone are participating in input-supply (fertilizer), food-grain marketing, and factory-
Although cooperatives are useful institutions for development, they were used as an instrument of the
government during the Derge period. The co-operative resources were embezzled by committee
There are many NGOs, bilateral, and multilateral organizations that work to support the farmers. There
are 7 multilateral and 6 bilateral organizations and 9 NGOs participating in the zone. Among these, 4
multilateral, 1 bilateral and 3 NGOs are working in development activity in Meket wereda. These non
government institutions provide solid support to the community. Some of the activities in which these
institutions participate involve the provision of inputs, grains for food-for-work, different farm
equipments, improved livestock breeds, beehive and pullets. They are also active in soil and water
35
conservation, agro-forestry (forest protection and seedling development) activities; in the construction of
veterinary clinics, seed-banks, drug stores; provision of vehicles, radio communications; organization of
seminars, training for different professionals, development agents, farmers; in spring and irrigation
water developments; in provision of credit; in pest and disease control and in promoting the extension
Farming activity requires financial resources. These resources are obtained either from own savings or
credit. Farmers can get the credit from the formal or non formal sectors or semi- formal sectors. There
are government as well as non-government organizations which supply credit to the farmers in the
formal way. Among these, office of agriculture, service co-operatives, Amhara Credit and Saving
Institutions (ACSI), Meket microfinance institution and different NGOs supply credit to the farmers.
The presence of these institutions in the area has partly solved the farmers` demand for financial
resources and helped them to obtain improved farm inputs on credit in order to increase farm
productivity. The lending interest rate of MFIs in Meket varies from 10 to 12.5 per cent per year
In addition to these microfinance institutions, local money-lenders serve as a source of credit to farmers.
The local money-lenders are also useful to the poor farmers providing credit for purchase of food grains,
purchase of farm input and emergency purposes. The interest rate paid for the money-lenders depends
mostly on the relation they have with the debter and the creditor-debtor agreement reached at the time
the deal is made. However the charge has always been discribed as exhorbitant when contrasted with
36
37
4. METHODOLOGY
Meket wereda is selected for the purpose of this study on the ground that it can represent the highland
weredas in North Wollo. The highland weredas of North Wollo have high population pressure with low
land holding. Land scarcity is one of the crucial problems in the study area Observing the possibilities for
optimal allocation of this scarce resource by considering Meket wereda as a representative of the highland
A multi-stage random sampling method was used to select farmers. Sample farmers were selected in two
stages. In the first stage, a total of 4 peasant associations (PAs) were purposively selected from 35 PAs in
the study district based on ease of accessibility, climatic condition, consultation with the experts of Wereda
Office of Agriculture and extension workers. Thereafter, a total of 110 farmers were chosen randomly. The
number of farmers selected, were proportional to the number of households of each PA. The selection was
made only from the highland and medium altitude of the study area. In Debeco, some parts of the kebeles
are low land area. This study did not include low land kebeles, so therelivant household population in this
Table 4.1. Sample PA’s, population and farm family head (FFH), (Number).
38
Peasant Population Family Sample
Association Male Female Total Head Farmers
Tsbelat 4466 4254 8720 2138 41
Gerelie 2912 2720 5632 1233 25
Hamusit 3770 3711 7481 1434 27
Debeco 3139 3188 6327 886 17
Total 14287 13873 28160 5691 110
Source: Wereda Office of Agriculture (1999)
The relevant data in this study have been collected from both primary and secondary source. Primary data
were obtained from 110 randomly selected farmers. Towards this end, a structured questionnaire was
Enumerators were recruited from the study area. The enumerators were composed of diploma holders and
extension agents who completed high school and had additional training on agricultural field. The
enumerators were selected based on their active participation in their assignment, and knowledge of the
study area. Moreover, adequate farm visits, direct observations and informal interviews were undertaken
both by the researcher and the enumerators. The secondary data were collected from studies conducted by
various researchers and information documented at various levels of Ministry of Agriculture, Planning and
Economic Development Offices, NGOs, Serinka Research Center, and other relevant institutions found in
Primary data were collected pertaining to crop and livestock activities in the study area. The production,
39
selling, purchasing, financing, and consumption of each type of crop and livestock activity was considered
for the study. The required information was based on the actual farming practices of the sample farmers.
Data were also collected on demographic variables; crop and livestock activities that are considered in
production process; the amount of input required per unit of activity; the prevailing market price for each
input and output; resources (land, labor, and capital) available on the farm for production purpose; family
income and expenditure of sample farmers; food consumption (crops and livestock products) availability
and requirement of farmers; type of activities performed by family labor particularly women and duration
of the activities; and problems encountered in crop and livestock farming and their possible solution.
Empirical evidences are important to identify distinct farming groups that exist because of the
In this regard, statistical tests are required to check whether observable samples are likely to have come
from the same population, i.e., to know whether the sample differences occuring are statistically
significant or not. Accordingly, mean, standard deviation, analysis of variance (ANOVA), t-statistic and
One-way analysis of variance was used to test the hypothesis that means variables (indicators) of
farming system are equal in order to test whether or not samples are from a common population.
Moreover, t-test was used to test the hypothesis that whether samples could likely be taken from the
same population or not when dealing with only two sample means. For such two groups, test of
40
homogeneity of variance was also applied to test sample variances for their significant differences.
There is a variation among family households with regard to their economic, land holding and other
important variables. Categorizing smallholder farmers based on important variables provide relevant
information for decisions regarding improvement of their income and employment opportunities. A
compromise strategy in an empirical research is to select variables with high discriminating power and to
omit highly correlated variables as suggested by purpose of the research and the researcher`(s) intuition
(Omiti, 1995). Also, Omiti in his study of crop-livestock integration in Ethiopian highlands stated that
within any farming system, households differ in family size and resource endowments and they often face
different constraints and welfare enhancing opportunities. He further indicated that households with similar
resource endowments and similar enterprise combinations may experience similar socio-economic and
institutional constraints and bear similar development needs which require similar technical and policy
intervention.
Information about the differences between households would enable allocation of research and extension
resources through co-ordinated interventions according to household groups, technology and policy
packages. Without proper categorization of households and prioritization of farmers` problems, valuable
resources may be wasted on developing short term solutions to problems of unidentified clientele (Smith,
1994).
The decision how to classify depends on the need for analysis, and distinguished for their own study
41
between systems of low income and higher incomes although these have similar activities (Shanner et al,
1982). For instance, production and marketing variables have been applied to categorize households in
Niger (Williams, 1994). Omiti had used household size, size of individual crop land, irrigated and pasture
land, number of working oxen, cows, sheep and donkeys and distance from the road and other economic
variables to categorize farmers as crop farmers, livestock farmers, or crop-livestock farmers in Ethiopian
highlands. Moreover, Bezabih (1991) classified farming systems of Hararghe highlands of Ethiopia based
on (1) land-labor ratio; (2) share of major crops in the cultivated area; (3) cropping intensities; (4)
livestock units; (5) market orientation; (6) off-farm employment. Hassen (1999) used family size, total
crop land per man equivalent, meher and belg crop produce, livestock unit, improved seed use, fertilizer
use, large cereal crops, and per cent share of cash crops to classify farming systems in South Wollo zone of
In this study, variables considered for the classification of farms were: Land-labor ratio, Total Live stock
Units, Number of oxen, Fertilizer use, Average family size and Crop production. Average values of
indicators considered for testing the differences between the two groups, are presented in table 4.2
Table 4.2 Average value indicators used in the study for classification of the farmers.
42
3 Tropical livestock unit Number 7.41 3.2
4 Fertilizer use Birr 284.36 60.7
5 Average Family size Number 6.60 5.13
6 Crop production Kg 2060 720
HIG: High income group, LIG: Low income group, ME: man equivalent
Stratification was done to identify factors that contribute for variation among groups of farmers in the two
farm groups. Selecting the most important variables that differentiate one set of observation from another
was considered. After selecting major variables that will discriminate most each farm into a homogeneous
For such purpose, cluster analysis was applied to obtain a relatively similar group of farms. The objectives
of cluster analysis is to group the observations into clusters so that each cluster is as homogeneous as
possible with respect to the cluster variable (Sharma, 1996). Clustering aims to allocate a set of individuals
to a set of mutually exclusive, groups such that individuals with in a group are similar to one another while
the individual in different groups are dissimilar. In cluster analysis several methods are available for
stratification of observation and all these methods perform the same task. Of all these methods, non-
In non-hierarchical clustering, the data are divided into K portions or groups with each portion representing
a cluster. Therefore, as opposed to hierarchical clustering, the number of clusters must be known a priori.
In non-hierarchical clustering, the observations are assigned to the cluster to which they are the closest.
Consequently, one has to know a priori the number of clusters present in the data set. Non-hierarchical
clustering techniques also present the user with a number of different algorithms that differ mainly with
43
respect to how the initial centers are obtained and how the observations are allocated among clusters. This
involves several algorithms which are differed mainly with respect to how distance between two clusters
are computed. It involves examining the data several times to estimate the cluster centers and to separate
the cases well. If the clusters centers are not known prior to classification, k-means cluster analysis is an
important non-hierarchical clustering method (Norusis,1992). It involves examining the data several times
to estimate the cluster centers and to separate the cases well. After several iteration process, K-means
cluster analysis yields various information regarding clusters for the selected variables, such as F-test, t-test
Based on the survey result and statistical output (table 4.3), the 110 household members were grouped into
two. Group I denoted as High Income Group(HIG), consisting of 28 households and group II denoted as
Table 4.3 Final Cluster Centers, F-value and t-value for the major selected variable for two groups:-
The values of the variables used to characterize the group differences are statistically significant at 5 per
cent level of significance, suggesting the existence of overall difference as a means of the indicators
between the groups. From this we conclude that within each group, there is variation among households in
terms of resource endowment, production practices and resource constraint and in development
opportunities.
High Income Group is characterized with high crop produce, higher livestock holding, higher family size,
higher own-cultivated crop land per man-equivalent, high fertilizer use, high oxen number and hence
comparatively high income. This group mostly share-in land and hire labor for herding of livestock
whenever they have labor shortage. Low Income Group represents relatively the lower strata which is
characterized by lower own-crop cultivated area per man-equivalent, lower input use, lower crop produce,
and lower livestock holding, low fertilizer use, low oxen number and hence comparatively getting low
income. This group hire-out their family labor and some of them share-out their land but some of them
The objective of the model is to maximize the individual farmer's income from his farm operation
without exceeding any of the physical limits he faces. Therefore, LP model was formulated to determine
the optimum resource allocation for a specified number of farm activities (Reddy, 1999). The figures
used were derived by taking into account the normal conditions of production and consumption patterns,
45
and resource performance, as indicated by the farmers. Input and output prices used were averages for
the survey year (1999/00), obtained from concerned institutions (DOA) and respondent farmers. For
local seeds, sowing period prices were used, and for improved seeds prices were obtained from the
DOA. Similarly, average yields were used with some adjustments for outliers.
The assumption of normality was considered as the LP technique used in this study is deterministic and
cannot account for unfavorable climatic conditions or any other disasters which adversely affect the
actual outcome of the farm activities in a specific year.
The model was specified in terms of its objective function, activities and constraints.
Subject to
46
where
Z = Gross margin
In developing optimization models for small farmers, objective is of paramount importance. Among the
several objectives that of a) securing adequate and assured food supply b) earning a cash income to meet
other material needs c) avoidance of risk (survival in uncertain environment) and d) provision for the
future, are important in many studies. The objective function is the gross margin which is to be maximized
subject to resource limitations with the non-negativity value of the activities to be considered after
satisfying family consumption requirements. In analyzing the optimal farm plan, conclusion will be drawn
based on the type of relationship existing among farm activities as complements, supplements, and
competitive. The objective function represents the monetary value of all the activities to be considered.
Farmers are operating in dry land agriculture under risk and uncertainty situations. Nevertheless, finding
47
historical data to capture risk in the farm model is a limitation. Hence the objective function also provides
economic plausibility of the optimal farm plan through conducting sensitivity analysis for changes in price
and yield of selected major resources and levels of crop and livestock enterprises.
The objective function is to maximize gross margin subject to minimum food requirement to ensure the
small farmers against constraints including land, labor, draft power and working capital. Gross margin
was calculated by deducting the total variable cost incurred by farmers from gross farm income realized
(from crop, livestock, trees and non-farm income), and all items included in the objective function
represent monetary value. The average open market price was used for monetizing the activities.
Although large varieties of crops and livestock enterprises are managed by farmers in the study area, a
representative farm will be considered, i.e. for the optimization purpose an attempt will be made to reduce
the number of these activities . In this process, the popularity of the activities expressed by the number of
growers will be considered. The actual farming practice served as an indicator to determine the major
farming activity. The activities could broadly be grouped into production, selling, purchasing and
consumption activities. The production activities include both crop and livestock cultivated on a
representative farm. The marketing activities include both disposition of agricultural produce (sale) and
acquisition of products which are required by the farm but not available on the farm. Credit activities
consist of working capital supplemented by borrowing for the farm due to non-availability of cash from
family’s own saving. The consumption activity takes in to account family subsistence requirement.
Annual crops such as cereals (wheat, teff, barley, wassera) and pulses (horse bean, field peas, lentil,
48
grass pea) are the predominant form of crop production in the main meher rain-fed cultivation and these
are the major crops included in the model. The cropping system in the study area is characterized by
tremendous diversity where sole-cropping is a common practice and the productivity of different crops
varies based on their variety, agro-ecological condition and technology used. Fallowing is practiced in
the area, thus its contribution to the objective function was also considered in the model. The farmers
are using improved variety of crops especially wheat in their farming practice, thus improved and local
seed productivity were considered together in the model. The impact of crop and livestock production
practices on the gross farm income of existing as well as alternative plan was analyzed.
Eucalyptus tree is one of the farmers` source of income and fuel wood in the study area. This was
included in the model as one of the activities. The method of income estimation used was, the actual
time required to reach for sale which has been estimated from the survey. Based on the information,
annual income was calculated by dividing total income by the number of years required for sale.
Actually, the amount of cash obtained from the interview of the sample farmers for the year of study
was greater than the estimated average amount, but for the formulation of the model, the minimum
Livestock production is another major production activity in the mixed farming system. Mixed crop-
livestock farming system is a risk diversification strategy whereby livestock provides an important
investment opportunity and stabilizes food availability in poor crop production years (Fernandez-Rivera
et al, 1993). Thus, to meet their multi-objective goals, farmers allocate their resources and management
49
skills to crops and livestock production. In the determination of the animal activities, their dependence
on cultivated area, particularly for feed has been given major emphasis. This is because the basic
objective of optimization model is the determination of a balanced farm organization which yields
maximum return from limited land and other inputs. Under the traditional land use system, animals
graze on pasture and crop residues. Crop residues are used for animal feed during shortage of pasture
and plowing time. Purchasing feeds for animals is not considered as an activity in this study because it
was not practiced by most of the sample farmers. There is no well-managed pasture production in the
study area. However, farmers in the study area are protecting certain pieces of their land for grass hay
production as well as some of the communal grazing land during the main rainy season for use at times
of feed shortages. Grazing pasture and grass hay are separate activities and they share mostly common
land.
The livestock components considered in the models were pairs of oxen, cows, sheep, goats, horses,
donkeys, bee-hives, and poultry keeping. The outputs of livestock production considered in the model
were milk, butter, egg, honey, draft power, manure as fuel and live animals.
The optimization model consider the smallholders` integration with marketing activity. As indicated
earlier, the main objectives of smallholder farmers of Ethiopian highlands are to produce food for their
families and to acquire farm income from sales of any surplus produce to purchase consumable items
and farm inputs (Getachew et al, 1991). Most farmers in the study area, give priority to the production
of food crops to meet household requirements and there after to the sale of surpluse produce. However,
50
in case of food deficit, the gap is met by selling animals, particularly small ruminants and chicken. The
model is built similarly to farmers` objective in such a way that crops needed for consumption are sold
after fulfilling the subsistence requirements. Regarding the purchase and selling prices, local free market
Subsistence objective is viewed as insurance against the risk of being unable to satisfy the demand for
food, to meet the diet requirements of family members, and having to pay relatively higher prices
(Niang, 1980). Thus, including this activity ensures smallholders to produce some portion of their
requirements; while purchasing serves to fulfill part of subsistence requirements from market. The
consumption requirement per adult equivalent (AE) per year is determined based on Gryseels and
Anderson (1983). The requirement is 200 kg of cereals, 50 kg of pulses, 30 litres of milk, and 500 kg of
fuel. Household preference for each crop type is determined according to production pattern. That is the
quantity of each crop grain type demanded is calculated by multiplying its percentage share in the total
production of cereal/pulses by the amount of total cereals/pulse grain required. The consumption of
cereals, pulses and milk were incorporated into the model as an activity which should be on the basis of
an amount assuring self-sufficiency regardless of the objective value. Farmers are supposed to consume
These activities help to transfer one activity of the model to another activity. It is rendering of one
activity for accomplishment of the other activity. These activities are also important to replace the culled
51
4.6.3. The Constraints
Major constraints identified in the farming systems of the study area are land, draft oxen, working
capital and human labor. The level of these resources acts as a constraint to optimize the feasible
planning. In addition to these resource constraints, there are other restrictions specified under different
(a) Land
Land constraint is the main discriminating variable among farm households. Thus, as a farm input,
farmland has its effect on the type of crops cultivated and acreage allocated to each crop. The
operational land size used for crop and livestock activities was considered as land constraint. For each
farming system, the total available land size per household was considered in the model. Because of
population growth and traditional technology of production, the practice of leaving the land as fallow is
The total land area required for food crop production and fallow is constrained to be less than or equal to
the area of owned and shared land in arable land holding. The total amount of land area that is used for
grazing as well as hay production is also considered to be less than or equal to the area of land allocated
∑ aij x j ≤ OL
∑ aij x j ≤ SL
∑ apj x j ≤ OP
∑ aej x j ≤ EL
Where OL, SL, OP and EL is amount of owned and shared arable land, owned pasture land and Eucalyptus
52
Tree land-holding respectively;
aej is the area of Eucalyptus land required for Eucalyptus production; and
apj is the area of pasture land required for grazing or grass hay preparation.
The major source of labor in traditional agriculture is family labor. Family labor (those who are able to
participate in farming and other activities) availability was measured in man-equivalents and was
expressed in man-hours. On the other hand, labor requirements for cropping operations were specified
for four labor periods. These labor periods are (i) February to May (LP1), (ii) June to August 20 (LP2),
(iii) August 21 to October (LP3), and (iv) November to January (LP4). Conversion of family members
In the traditional livestock management system, herding needs more labor than any other livestock-
related activities. Local animals graze mostly on native pasture, fallow lands, and stubble for eight to
twelve hours per day and some supplementary hay and weeds are given (Getachew et al., 1991).
Herding is accomplished by children who do not often participate in cropping activities. In addition,
most of the livestock activities other than herding such as milking, barn cleaning, calf-feeding and so on
are performed by women who are not mainly participating in cropping activities. Thus, this portion of
labor and labor for herding do not compete with labor force for cropping activities and are taken to be
human labor supply for livestock activity based on survey results. The total amount of human labor
required per unit of productive activities in a given labor period is constrained to an amount less than or
equal to the available family labor plus hired labor in the particular labor period i.e.
53
∑atj --ht xj* ≤ Lt
htxj* ≤ At
Where Lt, At are available family and hired labor in the t-th period, respectively;
ht = amount of hired labor required in the t-th period for j* -th activity; and
atj = amount of labor required in the t-th period for j-th activity.
Because cropping operations such as land preparation and planting (sowing) are almost exclusively
done by oxen, draft oxen, is taken as one of the major constraints in the farming system. Like human
labor constraint, draft oxen constraint was considered for different periods. Plowing activity though
done throughout the year, is critical in two crucial periods.Accordingly, only these two crucial periods
were considered in the model: (i)February to May (OX1) and (ii) June to August 20 (OX2).
Oxen power required for t* -th activity in the i* -th month(s) wtj should not exceed oxen power available wt
∑wtj x j - wt xj ≤ 0
Where, wt = amount of power available per pair of oxen in the t-th period. and
wtj = amount of power required per pair of oxen in the j-th period.
Cash is needed to meet expenses for short-term inputs and other expenses on the farm. Besides this,
cash is required to purchase food items other than food grains and clothing, aswell as to meet payments
for land use taxes, hired labor and social services. Farmers keep their saving in the form of livestock
such as cattle, sheep, goats, donkeys and so on. These animals can be sold and readily converted into
54
operating or working capital as needs arise. Although traditional production techniques do not allow the
use of more capital, as new technologies are introduced, farmers learn to develop the capacity to use
more capital (Sisay, 1983). Farm plus non-farm income, net of these expenses will provide cash
available that can be spent on farm activities. In this study, capital was imposed in the LP model to meet
Household total expenditure for the j-th activity is constrained to be less than or equal to the sum of
available cash income from crop, livestock, tree sale, borrowed, and off-farm activity.
∑Kij x j ≤ wk
kij = amount of working capital required for production and non-production activities.
(e) Livestock
In the study area, livestock constitute an important component of the farming system. The available
livestock number is taken to be the maximum level on the right-hand-side of the basic matrix table.
Oxen are bounded at a minimum level of one pair of oxen, and cows are bounded at a maximum holding
level. Horses/mules, and the donkeys are required by the farmer for transporting harvested crops to
threshing areas, grains to the storage, markets, and to milling places and purchased materials back to home;
so horses and donkeys are allowed to enter the optimum solution at their present average holding levels.
hij x j ≤ or ≥Ai
55
4.6.4. Other Restrictions
Although the primary aim of farmers in the study area is to meet household food consumption needs,
some surplus may be sold, if any. However, sometimes purchasing may take place to fill the gap that has
The annual milk balance indicating the quantity of milk that is available in cow-calf activity should be
matched with the quantity consumed and/or transferred into butter. Mathematically, it can be expressed
as follows:
56
(iii) Butter Balance
The annual butter balance row is used to balance the quantity of butter produced and sold.
ΣXbp -ΣXbs ≥ 0
Grazing or hay from natural pasture grasslands and stubble are important basal feeds for livestock.
Animals are also supplemented by hay and weeds. Thus, animal feed production (crop by-product and
pasture) activities and the demand for these should be balanced, and at least minimum quantity of
animal feed has to be provided from crop by-product and pasture land available. The general form of the
constraint is:
ΣXc ≥ Xcm
ΣXp ≥ Xpm
Where Xc and Xp are the Kg dry matter feed of crop by-product c and pasture p for livestock
consumption, respectively. Xcm and Xpm represent the minimum Kg dry matter requirement from crop
The minimum subsistence requirements are met either from own-harvest or outside sources (markets).
This constraint places a minimum crop and animal product requirement for subsistence. However, the
57
task of getting a true estimate of food crops consumed by peasant farmers is difficult (Sisay, 1983). In
this study minimum requirement for an adult equivalent (AE) was calculated based on the daily
requirement of 2100 calories as used by Niang (1980) by converting family members into adult
equivalent(AE). Furthermore, in estimating the quantity of each crop to be consumed by an AE, the
percentage of area allocated for a particular crop and its yield per hectare was also considered as farmers
in the study area produce a wide variety of crops. The constraint is mathematically stated as follows:
ΣYjiXj ≥ Sj
Where: Yji= yield per unit of the crop or livestock product j in the ith activity;
Xj= the level of activity in which crop or livestock product j appears in the year; and
Sj= the minimum amount of crop or livestock product j required for subsistence
Transfer rows help in this LP model to transfer one activity of the model to another. These rows also
help us to dispose the culled animals and surplus young animals through sales. In addition, replacement
of different categories of animals would be taking place through reproduction. The model was
developed on the assumption that the animals which are in excess of net replacement could be sold and
the net sales should not exceed net supply of the animals (Bezabih, 1991), and this can be expressed
mathematically as:
Where rij = number of replaced animal i required or culled animal i supplied for j-th activity; and
rij *= number of replacing animal i supplied or culled animal i disposed for j*-th activity
58
4.6.5. Estimation of Technical Coefficients
The most difficult task in setting up a LP problem is to obtain meaningful input-output coefficients. This
difficulty specially arises in the area where there is no farm records, previous results, and technical
studies on production relations as sources of adequate information on per unit resource requirements
and yields of different farm activities. Based on the information obtained on the husbandry of each crop
and livestock activity, the appropriate input-output coefficients could be estimated. However, estimation
of the technical coefficients is a problematic task for the smallholder sector as there are no farm records
and data generation heavily depends on memory and understandings of farmers and the technical
advisors working in the area. Some results from trials and previous studies were also inferred where
available. Hence much effort is required to obtain meaningful coefficients so as to set-up a realistic
model as far as possible. In this work, the required data obtained from the field survey and the secondary
sources on input-output relationships for crop and livestock were used in the empirical LP model.
The input coefficient refers to the number of units of each of the resources required to produce one unit
of activity. Accordingly, the average cropped area and the average labor available were calculated for
each group after converting female and child labor into their respective man-equivalents (Appendix 2).
The available oxen power was also computed on pair basis for the crucial two working seasons. For the
borrowed capital an average repayment period of nine months and an annual interest rate of 12.5 per
cent was assumed. The per hectare yields of annual crops (Table 6.9), and the per head products of
livestock were determined based on the survey and results of previous studies. The straw yield of crops
is calculated using the grain yield to straw ratio norm (Table 6.9). For milk production, a calving
interval of two years with about 410 litters of milk per lactation was taken. To get annual milk yield, the
lactation total yield is divided by calving interval and then multiplied by 365 (Gryseels 1988).
59
Furthermore, a cow and an ox is assumed to economically serve for ten years. Hence, the replacement
rates would be 0.1 per cow and per ox Gryseels(1988). The livestock feed supply comes from limited
communal grazing land and crop by-products. The requirement is determined as 2.5 per cent of the
average live-weight of the animals (Gryseels and Anderson 1983). The livestock labor requirements are
for herding, feeding, milking and barn-cleaning. The total labor requirement was first estimated for the
herd, and divided by the type and number of livestock owned with some provision for cows and oxen.
Minimum subsistence requirements were estimated based on the minimum calorie needs of the average
family (2100 calorie per day per adult equivalent (CSA 1997)). The estimated subsistence food
The calculation of input-output coefficients for livestock activity was made by computing feed
requirements and output of a given animal. In addition, the weight of the animal, feed requirement,
mortality and culling rate, economic life, and so on were considered in the specification of input-output
coefficient for different categories of livestock types. The annual egg produced per hen and honey
produced per beehive is entered with the quantity sold with its gross margin. For horse and donkey
keeping the average annual gross margin per head was considered in the model. Average values were
computed for inputs (seed, human labor, ox labor and working capital), yields and gross margins
60
5. DESCRIPTION OF THE FARMING SYSTEMS IN THE STUDY AREA
The existing farming situation of the study area was analyzed in terms of resource endowments, production
pattern, resource-use productivity, and farm income. The basic farm resources that are used in the
production process include: land, family labor, oxen power and working capital. The overall capacities of
these resources vary for each group. The basic aim of this chapter is to assess and evaluate the current
performance of average farming activities in the area. Therefore, these analytical results are the basis on
The sampled household heads were mainly men and members of a family are those persons related to the
head and working on the farm. The average number of the household members was found to be 6.6 for
high income group and 5.13 for low income group. (Table 5.1)
Table 5. 1 Distribution of average family members by age group sample farmers, 1999/00
Table 5.1 brings out that 59 per cent of the population in both groups are dependent on the remaining 41
61
per cent of the population. Out of the dependent population 21 per cent of HIG and 29 per cent of LIG are
children who will not participate in the farming system, youths and elders will help the family members in
some activities such as herding and house-keeping. The table further highlights that the average family size
of HIG was bigger than LIG. This is because when the resource endowment is high people prefer to have
larger families.
Each of the household members is converted into man-equivalent (ME) based on the working capacity
weight given to each age and sex group of the household members as shown in table 5.2. The ME is the
standardized figure in relation to the working capacity of an adult man. It represents the potential labor
Table 5.2 Family size and the labor force of sampled respondents, 1999/00
10 per cent of their total working time for unknown forced reasons, such as funeral occasions, sickness of
parents etc. Adult equivalent (AE) of each of the family members was determined by using the conversion
62
factor. (Appendix 2)
Table 5.2 shows that on an average there were 5.83 (3.39 males and 2.44 females) AEs per household
for high-income group, 4.43 (2.43 males and 2.0 females) AEs for low-income group and an average of
4.78 (2.67 males and 2.11 females) AEs for the overall sample. The AE compared with the man
equivalent (ME) helps to determine the extent to which some members of the family depend on the
working group.The labor force for different activities inclusive of farming, in terms of man-equivalent
(ME) was found to be 2.97 ME for average, 3.75 ME for High-income group and 2.69 ME for Low-
Apart from household head, other family members also work on the farm and outside the farm.
Commonly, farm work is shared by husband, wife, sons and/or daughters. In fact, the average ME
allocated to farm work is greater for males (2.35 ME for high income group, 1.57 ME for low income
group and an average of 1.77) than for females (1.4 ME for high income group, 1.12 ME for low income
The difference might be due to the participation of women in various activities other than farming such
as child-care, cooking, cleaning, fetching water, collecting firewood and dung, and trade/marketing,
livestock related activities and so on. However, women are actively involved in cropping activities
during peak working seasons, particularly in time of sowing, weeding and harvesting. On the other
hand, adult men are responsible for almost all farm operations although their participation in household
activities is limited. Youths and children under the age of fifteen also have responsibilities in farm
activities including herding animals and caring for small children in the household. Although the nature
63
of work done by children varies with age and gender of the child, the work performed by children often
represents a substitution of their time for that of their parents (Singh, 1988). This is true especially in
household activities.
One can clearly see from table 5.3 that the allocation of available labor force for farming in both areas is
generally smaller than the potential (available) labor supply. That is, only 64 per cent, 57 per cent, and
60 per cent of the total potential labor force is allocated for farming in high-income, low-income, and
overall income respectively. The remaining labor force, is used for activities such as animal husbandry,
In addition to the available family labor force, labor force for farming also depends on the number of
working days per month and the time (hours) spent on farm per working day. To this end, peak and
slack months are identified based on the frequency the respondents have already indicated with
reference to the particular month of the said seasons (as peak or slack). In this regard, May to November
are found to be peak months. The rest of the months are regarded as slack months for farming activities.
In order to calculate the number of days in a month in which farmers engage themselves in farming
activities, religious days, Saturdays and Sundays (during which farmers do not work on their farms) are
Overall
HIG LIG
64
Lab. Lab. Lab. Lab. Lab. Lab. Lab. Lab. Lab. Lab. Lab. Lab.
1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4 1 2 3 4
Total days 120 81 72 91 120 81 72 91 120 81 72 91
Working day 59 39 34 47 59 39 34 47 59 39 34 47
Available (ME) 3.75 3.75 3.75 3.75 2.69 2.69 2.69 2.69 2.96 2.96 2.96 2.96
Available working
hour per day 6 8 8 7.3 6 8 8 7.3 6 8 8 7.3
Total lab. hrs (per
quarter) (SS) 1328 1170 1020 1290 952 856 731 925 1048 924 805 101
8
Lab. usage(DD) 772 632 797 932 439 416 453 627 501 496 550 720
Crop 530 469 652 601 197 253 308 296 260 333 405 390
Livestock 242 163 145 331 242 163 145 331 242 163 145 331
Per cent labor =ΣDD//ΣSSx100 64 57 60
usage
The total available labor is found by multiplying total working hour with ME of each group (3.75 and 2.69 for HIG and LIG
respectively), SS: Supply, DD demand.
The educational status of the sampled household heads is shown in table 5.4. The high-income group
household heads in the study area have relatively better level of education than the household heads of
the low-income group. 39 per cent of the high-income group heads can read and write, and 47 per cent of
them attended school education. Out of them 4 per cent attended high school education. However, 14
per cent, 21 per cent and 19 per cent for high-income group, low-income group and an overall,
respectively of the farmer households are illiterate. On the other hand, in case of low income group, 47
per cent are literate (can read and write) and about 32 per cent have attended school education. In Table
5.5, educational background of all members in each household is, also, computed to assess the
educational level of the members of sample households. Here, it is assumed that children usually go to
65
school at the age of seven and above.
Table 5.4 Educational Status of the sampled household heads 1999/00 (Number and percentage)
Table 5. 5. Educational status of the sampled household members (Number and Percentage)
from the table that, 65 per cent of high-income group and 67 per cent of low-income group with an
average of 66 per cent of the farmer household members are illiterate. Similarly, only 15 per cent of high
income group, 16 per cent of low income group with an average of 16 per cent can read and write. And 20
per cent of high income group 17 per cent of low income group with an average of 18 per cent have
66
attended school education, out of whom an average of 1 per cent attended high school education.
Land is the most important and scarce resource contributing to agricultural production in the study area,
and since land use pattern largely determines the pattern of use of other resources, it is taken as a proxy for
Land shortage is acute in the study area due to topography settings (mountainous and hill side), population
pressure and infertility problems. Nearly one hectare of farming area is expected to sustain about seven
household members. So land is the main constraint of efficient farm production as well as of providing
adequate living conditions for the households in North Wollo zone as a whole
Table 5. 6. Average land use and cropping pattern, sample households, 1999/00.
67
Wheat per cent 40 34 36
Teff ,, 14 24 20
Barley ,, 16 16 16
Wassera ,, 8 7 7
Horse beans ,, 8 9 9
Field peas ,, 2 6 5
Lentil ,, 9 3 5
Grass pea ,, 3 1 2
Crop pattern for Share in area
Wheat ,, 29 25 26
Teff ,, 15 21 19
Barley ,, 11 6 7
Wassera ,, 12 12 12
Horse beans ,, 14 18 17
Field peas ,, 5 3 4
Lentil ,, 5 3 4
Grass pea ,, 9 12 11
The crop pattern included in the table contains only the major crops There are some other crops which
were not included in the table such as linseed, potato, onions and permanent trees like gesho, bamboo trees
etc.
There are two cropping seasons in North Wollo zone, the same is true for Meket wereda. However, the
four kebeles selected for the study are only meher producing kebeles. The major crops grown in the areas
are wheat, barley, teff, wassera from cereals and horse bean, field peas, lentil and grass pea from legumes.
68
The current production patterns and their management practice are briefly discussed below.
Wheat
Wheat is the dominant crop in the wereda as well as in the study site. Now a days due to the introduction
of improved varieties seed and fertilizer, the area coverage and productivity of the crop has increased
significantly. The number of farmers making use of improved technology has increased over time. This
shows the acceptance of the technology in the surrounding area. Some farmers which participated in this
Teff
Teff is the next important crop especially in the medium altitude of the study area. For teff, the farmers
were not accepting the introduction of improved variety of seed with fertilizer input, as eagerly as that of
wheat, and are preferring to sow their own seed without fertilizer. There are farmers who sow their own
seed with fertilizer, however, their number is negligible and they complain about shoot fly pest problem.
This is because, the fertilized crop revegetate earlier than the non-fertilized one, there by creating favorable
condition for the multiplication of the shoot fly. Second-hand information obtained from the office of
Agriculture indicates that, even if the problem is present in the area, no effective measures have been
suggested to the farmers for the eradication of this pest because of non-availability of chemicals for its
Barley
This crop is the dominant crop next to wheat in the high land area of the study site. No improved seed were
introduced for adoption by the farmers, but, sowing of their local seed with fertilizer a common practice
69
and the productivity has increased up to two folds. However, the prevalence of a frost problem has
hindered further expansionof the crop. The surveyed farmers expressed the view that fertilized barley is
more easily exposed to frost problem than the non-fertilized one. This may be due to increase in its crop
stand. Some farmers told that they will not add even organic fertilizer such as manure and ash to their land
because of the frost problem. However, some farmers have added inorganic fertilizer regardless of the frost
problem in that year to get higher yield. The seriousness of frost problem varies from year to year.
Wassera
Wassera is a combination of wheat and barley which grow together and is a common practice in the study
area. The area coverage is as high as that of teff and barley. This cropping practice is also common in
North and South Wollo zone as a whole. The farmers were sowing the two crops together in order to
secure their crop stand; if one of the crops failed, the other may give better result. The crop is used for all
purposes that wheat and barley are used for and the preparation process for food is similar to that of wheat
and barley. Sowing of wassera with fertilizer is the most common practice and the benefit obtained is very
Legumes
Legumes sown in the study area predominantly are horse beans, field peas, lentil, grass peas and linseed
etc. These crops are grown mainly for rotational cropping and the farmers instead of fallowing, they sow
legume crops in order to get a good yield for their next cereal production.
Cropping legume by itself is not common because of low productivity per hectare, as well as disease and
pest problems. Some legumes such as horse beans and field peas have become non-productive so that the
70
area coverage of lentil and grass peas has been increasing from time to time. Root rotting is the common
disease problem reported, especially for horse beans in the study area.
The number of plots one farmer have vary from 3 to 5 with an average of 4 plots of his own-land and it
reaches up to 8 plots when share-in lands are incorporated in his farming system. This is because each
farmer wants equal share from the productive and less-productive lands. So in order to share these lands
equally the number of plots has increased. In addition to high number of plots, the types of crops that a
farmer grow are many in number. A farmer cultivates almost all types of crops in the area. This is because
he wants to diversify his cropping pattern in order to sustain himself and his family and since the area has
unstable climatic condition, if one crop fails the other will survive so that the farmer avoid risks.
As it was known, land is the property of government, a farmer can use it but he can not sall or buy land,
however, farmers share-in and share-out their land for the following different reasons:-
(1) Those farmers who have no plowing oxen, will share-out their land to those farmers who have oxen.
(2) Female-headed households and elderly farmers, who are unable to plow, usually share-out their land.
(3) Some farmers, with small land parcels, share-out their land and migrate to other area in search of daily
labor work.
(4) Farmers having oxen, high number of family labor and small share of land are those who share-in land.
The sharing agreement is, that those farmers who share-in the land will incur whole variable costs and
labor services and output is shared equally. However, there are some other alternative agreements made
between the farmers; i.e. the share-out farmer will help in labor service and product is shared according to
the agreement. As has been shown in table 5.6, the amount of share-in land is greater than share-out land
because the study site is covering the highlands and medium altitudes, where the land problem is more
71
serious in comparison to its surrounding low-land areas. So most of the share out land is found in the low
The farming systems of smallholders in North Wollo are predominantly annual crop productions,
following the similar cropping calendar for these crops, both in main rainy season (meher) or short rainy
season (belg). The common practices performed for these annual crops are plowing, sowing, weeding,
harvesting, and threshing. Preparation of plots usually starts in the beginning of March and most crops
are sown from June to August. However, because of crop variety and soil type, variations may appear in
crop calendar for particular crops. The most common practice is to plow the land twice and sow it on the
third round. For some cereal crops, farm lands are generally cultivated more than two times before
sowing. Particularly, teff requires fine soil structure and the land has to be cultivated many times before
sowing. However, this is quite dependent on the availability of draft animals. However, leguminous
crops are either sown in the first plow or sown in the second round. The next phase is the weeding
period which begins just few weeks after the completion of sowing period. Usually, for the majority of
crops it is roughly undertaken from the mid of August to the end of October. Most of the time, small
cereals are weeded only once, except teff and wheat which will be weeded at least two times and no
weeding is done for pulse crops except horse beans which may be weeded one time if necessary. This is
because of shortage of feed for the animals in the area. Farmers assume, after one weeding the crop will
dominate weeds in competition of nutrients and they prefer the amount of feed obtained from the field than
the amount of grain reduction due to weed problem. As soon as crops are harvested, threshing and
winnowing take place within a month or so. However, sometimes the harvested crops are kept un-
threshed in big piles for long periods of time due to shortage of time and storage facilities. Crop
72
calendar for major crops is indicated in table 5.7.
Table 5.7 The crop calendar for major crops in the study area.
The introduction of improved seed and fertilizer has started recently in the study area. Before the
introduction of new extension system that has been adopted from “Sassakawa global 2000” some amount
of seed and fertilizer was brought into the area by different NGOs and Government. However, it was not as
much successful because the farmers were not volunteer to use the fertilizer on their land based on the
wrong impression that it will burn their land. They either sold it to merchants at very low price or used it
(especially urea) for decoration of their houses as cement and at times dumped the fertilizer any where and
took the sack for home use. Nowadays, awearness of improved seed and fertilizer has increased and some
farmers are not sowing with-out fertilizer.The amount of seeds and fertilizers used depend on the crop and
soil type of the area. The average amounts of local seed, fertilizer and improved seed used by the farmers
Table 5.8 Average seed and fertilizer rate per hectare used by the farmers in the study area, 1999/00
73
Crop type Component Type of Amount(kg)
fertilizer(s)
The productivity of crop for both grain as well as straw is varied based on crop type and method of farming
practice. Those farmers who used improved seed and fertilizer get two or three times more relative to non-
users.
Table 5.9 Average production of grain and straw per hectar under normal and improved practices,
1999/00
Local seed Improved seed
Particular Unit Local seed with fertilizer with fertilizer
Grain straw Grain straw Grain straw
Wheat kg/ha. 900 1200 1800 2400 2200 2950
Teff ,, 600 900 1000 1500
74
Barley ,, 700 1050 1400 2100
Wassera ,, 800 1250 1500 2250
Horse beans ,, 650 875
Field peas ,, 500 650
Lentil ,, 700 850
Grass pea ,, 600 800
Source: Wereda Office of Agriculture and survey results.
The soil condition in North Wollo zone in general is highly eroded and its fertility level is very low.
Farmers rarely understand soil management practices. Anyhow, because of little or no production obtained
when they continuously plow the land, they are obliged to use crop rotation, fallowing, and/or applying of
inorganic fertilizer as soil management practices. In addition to these, some farmers were applying animal
Fallow
Fallowing is one of the oldest and most widely used soil fertility maintaining practice in the study area. The
farmers fallow their land mostly for an interval of 3 to 5 years. However, because of shortage of land they
sometimes practise continious cropping without fallow even though the productivity of the land decreased
to very low level. In the last few years the introduction of inorganic fertilizer has reduced the amount of
fallow land.
Crop rotation
Crop rotation is practiced by some farmers especially in the medium altitude of the study area. Crop
rotation was followed cereals (wheat, barley, wassera, teff) by legumes (horse bean, field peas, lentil,
linseed, and grass pea). These leguminous plants are mainly planted with the aim of maintaining soil
75
fertility. The farmer, instead of leaving land fallow, he plants legumes to get some additional product
Inorganic fertilizer.
Soil fertility becomes the main concern of the farmer as well as other concerned institutes working in the
field of agriculture. The importance and adoption of inorganic fertilizer has increased in the study area over
time, Those lands which were out of production because of soil fertility problem become productive with
the application of Inorganic fertilizer. Even if its sustainability was in question, generally it was yielding an
interesting result in increasing the productivity of crops. The high-income group use more fertilizer than
low-income group because of endowment with a longer land holding and a higher working capital capacity
Animal manure
Animal dung is mainly used for fuel purpose rather than as manure. This is because of firewood shortage
in the study area. However, during the rainy season it is difficult to dry and accumulate it until the next dry
season reappear. So farmers distribute the dung on their field, especially in homestead, in order to increase
As, it was mentioned in the description of the study area that every year a lot of soil conservation work was
performed. This conservation practice even if its contribution is not as expected, because of disturbance of
the settled terraces by the farmers in need of fallowed soil, it conserves the soil and helps in maintaining
soil fertility.
76
5.3.8. Crop production problems
The crop production problems is a serious problem in the study area. The seriousness of the problem has
been measured by the proportion of the respondents confronted to the problem. Some of the problems were
integrated into the optimization model in order to see the extent to which the problems are limiting. Some
of the major problems of crop production include weather fluctuation, disease and pest problem, land
shortage and soil fertility problems. In addition to these high input cost, pesticide shortage and weed were
affecting to a less extent. As shown in table 5.10. in their assending order, the extent of problems in both
groups is similar with some differences
The problems of weather fluctuation, small land size and pest infestation were given in similar ranks by
respondents interviwed in both groups of farms which shows the seriousness of these three problems in the
study area, whereas market and labor shortage problems are viewed as less serious occupying relatively
77
5.4.1. Contribution of livestock to the farming system.
Livestock production has a major role in traditional mixed farming system, especially in areas where the
crop production is not sustainable. The livestock sector used as a transitional means to continue the
livelihood of the farmers. The primary objectives of keeping livestock are to get milk and meat for
As a result of increasing the shortage of the grazing land, it was reported that the number of livestock in the
study area has been decreasing over the years. However, the number of livestock is beyond the carrying
capacity of the grazing land. The main sources of feed are crop residues and limited private and communal
grazing areas.
The number of livestock differ from individual to individual. The high-income group has a relatively larger
number of livestock than the low-income group. This is because of the higher size of their private grazing
Table 5.11 Livestock population maintained per the sample holdings, 1999/00
HIG LIG Overall.
Type of livestock. No. TLU No. TLU No. TLU
Cow 1.00 1.00 0.50 0.50 0.60 0.60
Ox 1.93 1.93 0.83 0.83 1.11 1.11
Cow follower 0.50 0.30 0.32 0.20 0.37 0.22
Sheep 3.00 0.39 2.00 0.26 2.30 0.30
Sheep follower 0.84 0.05 0.50 0.07 0.59 0.04
Goat 1.36 0.18 0.30 0.02 0.57 0.07
Goat follower 0.38 0.06 0.12 0.01 0.21 0.01
Donkey 1.32 0.46 0.30 0.10 0.56 0.23
Horse 0.79 0.87 0.20 0.22 0.35 0.39
Poultry 3.00 0.04 1.67 0.02 2.00 0.03
Beehive 0.36 0.20 0.24
Total 4.82 2.23 3.0
78
Cattle
Cattle are kept for drought power, milk, meat and manure for fuel. High number of cattle with a farmer
shows a high economic status. The productivity of the animal is not considered, only the number is given
much importance. So the farmers are keeping their cattle even if they are non productive which aggravated
the shortage of feed in the area. Cattle are used as a form of saving and/or investment, so that they serve as
The number of sheep per household is greater than other number of livestock in the study area. Small
ruminants are kept because they reproduce themselves within a short period of time. Thus, they are used as
a means of cash income whenever the farmers are in need of money. Sheep are more adaptable than goats
in the study area. This is because of climatic condition and the absence of browsing plants. Sheep and
goats are the main source of meat during religious festivals and on occassions when some respectable
guests are recived However, even if the number of sheep and goat slaughtered per year differs according to
the economic status of the farmer, the average number is not more than two heads per year. Sheep wool is
used in making carpets and as a means of generating cash income through sale to carpet-makers for
commercial purpose. Farmers shear their sheep once or twice a year in the month of October and March.
Equines
Draft animals are kept for transportation and draught purposes. Donkeys, horses and mules play an
important role in transportation of both people and goods as well as in plowing activity. Plowing with
equines is common in the study area. Equines are used either alone for draught or jointl with an ox.
79
Equines need a guiding person during their plowing time, especially when they are used to plow without an
ox. The amount of land plowed per day with equines is larger than the amount of land plowed per oxen
alone. Equines perform better in second and third plowing than first plow but ox performs better than them
in the first plow. They are important in transportation of goods markets, from low-price areas to high-price
area and they transport farmers whenever they want to travel far. Farmers also hire-out their horses and
mules to other persons and tourists in return for a cash income. More than 90 per cent of the people in the
study area use equines as a means of transportation due to limited availability of modern transport in the
area and the inablity of the farmers to pay for the higher transport cost becouse of their low income status.
Moreover, horses and mules are used as in burial or funeral ceremonies particularly on the occation of the
Poultry
Chickens are kept mainly for production of eggs and reproduction of themselves as a means of cash
income and source of meat. The number of chicken per household is higher for high-income group than for
low-income group. Traditionally chicken are left to scavenge their feed from the surrounding area.
However, nowadays some improved breeds of poultry were distributed to the farmers so that the farmers
Bee keeping.
Despite the spercity of flowering plants and forest coverage, bee-keeping is an important activity in the
study area. Bees are mainly used as a source of income by selling honey. Most of the beehives are locally
prepared from mud and wood products. However, at the present time a Kenyan top-bar beehive is
introduced to the area by the NGO called SOS Sahel and office of agriculture. The beehive is prepared
80
from local material of the surrounding area while the top-bar was prepared with a machine at any wood-
Livestock feed is mainly based on natural pasture and straw. Communal and private pasture lands are the
main sources of feed. However, straw obtained from own-land and share-land is also used as a
supplementary feed during dry period and at times of work. Straw is given mainly for oxen and lactating
cows. The total availability of feed is not enough, so the farmers mostly graze their animals during the
rainy season and rely on strow as a feed supplement during the dry season.
The problems of livestock were identified in a similar way to crop production problems. Livestock is
reared with low quality feed and under low management conditions. The common problems are feed
shortage, disease problem, water shortage, and capital shortage in order of importance. Major problems of
livestock production were related to feed and shortage of pasture land. Feed and pasture shortage
definitely causes the most severe and widespread problems by both income groups. The severity of the
problem is related to stocking rate of animals since grazing land is limited in the study area. Moreover,
feeds obtained from the cultivated area such as crop leaves and residues of cereals are not enough for
Animal health problem is one of the most prevalant problems. Health problems (such as disease and
parasites) are inversely related to altitude. In medium altitude area, the health problems seem to be more
81
severe than in the high altitude area. Even if there are veterinary services delivered by the office of
agriculture, only few farmers take their animals to the veterinary services. This is because of high cost for
the medicine and low productivity of the animal which discourage farmers from making use of veterinary
services. The shortage of water is another problematic area of concern. Long distances have to be
covered to take animals to water sources during the dry season. Shortage of cash to purchase or cover
animals` and animals` related expenses (such as veterinary, mineral salt and so on) is another problem in
North Wollo zone is one of the highly deforested area in the country. No indigenous permanent trees are
seen in the study area except for some remnants of those indigenous trees that are to be found around
churches. These permanent trees are not destroyed because the people in the area are orthodox religion
followers who are mindful of the trees around the churches, since they give high respect to churches. So it
could be argued that “churches are the only forest genetic potential preservatives” in the surrounding area.
Eucalyptus is the only common permanent tree found in the area outside the compounds of churches.
Farmers are still planting it every year to a large extent and they use it as source of income and fire wood.
The value of eucalyptus tree differs from time to time. In the event of high building construction activity in
the surrounding area, the price is more. The study area is a source of providing eucalyptus tree for
construction in the North Wollo Zone, Tigray regional state towns and Asmara prior to the Ethiopian-
Eritrean dispute. However, now a days because of the interruption of sending it to Asmara and reduction of
construction work in the surrounding area, the price of the tree has declined. The price of one pole which
requires about 3 to 5 years to reach at this stage which used to be sold for Birr 6 to 8 before the dispute;
82
now price reduced to Birr 2 to 3 only. So, even if we calculate it with the lowest price of Birr 2 per pole, a
farmer can get up to Birr 4000 per hectare per year. This is because the farmers are planting more than the
recommended number of tree per hectare due to land shortage. So planting of eucalyptus tree is mach
beneficial to the farmers, however because of shortage of land for the annual crops and its effect on other
crops growing around it has made a controversial issue for the farmers to grow the eucalyptus tree in their
arable land. The farmers are preferring to grow these trees around their compounds and near the road,
however, crops which were grown near eucalyptus tree will reduce their productivity because of the
chemical that will liberate from it and its shading effect. Now a days the controversy of growing eucalyptus
tree in the arable land was discussed at different regional officials and bureau’s, and even if no effective
solution were made, the region has decided not to cultivate eucalyptus tree in arable lands. Instead, the
regional officials have suggested as an alternative measure, distribution of the surrounding mountainous
The distribution of the mountainous area in the region started three years ago and it seems effective. Some
of the weredas which distributed the land earlier was started to recover because of planting trees over it and
some of the indigenous remnants were starting to revegetate. So the farmers are obtaining income from
selling of grasses and used it as a source of feed for their livestock. However the farmers still prefer to
plant the eucalyptus tree in their compounds and the road near to their home. Because they suspect that
planting in mountainous area may not be successful because of thefts problem, and since these
mountainous areas are eroded, it will not reach for production in short period of time. In addition to these,
those plants grown in mountainous area will dry after some years, because their root will reach to the main
rock and the root will not farther penetrate it after some stage of growth.
The main sources of income for the farmer are derived from both farm and non-farm activities. Based on
83
the existing farm situation and prevailing price levels, farmers of HIG and LIG were obtaining an overall
gross margin of Birr 2765 of which 4491 for HIG and 2176 for LIG. The farmer is covering all his
expenses from this income. The expenses include: subsistence requirements, clothing, land tax, hiring of
labor and other variable input expenses. As indicated in table 5.12, the LIG farm income was not covering
all his expenses. So, the farmer in this group are expected to reduce either the variable costs or subsistence
requirements, which may lead to undernourishment. The LIG farmer to covers his expenses needs
Table 5.12 Sources of cash income and expenses of the sampled farmer (Birr), 1999/00
Among the various types of farm activities that are currently performed by the farmer, wheat contributes 33
per cent of the farmers income (table 5.13). Even if, the amount of contribution is very small, the livestock
and eucalyptus tree enterprises were two additional sources of farm income. Livestock contributes an
overall of Birr 499 with 663 for HIG and 443 for LIG, while eucalyptus contributes an overall of Birr 187
84
with 203 for HIG and 181 for LIG.
Table 5.13 Sources of total farm and non-farm income for different groups of sampled farmers
(Birr), 1999/00.
Source From own-crop From Share-in crop
usage shows that the gross margin per hectare of land is higher for the LIG than HIG. This accounts for an
overall of Birr 2684 with 2552 for HIG and Birr 2790 and for LIG. This may be due to their better
management of land. The available labor productivity of gross margin per man hour(GM/MH) shows the
number of working force per hour, where as gross margin per man equivalent (GM/ME) is the total
number of ME for the representative farm. Employed labor productivity of gross margin per hectare
(GM/ha) has an overall of Birr 1.18 with Birr 1.45 for HIG and Birr 1.12 for LIG and that of available
working force GM/hr is overall of Birr 0.79 with Birr 1.05 for HIG and Birr 0.67 for LIG. Farm cash
income per employed man-hour amounted to an overall of Birr 0.35 with 0.67 for HIG and 0.18 for LIG.
(Table 5.14 ).
Table 5.14 Marginal value productivities of various resources on sampled holdings (Birr)
The average resource productivity of major crops per hectare is Birr 3759, 2880, 2656, 2169 and 2025 for
improved and local wheat*, teff*, barley*, and wassera* respectively. Wheat* was the highest productive
of all crops. From legumes lentil and horse beans have better income than other legumes
86
Table 5.15 Total income from different crops and their relative contribution to the sampled farmers.
(In Birr)
Crop productivity HIG per cent LIG per cent Overall per cent
share share share
Improved wheat* 3520 15 3840 16 3759 16
Local wheat* 2880 13 2880 11 2880 12
Local wheat 1440 06 1440 06 1440 06
Teff 1365 06 1365 05 1365 05
Teff * 2438 10 2730 11 2656 11
Barley 1120 05 1120 04 1120 05
Barley* 1960 09 2240 09 2169 09
Wassera 1215 05 1215 05 1215 05
Wassera* 2025 09 2025 08 2025 08
Horse bean 1260 05 1440 09 1394 06
Field peas 1110 05 1295 05 1248 05
Lentil 1575 07 1800 07 1743 07
Grass pea 1120 05 1120 04 1120 05
Total 23028 100 24510 100 24133 100
* indicates a crop with fertilizer.
The productivity of crops sown with fertilizer is better even if we reduce the fertilizer and other costs from
this productivity income, the improved practice is better than the traditional one.
87
6. LINEAR PROGRAMMING OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS
After identifying farming situation, the next question is to investigate whether the allocation of
resources is optimal. This helps to envisage how the farm resources in the study area should be
reorganized in order to improve farm income with the existing level of technology. In this chapter,
the model outputs and the farmers` practices will be examined. Therefore, production patterns, farm
resource use, shadow prices of resources, households` farm income, resource productivity,
alternative specification of the model and alternative outcomes of the model with yield and price
The base model results for both income groups show a significant change in the production
pattern, resource use, farm income and returns to farm resources over the existing farm practices.
The base model results for both farming system areas depict a significant change in the
production pattern, resource use, farm income and returns to farm resources over the existing
farming practices.
Owing to the existing production system and consumption preference of the representative farms,
there is a remarkable change, weather posetive or negative, in almost all the crops. The model
favor wheat for both income groups. The result is compatible with farmers’ enterprise
prioritization for food security goals together with the consideration of production per unit area.
The area allocated to wheat is increased by 80 per cent and 74 per cent for HIG and LIG,
88
respectively over the existing practice. However, the total wheat area is shifted to improved
wheat with fertilizer production in the optimal model, so its increment extended by 272 per cent
and 1350 per cent for HIG and LIG, respectively. Farmers are rational, as those with relatively
smaller cultivable land, use it for wheat cultivation, as its productivity is higher than any other
crop of the area. As, indicated in table 6.1, improved wheat with fertilizer is selected in the
optimal plan. Similarly for other crops a crop with fertilizer is preferred by the model for own-
land crops but the reverse is true for share-land crops. However, since the model is constructed in
such a way that the subsistence requirement should be first fulfilled, all crop types are selected
either on own-crop land or on the share-crop land. The selection of the optimal model is similar
to the situation which was observed in the study area; since the owner of the share holder is the
one who covers the variable cost, he is not interested to incur additional cost for fertilizer and
other costs in the share area because the production is divided equally between the owner and
him.
Table 6.1 Existing/optimal cropping pattern and land use on sample holdings, 1999/00
89
HIG LIG Overall
Exist Opti %∆ Exist Opti %∆ Exist Opti %∆
ing mal ing mal ing mal
Own land
Improved wheat* 0.29 1.078 +272 0.03 0.435 +1350 0.1 0.6 +622
Local wheat* 0.06 - -100 0.03 - -100 0.04 -100
Local wheat 0.25 - -100 0.19 - -100 0.21 -100
Teff 0.15 - -100 0.17 0.025 -14.7 0.16 -100
Teff * 0.03 0.085 +183 0.01 0.081 +710 0.02 0.08 +400
Barley 0.17 - -100 0.10 - -100 0.12 -100
Barley* 0.07 0.004 -6 0.01 - -100 0.03 -100
Wassera 0.06 - -100 0.04 - -100 0.05 -100
Wassera* 0.09 - -100 0.01 - -100 0.03 -100
Horse bean 0.16 0.163 +2 0.06 0.14 +133 0.09 0.15 +171
Field peas 0.03 0.033 +10 0.04 0.056 +40 0.04 0.05 +34
Lentil 0.17 0.341 +100 0.02 0.042 +110 0.06 0.12 +103
Grass pea 0.05 0.056 +12 0.01 - -100 0.02 -100
Share land 0 0
Improved wheat* 0.1 - -100 0.02 - -100 0.04 -100
Local wheat* 0.03 - -100 0.02 - -100 0.02 -100
Local wheat 0.10 - -100 0.04 - -100 0.06 -100
Teff 0.13 - -100 0.08 0.158 +98 0.09 -100
Teff* - - - 0.01 - -100
Barley 0.06 0.432 +620 0.01 - -100 0.02 -100
Barley* 0.03 - -100 0.03 - -100 0.03 -100
Wassera 0.05 0.318 +536 0.003 0.182 +5966 0.01 0.22 +144
Wassera* 0.02 - -100 0.06 - -100 0.05 8-100
Horse bean 0.09 - -100 0.001 - -100 0.02 -100
Field peas 0.05 - -100 0.01 - -100 0.02 -100
Lentil 0.03 - -100 0.02 - -100 0.02 -100
Gras pea 0.09 - -100 0.04 - -100 0.05
* Shows the crop with fertilizer.
Livestock
The base model plan indicated that there are some differences between the farmer’s existing
practice and the base model. For HIG the numbers of heifers, bulls and lambs are increased by 50
per cent, 521 per cent and 14 per cent, respectively while for the LIG, heifer and lamb numbers
has been reduced by 91 per cent and 43 per cent respectively, but bulls numbers have increased
90
substantially (by 4076 per cent) in the optimal base model relative to the existing practice. The
increment in bull number for LIG is higher than for the HIG because of the presence of low
number of pairs of oxen by the former group under the existing practice. For HIG increasing the
number of heifers and lambs will be profitable for the farmer but the converse holds for the LIG
since they are hindered from increasing the number of hifers and lambs due to shortage of
resources and severe competition between resources to grow other profitable and more basic
enterprises. The land allocated for tree plantation remains the same in both the groups i.e. HIG
Table 6.2 Livestock number under existing and optimal condition, sample farmers, 1999/00.
91
There was no change in the utilization of the total area of land in both the farm groups, except the
variation in the reallocation of area among different crops; so, only changes in the utilization of
resource such as labor, oxen power and working capital were considered. The optimal solution of
the basic model shows a significant change in the utilization of labor, oxen power, and working
The overall labor employment is increased by 28 per cent i.e. 3 per cent in HIG and 45 per cent in
LIG farms. Oxen power utilization also increased by 9 per cent and 23 per cent in HIG and LIG
farms, respectively with an overall increase of 19 per cent. This is because of the fact that highest
proportion of land is covered by wheat and teff, which require more plowing and weeding.
Moreover, the required working capital was increased by 1 per cent and 13 per cent for HIG and
LIG, respectively. This is due to the high variable cost requirement for improved wheat with
Table 6.3 Labor, oxen power and working capital use under the base model.
92
The optimal farm plan indicates the improvement in farm income and resource productivity.
More specifically, under reallocation of resources, the overall gross margin per hectare (GM/ha)
improves by 8.6 per cent i.e. 9.4 per cent for HIG and 8 per cent for LIG. Similarly, cash income
(CI) improvements are also observed with an overall average of 30 per cent i.e. 20.5 per cent for
HIG and 49 per cent for LIG. The result shows that the low-income group were more benefited
Table 6.4 Change in farm income and resource productivity under optimal base model over
the existing one, sample holdings, 1999/00
Table 6.4 indicated that land productivity increased in base model by 8.6 per cent, 9.4 per cent
and 8 per cent for overall sample farmers, HIG and LIG, respectively. In the case of labor
productivity, gross margin per man hour (GM/MH) for employed persons are increased for HIG
because the increase in farm income is higher than the increase in labor usage from the existing
practice. But for LIG and overall, the increase in farm income is lower than the increase in labor
93
usage. Thus, GM/MH decreases. The GM/MH for available persons increased by 6.6 per cent,
8.6 per cent and 7.5 per cent for overall, HIG and LIG, respectively and cash income per man
hour (CI/MH) for employed is increased by 9.6 per cent, 16 per cent and 5.5 per cent for overall,
The marginal value result shows that land in all farm groups is the limiting factor. The marginal
value (shadow price) of land is about Birr 1305 and 960 per hectare for HIG and LIG,
respectively. The marginal value of land for LIG is small compared to HIG, due to the
inadequacy of capital available for farmers in the LIG hindering the cultivation of highly
productive crops. Besides, working capital and labor at weeding time (August 21 to October)
show a scarcity for both the groups. The existence of marginal value of labor especially for the
LIG is not clear. This may be due to their migration in search of work and they may be employed
by the HIG. Generally, the low income group has much higher excess to labor. Working capital
has marginal value of Birr 1.837 and 2.7 for HIG and LIG respectively. Labor has a marginal
value of 0.24 per person per hour. This implies that the values of the objective function would
increase by these amounts if an additional unit of these resources was made available. However,
the price of labor in the study area is still higher than the obtained marginal value, implying that it
94
2. Labor (Birr/MH)
August 21 to October 0.24 0.24
3. Working Capital (Birr) 1.837 2.7
The optimal alternative plan is prepared to find ways in which the productivity of existing
resource increased, by solving some of the existing constraints. In this case an optimal plan is
considered on changes of constraint components of the farmer such as working capital constraint.
This is because the farmers have a capital constraint as it is observed from the model result. So
the farmers are assumed to be borrowing enough amount of additional capital i.e. Birr 1506 for
HIG and Birr 697 for LIG. from the different organizations and using it for buying of improved
seed and fertilizer as well as buying of different improved livestock breeds. Even if a farmer has
other more serious problems, such as shortage of land, it is not possible to increase the holding
In this model changes in resource endowment and production pattern in comparison to the basic
model would be observed, by assuming that a farmer in any of the groups is using borrowed
working capital.
The alternative optimum plans result in a significant change in the levels of some farm activities
The crop area for HIG:- The area under own-wheat with fertilizer, own-teff with fertilizer and
field peas is increased and own-teff, lentil and grass pea areas are reduced. Similarly, for LIG, the
area under local wheat with fertilizer, teff, share-teff, field peas, lentil and grass pea is increased
while the area for teff, field peas, wassera, and share beans is reduced. The percentage of each
95
crop type is presented in table 6.6. In this regard, the direction and level of changes of activities
Table 6.6 Cropping pattern in the alternative plan sample holdings, 1999/00
The alternative plan for livestock production shows no significant change except in case of
heifers where number decreased by 90 per cent for HIG, while the goats number has increased by
96
Base Alternate Base Alternate Base Alternate
Livestock model plan model plan model plan
Ox 1.9 1.9 0.83 0.83 1.11 1.11
Cow 0.75 0.75 0.5 0.5 0.56 0.56
Heifer 0.75 0.075(-90) 0.05 0.05 0.23 0.056(-76)
Bull 1.991 1.991 7.1 7.1 5.79 5.79
Horse 0.8 0.8 0.2 0.2 0.35 0.35
Donkey 1.3 1.3 0.3 0.3 0.55 0.55
Sheep 4 4 2 2 2.51 2.51
Goat 1.4 1.4 0.3 5.52(+1740) 0.58 4.47(+670)
Bee hive 0.36 0.36 0.2 0.2 0.24 0.24
Poultry 3 3 2 2 2.25 2.25
Eucalyptus 0.05 0.05 0.17 0.17 0.14 0.14
The numbers in the parenthesis show the percentage increase or decrease from existing practice
In this plan also no change occured in the utilization of the total area of land for the two farm
types, but the allocation of cropped area among different crops is varied. So, the utilization of
labor, oxen power and working capital are changed because the resource requirements for
different enterprises are different. As shown in table 6.8, comparing the alternative plan to the
level in the basic plan, an overall improvement is seen in human labor, oxen power and working
capital utilization. Human labor employment is increased by 9 per cent and 6 per cent for HIG
and LIG, respectively with an overall increase of 7 per cent. Oxen power utilization increased by
an overall of 42 per cent, with 72 per cent for HIG and 25 per cent for LIG farms. The increment
of oxen labor is very high compared to human labor for LIG. Moreover, the required working
capital increased by 51 per cent and 31 per cent in HIG and LIG farms respectively with an
overall total increase of 39 per cent for the whole sample of farmers.
Table 6.8 Labor, Oxen Power and Working Capital Use under the Alternative Plan.
97
Base Alternate Base Alternate Base Alternate
model plan model plan model plan
1. Labor (hours):
Employed 3185 3480 (+9) 2812 2980 (+6) 2907 3107(+7)
Available 4292 4292 3236 - 3505 3505
% Employment 74 81 (+7) 87 92 (+5) 83 89 (+6)
2. Oxen Power(ox hr.):
Employed 260 447 (+72) 155 194 (+25) 182 258(+42)
Available 594 594 262 - 347 347
% Employment 44 75 (+35) 59 74 (+15) 52 74 (+22)
3. Working Capital 997 1506(+51) 532 696 (+31) 650 902(+39)
The (Birr)
numbers in the parenthesis show the percentage increase or decrease from existing practice
From the alternative optimum plan it is seen that there is a possibility to improve farm income
and resource productivity by proper allocation of resources. As it is observed from table 6.9 the
gross margin and cash income have increased by 22 per cent and 43 per cent for HIG, 2 per cent
and 7 per cent for LIG farms and an overall of 10 per cent and 29 per cent for both groups of
farms, respectively.
Table 6.9 Farm income and resource productivity under the alternative plan
The production option of both groups show relatively more farm resources but cultivable land
still remains the most limiting factor for them; particularly for the LIG, even borrowing of money
does not bring them a significant increment in their total gross income, due to serious shortage of
land. Labor (in some periods) appears to be a constraints in both farm groups. On the other hand,
similar to basic model, oxen power is not again a limiting factor in any of the operation periods
and in any of the groups. However, obtaining ox during plowing period remains to be a problem
As indicated in table 6.10, shadow prices of Birr 2710 and 3021 are observed for own-crop land
of HIG and LIG farms, respectively. On the other hand, during August 21 to October labor (Lab
3) has a shadow price of Birr 0.24 per man hour for HIG and Birr 0.228 per man hour for LIG
farms. The marginal value (shadow price) of working capital is not seen in this plan because of
While formulating models, the assumption that all parameters under consideration remain
production and income. In reality, farmers operate under both risky and unrisky factors.
Agricultural output and input prices fluctuate between seasons, years and places because of
external factors which affect the demand for and supply of these items. For these reasons, it is
important to perform some sensitivity tests on the plans and observe the subsequent effects on the
In this respect, the effect of changes in the price of the output and the major input, fertilizer and
improved seed (increment of variable cost) on the production pattern, resource use and farm
income is observed. Even if output price variation is not a serious problem in the study area,
changes in price of these major crops are considered because some times there are price
fluctuations during the period of crop harvesting and the period when foodgrains are distributed
to the needy people in the area. Moreover, because of the new extension system, there is an
increase in production and a price reduction is observed in the area. On the other hand, the price
of fertilizer and improved seed has been fluctuating from year to year.
100
6.3.1.1. Impact of Output Price Reduction on Base Model Solutions
Even if the price fluctuation is not a serious problem in the study area, the survey results and
secondary marketing data from Office of Agriculture show the presence of price fluctuation in
some seasons. Thus, to account for its further impact a 10 per cent and 25 per cent price reduction
is imposed on the model. This price is assumed based on the lowest price record obtained from the
department of agriculture’s weekly market studies of the study year (1999/00). The results as
desplayed in table 6.11 show no variation in cropping pattern for LIG at both levels of price
variation. This may be explained by the fact that most of the produced crop is used for self-
consumption by the LIG and hence price variations do not affect the model. But for HIG, even if
there is no variation at 10 per cent, it does appear at 25 per cent output price reduction. Wheat area
is reduced by 29 per cent and lentil and barley with fertilizer, increased by 104 and 2875 per cent,
respectively. Share areas of wassera and barley are shifted to own-area with fertilizer production.
Horse beans, field peas, and grass peas are shifted from own-land to the share-land area, while and
Table 6.11 Impact of output price variation on the cropping pattern under base plan
(1999/00).
Own land:
Improved wheat* 1.07 - 0.435 - 0.77 -29 0.435 -
Local wheat*
Local wheat
Teff 0.025 - 0.025 -
101
Teff* 0.085 - 0.081 - 0.085 - 0.081 -
Barley
Barley* 0.004 - 0.119 +2875
Wassera
Wassera* 0.089 +100
Horse bean 0.163 - 0.141 - -100 0.141 -
Field peas 0.033 - 0.056 - -100 0.056 -
Lentil 0.341 - 0.042 - 0.696 +104 0.042 -
Grass peas -100
Share land:
Improved wheat*
Local wheat*
Local wheat
Teff 0.158 - 0.158 -
Barley 0.432 -
Barley* -100
Wassera 0.318 - 0.182 - 0.182 -
Wassera* -100
Horse bean 0.326 +100
Field peas 0.067 +100
Lentil 0.246 +100
Grass peas 0.112 +100
Impact of Output Price Variation on Resource Use
An output price change similar to cropping pattern, has no effect on resource use and
productivity for LIG, but it causes some variations in resource use and resource productivity for
the HIG. The gross margin and gross margin per hectare(GM/ha) were both reduce for this group
by 3 per cent and 6 per cent at 10 per cent and 25 per cent output price reduction, respectively.
Similarly, both cash income and cash income per hectare (CI/ha) are reduced by 5.8 per cent and
12 per cent at 10 per cent and 25 per cent output price reduction respectively. Productivity of
resources for the HIG has also been affected negatively by output price reduction. The labor use
gross margin per hectare (GM/ha) has reduced by 2.6 per cent for both employed and available
labor at 10 per cent and it reduces by 6 per cent for employed and 9.4 per cent for the available
102
Table 6.12 Impact of output price variation on the optimum resource use resource
productivity and farm income under base model.
Output price variation has also a reduction effect on cash income per man-hour of employed
personnel. It is reduced by 5 per cent and 39 per cent at 10 per cent and 25 per cent price
reduction, respectively. Generally, a reduction in the output price of farm products has resulted in
reduction in resource productivity, resource usage and farm income of HIG. It also reduces the
improved technology usage, since the producers will not find it beneficiary. So, precautionery
Moreover, output price reduction has an adverse effect on the marginal value (MV) of resources.
MVs of land and working capital are decreased at both 10 per cent as well as 25 per cent of
output price variation for both farm groups. At 10 per cent, MV of land decreases by 12 and 11
per cent, and at 25 per cent it decreases by 23 and 26 per cent for HIG and LIG, respectively.
Similarly, MV of working capital at 10 per cent decreases by 14 and 13, and at 25 per cent it
decreases by 84 and 34 per cent for HIG and LIG, respectively. However, the MV of labor
103
remains the same at both output price reduction levels. (Table 6.13).
The effect brought no change in cropping pattern and resource use for both farm groups at 10 per
cent as well as 25 per cent output price reduction levels. This shows even if the price reduction
occurred, enough working capital would help to compensate it. (Table 6.14)
Table 6.14 Impact of output price variations on cropping pattern in alternative plan
Output price reduction has brought about some changes for some of the animal species. Goats
numbers has reduced by 88 per cent at both levels of price variation for HIG, and by 1.4 per cent
and 2.3 per cent at 10 and 25 per cent price variation as well as an insignificant increase in bull
number by 0.1 per cent for LIG. (Table 6.15)
Table 6.15 Impact of output price variation on the optimum resource of livestock in
alternative plan
Eventhough output price variation has not changed the cropping pattern, it certainly brought a
105
reduction effect on farm income and resource productivity. Gross margin (GM) and gross margin
per hectare (GM/ha) is reduced by 14 per cent and 32 per cent price for HIG and 6 per cent and
10 per cent for LIG at 10 per cent and 25 per cent levels, respectively. Cash income (CI) and
Cash income per hectare (CI/ha) also is reduced by 24 per cent and 54 per cent price reduction
for HIG and 27 per cent and 43 per cent for LIG at 10 per cent and 25 per cent levels
respectively. The result brings out that income reduction for the LIG is higher than the HIG.
Labor productivity also declines. Gross margin per man hour (GM/MH) for employed personnel
is reduced by 21 per cent and 38 per cent for HIG and 3 per cent and 6 per cent for LIG.
Similarly, for available personnel GM/MH is reduced by 16 per cent and 32 per cent for HIG and
5 per cent and 10 per cent for LIG at 10 per cent and 25 per cent levels of price reduction,
respectively. CI/MH for employed personnel also is reduced by 24 per cent and 58 per cent price
reduction for HIG and 23 per cent and 39 per cent for LIG at 10 per cent and 25 per cent levels of
Moreover, output price reduction has also an effect on the marginal value (MV) of resources.
MV of land is reduced by 13 per cent and 32 per cent at 10 per cent and 25 per cent of output
price reduction levels for both the groups. However, it does not bring about any change in
106
Table 6.16 Impact of output price variation on the farm income, optimum resource use,
productivity and MV of resources on alternative plan
Agricultural input usage is generally very low in the study area. The most commonly applied
fertilizer inputs are DAP (Diammomium phosphate) and urea (Ammonium Nitrate). The amount
107
of fertilizer applied to a crop varies depending on the crop, soil type and adoption level of the
farmers. According to the new extension system PADETS, the recommended rate was 100 kg
DAP and 50 kg urea per hectare for wheat package (DOA, 1998). The price variation of these
inputs brings a change in the variable cost of cultivation. The impact of 5 per cent and 25 per cent
variation in the variable cost are considered. This is because, even if 10 to 25 per cent input price
variation is common in the study area, more than 10 per cent price change makes the optimum
model infeasible for the LIG. However, at this percentage level there is no significant difference
for HIG. So, to see the impact for both groups clearly, 5 per cent and 25 per cent input price
Input Price variation has brought a change in the cropping pattern, farm income, resource use and
productivity. Cropping pattern for HIG has changed, i.e. wheat production is reduced by 5 per
cent and 10 per cent, while lentil area is increased by 14 per cent and 32 per cent at 5 per cent and
25 per cent of input price increment. For the LIG, a 5 per cent input price increment will bring
about a reduction in wheat and teff areas with fertilizer by 2 and 11 per cent, respectively wheras
teff area increases by 72 per cent. An increment of input price by more than 5 per cent for LIG
108
Table 6.17. Impact of input price increment on the cropping pattern of base model.
Input Price increment showed no effect on the livestock composition in the base model, (Table
6.18)
109
Table 6.18 Impact of input price increment on the livestock composition of base model.
The increment in variable cost or the input price also has an adverse effect on the farm income
and resource productivity. Gross margin (GM) and gross margin per hectare (GM/ha) are reduced
equally by 2 per cent and 17 per cent for HIG at 5 and 25 per cent input price increment. Cash
income (CI) and cash income per hectare (CI/ha) similarly decreases by 4 and 33 per cent at 5
and 25 per cent input price increment. Similarly, for LIG, GM and GM/ha as well as CI and
CI/ha decline by 2 and 9 per cent at 5 per cent but become infeasible at 25 per cent price
increment. Labor productivity is reduced with a maximum of 36 per cent for cash income
(CI/MH) at 25 per cent. Marginal values (shadow prices) of the resources are all reduced, i.e the
MV of land is reduced by 2 and 10 per cent and that of working capital is reduced by 13 and 41
per cent for HIG at 5 and 25 per cent, respectively, whereas it is reduced by 7 per cent for LIG at
5 per cent input price increment shown in table 6.19.
110
Table 6.19 Impact of Input Price Variation on Farm income, resource productivity and MV
of products of Base model.
From the table it can be observed that the input price increment has a higher effect on the cash
income of LIG than HIG. This is because, a small reduction in gross margin will have a
substantial impact on LIGs cash income since subsistence requirement has to be fulfilled first,
Similar to the base model, increment in input price (variable cost) has brought about some
changes in cropping pattern, farm income and resource productivity in the alternative plan,
though the magnitude of change is not as much as that of base plan. There is a very little
reduction observed in the area under wheat at both per cent of input price increment levels.
111
Unlike the earlier trend, here production of local wheat with fertilizer has entered and a shift of
barley production from the own-land production to the share-land production is observed. For
LIG the production pattern seems more stable than the HIG as there is no variation in cropping
pattern at all 5 per cent input price increment and minimal change at 25 per cent input price
Table 6.20 Impact of input price variation on cropping patternin alternative plan
112
The effect of input price increment on resource use shows that both gross margin per hectare
(GM/ha) and cash income per hectare (CI/ha) are reduced by a range of 2 per cent to 45 per cent
which is the highest reduction seen at 25 per cent input price increment in the LIG. The
productivity of land is also reduced up to 45 per cent for LIG, (see table 6.21). As already
observed the effect of input price increment is higher on cash income of LIG than HIG. The
marginal value (MV) of land is reduced by 3 per cent and 13 per cent for LIG and by 30 per cent
and 50 per cent for the HIG. The marginal value reduction of HIG is higher because when the
price of input increases, the incentive of producing high productive crops is reduced and the
Table 6.21 Impact of input price increment on the optimum resource use, farm income and
MV of resources under alternative plan.
113
The problem of output variation is most serious problem in the study area due to erratic rain
nature, pest infestation and low soil fertility problems etc. In this section the effect of output
reduction on the cropping pattern, farm income and change in the marginal value (MV) of
resources at 10 per cent and 25 per cent has been estimated. This level of output reduction is the
lowest and frequently occurring amount in the study area. So, to observe optimal solutions
Output reduction has brought a decrease in area of wheat and lentil by 3 per cent and 9 per cent at
10 per cent and 13 per cent and 40 per cent at 25 per cent output reduction, respectively. The
areas under teff, barley, horse bean, field peas and grass peas are increased by 11 per cent, 523
per cent, 11 per cent, 12 per cent and 11 per cent at 10 per cent output reduction for the HIG.
This also increases by 129 per cent, 1825 per cent, 33 per cent, 51 per cent and 34 per cent at 25
per cent output reduction level, respectively for HIG. Similarly, barley production area on share
land is reduced by 8 per cent and 24 per cent at 10 per cent and 25 per cent output reduction, but
that of wassera production area on share land (with fertilizer) is increased by 11 per cent and 33
per cent at 10 per cent and 25 per cent, respectively. The effect of output reduction is more
serious for LIG in that at 25 per cent output reduction the optimal solution becomes infeasible.
For LIG at 10 per cent output reduction wheat area is reduced by 6 per cent but teff area is
increased by 83 per cent. The effect of output reduction does not bring variation in livestock
114
HIG LIG HIG LIG
Value %∆ Value %∆ Value %∆ Value %∆
Own land:
Improvedwheat* 1.049 -3 0.41 -6 0.943 -13
Local wheat*
Local wheat
Teff - -100
Teff* 0.094 +11 0.148 +83 0.195 +129 Infeasible
Barley
Barley* 0.027 +523
Wassera
Wassera* 0.022 +100
Horse bean 0.181 +11 0.15 +7 0.217 +33
Field peas 0.037 +12 -100 0.05 +51
Lentil 0.31 -9 0.047 +12 0.204 -40
Grass pea 0.062 +11 0.075 +34
Share land:
Improved wheat*
Local wheat*
Local wheat
Teff -100
Barley
Barley* 0.397 -8 0.327 -24
Wassera
Wassera* 0.353 +11 -100 0.423 +33
Horse bean
Field peas 0.009 100
Lentil 0.108 100
Grass pea
The effect of output reduction on the farm income and resource productivity shows a decrease in
gross margin and gross margin per hectare (GM/ha) by 11 per cent for LIG at 10 per cent output
reduction. Both are also reduced by 8 per cent and 26 per cent for HIG at 10 per cent and 25 per
cent output reduction, respectively. Similarly, cash income and cash income per hectare (CI/ha)
are reduced by 16 per cent and 51 per cent, respectively for HIG at respective output reduction
levels. Likewise, both are reduced by 49 per cent for LIG at an output reduction of 10 per cent
and the model will become infeasible at 25 per cent level of output reduction for LIG so that the
farmer`s earned cash income, does not cover his expenses, thereby leading to a reduction in his
115
subsistence requirement. The MV of land is also reduced by 12 per cent and 101 per cent and
working capital decreased by 13 per cent and 65 per cent for both income groups, respectively at
10 per cent level of output reduction. Similarly, MV of land and working capital are reduced by
34 and 29 per cent respectively at 25 per cent output reduction for HIG,while the optimal
Table 6.23 Impact of output reduction on the optimum resource use and farmincome under
base model.
Like the base model, there is a reduction of the wheat area with a maximum of 17 per cent for
HIG at 25 per cent output reduction; while acrage of most other crops is increasing. For the LIG,
the reduction for own improved wheat at 10 per cent level is 9 per cent and for HIG it is 7 per
116
cent. However, the model is infeasible for the LIG at 25 per cent reduction level.
Table 6.24 Impact of output reduction on cropping pattern of Alternative plan (1999/00)
The output reduction has an effect on the farm income, resource usage and productivity. Thus,
both gross margin (GM) and gross margin per hectare (GM/ha) is reduced equally by 17 per cent
and 35 per cent for HIG at 10 and 25 per cent output reduction. Cash income (CI) and cash
income per hectare (CI/ha) similarly decline by 29 per cent and 59 per cent for HIG at 10 and 25
per cent output reduction, respectively. Likewise, for LIG, GM and GM/ha as well as CI and
117
CI/ha are reduced by 5.6 and 24 per cent at 10 per cent level of output reduction wheras they
become infeasible at 25 per cent output reduction. Labor productivity is reduced with a
maximum of 77 per cent for cash income (CI/MH) at 25 per cent for HIG. Marginal value
productivities (shadow prices) of the resources are all reduced. The MV productivity of land is
reduced by 13 and 32 per cent for HIG at 10 and 25 per cent output reduction and by 346 per cent
for LIG at 10 per cent. From these we conclude even though output reduction affected both
groups seriously the effect is hihg for LIG, so that the optimal model become infeasible at 25 per
Table 6.25 Impact of 10 per cent and 25 per cent output reduction on the optimum resource
use and farm income under alternate plan.
118
Land:(GM/ha) 2818 -17 2885 -5.7 2212 -35
(CI/ha) 1439 -29 550 -24 833 -59
Labor(GM/MH):
Employed 1.6 -15 0.75 -2.5 1.43 -24
Available 1.15 -17 0.70 -4 0.52 -62
Employed (CI/MH) 0.82 -26 0.15 -17 0.26 -77
3. MV. of resources:
1. Land 2358 -13 677 -346 1830 -32
2. Labor(lab. 3) 0.24 - 0.228 - 0.24 -
3. W/capital - - - - - -
119
7. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
The basic problem of Ethiopia’s agriculture is low level of productivity. Especially in the North
East part of the country, because of inadequate and erratic nature of rainfall, serious soil
degradation, high pest infestation and deforestation, low productivity in agriculture is the major
challenge. For smallholder farmers in the study area, it is difficult to get an additional income after
satisfying their subsistence requirement, at their existing land size and productivity.
This study attempts to investigate ways and means of improving the productivities of smallholders
by way of strengthening their access to improved farm technologies and through efficient
In this study an attempt has been made to analyze the existing agricultural situation in Meket
wereda by considering a sample of 110 household farms in terms of production pattern, farm
income, resource productivity and differences in marginal values of the limited resources. The
existing farming practices are compared with different optimal plans that have been produced by
using the linear programming model. These optimum plans are developed under a set of options
involving (1) base model; (2) alternative plan with increased working capital; and (3) sensitivity
analysis. The main objective of this comparative analysis is to investigate whether the existing
patterns are optimal or not and to indicate ways and means by which smallholder farmer`s
labor ratio of 0.5, 1.9 oxen number, 7.41 tropical live stock unit, expenditure of Birr 284 for
120
fertilizer per year, an overall family size of 6.6 and a production of 20.06 quintal of grains per
year. The low-income group is characterized by 0.3 unit of land-labor ratio, 0.83 oxen number,
having 3.2 tropical livestock unit (TLU), average family size of 5.1, an average of 7.20 quintal of
grain production and an expenditure of Birr 60.70 per year for purchasing fertilizer.
The different enterprises that contribute to the household income depends on resource endowment
and enterprise combination. Under the existing farmer`s practice, the gross margin from all farm
activities amounts to Birr 4491 for HIG and 2176 for LIG. The subsistence requirement share
absorbs 54 per cent and 84 per cent of the total farm income of the HIG and LIG, respectively,
during the year 1999/2000. The LIG is almost producing at subsistence level and some of the
group members cover their expenses from other non-farm income activities, such as petty trade,
The optimization results under current resource base and technology offer visible opportunities for
increasing farm income through a rationalized use of existing resource and correct choice of
cropping pattern. The major changes in production pattern can bring about an improvement in
gross margin by 9.4 per cent and 8 per cent for HIG and LIG respectively. The changes occurr
mainly by shifting the area allocated to different enterprises to those crops which are sown with
improved seed and fertilizer. In base optimal plan, average area of improved wheat with fertilizer
is increased by 272 per cent and 1350 per cent for HIG and LIG, respectively. However, limited
variation encountered in number of livestock except heifers, bulls and lambs. This increase of
farm income supports the hypothesis that there is sub-optimal use of resources in the present
121
Optimal use of resources increase farm income, human labor and oxen power usage. Thus, labor
usage increases by 3 per cent for HIG and 45 per cent for LIG and oxen power usage is increased
The analysis of the alternative optimal plans over the base model with allocation of enough
working capital shows a better prospect for increasing farm income than what could be realized
from the re-allocation of existing resource for both groups of farmers. Thus, an increment in gross
margin by 22, 2 and 10 per cent for HIG, LIG and all sampled farmers, respectively is observed.
After analyzing the optimal allocation of resources, the stability of the models subject to changes
in selected key parameters is reviewed. Thus, a sensitivity test was conducted with reduced output
price, increased input price (working capital) and with reduction in output. The variation shows a
value of the resources. However, the magnitude of reduction is higher in case of reducing output
and increasing the input cost, since the variation in each parameter by 25 per cent from the optimal
plan, caused the optimal solution infeasible. So higher variation in these key parameters need to
The findings of the study show that GM/ha of land for LIG is higher than for HIG, which implies
that the LIG farms are more productive in terms of per unit land area relative to the HIG.
However, the productivity of labor is directly proportional to farm size. The GM/hr and CI/hr for
available as well as employed labor is higher for HIG than LIG in both base and alternative
optimal models.
122
Finally, in view of the above findings, the following concluding remarks have been drawn.
1. The study shows the existence of ways to increase farm income by optimally allocating the
resources and proper choice of enterprise pattern. Thus, the development efforts that will
2. The optimal solutions in both base model and alternate optimal plan resulted in an increase in
gross margin. This was obtained by using improved seed with fertilizer. Thus, the availability of
improved seed, fertilizer and other inputs is crucial. i.e. modern inputs should be delivered at right
time and place with a reasonable cost, so that all farmers can afford to use it.
3. Land is the most acute constraint at existing condition as well as in the future. The farmer are
not able to fulfill their expenses. The only solution for the time-being is intensification of the
existing land by using improved technology. However, even with these technologies, the optimal
solution is not stable for high variation in output reduction and increase in input cost. From the
experience exhibited and actual practice, the reduction in output and increase of input cost are
frequently occurring in the study area. Hence, intensification of existing practice only will not be a
long-lasting solution for the surrounding farmers. More serious attention should be accorded to
activities that may bring major changes in the long run. Some of the interventions include:-
a. Taking the resettlement program as one alternative option to reduce the land problem. Many
farmers who were settled forcefully returned to their villages, after the failure of Derge regime and
some of them stayed without having their own arable land. They live by renting in the older or
123
female-householder`s land or they get food aid in addition to small amount of money they obtain
from daily labor work. However, some of these farmers returned to their resettlement area with
their parents and there are a lot of farmers who ask to go to the resettlement area. So, the
resettlement program should be continued keeping in view the interest of the farmers, and the
water-shed management to reduce the risk of erratic nature of weather problem by supplementing
c. Proper training and supplying of necessary materials for family planning. A continuous
discussion is required with priests, older people, kebele administrative leaders, other respected
people and with the whole community in order to convince them and implement the family
which has been undertaken to mitigate the weather situation of the study area. Much emphasis
should be given to research work in order to develop appropriate technology for the surrounding
area.
4. Working capital is another crucial constraint in the study area. The availability of sufficient
operating capital through borrowing enables the farmers to get inputs on time.
5. There is a need to facilitate non-farm employment opportunities such as petty trade, pottery
124
making, weaving and hand-crafting etc.
8. REFERENCES
This would increase income of peasants and
6. In a mixed farming economy, livestock is the most important sector which supports the crop
production. It serves as a liquid asset for farmers` immediate cash need and adds an important
source of animal protein. Thus, widening the scope of introducing high productive improved
breeds of animals and solving the crucial feed and health problem is necessary. In addition to
these, those activities such as poultry and beehive production which need less or no land should be
expanded and a strong support should be given from the government and concerned NGO’s ,
7. Given the existing acute land shortage and availability of excess mountainous area, planting
eucalyptus on farm-land is not appropriate, and the concerned bodies should work hard to
convince the farmers to abandon such practice. The previous started distribution of mountainous
area to the farmers should continue with strong follow-up, so that the farmers should use the land
Ablu , G.O.I (1975) Optimal Investment Decition in Perrenial Crop Production. A LP Approach.
Journal of Economics. Vol. 26. pp. 383-393.
Beneke, R.R. and WinterBoer, R. (1973). Linear Programming Application to Agriculture. Ames,
1st ed. The Iowa State University Press. Ames, Iowa, U.S.A
Bezabih, E. (1992). Analysis of the Farming System in the Hararghe Highlands. Their
Dependence on Agro Climatic Conditions, their Constraints, and Improvement
Strategies. Unpublished M.Sc. Thesis, AUA, Alemaya Ethiopia.
125
Bogahawatte, C. (1984). Evaluating Crop-Livestock Based Farming Systems. A Village Level
Study in the Dry Zone of Rain-fed District of Sri Lanka Agricultural Systems. Vol.
14, No. 4, PP. 199-212.
Bureau of Planning and Economic Development (B. P. E. D, 1998). Base Line Survey of Amhara
National State. Bureau of Planning and Economic Development. Baherdar, Ethiopia.
Central Statistical Authority. (CSA, 1998).The Sample Servey Year of 1997/98 (1990E C) Report
on Land Utilization. Statistical Bulletin 113, Vol. IV. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.
Clayton, E. S (1961). Technical and Economic Farm Allocation of Peasant Agriculture. West
View Press, Boulder, Colorado. U.S.A
Cunningham, E.P. (1992). EDI of the World Bank, Selected Issues in Livestock Industry
Development. The World Bank. Washington, D.C, U.S..A
Dalton, G.E. (1982). Managing Agricultural Systems, Applied Science Publishers. London.
Debebe. H. (1992 ). Crop Diversification with Tobacco, its Impact on Farmers Income and
Resource use. Unpublished M.Sc Thesis. AUA, Alemaya. Ethiopia.
Dillon, J.L. (1968). The Analysis of Response in Crop and Livestock Production. 1st ed. Oxford
Pergam on press Ltd., Headington Hill Hall. U.K
Dillon, J. and Hardaker, I B. (1980). Farm Management Research for Small Farm Development,
FAO, Agricultural Service Bulletin 41. Food and Agricultural Organization of the
United Nations . Rome, Italy
FAO:- (1990). Production Year Book Statistical Division of Economics and Social Policy
Development, Vol. 44, No 99. Rome, Italy.
______:- (1992) Ethiopian National Fertilizer Project Preparation Mission Vol.1. Report of the
Investment Support Program. Investment Center. Rome, Italy.
_______:- (1997) FAO/ WFP Crop and Food Supply Assessment mission to Ethiopia. No 26,
Rome, Italy.
Getachew Abate. (1995) Integration of Coffee with Food Production : A Case of Producer
Cooperative in Manna Wereda “Ethiopian Journal of Development Research”, vol.
11, No 1, PP. 23-46.
126
Gryseels, G. and Anderson F.M (1983 ). Role of Livestock Mixed Smallholder Farms in the
Ethiopian Highlands : A Case Study from Baso Worna near Debre Berhan Ph.D.
Dissertation, Agricultural university Wageningen, The Netherlands.
Gryseels, G. (1988). The Role of Livestock on Mixed Smallholder Farms in the Ethiopian
Highlands. A Case Study from Baso and Worena Woredas near Debreberhan.
Dissertation, Agricultural University, Wageningen. The Netherlands.
Habtemariam Abate (1997). Targeting Extension Service and the Extension Package Approach in
Ethiopia. MOA, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.
Haile-Mariam Teffera. (1995) Whole Farm Evaluation of Improved Management and Feeding
Strategies for Crossbred Dairy Cows in Selale Area, Central Ethiopian Highlands.
Unpublished M.Sc. Thesis. AUA, Alemaya, Ethiopia.
Hardaker, J.B (1979). A Review of Farm Researches of Small Farm Development in LDCs.
Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 30, No. 3, PP. 315-327.
Hassen Besher. (1999) Crop Livestock Integration on Smallholders` Farms and their Potential for
Improvement in South Wollo, Ethiopia. A Case Study of Deberesina and Tehulederie
Districts. Unpublished M.Sc. Thesis. AUA, Alemaya, Ethiopia.
Jahnke, H. E (1982). Livestock Production Systems and Livestock Development in the Tropical
Africa. Kieler Wissenschaft Sverlg. Viel, Germany.
Joachim Von Branum, Tesfaye Teklue, and Patrick Webb (1990) Policies for famine prevention
in Ethiopia and Suddan. IFPRI policy Brifs. USA.
Kahlon A.S. Dhawan K.C. Gill G.S (1975 ).Relative Profitability of Dairy Enterprise vis - a - vis
Crop Caltivation in the Punjab. Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 30,
No. 1-4.
Kothari, C.R. (1983). Introduction to Operations Research, 2nd ed. Vikas Publishing House Pvt.
Ltd., New Delhi:
Leftwich S.A B and Eckert S. K, (1995). Measurment of Farm Specific Thecnical Efficience
Comparison Method. Journal of Agricultural Economices, Vol. 3, PP. 115-122.
Low A.R.C. (1978) “ Linear Programming and the Study of Peasant Farming Situations A Reply
Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 29, No. 2, PP. 1989-1990.
Meket Wereda Office of Agriculture (WoA, 1999). Baseline Survey Data. Unpublished
Document. North Wollo, Ethiopia
National Bank of Ethiopian (NBE,1999). Quarterly Report of the National Bank of Ethiopia.
Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.
127
Niang, A. (1980). A Linear Programming Model of Representative Sahelian Farm: The Cases
of the Cotton Zone of Mali and the Peanut Zone of Senegal. Ph. D. Dissertation,
Purdue University.
North Wollo Zone Department of Plan and Economic Development (DOPED, 1997). Socio-
Economic Results, Unpublished Document. Woldia, Ethiopia
North Wollo Department of Agriculture (DoA, 1999 ). Base Line Survey Data, Unpublished
Document. Woldia, Ethiopia
Omiti, J.M. (1995). Economic Analysis of Crop-Livestock Integration: The Case Study of
Ethiopian Highland, Ph.D. Thesis. Armidale: University of New England,
Agricultural and Resource Economics Department UK
Panin A. and Brokken R (1993). Economics of Cow Traction Farm Technology in Ethiopia High
lands lLCA, Addis Ababa , Ethiopia. Conference 4 Workshop of the West Africa
Animal Traction Net work . Kano Nigeria. Publishing House Pvt. Ltd. 2nd ed. U.S.A
Ready. Suba (1999) Lecture Notes on Applied Methods of Operational Research in Agricultural
Economics Unpublished. Alemaya Agricultural University, Alemaya, Ethiopia.
Ruthenberg, H. (1980) Farming System in the Tropics. Third Edition, Clarendon Press Oxford.
UK
Schultz, T.W. (1964) Transforming Traditional Agriculture. Yale University press, New Haven.
U.S.A
Shanner, W., P. Philip, and W. Schmehil. (1982). Farming Systems Research and Development
Guidelines for Developing Countries. West view Press. Boulder, Colorado, U.S.A.
Sharma, S. (1996). Applied Multivariate Techniques. University of South Carolina. John Wiley
and Sons, Inc. New York, Chichester Brisbane. Toronto, Singapore, U.S.A.
Singh joginder, D. K. Grover and Prem Singh L. (1989). Scope of Co- operative Farming in
Haryana. A Pillage Plan Approach, Indian Co-operative. Review. vol. 26, No 3: PP.
319-28.
128
Singh, K. (1978). Optimem Land Use Pattern. and Resource Allocation in a Growing Economy.
Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 27, No 4.
Sisay Assefa. (1983). An Analysis of Resource Allocation in a Household Economy. Cases from
Chilalo Province of Ethiopia. Ethiopian Journal of Development Research, vol. 5-7,
No 2, PP. 103-129.
Smith, P.J (1994 ). Identifying Research Priorities in Developing Countries, Agricultural Systems,
Vol. 45, No 4 PP. 455-468. U.S.A
Solomon Gebreselassie. (1993). Optimizing Farm Enterprise Pattern and Resource Utilization in
Major Coffee Growing Areas: A Case Study of Smallholders in Shebedino Awraja,
Sidamo Region , Unpublished M.Sc. Thesis, AUA, Alemaya. Ethiopia
Storck, H, Bezabih, E., Birhanu, A, and Shimelis,W. (1991). Farming Systems and Form
Management Practices of Smallholder in a Hararghe Highlands. Farming System and
Resource Economics, Vo1. 2. Wissench afts verlag vauk kiel, Germeny.
Tesfaye assefa. (1989). An Economic Analysis of Co-operative Farming in the High Lands of
Ethiopia with Special Emphasis on Mixed Farming Systems. Unpublished M.Sc. Thesis,
AUA, Alemaya, Ethiopia
Tesfaye Zegeye and Debebe Habtewold (1995). Food Security in Ethiopia: A Situation
Analysis. In: Mulate Demeke, et al.(eds.). Food Security, Nutrition and Poverty
Alleviation in Ethiopia: Problems and Prospects. Proceedings of the Inaugural and First
Annual Conference of the AESE. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.
Tibaijuka, A. (1994). The Cost of Differential Gender Roles in African Agriculture. A Case Study
of Smallholder Banana-Coffee Farms in the Kajera Region. Tanzania. Journal of
Agricultural Economics. Vol. 45, No 1, PP. 68-81
129
Williams, J.O. (1994). Identifying Target Groups for Livestock Improvement Research. The
Classification of Sedentary Livestock Producers in Western Niger. Agricultural
Systems vol.46, No 2, PP. 227 -237 .
World Bank. (1984). Opportunities and Constraints in Peasant Farming. Working Paper. (1997)
Selected World Document indices. World Development Report, Oxford University
Press. New York. U.S.A.
130
9. APPENDICES
131
Butter yield per litre = 0.05 kg
Manure yield per year = 570 kg
Oxen
Oxen economic life span = 10 years
Oxen manure yield per year = 570 kg
Other cattle
Heifer and bull manure yield per year = 310 kg
Calves manure yield per year = 205 kg
Sheep
Economic life span = 7 years
Weaning rate of 150 per cent per year
Manure yield per year per ewe = 66 kg
Manure yield per year per lamb = 9 kg
Wool per large sheep/year = 0.45 kg
Wool per small sheep/year = 0.24 kg
Goat
Economic life span = 6.5 years
Birth rate of 165 per cent per year
Manure yield per year per doe = 66 kg
Manure yield per year per kid = 9 kg
Donkey
Economic life span = 16 years
Manure yield per year = 438 kg
Gross margin per year = Birr 420
Horse
Economic life span = 20 years
132
Manure yield per year = 762 kg
Gross margin per year = 680
Hen
If it is for egg production only
Economic life span = 3 years
Egg produced per year = 204
Gross margin per year in = 64
Bee
Honey produced per year = 8 kg
Gross margin per year =80
Appendix 7: Number of days, working hours, available labor force and oxen power.
Jan. Feb Ma Apr Ma Jun July Au Sep Oct No Dec
Total days 31 28 31 30 31 30 31 31 30 31 30 31
Working day 16 13 16 14 16 15 16 12 14 16 15 16
Av. working 6 6 6 6 6 8 8 8 8 8 8 8
hour per day
Available human labor
HIG 360 293 360 315 360 450 480 360 420 480 450 480
LIG 258 210 258 226 258 323 344 258 301 344 323 344
Available oxen power
HIG 336 258
LIG 148 114
134
Ja. Fe. Ma Apr. May June Jul. Aug Sep. Oct. Nov Dec.
wheat HH TT TT PP PP SS SS SW ww ww
Teff HT TT PP PP PS SW ww ww
Barley TT PP PP PP PS SS ww ww HH HH
Wassera HT TT PP PP PP SS SS ww ww
Beans PP SS S HH
Peas PP SS S HH
Lentil PP SS S HH
Grass pea HH HH PP SS
Where HH: harvesting, SS: Sowing, PP: plowing, WW: weeding, TT: Threshing.
135
Appendix 9: Questionnaire used for data collection.
1. General Information
Name of the wereda __________ Name of the kebele ________ Village name ____________
Name of the farmer __________Date of contact _________Name of enuminator_________
Nearest market name: a) for crop___________ b) for livestock__________
Transportation facilities Km(hour) ________________ _________
Participated in extension and production program or not _______ if participated When_________
2. Demographic characteristics
a) Household situation of the farmer.
Name of the family Age in years Sex Relation to the Occupation Marital status
member head
4. Farming practices
a) Indicate the production method practiced ___________________________________
b) Indicate the topography of the farm (each field)_______________________________
c) Measures to maintain soil fertility (fallowing, guie, chemical fertilizer, animal manure,
green manure etc.), which one of them is priority importance, _____________________
d) Indicate the field number that is more affected by soil erosion ____________________
e) Indicate the measures under taken __________________________________________
f) Importance of the measure _______________________________________________
136
g) Do you practice crop rotation _____________________________________________
- Indicate the usual sequence in cropping activities _______________________________
-Why you choose this practice ______________________________________________
h) Soil type _____________________________________________________________
-Causes of soil erosion _________________________________________________
-Effect of soil erosion __________________________________________________
-Period of siol erosion __________________________________________________
-Are they aware of the problem __________________________________________
I) Type of permanent tree
Amount/size ___________________
Income ____________ If no why? ____________________
5. Labor condition
a) Human labor
- Number of working days in each month ____________
- Is there human labor shortage/Surplus? _______ when it occurs? _______
In which type of farming is serious labor shortage occurred? _______________
What are the solutions to the shortage _________________________________
-Farm operation on monthly basis
Farm operation Months
Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June Jul. Aug. Sep Oct Nov. Dec.
b) Animal power
Types of activities Type of animal Number Hours used
137
6. Livestock situation
a) Livestock herd amount.
c) Livestock products
138
row planting ( rate)_____________
filling (rate)___________________
Amount of seed
___________ local_____________ improved
Fertilization
DAP _____ Urea _______ Manure ________ Other _________
8. Consumption condition.
Household food requirement____________________________________________
Amount used/ utilized_____________________________________________
How can you meet the additional requirement
Purchase
Source of money _______________ Amount__________________
Other
Source of money _______________ Amount__________________
9. Market situation.
a) Selling activity
Types of product sold Unit price ______________ Total value __________________
b) Purchasing activities
-Types of input purchased purpose_______ Unit price ______ Total value __________
-Farm implements purpose _______ Unit price ______ Total value __________
139
Source of fund Purpose Amount interest rate
_____________ _______ _________ _________
_____________ _______ _________ _________
Indicate who works for how often and for what purpose
O O O O O O O O O O O O O S S S S S S S S S S S
W W W T T B B W W H F L G W W W T H B W W F L G
H H H E E A A A A B P E P H H H E B A A A P E P
P W W F F R R S S E E N E P W W F E R S S E N E
F F F F L L P W A A T A F F F A L P W A T A
P I P W P W F P P P P P I P P P F P P P
S F F P S P
P P P P
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4
1 OCLAND 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
2 SCLAND 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
3 PLAND
4 EQUAL
5 LAB1 + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + +
140
6 LAB2 + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + +
7 LAB3 + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + +
8 LAB4 + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + +
9 OXLAB1 + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + +
10 OXLAB2 + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + +
11 W/CAP + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + +
12 OWHY -
13 OWHWFY -
14 OWHWFISY -
15 OTEFFY -
16 OTEFFWFY -
17 OBARLY -
18 OBARLWFY -
19 OWASY -
20 OWASWFY -
21 OHBEAY -
22 OFPEAY -
23 OLENTY -
24 OGPEAY -
25 SWHY -
26 SWHWFY -
27 SWHWFISY -
28 STEFFY -
29 SBARLY -
30 SBARLWFY -
31 SWASY -
32 SWASWFY -
33 SHBEAY -
34 SFPEAY -
35 SLENTY -
36 SGPEAY -
37 OSTROWY - - - - - - - - - - - - -
38 SSTROWY - - - - - - - - - - -
39 PASTY
O OO O O O O O O O O SO O S S S S S S S S S S
W WW T T B B W W H F WL G W W T H B W W F L G
H HH E E A A A A B P HE P H H E B A A A P E P
P WW F F R R S S E E WN E P W F E R S S E N E
FF F F L L P W A A FT A F F A L P W A T A
IP P W P W F P P IP P P P P P F P P P
S F F P S P
P P P P
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2 2
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4
40 MILKY
41 MANURP
42 HAYY
43 COWR
44 COWC
45 OXR
141
46 OXC
47 HEIFER
48 BULLR
49 HIFERS
50 BULLS
51 LAMBP
52 BTP
53 KIDP
54 EGGP
55 HONYP
56 EQCLPY
57 WHCR
58 TEFFCR
59 BARLCR
60 WASCR
61 HBEACR
62 GPEACR
63 FPEACR
64 LENTCR
65 MANCR
66 MILKR
67 COWM
68 OXENM
69 SHEEPM
70 POLTRY
71 BHIVE
72 HORSEM
73 DONKYM
74 GOATM
OBJ. FUN. - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
O S H P E C O H B S P B H D G WT B W H G F L
S S A A Q O X E U H O H O O O H E A A B P P E
T T Y S U WC E L E L I R N A C F R S E E E N
R R P T A K F L E T V S K T F L C A A A T
O O P L R K P R E E Y C C C C C C
W W P K Y
P P
2 2 2 2 2 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4
5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
1 OCLAND
2 SCLAND
3 PLAND 1 1
4 EQUAL 1
5 LAB1 + + + + + + + + + + + + +
6 LAB2 + + + + + + + + + + + + +
7 LAB3 + + + + + + + + + + + + +
8 LAB4 + + + + + + + + + + + + +
9 OXLAB1 + + + +
142
10 OXLAB2 + + + +
11 W/CAP + + + + + + + + + + + + + +
12 OWHy
13 OWHWFY
14 OWHWFISY
15 OTEFFY
16 OTEFFWFY
17 OBARLY
18 OBARLWFY
19 OWASY
20 OWASWFY
21 OHBEAY
22 OFPEAY
23 OLENTY
24 OGPEAY
25 SWHP
26 SWHWFY
27 SWHWFISY
28 STEFFY
29 SBARLY
30 SBARLWFY
31 SWASY
32 SWASWFY
33 SHBEAY
34 SFPEAY
35 SLENTY
36 SGPEAY
37 OSTROWY - + + + + +
38 SSTROWY -
39 PASTY - + + + + + +
SKELETON OF LP. MATRICES FOR A REPRESENTATIVE FARM.
O S H P E C O H B S P B H D G W T B W H G F L
S S A A Q O X E U H O H O O O H E A A B P P E
T T Y S U W C E L E L I R N A C F R S E E E N
R R P T A K F L E T V S K T F L C A A A T
O O P L R K P R E E Y C C C C C C
W W P K Y
P P
2 2 2 2 2 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4
5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
40 MILKY -
41 MANURP - - - - - - - -
42 HAYY - + + +
43 COWR + -1
44 COWC -
45 OXR - +
46 OXC
47 HEIFER - 1
48 BULLR - 1
49 HIFERS -
50 BULLS -
143
51 LAMBP -1
52 BTP
53 KIDP -1
54 EGGP -1
55 HONYP -1
56 EQCLPY -1
57 WHCR 1
58 TEFFCR 1
59 BARLCR 1
60 WASCR 1
61 HBEACR 1
62 GPEACR 1
63 FPEACR 1
64 LENTCR 1
65 MANCR
66 MILKCR +
67 COWM 1
68 OXENM 1
69 SHEEPM 1
70 POLTRY 1
71 BHIVE 1
72 HORSEM 1
73 DONKYM 1
74 GOATM 1
OBJ. FUN. - - - - - - - - - - -
M M WT B W H F L G C
S C S G H B L B K E H E
A I H E A A B P E P O
S C H O E U A T I G O Q
N L S F R S E E N E X
T O E A I L M P D G N U
U K F L S A A T A S
R W E T F L B S S S Y A
B C S S S S S S O S P S E S S S L
W S R P
T S S
4 4 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 7 6 6
8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 3 4 5 6 7 8 0 RHS 2 9
1 OCLAND ≤
2 SCLAND ≤
3 PLAND ≤
4 EQUAL ≤
5 LAB1 + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + ≤
6 LAB2 + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + ≤
7 LAB3 + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + ≤
8 LAB4 + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + ≤
9 OXLAB1 ≤
10 OXLAB2 ≤
11 W/CAP ≤
12 OWHY 1 ≤
144
13 OWHWFY 1 ≤
14 OWHWFISY 1 ≤
15 OTEFFY 1 ≤
16 OTEFFWFY 1 ≤
17 OBARLY 1 ≤
18 OBARLWFY 1 ≤
19 OWASY 1 ≤
20 OWASWFY 1 ≤
21 OHBEAY 1 ≤
22 OFPEAY 1 ≤
23 OLENTY 1 ≤
24 OGPEAY 1 ≤
25 SWHPY 1 ≤
26 SWHWFY 1 ≤
27 SWHWFISY 1 ≤
28 STEFFY 1 ≤
29 SBARLY 1 ≤
30 SBARLWFY 1 ≤
31 SWASY 1 ≤
32 SWASWFY 1 ≤
33 SHBEAY 1 ≤
34 SFPEAY 1 ≤
35 SLENTY 1 ≤
36 SGPEAY 1 ≤
37 OSTROWY ≤
38 SSTROWY ≤
39 PASTY ≤
SKELETON OF LP. MATRICES FOR A REPRESENTATIVE FARM.
M MWT B WH F
H L G C C S G B L B K
E E H S
A I H E A A B P
E E P O C H O U A T I
Q G O S
N L S F R S E E
I N E X O E A L M P D
U G N T
U K F L S A A
F T A S W E T L B S S
A S Y R
B C S S S S
E S S S P S S S L S O
R S P W
S S T
4 4 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 7 RHS
8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0
40 MILKY 1 ≤
41 MANURP 1 ≤
42 HAYY ≤
43 COWR ≤
44 COWC 1 ≤
45 OXR ≤
46 OXC 1 ≤
47 HEIFER 1 ≤
48 BULLR 1 ≤
49 HIFERS ≤
50 BULLS ≤
51 LAMBP 1 ≤
145
52 BTP 1 ≤
53 KIDP 1 ≤
54 EGGP 1 ≤
55 HONYP 1 ≤
56 EQCLPY 1 ≤
57 WHCR ≥
58 TEFFCR ≥
59 BARLCR ≥
60 WASCR ≥
61 HBEACR ≥
62 GPEACR ≥
63 FPEACR ≥
64 LENTCR ≥
65 MANCR 1 ≥
66 MILKR 1 ≥
67 COWM ≤
68 OXENM ≤
69 SHEEPM ≤
70 POLTRY ≤
71 BHIVE ≤
72 HORSEM ≤
73 DONKYM ≤
74 GOATM ≤
OBJ.FUN. + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + + +
Activities
146
21. SHBEAP Share horse bean production
22. SFPEAP Share field peas production
23. SLENTYP Share lentil production
24. SGPEAYP Share grass pea production
25. OSTROWP Own strow production
26. SSTROWP Share strow production
27. HAYP Hay production
28. PASTP Pasture production
29. EQUALP Equaluptus production
30. COWK Cow keeping
31. OXC Oxen keeping
32. HEEFRK Heifer keeping
33. BULLK Bull keeping
34. SHEEP Sheep keeping
35. POLTRY Poltry keeping
36. BHIVE Beehivekeeping
37. HORSE Horsekeeping
38. DONKY Donkeykeeping
49. GOAT Goatkeeping
40. WHC Wheat consumption
41. TEFFC Teff consumption
42. BARLC Barly consumption
43. WASC Wassera consumption
44. HBEAC Horse bean consumption
45. GPEAC Grass pea consumption
46. FPEAC Feild pea consumption
47. LENTC Lentil consumption
48. MANUB Manure Burnning.
49. MILKC Milk consumption
50. WHS Wheat Salling
51.TEFFS Teff Salling
52. BARLS Barly Salling
53. WASS Wassera Salling
54. HBEAS Horse bean Salling
55. GPEAS Grass pea Salling
56. FPEAS Feild pea Salling
57. LENTS Lentil Salling
58. CCOWS Culled Cow Salling
59. COXS Culled Ox Salling
60. SHEEPS Sheep salling
61. GOATS Goat Salling
62. HEEFRS Heifer Salling
63. BULLS Bull Salling
64. LAMBS Lamb Salling
65. BTPS Butter produced Salling
66.KIDS Kids Salling
67. EGGS Egg Salling
68. HONYS Honey Salling
147
69. EQUALS Equaluptus Salling
70. SSTROWT Share strow transfer.
LIST OF CONSTRAINTS
149