Managerial Economics (M.com IVth Sem.) 22-4
Managerial Economics (M.com IVth Sem.) 22-4
Managerial Economics (M.com IVth Sem.) 22-4
M.Com. IV Sem.
Mr. Abhi Dutt Sharma
Date: 22/04/2020
Cost Analysis
CONTENTS
Objectives
Introduction
Objectives
Introduction
The cost which a firm incurs in the process of production of its goods and services is an important variable for decision making.
Total cost together with total revenue determines the profit level of a business concern. In order to maximise profits a firm
endeavours to increase its revenue and lower its costs. To this end, managers try to produce optimum levels of output, use the
least cost combination factors of production, increase factor productivities and improve organisational efficiency.
8.1 Cost Concepts
Costs play a very important role in managerial decisions involving a selection between alternative courses of
action. It helps in specifying various alternatives in terms of their quantitative values. The kind of cost to be used
in a particular situation depends upon the business decisions to be made. Costs enter into almost every business
decision and it is important to use the right analysis of cost. Hence, it is important to understand what these various
concepts of costs are, how these can be defined and operationalised. This requires the understanding of the two
things, namely, (i) that cost estimates produced by conventional financial accounting are not appropriate for all
managerial uses, and (ii) that different business problems call for different kinds of costs.
Futurity is an important aspect of all business decisions. Future costs are the estimates of time adjusted past or
present costs and are reasonably expected to be incurred in some future period or periods. Their actual incurrence
is a forecast and their management is an estimate. Past costs are actual costs incurred in the past and they are
always contained in the income statements. Their measurement is essentially a record keeping activity.
Incremental costs are defined as the change in overall costs that result from particular decisions being made.
Incremental costs may include both fixed and variable costs. In the short period, incremental cost will consist of
variable cost — costs of additional labour, additional raw materials, power, fuel, etc. — which is the result of a
new decision being taken by the firm. Since these costs can be avoided by not bringing about any change in the
activity, incremental costs are also called avoidable costs or escapable costs. They are also called differential costs.
Sunk cost is one which is not affected or altered by a change in the level or nature of business activity. It will
remain the same whatever the level of activity.
Example: The most important example of sunk cost is the amortisation of past expenses, e.g., depreciation.
Out-of-pocket costs are those that involve immediate payments to outsiders as opposed to book costs that do not
require current cash expenditure.
Example: Wages and salaries paid to the employees are out-of-pocket costs while salary of the owner
manager.
If not paid, it is a book cost. The interest cost of owner's own fund and depreciation cost are other examples of
book costs. Book costs can be converted into out-of-pocket costs by selling assets and leasing them back from the
buyer.
Historical cost of an asset states the cost of plant, equipment and materials at the price paid originally for them,
while the replacement cost states the cost that the firm would have to incur if it wants to replace or acquire the
same asset now.
Example: If the price of bronze at the time of purchase, say, in 1974, was 15 a kg and if the present price is
18 a kg, the original cost of 15 is the historical cost while 18 is replacement cost. Replacement cost means the price
that would have to be paid currently for acquiring the same plant.
Explicit Costs and Implicit or Imputed Costs (Accounting Concept of Cost and Economic Concept of
Cost)
Explicit costs are those expenses which are actually paid by the firm (paid-out-costs). These costs appear in the
accounting records of the firm. On the other hand, implicit costs are theoretical costs in the sense that they go
unrecognised by the accounting system. These costs may be defined as the earnings of those employed resources
which belong to the owner himself.
Actual costs mean the actual expenditure incurred for acquiring or producing a good or service. These costs are
the costs that are generally recorded in books of account, for example, actual wages paid, cost of materials
purchased, interest paid, etc.
Direct (or Separable or Traceable) Costs and Indirect (or Common or Non-traceable) Costs
There are some costs which can be directly attributed to the production of a unit of a given product. Such costs are
direct costs and can easily be separated, ascertained and imputed to a unit of output. This is because these costs
vary with the output units. However, there are other costs which cannot be separated and clearly attributed to
individual units of production. These costs are, therefore, classified as indirect costs in the accounting process.
Shut-down costs are required to be incurred when the production operations are suspended and will not be
necessary if the production operations continue. When any plant is to be permanently closed down, some costs
are to be incurred for disposing off the fixed assets. These costs are called abandonment costs.
Economic costs can be calculated at two levels: micro-level and macro-level. The micro-level economic costs relate
to functioning of a firm as a production unit, while the macro-level economic costs are the ones that are generated
by the decisions of the firm but are paid by the society and not the firm. Private costs are those which are actually
incurred or provided for by an individual or a firm for its business activity. Social cost, on the other hand, is the
total cost to the society on account of production of a good. Thus, the economic costs include both private and
social costs.
Above are the some concepts of costs. But the important cost concepts which play crucial role in managerial
decision-making are as follows:
There are some inputs or factors which can be adjusted with the changes in the output level. Thus, a firm can
readily employ more workers if it has to increase output. Likewise, it can secure and use more raw materials, more
chemicals, without much delay, if it has to expand production. Thus, labour, raw materials, chemicals are the
factors which can be readily varied with the change in output. Such factors are called variable factors. On the other
hand, there are factors such as capital equipment, building, top management personnel which cannot be readily
varied— it requires a comparatively long time to make variations in them. The factors such as capital equipment,
building, which cannot be readily varied and require a comparatively long time to make adjustment in them are
called fixed factors. Therefore, fixed costs are those which are independent of output, i.e., they do not change with
changes in output. These costs are a "fixed" amount which must be incurred by a firm in the short run, whether
the output is small or large. Fixed costs are also known as overhead costs and include charges such as contractual
rent, insurance fee, maintenance costs, property taxes, interest on the capital invested, minimum administrative
expenses such as manager's salary, watchman's wages, etc. Thus, fixed costs are those which are incurred in hiring
the fixed factors of production whose amount cannot be altered in the short run.
Variable costs, on the other hand, are those costs which are incurred on the employment of variable factors of
production whose amount can be altered in the short run. Thus, the total variable costs change with changes in
output in the short run. These costs include payments such as wages of labour employed, the price of the raw
material, fuel and power used, the expenses incurred on transporting and the like. Variable costs are also called
prime costs. Total cost of a business firm is the sum of its total variable costs and total fixed costs. Thus, TC =
TFC+TVC.
In Figure 8.1, output is measured on the X-axis and cost on Y-axis. Since the total fixed cost remains constant
whatever the level of output, the total fixed cost curve (TFC) is parallel to the X-axis. This curve starts from a point
on the Y-axis meaning thereby that the total fixed cost will be incurred even if the output is zero. On the other
hand, the total variable cost curve (TVC) rises upward showing thereby that as the output is increased, the total
variable costs also increase. The total variable cost (TVC) starts from the origin which shows that when output is
zero the variable costs are also nil. It should be noted that total cost is a function of the total output, the greater the
output, the greater will be the total cost. In symbols, we can write:
TC = f(q)
Total cost curve (TC) has been obtained by adding up 'vertically' the total fixed cost curve and total variable cost
curve because the total cost is a sum of total fixed cost and total variable cost. The shape of the total cost curve
(TC) is exactly the same as that of total variable cost curve (TVC) because the same vertical distance always
separates the two curves.
The cost concept is more frequently used both by businessmen and economists in the form of cost per unit or
average cost rather than as totals. We, therefore pass on to the study of short run average cost curves.
Average fixed cost is the total fixed cost divided by the number of units of output produced. Therefore,
𝑇𝐹𝐶
AFC =
𝑄
Average variable cost is the total variable cost divided by the number of units of output produced. Therefore,
𝑇𝑉𝐶
AVC =
𝑄
Thus, average variable cost is the variable cost per unit of output.
We know that the total variable cost (TVC) at any output level consists of payments to the variable factors used to
produce that output. Therefore TVC= P1V1 + P2V2 + …. Pn Vn where P is the unit price and V is the amount of the
variable input. Average variable cost for a level of output (Q), given P is:
𝑇𝑉𝐶 𝑃𝑉 𝑉
AVC= = =𝑃
𝑄 𝑄 𝑄
The term V is the number of units of input divided by the number of units of output. Since the average product
(AP) of an input is the total output divided by the number of units of input (V),
V 1 1
Q Q/V AP
V 1
AVC P P
so we can write, Q VP
That is, average variable cost is the price of the input multiplied by the reciprocal of the average product of the
input. We know that due to first increasing and then decreasing marginal returns to the variable input, average
product initially rises, reaches a maximum and then declines. Since average variable cost is 1/AP, the average
variable cost normally falls, reaches a minimum and then rises. It first declines and then rises for reasons similar
to those operating in case of TVC. This is shown in Figure 8.2.
The average total cost or what is called simply average cost is the total cost divided by the number of units of
output produced. Therefore,
𝑇𝐶
ATC=
𝑄
Since the total cost is the sum of total variable cost and total fixed cost, the average total cost is also the sum of
average variable cost and average fixed cost.
This can be proved as follows:
𝑇𝐶
ATC =
𝑄
𝑇𝑉𝐶+𝑇𝐹𝐶
Therefore, ATC=
𝑄
𝑇𝑉𝐶 𝑇𝐹𝐶
= +
𝑄 𝑄
= AVC + AFC
Average total cost is also known as unit cost, since it is cost per unit of output produced.
MCn = TCn–TCn–1
In symbols, marginal cost is rate of change in total cost with respect to a unit change in output, i.e.,
𝑑(𝑇𝐶)
MC=
𝑑𝑄
where d in the numerator and denominator indicates the change in TC and Q respectively.
It is worth pointing out that marginal cost is independent of the fixed cost. Since fixed costs do not change with
output, there are no marginal fixed costs when output increases in the short run. It is only the variable costs that
vary with output in the short run. Therefore, marginal costs are, in fact, due to the changes in variable costs.
𝑑(𝑇𝑉𝐶)
MC=
𝑑𝑄
The independence of the marginal cost from the fixed cost can be proved algebraically as follows:
= TVCn – TVCn–1
Hence, marginal cost is the addition to the total variable costs when output is increased from n-1 units to n units
of output. It follows, therefore, that the marginal cost is independent of the amount of fixed costs.
In Table 8.1, MC is the slope of the TC curve. As TC curve first rises at a decreasing rate and later on at an increasing
rate, MC curve will also, therefore, first decline and then rise.
!
Caution The properties of the average costs (AVC, AFC, ATC) and marginal costs can briefly be described
as follows:
1. AFC declines continuously, approaching both axes asymptotically.
2. AVC first declines, reaches a minimum and rises thereafter. When AVC attains minimum, MC
equals AVC.
3. As AFC approaches asymptotically the horizontal axis, AVC approaches ATC asymptotically.
4. ATC first declines, reaches a minimum and rises thereafter. When ATC attains its minimum,
MC equals ATC.
5. MC first declines, reaches a minimum and rises thereafter — MC equals AVC and ATC when
these curves attain their minimum values. Furthermore, MC lies below both AVC and ATC when they
are declining; it lies above them when they are rising.
The laws governing costs are the same as the laws governing productivity. When output is increased in the short
run, it can only be done by increasing the variable input. But as more and more of a variable input is added to a
fixed input, the law of diminishing marginal productivity enters in. Marginal and average productivities fall.
Contt..