Globalization and The Urban Property Boo
Globalization and The Urban Property Boo
Cebu, Philippines
Edsel E. Sajor
ABSTRACT
INTRODUCTION
Development and Change 34(4): 713–741 (2003). # Institute of Social Studies 2003. Published
by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main St.,
Malden, MA 02148, USA
714 Edsel E. Sajor
1991). At the same time, new growth centres emerged in the urban areas of
countries of the Asia-Pacific Rim, a region considered to be the most
dynamic property investment area of international capital (Berry and
McGreal, 1999; Olds, 1995; Thrift, 1985).
The reach of the property boom was wide. For Southeast Asia, studies
have shown how the fast pace of internationally-linked property develop-
ments since the late 1980s have radically altered existing spatial patterns to
serve metropolitan expansion and have caused massive land conversions from
rural to urban use (Douglas, 1989; Firman, 1997; Kelly, 1998, 1999). They also
created new physical structures and complexes requiring large tracts of land
that cater primarily to middle and upper classes (Dick and Rimmer, 1998).
Most of the studies on Southeast Asian property development and urbanizing
trends have been confined to mega-cities or the primary metropolitan areas of
the country, such as Bangkok (Parnwell and Wongsuphasawat, 1997; Setchell,
1995; Yap, 1989, 1992), Jakarta (Douglas, 1989; Firman, 1997; Goldblum and
Wong, 2000; Jellineck, 2000) and Manila (Magno-Ballesteros, 2000). To date,
with the exception of Firman (1996, 2000) there is a dearth of material on
secondary or tertiary cities or intermediate urban areas of developing countries
in Southeast Asia.
There is an equally significant silence in the literature on the equity
implications of these bursts of real estate development in Southeast Asian
cities, particularly on how aggressive property development and market-
driven shifts in land prices have affected access to land to meet the basic
housing needs of low-income groups and the urban poor. A few recent
studies have touched on this theme, but again they are limited to the
mega-urban centres of Bangkok (Setchell, 1995; Yap, 1992) and Jakarta
(Goldblum and Wong, 2000).
Where the theme of equity in land development in developing countries
has emerged is not in recent literature on property development and global-
ization, but in the conventional urban housing literature on Third World
cities. In the latter, rising urban land values have always been an important
concern since access to land and tenurial security — largely determined by,
but not limited to, conditions of the market — are important not only to
housing but to urban subsistence (Berner, 2000: 555–6; Evers, 1984; Moser,
1998). But in the literature on urban housing in developing countries, rising
land prices in cities have conventionally been correlated with the impact of
the combined factors of dramatic population growth, and expansion and
concentration of the most productive activities in the cities, notably by
multinational manufacturing firms. It is commonly argued that constantly
high rural to urban migration and urban growth have shaped a high con-
sumption for urban land for housing (see Gilbert and Gulgler, 1992; Hardoy
and Satterthwaite, 1989; Kasarda and Parnell, 1993). Speculative land
buying and real estate development in the face of rapid urban growth have
also been touched upon, less prominently, as factors jacking up land prices
and exacerbating the problem of urban poor shelter. These phenomena,
716 Edsel E. Sajor
question arises: can Third World states and their city governments handle
the equity challenge as they compete for global capital (often in the form
of partnerships with, or through foreign portfolio investments in,
domestic property companies) and allow rapid property development?
Third World urban areas still face the problem of meeting the high demand
for land for housing, as a result of rising urban populations: at the same
time their urban spaces are being transformed into ‘open fields’ of inter-
national real estate investment and into global property commodities
triggering dramatic shifts in local land values and distribution. These
processes might translate as the ‘social costs of breaking into the world
market’ (Schmidt, 1998: 130).
Devising equitable and efficient land development policies has long been
a major challenge facing developing country cities. Various forms of effect-
ive state interventions — physical, legislative, and administrative — are
needed to increase efficiency and to distribute benefits in land development
equitably across income groups. Market mechanisms alone are unlikely to
achieve this, yet many of these cities’ governments have been plagued by
major institutional constraints and lack of managerial expertise, limiting
their potential to effectively intervene for socially desirable urban develop-
ment goals. Several authors have drawn attention to these institutional and
managerial capacity deficiencies in Southeast Asian cities.1
Yet, however significant these constraints may be, they do not exist in a
vacuum; they cannot be isolated from the characteristics and dynamics of
particular states and the dominant politics at work in the cities and coun-
tries of the region. In this context, it is important to identify the most
relevant characteristics of the state and to assess how these influence cap-
acity and performance in the land management of a city. What are the social
forces within and outside the state that prolong institutional and managerial
capacity deficiencies? Who profits from such a situation, and who displays
the most resistance to finding effective and long-term solutions?
Several scholars have broadly hinted at these issues, arguing that it
becomes harder to solve these management problems because there are
powerful vested interest groups working against solutions (Douglas, 1992;
Drakakis-Smith, 1995: 667; Hardoy et al., 2001: 311–12). It is claimed, for
instance, that in Thailand, Indonesia and the Philippines, national-level
officials in charge of major land development decisions and policies are
influenced and manipulated by powerful real estate interest groups and
1. For example, Douglas (1989) and Yeung (1989) discuss the administrative fragmentation
and lack of resources at the local level for implementing programmes in Southeast Asian
cities. Krongkaew (1996: 322) argues that Bangkok had neither effective control of land
use nor an official city plan in operation until 1992. Brennan (1993: 77) cites Metro
Manila as having virtually no effective measures to influence or control land
development. Goldblum and Wong (2000) note that metropolitan Jakarta is plagued by
weak government regulations and planning.
718 Edsel E. Sajor
often pursue a goal of rapid economic growth regardless of its adverse social
and environmental impacts (David, 2001; Firman, 1997; Setchell, 1995). At
the local city level, similar claims have been made for Bangkok, Metro
Manila and Jakarta.2 In most studies, however, discussion of these issues
is peripheral, and does not bring in the state and related politics as central to
urban management and land development.
2. For instance, Ruland and Ladavalya (1996: 62) note that in Bangkok, the
professionalization of the administration and the continuity of programmes and policies
are eroded by political in-fighting dominated by powerful politicians in the country.
Likewise, in the urban management of Metro Manila, deterioration has been said to
mirror dominant political and economic interests, depending much on old-style
patronage politics which prejudices the urban poor (Naerssen et al., 1996). In
metropolitan Jakarta, land-use decisions have largely taken place outside the planning
and legal process, with powerful private interests always managing to circumvent land use
regulations (Douglas, 1989: 233).
3. The exchange value of the Philippine peso fell from US$1 ¼ P36 in 1997, to US$1 ¼ P48
the following year. Local interest rates soared from between 13 and 14 per cent before the
financial crisis, to 32 per cent in 1998.
Globalization and the Property Boom, Metro Cebu 719
1988 5 1995 35
1989 9 1996 34
1990 9 1997 48
1991 13 1998 14
1992 23 1999 18
1993 16 2000 2
1994 25
N ¼ 251 projects
The land property projects in Metro Cebu in this period involved the
development or conversion of a total of 1030 hectares of mostly unused
lands. The great majority of the land was taken for residential projects,
some of which accounted for more than 100 ha each. According to the
government housing agency’s list of projects (HLRUB, 2000), the break-
down of land area per project class is as follows: a) residential subdivision:
864.6 ha (84 per cent of the total); b) industrial park: 63.0 ha (6 per cent);
commercial park: 37.3 ha (4 per cent); memorial park: 34.7 ha (3 per cent);
and condominiums: 30.6 ha (3 per cent).
This real estate boom in Metro Cebu occurred in an environment of
unprecedented mobility of capital across national borders and regions of
the globe as the economies of most countries were liberalized and invest-
ments deregulated. In the Philippines, the downfall of the authoritarian
Marcos regime in 1986 restored democracy and created the political environ-
ment necessary for restoring foreign business confidence in the country.
In the years that immediately followed, Metro Cebu became the country’s
major recipient of new foreign private investments in manufacturing and
foreign government assistance for infrastructure development. The value of
investments approved by or registered with the Board of Investment aver-
aged an annual growth of 156 per cent from 1987 to 1992. The number of
(mostly) transnational firms operating in the Mactan Export Processing
Zone (MEPZ) also increased, from ten in 1987 to thirty-four in 1990, and
from thirty-nine in 1991 and 120 in 1998 (PPDO, 2000). To accommodate
new firms, MEPZ II was set up in 1997, a 40 ha expansion of the original
119 ha land area of MEPZ (subsequently renamed MEPZ I). Since Metro
Cebu’s exports largely comprised goods produced by foreign-owned firms in
the export processing zone, exports also grew rapidly, increasing by 76 per
cent from 1987 to 1990 (from US$ 344.3 m to US$ 607.1 m), and by 217 per
cent from 1991 to 1998 (US$ 661.7 m to US$ 2,100.1 m) (ibid.).
Rapid expansion of the export manufacturing sector had an immediate
positive effect on real estate development in the area. It buoyed confidence
720 Edsel E. Sajor
This market potential was the result of substantial surplus which had
accumulated in the local economy, thanks to robust commercial and manu-
facturing activities, and which had the potential to be switched into real
estate investment. Two industry sectors formed the basis of this local
accumulation. The first was merchandise trading, founded on Cebu City’s
long mercantile history dating back to the nineteenth century. This trading
business has thrived on the city’s port-centred commerce; it was dominated
by the local Filipino-Chinese elite who ‘search the Visayas and Mindanao
for raw materials to be processed in Cebu or Manila, or who warehouse
Manila-made goods for southern distribution’ (Churchill, 1993: 6–7; see
also Mojares, 1997: 42). These families have accumulated large surpluses
through their long-term domination of copra trading, coconut oil process-
ing, wholesale/retail general merchandising, and in more recent decades,
construction and hardware.
The second local industry sector that became a major source of accumu-
lation was furniture manufacturing,4 which has sustained high growth
rates since the 1970s. According to official government statistics, Cebu’s
furniture industry represented an average export value of US$ 196 m
annually from 1988 to 1997 (PPDO, 2000), ranking second only to the
electronics industry sector dominated by transnational firms in the Mactan
Export Processing Zone.
4. As a major industry, Cebu’s furniture manufacturing dates back to the early 1960s, when
the national government provided capital support for this fledgling industry. Soon the
Cebuano producers took advantage of Cebu City’s traditional access to world markets
and produced for export. By 1980, rattan furniture ranked third in Cebu’s major export
products, behind the traditionally dominant exports of copper concentrates and coconut
oil (Bernaldez, 1997: 70–71).
722 Edsel E. Sajor
Five of these firms are highly ranked among the top 1000 corporations of
the Philippines (PBPPI, 1998) — the MRO Development Corporation is not
in this list. Three of them, Ayala Land Incorporation, Fil-Invest, and
Aboitiz Group, are also involved with banking and finance.5 Ownership
and control of banking and financing institutions have allowed them to use
domestic and international finance capital — through various loan instru-
ments, syndication, and networks — to generate funds for mega property
projects.
These big property corporations also have significant ties with inter-
national sources of capital and technology. Ayala Land Incorporation has
partnerships with Hongkong Land (PPI) BV, Rodamco Asia Management
Limited (a Dutch Investment company), Gammon Contruction Limited of
the Jardine Group (the largest construction company in Hong Kong) and
the Maison Individuelles SA (the largest housing supplier in France and
Europe) (see Ayala Land Incorporation, 1993). Similarly, Santa-Lucia
Realty & Development Corporation has various joint ventures with foreign
investors, although the company is entirely Filipino-owned;6 while the
Aboitiz Group of Companies is said to have substantial partnerships with
Japanese corporations.7 Another major source of foreign financing of all
five companies is through the Philippine stock exchange, where they are
listed and where foreign investors buy shares of their stocks as portfolio
investments.
Although the residential property development that occurred in Metro
Cebu between 1988 and 2000 included land for both the socialized housing
sector and the open-market sector,8 the socialized housing sector was
severely marginalized. Official data suggest that of the total of 864.6 ha
developed for residential purposes, 694.34 ha (or 80 per cent) was allocated
to the open-market — ranging from economic (low-cost housing) to presti-
5. Ayala Land Incorporation is controlled by the family of Zobel de Ayalas who is also the
principal owner of the Bank of Philippine Islands, the second largest bank in the
Philippines. The Ayala group of companies also has major interests in the insurance
business. Fil-Invest controls the East West Bank, while the Aboitiz Group of
Companies is the dominant shareholder of Union Bank.
6. Interview by the author with a top-ranking official of the company.
7. Interview by the author with an informant close to the inner circle of the Aboitiz family.
8. In the Philippines, regulations and standards for the socialized housing sector had been
established in 1982 by the legislature through Batasan Pambansa (BP) 220. This legislative
provision defined the concept of socialized housing as a project intended for the
underprivileged and homeless. The price of a housing package should be within the
lowest interest rate under the unified home lending programme and the value of the
combined house and lot package should not exceed P150,000 (roughly US$ 2,900 at
current exchange rates). Packages in which the lot value combined with the house cost
exceeds P150,000 are categorized as falling in the open-market sector. This sector’s house
and lot prices are not administratively controlled, but are determined by market
mechanisms.
Globalization and the Property Boom, Metro Cebu 723
gious or high-end projects — while only 170.25 ha (20 per cent) went into
socialized housing projects (HLURB, 2000).
Such a pattern of land use is hardly surprising, when the market is given a
free hand as the allocator of land for housing. The main players in Metro
Cebu’s property development boom were big private corporations and
medium and small construction companies, whose driving motivation is to
optimize returns to their investments and whose calculations are based on
signals of effective demand in the housing market. The latter, in turn, is a
function of the purchasing power of different groups in society, and not of
the basic need for shelter of low-income groups and the poor.9
A close examination of the official listings of the residential subdivision
projects from 1988 to 2000 of the Housing Land Use and Regulatory Board
(HLURUB), Region VII, covering the open-market housing sector, reveals
a highly regressive pattern. The major property developers operating in
Metro Cebu focused on developing prestigious and high-end housing pro-
jects. Almost half (49 per cent) of the total area used for open-market
residential projects in Metro Cebu fell under the category ‘prestigious
housing project’ (see Table 2). The typical cost of lots in this project class
is US$ 60,000 or higher (at 2001 rates). The next class of upper-end housing
projects, with lots typically costing US$ 20,000 to US$ 59,000 (at 2001 prices)
accounted for 18 per cent of the total land area. Together, these two
categories therefore ate up 67 per cent of the land developed in the resi-
dential, open-market sector during the property boom in Metro Cebu.10
These two categories represent low-density housing, usually no more than
twenty lots per hectare, due to the spacious lot sizes. The dominance of
these categories effectively limits the area available for lower class housing,
where far smaller standard lot size enables more families to construct
dwellings per hectare of land.
Natural land scarcity in Metro Cebu further aggravates the problem.
Metro Cebu is one of the least land-endowed cities in the archipelago. It
is situated in narrow Cebu island, which is approximately 215 km long and
only 35 km wide at the widest point. Cebu is mountainous, with more than
half of its territory covered by slopes steeper than 18 per cent. A major
9. Developers in Metro Cebu have been averse to investing in socialized housing projects
unless the government raised the ceiling for the selling price of social housing units. A
leading architect-developer in Cebu City was unabashed in saying: ‘There’s not much
money in low-cost housing. . .leaving real estate developers little choice but to opt for high-
end housing’ (Sun Star Daily, 5 March 1997; see also Sun Star Daily, 7 August 1997).
10. In constructing the four project class types in Table 2, I correlated mean lot sizes of each
subdivision with other important criteria including: residential subdivision amenities (e.g.
covered or uncovered tennis or basketball courts, swimming pools for communal use,
etc.); income-level of typical buyers; typical price per square metre in each subdivision;
and social symbolic elements that contribute to a hierarchical ranking of residential
subdivisions in Metro Cebu (for example, the degree of a subdivision’s attraction as the
traditional residence of recognized elite families of Cebu).
724 Edsel E. Sajor
property boom, between 1988 and 1992. While prices of residential lots
declined in the National Capital Region at this time, dropping an average
of 0.4 per cent annually, they rose in Metro Cebu at an annual average of
52.1 per cent (Econtec Inc., 1993: 3–4).
This dramatic price rise in Metro Cebu was closely linked to widespread
speculative buying of residential lots. Although the conventional literature
treats speculation as a positive bridging force, a brokerage operation
between the owner of the land and the builder, it may have, as in the case
of Metro Cebu, two closely related negative effects: (1) real estate specula-
tion activities actually alter the nature of the land commodity primarily by
restricting the supply of available land; and (2) speculation forces land
prices (far) above what they would have been without speculative activity.11
When a number of these high-end projects by Manila-based developers
were offered for sale in the early 1990s, there was clearly a strong market
demand in Metro Cebu. Lots in prestigious housing and in upper-end
subdivisions sold briskly. In the Royal Cebu Estates — Santa Lucia’s
Class A residential subdivision project in Metro Cebu, launched in
September 1990 — 70 per cent of lots were sold within 12 months.12 Sales
of high-end properties flourished from 1990 to 1996. Large, Manila-based
property companies launched new projects in quick succession and tried to
outdo each other in aggressive advertising and sophisticated marketing
of these prime properties. But it also became clear that the market for
high-end and upper-end residential developed lots was largely comprised
of speculative buyers: several real estate agent informants confirmed in
interviews that it was not uncommon for them to have clients who bought
five to ten high-end residential lots between 1990 and 1995, during the
dizzying appreciation of property values in Metro Cebu.
This pattern of speculative buying was also noted by a leading property
agent in Cebu. While lower cost lots, averaging 120 m2 to 200 m2, attracted
90 per cent end-user buyers, high-end subdivisions drew largely speculative
buyers (Sun Star Daily, 1 November 1996). The most concrete evidence of
the extent of this speculative buying is the unmistakable landscape of Metro
Cebu today, in which empty lots far outnumber those with built structures
in almost all the high-end and upper-end residential subdivisions that were
sold during the property boom. In the case of Royal Cebu Estate, mentioned
11. These ‘higher-than-necessary prices come in part from the expensive, usually highly
leveraged, financial arrangements that speculators get into, as well as from the
speculative pricing process itself. Both costs are passed on in the form of higher prices
for actual land users’ (Feagin, 1998: 152). Moreover, prices are driven up by competitive
bidding by investors who assume that future prices will be higher than present prices
(Haila, 1991: 352; Logan and Molotch, 1987: 26–7).
12. Interview with a real estate agent of the marketing agency of Santa Lucia Realty &
Development Corporation (25 January 2000).
726 Edsel E. Sajor
above, only twenty-five lots have visible housing structures out of the
1,000 lots that sold out so quickly, ten years ago.
The Manila-based property developers had been correct in identifying the
potential demand for high-end residential subdivision lots on the part of the
rich Chinese-Filipino merchants and the furniture exporter manufacturers
of Cebu. Members of these two groups turned out to be the major specu-
lative buyers. In my survey of thirty licensed real estate agents in Metro
Cebu in 2001,13 individuals belonging to these two groups clearly stood out
as the main clients in their sales transactions during the boom years for
high-end and upper-end subdivisions.
Distinct circumstances in Metro Cebu influence the propensity of individ-
uals in these two groups to be speculative buyers of urban land. A number
of rich Filipino-Chinese families prominent in merchandise trading have
traditionally engaged in long-term land speculation, utilizing surplus accu-
mulated in their commercial activities. Some of those who sold large tracts
of land at an enormous gain to developers in the 1990s had accumulated
these lands through speculative buying in the 1950s and the 1960s. Some of
these same families were attracted to the idea of making another round of
profit by becoming speculative buyers of developed residential lands in the
1990s. The furniture exporters of Cebu had special reasons for engaging in
speculative lot buying during the property boom. Beside the expectation of
high future returns, two specific reasons for speculative land buying were
mentioned during interviews: as a hedge against the uncertainties of a
volatile furniture export market;14 and as highly dependable bank collateral
for acquiring quick loans to finance manufacturing and exporting oper-
ations during unexpected financial gaps in their operations. In the case of
the Metro Cebu property boom of the 1990s, these two groups of investors
thus became the main agents of the process of switching capital from
commercial or industrial sources into landholdings (Feagin, 1998: 141;
Haila, 1991: 346; see also Evers, 1984: 491–2).
The property boom in Metro Cebu occurred in the context of local eco-
nomic growth shaped primarily by the spurt in the export manufacturing
13. From April to July 2001, the author conducted a direct survey of thirty licensed real estate
brokers operating primarily in Metro Cebu. In the survey, respondents were asked to rank
sets of buyers in various categories or class of residential subdivision lots (that is, what
they judged to be the biggest buyers of a certain class of subdivision property got the
highest mark).
14. With stiffer competition in the last decade from expanding furniture exports of countries
with richer raw materials and lower labour costs, such as Vietnam, Indonesia and China,
Cebuano furniture entrepreneurs are increasingly threatened with possible loss of foreign
buyers and eventual closure of their shops.
Globalization and the Property Boom, Metro Cebu 727
sector in the late 1980s, and a partly related population rise due largely to
high immigration. This distinct combination of urbanizing forces has cre-
ated a critical problem of local mass housing while, at the same time,
spiralling urban land prices have seriously constrained its solution.
In the 1950s and 1960s, Cebu province was characterized by large-scale
out-migration into the frontier areas of Mindanao.15 Since the mid-1970s,
however, this trend has reversed, with the province’s average annual popu-
lation growth rate surpassing the national average in the periods 1975–80
and 1980–90, as the result of heavy in-migration to the Metro Cebu area
(Fleiger, 1994: 7; Fleiger and Cusi, 1998: 28–9). Metro Cebu has developed
into the demographic growth centre of the province. From 1980 to 1990 it
experienced a population growth rate of 34.5 per cent, while the rest of the
province grew by only 19.9 per cent (Fleiger, 1994: 13).16
The implications of these demographic trends for local housing demand
are of course tremendous. Shelter needs and housing backlog have grown as
the poor resettle in the city. They have mostly occupied hazardous places
(for example, by creek banks) and privately owned lots (without the consent
of the landowners). The numbers of these ‘displaced informal settlers’ grew
during the property boom as landowners became more intolerant and with-
held consent to existing occupants of their idle lots in the city, in order to
make the lots more saleable as land prices kept rising.
New housing needs due to continuous in-migration and natural popula-
tion growth have also expanded Metro Cebu’s housing backlog. According
to the National Statistics Office, the housing backlog grew from 37.2 per
cent in 1980–90, to 44.8 per cent for 1990–2000. In absolute terms this
means an additional 39,500 housing units required. Estimates made in
1994 calculated the category of subsidized housing units or social housing
as constituting 73 per cent of future housing needs (Econtec Inc., 1994).17
15. During the 1950s, the population growth rate of Cebu province fell behind that of the rest
of the country by some 50 per cent mainly due to high out-migration (Fleiger and Cusi,
1998: 28).
16. This population expansion is evident in the visible growth of Cebu’s informal sector where
most of the in-migrants are employed. Although by its nature it is hard to reach an
accurate estimate of the informal sector, much less to statistically track its growth trends
in the last ten years, many accounts, observations and demographic indicators suggest
rapid growth. For 1995, one author puts the figure employed in the informal sector in
Cebu City alone at 73,000 self-employed and 12,000 unpaid family workers (Etimadi,
2000: 6).
17. A number of recent government and private research studies have further estimated that
figures for Cebu City, which constitutes the bulk of the housing backlog for the whole of
Metro Cebu, will remain high for the next nine years. In its Shelter Plan document for
2001, the Division for the Welfare of the Urban Poor (DWUP, 2001) concludes that there
will be a backlog of at least 75,250 units of socialized housing in the next nine years. A
study commissioned by the city government of Cebu arrived at an even higher estimate,
suggesting that 102,536 new housing units will need to be built in the next nine years, the
bulk of which will be defined as socialized housing (Schema Konsult Inc., 2000: 25).
728 Edsel E. Sajor
18. A 1995 survey study of poor communities in Cebu City noted that while six out of ten
urban poor respondents owned the house they occupy, only 1 per cent owned the lot
(Etemadi, 1995: 4). Recent studies on the housing sector in Metro Cebu are also
unanimous on the point that the extremely high price of urban land in Metro Cebu has
become the single biggest obstacle in the construction of adequate socialized housing units
to meet burgeoning shelter needs (see for example Etimadi, 2000; Schema Konsult Inc.,
2000).
Globalization and the Property Boom, Metro Cebu 729
19. One leading official of the government department for trade and investment for Central
Visayas region recounted that in 1988 and 1989 ‘major property developers immediately
jumped into the investment bandwagon of Metro Cebu started by the foreign investors in
export manufacturing and rode on this sector’s push-start of the local economy’
(interview, 9 April 2001).
730 Edsel E. Sajor
The leading role of the real estate sector, and the generation of a specu-
lative property market in the state-initiated development process in Metro
Cebu, can be understood through the prism of what scholars of Philippine
politics have described as the dominating and predatory role of powerful
provincial elite families and Manila-based oligarchs in a historically weak
state.20 These families have — to put it simply — privatized the state, in the
process strengthening themselves and further weakening the state’s resources
and bureaucratic apparatus (Anderson, 1998a; McCoy, 1994; Wurfel, 1988).
As a result of weak institutionalization, public administration is often
treated as a personal affair, and ‘the conceptual separation of the
state from all personal authority of individuals is often remote from the
Philippine ‘‘structures of authority’’’ (Hutchcroft, 1998: 14).21
The nature of this control and domination of the state by the provincial
elite and oligarchs is well-captured by Sidel (1999), who uses the terms
bosses and bossism in the Philippine context. ‘Bosses’ refer to the ‘predatory
power brokers who achieve monopolistic control over both coercive and
economic resources within given territorial jurisdictions or bailiwicks’: in the
Philippine context, these include small-town mayors, provincial governors,
congressmen, and even presidents (ibid.: 19).22 These bosses perform a
central role in capital accumulation at a local level, relying heavily on
coercive state power, sometimes combined with proprietary wealth, state-
based resources, and brokerage services to local landed and commercial
oligarchies (ibid.: 141–2). American-style electoralism (introduced during the
early American colonial period) has the overall impact of further entrench-
ing the hegemony of these local bosses (see Anderson, 1998b).
The province and city of Cebu have traditionally been dominated by such
bosses. Since the early twentieth century, the top elected executive positions
of the provincial and city government have been held by members of the
Osmeña clan, a political dynasty in the province, whose most prominent
members have also been major players in national government and politics,
20. The dominant position of the oligarchy in Philippine state and politics shares some basic
features of what is characterized as elite governance in several countries in Southeast Asia,
viz., Malaysia, Thailand and Indonesia, in which a narrow set of interlocking elite
interests — business, especially large corporations and conglomerates — work hand-in-
hand with the bureaucracy, in contrast to Western liberal democracies where the interests
of different groups are checked and balanced by a set of competing claims. Insulation
against special elite interests was never established by these states, which have
consequently been prey to nepotism, cronyism and occasional populism (McCargo,
1998; also see Jones 1998).
21. Hutchcroft (1998: 14) parallels the features of modern Philippine polity to Weber’s
description of patrimonial states (in Economy and Society): ‘In general, the notion of an
objectively defined official duty is unknown to the office that is based upon personal
relations of subordination’.
22. ‘‘‘Bossism’’, in turn, refers to the interlocking, multi-tiered directorate of bosses who use
their control over the state apparatus to exploit the archipelago’s human and natural
resources’ (Sidel, 1999: 19).
Globalization and the Property Boom, Metro Cebu 731
and whose economic interests have been urban real estate and commercial
agriculture.23
Third-generation Osmeña bosses were an important force in creating and
managing the property boom of Cebu from 1988 to 1998. The chief eco-
nomic architect of the so-called ‘Ceboom’ was Lito Osmeña, the governor of
Cebu from 1988 to 1992, who subsequently became President Ramos’s
economic adviser for national government flagship projects from 1992 to
1998. The latter position enabled him to attract significant national govern-
ment backing and resources for Cebu-based development projects. His first
cousin, Tomas Osmeña, was the mayor of Cebu City for two terms (1988–92
and 1992–95), while another cousin, John Osmeña, was a senator in the
Philippine Congress during this period. Like the first two generations of
Osmeñas (Sergio Osmeña Sr and Sergio Osmeña Jr), at the time of their
election both Lito and Tomas Osmeña were ‘successful real estate special-
ists’ with projects in the Philippines and on the American West Coast
(Mojares, 1994: 336). Early on in his gubernatorial term, Lito Osmeña
brokered projects for big Manila-based property developers such as Ayala
Land Incorporation, and for the Hongkong-based taipan Robert Kuok
(Sidel, 1999: 136).
Lito and Tomas Osmeña were forceful advocates of contemporary pro-
growth ‘boosterism’, the aggressive promotion of a pro-business agenda for
a particular city against the background of competing cities and alternative
investment opportunities, whose leading players — usually influential polit-
icians and local government leaders, corporate chairpersons, realtors, local
banks and chambers of commerce — all seek to define the city as an
economic growth machine and share a strong consensus on stimulating
investment and economic growth while limiting the redistributional function
of the state (Short, 1996: 210; see also Eichler, 1982; Feagin, 1983; Gordon,
1999; Logan and Molotch, 1987). The two Osmeñas encouraged public
officials and members of the local business community to aggressively
market Cebu’s competitive edge to attract foreign investors and promote
business. Cebu Investment Promotions Center, a partnership project of
government and private business, was set up for this purpose. They also
personally led overseas trade missions of businessmen, represented by the
Cebu Filipino-Chinese Chamber of Commerce and the Cebu Chamber of
Commerce and Industries, to network with chambers of commerce of newly
23. The founder of the political dynasty was Sergio Osmeña Sr who, after serving as
councillor and governor in the early years of the twentieth century, rose to become the
President of the Commonwealth just before the end of World War II. His son, Sergio
Osmeña Jr, became governor in 1951 and subsequently a senator and presidential
candidate in 1969. The Osmeñas who were elected after the restoration of democracy in the
country in 1986 — Lito (governor), Tomas (city mayor) and John (national senator) —
are third generation members of the clan. For an excellent account of the three generation
of Osmeña politicians, see Mojares (1994). For an incisive analysis of their ‘bossism’ see
Sidel (1999).
732 Edsel E. Sajor
24. One major project was the Cebu Business Park, a partnership involving five Manila-based
companies with substantial foreign equity participation. Ayala Group of Companies was
the leading corporation in the partnership. Governor Lito Osmeña is widely known to
have been behind this project, which involved the construction of a shopping mall, five-
star hotels and office towers in a prime lot area, a 49-ha golf course owned by the
provincial government of Cebu. Public confirmation of the project immediately caused
the price of urban lands in the surrounding vicinity to soar.
25. The Cebu City Council has been dominated by Osmeña’s local party: of the sixteen seats,
it held eight in 1988, fourteen in 1992, and all sixteen in 1995, and again in 1998 (Etimadi,
2000: 38).
26. In 1997 it was reported in the local press that some sixty-four low-income homeowners’
organizations, claiming to represent 12,000 families, had launched mass vigils demanding
that remaining provincial government lands be clearly classified as social housing sites, to
protect them against the common practice of spot zoning by the local government, which
usually results in public lands being allocated to property developers for commercial
development (Sun Star Daily, 17 March 1997).
Globalization and the Property Boom, Metro Cebu 733
27. Facing the constraints of land scarcity and high land prices which were the result of the
earlier policies in Cebu City, in the second half of the 1990s Mayor Garcia’s
administration prioritized high-density, medium-rise building. Not only was the price of
these units still beyond the reach of the urban poor, the programme was also unacceptable
to urban poor groups because this type of housing would not allow them to maintain their
traditional backyard or home-based informal sector livelihood activities such as raising
hogs or chicken, or selling prepared food.
Globalization and the Property Boom, Metro Cebu 735
officials more often act as facilitators for the land document processing
concerns of big property developers, undertaking spot zoning and granting
exemptions from existing use classifications at the request of the bosses.28
Moreover, at the time of writing, Cebu City government is still in the
process of producing a comprehensive land use and development plan; in
the absence of effective urban planning, ‘large commercial and speculative
interests are transforming the urban landscape everyday’ (Scott, 1998: 387).
Unlike the spatial planning practices of some cities (see, for example, Ortiz
and Bertaud, 2001), Cebu City LGU has shown no sign of following a
master plan or using specific planning tools to advance its official develop-
ment objective of providing affordable, low-cost housing.
The weakness of the civil bureaucracy is also manifest in the failure to
enforce social housing legislation. National legislation requires that devel-
opers of non-socialized housing projects provide at least 20 per cent of the
total subdivision area, or project cost, for socialized housing developments:
compliance by a developer with this provision is a prerequisite for the
issuance by the government of development permits and/or licences to sell.
This provision was meant to institutionalize enhanced private sector partici-
pation in socialized housing. However, in Cebu — and in most areas of the
country — this well-intentioned legislation suffers from the lack of enforce-
ment capability of the existing bureaucracy. According to the monitoring of
the Cebu Provincial Development Office in the period 1993 to 1999, only
ten subdivisions out of 125 housing projects in the open market sector in
Cebu City complied with the requirement of the Urban Development and
Housing Authority. In the rest of cases, developers either allocated spaces in
remote locations outside the city and far from basic infrastructure and
support services or did not provide any space at all (Etimadi, 2000: 96). In
spite of this, subdivision projects in Cebu always get their development
permits and/or licences to sell from local regulatory agencies — these are
frequently given on the basis of a mere affidavit of the developer promising
compliance. The government has thus had no success in exacting any social
obligations from the high-end private property developers to advance its
goals of universal housing.29 The same lack of enforcement is true of
another regulation which requires developers to secure an environmental
compliance certification (ECC) permit before starting projects or offering
these to the public for sale. In Cebu, private developers have managed to
start bulldozing land for subdivision projects and offering these projects’
lots for sale to the public, without acquiring an ECC permit.
28. This situation is very different to other planning systems. In the UK, for instance, salaried
planning authorities, while expected to serve elected representatives, conduct their
business with reference to an ideology of professional planning practice and deliberately
use ‘planning gain’ to secure some public advantage in granting permits for development
projects (Fanstein, 1994; Short, 1996: 463–87).
29. Others countries, such as Singapore, have been more successful; see Huat (2000).
736 Edsel E. Sajor
CONCLUSION
Urban development in Metro Cebu in the late 1980s and 1990s shows how
global and local processes interact in a secondary metropolis of a developing
country, to produce an outcome that exacerbates the traditional problem of
access to housing land for low-income and urban poor groups. The growth
boom, which initially started as a surge in foreign investment in manufac-
turing but was immediately taken over by the property sector, resulted in
development dominated by the production of high-end residential real
estate commodities and the rise of a speculative land market. This has led
to a spatial allocation and reordering that is highly regressive, pricing out
the low-income and urban poor from formal land markets and minimalizing
land allocation for mass housing, while generating windfall profits for high-
end residential property builders, big real estate owners, and speculators.
State and politics have often received scant attention in studying the
phenomena of rapid growth and property development in Southeast Asian
cities and their equity dimensions. Equity problems have too easily been
seen as the manifestations of inadequate urban managerial capacity, or lack
of expertise. However, the way that globally-linked rapid property develop-
ment affects a given land market and its impact on certain groups as winners
or losers depends on the nature of the state and its intervention in the
process. As the Metro Cebu case illustrates, control and domination of
the state by rent-seeking bosses — who are not simply members of the
local oligarchy but major property developers and brokers themselves —
have shaped a strong pro-growth governing agenda and forms of interven-
tion that enhance real estate values in the metropolis for the foreign and
domestic builders, for Cebu’s landed elite and for themselves. With strong
backing at the national level, the local government has doggedly pursued
this agenda and has mobilized various state resources and instruments,
while ignoring the consequences on urgent low-cost and mass housing
needs. At the same time, the lack of mobilization among the middle classes
or among low-income and urban poor groups means that there is no
significant constraining social force to check the opportunism and rent-
seeking activities of these bosses or to oppose the overarching pro-
growth agenda. Compounding the situation further is an incoherent and
weak bureaucracy that has prevented the implementation of socially respon-
sible legislation pertaining to sound local planning and mass housing
provisioning.
Acknowledgements
REFERENCES
Gilbert, A. and J. Gulgler (1992) Cities, Poverty and Development. Urbanization in the Third
World (2nd edn). New York: Oxford University Press.
Goldblum, C. and T. Wong (2000) ‘Growth, Crisis and Spatial Change: A Study of Haphazard
Urbanisation in Jakarta, Indonesia’, Land Use Policy 17: 29–37.
Gordon, I. (1999) ‘Internationalization and Urban Competition’, Urban Studies 36(5–6):
1001–16.
Gottdiener, M. (1985) The Social Production of Urban Space. Austin, TX: University of Texas
Press
Gottdiener, M. and J. Feagin (1988) ‘The Paradigm Shift In Urban Sociology’, Urban Affairs
Quarterly 24 (2): 163–87.
Gottlieb, P. (1995) ‘Residential Amenities, Firm Location and Economic Development’, Urban
Studies 32(9): 1413–36.
Haila, A. (1991) ‘Four Types of Investment in Land and Property’, International Journal of
Urban and Regional Research 15(3): 343–65.
Hardoy, J. and D. Satterthwaite (1989) Squatter Citizen. Life in the Urban Third World.
London: Earthscan Publications Ltd.
Hardoy, J., D. Metlin and D. Satterwaithe (2001) Environmental Problems in an Urbanizing
World. London: Earthscan Publications Ltd.
Healey, P. and S. Barrett (1990) ‘Structure and Agency in Land and Property Development
Processes: Some Ideas for Research’, Urban Studies 27(1): 89–104.
HLRUB (1999) ‘List of Subdivision’. Unpublished report. Cebu City: Housing Land Use and
Regulatory Board [Region VII].
HLRUB (2000) ‘List of Approved Projects’. Unpublished report. Cebu City: Housing Land
Use and Regulatory Board [Region VII].
Huat, C. (2000) ‘The Politics of Universal Provision of Public Housing’, in G. Bridge and
S. Watson (eds) A Companion to the City, pp. 609–616. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.
Hutchcroft, P. (1998) Booty Capitalism. The Politics of Banking in the Philippines. Quezon City:
Ateneo de Manila University Press.
Jellineck, L. (2000) ‘Jakarta, Indonesia: Kampung Culture or Consumer Culture’, in N. Low,
B. Gleeson, I. Elander and R. Lidskog, Consuming Cities. The Urban Environment in the
Global Economy after the Rio Declaration, pp. 265–80. London: Routledge.
Jones, D. (1998) ‘The Politics of Economic Governance’, in R. Maidment, D. Goldblatt and
J. Mitchell (eds) Governance in the Asia-Pacific, pp. 172–94. London and New York:
Routledge and Open University Press.
Kasarda, J. and A. Parnell (1993) ‘Introduction: Third World Urban Development Issues’, in
J. Kasarda and A. Parnell Third World Cities. Problems, Policies, and Prospects, pp. ix–xvii.
Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications, Inc.
Kelly, P. (1998) ‘The Politics of Urban–Rural Relationships: Land Conversion in the Philip-
pines’, Environment and Urbanization 10(1): 35–54.
Kelly, P. (1999) ‘Everyday Urbanization: The Social Dynamics of Development in Manila’s
Extended Metropolitan Region’, International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
23(2): 283–303.
Kothari, M. (1994) ‘Tijuca Lagoon: Evictions and Human Rights in Rio de Janeiro’, Environ-
ment and Urbanization 6(1): 63–73.
Knight, M. (1998) ‘Developing Countries and the Globalization of Financial Markets’, World
Development 26(7): 1185–1200.
Krongkaew, M. (1996) ‘The Changing Urban System in a Fast-growing City and Economy:
The Case of Bangkok and Thailand’, in Fu-Chen Lo and Yue-Man Yeung (eds) Emerging
World Cities in Pacific Asia, pp. 286–334. Tokyo: United Nations University Press
Leftwich, A. (1993) ‘Governance, Democracy and Development in the Third World’, Third
World Quarterly 14(3): 605–24.
Linn, J. (1987) ‘Success and Failure in Urban Management: Some Lessons for the East Asian
Experience’, in R. Fuchs, G. Jones and E. Pernia (eds) Urbanization and Urban Policies in
Pacific Asia, pp. 233–56. Boulder, CO and London: Westview Press.
740 Edsel E. Sajor
Logan, J. and H. Molotch (1987) Urban Fortunes. Political Economy of Place. Berkeley, CA:
University of California Press
Magno-Ballesteros, M. (2000) ‘The Urban Land and Real Estate Market in Metro Manila: A
Socio-Economic Analysis’. PhD dissertation, Faculty of Social Sciences, Catholic Univer-
sity of Nijmegen.
Manila Times (17 March 1990) ‘Boom Makes it Harder to Own Home in Cebu’.
Manila Times (8 August 1991) ‘Governor to Lead Mission to Singapore’.
McCargo, D. (1998) ‘Elite Governance: Business, Bureaucrats and the Military’, in R. Maidment,
D. Goldblatt and J. Mitchell (eds) Governance in the Asia-Pacific, pp. 126–49. London and
New York: Routledge and Open University.
McCoy, A. (1994) ‘‘‘An Anarchy of Families’’: The Historiography of State and Family in the
Philippines’, in A. McCoy (ed.) An Anarchy of Families. State and Family in the Philippines,
pp. 1–32. Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila University Press.
Mollenkopf, J. (1996 [1992]) ‘How to Study Urban Political Power’, in R. LeGates and F. Stout
(eds) The City Reader, pp. 219–28. London and New York: Routledge (2nd edn).
Mojares, R. (1994) ‘The Dream Goes On and On: Three Generations of the Osmeñas, 1906–
1990’, in A. McCoy (ed.) An Anarchy of Families. State and Family in the Philippines, pp.
311–46. Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila University Press.
Mojares, R. (1997) ‘A Mountain of Names’, in R. Mojares and S. Quimpo (eds) Cebu. More
Than An Island, pp. 34–42. Metro Manila: Ayala Foundation, Inc.
Moser, C. (1998) ‘The Asset Vulnerability Framework: Reassessing Urban Poverty Reduction
Strategies’, World Development 26(1): 1–19.
Naerssen, T., M. Ligthart and F. Zapanta (1996) ‘Managing Metropolitan Manila’, in
J. Ruland (ed.) The Dynamics of Metropolitan Management in Southeast Asia, pp. 168–206.
Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
NCSO (2000) Philippine Census 2000. Manila: National Census and Statistics Office.
Newstime (12 September 1992) ‘Singapore Mission sets Cebu Visit’.
Olds, K. (1995) ‘Globalization and the Production of New Urban Spaces: Pacific Rim Mega-
projects in the Late 20th Century’, Environment and Planning A. 27: 1713–43.
Ortiz, A. and A. Bertaud (2001) ‘Land Markets and Urban Management: The Role of Planning
Tools’, in M. Freire and R. Stren (eds) The Challenge of Urban Government. Policies and
Practices, pp. 239–52. Washington, DC: The World Bank Institute; Toronto: Centre for
Urban and Community Studies, University of Toronto.
Parnwell, M. and L. Wongsuphasawat (1997) ‘Between the Global and the Local. Extended
Metropolitanisation and Industrial Location Decision Making in Thailand’, Third World
Planning Review 19(2): 119–38.
Philippine Business Profiles and Perpectives Inc. (PBPPI) (1998) 1997–98 Philippine Business
Profile. Top 7000 Corporations. Metro Manila: Ortigas Center.
PPDO (2000) File folder on economic indicators. Provincial Planning and Development Office
of Cebu. Cebu City.
Pugh, C. (1997) ‘International Urban and Housing Policy: A Review of the ‘‘Cambridge
Studies’’, 1989–95’, Environment and Planning A 29: 149–67.
Ruland, J. (1996) ‘The Dynamics of Metropolitan Management in Southeast Asia: An Intro-
ductory Note’, in J. Ruland (ed.) The Dynamics of Metropolitan Management in Southeast
Asia, pp. 1–29. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies
Ruland, J. and B. Ladavalya (1996) ‘Managing Metropolitan Bangkok: Power Contest or
Public Service?’, in J. Ruland (ed.) The Dynamics of Metropolitan Management in Southeast
Asia, pp. 30–70. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
Sajor, E. (forthcoming) ‘Land Investors During the Property Boom of the 1990s and the Elite
of Metro Cebu’, in H. Dahles and O. van den Muizenberg (eds) Capital and Knowledge in
Asia, pp. 90–107. London and New York: Routledge.
Sassen, S. (1991) The Global City. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Sassen, S. (1998) Globalization and Its Discontents. Essays on the New Mobility of People and
Money. New York: The New Press.
Globalization and the Property Boom, Metro Cebu 741
Schema Konsult Inc. (2000) ‘Cebu City Strategic Masterplan Study’. Unpublished mimeo.
Cebu City: Schema Konsult Inc.
Schmidt, J. (1998) ‘Globalisation and Inequality in Urban South-east Asia’, Third World
Planning Review 20(2): 127–45.
Scott, J. (1998) Seeing Like a State. New Haven, CT and London: Yale University Press.
Setchell, C. (1995) ‘The Growing Environmental Crisis in the World’s Mega-Cities. The Case of
Bangkok’, Third World Planning Review 17(1): 1–18.
Short, J. (1996) The Urban Order. An Introduction to Cities, Culture, and Power. Oxford:
Blackwell Publishers.
Sidel, J. (1999) Capital, Coercion, and Crime. Bossism in the Philippines. Stanford, CA: Stanford
University Press.
Sun Star Daily (1 November 1996) ‘Property broker says end-users make 90% of South Hill
buyers’.
Sun Star Daily (5 March 1997) ‘Developers Need ‘‘Bonus’’ to Build Low-Cost Houses’.
Sun Star Daily (17 March 1997) ‘Capitol-owned Lots from City to Retain Dwellers Seek Help’,
Karen Flanes.
Sun Star Daily (7 August 1997) ‘The Building Boom in Cebu’, Ahmed Cuison.
Thirkell, A. (1996) ‘Players in Urban Informal Land Markets: Who Wins? Who Loses? A Case
Study of Cebu City’, Environment and Urbanization 8(2): 71–90.
Thrift, N. (1985) ‘The Internationalization of Producer Services and the Integration of the
Pacific Basin Property Market’, in M. Taylor and N. Thrift (eds) Multinationals and the
Restructuring of the World Economy, pp. 142–92. London: Croom Helm.
Wurfel, D. (1988) Filipino Politics. Development and Decay. Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila
University Press.
Yap, K. (1989) ‘Some Low-income Housing Delivery Subsystems in Bangkok, Thailand’,
Environment and Urbanization 1(2): 27–37.
Yap, K. (1992) ‘Low-income Housing Sub-markets’, in K. Yap (ed.) Low-income Housing in
Bangkok. A Review of Some Housing Sub-markets, pp. 7–30. HSD Monograph 25. Bangkok:
Division of Human Settlements Development, AIT.
Yeung, Y. (1989) ‘Bursting at the Seams: Strategies for Controlling Metropolitan Growth in
Asia’, in Frank Costa, Dutt Ashok, Laurence Ma and Allen Noble (eds) Urbanization in
Asia. Spatial Dimensions and Policy Issues, pp. 311–32. Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii
Press.
Yeung, Y. (1991) ‘Past Approaches and Emerging Challenges’, in The Urban Poor and Basic
Infrastructure Services in Asia and the Pacific, pp. 27–81. Regional Seminar Volume 1: A
report on the Seminar held on 22–28 January 1991 in Manila, Philippines. Asian Develop-
ment Bank and Economic Development Institute.