The Economics of Housing Bubbles

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 39

The Economics of Housing Bubbles

By Mark Thornton1

In America’s Housing Crisis:


A Case of Government Failure

Edited by Benjamin Powell and Randall Holcombe

Dr. Mark Thornton


Senior Fellow
Ludwig von Mises Institute
518 West Magnolia Avenue
Auburn, AL 36832-4528
334-321-2146; fax 2119
[email protected]

* Comments are welcomed. Please do not quote without permission. *

1
The author would like to thank Robert Blumen, Kevin Duffy, Robert Ekelund, Mike Pollaro, Jeff Scot,
Jeffrey Tucker, Doug Wakefield, Paul Wicks and the editors of the book for their commentary and
assistance. All error remains my responsibility.
The Economics of Housing Bubbles

Nothing better illustrates government failure and the housing crisis than the housing

bubble. Government policies make homes increasingly expensive and beyond the

economic reach of first-time home buyers. Then as interest rates rise and housing prices

fall, many home buyers find themselves with bad investments that they can no longer

afford. What started as a government effort to improve the prospects for home ownership

through a policy of “easy money” ends up having unintended consequences that will

leave many Americans economically scarred for the rest of their lives.2

When an economic bubble pops many people suffer economic harm. In the case

of a housing bubble, this includes home owners, particularly new home owners who buy

homes during the peak phase of the housing bubble. However, the harm also spreads to

labor because of unemployment, and creates a loss of value to owners of capital,

particularly in housing-related industries. At the individual level many people are forced

into bankruptcy. On the macroeconomic level the bursting of the housing bubble can send

the overall economy into recession or depression. Housing bubbles concentrate their

impact in the home building, materials and furnishings, real estate sales, and mortgage

businesses.

On top of all that, people suffer psychological consequences as well. Before the

bubble bursts, the people most involved in the bubble are confident, jubilant, and self-

assured by their apparently successful decision making. When the bubble bursts they lose
2
An easy money policy involves the central bank—the Fed—setting low interest rates and expanding the
money supply so that it is easier to get credit (i.e. loans) and it also involves government-sponsored credit
organizations like Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac who make getting home mortgages easier.

1
confidence, go into despair and lose confidence in their decision making. In fact, they

lose confidence in the “system,” which means they lose confidence in capitalism and

become susceptible to new political “reforms” that offer structure and security in

exchange for some of their autonomy and freedoms.

In this manner, great nations of people have given away their liberties in exchange

for security. The Russians submitted to Communism and the Germans submitted to

National Socialism because of economic chaos. In 20th century America, economic

crises—and fear more generally—provided the justification for the adoption of “reforms”

such as a central bank (i.e. the Federal Reserve, or “Fed”), the New Deal, the Cold War,

and even fiat money during the economic crisis of the early 1970s.3 Fear of terrorism

after 9/11 resulted in a massive transfer of power to government at the expense of

individual liberty.4 Submission of liberty and individual autonomy in exchange for

security and the “greater good” is now often referred to as choosing the dark side.5

The reason economic crises create fear and submission of liberty is that people do

not generally understand what caused the bust or economic crisis and generally do not

even know that there was a bubble in the first place. In fact, as the bubble is bursting

many people will deny that there is a problem and believe that the whole situation will

quickly return to what they consider normal. The average citizen thinks very little about

what makes the economy work, but simply accepts the system for what it is, and tries to

make the most of it.

3
Higgs (1987) shows how crisis (such as war or depression) lead to large increases in the size of
government that were only partially offset by cutbacks after the crisis was over. On the final page of the
book Higgs correctly predicted that future crises would include terrorism in addition to war and depression.
4
Higgs (2005, p. 4) correctly predicted (in the days immediately after 9/11) that among other things that
government would greatly expand its power “particularly surveillance of ordinary citizens.”
5
A crisis is a crossroad or turning point where the decision maker can make the correct or incorrect choice
with the wrong, fear driven choice being the “dark side.” See Thornton (2005b).

2
The purpose of this chapter is to show how the “system” works, why it generates

bubbles, why they eventually burst, and the macroeconomic effects of bubbles. Here we

apply the economic understanding of bubbles derived from the Austrian business cycle

theory (ABC theory)6 to the current case of the housing bubble and show that this aspect

of the housing crisis is the result of government failure—the inevitable failure of a

government bureaucracy (i.e. the Fed) to manage the money supply and interest rates in

an economically rational manner.7 However, the same reasoning can be applied to

historical bubbles, from the Tulip mania in 17th century Holland (see French 2006) to the

dot.com tech bubble of the late 1990s (see Callahan and Garrison 2003), and to future

bubbles.

What Causes Housing Bubbles?

There are three basic views of bubbles that are held by economists and the general public.

The dominant view among the general public and modern mainstream economists,

including the Chicago school and proponents of Supply-Side economics, is to deny the

existence of bubbles and to declare that what is thought to be “bubbles” is really the

result of “real” factors. The second view, which is espoused by Keynesians and by

proponents of Behavioral Finance, is that bubbles exist because of psychological factors

6
The Austrian school of economics is based on the writings of Carl Menger. It was members of the
German historical school who coined the term to derisively describe Menger and his students. Ludwig von
Mises and F. A. Hayek developed the Austrian business cycle theory, which rests on the foundation laid by
Richard Cantillon in his 1730 book (See Thornton forthcoming). Interestingly, former Fed chairman Alan
Greenspan attended Ludwig von Mises’s New York seminar and is thought to have been influenced by it,
although as Fed chairman he has distanced himself from the Misesian approach.
7
An important justification for stressing the ABC theory is the success of its practitioners in correctly
predicting previous bubbles. See for example Thornton (2004d).

3
such as those captured by the phrase “irrational exuberance.” The third view is that of the

Austrian school, which sees bubbles as consisting of real and psychological changes

caused by manipulations of monetary policy. This view has the advantages of being

forward looking and identifying an economic cause of bubbles. By identifying an

economic cause it also directs us to policy choices that would prevent future bubbles.

Most people agree with the majority of economists, that there is no such thing as a

housing bubble—housing prices, they say, “never go down.” Supply Siders and Chicago

school economists seem to view the declaration of a bubble as an affront to homo

economicus—rationally economic man—because they view it as an assertion of some

psychological flaw in people that requires government intervention.8 They note that if

there were a rational cause or causes of housing bubbles, or any type of bubble for that

matter, then even if only some people believed it was a bubble, they could profit by

selling homes at inflated prices and deflate the bubble long before it ever became over-

inflated and burst. Furthermore, if housing bubbles had irrational foundations, then

certainly a rational economic man could profit enormously by shedding light on the

erroneous psychological motivations that were causing the bubble.9

Although there is much diversity in this camp, it is well illustrated by two

economists from the Federal Reserve Bank of New York who recently examined

concerns about the existence of a speculative bubble in the U.S. housing market. While

McCarty and Peach (2004, 2) did find that a housing bubble could have a severe impact

8
Homo Economicus is the model of the rational economic person that economists use to build their models
and theories about the economy. This assumption asserts that people are rational and will always attempt to
maximize their utility. This is a source of contention and misunderstanding among economists and between
economists and other social scientists.
9
In the latest restatement of the ABC theory Hülsmann

4
on the economy—if it existed and were to burst—they ultimately concluded that such

fears were unfounded:

Our main conclusion is that the most widely cited evidence of a bubble is
not persuasive because it fails to account for developments in the housing
market over the past decade. In particular, significant declines in nominal
mortgage interest rates and demographic forces have supported housing
demand, home construction, and home values during this period. (2004, 2)

Furthermore they find “no basis for concern” for any severe drop in housing prices. In the

past when the U.S. goes into recession or has experienced periods of high nominal

interest rates, they found that any price declines have been “moderate” and that

significant declines can only happen regionally so that they would not have “devastating

effects on the national economy.”

This is essentially the view of Alan Greenspan (former chairman of the Federal

Reserve Bank, or Fed for short) and Ben Bernanke (current Chairman of the Fed). In

particular, Greenspan was aware of the possibility of a housing bubble, but he offered

many reasons to suggest that it did not exist, and that if one did exist it would not be a

major problem. The Chairman is usually difficult to interpret and at times so

incomprehensible as to be almost misleading that his testimony before Congress has been

labeled “Greenspam” (Thornton 2004b). However, on the topic of the housing bubble he

is clear and direct and worth quoting at length.

The ongoing strength in the housing market has raised concerns about the
possible emergence of a bubble in home prices. However, the analogy
often made to the building and bursting of a stock price bubble is
imperfect. First, unlike in the stock market, sales in the real estate market
incur substantial transactions costs and, when most homes are sold, the
seller must physically move out. Doing so often entails significant
financial and emotional costs and is an obvious impediment to stimulating
a bubble through speculative trading in homes. Thus, while stock market
turnover is more than 100 percent annually, the turnover of home

5
ownership is less than 10 percent annually—scarcely tinder for speculative
conflagration. Second, arbitrage opportunities are much more limited in
housing markets than in securities markets. A home in Portland, Oregon is
not a close substitute for a home in Portland, Maine, and the "national"
housing market is better understood as a collection of small, local housing
markets. Even if a bubble were to develop in a local market, it would not
necessarily have implications for the nation as a whole. (2002)

As the bubble was reaching its peak Greenspan (2005b) did admit that there was some

“apparent froth” in some local housing markets, but overall he found that conditions in

the housing market were “encouraging.” In his first speech after leaving office Greenspan

said that the “extraordinary boom” in the housing market was over, but that there was no

danger and that home prices would not decrease (Bruno 2006). The new Fed chairman,

Ben Bernanke (2006b), has admitted to the possibility of “slower growth in house

prices,” but confidently declared that if this did happen he would just lower interest rates.

Bernanke (2006a) also believes that the mortgage market is more stable than in the past.

Bernanke noted in particular that:

Our examiners tell us that lending standards are generally sound and are
not comparable to the standards that contributed to broad problems in the
banking industry two decades ago. In particular, real estate appraisal
practices have improved. (2006a)

A second view of housing bubbles and bubbles in general is that they exist, but

that they are fundamentally caused by psychological factors. Many people and many

important economists subscribe to this view of bubbles, including Keynesian economists

and proponents of Behavioral Finance, such as Robert Shiller. From this perspective the

business cycle is seen as the ebb and flow of mass consciousness and emotions. Real

factors may play a role, but the important causal factors for deviations in the business

cycle are psychological. Booms develop because people become confident and then

6
overconfident in the economy. Investors likewise are confident and increase their

tolerance for taking risk. Rising profits and asset prices lead to “speculative” behavior

where economic decisions are no longer based on old rules and procedures, but on the

bravery instilled by a “new era.”10 As the investment mania sets in the bubble expands.

Then, for whatever reason, people begin to lose faith and new investments are exposed as

disappointing. Economic reports and statistics turn sour, and stories of scandal begin to

appear in the press.11 Many investors remain determined that this turn of events is only

temporary, but results grow worse, prices continue to fall, and investment projects are

postponed, halted or cancelled. The mood of the market is one of gloom or even doom.

The economy enters a depression.

Representing the Behavioral Finance camp is Professor Robert Shiller of Yale

University, who is the author of Irrational Exuberance, the first edition of which

correctly predicted the stock market bubble; the second edition predicts the housing

bubble, whose “ultimate causes are mostly psychological.” Like the Keynesians to

follow, Shiller (2004) does not deny the existence of real factors; he simply downplays

them in order to emphasize psychological factors. With the case of the housing bubble he

finds three important factors. First, the increased risk and chaos in the world since the

technology bubble and the terrorist attacks of 9/11 have caused a flight of investment into

10
All of our actions involve some speculation about the future. Here “speculative” behavior refers to
actions that involve great risks which are unwarranted based on the normal or known fundamentals of the
economy. For example, betting on a round of golf with your friend involves some speculation and
uncertainty, but past experience provides some guidance to the risks you are taking. Here, betting on a
round of golf with Tiger Woods would be “speculative.”
11
It is a common misconception that corporate scandal is the source of bubbles and that it was companies
like Enron and WorldCom that tricked investors during the late 1990s to bid up the stock markets to such
high levels. It is true that scandal is a common feature of bubbles, but scandal could never account for more
than a small percentage of bubbles and in reality scandal is caused by the same source as the bubble itself—
the existence of cheap and abundant credit which must be allocated to increasingly risky and suspect
investments.

7
quality and safety—your own home. Second, the explosive growth in global

communications has increased the glamour appeal of living in one of the world’s leading

cities such as Paris, London, New York, and San Francisco. The third psychological

factor is “the speculative contagion that underlies any bubble.” Here one higher price

begets another and higher prices in one city lead to higher prices in another city, and the

process of higher prices simply builds on itself. Shiller declared that the first two factors

will remain in effect, but the third factor cannot last forever. Once prices begin to drop

the contagion works in the downward direction and can last for years before the process

is reversed again.

Representing the Keynesian camp is Paul Krugman, who is an economics

professor at Princeton University and a writer for the New York Times. Krugman did not

predict a housing bubble but he did finally realize that we were in one and that it

presented a big problem for the U.S. economy. Commenting on the hectic pace of

housing construction and the “absurd” housing prices Krugman (2005a) drew parallels to

previous investment manias:

In parts of the country there’s a speculative fever among people who


shouldn’t be speculators that seem all too familiar from past bubbles—the
shoeshine boys with stock tips in the 1920’s, the beer-and-pizza joints
showing CNBC, not ESPN, on the TV sets in the 1990s. (2005a)

It is also correct to connect the phenomenon of day traders of technology stocks in the

late 1990s to the house flippers of the recent housing bubble. The real question is: what

causes this irrational behavior? Krugman (2005b) suggested that, with the housing

bubble, the bubble builds on expectations of capital gains.

So when people become willing to spend more on houses, say because of a


fall in mortgage rates, some houses get built, but the prices of existing

8
houses also go up. And if people think prices will continue to rise, they
become willing to spend even more, driving prices still higher, and so
on…prices will keep rising rapidly, generating big capital gains. That’s
pretty much the definition of a bubble. (2005b)

Notice that Krugman places his emphasis on a supposedly unfounded change in taste or

demand—“when people become willing to spend more on houses,” but that the actual

cause of the change in the demand for housing—“say because of a fall in mortgage

rates”—is downplayed, as if anything might have ignited the bubble. The more Krugman

tries to provide an economic rationale for the bubble the more he sounds like the Austrian

economists who dominate the third and final view of the housing bubble.12 In fact,

Krugman (2005a) cites fellow Keynesian Paul McCulley, who did correctly predict the

housing bubble and did so in the manner typical of Austrian economists, where interest

rate cuts lead to higher home prices, a construction boom, and higher consumer spending

all based on increased debt—and he explicitly placed the blame for the bubble on the

Fed. The problem for Keynesians like Krugman and McCulley is that their cures—

discretionary monetary and fiscal policy—usually make matters worse (See Gallaway

and Vedder 2000). Even if they could be made to work perfectly it would create a

conundrum for Keynesian economists because a highly stabilized economy desensitizes

investors to risk and makes them “irrationally exuberant” and thus creates the prerequisite

for bubbles. Even Alan Greenspan (2005a) has warned, in his own convoluted way, that

“history has not dealt kindly with the aftermath of protracted periods of low risk

premiums.”

12
Another possible example of this is Baker and Rosnick (2005) who demonstrate the case for a housing
bubble and do so in a manner similar to Austrian economists. Even though they date the beginning of the
bubble to 1997 they ignore the real factor that tax law changes in that year were a catalyst to housing and
higher housing prices.

9
As you can see, the first view wishes to dismiss psychological reasons for bubbles

to focus only on real factors while the second view wishes to downplay real factors in

order to emphasize psychological causes. The third view believes that there are changes

in both real factors and market psychology during bubbles and that both are driven by the

cause of the business cycle—policy manipulations by the Federal Reserve. This view of

bubbles is based on the Austrian business cycle theory (hereafter ABC theory). This is a

minority view held by Austrian school economists and some “fellow travelers” of the

school.13

According to the ABC theory, if the Fed does not pursue a loose monetary policy

then bubbles like the technology stock bubble of the late 1990s or the one in housing that

we are now experiencing would not develop. If the Fed does follow a loose monetary

policy, then a bubble can develop somewhere in the economy, whether it be in tulip

bulbs, stocks, or real estate. If the new money is directed toward housing, a bubble will

develop in housing. Austrian economists further emphasize that the additional resources

allocated to housing are resources that are not available elsewhere in an economy, so that

while more resources than normal are allocated to housing construction, fewer resources

are available to other areas of the economy such as manufacturing, which will experience

higher costs for its inputs such as labor and materials and will produce a proportionately

smaller output. It is this mismatching of resources across industries and sectors that has to

be resolved—painfully—in the inevitable bust or correction.

In a real estate bubble the price of existing homes rises. The bubble also fuels the

construction of new homes so that the wages of construction workers rises and labor

13
A fellow traveler is someone who sympathizes with or supports various tenets of the Austrian school
without being an acknowledged member or embracing all aspects of Austrian economics.

10
reallocates itself into construction and related industries. The bubble also increases the

price of construction materials and land. Construction and construction-related industries

is also where the most unemployment occurs and where the biggest price and wage

declines occur in the inevitable bust.

A unique feature of the Austrian approach is that it does not see a need for prices

to increase uniformly across markets, or for prices to increase to extreme levels in all

markets. Many doubters of the housing bubble point to the smaller price increases in the

center of the country compared to coastal regions, but price is only one dimension of

bubbles—quantity can also increase beyond sustainable levels. In fact, one could

conceptualize a bubble where prices stayed the same and all the bubble adjustment

occurred only in the quantity dimension. If we doubled the number of houses and prices

barely budged, we would be left with too many houses for the population and all the

labor and materials that went into the production of those goods (i.e., houses) would be

tied up and unavailable to serve more urgent needs after the bursting of the bubble

revealed that the superfluous houses were bad investments.

Among the Austrians who identified the housing bubble is economist Frank

Shostak (2003) who defined a bubble as any activity that “springs up” from loose

monetary policies. “In other words, in the absence of monetary pumping these activities

would not emerge.” As a result of this pumping, a misallocation of resources develops

whereby non-productive activities increase relative to productive activities—something

that seems to clearly characterize the U.S. economy since he wrote in early 2003:

The magnitude of the housing price bubble is depicted…in terms of the


median price of new houses in relation to the historical trend between
1963 and 1979. In this regard the median price stood at 73% above the
trend in December 2002. (2003)

11
The only “problem” with his warning is that it came too soon. A year later Shostak

(2004) warned that there “is a strong likelihood that the U.S. housing market bubble has

already reached dangerous dimensions.” While early warning maybe a problem for

investors in home building stocks, the problems of predicting the timing and magnitude

of bubbles and business cycles affects all forecasters, and Shostak’s warning was

primarily for the purpose of judging public policy. In effect he was noting that

policymakers have made a mistake that they should correct immediately and not make

the situation in the housing market any worse.

Also from the Austrian camp is banker Christopher Meyer (2003), who noted that

there is always a bubble in the making in a world of fractional reserve banking and fiat

currency, and that housing has often been impacted by bubble conditions in the U.S. and

elsewhere. In the summer of 2003 he identified the current housing bubble:

The strong housing market has all the makings of being the next bubble—
in particular high leverage and unsustainable price increases. While the
larger economy seems to sputter along, the housing market continues to
run a hot race. Low interest rates have propelled refinancing, freeing up
$100 billion last year alone, according to the Wall Street Journal. Not
surprisingly, the low interest rates have increased buying power and
supported housing prices. (2003)

In early 2004 I pointed out to the on-going housing bubble to investors and

specifically said that it might not be a good idea to increase your mortgage: “it might not

be a good time for you to obtain a home equity loan to invest in hot tech stocks. We are

going through a housing bubble” (2004b). I followed this up later that year (Thornton

2004c) with a more detailed examination of the housing bubble and found:

12
Signs of a "new era" in housing are everywhere. Housing construction is
taking place at record rates. New records for real estate prices are being set
across the country, especially on the east and west coasts. Booming home
prices and record low interest rates are allowing homeowners to refinance
their mortgages, "extract equity" to increase their spending, and lower
their monthly payment! As one loan officer explained to me: "It's almost
too good to be true." In fact, it is too good to be true. (Thornton 2004c)

The problem with the “new era” diagnosis is that it ignores the historical fact that the

housing market, and the construction of structures in general, has experienced regular

cycles of boom and bust, with prices rising and falling for residential, commercial,

industrial, and agricultural real estate. Likewise, occupancy and lease rates, new

construction, and the fate of construction firms and land speculators point us to the

history of real estate bubbles. In fact, statistically, housing starts are a leading indicator of

the business cycle and home construction is procyclical (i.e. home construction is

positively related to changes in the overall economy, but more volatile). The Skyscraper

Indicator even shows that historically the building of a record-setting high skyscraper

foreshadows severe negative changes in the economic (See Thornton

What Goes Up

The ABC theory demonstrates that monetary inflation has different effects depending on

who receives the new money first and how it is spent. Is the new money introduced into

the economy in the areas of banking and investment, consumer loans, or directly to a

group of consumers or producers? Do the people who receive the money want to save it

or spend it? If they save it interest rates will go down, and if they spend it interest rates

will go up as entrepreneurs borrow money in order to increase production. If the money is

13
spent, it depends on who is spending it. The economy will experience different changes if

the money is given to welfare recipients instead of military generals. If the money is

saved the economy will experience different changes if it is invested in stocks rather than

housing. The point here is that monetary inflation can cause bubbles and booms in the

areas of the economy where it is first introduced. This foundation of the ABC theory

comes down to us from Richard Cantillon (1755), the founder of economic theory, who

wrote in the aftermath of the Mississippi Bubble (circa 1730). Tracking the flow of

monetary inflation through the economy is very difficult and most mainstream

economists just assume away the problem and declare that money is neutral on the

economy.

By the end of the 18th century the world had converted from free banking to

central banking, with the U.S. being the last major nation to establish a central bank in

1913. In the first treatise on monetary theory in the modern era, Ludwig von Mises

(1912) produced the ABC theory. With central banks established for the purpose of

producing monetary inflation, Mises could now establish a general theory of business

cycles rather than the case-by-case basis of Cantillon. By integrating the contributions of

Carl Menger, Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, and Knut Wicksell he was able to show that

when the central bank (e.g., the Fed) increases the supply of money, it causes the market

rate of interest to fall below the natural rate of interest that would have existed in the

absence of Fed intervention. This would cause investors to borrow more money, to

expand their investments, and to undertake riskier projects and more roundabout

production processes.14 As these borrowers compete for assets, resources, and goods,

14
More roundabout production processes are production processes that use advanced technology and
require more time to complete, but are more productive. An example of a direct production process would

14
price inflation inevitably occurs and the rate of interest will increase. This in turn will

negatively affect the economy and some of the riskier and more roundabout investment

projects will be discovered to be bad investments. Bankruptcies can also impact

previously existing investments and production processes that are caught in the wake of

the bust. Mises’s student F.A. Hayek expanded the ABC theory to include capital theory

and its integration into the structure of production.

According to the ABC theory, when a central bank makes loans or purchases

government bonds from banks it is injecting bank reserves into the economy. Banks now

have excess reserves which they can loan, but the existence of excess loanable funds

means that banks must reduce the interest rate they charge, reduce the credit quality

requirements of borrowers, or both. The result is a greater quantity of borrowing and

investing, particularly in projects that “pay off” over a long period of time. Lower interest

rates also discourage savings because the return from savings is lower. In this manner the

Federal Reserve drives the market rate of interest below the natural rate of interest that

would have existed in the absence of Federal Reserve intervention.

Ever since the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of

1980 and Paul Volcker’s (Chairman of the Fed from 1979 to 1987) war on inflation of the

early 1980s, interest rates have been on a downward path. This culminated in the large

reductions in the Federal Funds rate that followed in the aftermath of the 9/11 terrorists

attack in 2001. Under Greenspan the rate was reduced from 6.5% in November of 2000

to 1% in July of 2003. The Federal Funds rate remained at 1% until June of 2004,

be a dairy farmer who produces milk, processes it and sells it to people in the vicinity of his farm. A more
roundabout technique would be dairy farmers who sell their milk to a central processing facility (with
advanced technology) of a national company with headquarters in a different state and who in turn sell to
wholesalers and retailers all over the region.

15
coinciding with the launching of the final phase of the housing bubble.15 At this low

level, interest rates were actually negative when price inflation is taken into account.

The graph below depicts the history of the Federal Funds rate, which is the rate

that banks can borrow from other banks in order to meet their reserve requirements

imposed by the Fed. The Fed “targets” this short-term rate and injects reserves into this

market by purchasing government bonds from banks, thereby freeing up reserves in the

banking system. This essentially is the engine of inflation because the Fed simply makes

a bookkeeping entry in the bank’s account with the Federal Reserve—modern inflation is

essentially an electronic bookkeeping entry. In the graph below, the shaded areas

represent periods that are considered to have been recessions in the economy. As you can

see, the low rates of the 1960s resulted in no recession and a booming economy, but those

low rates also caused the Stagflation of the 1970s, where both price inflation and

unemployment were very high. This culminated in Volcker’s war on inflation of the early

1980s. By greatly reducing expectation of price inflation and deregulating the banking

system, the Fed has been able to reduce interest rates and ignite a giant boom in financial

and asset markets throughout the 1980s and 1990s, as well as the housing bubble of the

early 2000s when rates were pushed below their natural levels and when real rates were

negative, when adjusted for inflation.

15
The Philadelphia Housing Sector stock index apparently peaked at the end of August 2005.

16
When banks have access to bank reserves from the Fed at low rates they can offer

their customers lower rates on loans. The graph below shows the impact of changes in the

Federal Funds rate on mortgage rates; increasing during the 1970s and peaking during

Volcker’s war on inflation at 18%, and then generally declining throughout the 1980s and

1990s and then reaching historical lows during the early 2000s. During the housing

bubble interest rates on 30-year conventional mortgages were at their lowest levels ever

during the post-gold standard era. When interest rates fall, asset prices and real estate

prices tend to rise, and vice versa.

17
Naturally, lower rates for home mortgages have stimulated borrowing for real

estate purposes. The chart below shows that the amount of real estate loans at commercial

banks first exceeded $1 trillion in November 1994. In quick succession they then

exceeded $2 trillion in November of 2002 and $3 trillion in May of 2006. In addition to

the Fed, there are other factors that helped direct all this new credit money into real

estate. First, in 1997 homeowners were given a $250,000 exemption ($500,000 for

couples) for capital gains that resulted from the sale of their house, adding greatly to the

tax benefits of home ownership. This tax break could be said to have lit the fuse of the

housing bubble. Second, government-sponsored credit corporations such as Fannie Mae

and Freddie Mac, who can acquire capital at a subsidized rate because of the implicit

assumption that the Federal government will bail them out, began to collateralize home

mortgage debt on a grand scale so that lenders could quickly and easily resell the loans

18
they make. These government-sponsored agencies have helped stimulate the flow of

credit to riskier borrowers who might not otherwise have access to credit, and have

therefore helped to lower the credit standards of lending institutions. The problem with

these institutions is so large that even Alan Greenspan has publicly scolded them (Hays

2005). In truth, the original problem lies with Alan, not Fannie or Freddie.

The artificially low rates generated by the Fed also have the effect of discouraging

people from saving money and encourages them to borrow more for consumption and

speculation. The impact of monetary pumping by the Fed has driven down the personal

savings rate (as depicted on the graph below) down throughout the 1980s and 1990s, and

during the early 2000s it has driven the rate to zero—and even below—which means that

on average people are spending more than they earn. Contributing to the problem of the

19
low personal savings rate are the artificially inflated asset and real estate prices which

naturally make people feel wealthier and allow them to “cash out” equity from their

homes when they refinance their home mortgages. During the housing bubble many

Americans have used their homes as a kind of giant ATM to withdraw cash from the

equity in their homes. Others have used the “magic checkbook” from second mortgages

to spend the equity they have in their homes (Lloyd 2006).

At this point one should be wondering—how can borrowing be going up and

savings going down? One answer to the question is that America is borrowing money

from overseas in the form of the trade deficit, but the main answer is monetary pumping

by the Fed. By artificially lowering rates via increases in the money supply the Fed has

created a giant gap between borrowing and saving. In the graph below, the U.S. money

20
supply is given from 1959 to 2006 as measured by MZM (money of zero maturity).16

During the period from January 1959 to August 1971 (11.7 years), when Nixon took the

U.S. off the gold standard, the money supply grew by 82.2% for an average annual

growth rate of 5.26%. Between August of 1971 and 1984, when complete decontrol was

established in 1984 from the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control

Act of 1980 (13 years), the money supply increased by 180.4% for an average annual

growth rate of 8.25%. Since 1984 (16.6 years) the money supply as measured by MZM

has grown by 390.1%, or an average annual growth rate of 10%. It would seem that all

this new money first went into the New York Stock Exchange, especially during the

1980s, then the NASDAQ stock market during the late 1990s, and finally into the

housing market since the dot.com bust in 2000.

16
MZM is a relatively new measure of the money supply and one that is close to the Austrian school
definition of money, which is that “money” is immediately redeemable at par. MZM includes currency,
demand deposits (checking accounts), traveler’s checks, savings deposits, and deposits in money market
mutual funds.

21
A large part of the increase in the money supply found its way into the market for

home mortgages. Since the recession of 2001 the increase in mortgage debt is about equal

to the increase in MZM. This one stylized fact probably best illustrates the housing

bubble and its cause. Another measure of the housing bubble is the amount of real private

residential fixed investment as presented in the graph below. Investment in housing was

low during the Great Depression and WWII, but beginning in the mid-1940s investment

in housing (adjusted for price inflation) has shown a positive trend, which is based on

economic and population growth over that same period. Superimposed on the graph are

upper and lower channel lines based on the period from the 1920s to the mid-1990s. This

channel allows us to illustrate the normal booms and busts that occurred in the housing

market. A dot-and-dash trend line is drawn over the basic trend in housing investment.

This shows us that the cycle in housing investment was less severe before we went off the

22
gold standard, more severe on the fiat standard, and even more severe after monetary

deregulation in 1980. Most noteworthy is that investment in housing hit a boom high

during the dot.com bubble of the late 1990s and then “jumped the tracks” during the

recession of 2001, when historically it would have retreated back toward recessionary

levels. It therefore seems clear that in terms of investment value there has been a housing

bubble since at least the recession of 2001.

The ABC theory does not rely on measuring the cycle or bubble, but such

empirical measures do often help illustrate the approach. The next such measure is the

number of homes built. The graph below presents the number of privately owned housing

starts (apartments and other multiunit structures are not included here). Notice that sharp

downturns in the number of housing starts often coincides with the beginnings of

23
recessions (shaded in gray) and that the sharper the drop the longer the recession. For

example, in the late 1970s the number of housing starts fell from an annual rate of over

1.5 million to a rate of barely a half a million in the early 1980s, which was a severe

recession. Since the recession of 1991 the trend in new housing starts has been steeply

upward and there was no noticeable downturn in housing starts during the recession of

2001—the only recession on record where that did not occur. Instead housing starts

continued to increase and have set several new records over the last few years. In terms

of this quantity dimension the U.S. has been in a housing bubble since the early 2000s.

The final dimension of the housing bubble presented here is the price of houses.

Doubters of the housing bubble claim that housing prices are rising on the east and west

coasts, but are not rising by bubble proportions in much of the center of the country. Of

24
course housing prices have increased faster in the West and Northeast compared to the

Midwest and South, but ABC theorists would be shocked if home prices were rising

uniformly across the country. After all, the whole theory is based on changing relative

prices, not uniform increases or decreases in a price level. There are microeconomic and

public policy reasons why home prices rise more dramatically and are always at a higher

level in, for example, in California than they are in Alabama. These issues are explored in

many of the other contributions to this book. However, the same could be said about

stock prices during the technology bubble—rare stocks in tight supply (e.g., dot.coms)

did much better than widely held stocks (e.g., stocks in the DJIA). The same was true of

tulip bulbs during the Tulip Mania that happened in 17th century Holland—rare species

were affected more by monetary conditions than ordinary species, but they all went up in

price (see French 2006).

The ABC theory expects prices in general to rise, but not to rise uniformly. The

extent of the rise depends on both where the money is being injected and the flexibility of

the supply side of the markets where the injections are taking place. However, if we

consider the national price index for the typical 1996 one-family house between 1998 and

2005 we find that prices have increased by 45%, which is 1¼ times larger than the

increase in the Consumer Price Index. According to the Bureau of the Census, the price

of the average house, as opposed to the “typical” house, has been increasing even faster,

which indicates that people are buying bigger more expensive homes as well. The price

dimension—while muted somewhat by the economy’s ability to produce greater

quantities of housing—still indicates a large increase in the real price of housing. We

should also remember that new housing is generally is built on lower-priced land, that

25
house-building technology has reduced building costs, and that the large influx of labor

from Mexico has also helped hold down labor costs.

Must Come Down

The ABC theory shows that government failure is responsible for starting the housing

bubble in the first place. The monetary policies of the Fed have caused resources to be

allocated in an ultimately unsustainable fashion. In a housing bubble too many houses are

built, houses of the wrong sort are built, and houses are built in the wrong locations based

on the underlying fundamentals of the economy and people’s real desires for housing not

artificially stimulated by monetary inflation by the Fed. While most people are very

happy during boom times, the Austrian economists view the boom as the real problem

because this is where resources are misallocated. This is also when people become

financially overextended and engage in excessive luxury spending (Kostigen 2006).

Inflationary periods tend to be when the rich get richer and the poor get poorer.

The bubble must come to an end because it is based on an irrational allocation of

resources caused by the Fed’s misleading interest rate policy. Money that is tied up in an

asset bubble initially prevents monetary inflation from being revealed as price inflation as

measured by the Consumer Price Index. However, if the monetary pumping is used to

purchase assets like stocks, bonds, or real estate then the inflation is revealed in the price

of those assets, which will rise even though the underlying earnings of the assets has not

improved. When money begins to leak out of asset bubbles into consumption, then the

price of goods that are used to construct the Consumer Price Index (CPI) will begin to

26
rise. The asset bubble is popped or deflated when interest rates rise. This can occur when

either the market raises rates due to rising inflation premiums on loans or when the Fed

tries to curtail increases in the CPI by preemptively raising rates.

The bursting of the bubble reveals the cluster of errors in the housing market and

related industries and begins the process of reallocating resources to their best uses by

changes in prices, buying and selling, relocation, bankruptcy, and unemployment. The

macroeconomic effect of deflating the bubble is that it causes the economy to go into

recession or depression. However, the effects of the bubble will also be concentrated as it

is deflated. Notice in the graph below that the bubble (as described by employment in the

construction industry) began in 1997 when it rose above the level of the channel, which

dates back to the end of WWII. Notice too that the trend in construction employment has

always been negative during recessionary periods—even the recession of 2001—and that

the negative trends often begin prior to and extend beyond the periods identified as

recession. Because the trends in construction employment have been so strong for so long

during the housing bubble, it would not be surprising that the negative impact of the

bubble would take on a similar, but negative effect on construction employment and

spending, and that these effects would spread beyond to the construction materials

industry, mortgage lending, real estate sales, furniture, appliances, and household goods

items.

27
Another natural concern about the bursting of the housing bubble is the

indebtedness of the average American. As we previously have shown, the personal

savings rate of Americans has been declining for many years, in part due to the fact that

Americans have felt wealthier due to the rising price of their real estate properties. This is

then coupled with the rising debt of the average American household. As shown in the

graph below, total household debt was less than $500 when the U.S. went off the gold

standard in 1971, first exceeded $5 trillion in 1996 and $10 trillion in 2004. In October of

2005, the last reported period, total debt exceeded $11.5 trillion. Certainly these figures

should be adjusted for inflation, population, and economic growth, but that does not

reverse the fact that many Americans have taken on a large amount of debt and have not

set aside a similar amount of saving to offset this debt or to insulate themselves from

periods of economic distress.

28
As the economy goes into recession and unemployment increases, homeowners

with large mortgages will have a difficult time making their monthly payments and may

face the possibility of bankruptcy. This “squeeze” will be compounded by the fact that

many homeowners have taken equity out of their homes in recent years, increasing the

size of their mortgage. Further difficulties are presented by the fact that a large

percentage of borrowers have taken out variable-rate mortgages rather than fixed rate

mortgages, which means that their monthly payment will rise substantially when interest

rates increase. With some variable rate mortgages the monthly payment stays the same,

but then the principal on the loan increases when rates rise, which could place these

borrowers “upside down” on the homes – which means the mortgage would be much

larger than the value of the home. Lenders have also been providing mortgage loans

based on much smaller down payments (in percentage terms) with some lenders even

29
providing loans that exceed 100% of the price of the house. All of this points to the

likelihood of a large number of foreclosures and bankruptcies. This in turn points our

attention to the stability of the banking and mortgage lending industries and the

likelihood of a taxpayer bailout of banks and government-sponsored institutions like

Freddie Mac that buy mortgage loans from lenders.

Summary and Conclusions

There are three views of the housing bubble. The mainstream view does not believe in

bubbles and attributes such changes in the economy to real factors such as technology

shocks, and believes there is nothing the government can do to solve such real problems.

The Keynesian view is that bubbles exist because of psychological instabilities in the

economy, not real factors, and that countercyclical policies of the government should be

used to tame the business cycle. The Austrian business cycle (i.e., ABC) theory

incorporates real and psychological changes into a view where bubbles are caused by the

policy manipulation of the Federal Reserve.

The housing bubble that began in the late 1990s is a classic example of

government failure as applied to the housing crisis. Inflation of the money supply that

accompanied the Fed’s cheap credit policy led to a borrowing and building binge of an

unprecedented scale. The number of new homes built, the price of new and existing

homes, and the total amount of real estate investment all indicate that the Fed’s policy,

combined with a favorable tax policy and taxpayer-subsidized lending practices, created

the housing bubble.

30
The bubble is not just a bunch of hot air. Real resources are involved, which have

been misdirected during the bubble and which will have to make painful adjustments in

the aftermath of the bubble. This will involve unemployment, foreclosure, and

bankruptcy for many people, especially those in the construction and construction-related

industries. The macro economy will be sent into a recession or depression, which could

be of a lengthy duration because of the slowness of the housing market as compared to

the stock market, which can process very large changes in value within the period of one

market day.

The lesson of the housing bubble is that what at first appeared to be the

government trying to help improve home ownership for Americans has been a giant

government failure and will have the unintended effect of economically scaring many

homeowners, particularly those who bought houses at the peak of the bubble. Others have

been fooled into extracting equity from their homes, increasing their mortgages and

taking loans, such as variable-rate loans, which they believed were necessary to qualify to

buy houses at inflated prices. Similar trends in housing have occurred in countries around

the world as many of the world’s central banks have been engaged in monetary pumping

that has been injected into their housing sectors.

The policy lesson of the housing bubble, as provided by the ABC theory, is that

the Fed is responsible for the housing bubble as well as the normal booms and busts in

the economy, and that as long as it retains its authority to set what are in effect price

controls on interests rates, such bubbles will periodically appear in the economy. Federal

31
policy toward housing should be guided by the principles neutrality, laissez faire, and do

no harm.17

17
For recent statements concerning Austrian recommendations for reform regarding the money and the
business cycles see Herbener (2002) and Cochran (2004).

32
References

Baker, Dean and David Rosnick. 2005. Will a Bursting Bubble Trouble Bernanke? Evidence for

a Housing Bubble. Washington, DC.: Center for Economic and Policy Research,

November. Available at: http://www.cepr.net/publications/housing_bubble_2005_11.pdf

Bernanke, Ben S. 2006a. Speech to the Independent Community Bankers of America National

Convention and Techworld, Las Vegas, Nevada, March 8. Available at:

http://www.federalreserve.gov/BoardDocs/Speeches/2006/20060308/default.htm

Bernanke, Ben S. 2006b. Reflections on the Yield Curve and Monetary Policy.

Remarks before the Economic Club of New York, March 20. Available at:

http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2006/20060320/default.htm.

Bruno, Joe B. 2006. Former Fed Chair Says Housing Boom Over. Associated Press, May 19.

Available at: http://biz.yahoo.com/ap/060519/greenspan_speech.html?.v=2

Bureau of the Census. Price Indexes of New One-Family Houses Sold. Available at:

http://www.census.gov/const/price_sold.pdf

33
Callahan, Gene and Roger W. Garrison. 2003. Does the Austrian Theory of the Business Cycle

explain the Dot.com Boom and Bust? Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. 6

(summer): 67-98.

Cantillon, Richard. 1755 [1931]. Essai sur la Nature du Commerce en Général. Edited with an

English translation by Henry Higgs, London: Frank Cass and Company.

Cochran, John P. 2004. Capital, Monetary Calculation, and the Trade Cycle: The Importance of

Sound Money. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. 7 (spring): 17-25.

French, Doug. 2006. The Dutch Monetary Environment during Tulipmania. Quarterly Journal of

Austrian Economics. 9 (spring): 3-14.

Gallaway, Lowell and Richard Vedder. 2000. The Fraud of Macroeconomic Stabilization Policy.

Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. 3 (fall): 19-33.

Greenspan, Alan. 2002. Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook. Testimony before the Joint

Economic Committee of the U.S. Congress, April 17. Available at:

http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/testimony/2002/20020417/default.htm

Greenspan, Alan. 2005a. Reflections on Central Banking. Speech given at a symposium

sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole, Wyoming

34
August 26. Available at:

http://www.federalreserve.gov/Boarddocs/Speeches/2005/20050826/default.htm

Greenspan, Alan. 2005b. Mortgage Banking. Speech to the American Bankers Association

Annual Convention, Palm Desert, California (via satellite), September 26. Available at:

http://www.federalreserve.gov/BOARDDOCS/SPEECHES/2005/200509262/default.htm.

Hays, Kathleen. 2005. Greenspan steps up criticism of Fannie: Fed chief says company and

Freddie Mac have exploited their relationship with the Treasury. CNN.com, May 19.

Available at: http://money.cnn.com/2005/05/19/news/economy/greenspan_fannie/

Herbener, Jeffrey M. 2002. After the Age of Inflation: Austrian Proposals for Monetary Reform.

Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. 5 (winter): 5-19.

Higgs, Robert. 1987. Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American

Government. New York: Oxford University Press.

Higgs, Robert. 2005. Resurgence of the Warfare State: The Crisis Since 9/11. Oakland, Calif:

The Independent Institute.

Holcombe, Randall G. 1995. Public Policy and the Quality of Life: Market Incentives versus

Government Planning. Westport, Conn: Greenwood Press.

35
Hülsmann, Jörg Guido. 1998. Toward a General Theory of Error Cycles. Quarterly Review of

Austrian Economics. 4 (winter): 1-23.

Kostigen, Thomas. 2006. Skewed views: If the rich are doing so well, how much worse off are

the rest of us? MarketWatch, May 23. Available at:

http://www.marketwatch.com/News/Story/Story.aspx?guid=%7B3003D864-9DF1-4829-

8DB3-01E56C3A0F70%7D&siteid=google

Krugman, Paul, 2005a. Running out of Bubbles. New York Times. May 27. Available at:

http://www.nytimes.com/2005/05/27/opinion/27krugman.html?ex=1274846400&en=ee7

3a0d5d3c35710&ei=5088&partner=rssnyt&emc=rss

Krugman, Paul. 2005b. That Hissing Sound. New York Times, August 8. Available at:

http://www.nytimes.com/2005/08/08/opinion/08krugman.html?ex=1281153600&en=712

5767d2baf3fae&ei=5088&partner=rssnyt&emc=rss

Lloyd, Carol. 2006. Home Sweet Cash Cow: How our houses are financing our lives.

SFGate.com, March 10. Available at: http://www.sfgate.com/cgi-

bin/article.cgi?file=/gate/archive/2006/03/10/carollloyd.DTL

McCarthy, Jonathan and Richard W. Peach. 2004. Are Home Prices the Next “Bubble”? FRBNY

Economic Policy Review (December): 1-17.

36
Meyer, Christopher. 2003. The Housing Bubble. The Free Market (August). Available at:

http://www.mises.org/freemarket_detail.asp?control=450

Mises, Ludwig von. 1912 [1981]. The Theory of Money and Credit. Indianapolis, Ind.: Liberty

Classics.

Shiller, Robert J. 2000. Irrational Exuberance. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

Shiller, Robert J. 2004. Are Housing Prices a House of Cards? Project-Syndicate.org, September.

Available at: http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/shiller17

Shiller, Robert J. 2005. Irrational Exuberance. 2nd Edition. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University

Press.

Shostak, Frank. 2003. Housing Bubble: Myth or Reality? Mises Daily Article (on line), March

04. Available at: http://www.Mises.org/story/1177

Shostak, Frank. 2004. Who Made the Fannie and Freddie Threat?” Mises Daily Article (on line),

March 05. Available at: http://www.Mises.org/story/1463

Thornton, Mark. 2004a. Bull Market? LewRockwell.com, February 9. Available at:

http://www.lewrockwell.com/thornton/thornton11.html.

37
Thornton, Mark. 2004b. Greenspam. LewRockwell.com, February 16. Available at:

http://www.LewRockwell.com/thornton/thornton13.html.

Thornton, Mark. 2004c. Housing: Too Good to be True. Mises Daily Article (on line), June 04.

Available at: http://www.Mises.org/story/1533.

Thornton, Mark. 2004d. Who Predicted the Bubble? Who Predicted the Crash? The Independent

Review. 9 (summer): 5-30.

Thornton, Mark. 2005a. Skyscrapers and Business Cycles. Quarterly Journal of Austrian

Economics. 8 (spring): 51-74.

Thornton, Mark. 2005b. What is the "Dark Side" and Why Do Some People Choose It? Mises

Daily Articles (on-line), May 13. Available at: http://www.mises.org/articles.asp.

Thornton, Mark. Forthcoming. Cantillon on the Cause of the Business Cycle. Quarterly Journal

of Austrian Economics.

38

You might also like