The Economics of Best Execution
The Economics of Best Execution
The Economics of Best Execution
Lawrence E. Harris
USC
This paper was prepared for presentation at the New York Stock Exchange Conference on the
Search for the Best Price, New York, March 15, 1996.
The work presented here is still preliminary. I would be delighted to receive any suggestions,
comments or corrections.
Lawrence E. Harris
Professor of Finance and Business Economics
School of Business Administration
University of Southern California
Los Angeles, CA 90089-1421
1
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
The most sophisticated customers understand that they cannot buy something that they cannot
measure well. If brokers believe that their customers cannot measure execution quality, they are
unlikely to provide it, whether paid for it or not: Any broker who spends resources to provide
unrecognized execution quality will be undercut by those who do not. In competitive brokerage
markets, such brokers cannot compete. They must either go out of business or quit providing
high quality service. The most sophisticated customers therefore only pay for the level of
execution quality that they can audit. For them, best execution means “get me the execution that
I expect you to provide given what I pay you and the limitations of my ability to audit your
performance.” These traders define best execution relative to the costs of auditing it.
2
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
Any improvement in price relative to the BBO is called price improvement. Brokers may
negotiate the price improvement frequency ex ante, or, more commonly, audit it ex post.
The quality of service provided to limit orders varies by market and by dealer. All dealers
generally guarantee that limit orders will be executed if their limit prices match the opposing BBO
(offer for a buy order; bid for a sell order). Some dealers promise to display limit orders under
various conditions. Dealers who are exchange members must give their limit orders price priority
over their own trading and they must yield to their public limit orders at a given price. Some
dealers promise to fill limit orders after a certain amount of volume has been printed at that price.
The fact that dealers pay for order flows suggests that they could provide better execution
services than they do. In particular, dealers may not be providing as much price improvement for
market orders as they might. They may also be extracting excessive option values from their limit
orders and they may not be giving them as much exposure as they might. If brokers demanded
more price improvement and better limit order executions, dealers would pay less for their
preferenced order flows.
3
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
When suppliers are generating less than their required profits, they raise prices, cut service, or
quit. These forces tend to raise profits. In equilibrium, excess profits are zero.
3.B.1 Retail customers cannot easily determine whether they receive good execution
Good execution for market orders means good prices and quick service. Retail market order
traders can easily audit response times, but they are not well prepared to audit the quality of their
prices.
To effectively measure execution price quality, traders need to examine the relation between their
execution prices and nearby trade prices and quotes. However, few retail traders have access to
the transaction and quote records surrounding their trades. Those that do may not analyze their
4
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
transaction costs carefully because the process is too time consuming: The resulting information
is too expensive relative its value. Most retail traders only know the quoted spread and last price
at the time of their order submission. From this information alone, it takes many trades to reliably
estimate price improvement rates (unless they are extremely good or bad).
The execution audit problem for limit order traders is even more difficult because it can be hard to
determine whether a limit order should have executed, especially if the order matched or even
bettered the best BBO. The uncertainty associated with limit order executions greatly
complicates the execution audit problem.
Even if traders measure execution price quality, they still cannot judge whether they are receiving
good executions without having some norms against which they can compare their experiences.
To obtain such norms, they must either trade with several brokerages, or they must compare their
experiences with other traders. In either event, they must be careful to compare apples to apples
and oranges to oranges since some securities are harder to trade than others. Due to their costs,
retail traders rarely do such comparisons.
5
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
price their quotes (or limit orders) too aggressively. Spreads will have to be wide to recover
from uninformed traders what the liquidity suppliers lose to informed traders.
In exchange-organized markets, order precedence rules route liquidity-demanding order flows to
the orders or quotes that first display the best price. Spreads in these markets tend to be low
because offering liquidity to these order flows tends to be profitable, because traders will get the
order flow if they bid for it, and because limit order traders can compete with dealers.
In all markets where order preferencing arrangements are common and where dealers guarantee
execution at the BBO, the relation between quoted price and order flow may be weak. Generally,
the only orders that trader route to the best quoted prices are those that dealers are unwilling to
provide other incentives to attract. Since these are usually well-informed order flows (nobody
wants to trade with informed traders), spreads in those markets tend to be greater than they
would be if there were no order preferencing.
Dealer-organized securities markets tend to have high spreads for three reasons:
1. Order preferencing arrangements are common.
2. Dealers have weak incentives to attract order flow by price.
3. Public limit order traders cannot easily represent their interests.
3.D Clearinghouses
Order routing systems that match buyers to sellers who do not have relationships with each other
must provide a mechanism to guarantee that both sides will honor and fulfill their contracts.
Otherwise untrustworthy traders will not attempt to settle trades that have moved against them,
and uncreditworthy traders will not be able to do so. Such systems typically employ
clearinghouses that guarantee trade performance.
Clearinghouses regulate their members to ensure that they are trustworthy and creditworthy. In
the event that a member fails to perform, the other members end up bearing the cost.
The provision of these services can be quite expensive. The expense usually falls
disproportionately on those who are most trustworthy and creditworthy since they do not tend to
default. Accordingly, the most trustworthy and creditworthy members always want to remove the
least trustworthy and creditworthy from among them, or at least charge them risk-based fees for
participating. If they cannot do so, and if the expenses of belonging to the clearinghouse are high,
they may prefer to opt out.
6
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
7
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
8
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
4.E.2 Require that brokers report payments for order flow to their customers.
Regulators already require brokers to report that they have received payments for order flow.
Customers can learn the exact nature of the compensation on request. This proposal would
strengthen this requirement by making it easier for customers to learn about the payments for
order flow by presenting the information to them directly. Many customers, however, may find
the information to be confusing.
If brokers believe that reporting this information would upset their customers, they will ask their
dealers to substitute non-pecuniary order flow inducements for pecuniary inducements. They will
also expand their dealing operations, as described above.
4.E.3 Require that payments for order flow be rebated directly to the customer’s account.
If the retail brokerage market is quite competitive, as seems likely, the implementation of this
proposal will increase brokerage commissions. It will probably also alter the distribution of
brokerage commissions among order types and sizes. For those brokers whose commission
schedules currently discriminate between limit orders and market orders, the increase will
primarily fall upon market orders.
Given the lower net costs associated with executing market orders as compared to limit orders, it
may be instructive that more brokers do not presently offer lower commission rates to market
orders. Brokers may believe that their customers will not tolerate the additional complexity or
that the discrimination will alienate them. If these explanations are correct, the effect of this
rebate proposal will be to confuse investors who may not be interested in the issue.
This disclosure would certainly focus more attention on payments for order flow. Customers may
not want to receive these rebates if they believe (rightly) that they can only be funded through
poor transaction prices. In which case, brokers may choose to have their dealers to substitute
non-pecuniary order flow inducements for pecuniary inducements. This will cause the
competition for retail order flow to continue to remain focused on commissions rather than on the
combination of the commissions and rebates.
Alternatively, customers may start demanding these rebates, without recognizing that in
competitive markets, they can only be funded through less price improvement or greater
commissions. If so, brokers’ incentives to obtain price improvement for their customers will be
diminished, if not reversed. They may also have their dealer subsidiaries explicitly pay for order
flow instead of internalizing their excess profits.
Some practical problems are associated with rebating payments for order flow. Payments for
order flow may not be easy to allocate to individual orders. Although preferencing arrangements
may specify a price per share for various order types and sources, other conditions may be
attached to the contract that modify these payments. If these conditions depend on global
characteristics of the order flow, the allocation of payments to individual orders may be difficult.
Moreover, it may not be possible to do the allocation at the time of the trade. If so, the rebates
will be uncertain and deferred. Neither characteristic will likely appeal to retail customers. One
effect of the implementation of a rebate system may therefore be a restructuring of payment
arrangements to make it easier to allocate payments to individual orders. If so, the benefits, if
any, that come from existing arrangements may be lost.
9
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
10
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
delegating the authority and responsibility, subject to regulatory oversight, to self regulating
organizations (exchanges and dealer organizations). These SRO’s are much better equipped to
specify reasonable standards, and to enforce them.
The specification of performance standards raises several serious problems. Perhaps the most
important problem is that the specified standards may be inconsistent with consumer interests. If
the standards specify a higher level of service than consumers desire, they will pay more and be
worse off. It is unclear how a regulator would decide what services consumers want. Moreover,
since consumers have different preferences, attempts to regulate meaningful universal
performance standards almost guarantee that they will hurt some consumers.
Effective enforcement of performance standards requires that the standard be well defined, easily
measured, and appropriate. Otherwise, enforcement will be contentious and subject to selective
discrimination. It is unclear, however, that any agency can specify a set of standards that apply to
all trading problems that dealers face. For example, how would a requirement to provide price
improvement adjust for the fact that markets for different securities vary substantially?
Differences in spreads, trading activity and the degree of informed trading in the order flow would
need to be factored into the performance standard, but doing so would be quite difficult. Failing
to do so would be unfair.
Finally, even if regulators could specify reasonable standards, some combination of sticks and
carrots would be necessary to ensure that traders met those standards. The regulator therefore
would need to be able to control the allocation of privileges and/or have access to a meaningful
disciplinary procedure. The use of privileges to motivate traders is only effective if those
privileges are not already widely available. To be effective, such privileges often involve awards
of market power. This is troublesome, since the award of unique privileges may be anti-
competitive. Likewise, disciplinary procedures are only effective if regulators can place
meaningful sanctions on traders. Exchanges and dealer organizations already have similar
procedures in place to enforce their rules and, in the case of exchanges, to allocate specialties.
These procedures are cumbersome, contentious and quite expensive to run.
11
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
The display of limit orders would also improve limit order execution rates by making them more
available to other traders. However, without rules that route market orders to the best available
price, limit order execution rates would not necessarily improve much. Brokers would force
dealers to match the best price and only route to the limit order if their dealers were unwilling to
trade. The improvement in limit order execution rates in such markets depends on the extent to
which dealers who need liquidity take it from displayed public limit orders.
12
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
quick executions (it allows them to hold the trader on the phone and ask “now what would you
like to do”) they may resist the additional costs this system imposes upon them.
4.E.6.d Require brokers to route market orders only to dealers or markets displaying the best
price.
This rule would strengthen the relation between price and order flow. Dealers who want order
flow would have to quote aggressively for it. Bid/ask spreads would decrease. The decrease
might be quite substantial.
If regulators allow brokers to preference orders among those dealers who are at the best price,
dealers may still offer order flow inducements. These inducements, however, would be smaller
because the spreads will be tighter. Price improvement relative to the tighter spreads would be
less common.
The decrease in spreads would also improve public limit order execution rates by allowing more
standing limit orders to be executed.
This rule would not be effective if brokers could quickly advise their correspondent dealers that
an order is coming so that they can match the best available quote. To prevent such behavior, it
may be necessary to require that a dealer’s market-matching quote stand for a some interval
before it is eligible to attract order flow. Enforcement of this rule would require the operation of
a consolidated order routing system.
13
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
The adoption of this rule could force brokers to trade with dealers whom they do not trust to
settle their trades in a timely and efficient manner. To avoid settlement problems, some
clearinghouse would have to guarantee performance.
If regulators adopted this rule, it presumably would only apply to small market orders. Since
large orders often involve direct negotiations, it would probably be desirable to exempt them from
this rule.
4.E.6.e Maintain strict price-time priority among dealer and market quotes and require
brokers to route market orders accordingly.
This rule is the same as the previous one, except that brokers will not be able to preference
orders. The application of time precedence will further strengthen the relation between price and
order flow by rewarding those traders who most aggressively improve price.
Under this rule, spreads should narrow substantially. There will be no price improvement and no
payment for market orders.
14
Lawrence Harris The Economics of Best Execution
intermediaries in the markets, as it probably would, public traders might realize great benefits.
These considerations suggest a role for further regulation.
15