Reference Documents: Section 1
Reference Documents: Section 1
1. PGS, TS.Phạm Văn Vận, ThS. Vũ Cương, Kinh tế công cộng, Nxb Thống kê, 2006
2. Joseph Stiglitz, Economics of the public sector, Third Edition, 2000
3. Jean-Jacques Laffont, Fundamentals of Public Economics, MIT Press, 1998
4. Donijo Robbins, Handbook of Public Sector Economics, Marcel Dekker/CRC Press 2004
5. David Schultz, Encyclopedia of Public Administration and Public Policy, Facts On File Inc.; 2004
SECTION 1: INTRODUCTION
2. Methods to Study
a. The Method of Positive Analysis
The positive analysis is about explaining why there is a public sector, how government policies
are chosen, and how these policies affect the economy.
● Analyzing the effect of the corporate tax on inward investment is an example of positive
analysis.
★ INTRODUCTION
● Market failure occurs when freely functioning markets, operating without government
intervention, fail to deliver an efficient or optimal allocation of resources.
● Therefore economic and social welfare may not be maximized.
● This leads to a loss of economic efficiency.
■ 2 agents involving buyers and sellers
P
⇒ initial situation
Normally, there are 2 agents in the market, but in some specific cases (market failure such as imperfect competition,
etc.) ⇒ need a 3rd person.
★ MONOPOLY
1. DEFINITION OF MONOPOLY
● While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
● A firm is considered a monopolist if . . .
○ It is the sole seller of its product.
○ its product does not have close substitutes.
● Monopoly power occurs when the seller of a product can influence prices
○ A single seller is a monopolist
○ There is an oligopoly if there are several sellers
● Monopsony power occurs when the buyer of a product can influence the price
○ A single buyer is a monopsonist
● Other cases: Oligopoly and Oligopsony
2. WHY MONOPOLY?
The fundamental cause of monopoly is barriers to entry.
● The reason a monopoly exists is that other firms find it unprofitable or impossible to enter the
market.
● Barriers to entry are the source of all monopoly power; there are two general types of barriers
to entry:
○ technical barriers
○ legal barriers
No. of market Sole seller, with many buyers Many sellers, with many buyers
participants
★ MONOPOLY’S REVENUE
● Total revenue: TR=P . Q
TR
● Average revenue: AR=P=
Q
ΔTR
● Marginal revenue: MR=
ΔQ
⇒ A monopolist’s marginal revenue is always less than the price of its goods.
○ The demand curve is downward sloping.
○ When a monopoly drops the price to sell one more unit, the revenue received from
previously sold units also decreases.
★ MONOPOLY’S PROFIT
★ Regulation of Monopoly
■ The natural policy is to encourage competition.
■ This can be done directly by enforcing the division of monopolists…
For example, US antitrust legislation applied to Standard Oil (1911) and Bell System (1984) ⇒
division into separate competing firms.
■ … or by reducing barriers to entry:
○ Technology barriers can be reduced by an insistence on knowledge sharing.
For example, the US insists Microsoft provides information.
○ Legal barriers can be removed by changing the law.
But why were they imposed in the first place?
○ Patents are also a barrier to entry
● Optimum length trades reward for innovation against stifling competition.
○ Advertising and excess capacity can be part of an entry deterrence strategy.
● Advertising expenditure can be limited (e.g. tobacco).
● Providing excess capacity is held to deter entry is difficult.
P
D
AT AT ⇒ P = MC
C C
Regulate M
d Price Loss C
O Q0 Q
Usually, the government asks monopolists to produce at a specific price around the AC so they could
maintain the production while DWL is kept as low as possible.
In theory, P = AC is called the 2nd best price.
→ In the long run, normally, firms will not be able to continue to produce → Gov has to intervene.
⇒ When P is set at MC, firms may close the production soon → Gov should subsidize the firms with the
tax/subvention to monopolists.
○ For the Buyer: CS ↑
○ For the society: SW is maximized at Q0
⇒ The government prefers P = AC (the 2nd best price) as they do not need to further intervene.
○ Price discrimination
○ In case of no GI, monopolists wish to maximize their revenue & clear the store. Normally, the firm
will actively apply the two first types of price discrimination.
○ The firm has no incentive to apply the 3rd price discrimination because π is lower (as for the poor, P
< Pm) → loss of profit ⇒ Gov will intervene.
○ But there is an indirect effect:
Poor people consume with lower P but no real necessities (?)
→ they sell the product to the rich
→ both benefit while the firm suffers from a loss.
■ Two-part price
○ Without GI, P = Pm
○ P: ● Fixed part price ~ fixed value
● Variable part price ~ MC ~ suffer loss
Suppose that the regulatory commission allows the
P monopoly to charge a price P1 to some users while
offering the lower price of P2 to other users.
D
The profits on the sales to high-price customers are
enough to cover the losses on the sales to low-price
customers.
Exercise 1: A Monopolist has a total cost function C(q) = 1000 + 5Q and a demand function
P = 200 - 5Q, where P is price and Q is output. Use this information to calculate
a. The profit-maximizing price and the quantity
b. Maximized profit of the monopolist
c. If with GI, the monopolist must set the price at MC ⇒ profit of firm and welfare of the society
d. DWL and loss in CS under monopoly relative to the case of best welfare outcome.
A Monopsonist is
(1) A single seller with many buyers
(2) A single buyer with many sellers
(3) Several buyers with many sellers
(4) Several sellers with many buyers
Monopolies
(1) Will set a higher price and a higher level of output than would be set under competition
(2) Will set a higher price and a lower level of output than would be set under perfect
competition
(3) Will set a lower price and a lower level of output than would be set under perfect competition
(4) Will set a lower price and a higher level of output than would be set under perfect competition
When there is price discrimination, the monopoly will get the maximum profit
(1) False
(2) True
CHAPTER 2: EXTERNALITIES
Ngoại ứng
★ INTRODUCTION
Externalities arise whenever the actions of one party make another party worse or better off, yet the
first party neither bears the costs nor receives the benefits of doing so.
⤷ represents a market failure for which government action could be appropriate and improve
welfare.
⇒ How many types? 4
● In production: negative / positive
● In consumption: negative / positive
★ EXTERNALITY THEORY
a. NEGATIVE PRODUCTION EXTERNALITIES
● To understand the case of negative production externalities, consider the following example:
○ A profit-maximizing steel firm, as a by-product of its production, dumps sludge into a river.
○ The fishermen downstream are harmed by this activity, as the fish die and their profits fall.
● This is a negative production externality because:
○ Fishermen downstream are adversely affected.
○ And they are compensated for this harm.
⤷ Why? Because the river is a common resource, and fishermen cannot ask for
compensation. ⇒ TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS
○ The SMC is the sum of PMC and MD, representing the cost to society.
○ The socially optimal level of production is at Q2, the intersection of SMC and SMB.
○ The (created by the gap between the SMC and SMB) is the maximum SW.
○ The triangle is the DWL from the private production level (at Q1).
[2nd question - HOW?] The common direction is to lower DWL. (using Pigou tax to reduce Q and raise
P).
⇒ The tax will be imposed by the government on the producer, with the unit tax = MD. The new PMC
shall then move towards the SMC. (as SMC = PMC + MD = PMC + tax)
⇒ Q2 - optimal quantity will then be achieved by Pigouvian tax.
DWL S = PMC
P2
P1 △SW = △(CS + PS)
MD (MEC)
D = PMB
Q2 Q1 = SMB
△damage Qsteel
○ From the society’s viewpoint (SMB), every benefit from the consumption of cigarettes is deducted by the
value of MD (the damage of the 3rd person).
⇒ SMB is, therefore, on the left side of PMB.
⇒ In the case of positive consumption externalities, SMB is higher and on the right of PMB.
○ MC ∩ SMB=Q 2 → social/optimal quantity
⇒ At Q2, the SW is maximized.
○ When Q > Q2 ⇔ SMC > SMB, resulting in the DWL of the society.
[2nd question - HOW?] ⇒ The POLICY that should be applied is tax (unit tax = MD).
→ this tax must be paid by the CONSUMERS.
⇒ resulting in consumers having a lower willingness to pay ⇒ demand curve moving to the left (towards
SMB)
⇒ Q2 is achieved.
○ In the case of negative externalities in consumption, Gov must intervene and change the behavior of
consumers (not producers) by applying a tax on the consumers.
○ In the case of positive externalities in consumption, there is MEB and SMB = PMB + MEB. The market
quantity is then lower than the optimum quantity.
→ the government should apply subvention to the consumer so that the demand curve moves to SMB and
that Q optimum is achieved.
… in on
production producers
NEGATI
TAX
VE
… in on
SUMMARY of consumption consumers
EXTERNALI
TIES … in on
production producers
POSITIV SUBVENTI
E ON
… in on
consumption consumers
Hypothesis ■ The Coase Theorem: when there are well-defined property rights and costless
bargaining, then negotiations between the parties will bring about the socially
efficient level.
⇒ The author of this theorem is an economist conducting research on negative externalities
in production → found out all major reasons leading to the problem of Tragedy of the
Commons / common resources.
Conclusion ■ Thus, the role of government intervention may be very limited - that of simply
enforcing property rights.
■ Consider the Coase Theorem in the context of the negative production externality
example from before.
⇒ The fishermen are given property rights over the amount of steel produced.
○ According to the hypothesis:
(1) The river is no longer the common resource but is now a private asset (either the company or the
fishermen could own)
(2) Costless bargaining: The negotiation between who causes the externality and who suffers from
the damage will not result in any considerable cost.
⇒ bring about a socially efficient level ⇒ optimum quantity achieved.
○ When the fishermen become the owner of the river, the favorable Q to be produced is 0 so that no
more sludge is emitted. ⇒ no production since initial Q = 0.
(*) The negotiation shall also end at Q = Q2 even if the river is owned by the firm.
[?] If the river is owned by the firm, what could be the initial quantity decided to be produced?
→ Q1. At Q1, the PS is maximized but the damage (Q1*MD) is high enough so that the fishermen have the
incentives to ask for a reduction in production (a lower Q).
■ Through a process of bargaining, the steel firm will bribe <~give sb money to persuade them> the fishery to
arrive at Q2, the socially optimal level.
■ After that point, the MD exceeds (PMB - PMC), so the steel firm cannot come up with a large enough
compensation to further expand production.
■ Another implication of the Coase Theorem is that the efficient solution does not depend on which
party is assigned with the property rights, as long as someone is assigned.
■ The direction in which the bribes go does depend on the assignment, however.
⇒ IN SUMMARY: The Coase Theorem is provocative, but perhaps not terribly relevant to many of the most
pressing environmental problems.
⇒ not applicable in reality.
Exercise 1: Suppose that there is a market of steel with Q S = 10P - 270, QD = -2P + 150 (Q: tons; P:
million VND/ton)
The production of steel creates an external cost to the citizens, which is represented by MD curve: P = 3
a. Calculate the efficient quantity for the market and the efficient quantity for the society.
b. Calculate the DWL when there is no government intervention?
c. When the efficient social quantity is achieved, count the loss in CS and the loss in PS?
d. If the government decides to tax the production of steel, how much money could the government
receive?
Reply to the same questions with MD = 0.1Q
With MD = 3
1
Psteel ○ S = PMC: P= Q +27
SMC = PMC + 10 S
75
SW max MD
−1
○ D: P= Q +75
SW S= 2 D
loss PMC
1
P2 = 37.5 ○ SMC: P= Q +30
P1 = 35 10 S
a. The efficient quantity for the market is
30 D= the quantity at which PMC = PMB.
PMB 1 −1
27 Q 1 +27= Q +75 ⇒ Q 1=80
= SMB ⇒
3 MD 10 2 1
(MEC) The efficient quantity for the society is
Q2 = Q1 = 80 Qsteel the quantity at which SMC = SMB.
75
1 −1
⇒ Q 2 +30= Q +75 ⇒ Q2=75
10 2 2
c. CS at market’s efficient quantity Q 1=80 is:
b. When there is no government
1 intervention, the produced quantity is
CSQ = (75−35) 80=1600
2
1
Q 1=80 ; deadweight loss is the area of
the triangle generated by SMC and SMB,
from Q2 to Q1:
1
DWL= (Q 1 −Q 2) MD=7.5
2
1
CS at socially efficient quantity Q 2=75 is: CS Q2 = (75−37.5)75=1406.25
2
⇒ Loss in CS: ΔCS=−193.75
1
PS at market’s efficient quantity Q 1=80 is: PSQ = (35−27)80=320
2 1
1
PS at socially efficient quantity Q 2=75 is: PSQ = (37.5−30) 75=281.25
2
2
⇒ Loss in PS: Δ PS=−38.75
d. If the government decides to tax the production of steel, the unit tax shall be: t=MDQ❑
Exercise 2: There is some information concerning a market of tobacco (suppose that it is a case of a
negative externality in consumption):
PS = 160 + 4Q; PD = 230 - 3Q; MD = 1.5Q
a. Count the social optimal quantity and the private optimal quantity.
b. Calculate the DWL when producing at the private quantity
c. If the government uses tax to regulate this negative externality, how much tax could be collected?
d. Show your results in a graph of illustration.
CHAPTER 3: PUBLIC GOOD
Yes No
SW Q )¿
$3
Dtotal = SMB Q R is determined by the customer’s decision.
$2 Analyzing individual’s consumption behavior:
<graph below>
DJerry
$1
● DTom ∩ SMC=QTom
DTom
→ The trapezoid made up of SMB and SMC (from 0 to
O
1 5 Qfireworks QT ) is the social welfare at Q T .
→ The triangle made up of SMB and SMC (from QT
Pfireworks
onward) is the deadweight loss at Q T .
SWQTom
● DJerry ∩SMC =QJerry
→ The trapezoid made up of SMB and SMC (from 0 to
Q J ) is the social welfare at Q J .
S=
DWLQT SMC QJ
om
→ The triangle made up of SMB and SMC (from
onward) is the deadweight loss at Q J .
○ The government prefers to subsidize the individual with a higher demand curve because the marginal
subsidy is lower.
→ CRITICISM: unrealistic because in fact, there are millions of consumers but limited capacity of provision by
the private sector.
○ Tax price: the amount of money that the consumers pay to the government to satisfy their needs.
⇒ Between subsidy and tax price, the government should apply tax price.
⤷ The effect of the tax price mechanism is that everyone is happy (always receiving surplus).
→ unit tax price = PMB at Q*
○ Provided by the government means the government organizes the consumption (by the public sectors)
→ The government determines the supply and the aggregate demand (Q*)
As per the graph above, Σtax price per unit=1+ 2=3 ⇒ Σtax price=3.Q =15
¿
⇒ Ban đầu, G cũng phải trả chi phí cung cấp hàng hóa nhưng được bù đắp bởi tax paid by consumers.
⤷ I am the free-rider
★ When is private provision likely to overcome the Free Rider Problem?
○ While the free-rider problem clearly exists, there are also examples where the private market
is able to overcome this problem to some extent, but the private market may still fall short of
the socially optimal amount.
○ Examples of private provision of public goods.
● Privately financed fireworks displays
● Privately owned British lighthouse until 1842.
○ Under what circumstances are private market forces likely to solve the free-rider problem?
● Intense preferences <some individuals care more than others>
● Altruism <many caring about the needs or outcomes of others & willing to help them>
● Utility from one’s own contribution to the public goods.
¿
⇒ the Q R ≪¿ Q under private provision → always needs GI.
■ In some cases, the private market may already be providing a socially inefficient level of the
private good.
→ Public provision may crowd-out some of the private provision - as the government provides
more of the public goods, the private sector provides less.
■ For example, in the fireworks example with Tom and Jerry, if one assumes:
○ Tom and Jerry care only about the total number of fireworks provided.
○ Government provision will be financed by charging equal amounts to each of them.
○ And the government provides no more fireworks than were being provided privately
beforehand.
→ Each dollar of the public provision will crowd out private provision one-for-one.
■ The full crowd-out in the fireworks example is rare, though partial crowd-out is much more
common and can occur when:
○ People who don’t contribute to the public good are taxed to finance its provision.
○ Or when individuals derive utility from their individual contribution as well as the
total amount of the public good provided.
■ If noncontributors are forced to pay for the good (but it is still below the social optimum),
then the contributors’ effective income levels are higher than before.
■ As a result of this income effect, contributors buy more if the public good is a normal good,
offsetting the crowd-out to some extent.
■ Alternatively, as discussed previously, there may not be a full crowd-out if an individual
cares about his own contribution (the warm glow model).
■ In this case, an increase in government contributions will not fully crowd out giving.
■ Another problem for government provision is the measuring of costs and benefits of public
goods.
■ For example, improving a highway involves valuations of commuting time saved as well as
reduced traffic facilities.
■ Finally, our model of optimal public good provision assumes that the government knows each
person’s preferences over public & private goods.
Tax ⇒ State’s budget spending ~ which is considered by politicians (representants)
⤷ Public good/services (education, national defense, medical, transportation)
■ In reality, this runs into problems with preference revelation, preference knowledge, and
preference aggregation.
⤷ There is no model in reality; politicians consider building plans on spending budget <~dự thảo
ngân sách> annually. (one for each ministry)
⇒ The National Assembly approves these plans at meetings where ministers would present and
convince others to vote.
⤷ In fact, there are millions of people and problems (such as the free-rider problem or the problem
arising when somebody hides their preferences to avoid the tax price).
⇒ hard to aggregate social preferences
⇒ hard to build an exact model.
EXERCIS Suppose there are 2 individuals in the market of a pure public good with 2 private DCs:
E P1 = 10 - 0.1 Q P2 = 20 - o.1 Q
a. If SMC1 = 15, calculate the socially efficient quantity and maximum SW.
b. If SMC2 = 30, calculate the socially efficient quantity and maximum SW.
c. Suppose the good is provided by the private sector (by either the 1st or the 2nd person), calculate
the real quantities (supposing that SMC = 15).
d. In your opinion, how should the government intervene in this situation? → tax price = ?
e. In your opinion, should the individuals show honestly their real willingness to pay? Explain your
answer.
1
Social welfare: SW = 15.75=562.5
2
b. If SMC = 30, both socially efficient quantity and social welfare equal 0.
c. SMC = 15 ⇒ real quantity: 20−0.1Q 2 =15 ⇔ Q R =Q 2=50
d. The first way of intervention is subsidizing the individual with a higher demand curve in order to lessen the
cost of subvention.
⇒ The subsidy will result in the demand curve of the
P second person shifting upward and to the right until
30 Dt = SMB 1st and 2nd person’s the intersection of D2 and SMC generates a quantity
willingness to pay at Qt of Q2 = Qt.
⇒ The unit subsidy is the gap between D2 and D2’:
22.5 D’2 SW s=22.5−20=2.5
20 The second way of intervention is imposing tax
D2 prices. At Qt = 75, the 1st person’s willingness to
S=
15 SMC1
pay is 2.5, while that of the 2nd person is 12.5.
12.5 Summing up these two individuals' willingness to
D1 pay, we have the unit tax price being 15.
10
e. From society’s viewpoint, they should be honest in
revealing their preferences in order to maximize the
SW. However, in reality, people will try to avoid
2.5
doing that so that they can evade taxes.
O Q2 Qt Q1max Q2max Q
→ The government cannot control the behavior of every single one in the economy.
APPENDIX
★ PUBLIC PROVISION & OVERCONSUMPTION
P P
M M
C C
DWL DWL
O Q O Q
Qe Qm Qe Qm
⇒ For some goods, such as water, supplying the ⇒ For other goods, such as certain medical services,
goods freely rather than at MC results in relatively supplying the goods freely rather than at MC
little additional consumption. results in excessive consumption.
(not considering the cost when providing the goods
freely)
● For many goods, the issue is not so much the feasibility (= possibility) of rationing, but the
cost. The costs associated with the exclusion for private goods as well as for public goods are
called transaction costs.
● When transaction costs are sufficiently high, it may be more efficient to supply the goods
publicly than to have the goods supplied by the private market.
⇒ Cost of exclusion is used to exclude those who do not want to pay the cost ⇒ restricting the number of
consumers: Qm (without) < Q0 (with exclusive cost)
P
DISTORTIONS ASSOCIATED WITH THE
UNIFORM PROVISION:
→ When publicly provided private goods are
c D supplied in equal amounts to all individuals,
MC of
W some get more than their sufficient level and
L productio
some get less.
n
★ INTRODUCTION
● Asymmetric Information
○ Asymmetric information exists when either the buyer or the seller in a market exchange
has some information that the other does not have.
○ Information can cause the buyer or seller to lower the demand or supply of the good in
question.
E
E 1
Cost
2
D1 = MPB1
(asymmetric
information)
D2 = MPB2
(symmetric
O
information)
Q Q Quan
Output 2 1 Output tity
with with
symmet asymm
ric etric
informa informa
tion tion
Wage S2 = MPC2
Rate (symmetric
Wage information)
with S1 = MPC1
symme E (asymmetric
tric W 2 information)
inform 2
ation W E
1 1
Wage
with D1 =
asymm MPB
etric O
inform Q Q Quantity of
ation Quantity of 2 1 Quantity ofLabor
labor with labor with
symmetric asymmetric
information information
[?] What is the most a buyer will pay for any car?
Ans:
Let: q be the fraction of peaches,
1 - q be the fraction of lemons.
The expected value to a buyer of any car is at most:
EV = $1200(1 - q) + $2400q
● Suppose EV ≥$2000:
○ Every seller can negotiate a price between $2000 and $EV (no matter if the car is a lemon
or a peach).
○ All sellers gain from being in the market.
● Suppose EV < $2000:
○ A peach seller cannot negotiate a price above $2000 and will exit the market.
○ So all buyers know that the remaining sellers own lemons only.
○ Buyers will pay at most $1200 and only lemons are sold.
➔ Hence “too many” lemons “crowd out” the peaches from the market.
Gains-to-trade are reduced since no peaches are traded.
The presence of the lemons inflicts an external cost on buyers and peach owners.
[?] How many lemons can be in the market without crowding out the peaches?
Ans:
Buyers will pay $2000 for a car only if:
EV = $1200(1 - q) + $2400q ≥$2000
2
➔ q≥
3
So if over one-third of all cars are lemons, then only lemons are traded.
● A market equilibrium in which both types of cars are traded and cannot be distinguished by the
buyers is a pooling equilibrium.
● A market equilibrium in which only one of the two types of cars is traded, or both are traded but
can be distinguished by the buyers, is a separating equilibrium.
[?] What if there are more than two types of cars? Suppose that:
● car quality is uniformly distributed between $1000 and $2000
● any car that a seller values at $x is valued by a buyer at $(x+300).
Which cars will be traded?
Ans:
● The expected value of any car to a buyer is $1500 + $300 = $1800.
b. SIGNALING
● Adverse selection is an outcome of an informational deficiency.
● What if information can be improved by high-quality sellers signaling credibly that they are high-
quality?
● E.g. warranties, professional credentials, references from previous clients, etc.
Example of Signaling:
● A labor market has two types of workers; high-ability and low-ability.
● A high-ability worker’s marginal product is a H .
A low-ability worker’s marginal product is a L.
a L< a H
● h is the fraction of high-ability workers.
1 - h is the fraction of low-ability workers.
● Each worker is paid his expected marginal product.
● If firms knew each worker’s type they would
○ pay each high-ability worker w H =a H
○ pay each low-ability worker w L =a L
● .If firms cannot tell workers’ types then every worker is paid the (pooling) wage rate; i.e. the
expected marginal product w P =(1−h)a L + h a H .
● w P =(1−h)a L + h a H < aH : the wage rate paid when the firm knows a worker really is high-
ability.
● So high-ability workers have an incentive to find a credible signal.
● Workers can acquire “education”.
● Education costs a high-ability worker c H per unit
costs a low-ability worker c L per unit
c L >c H
● Suppose that education has no effect on workers’ productivity; i.e., the cost of education is a
deadweight loss.
● High-ability workers will acquire education units if
w H −w L =a H −a L > c H e H (i)
and w H −w L =a H −a L < c L e H (ii)
○ (i) says acquiring e H units of education benefits high-ability workers.
○ (ii) says acquiring e H units of education hurts low-ability workers.
● a H −aL >c H e H and a H −aL <c L e H together require
a H −a L a −a
<e H < H L
cL cH
● Acquiring such an education level credibly signals high-ability, allowing high-ability workers to
separate themselves from low-ability workers.
[?] Given that high-ability workers acquire e H units of education, how much education should low-ability
workers acquire?
Ans:
Zero. Low-ability workers will be paid w L =a Lso long as they do not have e H units of education
and they are still worse off if they do.
➔ Signaling can improve information in the market. But, total output did not change and education
was costly so signaling worsened the market’s efficiency.
➔ So improved information need not improve gains-to-trade.
c. MORAL HAZARD
● Asymmetric information can also exist after a transaction has been made. If it does, it can cause
a moral hazard problem.
● Moral Hazard occurs when one party to a transaction changes his behavior in a way that is hidden
from and costly to the other party.
e.g: If you have full car insurance are you more likely to leave your car unlocked?
● Moral hazard is a reaction to incentives to increase the risk of a loss and is a consequence of
asymmetric information.
● If an insurer knows the exact risk from insuring an individual, then a contract specific to that
person can be written.
● If all people look alike to the insurer, then one contract will be offered to all insurees; high-risk
and low-risk types are then pooled, causing low-risks to subsidize high-risks.
● Examples of efforts to avoid a moral hazard by using signals are:
○ higher life and medical insurance premiums for smokers or heavy drinkers of alcohol
○ lower car insurance premiums for contracts with higher deductibles or for drivers with
histories of safe driving.
d. INCENTIVES CONTRACTING
● A worker is hired by a principal to do a task. Only the worker knows the effort she exerts
(asymmetric information).
➔ The effort exerted affects the principal’s payoff.
● The principal’s problem: design an incentives contract that induces the worker to exert the
amount of effort that maximizes the principal’s payoff.
● Horizontal equity implies that we give the same treatment to people in an identical situation.
● Vertical equity implies that people with higher incomes should pay more tax. Vertical equity is
important for redistributing income within society.
CHAPTER 1: INEQUALITY
I. INCOME DISTRIBUTION
● There’s no simple relation between poverty/inequality and per capita income.
○ Inequality (high or low) seems to be very persistent, but it typically changes (up or
down) when output per capita changes.
○ There might be a complicated relation, involving the interaction of many factors.
● Inequality is probably determined by
○ history
○ social cleavages,
○ politics and government policies
● Careful statistical/econometric analysis is necessary to identify the effect of each factor.
II. INEQUALITY
1. Measuring Inequality
● size distributions
○ How much income does household X earn?
○ Sort people according to income and put them in major groups.
○ Ignore differences in the source of income (heritage or capabilities, for example)
○ A quartile is a fourth (25%) of the population;
a decile is a tenth (10%);
a quintile is a fifth (20%).
○ The Kuznets ratio: the ratio of the share of income of the highest x% divided by the
share of income of the lowest y%.
● Lorenz curves
○ Arrange the population according to the share of income they receive, from lowest to
highest (and put them in major groups).
○ Calculate cumulative percentages.
○ Plot the cumulative percentage of households against the cumulative percentage of the
income they earn.
○ The greater the Curvature of the Lorenz Line, the greater the Relative Degree of
Inequality
○ Four Possible Lorenz Curves
2. Causes of Inequality
a. Human Capital
● Demand for High-skilled and Low-skilled
Wage rate
labor
(dollars/hour)
○ High-skilled labor has a higher VMP
(value of the marginal product) than low-
skilled labor and greater demand.
VMP of ○ The demand curve for high-skilled labor,
skill D H , lies above the demand curve for
low-skilled labor, D L, by the VMP of
D skill.
H
D
0 L
Labor (thousands of
hours/day) and low-
Demand for high-skilled
skilled labor
D
H
D
0 L
Labor (thousands of
hours/day) and low-
Markets for high-skilled
skilled labor
b. Discrimination
● Human capital differences explain much of the income inequality that exists.
● Economists are not sure whether (and disagree about) discrimination adds to income inequality.
● One line of argument is that competition prevents discrimination. But race and sex income
differences do persist.
● Poverty is
○ Lack of income;
○ Lack of drinking water;
○ Lack of access to health care;
○ Lack of protection against adverse shocks.
∑ ❑(Y p−Y i )
NPG= i=1
NY p
● Foster-Greer-Thorbecke Measure
○ Is a very general form of poverty measure that satisfies
■ anonymity (no person is worth more than another),
■ population independence (a larger population doesn’t change it, ceteris paribus),
■ monotonicity (making a person richer won’t decrease the index) and
■ distributional sensitivity (taking income away from a poor person makes the
poverty index worse).
H α
1 Y −Y i
Pα = ∑ ❑ p
N i=1 Yp( )
○ If α=2, you get a measure that is extremely sensitive to the depth and severity of
poverty.
● Is “$1 a day” too low?
● Is “$2 a day” too low?
○ Lots of people live between “$1 a day” and “$2 a day”, and although there are fewer
people below “$1 a day”, the proportion of people living under “$2 a day” hasn’t fallen
much.
● How about “$15 a day” as the standard to say that someone is poor?
○ If “$15 a day” makes you poor in the US, why should you be non-poor if you make “$10
a day” in Zambia?
● How about using income rather than consumption, and national accounts rather than surveys?
○ The number of poor people seems to be much fewer.
b. Description
● Lost of A: abcd
M M ● Gain of B: abef
U e U ● Gain of Social welfare: cdef
B ● g: max of social welfare, revenue i = h
A f ● Conclusion: at which point there is perfect
g equality?
d
c
O O
h b a ’
Reve Reve
nue A nue B
c. Some problems
● The 1st hypothesis: if people have different MU functions?
● The 2nd hypothesis: the law of diminishing MU is true with the goods, but how about the revenue?
● The 3rd hypothesis: all programs of redistribution need at least the administrative cost ⇒ loss of
total revenue
2. Theory of Egalitarianism
● The function of social welfare W = U1 = U2 = Ui =…= Un
● Some problems
○ Perfect equality
○ But what happens if people have different MU functions?
○ Not easy to implement in the real-life
3. Rawls Theory
● Social welfare depends only on the benefit
B of the poorest.
( ⇒ max social welfare = max
U utility of the poorest.
W
B) E ● The function of Social welfare W =
*
U min{U1, U2,…, Un}
2
W
O 1
U A
Redistribution (
1
according to Rawls’U
theory ) A
INTRODUCTION
● In the real world, it is not always easy for the government to maximize welfare.
● Politicians have considerations other than getting to the socially efficient level or conducting
cost-benefit analyses in order to approve a project. Instead, such economic decisions are made in
the context of a political system.
● This lesson focuses on the fourth question of public finance: Why do governments do what they
do?
● We start by discussing the “best-case scenario” in which the government appropriately measures
and aggregates the preferences of its citizens in deciding what projects to undertake.
● Then we examine both direct democracy and representative democracy.
● Finally, we examine government failure, the inability (or unwillingness) of government to
appropriately address market failures.
a. LINDAHL PRICING
● Lindahl pricing is a system where individuals report their willingness to pay for each quantity of
the public good, and the government aggregates preferences to form a measure of the social
benefit.
● To illustrate Lindahl’s procedure, imagine that the public good in question is fireworks for two
people (Ava and Jack).
● First, the government announces tax prices for the public good, that is, the share of the cost that
each individual must bear.
● When a tax price is arrived at where both individuals want the same amount of the public good,
the government has reached Lindahl equilibrium.
● The government produces the public good at that level and finances it by charging each person
their tax price.
● Each person announces how much of the public good he or she wants at those tax prices.
● If the individual announcements differ, the government raises the tax price for the person who
wants more of the good and lowers it for the person who wants less.
★ MAJORITY VOTING
a. WHEN IT WORKS
● The Lindahl pricing scheme had a very high standard for coming to a consensus: only when
citizens were unanimously in agreement did the government achieve Lindahl equilibrium.
● A common mechanism used to aggregate individual votes into a social decision is majority
voting, in which individual policy options are put to a vote, and the option that receives the
majority of votes is chosen.
● Majority voting does not always provide a consistent means of aggregating preferences.
● To be consistent, an aggregation mechanism must satisfy three goals:
○ Dominance: If one choice is preferred by all voters, then the aggregation mechanism
must be such that this choice is made by society.
○ Transitivity: Choices must satisfy this mathematical property.
○ Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives: The introduction of a third choice does not
change the ranking of the first two choices.
● It turns out that with these three conditions, majority voting can only produce a consistent
aggregation of individual preferences if preferences are restricted to take a certain form.
Type of voters
● A town is deciding on education taxes (and spending). There are 3 possibilities: high, medium,
and low spending. There are also 3 groups, represented in equal proportions.
● Consider pairwise voting:
○ High vs Low: Parents vote for H, Elderly and Young Couples vote for L.
⇒ L wins,
○ High vs Medium: Parents vote for H, Elderly and Young Couple vote for M.
⇒ M wins.
○ Medium vs Low: Parents and Young Couples vote for M, Elderly vote for L.
⇒ M wins.
➔ Since M has beaten both H and L, M is the overall winner in this case.
Type of voters
School
School 0
0 L M H
L M H
spendi
spendi
The utility of private parents ng
Elders are Young Parents ng goes in either direction from
single- marrieds are are single- M.
peaked at single-peaked peaked at
“L”. at “M”. “H”.
● The failure of these preferences for the “private parents” in this second case is what leads to the
inability of majority voting to consistently aggregate preferences.
● Fortunately, single-peakedness is a reasonable assumption in most cases
Exercise 1: Suppose that there are 5 voters with preference rankings for 4 projects (A, B, C, D) as
follows:
1 2 3 4 5
First B A C A D
Second C D B C B
Third D C D B C
Fourth A B A D A
★ LOGROLLING
● Logrolling or voting trader: a mechanism by which voters can buy, sell or exchange the bill
saying “yes” from other voters.
● Objectives: To be the winner in majority voting.
a. INCREASE SW
(*) X can buy votes from Y with the minimum price of 50 and the maximum price of 55 <~vì
nếu trên 55 thì X sẽ mua của Z>.
b. DECREASE SW
X Y Z
(a) Defense
spending
0 J1 25 G 50
% Voters for John % Voters for George 1 %
(b Defense
) J2 25 G 50 spending
0
% Voters for John % Voters for George 1 %
(c) Defense
J2 25 G 50 spending
0
% Voters for John % 2Voters for George %
(d Defense
) spending
0 J3 = G3 = 50
% 25% %
● John is trying to appeal to those who don’t want much defense, so he places himself at J 1 while
George chooses a much higher level of defense G 1. In this case (a), the candidates split the vote
equally.
● But now imagine that John changes his position to J2. By doing so he gets the majority of the
votes (case (b)).
● In response, George lowers his position to G2. By doing so, George now gets a majority of the
votes (case (c)).
● This process will continue until the median voter’s preferences are arrived at (case (d)).
● The median voter model is a powerful tool but relies on a number of assumptions worth
mentioning:
○ Single-dimensional voting: Voters only care about one issue.
○ Only two candidates: With a 3rd candidate, there is no stable equilibrium.
○ No ideology or influence: Assumes politicians only care about votes, not ideological
positions.
○ No selective voting: All citizens actually vote.
○ No money as a tool of influence
○ Perfect information along three dimensions: voter knowledge of the issues, politician
knowledge of the issues, and politician knowledge of voter preferences.
★ Lobbying
● The issues of money and information make it likely that elected officials will be lobbied by
highly interested and informed subgroups.
● Lobbying is the expansion of resources by certain individuals or groups in an attempt to influence
a politician.
● Lobbyists can:
○ Inform politicians
○ Reward politicians
● The problem with lobbying arises when an issue benefits a small group and imposes small costs
on a larger (perhaps even a majority) group.
○ In this case, politicians might support socially inefficient positions.
● The key point to remember is that large groups of people with a small individual interest in an
issue suffer from a free-rider problem in trying to organize politically.
● Small groups with large interests overcome the free-rider problem.
● On average, the
predicted share of
the vote for the
incumbent party
is within 2.6
percentage points
of the actual vote
received.
● It has done a
pretty good job at
predicting
winners in
presidential
elections.
● The fact that voters respond to economic conditions close to the Presidential election has led
some to posit the existence of a political business cycle, where politicians attempt to manipulate
economic conditions.
● Although the actual business cycle may or may not exist, it is clear that incumbents do use
government powers of taxation and spending to try to win voter favor.
★ Size-Maximizing Bureaucracy
● Niskanen (1971) developed a model of the budget maximizing bureaucrat. In this model, the
bureaucrat runs an agency that has a monopoly on the government provision of some good or
service.
● Bureaucrat’s salary is typically unrelated to efficiency. His compensation consists of salary, but
also perks like the size of his office and support staff.
● The larger government tries to rein in the bureaucrats.
● A key question is then whether goods and services are more efficiently provided by the public or
private sector.
○ For most goods and services, it is abundantly clear that private provision is more
efficient.
○ In a review of the literature, Mueller (2003) finds that only 5 of 71 studies found state-
owned companies outperformed their private counterparts.
● For some goods, such as social services, public provision may be superior, especially when there
is a market failure.
○ Hart, Shliefer, and Vishny (1997) compared public and private prisons. Private prisons
were 10% cheaper, through lower wages to guards. The low pay led to more violence,
however.
★ Leviathan Theory
● Leviathan theory sees individual bureaucrats and the larger government as one monopolist that
simply tries to maximize the size of the public sector.
● This view would help explain rules that explicitly tie the government’s hands in terms of taxes
and spending.
★ Corruption
● Finally, corruption is where government officials abuse their power in order to maximize their
own personal wealth or that of their associates.
● Application: Government Corruption
○ Former Illinois governor George Ryan was indicted in December 2003 for selling state
contracts to his friends in exchange for cash, gifts, loans, and trips for his family. The
case is still pending.
○ This was uncovered as part of “Operation Safe Road,” which investigated bribes that
many truck drivers had given to officials at then Secretary of State Ryan’s office to
obtain a driver’s license. At least 20 people had died in accidents involving drivers who
had bribed officials for their licenses.
○ The investigation resulted in 70 indictments and over 60 convictions of many people who
were close friends and allies of the former governor.