Unit IV
Unit IV
Unit IV
SYBA
PROFIT IN PC IN THE SHORT-RUN
• At equilibrium, AR = AC
• Firm is at equilibrium at point A where
MR=MC
• TR= AQ x OQ = OPAQ
• TC = AQ x OQ = OPAQ
• Since, TR = TC we have normal profit
LOSS
• AR < AVC
• The firm can minimize its losses up to fixed
costs only by not producing
• E is point of equilibrium
• TR = EX * OX = OPEX
• TC = BX * OX = OABX
• Loss = OABX – OPEX
= PABE
= Shaded area + PDCE
= TFC + part of TVC
LONG-RUN EQUILIBRIUM OF FIRMS UNDER
IDENTICAL COST CONDITIONS
▪ All factors of production are variable in the long run
▪ Firms enter and exit the industry
▪ When some firms are earning super-normal profit in the long-run, i.e. AR > AC,
new firms are lured to enter the industry
▪ Thus, output increases and prices fall
▪ When firms face losses, AR < AC, some firms exit the industry
▪ Output reduces and prices rise
▪ Normal profits
LONG RUN EQUILIBRIUM OF FIRMS UNDER
DIFFERENTIAL COST CONDITIONS
LAC
D=LAR=LM
R
(2) The MC curve must cut the MR curve from below and after the point of equilibrium it
must be above the MR. This is the second order condition.’ Under conditions of perfect
competition, the MR curve of a firm coincides with the AR curve. The MR curve is
horizontal to the X- axis. Therefore, the firm is in equilibrium when MC=MR=AR (Price).
In Figure 1(A), the MC curve cuts the MR curve first at point A. It satisfies the condition of
MC = MR, but it is not a point of maximum profits because after point A, the MC curve is
below the MR curve. It does not pay the firm to produce the minimum output OM when it
can earn larger profits by producing beyond OM.
Point В is of maximum profits where both the conditions are satisfied. Between points A and
B. it pays the firm to expand its output because it’s MR > MC. It will, however, stop further
production when it reaches the OM1 level of output where the firm satisfies both the
conditions of equilibrium.
If it has any plans to produce more than OM1 it will be incurring losses, for its marginal cost
exceeds its marginal revenue beyond the equilibrium point B. The same conclusions hold
good in the case of a straight line MC curve as shown in Figure 1. (B)
Short-run equilibrium
Short run means period of time within which the firms can alter their level of output only by
increasing or decreasing the amount of variable factors such as labour and raw material,
while fixed factors, like capital equipment remain unchanged. Moreover, in the short run,
new firms can neither enter the industry nor the existing firms can leave it.
For the sake of simplicity of study, let us suppose that in an industry all factors of production,
are homogenous. All the firms are equally efficient such as they have identical cost curve.
Under the circumstances each firm of a given industry, in equilibrium may get either:
(i) Super normal profit.
(ii) Normal profit.
(iii) Suffer losses
All the three situations depend upon the price determined by the industry.
1. Short-Run Equilibrium of a Competitive Firm (Maximising Profits)
The case of a perfectly competitive firm earning supernormal profits in the short run is shown
in Fig. 13.2, where the average cost curve of the efficient firm lies below its average revenue
curve. The firm is in equilibrium at point 'E', where the MC curve cuts the MR curve from
below. Corresponding to the equilibrium point, the equilibrium output is OQ, which is sold at
the equilibrium price OP. Since this price (OP or EQ) exceeds the average cost (BQ), the firm
will earn super normal or excess profits in this situation (shown by shaded area in Fig. 13.2).
Total profits from the sale of equilibrium output are 'profit per unit of output x quantity', i.e..
(EQ-BQ) OQ = Area (APEB). Alternatively,
Super normal Profits = Total Revenue - Total Cost
= Price x Equilibrium Quantity - Average Cost x Quantity Equilibrium
= (OP x OQ)- (BQ x OQ)=Area (OPEQ-OABQ)
=Area (APEB)
2. Short-Run Equilibrium of a Competitive Firm (Earning Normal Profits)
In the short-run, there are some firms of average efficiency earning only normal profits just
sufficient to induce them to continue to operate in the short-run. These normal profits are
included in the costs. Fig. 13.4 illustrates such a case for a competitive firm, which is just
able to break-even (no profit-no loss situation) at point ‘E'. Here, the AC curve is tangent to
the AR curve at the minimum point 'E' of the former. This means that the price of the product
is equal to its average cost. In other words, total cost is equal to total revenue. Such a
competitive firm, which neither makes excess profits nor suffers losses in the short-run is
called a marginal firm.
4. Shut-down point
So far, we have been analyzing the question of how much a competitive firm will produce. In
certain circumstances, however, the firm will decide to shut down and not produce anything
at all.
Here we need to distinguish between a temporary shutdown of a firm and the permanent exit
of a firm from the market. A shutdown refers to a short-run decision not to produce anything
during a specific period of time because of current market conditions. Exit refers to a long-
run decision to leave the market. The short-run and long-run decisions differ because most
firms cannot avoid their fixed costs in the short run but can do so in the long run. That is, a
firm that shuts down temporarily still has to pay its fixed costs, whereas a firm that exits the
market does not have to pay any costs at all, fixed or variable. For example, consider the
production decision that a farmer faces. The cost of the land is one of the farmer’s fixed
costs. If the farmer decides not to produce any crops one season, the land lies fallow, and he
cannot recover this cost. When making the short-run decision of whether to shut down for a
season, the fixed cost of land is said to be a sunk cost. By contrast, if the farmer decides to
leave farming altogether, he can sell the land. When making the long-run decision of whether
to exit the market, the cost of land is not sunk. (We return to the issue of sunk costs shortly.)
Now let’s consider what determines a firm’s shutdown decision. If the firm shuts down, it
loses all revenue from the sale of its product. At the same time, it saves the variable costs of
making its product (but must still pay the fixed costs).
Thus, the firm shuts down if the revenue that it would earn from producing is less than its
variable costs of production.
A bit of mathematics can make this shutdown rule more useful. If TR stands for total revenue
and VC stands for variable cost, then the firm’s decision can be written as
Shut down if TR < VC.
The firm shuts down if total revenue is less than variable cost. By dividing both sides of this
inequality by the quantity Q, we can write it as
Shut down if TR/Q < VC/Q.
The left side of the inequality, TR/Q, is total revenue P 3 Q divided by quantity Q, which is
average revenue, most simply expressed as the good’s price, P. The right side of the
inequality, VC/Q, is average variable cost, AVC. Therefore, the firm’s shutdown rule can be
restated as
Shut down if P < AVC.
That is, a firm chooses to shut down if the price of the good is less than the average variable
cost of production. This rule is intuitive: When choosing to produce, the firm compares the
price it receives for the typical unit to the average variable cost that it must incur to produce
the typical unit. If the price doesn’t cover the average variable cost, the firm is better off
stopping production altogether. The firm still loses money (because it has to pay fixed costs),
but it would lose even more money by staying open. The firm can reopen in the future if
conditions change so that price exceeds average variable cost.
Diagrammatically, it is explained below. The firm shuts down as losses are more than the
fixed costs. The firms will not be able to cover even AVC. This fact is clear from figure 14.
In figure 14, when price falls to OP, below the shut-down point, Equilibrium takes place at
point E. Losses which are incurred are equal to BE per point.
Total loss = Total Rectangle (ABEP)
= Shaded Rectangle ABCD + rectangle DCEP
= TFC + some part of TVC.
Since, losses are more than TFC, the firm shuts down its unit.
• FIRST, AT ITS OPTIMUM OUTPUT THE FIRM CHARGES A PRICE THAT EXCEEDS
MARGINAL COSTS, THE MC FIRM MAXIMIZES PROFITS WHERE MARGINAL
REVENUE = MARGINAL COST. SINCE THE MC FIRM'S DEMAND CURVE IS
DOWNWARD SLOPING THIS MEANS THAT THE FIRM WILL BE CHARGING A PRICE
THAT EXCEEDS MARGINAL COSTS
• EXCESS CAPACITY : FIRM'S PROFIT MAXIMIZING OUTPUT IS LESS THAN THE
OUTPUT ASSOCIATED WITH MINIMUM AVERAGE COST
REFERENCES
• HTTPS://MSBRIJUNIVERSITY.AC.IN/ASSETS/UPLOADS/NEWSUPDATE/MONOPOLISTI
C.PDF
• GREGORY MANKIW
MONOPOLY
INTRODUCTION
• The term monopoly means a single seller (mono = single and poly = seller)
• A monopoly refers to a firm which has a product without any substitute in the market
• Natural Monopolies : When a firm’s average-total-cost curve continually declines, the firm
has what is called a natural monopoly.
CONDITIONS FOR EQUILIBRIUM
• MR = MC
TR = AR x output
= AQ x OQ
= OPAQ
TC = AC x output
= BQ x OQ
= OP’BQ
Profit = TR – TC
= OPAQ – OP’AQ o
= P’PAB
NORMAL PROFIT
• TR = AR x Output
= AQ x OQ
= OPAQ
• TC = AC x Output A
= AQ x OQ
= OPAQ
O
LOSSES
• TC = AC x Output
= BQ x OQ
= OP’BQ
• TR = AR x Output
= AQ x OQ
= OPAQ
• Losses = TC - TR
= OP’BQ – OPAQ
= PP’BA Q
LONG-RUN EQUILIBRIUM
• E : point of equilibrium
• QP: equilibrium price
• OQ: Equilibrium output
• Super normal profit: KPHN
• At the equilibrium output OQ, the plant is
not being fully utilized
• LAC is not minimum at this point
INEFFICIENCY IN MONOPOLY
REFERENCES
• https://www.toppr.com/guides/business-economics-cs/analysis-of-market/equilibrium-in-mo
nopoly/
• http://www.economicsconcepts.com/long_run_equilibrium_under_monopoly.htm
• https://courses.lumenlearning.com/wmopen-microeconomics/chapter/the-inefficiency-of-mo
nopoly/
• Principles of Microeconomics, Gregory Mankiw
OLIGOPOLY
FEATURES
• Few firms/sellers
• Interdependence
• Non-Price competition
• High entry and exit barriers
• Role of selling costs
• Group behavior
• Indeterminate demand curve
Types of oligopoly
1. Pure or perfect oligopoly
3. Collusive oligopoly
4. Non-collusive oligopoly
Non-collusive oligopoly- KINKED DEMAND
CURVE
• Paul Sweezy, 1939
• Price rigidity
• Demand curve has two parts- relatively
elastic and relatively inelastic
• MR curve has two segments, there is
discontinuity
Equilibrium in cartel
PRICE LEADERSHIP
Low cost firm
Dominant firm
• Refers to a type of leadership in which only one organization dominates the entire industry.
• Under dominant price leadership, other organizations in the industry cannot influence prices.
• The dominant organization uses its power of monopoly to maximize its profits and other organizations
have to adjust their output with the set price.
Barometric price leadership
• Usually it is a firm which from past behaviour has established the reputation of a good forecaster of
economic changes
• Barometric price leadership may be established for various reasons:
1. Rivalry between several large firms in an industry may make it impossible to accept one among them as
the leader
2. Followers avoid the continuous recalculation of costs, as economic conditions change
3. The barometric firm usually has proved itself as a ‘reasonably’ good forecaster of changes in cost and
demand conditions in the particular industry and the economy as a whole, and by following it the other
firms can be ‘reasonably’ sure that they choose the correct price policy.
References
• https://www.yourarticlelibrary.com/oligopoly-market/the-oligopoly-market-example-types-and-features-
micro-economics/9140
• https://www.economicsdiscussion.net/wp-content/uploads/2016/01/clip_image002-49.jpg
• https://www.economicsdiscussion.net/oligopoly/cartels-types-joint-profit-maximisation-and-market-shari
ng-cartel/7370
• https://www.economicsdiscussion.net/collusive-oligopoly/price-leadership-with-3-forms-and-diagrams/5
492