Cost Curve
Cost Curve
Contents
• 1 Short-run average variable cost curve (SRAVC)
• 2 Short-run average total cost curve (SRATC or SRAC)
• 3 Long-run average cost curve (LRAC)
• 4 Short-run marginal cost curve (SRMC)
• 5 Long-run marginal cost curve (LRMC)
• 6 Graphing cost curves together
• 7 Cost curves and production functions
• 8 Relationship between different curves
• 9 Relationship between short run and long run cost curves
• 10 U-shaped curves
• 11 See also
• 12 Notes
• 13 References
[edit] Relationship between short run and long run cost curves
Basic: For each quantity of output there is one cost minimizing level of capital and a unique short run average
cost curve associated with producing the given quantity.[9]
• Each STC curve can be tangent to the LRTC curve at only one point. The STC curve cannot cross
(intersect) the LRTC curve.[2]:230[8]:228-229 The STC curve can lie wholly “above” the LRTC curve with no
tangency point.[10]:256
• One STC curve is tangent to LRTC at the long-run cost minimizing level of production. At the point of
tangency LRTC = STC. At all other levels of production STC will exceed LRTC.[11]:292-299
• Average cost functions are the total cost function divided by the level of output. Therefore the SATC
curveis also tangent to the LRATC curve at the cost-minimizing level of output. At the point of tangency
LRATC = SATC. At all other levels of production SATC > LRATC[11]:292-299 To the left of the point of
tangency the firm is using too much capital and fixed costs are too high. To the right of the point of
tangency the firm is using too little capital and diminishing returns to labor are causing costs to increase.
[12]
• The slope of the total cost curves equals marginal cost. Therefore when STC is tangent to LTC, SMC =
LRMC.
• At the long run cost minimizing level of output LRTC = STC; LRATC = SATC and LRMC = SMC,[11] :
292-299
.
• The long run cost minimizing level of output may be different from minimum SATC,[8]:229 [13]:186.
• With fixed unit costs of inputs, if the production function has constant returns to scale, then at the
minimal level of the SATC curve we have SATC = LRATC = SMC = LRMC.[11]:292-299
• With fixed unit costs of inputs, if the production function has increasing returns to scale, the minimum of
the SATC curve is to the right of the point of tangency between the LRAC and the SATC curves.[11]:292-299
Where LRTC = STC, LRATC = SATC and LRMC = SMC.
• With fixed unit costs of inputs and decreasing returns the minimum of the SATC curve is to the left of the
point of tangency between LRAC and SATC.[11]:292-299 Where LRTC = STC, LRATC = SATC and LRMC
= SMC.
• With fixed unit input costs, a firm that is experiencing increasing (decreasing) returns to scale and is
producing at its minimum SAC can always reduce average cost in the long run by expanding (reducing)
the use of the fixed input.[11]:292-99 [13]:186
• LRATC will always equal to or be less than SATC.[1]:211
• If production process is exhibiting constant returns to scale then minimum SRAC equals minimum long
run average cost. The LRAC and SRAC intersect at their common minimum values. Thus under constant
returns to scale SRMC = LRMC = LRAC = SRAC .
• If the production process is experiencing decreasing or increasing, minimum short run average cost does
not equal minimum long run average cost. If increasing returns to scale exist long run minimum will
occur at a lower level of output than SRAC. This is because there are economies of scale that have not
been exploited so in the long run a firm could always produce a quantity at a price lower than minimum
short run aveage cost simply by using a larger plant.[14]
• With decreasing returns, minimum SRAC occurs at a lower production level than minimum LRAC
because a firm could reduce average costs by simply decreasing the size or its operations.
• The minimum of a SRAC occurs when the slope is zero.[15] Thus the points of tangency between the U-
shaped LRAC curve and the minimum of the SRAC curve would coincide only with that portion of the
LRAC curve exhibiting constant economies of scale. For increasing returns to scale the point of tangency
between the LRAC and the SRAc would have to occur at a level of output below level associated with the
minimum of the SRAC curve.
These statements assume that the firm is using the optimal level of capital for the quantity produced. If not, then
the SRAC curve would lie "wholly above" the LRAC and would not be tangent at any point.
[edit] U-shaped curves
Both the SRAC and LRAC curves are typically expressed as U-shaped.[8]:211; 226 [13]:182;187-188 However, the shapes of
the curves are not due to the same factors. For the short run curve the initial downward slope is largely due to
declining average fixed costs.[2]:227 Increasing returns to the variable input at low levels of production also play a
role,[16] while the upward slope is due to diminishing marginal returns to the variable input.[2]:227 With the long run
curve the shape by definition reflects economies and diseconomies of scale.[13]:186 At low levels of production
long run production functions generally exhibit increasing returns to scale, which, for firms that are perfect
competitors in input markets, means that the long run average cost is falling;[2]:227 the upward slope of the long
run average cost function at higher levels of output is due to decreasing returns to scale at those output levels.
[2]:227
[edit] References
1. ^ a b c d e f Perloff, J. Microeconomics, 5th ed. Pearson, 2009.
2. ^ a b c d e f g h i Perloff, J., 2008, Microeconomics: Theory & Applications with Calculus, Pearson. ISBN
9780321277947
3. ^ a b c d e f g Lipsey, Richard G. (1975). An introduction to positive economics (fourth ed.). Weidenfeld & Nicolson.
pp. 57–8. ISBN 0297768999.
4. ^ Sexton, Robert L., Philip E. Graves, and Dwight R. Lee, 1993. "The Short- and Long-Run Marginal Cost Curve:
A Pedagogical Note", Journal of Economic Education, 24(1), p. 34. [Pp. 34-37 (press +)].
5. ^ Gelles, Gregory M., and Mitchell, Douglas W., "Returns to scale and economies of scale: Further observations,"
Journal of Economic Education 27, Summer 1996, 259-261.
6. ^ Frisch, R., Theory of Production, Drodrecht: D. Reidel, 1965.
7. ^ Ferguson, C. E., The Neoclassical Theory of Production and Distribution, London: Cambridge Univ. Press,
1969.
8. ^ a b c d e Pindyck, R., and Rubinfeld, D., Microeconomics, 5th ed., Prentice-Hall, 2001.
9. ^ Nicholson: Microeconomic Theory 9th ed. Page 238 Thomson 2005
10.^ Kreps, D., A Course in Microeconomic Theory, Princeton Univ. Press, 1990.
11.^ a b c d e f g Binger, B., and Hoffman, E., Microeconomics with Calculus, 2nd ed., Addison-Wesley, 1998.
12.^ Frank, R., Microeconomics and Behavior 7th ed. (Mc-Graw-Hill) ISBN 978-007-126349-8 at 321.
13.^ a b c d Melvin & Boyes, Microeconomics, 5th ed., Houghton Mifflin, 2002
14.^ Perloff, J. Microeconomics Theory & Application with Calculus Pearson (2008) p. 231.
15.^ Nicholson: Microeconomic Theory 9th ed. Page Thomson 2005
16.^ Boyes, W., The New Managerial Economics, Houghton Mifflin, 2004.
Retrieved from "http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Cost_curve"
Categories: Costs | Economics curves
Hidden categories: All articles with unsourced statements | Articles with unsourced statements from July 2010
Personal tools
• Log in / create account
Namespaces
• Article
• Discussion
Variants
Views
• Read
• Edit
• View history
Actions
Search
Top of Form
Special:Search
Bottom of Form
Navigation
• Main page
• Contents
• Featured content
• Current events
• Random article
• Donate to Wikipedia
Interaction
• Help
• About Wikipedia
• Community portal
• Recent changes
• Contact Wikipedia
Toolbox
• What links here
• Related changes
• Upload file
• Special pages
• Permanent link
• Cite this page
Print/export
• Create a book
• Download as PDF
• Printable version
Languages
• Deutsch
• Euskara
• 日本語
• This page was last modified on 24 March 2011 at 11:15.