Economics 101 (PDFDrive)
Economics 101 (PDFDrive)
101
FROM CONSUMER BEHAVIOR TO
COMPETITIVE MARKETS—EVERYTHING YOU
NEED TO KNOW ABOUT ECONOMICS
ALFRED MILL
Avon, Massachusetts
CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION
WHAT IS ECONOMICS?
CONTROLLING COSTS
PERFECT COMPETITION IN THE SHORT RUN
GAME THEORY
PRICING BEHAVIORS
MARKET FAILURES
FINANCIAL MARKETS AND LOANABLE FUNDS THEORY
APPROACHES TO GDP
REAL GDP CHANGES AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE
UNEMPLOYMENT DEFINED
UNEMPLOYMENT CLASSIFIED
TYPES OF INFLATION
MACROECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM
THE KEYNESIAN VIEW AND FISCAL POLICY
SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMICS
ECONOMIC GROWTH
CONDITIONS FOR ECONOMIC GROWTH
HOW ECONOMIC POLICY AFFECTS GROWTH
Why you can have too much of a good thing. (Utility is diminishing).
Why unemployment by any other name is probably not unemployment.
Why what is true in the long run might not be true in the short run.
Why policymakers who manage expectations can manage reality.
Why, if given a choice between inflation and deflation, you should choose
inflation.
Why individuals are better at managing their finances than are
governments.
You open the door to your fridge and gaze at the food inside and declare,
“There’s nothing to eat in this house.” Later, you walk into a closet full of
clothes and then think, “I have nothing to wear.” You are faced with scarcity.
You never have enough of what you need or want. The fact is, you have plenty
to eat and many clothes to wear. You chose to ignore the options you faced then
and there, but eventually you know you will relent and eat the apple next to the
shriveled grapes at the bottom of the bin, and then put on the shirt and pants you
hate. You are a creature of economics. Given scarcity, you look at the choices
you face, evaluate, and then choose.
STUDYING SCARCITY
Economics is the study of how individuals, institutions, and society choose to
deal with the condition of scarcity. It is fascinating to see how people react to
scarcity. Some create complex plans and systems to make sure that everyone
gets their fair share of scarce resources. Others make things up as they go along.
Everybody practices economics on a daily basis. From a single individual to the
largest society on earth, people are constantly engaged in the struggle to survive,
make ends meet, and even thrive given the relative scarcity they face.
Economics has been around a long time, though it has not always
been known by that name. Philosophers studied scarcity and choice
been known by that name. Philosophers studied scarcity and choice
long before the field was so named. The father of modern
economics, Adam Smith, was considered a moral philosopher, not
an economist.
The people who study these choices are economists. The field of economics is
huge because people have an immense range of choices. Some economists study
the decision-making of individuals and institutions; others study how nations
handle scarcity. Economists develop theories to explain the behavior of whatever
it is they are studying. Some of these theories are then tested against real-world
data, and sometimes these theories are put into practice without ever being
tested. Economists work for universities, financial institutions, major
corporations, and governments.
MICROECONOMICS
The field of microeconomics focuses its attention on the decision-making of
individuals and businesses. Microeconomics is primarily concerned with
markets for goods, services, and resources. Markets are central to understanding
microeconomics. Whenever and wherever buyers and sellers come together to
exchange resources, goods, or services, a market is created and the behavior of
these markets is of particular interest to economists. Are they functioning
efficiently? Do participants have access to adequate information? Who and how
many participate in the market? How do the decisions made in one market
impact the decisions in a related market?
MACROECONOMICS
SCARCITY
Without scarcity there would be no need for the study of economics. For that
matter, if scarcity did not exist, there would be no need for this book. You’re not
that lucky, however. Scarcity is the universal condition that exists because there
is not enough time, money, or stuff to satisfy everyone’s needs or wants. The
stuff that everyone wants is made from resources. In an effort to make
economics sound more “economic-y,” resources are referred to as the factors of
production. The factors of production include land, labor, capital, and
entrepreneurship.
Scarcity exists for everyone. From rich to poor, all face the condition.
Scarcity in America looks different from scarcity in Somalia to be
sure. Here, there is plenty of food and clean water, but in Somalia
both are lacking. Scarcity isn’t just a function of limited resources,
but also of unlimited wants, and that is something both America and
Somalia share.
Somalia share.
Land is inclusive of all natural resources and not just some random piece of
property. Trees, mineral deposits, fish in the ocean, ground water, and plain
old land are all included. Land can be divided into renewable and
nonrenewable natural resources. Renewable resources, like pine trees and
chickens, are easily replenished. Nonrenewable resources, like oil and
Atlantic cod, are difficult to replenish. The payment for land is referred to
as rent.
Labor refers to people with their skills and abilities. Labor is divided into
unskilled, skilled, and professional. Unskilled labor refers to people without
formal training who are paid wages to do repetitive tasks like make
hamburgers or perform assembly-line production. Skilled labor refers to
people paid wages for what they know and what they can do. Welders,
electricians, plumbers, mechanics, and carpenters are examples of skilled
laborers. Professional laborers are paid wages for what they know. Doctors,
lawyers, engineers, scientists, and even teachers are included in this
category.
Capital in economics does not refer to money, but to all of the tools,
factories, and equipment used in the production process. Capital is the
product of investment. Stop. Isn’t that confusing? Up until now you have
probably lived a happy life thinking that capital was money and that
investing is what you do in the stock market. Well, sorry. Capital is
physical stuff used to make other stuff, and investment is the money spent
on buying that stuff. To make capital, you have to have capital. Because
capital is always purchased with borrowed money, it incurs an interest
payment.
Money Talks
allocation
allocation
Economists describe getting the right resources to the right people
as allocation. Allocative efficiency occurs when marginal benefit
equals marginal cost. When this condition is met, the greatest
benefit accrues to society.
TRADE-OFFS AND
OPPORTUNITY COST
Making an Assumption Out of You and Me
MARGINAL ANALYSIS
Economists like to think of people as little computers who always count the
benefit of their decisions versus the cost of those decisions. Because you usually
make decisions one at a time, economists refer to the benefit of a decision as
marginal benefit. Marginal benefit can be measured in dollars or utils, whichever
you prefer. Utils are the amount of utility or happiness you get from doing
something. They can be converted into dollars easily.
Say that you like to swim laps in the pool for an hour. How many utils do you
receive from swimming laps? How much would you have to be paid to not swim
laps? If your friend were to keep offering you ever-increasing amounts of money
to not swim in the pool, then it is probably safe to assume that the dollar amount
you accept to not swim in the pool is at least equal to the amount of happiness or
utility you would have received had you taken a swim. If it takes $20 to keep
you from swimming, then you value swimming no more than $20. Swimming is
worth 20 utils to you.
Marginal cost is a related concept. Marginal cost is simply what it costs to
either produce or consume one extra unit of whatever it is you are producing or
consuming. Go back to the swimming example. Assume that swimming in the
pool has a marginal cost of $5. If you earn 20 utils from swimming, would you
pay $5 to earn $20 worth of benefit? Of course you would. Now assume that
swimming in the pool costs $20.01. Would you spend $20.01 to earn $20 worth
of benefit? Probably not. Economists conclude that you will swim as long as the
marginal benefit exceeds or equals the marginal cost. For you that means you
will swim as long as the marginal cost is less than or equal to $20. If the
marginal benefit outweighs the marginal cost, you would probably do it. If the
marginal benefit is less than the marginal cost, you probably would not do it. If
the marginal benefit equals the marginal cost, it means you are indifferent.
ASSUMPTIONS IN ECONOMICS
Economists make certain assumptions when they’re talking about their favorite
subject. They expect you to know (and agree with) these assumptions. The three
big ones are:
The assumptions economists make are subject to criticism and debate. Many
critics believe that the field has a tendency to be too abstract and theoretical to
have any real-world value. The failure of most economists to predict the most
recent economic downturn seems to support the view that economics ignores
human psychology at its own peril.
Economics is at a turning point as a field of study, and the assumptions that
economists hold dear need to be carefully examined. Instead of being tidy,
abstract, and mathematical like physics, economics must become a little more
messy, complex, and organic, like biology.
Money Talks
consumption
Household spending on new domestic goods and services.
THE EMERGENCE OF FREE
TRADE AND THE IMPORTANCE
OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE
Why All Roads Lead to Rome
For as long as there have been people, there has been trade. At
first, trade was a simple matter. For example, people in a family
exchanged food with their neighbors. Over time, trade expanded as
people were exposed to new goods from faraway places and
developed a taste for them. As tribes became kingdoms and
kingdoms became empires, trade grew in importance. This growth in
trade led to the emergence of the influential merchant class. These
merchants braved hardships in search of profit, and their activities
helped to form the modern world. Although the scale of trade has
grown incredibly throughout history, what has not changed is that
trade always occurs between individuals.
MERCANTILISM
FREE TRADE
Absolute Advantage
An absolute advantage exists if you can produce more of a good or service
than someone else, or if you can produce that good or service faster than
someone else. An absolute advantage implies that you are more efficient, that is,
able to produce more with the same amount of resources. For example, Art can
write one hit song per hour, whereas Paul can write two hit songs per hour. Thus,
Paul has an absolute advantage in songwriting.
Comparative Advantage
A comparative advantage exists if you can produce a good at a lower
opportunity cost than someone else. In other words, if you sacrifice less of one
good or service to produce another good or service, then you have a comparative
advantage. In the example given earlier, Art and Paul are songwriters, but what
if both are also capable of performing complex brain surgery? If Art and Paul
can both successfully complete two brain surgeries in an hour, then which has a
comparative advantage in songwriting, and which has a comparative advantage
in brain surgery?
To calculate the comparative advantage, you must determine the opportunity
cost that each person faces when producing. In Art’s case, for every hit song he
cost that each person faces when producing. In Art’s case, for every hit song he
writes, he sacrifices two successful brain surgeries. In an hour, Paul can produce
either two hit songs or two brain surgeries. This means that Paul sacrifices one
brain surgery for every hit song he writes, and therefore, has the comparative
advantage in songwriting. Art, on the other hand, has the comparative advantage
in brain surgery because for every brain surgery he performs, he only sacrifices
half of a hit song, compared to Paul, who sacrifices a whole hit song for the
same surgery. In conclusion, Art should specialize in brain surgery and Paul in
songwriting because that is where they find their comparative advantage.
The theory of comparative advantage allows you to better understand how the
American economy has changed over the last sixty years. In that time period, the
United States transitioned from a low-skilled, manufacturing economy to a high-
skilled, diversified economy. Sixty years ago, most of your clothes would have
been produced domestically, but today the tags on your clothing indicate that
they were manufactured in places as diverse as Vietnam, Bangladesh, Honduras,
Morocco, and of course, China.
In the same time period, a great wave of technological innovation and other
cultural advances have taken place. For example, if you were to poll a group of
cultural advances have taken place. For example, if you were to poll a group of
high school freshman about their post–high school plans sixty years ago and
another group today, you would likely discover that today’s students are far
more likely to pursue higher education than they were in the 1940s and 1950s. In
the past, dropping out of high school and working at the mill or the factory was
the norm; today, dropping out of high school is cause for concern. There are
more jobs as well as more job titles than there were sixty years ago. In other
words, there are greater opportunities today than there were sixty years ago. Of
course, this comes with one major catch: You must have the education or
training in order to take advantage of the opportunity.
So what does this have to do with comparative advantage? An example might
help. Consider 100 typical American high school students and then consider 100
young people of the same age in Bangladesh. In which country is the opportunity
cost of producing a T-shirt higher? If you look at the American students, you
would have to agree that they have more opportunities than the Bangladeshi.
When Americans specialize in T-shirts, more potential doctors, nurses, teachers,
engineers, mechanics, firefighters, police officers, business managers,
machinists, and social workers are sacrificed than in Bangladesh, where the
majority of workers will most likely become subsistence farmers. The
opportunity cost of producing T-shirts is much lower in Bangladesh than in
America, and therefore Bangladesh has a comparative advantage in producing T-
shirts. Even though the United States has the capacity to produce T-shirts more
efficiently (absolute advantage), from an economic standpoint, it makes sense to
trade pharmaceuticals, refined chemicals, capital equipment, and know-how for
T-shirts.
INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND
TRADE BARRIERS
Free Trade Without Borders
When trade is both voluntary and free, the buyer and the seller both benefit (if
you buy a quart of milk, the dairy farmer gets money and you get milk without
having to milk a cow). Because voluntary free trade is mutually beneficial, it
creates wealth. Wealth is nothing more than the collective value of all you own.
In an interesting experiment from the Foundation for Teaching Economics, a
group of participants were each given a random object to which they assigned a
value. Then the group traded their objects freely. Soon after, participants were
again asked to assign a value to the object in their possession. The sum of the
second set of values was greater than the first. Without anything new being
added, wealth was (and is) created through the simple act of voluntary free trade.
INTERNATIONAL TRADE
When you trade with people in other countries, the same results of mutual
benefit and wealth creation occur. Prior to World War II, trade agreements
between nations were for the most part bilateral, that is, between the two parties,
with special interests protected and trade barriers (such as taxes on imports and
exports) common. The benefits of free trade were not realized, and nations
drifted toward isolationism and protectionism.
Toward the end of World War II, representatives from much of the
industrialized free world gathered in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, to address
the economic issues that were often the cause of international conflict. The
conference produced the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World
conference produced the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World
Bank, but not a trade organization for encouraging international cooperation. In
1947, many nations including the United States came together and formed the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). The goal of GATT was to
reduce trade barriers so that member countries could equally enjoy the benefits
of free trade.
The growth in international trade was accompanied by a rise in living
standards among the members of the agreement. In 1995, the GATT became the
World Trade Organization (WTO). Under GATT and later the WTO, more and
more countries have become supporters of fewer barriers to trade. As a result,
international trade has continued to expand, and many nations have reaped the
benefits. For example, since joining the EU and opening itself to international
trade, Ireland has gone from being one of Europe’s poorest countries to one of
its wealthiest.
From time to time, countries will seek to tax, limit, or even ban international
trade. Why? Even though voluntary trade is mutually beneficial, the benefits are
spread out over society, and the costs are sometimes borne directly by a specific
group. People might have a strong interest in preserving their industry, raising
tax revenue, saving the environment, or even creating social change. At times a
country might limit trade in order to punish another country. Tariffs, quotas, and
embargoes are a few of the tools that a country will use in order to accomplish
these other interests.
Tariffs
A tariff is a tax on trade. Tariffs can be used to raise revenue for the
government or in order to benefit a certain segment of the economy. You might
pressure Congress to enact a tariff on imports if your industry is subject to
foreign competition. For example, for years the U.S. steel industry was protected
from cheap foreign competition by protective tariffs. In 2007, India proposed a
tariff on rice exports in order to prevent food shortages. The Smoot-Hawley
tariff of 1930 was intended to protect American industry and raise much-needed
tax revenue for the government.
Tariffs are not without their downsides:
Quotas
Quotas are limits on trade. Instead of a tax on imports, you might use a quota
to limit the number of imported goods coming into your country. In the 1970s
and 1980s, U.S. automobile manufacturers and labor unions supported
government quotas on foreign car imports to limit competition and preserve
American jobs. The result was higher prices and lower quality.
Money Talks
price
The monetary amount for which consumers and producers buy and
sell some quantity of a good or service.
They do not generate tax revenue for the government, but do create more
responsibility.
They provide an incentive to smuggle goods illegally in order to avoid the
quota, thus creating black markets.
In addition, quotas may be manipulated by foreign firms to limit
competition from other foreign firms. For example, if there is a quota on
German cars imported into the United States, then the German firm that
first fills the quota has effectively blocked other German firms from
competing in the American market.
Embargoes
An embargo is a ban on trade with another country. The purpose of an
embargo is usually to punish a country for some offense. The embargo you may
be most familiar with is America’s embargo against Cuba. In the wake of the
communist revolution, and later the Cuban Missile Crisis, the United States
enacted an embargo that banned all trade with the island nation. Even though the
events are now far in the past, the embargo persists. Once again, you might
consider who benefits from the trade embargo in order to understand why it is
still in place.
TRADITIONAL ECONOMIES,
COMMAND ECONOMIES, AND
MARKET ECONOMIES
That’s Not the Way We Do Things!
Why are some countries so rich and others so poor? Does the presence of
abundant natural resources account for a country’s wealth? Why is there such a
lack of economic development among different indigenous groups around the
world? How important is government to an economy and what are the
government’s appropriate economic roles? A study of different economic
systems will shed some light.
1. What to produce?
2. How to produce?
3. Whom to produce for?
Traditional Economies
In a traditional economic system, the questions of what and how to produce
and whom to produce for are answered by tradition. If you’ve seen a
documentary on a primitive culture, then you’ve also seen a traditional economy
in action. The Kalahari Bushmen live in one of the world’s harshest
environments, where even the most basic resources are in meager supply. In
order to survive and have enough food, the Bushmen have developed a division
of labor based on gender. Women perform the food gathering and men perform
the hunting. The food is then shared with the whole tribe. In this type of system,
stability and continuity are favored over innovation and change. The roles of the
people are defined by gender and status in the community. In this system, the
old, young, weak, and disabled are cared for by the group. The group shares the
few possessions they have, and private property is an alien concept. For the most
part, everyone in this system understands his or her relationship to the
community, and as a result, life hums along in a fairly predictable way.
Command Economies
Command Economies
As hunter-gatherer societies grew and eventually exhausted their natural food
supplies, some survived by becoming sedentary farmers. With the advent of
farming came a need for an organized system of planting, harvesting, and storing
crops. This required a greater amount of structure than existed in a traditional
economy. In order to ensure the survival of the society, decisions had to be made
about what crops to grow and how much of the harvest to store. Over time,
decision-making became centralized, and the command economic system
developed. The key characteristic of the command economy is centralized
decision-making. One leader (or a group of powerful individuals) makes the key
economic decisions for the entire society.
Examples of command systems include most, if not all, ancient civilizations,
plus the communist countries of today. The pharaohs of Egypt represent the
centralized decision-making present in a command economy. The pharaoh and
his various officials made the key economic decisions of what to produce, how
to produce, and for whom to produce. The decisions might have gone something
like this, “I command you to construct a big pyramid of brick and mortar using
slaves for labor, and all of it is for me.” The advantage of this type of system is
the ability for decision-makers to produce rapid changes in their society. For
example, Soviet dictator Josef Stalin’s five-year plans quickly transformed the
Soviet Union from a peasant-based agrarian society into one of the world’s
industrial superpowers.
At Your Command
During World War II, the United States practiced command economy
when the government took over factories and planned production for
the war effort. Every aspect of American life was in some way
influenced by government involvement in the economy. Even today
you can see the influence. The modern payroll withholding system
was instituted during the war to provide the government with a
steady stream of tax revenue.
Market Economies
In total contrast to the command economic system is the market economy.
Market economies are characterized by a complete lack of centralized decision-
making. As opposed to top-down planning, market economies operate bottom-
up. Individuals trying to satisfy their own self-interest answer the questions of
what, how, and for whom to produce. Private citizens, acting on their own free
will as buyers or sellers, trade their resources or finished products in the market
in order to increase their own well-being. Though it might appear
counterintuitive, market economies achieve greater abundance, variety, and
satisfaction than either traditional or command economic systems.
Although they cannot be classified as pure market systems, Hong Kong, the
United States, Australia, and New Zealand are representative of market
economies. In each you will see a greater variety of goods and services being
produced than anywhere else. Also, because the focus is not on serving the state,
individuals are free to choose their vocation, own private property, and
determine for themselves how to best use the resources they possess. Markets
reward innovation, productivity, and efficiency but discourage complacency,
idleness, and waste. If markets have a downside, it is that those who are unable
or unwilling to produce because of either circumstance or choice are often
sidelined and unable to enjoy the benefits of the system.
Money Talks
productivity
The amount of output produced with a given amount of resources.
CAPITALISM VERSUS
SOCIALISM
Adam Smith and Karl Marx Duke It Out
Today, traditional economies are few and far between, command economies are
waning, and pure market economies are nonexistent. What does exist is a variety
of command and market systems; in effect, economic hybrids. The two most
common economic hybrids are socialism and capitalism. Imagine an economic
continuum with a pure command economic system on the left and a pure market
system on the right. If you were to arrange modern nations along this continuum,
toward the far left would be places like North Korea and Iran, in the middle
would appear many western European and Latin American nations, and to the
right would appear many former British colonies, such as the United States,
Australia, and Hong Kong. For all practical purposes, those nations on the left
were described in the discussion on command economies. However, the middle
and the right of the continuum represent the dichotomy of socialism and
capitalism.
regulate markets
preserve competition
subsidize and tax firms
enforce private contracts
redistribute income from workers to non-workers
For example, the U.S. government creates rules for the labor market, breaks
up monopolies, subsidizes some farmers, taxes polluters, hears cases involving
breaches of contract, and collects Social Security taxes.
In socialism, the government takes a much more active role in the economy.
Although individuals are allowed private property, the state may own firms in
key industries and regulate even more economic decisions than in capitalism. In
France it is not uncommon for the government to take a major stake in French
companies, if not outright own them. The French labor market is more heavily
regulated than its American counterpart. In 2006, French students poured into
the streets, protesting the fact that the government was being pressured by
French firms for the right to fire employees at will during their first two years of
employment. Compare this to the United States, where there is no guarantee of
employment.
More often than not, socialist countries manage the prices of many goods and
services. The EU manages prices on such things as pharmaceuticals, cell
telephone service, and food. Also, socialist countries are more active in taxing in
order to redistribute income from workers to non-workers. Germany is well
known for its generous cradle-to-grave social welfare system that promises care
for its citizens. The German welfare state is financed by a redistributive tax
system that many Americans would find intolerable. As of 2015, the highest
marginal tax rate on personal income in Germany was 47.5% compared to the
United States’ rate of 39.6%.
Of all humankind’s inventions, money stands out as one of the most widespread
and useful. A day probably does not go by that you don’t use it or think about it.
It’s hard to imagine a time when people didn’t have money, and it can be scary
to imagine what your life would be without it. From barter to shells to coin to
paper to digital, the story of money spans much of human history.
BARTER
Before money was invented, and in times when money was either worthless or
extremely scarce, barter was used as a means for people to get what they needed
or wanted. Barter is simply the act of exchanging one good or service for another
good or service. An example of barter is when a farmer trades a dozen chicken
eggs with a baker for a fresh loaf of bread. Although barter was more common in
the past, it still exists today.
Barter is not without its downsides. Obviously, trade will not occur unless
both parties want what the other party has to offer. This is referred to as the
double coincidence of wants. In the example of the farmer and baker, if the
baker has no need or desire for eggs, then the farmer is out of luck and does not
get any bread. However, if the farmer is enterprising and utilizes his network of
village friends, he might discover that the baker is in need of some new cast-iron
trivets for cooling his bread, and it just so happens that the blacksmith needs a
new lamb’s wool sweater. Upon further investigation, the farmer discovers that
the weaver has been craving an omelet for the past week. The farmer will then
the weaver has been craving an omelet for the past week. The farmer will then
trade the eggs for the sweater, the sweater for the trivets, and the trivets for his
fresh-baked loaf of bread. Whew! There has got to be an easier way to do things.
The previous example illustrates the need for a more efficient means of
exchanging goods and services. As a result of the downsides to barter, cultures
in different times and places eventually developed money.
medium of exchange when it is being used for the purpose of buying and
selling goods or services.
store of value when you get it today and are still able to use it later.
standard of value when you are using it to measure how much a good or
service is worth.
Portability refers to the ease with which money can be carried from place to
place.
Durability means that when you forget to remove it from your pocket
before doing the laundry, you do not wind up broke.
Divisibility means your money can be broken into smaller units and end up
finding its way between the cushions of your couch.
Stability exists when money’s value does not vary too much (a dollar today
buys pretty much the same amount of something as it did last week and will
next week).
Acceptability means people agree that the money represents what it is
supposed to represent and are willing to exchange goods and services for it.
Nonportable Money
The Pacific island of Yap is known for its money, which is decidedly
not portable. Large rounded stones weighing hundreds of pounds
are used as a medium of exchange. If you plan on visiting Yap, wait
until you are there to exchange your currency because it will not fit
under the seat or in the overhead compartment of an airliner.
Commodity Money
When relatively scarce minerals, metals, or agricultural products are used as a
means of exchange, they are considered commodity money. Gold and silver
struck into coins are examples of commodity money. An advantage of
commodity money is that it can be used for purposes other than money. In the
1980s, many women adorned themselves in jewelry featuring gold coins, such as
the Chinese Panda or the Canadian Maple Leaf. American colonists not only
smoked tobacco, but they also used it as money. The salt we take for granted
was at one time scarce enough that Roman soldiers were paid in it. On the other
hand, a commodity’s usefulness also makes it a disadvantage to using it as
money. If a country is dependent upon using a commodity for its money and as a
resource, then money may be too precious to spend.
Representative Money
Representative money developed as an alternative to commodity money. One
of the properties of gold is its high density. Transactions requiring large amounts
of gold would have been unpleasant due to it being extremely heavy and difficult
to transport. Goldsmiths offered a solution to this problem. By issuing receipts
for gold they had on deposit, representative paper money was born. Instead of
trading the physical gold, all people had to do was trade the receipts for the gold.
Whenever they wanted the actual gold, they could redeem their receipts. After
years of acceptance, people became more comfortable with the idea of
representative paper money and the concept stuck.
The inconvertible fiat standard that exists today addresses the weakness of the
gold standard. The gold standard’s major disadvantage is that it acts as a limit on
economic growth. According to economist Adam Smith, wealth is not a function
of how much gold or silver a country has, but is rather the sum of all the goods
and services an economy produces. It makes sense that the amount of money an
economy has should in some way reflect its capacity to produce wealth. As
businesses expand, they require money in order to purchase the tools, factories,
and equipment necessary to meet both their productive needs and the demand for
their goods and services. Because it is not backed by anything real or tangible,
the money supply is able to grow as the economy grows.
Promises, Promises
Promises, Promises
Money is debt. The U.S. dollar is a promise to pay from the U.S.
Federal Reserve to the holder. You might ask, “A promise to pay
what?” The answer is another dollar.
When you stop to think about it, the inconvertible fiat standard sounds like
science fiction. Today’s money is intrinsically worthless and is only redeemable
for more of the same. The system works because the government says so and
everyone collectively believes it. Money is backed by nothing more than faith.
When you think about direct deposit, online bill payments, debit cards, and
checks, the idea of money is weirder still. You work, pay your bills, buy your
groceries, and manage to survive and even thrive in the economy, yet you can go
for days or weeks without even touching, seeing, or smelling money. Money is
imaginary. Ponder your bank account. There are not little stacks of dollar bills
sitting in the bank vault with your name on them. Instead, checking and savings
accounts are nothing more than information stored on computers.
Noncirculating “Money”
The currency and coin inside of a bank is not counted in the M1.
Why not? Because it’s not money until you walk out of the bank. So
technically, it is inaccurate for a bank robber to demand money while
in a bank.
in a bank.
Changes in the M1 and M2 are monitored by the Fed and act as indicators of
economic activity. Sudden changes in the ratio of M1 to M2 might indicate
either imminent inflation or recession. In general, if the M1 grows faster than the
combined rate of labor force and productivity growth, then inflation will result.
If, however, the M2 were to suddenly grow at the expense of M1 because people
are saving and not spending, then that would tend to indicate that the economy is
headed toward recession.
THE TIME VALUE OF MONEY
AND INTEREST RATES
Carpe Diem!
PRINCIPLES OF INTEREST
Interest is nothing more than a payment for using money. An interest rate is the
price of using money. What determines this price? It helps to think of an interest
rate as a set of blocks stacked upon each other. These blocks include:
opportunity cost
expected inflation rate
default risk premium
liquidity premium
maturity risk premium
Many older Americans can remember a time in the late 1970s and
early 1980s when interest rates on loans like home mortgages were
as high as 20%. Compared to today’s low rates, that is quite a
difference. The explanation for the difference is inflation. Interest
rates include a premium for inflation. So even though your savings is
earning a much lower rate today, when you adjust for inflation, the
differences pretty much disappear.
Expected Inflation Rate
While the basic interest rate of 2% may repay you for your opportunity cost, it
doesn’t account for inflation, which will eat away at that return. So, the second
block of interest represents the cost of expected inflation. Assume that inflation
has been stable for years at a rate of 3% and people are pretty confident that it
will remain at 3%. A lender or investor will cover the cost of expected inflation
and add 3% to the 2% real interest rate, to arrive at a nominal interest rate of 5%.
The nominal interest rate is the basic rate that an investor or lender will charge
for the use of money.
Liquidity Premium
If there is a chance that the investment or loan will be difficult to turn around
and sell to another lender or investor, like a ten-year car loan, another interest
block is added. This is because there’s money to be made in buying and selling
loans but not so much when those loans are for non-liquid commodities. Not
many people are willing to assume the risk of buying a loan that is backed by a
fully depreciated asset, such as a car at the end of a ten-year loan. This fourth
block is referred to as a liquidity premium. Commodities that are difficult to turn
into cash demand a higher interest rate.
Maturity Risk
One final block is added for maturity risk. As time passes, there is a chance
that interest rates will increase. If this happens, the value of the investment
that interest rates will increase. If this happens, the value of the investment
decreases, because who would want an investment that earns only 2% when you
can get a similar one that earns 4%?
So, here’s an example of how an interest rate is calculated: The real interest
rate is 2% and the inflation rate is 3%, which combine to form a 5% nominal
interest rate. Assume the risk premium is 4%, the liquidity premium is 2%, and
the maturity risk premium is 1%. The total nominal interest rate would stack up
to 12% (2% + 3% + 4% + 2% + 1%).
THE ORIGIN OF BANKING
Est. 2000 B.C.
Hushed tones, cool marble counters, the smell of cash, pens chained to tables
with blank deposit slips, solid steel doors with impressive locks, velvet-lined
cords directing customers to the appropriate teller—a bank is an important place.
Banks are everywhere. In the time it takes to walk from one Starbucks to
another, you’ll pass at least a few banks! From small towns to large cities, the
ubiquity of banks reveals their importance to the economy. Much maligned of
late, banks are an integral part of the economy. Without them, capitalism would
not function.
EARLY BANKING
The roots of banking can be traced to the earliest civilizations. The Egyptians
and early societies of the Middle East developed the prototype upon which
modern banking is based. Agricultural commodities were stored in granaries
operated by the government, and records of deposits and withdrawals were
maintained. Ancient civilization introduced the moneychangers, who would
exchange currency from different countries so that merchants, travelers, and
pilgrims could pay taxes or make religious offerings.
In the Renaissance era, Italian city-states were home to the first banks, which
financed trade, the state, and the Catholic Church. In order to avoid the Church’s
prohibition against usury (charging interest), the bankers would lend in one
currency but demand repayment in another currency. Profit was thus earned by
using different exchange rates at the time the loan was made and when it was
repaid. The successes of the Italian bankers induced a spread of banking further
repaid. The successes of the Italian bankers induced a spread of banking further
across the continent. In England, goldsmiths were responsible not only for
storing gold and issuing receipts, but also for developing what is now termed
fractional reserve banking. By issuing more receipts than there was gold on
deposit, the goldsmiths increased the profit potential of the banking industry.
From the time of the American Revolution to the Civil War, the United States
saw an expansion of relatively unregulated banking that helped finance the
growth of the young republic. Modern banking in the United States traces its
origins to the National Bank Act of 1863, which gave the government a means to
finance the Civil War.
BALANCE SHEETS
A balance sheet compares the assets a bank owns with the liabilities it owes. If
you have never taken a course in accounting, then you might not be familiar with
the following equation: Assets = Liabilities + Stockholder’s Equity. If you
haven’t fallen asleep yet, please bear with me through the following explanation:
Because assets equal liabilities plus stockholder’s equity, a bank with (for
example) $1 million in assets and $500,000 in liabilities would have $500,000 in
stockholder’s equity. Additionally, changes in a bank’s liabilities can create an
equal change in a bank’s assets. For example, if customers deposit $100,000 in a
bank (a liability), then the bank’s reserves increase by $100,000 (an asset). On
bank (a liability), then the bank’s reserves increase by $100,000 (an asset). On
the other hand, if customers withdraw $25,000, then bank reserves are reduced
by $25,000 as well.
BANK RESERVES
What exactly are bank reserves? Reserves are funds that are either available for
lending or held against checkable deposits. The reserves available for lending are
called excess reserves and those held against checkable, but not savings, deposits
are called required reserves (see sidebar, “Capital Requirements Defined”).
Required reserves are held either as cash in the bank’s vault or are deposited in
the bank’s reserve account with the Fed.
In the United States, the required reserve ratio, set by the Fed, is the
percentage of checkable deposits that a bank cannot lend. For large banks, the
required reserve ratio is 10%. Therefore, assuming a 10% required reserve ratio,
if customers deposit $100,000 into checking accounts, required reserves increase
by $10,000 and excess reserves increase by $90,000. When the economy is
healthy, banks tend to lend out all excess reserves. Why? Banks profit by
charging interest on loans, so they have a strong incentive to maximize the
charging interest on loans, so they have a strong incentive to maximize the
amount they lend.
Bank Runs
Bank runs or bank panics have occurred multiple times throughout American
history. Because banks operate with far less than 100% required reserves, it is
possible that if enough customers demand their account balances on a single day,
the bank will not be able to meet the demand. This of course would be
catastrophic for the bank and its customers. The bank would be insolvent and the
customers unable to withdraw their funds would be broke.
What would cause customers to demand their account balances all at once?
Fear, whether based in truth or not. Many bank panics have been caused because
of rumor or speculation about a bank’s financial health. If enough people believe
the rumor, they will logically want to withdraw their funds and move them to
another financial institution or stuff them under the mattress. Once the line starts
forming at the bank’s door, other customers will notice and the rumor will
spread. Banks can avert a run if they are able to borrow from other banks and
provide their customers’ balances. However, if the speculation or rumors are
pervasive, then banks may become unwilling to lend to each other. When this
happens, it sparks even more speculation, and can create a run on the entire
financial system.
Prior to the Civil War, banks were chartered by the states and were capable of
issuing their own currency. In response to the government’s need for revenue to
pay for the war, Congress passed the National Bank Act of 1863, which created
federally chartered banks capable of issuing the new national currency and
government bonds.
Money Talks
bond
A security that is a promise from a borrower to pay a lender on a
specified date with interest.
Bank Deregulation
The deregulation of banking that occurred in the late twentieth century
allowed banks to operate nationwide and also allowed them to expand the level
of services they provided. Eventually certain regulations were repealed and
banks engaged in the business of speculative investment. As the walls separating
traditional banks from bank-like institutions came down, the seeds for another
financial crisis were sowed. Today, the banking industry is in flux. A push for
regulation to prevent future bank crises exists. As the line between banks and
other financial institutions has blurred, the task for lawmakers is to create a
regulatory framework that encompasses all bank-like activities. History will
show whether or not they were successful.
SUPPLY AND DEMAND:
MARKETS
Horse-Trading 101
You’re watching the news when someone says, “Higher gas prices should lower
demand.” How do you evaluate a statement like that? This guy is on television,
so he must know what he’s talking about, right? Don’t be so sure. Many
intelligent individuals throw around economic arguments using economic
terminology and may even sound convincing, but there is a lot of bad economics
going around! To have a good understanding of economics, you must have a
grasp of supply and demand. The concepts are central to even the most complex
of economic arguments, yet they are easily understood.
WHAT’S A MARKET?
Markets are places that bring together buyers and sellers. However, markets do
not have to be physical places. Markets exist whenever and wherever buyer and
seller interact, be it a physical location, via mail, or over the Internet. Several
conditions must be met in order for markets to function efficiently. Typical
conditions for an efficient market include a large number of buyers and sellers
acting independently according to their own self-interest, perfect information
about what is being traded, and freedom of entry and exit to and from the
market.
Market Efficiency
Economists disagree over the efficiency of markets. Some argue
that the market price effectively captures all of the available
information about the product. Others argue that prices do not reflect
all available information. They argue that this information asymmetry
undermines market efficiency.
Money Talks
monopsony and monopoly
A monopsony is when there’s basically only one buyer for a product.
A monopoly is when there’s basically only one seller for a product.
Perfect information implies that both buyer and seller have complete access to
the costs of production and perfect knowledge of the product, and no
opportunities exist for arbitrage, which is buying low in one place and selling
high in another. Contrast that condition with the experience of buying a car.
Chances are the seller has the bulk of information about the cost and
specifications of the vehicle, whereas you deal with limited information at best
in making your purchase decision.
Freedom of entry and exit into the market also increases the market’s
efficiency by allowing the maximum number of buyers and sellers to participate.
Licensing requirements are an example of a barrier to entry. By requiring
licenses to sell or produce goods and services, the government limits the
potential number of sellers, resulting in less competition and higher prices.
COMPETITIVE MARKETS
A variety of factors affect supply and demand, which in turn affect price and
quantity. Changes in the market for one good will create changes in the market
for another good. This happens as price changes are communicated across
markets. This phenomenon should be considered when policymakers attempt to
influence markets, or unintended consequences can result.
How might driving an SUV contribute to starvation in Southeast Asia?
Several years ago gas prices suddenly began to climb. As a result, there was
considerable political pressure to alleviate the squeeze placed on the
pocketbooks of many Americans. Instead of driving less or commuting, many
wanted to continue their lifestyle of driving an inefficient vehicle without having
to pay higher prices. According to Thomas Sowell of the Hoover Institution,
politicians and many people are fond of ignoring the aphorism “there is no such
thing as a free lunch.” So, here is what happened.
As gas prices increased, demand for alternative fuels increased. This increase
in demand for alternative fuels was popular among corn growers who had a
product called ethanol. In order to provide ethanol at a lower cost, corn growers
lobbied Congress for greater subsidies. This resulted in more land being placed
into corn production at the expense of other crops, namely wheat. As wheat
supplies decreased and wheat prices rose, the price of the substitute crop, rice,
also rose because there was now more demand for rice. This led to the price of
rice increasing to the point where people in South and Southeast Asia were
unable to afford their basic staple. Starvation quickly ensued. Markets talk to
each other. No one intended for starvation to occur, but when people ignore
scarcity, unintended consequences can and do occur.
scarcity, unintended consequences can and do occur.
Conditions
Certain conditions are necessary for the functioning of an efficient market: a
large number of buyers and sellers each acting independently according to their
own self-interest, perfect information about what is being traded, and freedom of
entry and exit to and from the market. Add to this list that firms deal in identical
products and that they are “price-takers” (that is, they are unable to influence
price much), and you now have perfect competition.
Identical products mean that there are no real differences in the output of
firms. They are all making and selling the same stuff. Think of things like wheat,
corn, rice, barley, and whatever else goes into making breakfast cereal. Wheat
grown by one farmer is not significantly different from wheat grown by another
farmer.
Economists refer to firms as “price-takers” when a firm does not set the price
of its output, but instead sells its output at the market price. Remember, one
outcome when markets have many different small buyers and sellers is that none
are able to influence the price of the product.
SUPPLY AND DEMAND:
CONSUMER BEHAVIOR
In Which Economists Define Happiness
DEMAND
If you have ever witnessed an auction, then you might have noticed that there are
many more low bids for an item than high bids. That is, people are more willing
and able to pay a low price for an item than to pay a high price. This willingness
and ability to buy something is referred to as demand. The fact that more people
are willing to buy at lower prices than at higher prices is called the law of
demand.
Income Effect
Income effect is based on your budget constraint. As the price of a good
drops, your purchasing power increases. As the price increases, your purchasing
power falls. Income effect explains the logic behind discounts and sale prices.
When goods go on sale at a lower price, your limited income is able to purchase
more, so that is what you do.
Substitution Effect
Substitution effect is another explanation for the law of demand. The
substitution effect says that you substitute relatively less expensive items for
relatively more expensive items. For example, imagine you are at the grocery
store to buy food for five days’ worth of meals—three chicken dinners and two
dinners with beef. If the store happens to have beef on sale, you might substitute
one day’s chicken with beef. So what happened? The law of demand happened.
Beef prices were relatively lower and you bought more beef.
Elasticity of Demand
Think about all of the things that you buy in a year. You might purchase
goods and services as diverse as chewing gum, emergency room visits, and cars.
Sometimes you are very sensitive to the price and at other times you are not. For
example, you’re more likely to shop around for a good price on a car than on an
emergency room visit. Economists refer to this sensitivity to price as elasticity of
demand.
When you can delay the purchase of a good, if it has many close substitutes,
or if it takes a large percentage of your income, demand is typically price
sensitive or elastic.
If, however, the purchase must be made immediately, no close substitutes
exist, or the purchase does not take a significant percentage of income,
demand is price insensitive or inelastic.
ELASTICITY OF SUPPLY
Elasticity of supply is the producers’ sensitivity to changes in price on the
quantity they are willing to produce. The key factor in supply elasticity is the
amount of time it takes to produce the good or service. If producers can respond
to price changes rapidly, supply is relatively elastic. However, if producers need
considerable time to respond to changes in the market price of their product,
supply is relatively inelastic. Compare corn tortillas and wine. Corn tortillas are
easily produced with readily available materials. If the market price of corn
tortillas were to suddenly increase, producers would have little difficulty in
producing more tortillas in response to the price change. Now, if the market
price of Pinot Noir were to suddenly increase, winemakers would have much
price of Pinot Noir were to suddenly increase, winemakers would have much
more difficulty responding to the price change. Vines take years to develop,
grapes take time to ripen, and wine needs time to age. All of these factors give
wine a relatively inelastic supply.
A PRICE IS BORN
When supply meets demand, something interesting happens. A price is born. In
an efficient market, prices are a function of the supply and demand for the good
or service. Instead of central planners, government officials, or oligarchs
dictating artificial prices or rationing who gets what, the market relies on the
impersonal forces of supply and demand to determine prices and to serve the
rationing function. The pitting of consumers trying to maximize their utility
against producers trying to maximize their profits is what determines the price of
goods in the market and also the quantity that is bought and sold.
Supply and demand ration goods and services efficiently and fairly. Prices are
efficient because they are understood by most participants in the market. If you
give a child $5 and send her into a candy shop, she could figure out what she can
afford without having to ask anyone for help. A price conveys much
information. The price of a good communicates to consumers whether or not to
purchase and to the producer whether or not to produce it. Prices are fair because
they are neutral; they favor neither buyer nor seller.
FINDING EQUILIBRIUM
Change in either demand or supply will cause change in both price and quantity.
As price changes, producers are willing to produce more or less. Price affects the
quantity producers supply, but it does not affect supply. For example, the supply
of coffee is influenced by weather, land prices, other coffee producers, coffee
futures, cocoa profits, and subsidies to coffee producers. The one thing that does
not influence the supply of coffee is the current price of coffee. This often causes
confusion, but it need not. Understand that supply refers to producers’
willingness to produce various amounts at various prices, and not to some fixed
quantity.
Nature plays a big part in determining the supply of coffee. Rain, sunshine,
temperature, and disease are obvious examples of variables in nature that
will affect the coffee harvest. Excellent weather conditions often lead to
large increases in supply, and poor weather leads to the opposite.
Input or resource prices have a direct influence on producers’ supply
decisions. Land, seed, fertilizer, pesticide, harvesting equipment, labor, and
storage are just a few of the costs that coffee producers face. Supply
decreases as those costs rise, making growers less able to produce at each
and every market price. Supply increases when the cost of production falls.
The presence of more or less competition causes increases or decreases in
supply. As the popularity of coffee has risen, more and more producers
have entered the market. The introduction of more competition increased
the quantity of coffee supplied at each market price.
Expectations of future price increases tend to decrease supply, but
expectations of future price decreases have the opposite effect. If producers
expect higher prices in the future, they will be less willing to supply in the
present. Coffee producers might withhold production in order to sell when
prices are higher. If prices are expected to move lower in the future,
producers have an incentive to sell more in the present.
The profitability of related goods and services also affects the supply of a
good like coffee. For example, coffee-growing land is also favorable for
growing cocoa. If the profits are greater in the cocoa market than in the
coffee market, over time more land will be pulled from coffee production
and put into cocoa production. Likewise, if profits in the coffee market are
greater, eventually, more land will be put into coffee production at the
expense of cocoa production.
Government policies can also affect supply. Government can tax, subsidize,
or regulate production, and this will affect supply. If Brazil wants to reduce
the local production of coffee in order to restore forests, the Brazilian
government can tax coffee production. This would increase the cost of
production and reduce the supply. If government wants to encourage
production and increase supply, it can subsidize producers, that is, pay them
to produce. Vietnam might subsidize coffee production in its highlands in
order to increase the supply of this valuable export commodity. Regulation
often has the effect of limiting supply. If Vietnam wanted to preserve its
highland rainforests, it might make rules or regulations that effectively limit
the ability of coffee growers to produce.
Technology and the availability of physical capital are key determinants of
supply. Technological innovation has allowed producers in many different
industries to increase the quantity of goods that they are willing and able to
produce at each and every price.
Increases in the amount of physical capital available relative to labor also
help firms to increase output. Economists refer to this phenomenon as
capital deepening. As capital deepening increases for a firm, so does
supply.
Money Talks
capital
Capital in economics does not refer to money, but to all of the tools,
factories, and equipment used in the production process. Capital is
the product of investment.
Cross-Price Elasticity
A CASE IN POINT
Imagine that you are a teacher earning $5,000 a month and decide to quit your
Imagine that you are a teacher earning $5,000 a month and decide to quit your
job and start selling snow cones instead. You buy a freezer cart that you can
wheel around, order all of the supplies you need, and pay the required licensing
fees. Assume your total cost equals $2,000. So you get out there and start
hustling snow cones, and you’re actually good at it. At the end of the month, you
calculate that you have earned $6,000 in total revenue. What are your accounting
profits? $6,000 in total revenue – $2,000 in total cost = $4,000 in accounting
profit.
What are your economic profits? $6,000 in total revenue – ($2,000 in explicit
cost + $5,000 in opportunity cost) = −$1,000 economic loss. The opportunity
cost is what you could have been earning as a teacher.
In this example, we knew what salary the teacher earned so we could calculate
the opportunity cost more easily. But what if the situation were slightly
different? Suppose the teacher was selling snow cones in the summer, not during
the school year, so her teaching salary was unaffected. She might be giving up
other opportunities, but perhaps it isn’t clear what those opportunities would be
or how much she might earn pursuing them. What’s the going rate for tutoring, a
common summertime pursuit for teachers? Maybe it varies from $10 an hour to
$100 an hour, depending on a variety of factors. Or maybe the opportunities
aren’t income generating—maybe she could be lying on the beach, recuperating
so she can be ready for another round of teaching in the fall.
In another scenario, suppose our snow-cone seller was a twelve-year-old kid.
Instead of selling snow cones, what else could he be doing? Mowing lawns or
delivering newspapers? (Does anyone deliver newspapers anymore?) In this
case, the opportunity cost is likely to be close to zero.
The short run is defined as the period of time in which firms are able to vary
only one of the inputs to production, usually labor. The long run is the period in
which firms are able to vary all the inputs in the production process.
If you operate a restaurant, in the short run (today and next week) you can
only add or subtract workers to adjust the level of production. If your place is
busy, you schedule or call up more of your workers. If business is slow, you
send the employees home. The long run is the period in which you are able to
expand the kitchen or add new equipment. So in response to an increase in
business activity, in the short run you can schedule more workers, but in the long
run you can make the restaurant bigger.
A firm’s short-run production decisions are based on the firm’s production
A firm’s short-run production decisions are based on the firm’s production
function. A production function shows how a firm’s output changes as it makes
changes to a single input, like labor.
Businesses or firms strive to earn the most profits possible. Call that the Law of
Gordon “Greed Is Good” Gekko. Businesses try to increase profitability by
trying to increase revenue and decrease cost. In a competitive environment,
firms can’t do much to increase revenue. If Target is selling Beautiful Brand
toilet paper for $1 per four-pack, Walmart is also going to have to sell Beautiful
Brand toilet paper for about $1 per four-pack. They lack pricing power. Firms
do, however, have the ability to control costs, so in order to maximize their
profits they try to produce at the lowest cost possible.
Think of it this way: If you’d like to have enough money in the bank to retire
someday, you may be able to work toward getting a raise (or a better job with an
increase in pay), but you may not have a lot of control over this—your
boss/company will determine how much, if any, of a raise you can get, and your
ability to get a better-paying job depends on where you live, your credentials,
your work experience, how competitive your job market is, and other factors.
But even if you couldn’t easily get an increase in salary, you probably could cut
out Netflix and save a few bucks that way.
Money Talks
depreciation
As capital ages, its value declines because it breaks down and
eventually needs replacement.
TYPES OF COSTS
1. The first category of costs is fixed costs or overhead. A firm’s fixed costs
are those costs that don’t change regardless of the level of production.
Rent, property tax, management salaries, and depreciation are examples.
Whether a factory is running at full capacity or is idle, the overhead
remains the same.
2. Firms also face variable costs. Variable costs change with the level of a
firm’s output. Utilities, hourly wages, and per-unit taxes are
representative of variable costs. As a firm’s production increases, so do
its variable costs.
3. Total cost is the sum of a firm’s fixed and variable costs.
Remember how we said earlier that economists also consider opportunity cost
when calculating profitability? Forget that for now. For the purposes of this
discussion on costs, we’re looking at profit exactly the way an accountant does:
Revenue − Costs (Fixed and Variable) = Profit.
In the long run, all costs are variable. Over time, firms are able to
add or subtract capital, renegotiate rent, and alter management
salaries. The distinction between fixed and variable costs disappears
with the passage of time.
Marginal Revenue
Firms like McDonald’s maximize their profits when they produce at the point
where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. In other words, if a firm wants to
make the largest profits it can, it will produce up to the point where the
additional cost of producing one more item is the same as the additional revenue
earned by producing one more item.
If the additional cost of making “one more hamburger” is 99 cents (for
example) and that hamburger can be sold for 99 cents, then marginal cost and
marginal revenue are equal. This is the happy place economists dream of. If the
additional cost of making “one more hamburger” is instead $1.29 and selling it
can only generate revenue of 99 cents, McDonald’s will have some explaining to
do to their stockholders and will probably shortly be in search of a new CEO.
PERFECT COMPETITION IN THE
SHORT RUN
Let’s Pretend!
In other words, businesses must compete against each other without any
advantages (or disadvantages!). The result is that the industry sets the price
rather than individual businesses, and demand is perfectly elastic. (Remember
that if a good has many acceptable substitutes, the demand is price sensitive,
which is another way of saying demand is elastic.)
For an industry, the short run is the period of time in which firms are unable to
enter or exit the market because they are only able to vary their labor and not
their fixed capital. That is to say, if demand plummets, a business cannot quickly
reduce their fixed costs; if demand skyrockets, they cannot quickly expand to
produce more. In the short run, it is possible for firms in a perfectly competitive
industry to earn economic profits or even operate at a loss as supply and demand
for the entire industry’s output changes.
For example, assume that the glazed doughnut industry is perfectly
competitive. Imagine that scientists working in New Zealand discover that
competitive. Imagine that scientists working in New Zealand discover that
glazed doughnuts, when consumed with coffee, are extremely beneficial to
consumers’ health. As a result of this great news, the demand for doughnuts
increases. This results in a new, higher equilibrium price. Remember that the
market price represents the firm’s marginal revenue, so for firms in the doughnut
industry, their total revenue has increased by more than their total economic
cost. This means that glazed doughnut firms are earning economic profits.
Six months later, scientists in California reveal that the earlier New Zealand
doughnut research was flawed, and that, in fact, consuming large amounts of
glazed doughnuts with coffee might pose a risk to consumers’ health. First there
is denial, then consumers slowly awaken to the reality that they are fifty pounds
heavier and finding it difficult to sleep. At this point, the demand for glazed
doughnuts decreases below its original equilibrium. For many firms in the
doughnut industry, this decrease in the market price means that they are now
producing at a short-run loss, because their total revenue is less than their total
cost of production.
PERFECT COMPETITION IN THE
LONG RUN
The Race to Zero
Unlike the short run, in the long run, firms are able to enter and exit the market.
New firms enter the market in response to the presence of economic profits, and
old firms exit the market in response to losses. To continue the doughnut
example from the last section, consider how in light of the New Zealand
research, economic profits in the glazed doughnut industry would attract new
firms to the industry. As new firms enter, competition increases, which means
that the industry supply of glazed doughnuts increases. The increased supply
reduces the equilibrium price of doughnuts and economic profits disappear.
Considering the California research, in the face of economic losses, some
firms will reach the shutdown point and withdraw from the industry. This
reduces competition and decreases the industry supply of glazed doughnuts.
Decreased supply increases the equilibrium price in the market. In the end, fewer
firms remain as the industry returns to its long-run equilibrium with zero
economic profits.
Perfect competition does not really exist. It is unlikely that you will find an
industry in which all of the conditions for perfect competition are met. However,
perfect competition provides an example with which to compare the market
structures that do exist. Although it isn’t real, it provides a nice frame of
reference.
Monopolistic Competition
Monopolistic competition is a market structure very similar to perfect
competition. There are many buyers and sellers, barriers to entry are minimal or
at least equal for all firms, and information is readily available. However, in
monopolistic competition, firms do not offer identical products, but differentiate
their products from those of their competition. Product differentiation is the
process by which producers are able to convince consumers that their particular
process by which producers are able to convince consumers that their particular
product is different from other producers’ products.
The industry that should come to mind when you think of monopolistic
competition is fast food. The fast-food industry has many different producers
competing for the dollars of many different consumers. All are welcome to start
a fast-food restaurant as long as they pay the required licenses. Most producers
have a good idea of what they are getting into and customers tend to understand
the products quite well. Why is fast food monopolistically competitive? Product
differentiation. Each firm offers a different menu. Taco Bell, Chick-fil-A,
McDonald’s, and Subway all compete against each other in the fast-food market
while providing customers with a variety of choices. Product differentiation is
one of the reasons that new entrants are able to survive in this cutthroat industry.
If you are different enough, then you might have a chance.
Next time you are in the produce section of the grocery store, take a look at
how many varieties of apples are available. Do you remember the days when
apples were either red or green? Today there are Red Delicious, Pink Lady,
Granny Smith, Gala, Fuji, and Honeycrisp, to name a few. In addition, there are
small, medium, and large. There are organic and pesticide-treated. Some are sold
individually and some are packaged. Apple producers have differentiated their
products. Why? Remember how competitive firms were unable to influence
price? When producers differentiate their products and are successful, they are
able to charge a higher price than their competition.
Many of the companies with which you are most familiar do not exist in
perfectly competitive markets or even in highly competitive markets. The major
automobile manufacturers, airlines, telecommunications companies, food
producers, and discount retailers compete in an oligopolistic market structure—
that is, a market with few producers.
At a local level, many of the utilities you use are monopolies. Oligopoly and
monopoly are common market structures in the United States. In the last section,
we briefly described monopolies. Now, let’s look at oligopolies. To know how
the American economy works, you need a good understanding of these
imperfectly competitive market structures.
OLIGOPOLY
Loss of Competition
Why does it matter if firms consolidate, industries mature, and markets
become oligopolistic? As competition decreases, a number of negative effects
occur. Prices become higher, and productive and allocative efficiency, which
benefit society, are lost. Notice how these are industries where consumers tend
to dislike the producers. (Has anyone ever actually loved an airline the way they
love a chocolate-chip cookie?) An interesting coincidence, wouldn’t you say?
To determine whether a market meets the condition of oligopoly, economists
calculate the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) for the market. A relatively low
index number identifies a market as competitive, and a relatively high index
number indicates oligopoly. The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and the
Justice Department can use the index numbers as a way to determine whether or
not to approve mergers between companies in an industry. If the merger would
significantly increase the HHI, then the merger would most likely be blocked
because it would reduce competition.
Regulators and economists also use concentration ratios to determine if a
market is oligopolistic. The more market share is dominated by a few firms, the
higher the concentration ratio. For example, if the four-firm concentration ratio
is 80%, then the four largest firms have 80% of the market share. According to
the 2002 census, the four-firm concentration ratio for the vacuum-cleaner
industry was 78%, and the eight-firm concentration ratio was 96.1%. It is safe to
say that the vacuum-cleaner industry is an example of oligopoly. By way of
comparison, a perfectly competitive industry would have a four-firm
concentration ratio of about 0%, and an industry dominated by a monopoly
would have a one-firm concentration ratio of 100%.
The large market share that oligopolists enjoy shapes the way they view the
market. Unlike firms in more competitive market structures that behave
independently of each other, the oligopolists have an interdependent relationship
with each other. Because the oligopolists control so much market share, their
individual decisions have considerable impacts on market prices. Knowing this
to be the case, the oligopolist tends to be more aware of the competition and
takes this into account when making production and pricing decisions.
COLLUSION AND CARTELS
World Domination or Die! Revisited
One of the blessings of competition is that it leads to lower prices for consumers.
For the producer, however, this blessing is a curse. Low prices often mean low
profits. Given a choice between competition and cooperation, profit-maximizing
firms would more often than not prefer cooperation. Regardless of what you
learned in kindergarten, you do not want the businesses you buy from to
cooperate because they might all decide that chocolate should cost $100 a pound
or they might all agree to throttle back production to create an artificial scarcity.
It’s in your best interest for businesses to compete against each other to produce
those low low prices consumers like so well. Adam Smith, the father of modern
capitalism, warned that nothing beneficial comes from the heads of business
getting together, and history has proven him right.
Money Talks
cartel
A group of producers that agree to cooperate instead of compete
with each other. Cartels seek higher profits for their members by
collectively reducing production in order to increase prices.
Collusion
In the United States, firms are forbidden from cooperating to set prices or
production. The abuses of the late nineteenth-and early twentieth-century trusts
were the impetus for the “trust-busting” of President Theodore Roosevelt. With
the Sherman Antitrust Act and later the Clayton Antitrust Act, the government
the Sherman Antitrust Act and later the Clayton Antitrust Act, the government
prohibited outright collusion and other business practices that reduced
competition.
Money Talks
collusion
Collusion means any type of illegal conspiracy. For economists,
collusion also implies an intent to cheat or defraud consumers (and
others) by artificially reducing competition.
Even though it violates the law, businesses from time to time will collude in
order to set prices. Colluding firms can divide up the market in a way that is
beneficial for them. The firms avoid competition, set higher prices, and reduce
their operating costs. Because collusion is illegal and punishable by fine and
prison, executives at firms are reluctant to engage in the practice. The meetings
of business leaders are almost always in the presence of attorneys in order to
avoid the accusation of collusion.
Forming Cartels
Businesses that collude may form cartels. A cartel is a group of businesses
that effectively function as a single producer or monopoly able to charge
whatever price the market will bear. Probably the best-known modern cartel is
the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries, or OPEC. OPEC is
made up of thirteen oil-exporting countries and is thus not subject to the antitrust
laws of the United States. OPEC seeks to maintain high oil prices and profits for
their members by restricting output. Each member of the cartel agrees to a
production quota that will eventually reduce overall output and increase prices.
OPEC is bad news for anyone who enjoys cheap gasoline.
Fortunately for consumers, cartels have an Achilles’ heel. The individual
members of a cartel have an incentive to cheat on their agreement. Cartels go
through periods of cooperation and competition. When prices and profits are
low, the members of the cartel have an incentive to cooperate and limit
production. It is the cartel’s success that brings the incentive to cheat. If the
cartel is successful, the market price of the commodity will rise. Individual
members driven by their own self-interest will have an incentive, the law of
supply, to ever-so-slightly exceed their production quota and sell the excess at
the now higher price. The problem is that all members have this incentive and
the result is that eventually prices will fall as they collectively cheat on the
production quota. Cartels must find ways to discourage cheating. Drug cartels
use assassination and kidnapping, but OPEC uses something a little more
civilized. The single largest producer in the cartel is Saudi Arabia. Saudi Arabia
also has the lowest cost of production. If a member or members cheat on the
cartel, then Saudi Arabia can discipline the group by unleashing its vast oil
reserves, undercutting other countries’ prices, and still remain profitable. After a
few months or even years of losses, the other countries would then have an
incentive to cooperate and limit production once again.
GAME THEORY
I’d Like to Buy a Vowel, Please
Economists have discovered that game theory is useful for understanding the
behavior of oligopolists. Game theory looks at the outcomes of decisions made
when those decisions depend upon the choices of others. Game theory is a study
of interdependent decision-making.
1. Assume that on the first day, both gas stations charge a high price. Both
earn profits of $1,000.
2. On the second day, one of the stations charges a high price, but the other
cheats and charges a low price to earn profits of $1,200.
3. Predictably, the next day the other station retaliates and lowers its price,
resulting in profits of $750 for each.
4. Eventually both gas stations come to the realization that if they both set a
high price and do not cheat, they both will earn higher profits in the long
run. They learn that if they cheat, their additional profit for the next day
will not offset the lower profits that will ensue.
PRICING BEHAVIORS
Money, Money, Money
Price Leadership
Price leadership takes place when a dominant firm makes the pricing decision
for the rest of the market. These decisions are often made public long before the
new price goes into effect, and represent a form of tacit collusion. Smaller firms
in the industry will usually follow suit and match the price leader’s price. Price
leadership offers firms an opportunity to capture a price that is higher than
would occur if the firms directly competed on price. Consumers usually fare
better under price leadership than they would if the firms formed a cartel but
worse than if they were highly competitive.
Price Wars
Price wars occur when firms break out of the price leadership model and
begin undercutting one another’s prices. Although it sounds bad, price wars are
begin undercutting one another’s prices. Although it sounds bad, price wars are
often advantageous to consumers because of the competitive prices created in
the process. Some firms have been accused of financing price wars by raising
prices in one part of their market in order to cut their price in another part of
their market. A price war continues until the firms once again reach tacit
collusion and return to the price leadership model.
Product Differentiation
While in the price leadership operating mode, firms compete on the basis of
product differentiation as opposed to price. By emphasizing their product’s
differences and uniqueness, firms attempt to wrest market share from one
another. As in the monopolistically competitive market, oligopolists engaging in
non-price competition will spend large sums on advertising. For example, the
major American beer brands do not compete on price, but instead rely on non-
price competition in the form of advertising in order to gain market share from
one another.
On the opposite end of the spectrum from perfect competition lies monopoly. As
the name suggests, monopoly is a market dominated by a single seller. In the
United States, monopolies are generally not allowed to exist, and every effort is
made by government regulators at the FTC to prevent their creation. The reason
for this prohibition is that monopolies create a serious problem for both
consumers and likely competitors in the marketplace. Despite the fact that
monopolies are undesirable, there are several good reasons for some to exist.
The following are the primary reasons for the existence of most monopolies in
the United States:
economies of scale
geography
government protection
government mandate
Price Increases
Monopoly occurs when a competitive firm eliminates all competition.
Through control of key resources, mergers, and even a little help from
government, once-competitive firms may find themselves in the enviable
position of being a monopolist. A typical pricing behavior for a monopoly is to
increase prices as much as possible.
John D. Rockefeller’s Standard Oil Trust is probably the most notable
American monopoly. By controlling the resource, purchasing the competition,
and having political influence, Standard Oil at its height of power virtually
controlled all oil production in the United States. This was good for Mr.
Rockefeller as it made him the world’s wealthiest man, but for consumers and
possible competitors, the results of the Standard Oil Trust were high prices,
inefficient production, and significant barriers to entry. Eventually, the Sherman
Antitrust Act was used to break up Standard Oil, and ever since the government
has taken an active role in preventing further monopolies.
Price Discrimination
Because they lack competition, monopolies can engage in price discrimination
to make it difficult for other firms to do business. Price discrimination is the
ability to charge different customers different prices for the same good or
service. For example, a railroad monopolist could charge different rates to
different customers for carrying the same amount of freight. Today, thanks to the
Clayton Antitrust Act, price discrimination for the most part is illegal.
Some forms of price discrimination still exist because they are seen as
acceptable.
You might have benefited from price discrimination the last time you went to
a movie theater or flew on an airplane. Senior citizen, student, and military
discounts are usually offered at theaters. Business travelers and vacationers often
discounts are usually offered at theaters. Business travelers and vacationers often
pay very different prices for tickets on the same flight even though they might
both fly coach. How do the airlines get away with it? It is defensible because
vacationers and business travelers have different elasticities of demand for
airline tickets. Vacationers have elastic demand for tickets because they are able
to book travel months in advance and are often willing to purchase
nonrefundable fares. Business travelers’ demand is much more inelastic, and
thus they are willing to pay the higher price for the convenience of refundable
fares and the privilege of booking tickets at short notice. By being allowed to
charge different prices for basically the same ticket, the airline is able to better
ration tickets between those who need a ticket and those who want a ticket.
MONOPOLY: THE GOOD, THE
BAD, AND THE UGLY
Not Just a Board Game
Monopoly isn’t always a bad thing. Then again, it isn’t always a good thing.
Sometimes monopoly is downright ugly, unless of course, you are the proud
parent of a monopoly. When monopoly is allowed to exist, it is for a good
reason. Yet, even though the reason is good, monopolies can have some negative
effects. History has shown that left unchecked, monopolies can harm an
economy.
THE GOOD
Good monopolies come in several forms depending on the type of output
(good/item/service) being produced.
Natural Monopoly
The first is natural monopoly. When the average cost of production falls as a
factory grows larger, then economies of scale are present. Natural monopoly
exists when economies of scale encourage production by a single producer. A
commonly cited example of natural monopoly is your local electrical utility. A
feature of power plants that encourages natural monopoly is that as the size of a
power plant increases, the cost per kilowatt hour of electricity falls. You might
own a small electrical generator. Imagine the cost of operating the generator or
multiple small generators just to meet your home’s electrical needs. Now
imagine the cost of every household in a city running on multiple portable
generators. The total fixed cost of generators for the community would be quite
generators. The total fixed cost of generators for the community would be quite
high, and the variable cost of running gas or diesel generators would be
astronomical.
Compare that situation with the one that most likely exists in your city.
Instead of multitudes of portable generators, a few large coal-fired power plants
are able to generate electricity for the entire city at a much lower total cost.
Remember that utilities are monopolies. What keeps the utility from charging a
monopoly price for electricity? Government regulates the prices that utilities are
able to charge their customers for electricity. By controlling prices, government
encourages low-cost production while allowing the utility to experience an
accounting profit on production.
Technological Monopoly
The technological monopoly is another form of monopoly that is encouraged.
When a firm invents a new product or process and receives patent protection, the
firm becomes a technological monopolist for that particular product. According
to the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office, patent protection lasts for twenty years
from the date on which it was originally applied. During that period of time, no
other firm may develop or import the technology. The patent holder may
develop or sell the rights to develop the technology to a firm that can legally
operate as a monopolist.
During the period of patent protection, the patent holder as a monopolist can
charge a monopoly price and earn economic profits. If monopoly prices are
higher than competitive prices, why is this encouraged? Patent protection
encourages innovation, invention, and research and development. Without the
protection, firms would have little incentive to invest billions of dollars in
research knowing the firm next door could just copy the product without having
made the investment and profit nonetheless. It is because of patent protection
and the ability to earn monopoly profits that American and European
pharmaceutical companies develop so many life-saving medications. Without
patent protection, there would be little incentive for the pharmaceutical industry
patent protection, there would be little incentive for the pharmaceutical industry
to pursue its research.
THE BAD?
At times government may decide to step into the marketplace in order to provide
a good or service. An example of government monopoly is the U.S. Postal
Service.
The Ugly
The Ugly
Pure, unregulated monopoly is ugly. A firm that is the sole provider of a good
or service is able to prevent competition. It can charge whatever price the
consumer will pay. This is the monopoly that is most harmful to society.
Although one may say “to the victor go the spoils,” once-competitive firms that
become monopolists need to be checked by regulation or broken up into
competing firms. Competition benefits society by providing a variety of goods
and services at competitive prices that accurately reflect the costs of production.
Pure monopoly is the opposite of this condition. Pure monopoly is one good at a
price that in no way reflects the true cost of production.
The diamond monopoly of De Beers is the classic example of monopoly gone
bad. De Beers at the height of its power dictated the diamond industry. By
controlling the resource and coercing the wholesalers and cutters to abide by its
demands, De Beers created an illusion of scarcity and value in the diamond
market that allowed it to earn economic profits for over 100 years. Now, before
you sell your diamonds in disgust, you should remember that you were not
coerced to buy the diamond. You bought the diamond because the benefit
outweighed the cost. The problem for the buyer is that you never realized how
much of the cost was De Beers’s profit.
GOVERNMENT IN THE
MARKETPLACE: PRICE
CEILINGS AND PRICE FLOORS
But They Meant Well
From time to time, people will petition government to step in and correct
perceived wrongs in the market. Often this leads to unexpected results. Without
considering how people might respond to incentives, well-intentioned policies
can go astray. Because people are not going to stop acting like people,
governments must consider whether or not their actions create perverse
incentives. Likewise, there are times when the market fails to provide goods or
properly assign costs. This calls for government intervention to either provide or
redirect incentives in such a way that the market functions better. Two
approaches governments use are price ceilings and price floors.
PRICE CEILINGS
In the early 1970s, America was faced with ever-increasing food prices. As a
result, people clamored for the government to step in and halt the increases.
Instead of considering the source of the problem and doing something about that,
government attempted to treat the symptoms. In an effort to alleviate the
suffering of households, the Nixon administration enacted price controls. One
such price control was an effective price ceiling on food. Retailers could not
charge a price higher than the government-mandated ceiling.
A price ceiling is a legal maximum price for a good, service, or resource. At
the time, the theory was that if the government imposed a price ceiling on food,
the time, the theory was that if the government imposed a price ceiling on food,
prices would stop going up and everyone would have the food they wanted at the
price they wanted. Of course, this assumes that people do not behave like people.
Remember that prices are the result of the equilibrium of supply and demand.
Also remember that these two forces are completely shaped by human nature.
The law of demand, which governs consumer behavior, says that as prices
fall, consumers have an incentive to buy more, and as prices rise, consumers
have an incentive to buy less. The law of supply, which governs producer
behavior, says that as prices rise, producers have an incentive to produce more,
and as prices fall, producers have an incentive to produce less.
What effect does a price ceiling have on the market for food? Look at the
incentives. A price ceiling encourages consumers to purchase, but discourages
producers from producing. Assume that meat is currently selling for $5 per
pound. Consumers feel that the price is too high, so they petition government for
a price ceiling of $3 per pound. Representatives, senators, and presidents all like
to get re-elected, so they cater to consumers and enact the price ceiling. The $3
price signals to consumers to purchase more, but signals to producers to produce
less. The result of the price ceiling is a shortage of meat at the price of $3 per
pound. At that price, more meat is demanded than is supplied. Consumers got a
price ceiling of $3, but many consumers did not get any meat at all.
Price controls are inefficient for many reasons. One reason worth
considering is that they increase the need for monitoring and
enforcement. That means increased government bureaucracy,
which does not come cheap. Increased government spending
equals more taxes or more borrowing.
Eventually, America abandoned price controls, but it took a decade to get the
Eventually, America abandoned price controls, but it took a decade to get the
underlying inflation under control. Even today you still hear of people
demanding that government cap prices of various commodities. As late as 2007,
people were asking for price limits on gasoline. People continue to behave like
people, and they still want low prices. Government and consumers would be
wise to learn from the mistakes of the past and realize that attempts to control
the market result in unintended consequences.
PRICE FLOORS
Consumers are not the only ones who ignore the basics of supply and demand.
Producers have at times called for price floors. A price floor is a legal minimum
price for a good, service, or resource. Probably the best-known price floor is
minimum wage. In the market for resources like labor, households supply and
businesses demand. Politicians representing areas with large populations of
unskilled labor are often pressured by voters to increase minimum wage. It’s
believed that an increase in the minimum wage is justified because employers
will pay the higher wage and maintain the same number of workers. However,
that works only if you assume that people do not behave like people.
For example, suppose that the city council of a major city, under pressure
from voters, raises the minimum wage from the federal minimum to a city
minimum of $10 an hour. Further assume that the equilibrium wage in the inner
city area was already $8 an hour and that in the suburbs it was $11 an hour.
What will happen in the inner city and what will happen in the suburbs? In the
inner city more producers (workers) will be willing to supply their labor at the
higher price, but fewer consumers (employers) will be willing to employ that
labor at the higher price. As a result, a surplus of unskilled labor develops, better
known as unemployment. In the suburbs, the increase in the minimum wage has
no effect, as the equilibrium wage was already $11. In the end, the policy meant
to help the poor helped those who maintained their jobs, but resulted in
unemployment for those who were laid off and those who entered the job market
unemployment for those who were laid off and those who entered the job market
looking for work at $10 an hour.
Interestingly enough, those most in favor of increasing the minimum wage are
often the same people who would be most harmed by the increase. Politicians
know this now and will often pass increases in the minimum wage that keep it
less than the average equilibrium wage for unskilled labor. For example, if the
average market equilibrium unskilled labor wage is $8 an hour, then politicians
will gladly increase minimum wage from $6 to $7.50, knowing that it will have
little economic effect. Yet, they can still put a feather in their cap for “raising”
the minimum wage.
GOVERNMENT IN THE
MARKETPLACE: TAXES AND
SUBSIDIES
The Only Certainties in Life
Some economists argue that subsidized loans and grants for college
students are part of the problem, not the cure. The financial aid
system, while well intentioned, has the effect of increasing demand
for college. As you know, increased demand leads to higher prices.
Other subsidies are directed at consumers rather than producers (for example,
a rent subsidy for a low-income earner). Consumer subsidies are often meant to
protect the disadvantaged rather than to affect supply or demand, but such
subsidies do affect the market.
Black markets allow illegal trade to occur. Even food subsidies for needy
families are subject to black market activity. Some receiving food assistance will
willingly trade $2 in food assistance for $1 cash. They benefit because they now
have the freedom to purchase what they want. The buyer benefits by purchasing
groceries at half price. The problem with the system is that it is inefficient and
creates disutility for the recipients. The taxpayer wins under a cash payment
creates disutility for the recipients. The taxpayer wins under a cash payment
system because he is able to give the same value of service at a fraction of the
cost. The recipient wins because he is able to buy groceries without the stigma of
having to pay using food stamps, and if he so chooses he can buy other things he
values more.
The obvious argument against a system like this is that some might not buy
food with the food assistance, but instead purchase alcohol, cigarettes, or even
illegal drugs. Consider this example: Assume that a person receiving food
assistance also has an addiction to cigarettes. She receives $100 in food stamps
and immediately sells them on the black market so that she can buy $50 in
cigarettes. In the end, she has $50 in cigarettes and no food. Now assume that a
person receiving food assistance receives $100 cash. He purchases $50 in
cigarettes, but now has $50 left for food. He is better off and the taxpayer is
better off. In addition, the cash payment system removes the black market and is
much less expensive to administer.
MARKET FAILURES
Come on and Take a Free Ride
PUBLIC GOODS
Sometimes the market does not provide a good or service that people want. If a
good is non-rival and non-excludable, the free market will probably not provide
it.
POSITIVE EXTERNALITY
POSITIVE EXTERNALITY
NEGATIVE EXTERNALITY
BLACK MARKETS
Have you ever wondered what the people on the news are talking about when
they say something like, “The Dow Jones Industrial Average closed up 30 points
today on heavy trading. The S&P 500 also edged higher. The NASDAQ was
mixed. Foreign markets opened lower on news that the Fed will maintain near-
zero interest rates for the foreseeable future. Corporate bond prices sank as many
issues were downgraded while the yield on the ten-year treasury ended lower”?
If you subscribe to the Wall Street Journal or Financial Times, or regularly
watch CNBC, Bloomberg, or the Fox Business channel, you probably
understand the lingo. But if you’re like many Americans, the financial markets
are a complete mystery. Even though they appear complicated, financial markets
serve a very basic purpose: to connect the people who have money with the
people who want money.
Economists offer a simple model for understanding financial markets and how
the real interest rate is determined. (Remember that the real interest rate is the
amount of nominal interest left standing after the rate of inflation is accounted
for/subtracted.) Like many bright ideas economists come up with, this model is
purely imaginary but it helps to explain what happens in financial markets. The
hypothetical market they’ve identified is referred to as the loanable funds
market. It exists to bring together “savers” and “borrowers.” Savers supply and
borrowers demand. The real interest rate occurs at the point where the amount
borrowers demand. The real interest rate occurs at the point where the amount
saved equals the amount borrowed.
According to the law of supply, producers are only willing to offer more if
they can collect a higher price because they face ever-increasing costs. In the
loanable funds market, the price is the real interest rate. Savers, the producers of
loanable funds, respond to the price by offering more funds as the rate increases
and less as the rate decreases. Borrowers act as consumers of loanable funds—
their behavior is explained by the law of demand. When the interest rate is high,
they are less willing and able to borrow, and when interest rates are low, they are
more willing and able to borrow.
Money Talks
investment
Newcomers to economics are often confused by the use of the term
investment. In economics, investment means borrowing in order to
purchase physical capital. If the topic is stocks and bonds, then
investment is understood to mean pretty much the same thing as
saving. Savers engage in financial investment, which provides the
funds for borrowers to engage in capital investment.
According to the expanded view of the loanable funds theory, savers are
represented by households, businesses, governments, and the foreign sector.
Borrowers also are represented by these same sectors. Changes in the saving and
borrowing behavior of the various sectors of the economy result in change in the
real interest rate and change in the quantity of loanable funds exchanged. For
example, a decision by foreign savers to save more in the United States results in
a lower real interest rate and a greater quantity of loanable funds exchanged for
the country. A decision by the U.S. government to borrow money and engage in
deficit spending would increase the demand for loanable funds, and result in a
deficit spending would increase the demand for loanable funds, and result in a
higher real interest rate and a greater quantity of loanable funds exchanged. The
loanable funds theory of interest rate determination is useful for understanding
changes in long-term interest rates.
LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE
John Maynard Keynes’s liquidity preference theory explains short-term nominal
interest rates. Instead of looking at saving and borrowing behavior as the
determinant of interest rates, Keynes taught that short-term interest rates are a
function of consumers’ liquidity preference or inclination for holding cash. In
Keynes’s theory, the money market, as opposed to the loanable funds market,
was central to explaining interest rates.
The money market is where the central bank supplies money, and households,
businesses, and government demand money at various nominal interest rates.
Central banks like America’s Federal Reserve act as regulated monopolies and
issue money independent of the interest rate. Liquidity preference is the demand
for money. At high nominal interest rates, people would rather hold interest-
bearing non-cash assets like bonds, but as interest rates fall, people are more
willing to hold cash as an asset because they are not sacrificing much interest to
do so.
As previously described, the money market is where the central bank supplies
money, and households, businesses, and government demand money at various
nominal interest rates. Firms, banks, and governments are able to obtain short-
term financing in the money market. Securities (financial instruments such as
stocks and bonds) with maturities of less than one year are included in this
market.
COMMERCIAL PAPER
Businesses with excellent credit can easily borrow in the money market by
issuing commercial paper, which is nothing more than a short-term IOU. For
example, Behemoth Corporation is expecting payment from its customers at the
end of the month, but has to pay its employees before then. In this case,
Behemoth Corporation can issue commercial paper in exchange for cash with
which to pay its employees. As soon as the customers make their payment to
Behemoth Corporation, the company can turn around and repay whoever holds
its commercial paper. For the company, commercial paper allows them to
manage their cash flow at a cheaper rate than taking on longer-term debt would
allow, and for the lender it provides a liquid and relatively safe way to earn some
interest on their extra cash.
Commercial paper is an unsecured debt, meaning that it doesn’t represent any
type of ownership interest and no collateral is offered in exchange. You’re
repaid by cash flow (as in the example just presented, once the customers pay
Behemoth Corporation at the end of the month, you’ll get your original
Behemoth Corporation at the end of the month, you’ll get your original
investment plus interest back). If the firm defaults on their repayment, you’re
stuck without a lot of good options. It’s not as if you can send out the
neighborhood repo guy and seize the office furniture.
Companies with less-than-perfect credit have to offer higher interest rates in
order to get any takers, who will be assuming more than the usual risk. Demand
is much greater for higher-rated commercial paper. Commercial paper is usually
sold in big chunks (say, $100,000 per issue), the interest is taxable, and the
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) doesn’t regulate their sale. This is
why money market funds are popular with private investors (the little guys like
you and me). They allow for diversification, spreading the risk out over a
number of different commercial paper investments.
TREASURY BILLS
Like corporations, sometimes the U.S. government needs a little cash on hand to
make the wheels of governance run smoothly. When it does, it auctions Treasury
bills (T-bills) for its short-term cash needs. The T-bills have various maturities
of less than one year. Investors like T-bills because they allow them to earn risk-
free interest while maintaining liquidity in case they need their cash quickly for
other purposes. The government benefits because T-bills provide the government
with easy access to cash for government spending, and what government doesn’t
love easy access to cash?
FEDERAL FUNDS
Banks, like any other business, sometimes have to have access to more cash than
they have tucked away in the vault. To meet their short-term financing needs,
they lend and borrow federal funds, also known as fed funds. Banks may borrow
from each other in the fed funds market to satisfy their legal reserve
requirements or to meet their contractual clearing balances. This component of
the money market is important for maintaining bank liquidity. It also increases
efficiency by encouraging banks to put all of their available excess reserves to
work earning a return. Because banks keep most of their reserves on deposit with
the Fed, the exchange of these federal funds occurs almost immediately as the
banks exchange their reserve balances between each other. The Federal Reserve
affects this market by influencing the fed funds rate, which is the interest rate
banks charge each other for the use of overnight federal funds.
THE BOND MARKET
Call Me Bond, Coupon Bond
For long-term financing, governments and firms are able to borrow in the bond
market. When investors buy bonds, they are lending money to sellers with the
expectation that they will be repaid their principal plus interest. For bond issuers,
the bond market provides an efficient means of borrowing large sums of money.
For the buyer, bonds provide a relatively secure financial investment that
provides interest income.
Coupon bonds are sold at or near face value and provide guaranteed interest
payments.
Zero coupon bonds are sold at a discount from face value and pay face
value at maturity.
Either type makes an attractive investment for people seeking interest income
while preserving their principal. The ability to sell bonds on the secondary
market makes them relatively liquid, which is also important to investors.
The U.S. government issues several types of bonds with maturities greater
than a year. Treasury notes and Treasury bonds are primary sources for
financing the federal budget.
Treasury notes are medium-term securities with maturities ranging from
two to ten years.
Treasury bonds are long-term securities that mature after thirty years.
The interest rate on the ten-year Treasury note is important because it serves
as a benchmark interest rate for both corporate bonds and mortgages. As the
interest rate on the ten-year Treasury note fluctuates, corporate rates and
mortgage rates fluctuate as well.
In addition to the Treasury, independent agencies of the U.S. government are
able to borrow by issuing bonds. Although they lack the guarantee of repayment
that Treasury securities have, agency securities are backed by the government
and as such are seen as virtually guaranteed. The Federal National Mortgage
Association (Fannie Mae), the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation
(Freddie Mac), and the Student Loan Marketing Association (Sallie Mae) are
well-known agencies that issue bonds in order to finance their operations.
Agency securities provide an alternative for investors looking for the security of
government bonds but with higher interest rates.
State and local governments are also able to borrow through the bond market.
Municipal bonds often finance schools, roads, and other public projects. The
interest paid on the municipal bonds is exempt from federal income taxes, which
makes them attractive to investors. Because the interest is tax exempt, municipal
bonds do not have to offer as high an interest rate to attract investors. As a result,
state and local governments are able to borrow more cheaply than the private
sector.
CORPORATE BONDS
Firms are able to borrow in the bond market by issuing corporate bonds.
Firms are able to borrow in the bond market by issuing corporate bonds.
Corporate bonds provide businesses with the money they need for capital
investment without having to arrange bank financing. In addition, corporate
bonds allow for businesses to obtain funds without diluting ownership in the
company. The chief advantage of bonds is that they provide firms with financial
leverage. For example, if a company has $1,000 to invest in capital and can
expect a return of 10%, the company will earn $100 from the investment. If,
however, the firm borrows $1,000,000 and invests in capital that returns 10% a
year, the firm is able to earn $100,000 without risking its own money. Because
firms lack the ability to tax to repay bonds (and therefore occasionally default on
them), investors require a higher interest rate on corporate bonds than on
Treasury and municipal bonds to offset the increased risk.
BOND RISKS
Bonds are not without their downsides. Investors face investment risk, inflation
risk, interest rate risk, and the risk of early call (early call means the issuer can
recall [“retire”] the bond before the expected maturity date).
Since the possibility exists that governments or firms may fail to pay back
their borrowed money, all bondholders face investment risk.
If the rate of inflation increases during the life of a bond, the investor’s
return is offset by the inflation.
If interest rates increase during the life of a bond, the value of the bond
decreases until its effective yield equals the new higher interest rate. For
bondholders, this means that they might lose principal if they try to sell it
before maturity.
If interest rates decline during the life of a bond, the issuer may find it
beneficial to retire or call the old bonds and refinance at the new lower
interest rate. For bondholders, this means that they lose out on earning the
higher interest they would have had when the bond matured.
Interest rates are made up of several components: the real rate, expected inflation
premium, default risk premium, liquidity premium, and maturity risk. The real
rate and the expected inflation premium make up the risk-free rate of return. This
risk-free rate of return acts as the benchmark on which all other interest rates are
based. Today the various bonds issued by the U.S. Treasury are the proxies for
the risk-free rate of return.
Treasury securities have this distinction because the United States has never
defaulted on its debt in its 220-plus-year history, and the secondary market for
U.S. Treasury securities is considered “deep” because it is backed by the full
faith and credit of the United States. The importance of the secondary market in
the Treasury cannot be understated. Because so many governments, banks,
businesses, and individuals desire U.S. Treasury securities as a risk-free place to
park their money, a condition is created where there is no doubt to the liquidity
of the securities. The only appreciable risk faced by the holders of Treasury
of the securities. The only appreciable risk faced by the holders of Treasury
securities is maturity risk. The longer the term of a bond, the greater the chance
that interest rates will change from the one that existed at the time of purchase. If
interest rates were to unexpectedly rise during the life of the bond, the value of
the bond would decrease. As new bond prices fall, the effective interest rate on
the bonds increase, which makes previously issued bonds less attractive. This, in
turn, makes them less valuable.
THE STOCK MARKET
Taking Stock of Companies
Of all the financial markets, none receives as much media coverage as the stock
market. Unlike bond markets, where investors are making loans to governments
and firms, the stock market is where investors are able to purchase partial
ownership in firms represented by shares of stock.
STOCKS, SIMPLIFIED
Companies that are privately held don’t issue stock for public purchase. Instead,
they keep the shares among a small group of owners, often the founders. But for
companies that want or need outside investment, trading on one of the stock
exchanges is a good way to do this.
Firms are able to raise the money they need for capital investment by
issuing stock in an initial public offering (IPO).
Investors purchase the stock with the expectation that it will either pay
dividends or earn capital gains. Investors earn dividends when a company
divides a portion of the profits among all of the owners according to the
number of shares each owns. For example, if there are 100 shares of stock
for a company, and the firm earns profits of $1,000,000 and decides to
distribute half of the profits to its shareholders while reinvesting the other
half, each share will earn a dividend of $500,000/100 or $5,000.
Stock earns capital gains when it is sold at a higher price than for what it
was purchased. Suppose you purchase a share of General Motors for $35.75
and a few months later, GM announces a hot new car that runs on sunlight
rather than gasoline. It seems likely that GM will earn lots of lovely money
selling that car, so people want to buy stock in the company. Demand
drives the price of the stock higher. When it reaches $50.25, you decide to
sell and realize a capital gain of $14.50.
Money Talks
stock options
Stock options are a type of derivative that allow for the purchase of
shares of stock at a predetermined price. Companies often issue
stock options to key employees as a reward for performance. The
recipients can either sell their option contract on the options
exchange or wait and exercise their option when the share price of
the stock increases.
The majority of stock purchases and sales occur in the secondary market.
When you place an order to buy stock, you are most likely buying shares that
were previously owned by another individual. If Tina buys Coca-Cola stock in
the market, she is buying it from someone else, not Coca-Cola. If she pays $150
for two shares of Coca-Cola stock, some other investor who sold the stock will
receive $150, but Coca-Cola will receive nothing. The only time the firm
receives money in a stock purchase is through an IPO or when the firm sells
stock that it had repurchased earlier.
TYPES OF STOCKS
Whether you know it or not, foreign exchange is a part of your everyday life.
From the products you buy to the vacations you take, foreign exchange affects
much of what you do. The flow of currency between nations is also a matter of
record keeping. The balance of payments records all of the inflows and outflows
of currency from a country. The sum of net exports, net foreign factor income,
and net transfers is the current account balance, while net foreign investment and
official reserves make up the financial account.
EXCHANGE RATES
What determines the price of apples? If you answered supply and demand, then
you would be correct. What determines the foreign exchange price of a dollar?
Once again, if you said supply and demand, then you are right on target.
Whenever one currency is exchanged for another, foreign exchange has occurred
and an exchange rate has been paid. The exchange rate is nothing more than the
current price of a currency in terms of another currency. For example, $1 may
buy you €0.73, £0.64, ¥89.41, or SFr 1.07.
Exchange rates are determined in the world’s largest market, the foreign
exchange market. Annual trade volume approaches $1 quadrillion (a thousand
trillion), with transactions occurring twenty-four hours a day. The foreign
exchange market is dominated by the British, Americans, and Japanese with the
vast majority of trades occurring in the U.S. dollar. The euro (€), pound sterling
(£), Japanese yen (¥), and Swiss franc (SFr) are the other hard currencies most
often traded.
Who’s involved?
Large banks are the main players in the foreign exchange market, brought
together through a system of interconnected brokers. The banks serve both
corporate and individual customers who need foreign exchange in order to
conduct business.
Central banks also participate in the foreign exchange market in order to
either manipulate exchange rates or to correct imbalances between their
country’s current and financial accounts.
Finally, speculators looking to profit from arbitrage opportunities also
participate in this immense market.
When traveling, you can often find the best exchange rates on your
credit card or by accessing an ATM. Banks are the major players in
the foreign exchange market and are able to grant their customers
some of the most competitive rates.
Exchange rates are subject to the forces of supply and demand. As exchange
rates rise, people are more willing to sell their currency, but others are less
willing to buy, and vice versa. Appreciation occurs when an exchange rate
increases, and depreciation occurs when exchange rates fall. Changes in
exchange rates can wreak havoc on businesses and entire economies.
Economists and policymakers must therefore consider the implications of their
actions on exchange rates. Tastes, interest rates, inflation, relative income, and
speculation affect exchange rates and thus economies as a whole.
Taste and Preference
As consumers’ tastes for imported goods change, so does the exchange rate
between the countries involved. The popularity of cars and consumer electronics
from South Korea among American consumers necessarily creates a demand for
South Korea’s currency, the won (W). In order for American importers to
acquire South Korean products, they must supply dollars and demand won in
foreign exchange. The result of this change in tastes is a depreciation of the
dollar and appreciation of the won.
Over time, appreciation of a country’s currency may reduce the popularity of
its products as they become relatively more expensive. Given that people often
prefer relatively cheaper goods, foreign manufacturers that export goods to the
United States might choose to price their products directly in dollars as opposed
to their domestic currency. This helps to insulate the manufacturer from
changing exchange rates, which might reduce their product’s competitiveness on
the American market. German automakers engage in this practice to offset the
effects of the euro’s relative strength against the dollar.
Over the course of a year you might hear experts lamenting the size
of the trade deficit, while later others might complain of a weak
dollar. Actually, a weak dollar is the remedy for a trade deficit.
Depreciated dollars encourage exports and discourage imports.
Words like strong and weak can be misleading. They do not
necessarily mean good or bad.
In the United States, most producers focus on meeting the demands of the
domestic market. Some, however, produce goods and services for export to
foreign markets. Other businesses import those goods and services for which
there is a demand or the United States does not produce. Half of the United
States’ trade occurs with Canada, Mexico, China, Japan, Germany, and the
United Kingdom.
Net Transfers
Other actions besides trade require foreign exchange. Transfer payments,
called remittances, and foreign aid create outflows of currency from rich
countries to poor countries in foreign exchange markets. Remittances differ from
foreign factor income in that they are unearned by the recipients. Foreign aid in
the form of cash payments also creates a need for foreign exchange. The United
States’ aid payments to Pakistan, Israel, and Egypt are examples.
Net Foreign Investment
Unlike net exports, net foreign factor income, and net transfers, which involve
one-time exchanges, net foreign investment creates recurring payments and
income. When citizens of one country purchase the real or financial assets of
another country, it is classified as net foreign investment. Net foreign investment
also includes portfolio investment. Portfolio investment occurs when foreigners
purchase the financial assets of another country. During the recent financial
crisis, the dollar appreciated quickly as foreign investors sought the safety of
U.S. Treasury bills, notes, and bonds. Purchasing shares of stock in foreign
companies is another form of portfolio investment. Because developing
countries often have higher rates of economic growth and higher rates of
interest, financial investors might purchase bonds and stocks in these countries.
Capital Controls
Money Talks
monetary policy
Efforts by the central bank of a country to stabilize prices, promote
full employment, and encourage long-run economic growth through
controlling the money supply and interest rates.
In 2010, Greece suffered a severe financial blow when its sovereign debt’s
credit rating was reduced. Unable to implement independent monetary policy,
the Greeks have been forced to reduce their spending and raise taxes or risk
default. The EU’s reaction to this crisis will either weaken or bolster the euro’s
chances of becoming the dominant world currency.
THE PRIVATE SECTOR AND THE
PUBLIC SECTOR
Just Goin’ with the Flow
Where is the government getting the income with which to buy the
factors of production from households and goods from the firms?
Taxes, in both the factor market and the product market, are the
source of governments’ income. Taxes on personal income and
corporate profits are collected in the factor market. Sales tax is an
example of a tax collected in the product market. Sometimes the
government subsidizes firms, which represents a flow of money from
government to firms. Like firms that receive subsidies, many
households receive transfer payments like Social Security and
welfare.
THE FOREIGN SECTOR
It’s a Small, Small World
Of course, the domestic economy does not exist in isolation, with the United
States floating in its own little economic bubble. The United States is part of the
much larger world economy. The foreign sector refers to the rest of the world.
Foreign Transfers
A considerable amount of money is transferred to other countries not in
payment for goods and services but to help support family members. This type
of transfer, called a remittance, affects the economy but does not constitute a
direct exchange in a market. India is a prime example of a country dependent
upon a large expatriate community. Many Indians living abroad remit money to
their extended families back in India. Likewise, Mexico is heavily dependent
upon remittances from emigrants working in the United States.
So far in our discussion of the circular flow theory, financial intermediaries have
been left out of the picture, literally. The financial sector, or intermediaries like
banks, credit unions, insurance companies, and stock exchanges, help to
facilitate all of the transactions that have been mentioned in this discussion. The
importance of financial intermediaries cannot be underestimated. They stand in
the middle of almost all transactions. Without them, most modern markets would
be unable to function. They are the grease that makes the wheels turn smoothly,
the key that unlocks the door, the wind beneath your wings.
FINANCIAL INTERMEDIARIES
Most of the transactions that are conducted in the product market either involve
the use of checks, debit cards, credit cards, cash drawn from ATMs (rather than
from under your mattress), or in the case of exports and imports, foreign
exchange. All of these services are provided by the financial intermediaries but
of course not out of the goodness of their hearts. Rather, like any business, they
are motivated by the potential of profit, so they charge a fee for their services.
Up to this point, all of the income that has been earned by households, firms,
government, and the rest of the world has been spent in the circular flow model.
Dollar in = dollar out. But private, public, and foreign sectors don’t only spend
money—they also save it. To account for the fact that the different economic
sectors save a portion of their income, the circular flow model enters the third
dimension.
This third dimension is the financial markets. Households save for the future,
government can run a budget surplus, businesses retain earnings for future
investment, and the foreign sector engages in real and portfolio investment in the
United States. Where do all of these savings go? Savings flow to financial
intermediaries and from there (in the form of loans) to all sectors of the
economy:
When households save, they may buy shares of stock, bonds, or certificates
of deposit.
Government finances its spending in excess of taxes by issuing the various
Treasury securities.
THE GROSS DOMESTIC
PRODUCT
Keeping Score
Keeping score is important. If you are trying to lose a few extra pounds, stepping
on the scale from time to time allows you to evaluate your performance. In
school, teachers assign grades to assess students’ level of understanding. In
baseball, statistics on nearly every aspect of the game are used to determine the
pitchers and the batting order. Data and statistics are useful for making informed
decisions. During World War II, the U.S. government wanted to better
understand the economy’s ability to generate the necessary materials for the war
effort. This led to the development of gross domestic product (GDP) as a means
of measuring economic output. GDP is important today as an overall indicator of
economic performance.
GDP is not static. Instead, GDP is a flow. Imagine a bathtub with a running
faucet and open drain. The water flowing from the faucet is GDP, the water
accumulating in the tub is the wealth of the nation, and the water exiting the
drain represents an outflow like depreciation. As long as the GDP exceeds
outflows of wealth, the wealth of the nation grows. Essentially GDP measures
that production that is new and is not a measure of accumulated wealth.
COUNTED OR NOT?
GDP includes much economic activity but not all of it. As a measure of
production, GDP does not include purely financial transactions. When you
purchase shares in the stock market, only the broker’s commission would be
counted in GDP. This is because the purchase of stock represents a transfer of
ownership from one shareholder to another, and neither a good nor service is
produced. Similarly, transfer payments like Social Security are not computed in
GDP. Social Security payments are not made in return for the production of a
new good or service, but instead represent a transfer from a taxed wage earner to
a recipient.
Production for which no financial transaction occurs is also excluded from
GDP. A stay-at-home parent who cares for the children, cleans the house, cooks,
and runs errands certainly produces something of great value, but because no
monetary payment is made, the value is undetermined and excluded.
Interestingly, paying someone to do all of those activities would be included in
GDP. Building a deck on your house, mowing your own grass, and changing
your own oil are all services that can be purchased, but when you perform them
for yourself, they are not included in GDP.
Apartment and house rent is included in consumption, and therefore GDP.
Homeowners and mortgage payers do not pay rent, so the BEA imputes a rental
payment on their housing. Whether you are an owner or a renter, when it comes
to GDP, everyone is a renter.
to GDP, everyone is a renter.
To avoid overstating GDP, resale and intermediate production is excluded.
Most home purchases are not counted in GDP. The resale of homes does not
represent new production and is excluded. The only time home purchases are
included is when the house is newly constructed. The primary reason resale is
not counted is to avoid double-counting. Older homes were included in a
previous year’s GDP. Consider the sale of flour, butter, and sugar to a bakery
that produces fresh bread. If the purchase of ingredients were included in GDP
along with the sale of the fresh bread, the GDP would be overstated. To avoid
this, GDP includes only final production of the bread. The price of the bread
includes the earlier cost incurred in acquiring the ingredients.
GDP: PRIVATE SPENDING AND
INVESTMENT
Because You’re Worth It
Autonomous Consumption
Economists recognize that some consumption is independent of disposable
income and refer to this as autonomous consumption. During periods of
recession, consumption of durable goods is curtailed while consumption of
essentials like food, rent, clothing, and healthcare remains relatively unaffected.
Do you remember what it was like on September 12, 2001? What type of
consumption occurred and what type did not? Chances are that autonomous
consumption of necessities and nondurables continued unabated, but
consumption of durable goods (except for guns and ammo) and discretionary
spending came to a halt.
GROSS PRIVATE INVESTMENT
Future Expectation
The level of investment in the economy is influenced by expectations of future
business conditions and interest rates. Positive expectations tend to boost
investment while negative expectations result in less investment. Businesses
respond this way in order to have the right amount of productive capacity to
meet the expected future demand for their products. Interest rates are also a
major consideration in the decision to invest. As interest rates rise, the relative
profitability of investment decreases. Decisions to invest compare the expected
rate of return to the current interest rate. As long as the expected rate of return
exceeds the interest rate, businesses will undertake investment with the
expectation of profit. Increased interest rates have the effect of making fewer
investments profitable.
The GDP isn’t measured just by adding together private spending and
investment by households and businesses in the domestic market. It is also
affected by government spending and international trade.
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
Government spending includes federal, state, and local expenditures on capital,
infrastructure, and employee compensation. Military expenditures, road
construction, and teacher salaries are all included. Government spending is
financed by taxation and borrowing. The opportunity cost of government
spending is the forgone consumption and gross private investment that might
have otherwise occurred (you might have spent that $500 on a nice new
television but you had to send it to Uncle Sam instead). Transfer payments (such
as Social Security benefits and certain subsidies to businesses) are not included
as government spending for the purpose of calculating GDP.
Government spending accounts for about 40% of the GDP in the United
States. Government spending as a percentage of GDP varies widely throughout
the world from a low of about 16% in countries such as Bangladesh and the
Central African Republic, to about 65% in countries such as Cuba and Lesotho.
In most developed countries, government spending as a percentage of GDP runs
about 35–50%.
Pork-Barrel Politics
NET EXPORTS
NET EXPORTS
Net exports, or exports minus imports, are the last spending variable in
measuring GDP. Export of new domestic production adds to GDP. Imports, on
the other hand, subtract from GDP. The United States typically runs a balance of
trade deficit, so in most years net exports are deducted from, instead of added to,
GDP. In recent years, export growth has helped to sustain GDP. Compared to
most other nations, U.S. net exports represent a very small percentage of
economic activity. Even though no country engages in as much international
trade by volume as the United States, the United States remains one of the least
trade-dependent nations in the world.
Net exports may not be a real big deal in America, but for developing
countries, net exports are the road to economic growth. China is a
key example of a country dependent on net exports for growth. As
the Chinese economy matures, its industry may become more
oriented toward domestic production.
Net exports are influenced by exchange rates, and like consumption and
investment, also by interest rates. Appreciation of the dollar makes American
goods relatively expensive, so exports decline and imports rise. Depreciation of
the dollar, on the other hand, makes American goods relatively cheap, so exports
increase and imports decrease. Interest rates impact net exports through their
effect on the exchange rate. High interest rates in America lead to an
appreciation of the dollar, which reduces net exports, but low American interest
rates help to depreciate the dollar and encourage net exports.
APPROACHES TO GDP
Lies, Damned Lies, and Statistics
Income Underreporting
Another way of calculating the GDP is to add together all of the production
activity in a country. In this approach, the value added at each stage of the
production process is calculated. For example, a car is the final output but the
engineer’s intermediate input has a value that can be determined. An obvious
drawback to this approach is determining the difference between intermediate
and final goods. Is a pound of sugar an intermediate or final good? The answer
is, it depends on who is buying it and why.
In this approach, market and nonmarket production must both be valued.
Market production is goods produced for sale in the marketplace (such as
widgets produced by corporations). Nonmarket production includes services not
for market sale (such as that provided by the government or nonprofits—for
example, the free lunch program offered each summer by your local school).
Nonmarket production can be difficult to value as it doesn’t have a price tag
attached to it, so generally it is considered to be the cost of production.
U.S. government agencies do not use this approach to calculate GDP.
U.S. government agencies do not use this approach to calculate GDP.
The concepts of nominal and real appear throughout economics, and GDP is no
exception. Nominal GDP is reported using current prices. In order for
economists to make valid comparisons in GDP from year to year, the price
changes that occur with time’s passage have to be addressed. Real GDP reports
output, holding prices constant. If the change in prices (inflation) is not
accounted for in calculating GDP, results may be misleading—the economy may
appear to be growing when in fact all that’s happening is inflation.
Nominal GDP must be deflated in order to calculate real GDP. Assume an
extremely simple economy that produces multicolored beach balls. In 2014, the
economy produced 100 beach balls that were all purchased by consumers at $1
apiece. In 2015, the economy produced 100 identical beach balls that were all
purchased by consumers for $1.25 apiece. Given this information, nominal GDP
for each year can be calculated by multiplying the number of beach balls by that
year’s current price, so in 2014 nominal GDP was $100, and in 2015 it was
$125. An outside observer might come to the incorrect conclusion that output
increased by 25%. The reality was that output did not change, but prices rose by
25%. To compare what really happened, prices must be held constant. Using
2014 prices, the real GDP for 2014 and 2015 is $100; in other words, real output
remained constant.
Over the last fifty years, America has undergone alternating periods of recession
and economic expansion. The ups and downs have occurred against a
background of long-run economic growth. In other words, from year to year the
GDP may go up and down overall but the trend is upward. Since 1960, the U.S.
real GDP has increased by more than $10 trillion.
If you have ever been on a long car trip, you can understand the business
cycle. Imagine cruising along a two-lane highway, going with the flow of traffic.
This going with the flow is the norm and represents the average rate of economic
growth. Occasionally, somebody will be moving a little too slowly, so you scan
for oncoming traffic. If it’s clear, you accelerate and pass the slower driver.
Passing represents those periods where spending exceeds the productive
capacity. Every once in a while, you make a mistake while trying to pass slower
traffic. You scan for oncoming traffic and make your move, only to discover that
a fully loaded eighteen-wheeler is barreling down the highway in the oncoming
lane. You immediately switch back into your lane, shaking violently, and slow to
thirty miles per hour, thankful that you are still alive. Events like this are
representative of economic contractions. Eventually, you compose yourself and
start to travel with the flow of traffic again.
Now, to really understand the business cycle, imagine that you are blindfolded
the whole time and relying on an extremely myopic passenger speaking Swahili
to provide information about what is happening. To be sure, it would be an
interesting ride. Why the blindfold and Swahili? Outside of psychics, prophets,
meteorologists, and the rare economist, most Americans have difficulty seeing
into the future. The language of economists and financial experts is often
difficult to interpret.
In a 1968 speech, the late presidential candidate Robert F. Kennedy stated the
following about the weaknesses of our key measure of economic performance at
that time, gross national product. The same weaknesses apply to GDP:
“Too much and for too long, we seemed to have surrendered personal
excellence and community values in the mere accumulation of material
things. Our gross national product . . . if we judge the United States of
America by that . . . counts air pollution and cigarette advertising, and
ambulances to clear our highways of carnage. It counts special locks for
our doors and the jails for the people who break them. It counts the
destruction of the redwoods and the loss of our natural wonder in chaotic
sprawl. It counts napalm and it counts nuclear warheads, and armored cars
for the police to fight the riots in our cities. It counts Whitman’s rifle and
Speck’s knife, and the television programs which glorify violence in order
to sell toys to our children.
“Yet the gross national product does not allow for the health of our
children, the quality of their education, or the joy of their play. It does not
include the beauty of our poetry or the strength of our marriages; the
intelligence of our public debate or the integrity of our public officials. It
measures neither our wit nor our courage; neither our wisdom nor our
learning; neither our compassion nor our devotion to our country; it
measures everything, in short, except that which makes life worthwhile. And
it can tell us everything about America except why we are proud that we
are Americans.”
REAL GDP AND SOCIAL GOOD
Kennedy’s point should be clear. GDP, for all of its inclusiveness, excludes
many important things—not least of which is the value of unpaid labor such as
caring for your children or elderly parents. However, consider the fact that as
real GDP has increased, the burdens of scarcity and the incidence of absolute
poverty have been lifted for millions of people. Yesterday’s relative wealth is
today’s relative poverty. Compared to the lives of Americans of previous
generations, the availability of healthcare, education, nutrition, sanitation, and
housing has increased with the increases in real GDP. These have led to an
increase in longevity.
The increase in real GDP has been accompanied by more leisure time as well.
The average workweek has steadily declined, and the average number of
vacation days has increased. As a measure of well-being, the GDP has both
strengths and weaknesses.
In response to complaints about what GDP measures, other formulas have been
explored that address its shortcomings. Some of these include:
One of the most gratifying things that you can hear is, “We like you, and you’re
the right fit for this company. Congratulations, you’re hired!” One of the worst
things you can hear is, “You’re fired.” Unemployment can make economics
suddenly appear very relevant to your life. Economists define, measure, classify,
evaluate, and seek to understand this all-too-common phenomenon. Many
economists have made it their life’s work to minimize the problem of
unemployment, and policymakers are under political pressure to do so as well.
According to the Census Bureau, the 2008 U.S. population was approximately
300 million, of which 145 million were employed. How many were
unemployed? It might come as a surprise to you that the answer to that question
cannot be determined from the information given. True, you can infer that 155
million did not work, but that does not necessarily mean that they were all
unemployed. Are toddlers and kindergarteners unemployed? To determine the
number of unemployed, you must first define the term unemployment.
Persons sixteen years of age or older are considered unemployed if they have
actively searched for work in the last four weeks, but are not currently
employed. The employed are those who have worked at least one hour in the
previous two weeks. People who meet neither criterion are not considered in the
labor force, which is the number of employed persons plus the number of
unemployed persons. The unemployment rate that you hear quoted in the news is
not a percentage of the population, but a percentage of the labor force that is not
not a percentage of the population, but a percentage of the labor force that is not
currently employed.
There are many reasons for not participating in the labor force. Full-time
students, retirees, stay-at-home parents, the disabled, and the institutionalized do
not participate. Members of the military on active duty are not considered part of
the labor force either. At any point in time there are people entering, exiting, and
re-entering the labor force. Furthermore, people are forever getting hired, fired,
and furloughed. They are also quitting, cutting back, and retiring. The labor
force is in constant flux, which makes measuring unemployment a daunting task.
MEASURING UNEMPLOYMENT
TYPES OF UNEMPLOYMENT
Frictional Unemployment
Is 0% unemployment a good goal for society? It is most definitely not. A 0%
unemployment goal ignores the presence of frictional unemployment. Frictional
unemployment occurs when people voluntarily enter the labor force, or when
they are between jobs for which they are qualified. It is frictional because the
labor market does not automatically match up all available jobs with all available
workers.
Instead, a job search requires time for the right worker to find the right job.
Both workers and society benefit when job applicants are matched to the
appropriate job. You want mechanical engineers to get jobs in mechanical
engineering, not pet grooming.
The rate of frictional unemployment is relatively low, and as technology
increases and search times diminish, it becomes even lower. The advent of
online job search sites and social networking has reduced job search times for
many workers.
Government Incentives and Frictional
Unemployment
Structural Unemployment
Structural unemployment occurs when job seekers’ skill sets are not in
demand because of geography or obsolescence. As industries die out in certain
regions of the country or relocate to other regions, the workers may not be able
to move with the job. This leaves workers with a skill set that is no longer in
demand. These workers must either retrain or accept a lower-paying job in an
industry that requires less skill. Structural unemployment is often the outcome of
what economist Joseph Schumpeter called creative destruction. As innovation
occurs, old technologies and industries are destroyed, which frees up the
resources for the new technology and its industry.
The invention of the personal computer was the death knell for the typewriter.
As the new technology advanced, the old technology and its industry were
destroyed. Over time, skilled typewriter repair technicians found that their skill
set was no longer in demand and faced the permanent destruction of their jobs.
As this was occurring, new jobs were being created in the new industry. The
problem for workers is that their skill sets may not translate into the new
industry. The solution for structural unemployment is education and retraining.
Unemployment Classifications
Unemployment Classifications
Cyclical Unemployment
The most insidious type of unemployment is cyclical. Cyclical unemployment
occurs because of contractions in the business cycle. It is not voluntary, nor is it
the result of a skill-set mismatch. During periods of recession, the official
unemployment rate increases as cyclical unemployment adds to the always-
present frictional and structural rates of unemployment. The recession that began
in 2007 saw the official unemployment rate increase from 5% to 10%. The
additional increase is directly attributed to cyclical unemployment.
The real problem with cyclical unemployment is that it creates a feedback
loop. As one group becomes cyclically unemployed, they cut back on spending,
which leads to more cyclical unemployment. This feedback loop resulted in 25%
unemployment during the Great Depression. Policymakers respond to cyclical
unemployment with discretionary fiscal and monetary policy. In addition,
automatic stabilizers like unemployment compensation help to dampen the
feedback loop by allowing affected workers to have some capacity for spending.
Ultimately the goal of policymakers is to eliminate cyclical unemployment
altogether.
FULL EMPLOYMENT
When the economy is producing at its optimum capacity, cruising down the road
at the speed limit, neither speeding nor driving too slowly, it is safe to assume
that the economy is also at full employment. Full employment occurs when
cyclical unemployment is not present in the economy. This economic nirvana is
the goal that policymakers seek to maintain.
Economists associate full employment with the natural rate of unemployment.
The natural rate hypothesis advanced by Nobel economists Milton Friedman and
Edmund Phelps suggests that in the long run there is a level of unemployment
that the economy maintains independent of the inflation rate. The idea is that left
alone, the economy will maintain full employment and experience the natural
rate of unemployment most of the time.
It is possible for the natural rate of unemployment to vary. If frictional or
structural rates of unemployment were to change, then the natural rate of
unemployment would change. A technology that permanently reduces search
times for job seekers would have the effect of reducing both frictional
unemployment and the natural rate of unemployment. Permanent changes in
unemployment compensation that encourage or discourage lengthy periods of
unemployment would also affect the natural rate. Finally, lasting increases in
worker productivity would reduce the natural rate of unemployment.
Different countries have different natural rates of unemployment. Economies
that are more market oriented like the United States have low natural rates of
unemployment. Socialist economies tend to have higher natural rates of
unemployment. Economists theorize that socialist economies have both higher
frictional and structural rates of unemployment because of government policies
that lead to less flexible labor markets. The highest natural rates of
unemployment occur in countries where labor is unskilled and immobile, and job
creation is stymied by corrupt, inefficient governments.
WHY UNEMPLOYMENT IS BAD
Living Up to Your Potential
Unemployment creates a measurable cost for the economy and individuals. The
opportunity cost of unemployment is immense when considering the scale of the
U.S. economy.
When workers are unemployed, they are unable to produce output. According
to the economist Arthur Okun, for every 1% that the official unemployment rate
exceeds the natural rate of unemployment, there is a 2% gap between actual and
potential real GDP. Given the GDP and unemployment figures from 2009, when
actual output was $14 trillion and unemployment was 10%, and assuming a
natural rate of 5%, actual output may have been $1 trillion to $2 trillion below its
potential. By way of comparison, a $2 trillion output gap is like sacrificing the
entire economic output of France.
TRENDS IN UNEMPLOYMENT
The U.S. economy has undergone several major shifts. Initially, the United
States was an agrarian nation and most employment was related to farming. The
Industrial Revolution saw a shift toward manufacturing employment. Today,
most jobs are created in the service sector. As America moves away from
agriculture and manufacturing, fewer and fewer jobs in those areas will remain.
Globalization has shifted many low-skill jobs overseas, which leaves America’s
unskilled workers with fewer opportunities.
Demand for labor is driven by worker productivity. The more skills workers
possess, the greater the demand for their labor. To stay competitive, future
workers must realize that they are not just competing against their fellow
Americans but against the rest of the world. The days when you could graduate
from high school and get a good-paying job at the factory are gone, unless, of
course, you live in China. To compete in the global job market, Americans must
course, you live in China. To compete in the global job market, Americans must
be willing to train, stay mobile, and constantly adjust to the changing needs of
their employers.
Less than a high school diploma: 8.6% (in May 2014, it was
9.2%)
High school graduate, no college: 5.8% (in May 2014, it was
6.5%)
Some college or associate’s degree: 4.4% (in May 2014, it was
5.5%)
Bachelor’s degree or higher: 2.7% (in May 2014, it was 3.2%)
INFLATION DEFINED
The Incredible Shrinking Dollar
Were you a little frustrated a few years back when gas prices suddenly rose? The
increase in gas prices probably created some hardship as you altered your
spending in order to accommodate its higher cost. Now imagine that not just gas
prices, but the price of almost everything you buy, suddenly and unexpectedly
increases. If you are on a fixed income, then there is only so much altering you
can do to a budget before you realize that high prices are killing your finances.
Inflation is a phenomenon that you need to understand if you want to
comprehend how the economy works.
WHAT IS INFLATION?
No word strikes more fear into the hearts of central bankers than inflation.
Defined as a general increase in prices or as a decrease in money’s purchasing
power, inflation creates problems for more than central bankers. Inflation affects
everyone in the economy. Governments, businesses, and households are subject
to inflation’s influence.
Inflation is either created by excessive demand or increases in producers’ per-
unit costs, but it is sustained by too much money in circulation. Left unchecked,
inflation can have cataclysmic results for a society.
During the 1920s, the Weimar Republic of Germany suffered from extreme
inflation. Instead of taxing or borrowing to raise revenue, the government began
to print money for the purpose of making its purchases. The result was runaway
inflation. Some historians credit the period of inflation and the resulting loss of
confidence in the Weimar Republic for sowing the seeds of Hitler’s eventual rise
confidence in the Weimar Republic for sowing the seeds of Hitler’s eventual rise
to power.
Hyperinflation
Hungarian inflation was so severe in 1945 and 1946 that prices were
measured in not tens or hundreds, but billions, trillions, and even
octillions. By the end of the period of Hungarian hyperinflation, the
total supply of pengos in circulation had less value than a single
pengo did at the beginning.
If you were around in the 1970s, then you might remember the time period
known as the Great Inflation. The Vietnam War, OPEC, the collapse of the
adjustable peg system (where world currencies were pegged to the dollar), and
poorly managed monetary policy created conditions of rising prices and
uncertainty. Although American inflation did not even come close to
approaching the levels of inflation in the Weimar Republic and modern-day
Zimbabwe, it was enough to cause political turmoil and bring lasting change to
the way policymakers manage the price level.
MEASURING INFLATION
Inflation is the rate of increase in the average price level of the economy. To
measure inflation first requires that the price level be measured. Economists
have come up with different ways to measure the general price level in the
economy, and therefore, inflation. The most often cited measure of inflation is
the change in the consumer price index (CPI). In addition, economists and
policymakers pay attention to changes in the producer price index (PPI) and
personal consumption expenditure (PCE) deflator.
Consumer price index (CPI): The consumer price index is a market basket
approach to measuring inflation constructed by the Bureau of Labor
Statistics. Changes in the CPI indicate inflation or deflation. CPI is the most
widely used measure of inflation in the American economy.
Producer price index (PPI): A measure of producer price inflation that acts
as a leading indicator of future consumer price inflation.
Personal consumption expenditure (PCE) deflator: A price index used to
measure consumer price inflation that is more inclusive than the popular
consumer price index (CPI).
The CPI
The CPI is a market basket approach to measuring the price level and inflation
published by the BLS. The CPI measures the average cost of food, clothing,
shelter, energy, transportation, and healthcare that the average urban consumer
buys. To understand CPI, imagine that you are given a shopping list of
thousands of different items. You are then told to research and write down the
price of each specific item, and afterward add them all together. The total cost of
the list would represent an average price level. Further assume that a year later
you took the same list and repeated the process. Increases in the shopping list’s
you took the same list and repeated the process. Increases in the shopping list’s
total would represent inflation.
The PPI
The PPI is similar to the CPI, but instead of consumer prices, the PPI looks at
producer prices. The PPI includes all domestic production of goods and services.
Unlike the CPI, the PPI also includes the prices of goods sold by one producer to
another. Changes in the PPI can be used as a predictor of future changes in the
CPI. Before consumer prices change, the producer price changes. Because it
predicts changes in the CPI, the government and central bank use the PPI to
create fiscal and monetary policy in anticipation of possible consumer inflation.
DEMAND-PULL INFLATION
Demand-pull inflation occurs when spending on goods and services drives up
prices. In other words, aggregate demand is greater than aggregate supply.
Demand-pull inflation is fueled by income, so efforts to stop it involve reducing
consumers’ income or giving consumers more incentive to save than to spend.
Money Talks
aggregate demand
The inverse relationship that exists between the real GDP and the
price level in the economy. Aggregate demand (AD) is the
willingness and ability of households, firms, government, and the
foreign sector to buy the new, domestic production of a nation.
Money Talks
Money Talks
aggregate supply
The real gross domestic product that firms are willing to produce at
each and every price level. In the short run, real GDP and price level
are directly related, but in the long run, real GDP is independent of
the price level.
Demand-pull inflation persists if the public or foreign sector reinforces it. Low
taxes and profligate government spending exacerbate demand-pull inflation. A
failure of the central bank to reign in the money supply also makes the demand-
pull inflation worse.
Demand-pull inflation can spread across borders as well. China’s and India’s
economic growth not only puts pressure on prices in these countries, but also
prices worldwide as the demand for imports increase.
Money Talks
asset inflation
Asset inflation is a type of inflation that occurs only in a specific
industry, such as the housing market, and can happen when overall
inflation is otherwise low. This creates what is popularly called a
“bubble,” where prices rise quickly, beyond a sustainable point. It
can be made worse by a supply shortage. Eventually the market
collapses, rapidly devaluing the assets in that class.
Monetizing the debt refers to the process by which the central bank
buys new government debt, thus increasing the supply of money in
circulation. When debt is monetized, the government is able to
spend without raising taxes or borrowing from the private sector. The
downside is that debt monetization is extremely inflationary.
COST-PUSH INFLATION
Cost-push inflation occurs when the price of inputs increases. Businesses must
acquire raw materials, labor, energy, and capital to operate. If the price of these
were to rise, it would reduce the ability of producers to generate output because
their unit cost of production had increased. If these increases in production cost
are relatively large and pervasive, the effect is to simultaneously create higher
inflation, reduce real GDP, and increase the unemployment rate.
Stagflation
Money Talks
assets
Everything that is owned by an individual or firm. For banks, assets
include its reserves, loans to customers, securities, and real estate.
Good Inflation
Inflation creates winners and losers. Knowing who wins is important for
understanding why it is sometimes allowed to persist. When inflation is expected
and stable, it is rather benign. People and institutions can plan for it and build it
into their decision-making. If inflation is unexpected, it creates a win-lose
situation in society. Who stands to gain from inflation?
One of the triumphs of Fed policy came in the early 1980s when the central bank
under the direction of then-chairman Paul Volcker raised interest rates and
helped bring inflation down from double digits to a more modest 4%, thus
ending the period known as the Great Inflation. If you were around at the time,
then you will recall that the Fed action also resulted in the worst recession in
decades. In retrospect, many economists agree that the reduction in inflation or
disinflation that resulted was worth the cost of recession. From the 1980s
onward, inflation remained relatively low and stable and ushered in an economic
era known as the Great Moderation.
DISINFLATION
Disinflation is beneficial to an economy for several reasons. Disinflation reduces
pressure to increase wages, as prices are more stable. Disinflation also results in
lower, more stable interest rates, which makes capital investment less costly and
easier to plan. Arguably the most important outcome of disinflation is that
producers’ and consumers’ inflationary expectations are lowered, which results
in a profoundly more stable economic environment.
Central bank authorities try to manage not only actual inflation, but more
importantly, the expectation of future inflation. Because the fear of inflation is
often enough to create it, policymakers are in the business of acting as a
psychologist to the economy.
It is not enough to talk the talk when it comes to managing expectations,
however; the Fed must walk the walk. If you have ever dealt with children, you
know that words without action are meaningless. A parent may respond to a
teenager’s rude behavior by threatening, “If you don’t stop behaving this way, I
will confiscate your cell phone for the weekend.” If the rude behavior continues
and the parent doesn’t act on the threat, the parent’s credibility is undermined. A
parent who consistently follows through, however, is much more credible.
Likewise, the Federal Reserve bolsters its credibility when it raises interest
Likewise, the Federal Reserve bolsters its credibility when it raises interest
rates in response to inflation fears, but loses credibility when it fails to respond
forcibly to the possibility of inflation. The Fed’s credibility as an inflation
fighter was greatly reinforced by Paul Volcker’s chairmanship because he said
what he meant and meant what he said.
DEFLATION
If inflation is bad and disinflation is better, then deflation must be best, right?
Wrong. Deflation occurs when the average price level is declining and money’s
purchasing power is increasing. What could be wrong with that? The problem
with deflation is that it creates a perverse set of incentives in the economy. If
prices are steadily declining, then consumers delay their purchase of durable
goods as the deals just keep getting better as time passes. If this behavior
continues, manufacturing grinds to a halt and widespread unemployment results.
The unemployment would then reinforce the deflation, as fewer and fewer
consumers would be willing and able to purchase goods and services. Producers
respond similarly to deflation by delaying investment and compounding the
effects of the delayed consumption.
Deflation poses a policy dilemma for central banks that primarily use interest
rates to influence economic activity. In response to increased inflation, central
banks raise interest rates to reduce the flow of credit and cool inflation pressure.
There is no upper limit to how high an interest rate can go, but the opposite is
not true. Given deflation, central banks will lower interest rates to encourage
investment and consumption. If the lower interest rates do not have the desired
effect, central banks will continue to lower them until they hit what economists
refer to as the zero bound. Once interest rates are at zero, they cannot go lower.
John Maynard Keynes referred to this weakness in monetary policy as
liquidity trap. If consumers and investors will not borrow at 0% interest, then
you are out of options.
The Deflation Solution
Once you understand the concepts of supply and demand, GDP, unemployment,
and inflation, you have a toolkit for understanding the economic fluctuations that
occur. The aggregate demand and aggregate supply model will allow you to
analyze the entire economy. You’ll even be able to predict what might happen
given certain events. If you’re not careful, you might end up sounding like an
economist the next time the Fed raises interest rates.
AGGREGATE DEMAND
Recall that demand is the willingness and ability of consumers to purchase a
good or service at various prices in a specific period of time. Aggregate demand
(AD) is a similar concept, but has some important distinctions. AD is the
demand for all final domestic production in a country. Instead of just
households, AD comes from all sectors of the economy. Furthermore, AD relates
the price level to the amount of real GDP instead of price to quantity.
The relationship between the price level and the amount of real GDP is
inverse. The higher the price level, the less real GDP is demanded, and the lower
the price level, the more real GDP is demanded. This is true because as the price
level rises, money and other financial assets lose purchasing power. Fewer
people demand our exports, and corresponding higher interest rates discourage
investment and consumption. As the price level decreases, purchasing power
increases, exports become more affordable to foreigners, and the corresponding
lower interest rates encourage investment and consumption.
lower interest rates encourage investment and consumption.
Changes in AD occur when consumption, private investment, government
spending, or net exports change independent of changes in the price level. For
example, if the general mood of the country improves and consumers and
businesses are feeling more confident, they will consume and invest more,
regardless of the price level. This increase in consumption and investment
increases AD.
Likewise, increases in government spending or net exports also tend to
increase AD. Reductions in any of the spending components of GDP will tend to
suppress AD. If government raises the average tax rates on income, households’
disposable income is reduced, and they consume less, which reduces AD.
AGGREGATE SUPPLY
Supply is the willingness and ability of producers to generate the output of some
good or service at various prices in a specific time period. Aggregate supply is a
much broader concept than supply because it is inclusive of all domestic
production, not just a singular good or service. Like an individual firm, an
economy has a production function that relates the amount of labor employed
with the amount of output or real GDP that the economy can produce with some
fixed level of capital. In the short run, the amount of real GDP supplied is
directly related to the price level. However, in the long run, the amount of real
GDP producers collectively supply is independent of the price level.
Changes in LRAS
Macroeconomic equilibrium occurs when the real GDP that is demanded by the
different economic sectors equals the real GDP that producers supply. Short-run
equilibriums occur when AD equals SRAS, and long-run equilibriums occur
when AD equals LRAS. Changes in macroeconomic equilibrium occur when
there are changes in AD, SRAS, or LRAS.
Increases in AD relative to SRAS result in both increased price level and
increased real GDP in the short run, but just increased price level in the long run.
Changes in SRAS relative to AD also lead to changes in real GDP and price
level. Unlike AD changes, which lead to GDP and price level moving in the
same direction, SRAS changes result in GDP and price level moving opposite
from each other.
Say’s Law
He also observed that wages and other input prices were not downwardly
flexible. Workers did not readily accept pay decreases, nor did employers offer
them. As a result, periods of high unemployment could persist as market forces
did not function to bring the economy to full employment. The implication of
did not function to bring the economy to full employment. The implication of
these observations was that government intervention was necessary in the case
of high unemployment.
Embracing Keynes
Keynesian economic policy was made the law of the land through
the passage of the Employment Act of 1946. Signed by President
Truman, the law requires government to pursue maximum
employment, production, and purchasing power. The law also
created the Council of Economic Advisors.
The influence of Keynesian thought grew from the 1930s until the 1970s. The
research of New Zealand–born economist A.W. Phillips helped reinforce
Keynes’s influence on governments during this period. Phillips studied the
relationship between wage inflation and the unemployment rate in Britain and
concluded that periods of wage inflation were associated with periods of low
unemployment. Periods of stagnating wages were associated with periods of
high unemployment. American economists Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow
adapted the Phillips curve for the U.S. economy. Using this model, they
compared general price inflation (instead of wage inflation) to the
unemployment rate. Many policymakers and economists reached the logical
conclusion that Keynesian-style fiscal policies that stimulate AD could be used
conclusion that Keynesian-style fiscal policies that stimulate AD could be used
to sustain low unemployment at the cost of some known amount of inflation.
The idea worked something like this: If policymakers wanted to reduce
unemployment from 7% to 5%, the trade-off would be a known change in the
inflation rate from 1% to 2%.
The experience of the 1970s caused some serious doubts about the legitimacy
of the Phillips curve. Remember stagflation? During the 1970s, both inflation
and unemployment simultaneously increased. These results did not align with
the predictions of the Phillips curve, which implied the two were trade-offs.
Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps viewed this real-world data as a
disproof of the Phillips curve, and more importantly, of the validity of Keynesian
economics. Friedman and Phelps introduced the natural rate hypothesis, which
concluded that the rate of unemployment is independent of inflation in the long
run. Efforts by government to reduce unemployment by creating temporary
inflation would be ineffective. Workers would try to keep their real wages from
falling by demanding higher nominal wages in line with inflation.
The new consensus on the Phillips curve is that there are two types of curves.
There is a short-run Phillips curve that implies a trade-off between inflation and
unemployment, and there is a long-run Phillips curve that exists at an economy’s
natural rate of unemployment. Sampling a few years of inflation and
natural rate of unemployment. Sampling a few years of inflation and
unemployment data may suggest an inverse relationship between the two, but
including all available data reveals no relationship between the two variables.
Economists chalk up changes in the short-run Phillips curve versus the long-
run Phillips curve as being the result of changing inflation expectations.
Phillips’s original observations about the British economy were about a time
period where expected inflation was stable. The breakdown of the adjustable peg
exchange rate regime in 1971 effectively ended any type of gold standard and
introduced a period of uncertainty about inflation. The resulting increases in
inflation expectations help to explain the increased inflation and unemployment
that occurred. Short-run Phillips curves exist during periods of stable inflation
expectations. When inflation expectations change, the short-run Phillips curve
relationship breaks down, and either simultaneous increases or decreases in
inflation and unemployment can occur. Once a new expected inflation rate
embeds itself into the economy, a new short-run Phillips curve emerges.
Alan Greenspan attributes the reduction in inflation expectations as the reason
for the low inflation and unemployment that occurred during his chairmanship at
the Fed. According to Greenspan, productivity gains from globalization subdued
inflation fears for much of his tenure. Taking into account the influence of
inflationary expectations, Keynesian policies will only work as long as inflation
expectations remain stable. If the Keynesian AD policies create higher inflation
expectations, they will be thwarted as attempts to stimulate AD and reduce
unemployment will only create more inflation.
THE FEDERAL RESERVE
SYSTEM
The Bank We Love to Hate
America has a long and storied love-hate relationship with its banking system.
The most vilified institution is the nation’s central bank, the Federal Reserve, or
just the Fed. The Fed is not America’s first central bank or even its second.
Regardless of your feelings toward it or the history behind it, the Fed is at the
center of the American economy and deserves your careful consideration.
Cash on Hand
THE FOMC
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) is the chief architect of the
nation’s monetary policy. The twelve voting members of the committee are
made up of the Fed chairman, the Board of Governors, the Federal Reserve Bank
of New York’s president, and four other district bank presidents who serve on a
rotating basis, although all the district bank presidents are present at the
committee meetings. The FOMC meets eight times a year, or about once every
six weeks, to review economic performance and decide the course of monetary
policy by targeting the fed funds rate. FOMC meetings are closely monitored by
the press and financial markets. Members of the media and investors carefully
analyze the FOMC’s press releases, looking for clues as to what might be the
future direction of policy.
Briefcase Speculation
The goal of monetary policy is to promote price stability, full employment, and
economic growth. The Fed, a monopolist over the money supply, is in a unique
position to influence aggregate demand in the economy. Fed policy affects
excess reserves in the banking system, which directly influences the money
supply, which, in turn, changes interest rates. These changes in interest rates lead
to changes in aggregate demand via consumption, investment, and net exports.
The resulting change in AD affects GDP, inflation, and unemployment.
Reserve Requirement
A bank’s reserve requirement is the percentage of checking account balances
that the bank is not able to lend against. If the Fed were to raise the requirement,
banks would have fewer excess reserves from which they could lend. This would
reduce the money supply and result in higher interest rates, discouraging capital
investment and durable goods consumption. This decrease in investment and
consumption lowers AD and leads to less real GDP, higher unemployment, and a
reduction in inflation. Lowering the reserve requirement would have the exact
opposite effect.
Discount Rate
The discount rate is the interest rate that member banks pay the Fed to borrow
money overnight, usually when they are in financial distress. Raising the
discount rate discourages borrowing, but lowering the discount rate encourages
it. If the Fed wants to reduce inflation, it raises the discount rate. When the Fed
does this, the following chain of events is set into motion: The Fed announces an
increase in the discount rate; banks are discouraged from borrowing; excess
reserves are less likely to be lent; the money supply does not grow; interest rates
rise; consumption, investment, and net exports fall; AD decreases; GDP falls;
rise; consumption, investment, and net exports fall; AD decreases; GDP falls;
unemployment rises; and inflation falls. Lowering the discount rate would have
the exact opposite effect.
The problem with the discount rate is that banks are reluctant to
borrow directly from the Fed. The reluctance stems from the fact that
other forms of borrowing are available at lower rates, so going to the
Fed’s discount window is a public admission that something is wrong
with the borrowing bank. A bank in good financial position will
usually borrow to cover its short-term needs in the interbank lending
market. The principal decision-makers at a bank do not want to
scare away investors or current shareholders by borrowing from the
Fed.
The discount rate is useful as a signal of future interest rate policy. This
signaling function is important, as financial markets do not like surprises.
Money Talks
fiscal policy
The use of the federal budget in order to reduce unemployment or
stabilize prices.
Monetary policy has different effects in the short run and the long run.
Expansionary monetary policies designed to reduce short-term interest rates and
spur full employment and economic growth eventually lead to higher interest
rates as they induce inflation. This means that monetary policy must be carefully
applied. If the Fed introduces a monetary stimulus, they must also plan to
remove the stimulus in order to prevent future inflation. The problem for
policymakers is in timing the policy. Early removal of monetary stimulus might
result in a protracted recession, but maintaining low interest rates for too long
will almost certainly lead to higher inflation.
Too much reliance on monetary policy to reduce inflation can also lead to
problems. Over the business cycle, if government uses expansionary fiscal
policy to offset recessions and then relies on the Fed to contain periods of
inflation, interest rates will ratchet up and long-term economic growth will be
stymied. At some point government must reign in its spending and/or raise taxes
to keep long-term interest rates from rising too high.
SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMICS
The Rise of Voodoo Economics
The concurrent high unemployment and inflation of the 1970s was a painful
period in American economic history. Stagflation came as a shock to many
politicians and economists alike. By the 1970s, Keynesian economic thought
was embedded in the minds of most policymakers. Although Milton Friedman
and Edmund Phelps had publicly refuted the idea that there is stable trade-off
between inflation and unemployment, policymakers were not quite willing to let
go of the belief.
Coining a Phrase
Although it might appear that all things Keynes are associated with
Democrats and supply side with Republicans, this is not the case.
Much of the criticism of supply-side economic theory came in the
1980 Republican primary from Reagan’s chief opponent, George
H.W. Bush, who referred to Reagan’s economic plan as “voodoo
economics.”
SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMICS
Sometimes reality has a way of ruining a great idea. Reagan got his tax cuts and
he got his increases in defense spending, but he also got huge deficits. Increased
he got his increases in defense spending, but he also got huge deficits. Increased
tax revenues failed to materialize. Instead, tax revenues drastically fell, and
government budget deficits increased steadily during Reagan’s administration.
A criticism of supply-side economics is that it effectively redistributes income
to the rich. Because the mantra of supply-side economics is “tax-cuts on income
and capital gains,” it stands to reason that the immediate beneficiary is going to
be those with significant income.
Although supply-side economics is not mentioned much anymore, its
arguments and logic are still part of the Republican and Libertarian political
platforms. Cutting taxes, creating incentives for people to save and invest, and a
general distrust of government involvement in the economy are supply-side
ideas that still resonate with many voters. Democrats tend to promote a more
populist agenda. Tax cuts for the middle class with tax increases on the wealthy,
increased regulation of business, and the use of transfer payments to redistribute
income are all ideas advanced by the Democrats and associated for good or bad
with the Keynesians.
A COMPLETE TOOLBOX
Although supply-side economics as a field of study is derided by most
mainstream economists, it has served to remind people that incentives matter.
Policymakers must consider not only what voters want, but also how their
policies shape the incentives of consumers and producers. Whenever
government creates a new mandate that seeks to regulate economic behavior, it
must also be prepared to deal with the unintended consequences that occur as the
new mandate alters the incentives of individuals and institutions.
Ignoring the supply side of the economy leads to a unilateral approach to
policymaking that ultimately boxes government into two choices: increase
aggregate demand or decrease aggregate demand. By recognizing the role of
aggregate supply, policymakers can promote more policy solutions to achieve
their ultimate economic goals. For example, recognizing that a tax cut on
their ultimate economic goals. For example, recognizing that a tax cut on
personal income has demand-side and supply-side effects allows policymakers
to sell the option to their diverse constituencies.
ECONOMIC GROWTH
Building a Better Society
In Jared Diamond’s study of human history, Germs, Guns, and Steel, he talks
about the question that prompted him to study the course of human events. As an
avid bird watcher, Diamond took many trips to New Guinea, where he
befriended a man named Yali. Yali asked Diamond why it was that the European
descendants had so much while the people of New Guinea had so little.
Diamond’s fascinating account of the forces that shaped human history and the
distribution of wealth is great reading. But for an economist, economic growth is
described more simply—it’s merely an increase in the GDP.
WHY GROW?
Proponents of economic growth focus on the benefits it creates for society. The
advances in food production, healthcare, longevity, and material abundance
would not be possible without economic growth. A century ago, most Americans
were involved in agricultural production and yet subsisted on far fewer calories
than today’s Americans, less than 2% of whom are farmers. The average life
span has increased from 48 to 78 years in the same period because of the
eradication of many diseases and advances in basic sanitation and healthcare.
The quality and quantity of material goods has increased as well, allowing more
Americans the things that only the wealthy could acquire in previous
generations. The average workweek has decreased in the same period of time,
allowing people more leisure. For most, economic growth has been a blessing.
As the economy grows and diversifies, more and more people are able to
escape subsistence farming and pursue other areas of interest. This freedom for
most everyone to pursue their interest and passion did not exist for most of
recorded history. The creative explosion of production that has occurred over the
last 150 years has yielded advances in all fields of human endeavor. Where life
was nasty, brutal, and short for most, it is now relatively humane, peaceful, and
long. If you have ever visited an old cemetery, you might have noticed the
number of graves for young children. What was once a common occurrence is
now a rare tragedy. The diseases that ravaged the population less than a century
ago are for the most part eradicated. All of this is possible because of economic
growth.
As people have become more specialized and more productive, their value to
society has increased as well. Consider the amount of time and resources now
devoted to raising an American child. The average American child has over
$250,000 invested in her human capital. Aid organizations understand that
increasing an individual’s value to society is important for developing a stable,
productive society. Organizations that provide food assistance in the developing
world have discovered that delivering families’ food rations to the daughters in
school increases the value of the daughter to the family, which reduces the
incidence of childhood pregnancy and prostitution.
CONDITIONS FOR ECONOMIC
GROWTH
Planting the Seeds of Production
HUMAN CAPITAL
The most important element in economic growth is human capital. Human
capital consists of the education, skills, and abilities possessed by an individual.
Countries that invest heavily in human capital tend to have more economic
growth than similarly endowed countries that do not. The United States is one of
the world leaders in developing human capital. Compulsory primary and
secondary education, mandatory vaccinations, and abundant nutrition have
contributed to making America the most productive nation on earth. No nation
spends more on educating and developing human capital than the United States.
Individual freedom and the ability to acquire private property are also
essential elements in developing human capital. When individuals are free to
choose their vocation and enjoy the benefits of private property, their
productivity is higher than in places where individual freedom or private
property is not valued. By way of comparison, the average German was far more
productive in capitalist West Germany than in communist East Germany, and the
average South Korean today is far more productive than the average North
average South Korean today is far more productive than the average North
Korean, because economic freedom provides the incentive to produce more in
order to have more.
PHYSICAL CAPITAL
Some capital replaces labor, while other capital enhances it. A robot
that welds automobile frames replaces workers, but a pneumatic
jackhammer both enhances and replaces workers. One worker with
a pneumatic jackhammer can do the work of several workers armed
with sledgehammers. Regardless of whether or not it replaces or
enhances, capital leads to greater productivity.
Because physical capital is the result of investment, interest rates play a key
role in its development. Low, stable interest rates encourage investment. In the
short run, investment creates increased aggregate demand, but in the long run it
expands the economy’s stock of capital. High interest rates or unstable interest
rates are injurious to investment decisions and result in the formation of less
capital.
Once capital is deployed, it must be maintained. Capital needs adequate
infrastructure to realize its potential. Roads, waterways, rail systems, and reliable
utility systems make capital easier to access and greatly improve the chances that
it will be used effectively. One of the failures of the Soviet Union was an
ineffective use of capital. The Soviets built factories that dwarfed their Western
counterparts. But because of inadequate infrastructure, they were often difficult
to get to. This made distributing their output more difficult. The developing
world lacks steady sources of power and the transportation networks that are
world lacks steady sources of power and the transportation networks that are
necessary for efficient use of factories. Europe, Japan, and the United States, by
comparison, have ample infrastructure to facilitate the continuous use and
transport of capital’s output.
Another condition for growth is the rule of law. Government officials should
obey the law and should also apply the law uniformly and fairly. Corruption and
cronyism discourage domestic and foreign investment by effectively raising the
cost of capital. Firms, individuals, and foreign investors must know that their
property is protected by law. One reason that capital investment is lacking in the
property is protected by law. One reason that capital investment is lacking in the
developing world stems from the fact that corrupt governments are far more
likely to seize private property in the name of national interests. Venezuela’s
seizure of foreign-owned oil fields in 2007 most likely deters future foreign
investment. Unlike Venezuela, former British colonies such as the United States,
Canada, Australia, New Zealand, and Hong Kong inherited the English common
law with its emphasis on private property, which makes them safe and attractive
to foreign investors. Foreign owners of capital have basically the same rights as
domestic investors. As a result, more capital accumulates in these countries than
in most others.
HOW ECONOMIC POLICY
AFFECTS GROWTH
The Government Gets Involved
Fiscal policy that does not lead to a balanced budget impacts long-term
interest rates and capital investment. Budget deficits in the absence of capital
inflow or increased domestic saving lead to higher long-term interest rates and
hinder investment in capital. If capital inflows or domestic savings are enough to
offset government borrowing, the interest rate effect of a deficit is negated.
Regardless of immediate interest rate effects, budget deficits, if large enough,
create uncertainty and may effectively discourage investment. The presence of
budget surpluses reduces long-term interest rates and encourages capital
investment.
TAX POLICY
Changes in tax policy affect businesses and are likely to also impact the rate of
economic growth. Increasing the tax burden on firms reduces their ability and
incentive to invest in capital. Increasing the capital gains tax on financial
investors reduces the flow of savings firms use to make real investments in
physical capital. Businesses faced with too high a tax burden may choose to
physical capital. Businesses faced with too high a tax burden may choose to
produce elsewhere. It is important to understand that capital is free to flow.
Placing taxes on business, although politically popular, is a recipe for reduced
growth.
Money Talks
flat tax
A flat tax is one that taxes all households at the same rate
regardless of the level of income. Given a flat tax of 15%, a
household earning $40,000 would pay $6,000 in taxes, while a
household earning $100,000 would pay $15,000 in taxes. The
benefit of a flat tax is its simplicity. The downside is that for many
households a flat tax would represent an increase in their tax
burden. Even though many are in the 20% to 30% marginal tax
brackets, their average tax rates are much lower because of
exemptions, deductions, and the fact that the marginal tax rate is
only on the incremental income and not the total income.
Taxes on personal income affect work incentives and can thus also influence
the rate of growth. In the United States, the more productive you are, the more
income you earn. The more income you earn, the higher your marginal tax rate.
This is what economists call a progressive tax system. If tax rates are increased
on upper incomes, they increase the tax burden of the most productive members
of society. Although American tax rates are much lower than in Europe, given a
high enough tax rate, the productive worker will either reduce productivity or
move to where productivity is not taxed as highly. So far, America has been the
beneficiary of high tax rates in Europe. Europe has suffered a brain drain as its
best and brightest, thus most highly taxed, move toward countries with lower tax
rates.
rates.
According to the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD), the brain drain is serious enough that European countries are
establishing government programs to encourage expatriates to migrate back.
Maybe they should try a tax cut. Europe’s loss is America’s gain as human
capital has increased steadily in the United States.
Before 2007, had you ever heard of subprime mortgages, CDOs, or credit default
swaps? In 2007, possibly the worst financial crisis in U.S. history began.
Through 2008 and 2009 the financial crisis became a global recession. The scale
of the financial and economic crisis is measured in tens of trillions of dollars. As
this is being written, the economy has slowly begun to recover, but no one is
sure if the recovery will be sustained.
On September 11, 2001, terrorists hijacked civilian aircraft and flew them into
the World Trade Center and Pentagon while another plane crashed in a
Pennsylvania field. The impact of the terrorist attacks created fear in a by-then
Pennsylvania field. The impact of the terrorist attacks created fear in a by-then
retreating stock market. This fear helped to send the United States into a shallow
recession in 2001 and 2002. The Federal Reserve responded by immediately
lowering the fed funds rate and injecting large amounts of money into the
banking system.
These injections, along with the Bush tax cuts, two wars, and a deregulated
financial sector, led to a pool of money that created a boom in residential and
commercial real estate investment. Much of the spending that occurred during
the years 2002 through 2005 was fueled by home-equity borrowing at
historically low rates of interest. Deregulated banks added fuel to the fire by
lending money to pretty much anybody who showed up for a loan. Consumers
went on a credit spending binge as the booming housing market created a wealth
effect. Interest rates that should have otherwise crept up were unusually low as
China, Japan, and the oil-producing states continued to save large sums in the
United States. Furthermore, faith in the Fed’s inflation-fighting capability kept
inflation fears at bay. The private, public, financial, and foreign sectors all had a
hand in creating the conditions for disaster.
Asset price bubbles occur when easy credit flows toward a certain
class of asset, like stocks, houses, or commodities. Precious metals
are currently trading at all-time highs and may be the next bubble to
burst. There is a debate among economists as to whether central
bankers should raise interest rates to contain asset bubbles or allow
them to run their natural course.
In 2006, the overheated housing market began to slow down. Savvy investors
soon began pulling away from housing and putting money into commodities like
oil and precious metals. In 2007, the housing market went into complete free-fall
oil and precious metals. In 2007, the housing market went into complete free-fall
while oil prices shot up. This combination of events brought the spending party
to a halt as consumers saw their wealth decreasing at the same time highly
visible energy and food prices increased. Real estate investors, and eventually
homeowners, began to walk away from properties that were now worth less than
the balance on the mortgage or mortgages. Murmurs of stagflation were heard in
the media. They were wrong.
SECURITIZATION
One of the culprits in the run-up to the meltdown was a financial innovation
called securitization. Traditionally, banks made loans to customers, carried the
loan on their balance sheet, and earned profit from the interest and fees. This
gave banks a strong incentive to carefully assess a borrower’s risk of default.
With financial innovation and shareholders hungry for ever-greater returns, more
and more pressure was put on banks to increase profits by expanding their
lending activities. Banks delivered these profits by becoming loan originators
that charged fees to make the original loans, which they then sold to investment
banks. The investment banks packaged the loans into bundles and sold them as a
type of bond called a collateralized debt obligation (CDO).
Principal-Agent Problems
Many of the institutional investors, banks, and pension funds have conservative
investment policies that limit the types of investments they can make. These
investors rely on bond rating agencies like Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s to
determine the overall level of risk of an investment. Many can only invest in
AAA or AA+ rated bonds. These are the highest ratings and typically indicate
that the investment is extremely safe. Many of the CDOs that investors bought
had these high ratings.
To sweeten the deal, some investment banks that marketed CDOs to investors
sold a type of insurance called a credit default swap (CDS) that would pay the
investor if the CDO went into default. For the investor, this was enough to make
CDOs the perfect investment. For the investment banks, they were making
money hand over fist selling the CDOs and then again charging for the CDSs.
Profits went through the roof, as did the incentive for managers and chief
executive officers to market these products to their customers. There was only
one small problem. The CDOs were much less secure than people believed and
the CDSs were not adequately funded. If the CDOs were to default en masse, the
investment banks that sold the CDSs would be liable for hundreds of billions of
dollars. That is exactly what happened.
Bear Stearns was the first Wall Street victim of the mortgage crisis. When the
housing bubble burst, the value of the CDOs came into question. Bear had
heavily marketed the CDOs and also invested in them. In the face of heavy
financial losses, Bear Stearns’s balance sheet became toxic. If they sold their
assets, the value of the firm would plummet. Soon other investment banks
refused to lend to Bear, and the company faced insolvency. The New York
Federal Reserve president, Tim Geithner, orchestrated a bailout of Bear Stearns
by lending money to banking giant JPMorgan Chase with the understanding that
JPMorgan would use the funds to purchase Bear Stearns at a deep discount. It
JPMorgan would use the funds to purchase Bear Stearns at a deep discount. It
was hoped that this would prevent a widespread panic, but exactly the opposite
happened. Soon Lehman Brothers was on the ropes, but this time no one came to
the rescue of the firm. The panic had spread.
Money Talks
moral hazard
A moral hazard is created when insurance or expectation of a
government bailout encourages risk-taking behavior. Economists
and policymakers must address moral hazard when making
decisions. Failure to do so encourages more risk taking. Ignoring
moral hazard is a moral hazard.
The collapse of the mortgage security market meant that trillions of dollars’
worth of financial assets had become worthless. This economic recession was a
deadly combination of a financial crisis compounded with a wider economic
crisis. In the face of economic recession, the Keynesian prescription is for
expansionary monetary and fiscal policy to stimulate the economy. The problem
was that the tools of policy that are normally effective were both severely
hampered.
THE FED
The usual prescription for a recession is for the Fed to buy Treasury bills from
primary security dealers and then allow the money creation process to work its
magic. When banks are unwilling to lend, this prescription does not work.
Instead of money being created, the financial system was destroying money.
Because many of the failures in the financial system had occurred outside of
traditional banking, the Fed was hard-pressed to get money where it needed to
be.
The Fed is set up by law to work with the banks. The tools it has at its
disposal are aimed at banks, but this financial crisis was different. The shadow
banking system that had been created by deregulation was out of the scope of the
Fed. In order for the Fed to get things working again, the shadow system had to
be transformed into the more regulated traditional banks. That is what they did.
Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley, the last of the great investment banks,
changed their status under SEC regulations and submitted to the Fed.
changed their status under SEC regulations and submitted to the Fed.
Quantitative Easing
A visit to the Federal Reserve Board of Governors website throughout the
financial crisis indicated that something interesting was happening. Almost on a
monthly basis, the Fed was inventing new tools of monetary policy. The first
was the Term Auction Facility (TAF), which allowed banks to bid on loans from
the Fed without the perceived downside risk to borrowing from the discount
window. Soon the Fed was creating other lending facilities to inject money into
the system. The Fed started buying up mortgage-backed securities and agency
debt. Ultimately what the Fed was doing was creating markets for assets in
exchange for cash, a process called quantitative easing.
In the end, most of the facilities created during 2008 to halt the financial
collapse expired in February of 2010. The Federal Reserve did not forgo
traditional policy measures during the recession. The FOMC reduced its target
for the fed funds rate to 0%. This is as expansionary as the Fed can get with open
market operations.
Theories affect the way economists and policymakers tell the story
of what is actually happening. These narratives of reality have the
power to affect reality if enough people believe them. The story of
expected inflation creating inflation is a powerful story, and if
expected inflation creating inflation is a powerful story, and if
policymakers do not address it, the story could become the reality.
When an economy falls into recession, businesses cut production and quickly
lay off workers. During economic recovery, the logical conclusion is that this
process should run in reverse, but that is not necessarily the case. As production
begins to pick back up, firms often discover that their remaining workforce has
become much more productive. As a result, firms are able to steadily increase
output without hiring more workers. As output continues to increase, firms
increase the number of hours their labor force works before hiring more. Finally,
after accounting for increased productivity and increased working hours, if
demand is present then firms begin to hire. Unfortunately for the unemployed,
this process can take a very long time. Jobless recovery is the bane of the
politician’s existence. The GDP may increase, but unemployment can still
remain high for a while. The unemployed vote and do not really care for the neat
explanation just given.
The Federal Reserve is walking a precarious tightrope when it comes to
inflation. It does not help that so many pundits are warning of coming inflation.
Expecting inflation is often enough to spark inflation. The Fed has introduced
hundreds of billions in reserves to the financial system in order to unfreeze the
flow of credit. The danger to the economy comes in two forms. First, if the Fed
begins contracting the money supply too soon, the economy may fall back into
deeper recession. Second, if the Fed waits too long to contract the money supply,
then inflation may take hold, and that would require the Fed to respond by
sending the economy back into recession.
THE ENVIRONMENT AND THE
ECONOMY
Tree-Huggers Unite!
Most Americans believe that protecting the environment is a valuable goal for
our society. The way that government and environmentalists have gone about
achieving this goal has for the most part ignored the realities of economics. The
Endangered Species Act, the Clean Air Act, and the Clean Water Act all have
laudable goals. Critics of the legislation are not pro-extinction, pro-smog, and
pro–dirty water. For most, the criticism is in how these goals are achieved and
not the goals themselves. Economists offer a unique perspective on the
environment, and inclusion of economic principles can be used to bring about
the goal of environmental protection more efficiently and with greater utility.
IS GROWTH SUSTAINABLE?
One of the costs of an ever-growing economy is the strain that it places on the
environment. As the population expands more and more, resources are required
to sustain the population. This growth need not necessarily lead to environmental
collapse. Instead, markets can be used to alter the incentives of individuals and
firms as they face trade-offs in their use of resources.
Demand for resources tends to increase the price of those resources. As the
price increases, individuals and firms that use these resources face an incentive
to use less in the case of nonrenewables. In the case of renewable resources,
entrepreneurs gain an incentive to increase the production of the renewable
resource. These incentives are powerful and efficient.
Renewable Resources
Consider the case of lumber, a renewable resource. Increased demand for
lumber has led to an increase in the price of lumber. This price increase leads
tree farmers to expand their output to meet the demand. The net effect of
increased demand for lumber is increased demand for forests. Increased demand
for forests makes the land more desirable and leads to more land being placed
into forest production. Some would argue that if you cut down the trees,
eventually there will be none left. However, this statement ignores economic
incentives. Would there be more corn or less corn if people stopped eating it? If
you answered less, you would be correct. If people stop eating corn, farmers
have no incentive to grow corn. Likewise, if people eat more corn, then farmers
grow more corn. The same is true with trees. Trees take longer to grow, though,
and as a result they’re priced much higher than corn.
Nonrenewable Resources
In the case of nonrenewables like coal, oil, and natural gas, markets provide
incentives to both producers and consumers. As demand increases for these
factors of production, the price increases. This leads to higher prices and higher
costs of production for firms that use the resources. These higher costs provide
firms with an incentive to become more efficient in the use of the resource. For
example, if a firm uses natural gas in production and gas prices rise, the firm has
a strong incentive to use its natural gas in the most efficient way possible. Firms
that are wasteful and inefficient will find it difficult to compete against firms that
use resources more efficiently. They’ll eventually go out of business.
Economic Efficiency
Per-Unit Taxes
A per-unit tax on the production of a good or service could be used to reduce
the amount of pollution that the firm produces. The tax on the producer increases
the cost of production, which reduces their willingness and ability to produce
their product. The market outcome is for the price of the good or service to
increase and for the quantity to decrease. The result is less production, and
therefore, less pollution. The problem with a per-unit tax is that it would most
likely be levied on all producers in an industry, which means that cleaner, more
efficient producers are taxed at the same rate as the heavier polluters. The tax
reduces pollution in the industry, but does not increase the incentive for
individual producers to clean up their act. Also, if demand for the good or
service increases, then the quantity of pollution would still increase. The
ultimate goal is to reduce pollution and not just punish producers.
Pollution Permits
Another option is to create a market for pollution permits. Under a permit
scheme, the government establishes a cap on how much of a certain pollutant
will be allowed in the atmosphere that year. For example, assume that last year 7
million tons of nitrogen oxide gas was released into the atmosphere and
government wants to reduce it to 6 million tons. Government would allocate to
industry the number of permits required to achieve this goal. If each permit
allowed one ton of emissions, then government would allocate 6 million permits
to firms. The firms would be required to surrender one permit for each ton of
pollutant they produced. Under the system, firms and even individuals could buy
and sell the permits in an exchange. Firms that are relatively clean could sell
their unused permits to firms that are heavier polluters. Individuals could also
buy permits and effectively keep a certain amount of pollution out of the
atmosphere. This scheme encourages firms to become more efficient and reduce
atmosphere. This scheme encourages firms to become more efficient and reduce
pollution simultaneously. Unlike pollution taxes, this solution rewards firms for
reducing pollution instead of punishing all firms equally.
Climate Exchanges
U.S. currency.
Photo Credits: © Joo Lee/123RF; Ashwin Kharidehal Abhirama/123RF; Robert Brown/123RF
World currency.
Photo Credits: © Joo Lee/123RF; Ashwin Kharidehal Abhirama/123RF; Robert Brown/123RF
President Woodrow Wilson who signed the Federal Reserve Act into law
in 1913, creating the Federal Reserve System.
Photo Credits: © Olga Popova/123RF; Norman Kin Hang Chan/123RF
Newspaper headlines from the Great Recession.
Photo Credits: © Olga Popova/123RF; Norman Kin Hang Chan/123RF
Published by
Adams Media, a division of F+W Media, Inc.
57 Littlefield Street, Avon, MA 02322. U.S.A.
www.adamsmedia.com
2015025897
2015025897