1 Small Is Beautiful Economics As If People Mattered
1 Small Is Beautiful Economics As If People Mattered
1 Small Is Beautiful Economics As If People Mattered
E R Schumocher
SMALL IS BEAUTIFUL
Economics os lí People Mottered
±M
SMALL IS BEAUTIFUL
SMALL IS BEAUTIFUL
Economics as if People Mattered
E. F. SCHUMACHER
PERENNIAL LIBRARY
Harper & Row, Publishers
New York, Hagerstown, San Francisco, London
This book was originally publishcd by Blond & Briggs Ltd,
London, ¡n 1973. It ¡s here reprinted by arrangement. A hard-
cover edítion ís published by Harper & Row, Publishers, Inc.
84 20 19
Few can contémplate without a sense of exhilara-
tion the splendid achievements of practical energy
and technical skill, which, from the latter part of
the seventeenth century, were transforming the
face of material civilisation, and of which England
was the daring, if not too scrupulous, pioneer. If,
however, economic ambitions are good servants,
they are bad masters.
The most obvious facts are the most easily
forgotten. Both the existing economic order and
too many of the projects advanced for reconstruct-
ing it break down through their neglect of the
truism that, since even quite common men have
souls, no Lacrease in material wealth will com-
pénsate them for arrangements which insult their
self-respect and impair their freedom. A reason-
able estímate of economic organisation must
allow for the fact that, unless industry is to be
paralysed by recurrent revolts on the part of out-
raged human nature, it must satisfy criteria which
are not purely economic.
R. H. Tawney
Religión and the Rise of Capitalism
PART II RESOURCES
1. —
The Greatest Resource Education 79
2. The Proper Use of Land 102
3. Resources for Industry 118
4. Nuclear Energy —Salvation or Damnation? 134
5. Technology with a Human Face 146
vii
PART IV ORGANISATION AND OWNERSHIP
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Introduction
Theodore Roszak
8
i£ they were never correct? What if there stir, in all those
expertly quantified millions of living souls beneath the
statistical surface, aspirations for creativity, generosity,
brotherly and sisterly cooperation, natural harmony, and
self-transcendence which conventional economics, by vir-
tue of a banal misantbropy it mistakes for "being realis-
tic," only works to destroy? (and there is no
If that is so
doubt in my mind that it is), then it is no wonder the
policies which stem from that economics must so often be
made to work, must be forced down against resistance
upon a confused and recalcitrant human material which
none daré ever consult except by way of the phony plebis-
cite of the marketplace, which always tums out as pre-
dicted because it is rigged up by cynics, voted by
demoralized masses, and tabulated by opportunists. And
what sort of science is it that must, for the sake of its
predictive success, hope and pray that people will never
be their better selves, but always be greedy social idiots
with nothing finer to do than getting and spending, getting
and spending? It is as Schumacher tells us: **when the
available *spiritual space* is not filled by some higher
motivations, then it will necessarily be filledby something
lower —by mean, calculating attitude to life
the small,
which is economic calculus."
rationalized in the
If that is so, then we need a nobler economics that is
not afraid to discuss spirit and conscience, moral purpose
and the meaning of life, an economics that aims to edú-
cate and elévate people, not merely to measure their low-
grade behavior. Here it is.
PART I
One of the most fateful errors of our age is the belief that
"the probiem of production" has been solved. Not only is
13
systems there is at present not much to choose between
them.
The arising of this error, so egregious and so finnly
rooted, is closely cormected with the philosophical, not to
say religious, changes during the last three or four cen-
turies in man's attitude to nature. I should perhaps say:
Western man's attitude to nature, but since the whole
world is now in a process of westemisation, the more
generalised statement appears to be justified. Modem man
does not experience himself as a part of nature but as
an outside forcé destined to domínate and conquer it. He
even taiks of a battle with nature, forgetting that, if he
won the battle, he would find himself on the losing side.
Until quite recently, the battle seemed to go well enough
to give him the illusion of unlimited powers, but not so
well as to bring the possibility of total victory into view.
This has now come into view, and many people, albeit
only a minority, are beginning to realise what this means
for the continued existence of humanity.
The illusion of unlimited powers, nourished by astonish-
ing scientific and technological achievements, has pro-
duced the concurrent illusion of having solved the
problem of production. The latter illusion is based on the
failure to distinguish between income and capital where
this distinction matters most. Every economist and busi-
nessman is familiar with the distinction, and applies it
conscientiously and with considerable subtlety to all eco-
—
nomic affairs except where it really matters: namely,
the irreplaceable capital which man has not made, but
simply found, and without which he can do nothing.
A businessman would not consider a firm to have
solved its problems 9f production and to have achieved
viability if he saw that it was rapidly consuming its
capital. How, then, could we overlook this vital fact
when it comes to that very big firm, the economy of
Spaceship Earth and, in particular, the economies of its
rich passengers?
14
One reason for overlooking this vital fact is that we are
estranged from reality and inclined to treat as valueless
everything that we have not made ourselves. Even the
great Dr. Marx fell into this devastating error when he
formulated the so-called "labour theory of valué.'* Now
we have indeed laboured to make some of the capital
—
which today helps us to produce a large fund of scien-
tifíc, technological, and other knowledge; an elabórate
physical infrastructure; innumerable types of sophisti-
cated capital equipment, etc. —
but all this is but a smaU
part of the total capital we are using. Far larger is the
capital provided by nature and not by man —
and we do
not even recognize it as such. This larger part is now
being used up at an alarming rate, and that is why it is an
absurd and suicidal error to believe, and act on the belief,
that the problem of production has been solved.
Let US take a closer look at this "natural capital.**
First of all, and most obviously, there are the fossil fuels.
No one, I am sure, will deny that we are treating them
as income ítems although they are undeniably capital
ítems. If we treated them as capital ítems» we should be
concemed with conservation; we should do everything ín
oür power to try and minimize their current rate of use;
we might be saymg, for instance, that the money
obtained from the. realisation of these assets — these
irreplaceable assets — ^must be placed into a special fund
to be devoted exclusívely to the evolution of production
methods and pattems of livíng which do not depend on
fossil fuels at all or depend on them only to a very slight
extent These and many other things we should be doing
íf we treated fossil fuels as capital and not as income.
15
off the colusión course on which we are moving with
ever-increasing speed —we happily
talk of unlimited prog-
ress along the beaten track, of "education for leisure"
in the rich countries, and of **the transfer of technology"
to the poor countries.
The liquidation of these capital assets is proceeding
so rapidly that even in the allegedly richest coimtry in
the world, the United States of America, there are many
worried men, right up to the White House, calling for the
massive conversión of coal into oil and gas, demanding
ever more gigantic efforts to search for and exploit the
remaining treasures of the earth. Look at the figures that
are being put forward under the heading "World Fuel
Requirements in the Year 2000." If we are now using
something like 7000 million tons of coal equivalent, the
need in twenty-eight years' time will be three times as
large —around 20,000 million tons What are twenty-eight
I
16
— —
But what it will be asked about the income fuels?
Yes, índeed, what about tbem? Cuirently, they contribute
(reckoned in calones) less than four per cent to the worid
total. In the foreseeable future they will have to contrib-
ute seventy, eighty, ninety per cent. To do something on
a small scale one thing: to do it on
is a gigantic scale is
17
fuels, we have indeed been living on the capital of living
nature for some time, but at a fairly modest rate. It is
only since the cnd of World War II that we have
succeeded in increasing this rate to alarming proportions.
In comparíson with what is going on now and what has
been going on, progressively, during the last quarter of a
century, all the industrial activities of mankind up to, and
including, World War n are as nothing. The next four or
five years are likely to see more industrial production,
taking the worid as a whole, than all of mankind accom-
plished up to 1945. In other words, quite recently — so
recently that most of us have hardly yet become con-
scious of it — there has been a unique quantitative jimip
in industrial production.
Partly as a cause and also as an effect, there has also
been a unique qualitative jump. Our scientists and tech-
nologists have leamed to compound substances unknown
to nature. Against many of them, nature is virtually
defenceless. There are no natural agents to attack and
break them down. It is as if aborigines were suddenly
attacked with machine-gun fire: their bows and arrows
are of no avail. These substances, imknown to nature,
owe their almost magical effectiveness precisely to
nature's defencelessness —
and that accounts also for theii
dangerous ecological impact. It is only in the last twenty
years or so that they have made their appearance in bulk.
Because they have no natural enemies, they tend to
accumulate, and the long-term consequences of this
accumulation are in many cases known to be extremely
dangerous, and in other cases totally unpredictable.
In other words, the changes of the last twenty-five years,
both in the quantity and in the quality of man's industrial
processes, have produced an entirely new situation a situ- —
ation resulting not from our failures but from what we
thought were our greatest successes. And this has come so
suddenly that we hardly noticed the fact that we were very
rapidly using up a certain kind of irreplaceable capital
18
asset, namely the tolerance margins which benign nature
always provides.
Now let me retum
to the question of "income fuels"
with which had previously dealt in a somewhat cavalier
I
19
materials in ever-increasing quantities will be made entirely
safe; also that be the task of politicians and social
it will
scíentists to créate a world society in which wars or civil
disturbances can never happen. Again, it is a proposition
to solve one problem simply by shifting it to another
sphere, the sphere of everyday human behaviour. And this
20
rcfuse to accept all three parts of my argument, I suggest
that any one of them suñices to make my case.
And what is my case? Simply that our most important
task is to get off our present colusión course. And who is
there to tackle such a task? I think every one of us,
whether oíd or young, powerful or powerless, rich or poor,
influential or iminfluential. To
about the future is
talk
useful only if it leads to action now. And what
can we do
now, while we are still in the position of "never having had
it so good"? To say the least —
which is already very much
— we must thoroughly understand the problem and begin
to see the possibility of evolving a new life-style, with new
methods of production and new pattems of consumption:
a life-style designed for permanence. To give only three
preliminary examples: in agriculture and horticulture, we
can interest ourselves in the perf ection of production meth-
ods which are biologically sound, build up soil fertility, and
produce health, beauty and permanence. Productivity will
then look after itself. In industry, we can interest ourselves
in the evolution of small-scale technology, relatively non-
violent technology, "technology with a human face," so
that people have a chance to enjoy themselves while they
are working, instead of working solely for their pay packet
and hoping, usually forlornly, for enjoyment solely during
their leisure time. In industr>', again —and, surely, industry
is the pace-setter of modem life —we can interest ourselves
in new forms of partnership between management and
men, even forms of common ownership.
We often hear it said that we are entering the era of
"the Learning Society." Let us hope this is true. We still
have to leam how to live peacefully, not only with our
fellow menbut also with nature and, above all, with those
Higher Powers which have made nature and have made
us; for, assurediy, we have not come about by accident and
certainly have not made ourselves.
The themes which have been merely touched upon in
21
this chapter wiÜ have to be further elaborated as we go
along. Few people will be easily convinced that the chal-
lenge to man's future cannot be met by making marginal
adjustments here or there, or, possibly, by changing the
political system.
The following chapter is an attempt to look at the whole
22
2
Peace and Permanence
23
help the poor, because this is the way by which they wiU
become richer still.
Gandhi used to talk disparagingly of "dreaming of sys-
tems so perfect that no one wiU need to be good." But is it
not precisely this dream which we can now implement in
reality with our marvellous powers of science and technol-
ogy? Why ask for virtues, which man may never acquire,
when scientific rationality and technical competence are all
that is needed?
Instead of listening to Gandhi, are we not more inclined
to listen toone of the most influential economists of our
century, the great Lord Keynes? In 1930, during the world-
wide economic depression, he feit moved to speculate on
the "economic possibilities for our grandchildren" and con-
cluded that the day might not be all that far off when
everybody would be rich. We shall then, he said, "once
more valué ends above means and prefer the good to the
useful."
"But beware!" he continued. *The time for all this is not
yet. For at least another hundred years we must pretend
to ourselvesand to every one that fair is foul and foul is
fair; is useful and fair is not. Avance and usury
for foul
and precaution must be our gods for a little longer still.
For only they can lead us out of the tunnel of economic
necessity into daylight."
This was written forty years ago and since then, of
course, things have speeded up considerabiy. Maybe we do
not even have to wait for another sixty years until univer-
sal plenty will be attained. In any case, the Keynesian
message is clear enough: Beware! Ethical considerations
are not merely irrelevant, they are an actual hindrance,
"for foul is useful and fair is not." The time for faimess
is not yet. The road to heaven is paved with bad
intentions.
I shall now consider this proposition. It can be divided
into three parts:
24
—
First, that universal prosperity is possible;
Second, that its attainment is possible on the basis of
the materialist philosophy of "enrich your-
selves'*;
Third, that this is the road to peace.
25
—
TABLE I (1966)
26
foiir, half of which would be attributable to population
mercase and half to increased consumption per head.
Th's half-and-half split is interesting enough. But the
split between the "rich" and the "poor" is even more inter-
27
knowledge of fossil fuel reserves this is an implausible
figure, even if we assume that one-quarter or one-third of
the world total would come from nuclear fission.
It is olear that the "rich" are in the process of stripping
the world of its once-for-all endowment of relatively
cheap and simple fuels. It is their continuing economic
growth which produces ever more exorbitant demands,
with the result that the world's cheap and simple fuels
could easily become dear and scarce long before the poor
countries had acquired the wealth, education, industrial
sophistication,and power of capital accumulation needed
for the application of altemative fuels on any significant
scale.
Exploratory calculations, of course, do not prove any-
thing. A
proof about the future is in any case impossible,
and has been sagely remarked that all predictions are
it
28
ral gas, or even coal. And why should nuclear energy be
confinad to supplying one-quarter or one-third of total
requirements? The problem can thus be shifted to another
plañe, but it refuses to go away. For the consumption of
29
world, because it contains within itself no limiting princi-
pie, while the environment in which it is placed is strictly
already.
We find, therefore, that the idea of unlimited economic
growth, more and more until everybody is saturated with
wealth, needs to be seriously questioned on at least two
counts: the availability of basic resources and, altema-
tively or additionally, the capacity of the
environment to
cope with the degree of interference implied. So much
30
about the physical-material aspect of the matter. Let us
now tura to certain non-material aspects.
31
After a while, even the Gross National Product refuses to
rise any further, not because of scientific or technological
failure, but because of a creeping paralysis of non-coopera-
tion, as expressed in various types of escapism on the part,
not only of the oppressed and exploited, but even of highly
privileged groups.
One can go on for a long time deploring the irrationality
and stupidity of men and women in high positions or low
— "if only people would realise where their real interests
lie!" But why do they not realise this? Either because their
intelligence has been dimmed by greed and envy, or
because in their heart of hearts they understand that their
real interests lie somewhere quite different. There is a
revolutionary saying that "Man shall not Uve by bread
alone but by every word of God."
Here again, nothing can be "proved.** But does it still
look probable or plausible that the grave social diseases
infecting many rich societies today are merely passing
phenomena which an able govemment — if only we could
get a really able government! —could eradicate by simply
making faster use of science and technology or a more
radical use of the penal system?
I suggest that the foundations of peace cannot be laid
by universal prosperity, in the modem sense, because such
prospérity, if attainable at all, is attainable only by culti-
vating such drives of human nature as greed and envy,
which destroy and thereby
intelligence, happiness, serenity,
the peacefulness of man.
could wcll be that rich people
It
32
ing for peace unless he is working primarily for the
restoration of wisdom. The assertion that "foul is usfeul
and fair is not" is the antithesis of wisdom. The hope that
the pursuit of goodness and virtue can be postponed until
we have attained universal prosperity and that by the
single-minded pursuit of wealth, without bothering our
heads about spiritual and moral questions, we could estab-
lishpeace on earth, is an unrealistic, unscientific, and
irrational hope. The exclusión of wisdom from econom-
ics, science, and technology was something which we
could perhaps get away with for a little while, as long as
we were relatively unsuccessful; but now that we have
become very successful, the problem of spiritual and
moral truth moves into the central position.
From an economic point of view, the central concept
of wisdom is permanence. We must study the economics
of permanence. Nothing makes economic sensc unless its
continuance for a long time can be projected without
ninning into absurdities. There can be "growth" towards
a limited objective, but there cannot be unlimited, gen-
eralised growth. It is more than likely, as Gandhi said,
that "Earth provides enough to satisfy every man's need,
but not for every man's greed." Permanence is incom-
patible with a predatory attitude which rejoices in the fact
that "what were luxuries for our fathers have become
necessities for us."
The and expansión of needs is the antithesis
cultivation
of wisdom. It is freedom and peace.
also the antithesis of
Every increase of needs tends to increase one's depend-
ence on outside forces over which one cannot have con-
trol, and therefore increases existential fear. Only by a
reduction of needs can one promote a genuine reduction
in those tensions which are the ultímate causes of strife
and war.
The economics of permanence implies a profound reori-
entation of science and technology, which have to open
their doors to wisdom and, in fact, have to incorpórate
33
wisdom into their very structure. Scientific or technologi-
cal "solutions" which poison the environment or degrade
the social structure and man himself are of no benefit, no
matter how brilliantly conceived or how great their super-
ficial attraction. Ever-bigger machines, entailing ever-big-
ger concentrations of economic power and exerting ever-
greater violence against the environment, do not represen!
progress: they are a denial of wisdom. Wisdom demands
a new orientation of ^cience and technology towards the
organic, the gentle, the non-violent, the elegant and beau-
tiful. Peace, as has often been said, is indivisible —how
then could peace be built on a foundation of reckless
Science and violent technology? We must look for a revolu-
tíon technology to give us inventions and machines
in
which reverse the destructive trends now threatening us al!.
34
power m a few hands and tum the masses into mere
machine minders, if indeed they do not make them
unemployed."
Suppose it becomes the acknowledged purpose of inven-
tors and engineers, observed Aldous Huxley, to provide
ordinary people with the means of "doing profitable and
intrinsically significant work, of helping men and women
to achieve independence from bosses, so that they may
become their own employers, or members of a self-
35
general frustration and alienation, with soaring crime rates,
and so forth.
The second requirement is suitability for small-scale
application. On the probiem of "scale," Professor Leopold
Kohr has written brilliantly and convincingly; its relevance
to the economics of permanence is obvious. Small-scale
operations, no matter how numerous, are always less likely
to be harmful to the natural environment than large-scale
ones, simply because their individual forcé is small in rela-
tion to the recuperative forces of nature. There is wisdom
only on account of the smallness and patchi-
in smallness if
ness of human knowledge, which relies on experimeijt far
more than on understanding. The greatest danger invari-
ably arises from the ruthless application, on a vast scale,
of partial knowledge such as we are cuirently witnessing
in the application of nuclear energy, of the new chemistry
in agriculture, of transportaíion technology, and countless
other things.
Although even small communities are sometimes guilty
of causing serious erosión, generally as a result of igno-
rance, this is trifling in comparison with the devastations
caused by gigantic groups motivated by greed, envy, and
the lust for power. It is, moreover, obvious that men orga-
nised in small units will take better care of their bit of
land or other natural resources than anonymous com-
panies megalomanic governments which pretend to
or
themselves that the whole universe is their legitimate
quarry.
The is perhaps the most important of
third requirement
all — methods and equipment should be such as to
that
leave ampie room for human creativity. Over the last
hundred years no one has spoken more insistently and
warningly on this subject than have the Román pontiffs.
What becomes of man if the process of production "takes
away from work any hint of humanity, making of it a
merely mechan ical activity"? The worker himself is turned
into a perversión of a free being.
36
—
"And so bodily labour [said Pius XI] which even after
original sin was decreed by Providence for the good of
man's body and soul, is in many instances changed into an
instrument of perversión; for from the factory dead matter
goes out improved, whereas men there are corrupted and
degraded.**
Again, the subfect is so large that I cannot do more
than touch upon it. Above anything else there is need for
a proper philosophy of work which understands work not
as that which it has indeed become, an inhuman chore as
soon as possible to be abolished by automation, but as
something "decreed by Providence for the good of man's
body and soul.*' Next to the family, it is work and the
relationships established by work that are the true founda-
tions of society. If the foundations are unsound, how could
society be sound? And if society is sick, how could it fail
to be a danger to peace?
"War is a judgement," said Dorothy L. Sayers, "that
overtakes societies when they have been living upon ideas
that conflict too violently with the laws governing the
universe. . Never think that wars are irrational catastro-
. .
37
—
38
overeóme by gaining preeminence in wealth, power,
it
39
3
The Role of Economics
40
the University's curriculum a science "so prone to usurp
the rest"; even Henry Drummond of Albury Park, who
endowed the professorship in 1825, felt it necessary to
make it clear that he expected the University to keep the
new study "in its proper place." The ^st professor, Nassau
Sénior, was certainly not to be kept in an inferior place.
Immediately, in his inaugural lecture, he predicted that
the new science "will rank in public estimation among the
first of moral sciences in interest and
and in utility"
claimed that "the pursuit of wealth is, to the mass of
. . .
41
are thought of as either saboteurs or fools. Cali a thing
immoral or ugly, soul-destroying or a degradation of man,
a peril to the peace of the worid or to the well-being of
future generations; as long as you have not shown it to be
"uneconomic" you have not really questioned its right to
exist, grow, and prosper.
42
whether an activity carried on by a group within society
yields a profit to society as a whole. Even nationalised
industries are not coosidered from this more comprehen-
sive point of view. Every one of them is given a financial
target —^which is, in fact, an obligation —
and is expected
to pursue this target without regard to any damage it
might be inflicting on other parts of the economy. In fact,
the prevailing creed, held with equal fervour by all politi-
cal parties, is that the common good will necessarily be
maximised if everybody, every industry and trade, whether
nationalised or not, strives to eam an acceptable "return"
on the capital employed. Not even Adam Smith had a
more implicit faith in the "hidden hand" to ensure that
"what is good for General Motors is good for the United
States."
However that may be, about the fragmentary nature of
the judgements of economics there can be no doubt what-
ever. Even within the narrow compass of the economic
calculus, these judgements are necessarily and methodi-
cally narrow. For one thing, they give vastly more weight
to the short than to the long term, because in the long
term, as Keynes put it with cheerful brutality, we are all
dead. And then, second, they are based on a definition of
cost which exeludes all "free goods," that is to say, the
entire God-given environment, except for those parts of
it that have been privately appropriated. This means that
43
mentally that of prívate profit-making, and this means that
it is inherent in the methodology of economics to ignore
man's dependence on the natural world.
Another way of stating this is to say that economics
deals with goods and services from the point of view of the
market, where willing buyer meets willing seller. The buyer
is essentially a bargain hunter; he is not concemed with the
44
make máximum use of this freedom from responsibil-
the
ity. Ifa buyer refused a good bargain because he suspected
that the cheapness of the goods in question stemmed from
exploitation or other despicable practices (except theft),
he would be open to the criticism of behaving "uneconom-
ically," which is viewed as nothing less than a fall from
grace. Economists and others are wont to treat such
eccentric behaviour with derision if not indignation. The
religión of economics has its own code of ethics, and the
FirstGk)mmandment is to behave "economically" in any —
casewhen you are producing, selling, or buying. It is only
when the bargain hunter has gone home and becomes a
consumer that the First Commandment no longer applies:
he is then encouraged to "enjoy himself in any way he '
45
a procedure by which the higher reduced to the level of is
46
words, we may expect that economics must derive its aims
and objectives from a study of man, and that it must
derive at least a large part of its methodology from a
study of nature.
In the next chapter, I shall attempt to show how the
conclusions and prescriptions of economics change as the
underlying picture of man and his purpose on earth
changes. In this chapter, I confine myself to a discussion
of the second part of meta-economics, i.e. the way in
which a vital part of the methodology of economics has
to be derived from a s'tudy of nature. As I have empha-
sised already,on the market all goods are treated the same,
because the market is essentially an institution for unlim-
ited bargain hunting, and this means that it is inherent in
the methodology of modem economics, which is so largely
market-oriented, to ignore man's dependence on the natu-
ral world. Professor E. H. Phelps Brown, in his Presiden-
tial Address to the Royal Economic Society on "The
Underdevelopment of Economics," talked about "the
smallness of the contribution that the most conspicuous
developments of economics in the last quarter of a cen-
tury have made to the solution of the most pressing prob-
lems of the times," and among these problems he lists
"checking the adverse effects on the environment and the
quálity of life of industrialism, population growth and
urbanism."
As a matter of fact, to talk of "the smallness of the con-
tribution" is employ an euphemism, as there is no con-
to
tribution at on the contrary, it would not be unfair to
all;
47
ble to develop any economic theory at all, unless one were
prepared to disregard a vast array of qualitative distinc-
tions. But it should be just as obvious that the total
suppression of qualitative distinctions, wbile it makes
theorising easy, at the same time makes it totally sterile.
Most of the "conspicuous developments of economics in
the last quarter of a century" (referred to by Professor
Phelps Brown) are in the direction of quantification, at
the expense of the understanding of qualitative d;fferences.
Indeed, one might say that economics has become increas-
ingly intolerant of the latter, because they do not fit into
its method and make demands on the practical under-
standing and the power of insight of economists, which
they are unwilling or unable to fulfil. For example, having
established by his purely quantitative methods that the
Gross National Product of a country has risen by, say, five
per cent, the economist-tumed-econometrician is unwill-
ing, and generally unable, to face the question of whether
this is to be taken as a good thing or a bad thing. He
would lose all his certainties if he even entertained such a
question: growth of GNP must be a good thing, irrespec-
tive of what has grown and who, if anyone, has benefited.
The idea that there could be pathological growth,
unhealthy growth, disruptive or destructive growth, is to
him a perverse idea which must not be allowed to surface.
A small minority of economists is at present beginning to
question how much further "growth" will be possible,
since infinite growth in a finite environment is an obvious
impossibility; but even they cannot get away from the
purely quantitative growth concept. Instead of insisting on
the primacy of qualitative distinctions, they simply sub-
stitute non-growth for growth, that is to say, one empti-
ness for another.
It is of course true that quality is much more difñcult to
"handle" than quantity, just as the exercise of judgement
is a higher function than the ability to count and calcúlate.
48
certainly more easily defined than qualitative differences;
their concreteness is beguiling and gives them the appear-
"Goods"
primary secondary
49
goods, because the latter presuppose the availability of the
former. An expansión of man's ability to bring forth sec-
ondary producís is useless iinless preceded by an expansión
50
fact, without going into any further details, it can be said
that economics, as currently constituted, fully applies only
to manufactures (category 3), but it is being applied
without discrimination to all goods and services, because
an appreciation of the essential, qualitative differences
between the four categories is entirely lacking.
These differences may be called meta-economic, inas-
much as they have to be recognised before econoraic
analysis begins. Even more important is the recognition of
the existence of "goods*' which never appear on the
market, because they cannot be, or have not been, pri-
vately appropriated, but are nonetheless an essential
precondition of all human activity, such as air, water, the
soil, and in fact the whole framework of living nature.
51
As we have economics is a "derived" science
seen,
which accepts from what I cali meta-
instructions
economics. As the instructions are changed, so changes
the content of economics. In the following chapter, we
shall explorewhat economic laws and what definitions of
the concepts "economic" and "uneconomic" result when
the meta-economic basis of Western materialism is aban-
doned and the teaching of Buddhism is put in its place.
The cholee of Buddhism for this purpose is purely inci-
dental; the teachings of Christianity, Islam, or Judaism
could have been used just as well as those of any other
of the great Eastem traditions.
52
4
Buddhist Economics
53
that economic laws are as free from "metaphysics** or
"valúes" as the law of gravitation. We need not, however,
get involved in arguments of methodology. Instead, let us
take some fundamentáis and see what they look like when
viewed by a modera economist and a Buddhist economist.
There is universal agreement that a fundamental source
of wealth is human labour. Now, the modera economist
has been brought up to consider "labour" or work as little
more than a necessary evil. From the point of view of the
employer, it is in any case simply an item of cost, to be
reduced to a minimum if it cannot be eliminated alto-
gether, say, by automation. From the point of view of the
workman, it is a "disutility"; to work is to make a sacrifice
of one's leisure and comfort, and wages are a kind of
compensation for the sacrifice. Henee the ideal from the
point of view of the employer is to have output without
employees, and the ideal from the point of view of the
employee is to have income without employment.
The consequences of these attitudes both in theory and
in practice are, of course, extremely far-reaching. If the
ideal with regard to work is to get rid of it, every method
that "reduces the work load" is a good thing. The most
potent method, short of automation, is the so-called "divi-
sión of labour" and the classical example is the pin factory
eulogised in AdamSmith's Wealth of Nations.^ Here it is
not a matter of ordinary specialisation, which mankind has
practised from time immemorial, but of dividing up every
complete process of production into minute parts, so that
the final product can be produced at great speed without
anyone having had to contribute more than a totally
insignificant and, in most cases, unskilled movement of his
limbs.
The Buddhist point of view takes the function of work
to be at least threefold: to give a man a chance to utilise
and develop his faculties; to enable him to overeóme his
ego-centredness by joining with other people in a common
task; and to bring forth the goods and services needed for
54
a becoming existence. Again, the consequences that flow
from this view are endless. To organise work in such a
manner that it becomes meaningless, boring, stultifying,
or nerve-racking for the worker would be little short of
criminal; it would indicate a greater concern with goods
than with people, an evil lack of compassion and a soul-
destroying degree of attachment to the most primitive side
of this worldly existence. EquaUy, to strive for leisure
as an altemative to work would be considered a complete
misunderstanding of one of the basic truths of human
existence, namely that work and leisure are complemen-
tary parts of the same living process and cannot be
separated without destroying the joy of work and the
bhss of leisure.
From the Buddhist point of view, there are therefore
two types of mechanisation which must be clearly dis-
tinguished: one that enhances a man's skill and power and
one that tums the work of man over to a mechanical
slave, leaving man in a position of having to serve the
slave. How one from the other? "The craftsman
to tell the
himself," says Ananda Coomaraswamy, a man equally
competent to talk about the modem West as the ancient
East, "can always, if allowed to, draw the delicate distinc-
tion between the machine and the tool. The carpet loom
is a tool, a contrivance for holding warp threads at a
stretch for the pile to be woven round them by the
craftsmen*s fingers; but the power loom is a machine, and
its significance as a destróyer of culture lies in the fact
that it does the essentially human part of the work."^ It
is clear, therefore, that Buddhist economics must be very
different from the economics of modem materialism, since
the Buddhist sees the essence of civilisation not in a
multiplication of wants but in the purification of human
same time, is formed primar-
character. Character, at the
ily by a man's work. And work, properly conducted in
conditions of human dignity and freedom, blesses those
who do it and equally their products. The Indian
55
a
of. It directs his free will along the proper course and dis-
ciplines the animal in him into progressive channels. It
ñirnishes an excellent background for man to display his
scale of valúes and develop his personality.®
If a man
has no chance of obtaining work he is in a
desperate position, not simply because he lacks an income
but because he lacks this nourishing and enlivening factor
of disciplinad work which nothing can replace. A modera
economist may engage in highly sophisticated calculations
on whether fuU employment "pays" or whether it might
be more "economic" to run an economy at less than
full employment so as to ensure a greater mobility of
56
planning for employment, and the primary purpose oí
full
57
there is, the more time and strength is left for artistic
creativity. It would be highly uneconomic, for instance, to
go in for complicated tailoring, like the modern West,
when a much more beautiful effect can be achieved by
the skilful draping of imcut material. It would be the
height of foUy to make material so that it should wear
58
resources are obviously less likely to be at each other's
throats than people depending upon a high rate of use.
Equally, people who live in highly self-sufficient local
59
off from any form of lifc other than human, the feeling of
belongÍDg to an ecosystem is not revi ved. This results in a
harsh and improvident treatment of things upon which we
ultimately depend, such as water and trees.»
60
sider it a great economic achievementif all European art
61
currently practised without regard to religious and spirit-
ual valúes, is actually producing agreeable results. As far
62
5
A Question of Size
63
became possible only through this unification? All the
same, the German-speaking Swiss and the German-speak-
ing Austrians, who did not join, did just as well economi-
cally, and if we make a list of all the most prosperous
countries in the worid, we find that most of them are very
small; whereas a list of all the biggest countries in the
world shows most of them to be very poor indeed. Here
again, there is food for thought.
And third, I was brought up on the theory of the "econ-
—
omies of scale" that with industries and firms, just as
with nations, there is an irresistible trend, dictated by
modem technology, for units to become ever bigger. Now,
it is quite true that today there are more large organisa-
tions and probably also bigger organisations than ever
before in history; but the number of small units is also
growing and certainly not declining in countries like
Britain and the United States, and many of these small
units are highly prosperous and provide society with most
of the really fruitful new developments. Again, it is not
altogether easy to reconcile theory and practice, and the
situation as regards this whole issue of size is certainly
puzzling to anyone brought up on these three concurrent
theories.
Even today, we are generally told that gigantic organi-
sations are inescapably necessary; but when we look
closely we can notice that as soon as great size has been
created there is often a strenuous attempt to attain
smallness within bigness. The great achievement of Mr.
Sloan of General Motors was to structure this gigantic
firm in such a manner that it became, in fact, a federa-
tion of fairly reasonably sized firms. In the British
National Coal Board, one of the biggest firms of Western
Europe, something very similar was attempted imder the
chairmanship of Lord Robens; strenuous efforts were
made to evolve a structure which would maintain the
unity of one big organisation and at the same time créate
the "climate" or feeling of there being a federation of
64
.
65
requirement when it comes to the question of size: there
is no single answer. different purposes man needs
For his
many both small ones and large ones,
different structures,
some exclusive and some comprehensive. Yet people find
it most diíficult to keep two seemingly opposite necessities
66
difficult questions. It is not possible to programme a Com-
puter and get the answer. The really serious matters of
life cannot be calculated. We cannot directly calcúlate
what is right; but we jolly well know what is wrong! We
can recognise right and wrong at the extremes, although
we cannot normally judge them finely enough to say:
"This ought to be five per cent more/* or "that ought to be
five per cent less."
say that the upper limit of what is desirable for the size of
a city is probably something of the order of half a million
iiAabitants. It is quite clear that above such a size noth-
its own sake but also because it is, to my mind, the most
67
and Communications. A highly developed transport and
Communications system has one immensely powerful
effect: it makes people footloose,
Millions of people start moving about, deserting the
rural áreas and the smaller towns to follow the city lights,
to go to the big city, causing a pathological growth. Take
the country in which all this is perhaps most exemplified
68
—
69
logical development, which has, of course, many roots,
but one of its clearly visible roots lies in the great achieve-
ments of modem technology in terms of transpon and
Communications.
While people, with an easy-going kind of logic, believe
that fast transpórt and instantaneous Communications open
up a new dimensión of freedom (which they do in some
rather trivial respects), they overlook the fact that these
achievements also tend to destroy freedom, by making
everything extremely vulnerable and extremely insecure,
unless conscious policies are developed and conscious
action is taken to mitigate the destnictive effects of these
technological developments.
Now, these destnictive effects are obviously most severe
in large countries, because, as we have seen, frontiers pro-
duce "stnicture," and it is a much bigger decisión for
someone to cross a frontier, to uproot himself from his
native land and try and put down roots in another land,
than to move within the frontiers of his country. The
factor of footlooseness is, therefore, the more serious, the
bigger the country. Its destnictive effects can be traced
both in the rich and in the poor countries. In the rich
countries such as the United States of America, it pro-
duces, as already mentioned, *'megalopolis." It also pro-
duces a rapidly increasing and ever more intractable
problem of "drop-outs," of people, who, having become
footloose, cannot find a place anywhere in society. Directly
connected with produces an appalling problem of
this, it
70
populatíon of 175,000 in the early 1920s, just fifty years
ago. Its population now approaching three million. The
is
71
a non-problem? There is no such thing as the viability of
States or of nations, there ¡s only a probiem of viability
of people: people, actual persons like you and me, are
viable when they can stand on their own feet and eam
their keep. You do not make non-viable people viable by
putting large numbers of them into one huge community,
and you do not make viable people non-viable by splitting
a large community into a number of smaller, more intí-
mate, more coherent and more manageable groups. All this
is perfectly obvious and there is absolutely nothing to
argüe about. Some people ask: "What happens when a
country, composed of one rich province and several poor
ones, falls apart because the rich province secedes?'* Most
probably the answer is: "Nothing very much happens."
The rich will continué to be rich and the poor will con-
tinué to be poor. "But if, before secession, the rich prov-
ince had subsidised the poor, what happens then?" Well
then, of course, the subsidy might stop. But the rich rarely
subsidise the poor; more often they exploit them. They
may not do so directly so much as through the terms of
trade. They may obscure the situation a little by a certain
redistribution of tax revenue or small-scale charity, but the
last thing they want to do is secede from the poor.
72
over the world, it has never been held that it had to annex
the whole world in order to do so.
What about the absolute necessity of having a large
intemal market? This again is an optical illusion if the
meaning of "large" is conceived in terms of political
boundaries. Needless to say, a prosperous market is better
than a poor one, but whether that market is outside the
political boimdaries or inside, makes on the whole very
little difference. I am not aware, for instance, that Ger-
73
not brought forth, their only choice is
If this effort is
either to remain in their miserable condition where they
are, or to migrate into the big city where their condition
will be even more miserable. It is a strange phenomenon
indeed that the conventional wisdom of present-day eco-
nomics can do nothing to help the poor.
Invariably it proves that only such policies are viable as
have in fact the result of making those already rich and
powerful, richer and more powerful. It proves that indus-
trial development only pays if it is as near as possible to
the capital city or another very large town, and not in the
rural áreas. It proves that large projects are invariably
more economic than small ones, and it proves that capital-
intensive projects are invariably to be preferred as against
labour-intensive ones. The economic calculus, as applied by
present-day économics, forces the industrialist to elimínate
the himian factor because machines do not make mistakes,
which people do. Henee the enonnous effort at automation
and the drive for ever-larger units. This means that those
who have nothing to sell but their labour remain in the
weakest possible bargaining position. The conventional
wisdom of what is now taught as économics by-passes the
poor, the very people for whom development is really
needed. The économics of giantism and automation is a
left-over of nineteenth-century conditions and nineteenth-
century thinking and it is totally incapable of solving any
of the real problems of today. An entirely new system of
thought is needed, a system based on attention to people,
—
and not primarily attention to goods (the goods will
look after themselves!). It could be simmied up in the
phrase, "production by the masses, rather than mass pro-
duction." What was impossible, however, in the nineteenth
century, is possible now. And what was in fact —
if not
74
degradation —
a fight in intímate contact with actual peo-
pie, with individuáis, families, small groups, rather than
States and other anonymous abstractions. And this presup-
poses a political and organisational structure that can
provide this intimacy.
What is the meaning of democracy, freedom, human
dignity, standard of living, self-realisation, fulfilment? Is it
75
1
PART 1
Resources
7
The Greatest Resource —
Education
the fact that man, not nature, who provides the pri-
it is
79
.
80
At one pole we have the literary intellectuals . . . at the
other the scientists." He deplores the "gulf of mutual
incomprehension" between these two groups and wants it
brídged. It is quite clear how he thinks this "bridging"
81
ress, then there must be something more to education than
Lord Snow suggests. Science" and engineering produce
"know-how"; but "know-how" is nothing by itself; it is a
means without an end, a mere potentiality, an unfinished
sentence. "Know-how" is no more a culture than a piano
is music. Can education help us to finish the sentence, to
82
First of all, there is language. Each word is an idea. If
the language which seeps into us during our Dark Ages is
83
—
a judgement; others again are tacit assumptions or pre-
suppositions which may be very difficult to recognise.
I say, therefore, that we think with or through ideas and
that what we cali thinking is generally the application of
pre-existing ideas to a given situation or set of facts. When
we think about, say, the political situation we apply to
that situation our political ideas, more or less systemati-
cally, and attempt to make that situation "intelligible" to
ourselves by means of these ideas. Similarly everywhere
else. Some of the ideas are ideas of valué, that is to say,
84
.
One sticks one's finger into the soil to tell by the smell
in what land one is: my finger into existence
I stick — it
85
phy that rejects them can hope to stand. . . . Only on the
firm foundation of unyielding despair can the soul's habi-
tation henceforth be safely built." Sir Fred Hoyle, the
astronomer, talks of "the truly dreadful situation in which
we find ourselves. Here we are in this whoUy fantastic
universe with scarcely a clue as to whether our existence
has any real significance."
Estrangement breeds loneliness and despair^ the
"encounter with nothingness," cynicism, empty gestures
of defiance, as we can see in the greater part of existential-
istphilosophy and general literature today. Or it suddenly
turns —
as I have mentioned before —
into the ardent
adoption of a fanatical teaching which, by a monstrous
simplification of reality, pretends to answer all questions.
So, what is Never has science
the cause of estrangement?
been more triumphant; never has man's power over his
environment been more complete ñor his progress faster.
It cannot be a lack of know-how that causes the despair
not only of religious thinkers like Kierkegaard but also of
leading mathematicians and scientists like Russell and
Hoyle. We know how to do many things, but do we know
what to do? Ortega y Gasset put it succinctly: "We cannot
live on the human level without ideas. Upon them depends
what we do. Living is nothing more or less than doing one
thing instead of another." What, then, is education? It is
the transmission of ideas which enable man to choose
between one thing and another, or, to quote Oretega again,
"to live a Ufe which is something above meaningless trag-
edy or inward disgrace.'*
How could, for instance, a knowledge of the Second Law
of Thermodynamics help us in this? Lord Snow tells us
that when educated people deplore the "illiteracy of scien-
tists'* he sometimes asks "How many of them could
describe the Second Law of Thermodynamics?" The
response, he reports, is usually cold and negativo. "Yet,"
he says, "I was asking something which is about the
scientific equivalent of Have you read a work of Shake-
:
86
—a
by it.
87
—
he hears about the scientific revolution and ours being an
age of science, he tums to the so-calle*d humantties. Here
indeed he can find, if he is lucky, great and vital ideas to
fill his mind, ideas with which to think and through which
to make the world, society, and his own life intelligible. Let
US see what are the main ideas he is likely to find today. I
cannot attempt to make a complete list; so I shall confine
myself to the enumeration of six leading ideas, all stem-
ming from the nineteenth century, which still domínate, as
far as I can see, the mind^of "educated" people today.
88
matism, and affecting even mathematics, which has been
defined by Bertrand Russell as "the subject in which
we never know what we are talking about, or whether
what we say is true."
6. Finally there is the triumphant idea of positivism,
that validknowledge can be attained only through the
methodSs of the natural sciences and henee that no
knowledge is genuine unless it is based on generally
observable facts. Positivism, in other words, is solely
interested in "know-how" and denies the possibility of
objective knowledge about meaning and purpose of any
kind.
89
metaphysical doctrines, with the peculiar and ironical dis-
tinction that they deny the validity of all metaphysics,
including themselves.
What do these six "large*' ideas have in common,
besides their non-empirical, metaphysical nature? They all
assert that what had previously been taken
to be something
of a higher order is "nothing but" a more subtle
really
—
manifestation of the "lower" unless, indeed, the vcry dis-
tinction between higher and lower is denied. Thus man,
like the rest of the uni verse, is really nothing but an acci-
dental coUocation of atoms. The difference between a man
and a stone is little more than a deceptive appearance.
Man's highest cultural achievements are nothing but dis-
guised economic greed or the outflow of sexual frustra-
tions. In any case, it is meaningless to say that man should
aim at the "higher" rather than the "lower" because no
intelligible meaning can be attached to purely subjective
notions like "higher" or "lower," while the word "should"
is just a sign of authoritarian megalomanía.
The ideas of the fathers in the nineteenth century have
been visited on the third and fourth generations living in
the second half of the twentieth century. To their origina-
tors, these ideas were simply the result of their intellectual
processes. In the third and fourth generations, they have
become the very tools and Instruments through which the
world is being experienced and interpreted. Those that
bring forth new ideas are seldom ruled by them. But their
ideas obtain power over men's Uves in the third and fourth
generations when they have become a part of that great
mass of ideas, including language, which seeps into a per-
sonas mind during his "Dark Ages."
These nineteenth-century ideas are firmiy lodged in the
minds of practically everybody in the Western world today,
whether educated or uneducated. In the uneducated mind
they are still rather muddled and nebulous, too weak to
make the world intelligible. Henee the longing for educa-
tion, that is to say, for something that will lead us out of
90
the dark wood of our muddled ignorance into the light of
understanding.
I have said that a purely scientific education cannot do
this for US because it deals only with ideas of know-how,
whereas we need to understand why things are as they are
and what we are to do with our lives. What we learn by
studying a particular science is in any case too specific and
specialised for our wider purposes. So we tum to the
huraanities to obtain a clear view of the large and vital
ideas of our age. Even in the humanities we may get
bogged down in a mass of specialised scholarship, fumish-
ing our minds with lots of small ideas just as unsuitable as
the ideas which we might pick up from the natural sci-
ences. But we may also be more fortúnate (if fortúnate it
is) and find a teacher who will "clear our minds," clarify
the ideas —
the "large" and universal ideas already existent
in our —
minds and thus make the world intelligible for us.
Such a process would indeed deserve to be called "edu-
cation." And what do we get from it today? A view of
the world as a wasteíand in which there is no meaning or
purpose, in which man's consciousness is an unfortunate
cosmic accident, in which anguish and despair are the
only final realities. If by means of a real education man
manages to climb to what Ortega calis "the Height of Our
Times" or "the Height of the Ideas of our Times," he finds
himself in an abyss of nothingness. He may feel like echo-
ing Byron:
91
claimed to do away with metaphysics, are themselves a
bad, vicious, life-destroying type of metaphysics. We are
suffering from them as from a fatal disease. It is not tnie
that knowledge is sorrow. But poisonous errors bring un-
iimited sorrow in the third and fourth generation. The
errors are not in science but in the philosophy put forward
in the ñame of science. As Etienne Gilson put it more
than twenty years ago:
92
This passage can be applied, without change, to
present-day civilisation. We have become confused as to
what our convictions really are. The great ideas of the
nineteenth century may fill our minds in one. way or
another, but our hearts do not believe in them all the
same. Mind and heart are at war with one another, not,
as is commonly asserted, reason and faith. Our reason has
become beclouded by an extraordinary, blind and unrea-
sonable faith in a set of fantastic and life-destroying ideas
inheriíed from the nineteenth century. It is the foremost
task of our reason to recover a truer faith than that.
93
depth with which the subjects are usually presented, and
the absence of metaphysical awareness. The sciences are
being taught without any awareness of the presupposi-
tions of science, of the meaning and significance of sci-
entific laws, and of the place occupied by the natural
sciences within the whole cosmos of human thought. The
result is that the presuppositions of science are normally
mistaken for its findings. Economics is being taught with-
out any awareness of the view of human nature that
underlies present-day economic theory. In fact, many
economists are themselves unaware of the fact that such a
view is implicit in their teaching and that nearly all their
theories would have to change if that view changed. How
could there be a rational teaching of politics without
pressing all questions back to their metaphysical roots?
Political thinking must necessarily become confused and
end in "double-talk" if there is a continued refusal to
94
Education can help us only if it produces "whole men."
The tnily educated man is not a man who knows a bit of
everything, not even the man who knows all the details of
all subjects (if such a thing were possible) the "whole :
95
saved from despair, but landed in confusión. His funda-
mental convictions are confused; henee his actions, too,
are confused and uncertain. If he would only allow the
light of consciousness to fall on the centre and face the
question of his fundamental convictions, he could créate
order where there is disorder. That would "edúcate" him,
in the sense of leading him out of the darkness of his
metaphysical confusión.
I do not think, however, that this can be successfully
—
done unless he quite consciously accepts even if only pro-
visionally —
a number of metaphysical ideas which are
almost directly opposite to the ideas (stemming from the
nineteenth century) that have lodged in his mind. I shall
mention three examples.
While the nineteenth-century ideas deny or oblitérate
the hierarchy of levéis in the universe, the notion of an
hierarchical order is an indispensable instniment of under-
standing. Without the recognition of "Levéis of Being" or
"Grades of Significance" we cannot make the world intel-
ligible to ourselves ñor have we the slightest possibility
to define our own position, the position of man, in the
scheme of the universe. It is only when we can see the
world as a ladder, and when we can see man's position on
the ladder, that we can recognise a meaningful task for
—
man's life on earth. Maybe it is man's task or simply, if
—
you like, man's happiness to attain a higher degree of
realisation of his potentialities, a higher level of being or
"grade of significance" than that which comes to him
"naturally": we cannot even study this possibilty except
by recognising the existence of a hierarchical stnicture. To
the extent that we interpret the world through the great,
vital ideas of the nineteenth century, we are blind to these
differences of level, because we have been blinded.
As soon, however, as we accept the existence of "levéis
of being," we can readily understand, for instance, why
the methods of physical science cannot be applied to the
study of politics or economics, or why the findings of
96
physics — as Einstein recognised —have no phUosophical
implications.
If we accept the Aristotelian división of metaphysics
into ontology and epistemology, the proposition that there
are levéis of being is an ontological proposition; I now
add an epistemológica! one: the nature of our thinking is
97
the help of these higher forces that the opposites can be
reconciled Ln the living situation.
The physical sciences and mathematics are concerned
exclusively with convergent problems, That is why they
can progess cumulatively, and each new generation can
begin just where their forbears left ofií. The pnce, how-
ever, is a heavy one. Dealing exclusively with conver-
gent problems does not lead into life but away from it.
98
coming or reconciling opposites. They are divergent prob-
lems and have no solution in the ordinary sense of the
word. They demand of man not merely the employment
of his reasoning powers but the commitment of his whole
personality. Naturally, spurioiis solutions, by way of a
clever formula, are always being put forward; but they
never work for long, because they invariably neglect one
of the two opposites and thus tose the very quality of
human life. In economics, the solution offered may pro-
vide for freedom but not for planning, or vice versa. In
industrial organisation, it may provide for discipline but
not for workers' participation in management, or vice
versa. In politics, it might provide for leadership without
democracy or, again, for democracy without leadership.
To have to grapple with divergent problems tends to
be exhausting, worrying, and wearisome. Henee people
try to avoid it and to run away from it. A busy executive
who has been dealing with divergent problems all day
long will read a detective story or solve a crossword
puzzle on his journey home.He has been using his brain
all day; why does he go on using it? The answer is that
the detective and the crossword puzzle present
story
convergent problems, and thai is the relaxation. They
require a bit of brainwork, even difficult brainwork, but
they do not cali for this straining and stretching to a
higher level whichis the specific challenge of a divergent
99
good and evil, claiming that good is higher than evil.
Keynes; he surely had nobler gods. But ideas are the most
powerful things on earth, and it is hardly an exaggeration
100 .
to say that by now the gods he recommended have been
enthroned.
In ethics, as in so many other fields, we have recklessly
and wilfully abandoned our great classical-Christian herit-
age. We have even degraded the very words without
which cannot carry on, words like "virtue,'*
ethical discourse
"love," "temperance." As a result, we are totally ignorant,
totally uneducated in the subject that, of all conceivable
subjects, is the most important. We have no ideas to think
with and therefore are only too ready to believe that
ethics is a field where thinking does no good. Who knows
anything today of the Seven Deadly Sins or of the Four
Cardinal Virtues? Who could even ñame them? And if
these venerable, oíd ideas are thought not to be worth
bothering about, what new ideas have taken their place?
What is to take the place of the soul- and life-destroy-
ing metaphysics inherited from the nineteenth century?
The task of our generation, I have no doubt, is one of
metaphysical reconstruction. It is not as if we had to
invent anything new; at the same time, it is not good
enough merely to revert to the oíd formulations. Our task
—and the task of all education — is to understand the
present world, the world in which we Uve and make our
cholees.
The problems of education are merely reflections of the
deepest problems of our age. They cannot be solved by
organisation, administration, or the expenditure of money,
even though the importance of all these is not denied. We
are suffering from a metaphysical and the cure
diseasc,
must therefore be metaphysical. Education which fails to
clarify our central convictions is mere training or indul-
gence. For it is our central convictions that are in disorder,
and, as long as the present anti-metaphysical temper per-
sists, the disorder will grow worse. Education, far from
101
2
The Proper Use oí Land
the land. Study how a society uses its land, and you can
come to pretty reliable conclusions as to what its future
will be.
The land carries the topsoil, and the topsoil carries an
immense variety of living beings including man. In 1955,
Tom Dale and Vemon Gilí Cárter, both highly experienced
ecologists, published a book called Topsoil and Civilisa-
tion. Icannot do better, for the purposes of this chapter,
than quote some of their opening paragraphs:
102
he has lived for long. This is the main reason why his pro-
gressive civilisations have moved from place to place. It has
bcen the chief cause for the decline of his civilisations in
older settled regions. It has been the dominant factor in
determining all trends of history.
The writers of history have seldom noted the importance
of land use. They seem not to have recognised that the
destinies of most of man's empires and civilizations were
determined largely by the way the land was used. While
recognising the influence of environment on history, they
fail to note that man usually changed or despoiled his
environment.
How did civilised man despoil this favourable environ-
ment? He did it mainly by depleting or destroying the
natural resources. He cut down or bumed most of the
usable timber from forested hillsidcs and valleys. He over-
grazed and denuded the grasslands that fed his livestock.
He killed most of the wildlife and much of the fish and
other water Ufe. He permitted erosión to rob his farm land
of its productive topsoil. He allowed eroded soil to clog the
streams and fill his reservoirs, irrigation cañáis, and harbours
with silt. In many cases, he used and wasted most of the
easily mined metáis or other needed minerals. Then his
civilisation declined amidst the despoliation of his own crea-
tion or he moved to new land. There have been from ten
to thirty different civilisations that have followed this road
to ruin (the number depending on who classifies the civil-
isations ).i
103
that of Eugene Rabinowitch, editor-in-chief of the Bulletin
of Atomic Scientists.
The only animáis [he says (in The Times of 29 April, 1972)],
whose disappearance may threaten the biological viability of
man on earth are the bacteria normally inhabitíng our bodies.
For the rest there is no convincing proof that mankind could
not survive even as the only animal species on earth! If
economical ways could be developed for synthesising food
—
from inorganic raw materials which is likely to happen
—
sooner or later man may even be able to become inde-
pendent of plants, on which he now depends as sources of
his food. . . .
I personally —
and, I suspect, a vast majority of mankind
—would shudder at the idea [of a habitat without animáis
and But millions of inhabitants of "city jungles**
plants].
of New
York, Chicago, London or Tokyo have grown up
and spent their whole lives in a practically "azoic" habitat
(leaving out rats, mice, cockroaches and other such ob-
noxious species) and have survived.
104
rational thinking than that represented by the last two
quotations.
There are always some things which we do for their
own sakes, and there are other things which we do for
some other purpose. One of the most important tasks for
any society is to distinguish between ends and means-to-
ends, and to have some sort of cohesive view and agree-
ment about this. Is the land merely a means of production
or is it something more, something that is an end in itself?
And when I say "land," I include the creatures upon it.
105
demanded these same amenities and comforts while he
was engaged in "production," he would be told that this
would be uneconomic, that it would be inefficient, and
that society could not afford such ineñiciency. In other
words, everythmg dependa on whether it is done by man-
as-producer or by man-as-consumer. If man-as-producer
travels first-class or uses a luxurious car, this is called a
waste of money; but if the same man in his other incama-
tion of man-as-consumer does the same, this is called a
sign of a high standard of lif e.
106
as a §tatement of fact, that they are in a certain sense
sacred. Man made them, and it is irrational for him
has not
to treat things that he has not made and cannot make and
cannot recréate once he has spoilt them, in the same
manner and spirit as he is entitled to treat things of his
own making.
The higher animáis have an economic valué because of
have a meta-economic valué in them-
their utility; but they
selves. If I have a car, a man-made thing, I might quite
legitimately argüe that the best way to use it is never to
bother about maintenance and simply run it to ruin. I may
indeed have caJculated that this is the most economical
method of use. If the calculation is correct, nobody can
criticise me for acting accordingly, for there is nothing
sacred about a man-made thing like a car. But if I have
an animal —be it only a calf or a hen —
a living, sensitivo
creature, am I allowed to treat it as nothing but a utility?
Am I allowed to run it to ruin?
It no use trying to answer such questions scientif-
is
107
"dominión," not the right to tyrannise, to ruin and
exterminate. It is no use talking about the dignity of man
without accepting that noblesse oblige. For man to pul
himself into a wrongful relationship with animáis, and
particularly those long domesticated by him, has always,
been considered a horrible and infinitely
in all traditions,
dangerous thing to do. There have been no sages or holy
men in our or in anybody else's history who were cruel to
animáis or who looked upon them as nothing but Utilities,
and innumerable are the legends and stories which link
sanctity as well as happiness with a loving kindness
towards lower creation.
It is interesting to note that modem man is being told,
in the nam.e of science, that he is really nothing but a
naked ape or even an accidental collocation of atoms.
*'Now we can define man," says Professor Joshua Leder-
berg. "Genotypically at least, he
is six feet of a particular
108
more disposed to feel compassion for his fellowmen.'* No
one ever raised the question of whether they could afford
to live in accordance with these convictions. At the level
of valúes, of ends-in-themselves, there is no question of
"affording."
What applies to the animáis upon the land applies
equally, and without any suspicion of sentimentality, to the
land itself. Although ignorance and greed have again and
again destroyed the fertility of the soil to such an extent
that whole civilisations foundered, there have been no
traditional teachings which failed to recognise the meta-
economic valué and significance of "thé generous earth."
And where these teachings were heeded, not only agricul-
ture but also all other factors of civilisation achieved
health and wholeness. Conversely, where people imagined
that they could not "afford" to care for the soil and work
with nature, instead of against it, the resultant sickness of
the soil has invariably imparted sickness to all the other
factors of civilisation.
In our time, the main danger to the soil, and therewith
not only to agriculture but to civilisation as a whole, stems
from the townsman's determination to apply to agriculture
the principies of industry. No more typical representative
of this tendency could be found than Dr. Sicco L.
Mansholt, who, as Vice-President of the European Eco-
nomic Community, launched the Mansholt Plan for
European Agriculture. He believes that the farmers are
"a group that has still not grasped the rapid changes in
society." Most of them ought to get out of farming and
become industrial labourers in the cities, because "factory
workers, men on building sites and those in administra-
tive Jobs —have week and two weeks' annual
a five-day
hoüday already. Soon they may have a four-day week
and four weeks' holiday per year. And the farmer: he is
condemned to working a seven-day week because the five'
day cow has not yet been invented, and he gets no holiday
at all.''* The Mansholt Plan, accordingly, is designed to
109
achieve, as quickly as humanely possible, the amalgama-
tion of many small family farms into large agricultural
units operated as if they were faetones, and the máximum
rate of reduction in the community's agricultural popula-
tion. Aid is to be given "which would enable the older as
well as the younger f armers to leave agriculture."^
In the discussion of the Mansholt Plan, agriculture is
generally referred to as one of Europe's "industries." The
question arises of whether agriculture is, in fact, an indus-
try, or whether it might be something essentially differ-
ent. Not surprisingly, as this is a metaphysical or meta- —
—
economic question, it is never raised by economists.
Now, the fundamental "principie" of agriculture is that
it deals with life, that is to say, with living substances. Its
products are the results of processes of life and its means
of production is the living soil. cubic centimetre ofA
fertile soil contains milliards of living organisms, the full
exploration of which is far beyond the capacities of man.
The fundamental "principie" of modera industry, on the
other hand, is that it deals with man-devised processes
which work reliably only when applied to man-devised,
non-living materials. The ideal of industry is the elimina-
tion of livmg substances. Man-made materials are prefer-
able to natural materials, because we can make them to
measure and apply perfect quality control. Man-made
machines work more reliably and more predictably than
do such living substances as men. The ideal of industry is
to eliminate the living factor, even including the human
factor, and to turn the productive process over t<$
110
from being compatible with each other, are in opposition.
Real life produced by the incom-
consists of the tensions
patibility of opposites, each of which is needed, and just
as life would be meaningless without death, so agrículture
would be meaningless without industry. It remains true,
however, that agrículture is primary, whereas industry
is secondary, which means that human life can continué
111
ness and harmony of man, as well as the beauty of his
habitat. If all these things are left out of the experts'
considerations, man himself is left out —even if our
experts try to bring him in, as it were, after the event, by
pleading that the community should pay for the "social
consequences" of their policies. The Mansholt Plan, say
the experts, "represents a bold initiative. It is based on
the acceptance of a fundamental principie: agricultural
income can only be maintained if the reduction in the
agricultural population is accelerated, and if farms rapidly
reach an economically viable size."'' Or again: "Agricul-
ture, in Europe at least, is essentially directed towards
food-production. . . . It is well known that the demand for
food increases relatively slowly with increases in real
income. This causes the total incomes eamed in agricul-
ture to rise more slowly in comparison with the incomes
eamed in industry; to maintain the same rate of growth of
incomes per head is only possible if there is an adequate
rate of decline in thenumbers engaged in agriculture."^
. ."The conclusions seem inescapable: under circum-
.
112
production." A wider view sces agriculture as having to
fuL6J at least three tasks:
113
—
114
its second task, which is to humanise and ennoble
fulfil
115
is just a "declining enterprise." Why prop it up? There are
no "necessary improvements'* as the land, but
regarás
only as regards farmers* incomes, and these can be made if
there are f ewer f armers. This is the philosophy of the
townsman, alienated from living nature, who promotes his
own scale of priorities by arguing in economic terms that
we cannot "afford" any other. In fact, any society can
afford to look after its land and keep it healthy and beauti-
ful in perpetuíty. There are no technical difficulties and
there is no lack of relevant knowledge. There is no need
to consult economic experts when the question is one of
priorities. We know too much about ecology today to have
any excuse for the many abuses that are currently going
on in the management of the land, in the management of
animáis, in food storage, food processing, and in heedless
urbanisation. If we permit them, this is not due to poverty,
as if we could not afford to stop them; it is due to the
fact that, as a society, we have no firm basis of belief in
any meta-economic valúes, and when there is no such
belief the economic calculus takes over. This is quite
inevitable. How could it be otherwise? Nature, it has been
said, abhors a vacuum, and when the available "spirit-
ual space" is not filled by some higher motivation, then it
will necessarily be filled by something lower —
by the small,
mean, calculating attitude to life which is rationalised in
the economic calculus.
I have no doubt that a callous attitude to the land and to
the animáis thereon is connected with, and symptomatic
of a great many other attitudes, such as those producing a
,
116
í great deal of philosophical, not to say religious, change.
It is not a question of what we can afford but of what we
117
3
Resources for Industry
118
—
—
which would then greatly exceed at 800 million tons
the total oil imports which Western Europe and Japan
currently obtain from the Middle East and África.
An industrial system which uses forty per cent of the
world's primary resources to supply less than six per cent
of the world's population could be called efl&cient only if it
obtained strikingly successful results in terms of human
happiness, well-being, culture, peace, and harmony. I do
not need to dwell on the fact that the American system
fails to do this, or that there are not the slightest prospects
that it could do so // only it achieved a higher rate of
growth of production, associated, as it must be, with an
ever-greater cali upon the world's finite resources. Pro-
fessor Walter Heller, former Chairman of the U.S. Presi-
119
dent's Council of Economic Advisers, no doubt reflected
the opinión of most modem economists when he expressed
this view:
120
known to be: all this for nineteen non-rene wable natural
Of
resources of vital importance to industrial societies.
particular interest is column of the table which
the last
shows "U.S. Consumption as % of World Total." The
figures are as follows:
Aluminura
American mines and successful Middie Eastem pressures to
raise oil pnces suggest that the political question may arise
long before the ultímate economic one.
122
the earlier chapters. It is impossible to get away from iL
It is impossible to overemphasise its centrality. It might be
said that energy is for the mechanical world what con-
sciousness is for the human world. If energy fails, every-
thing fails.
123
which has been and still is highly predictable, the authors
of these studies almost invariably look at innumerable con-
stituent parís of the total situation, none of which is
separately predictable, since the parts cannot be under-
stood unléss the whole is understood.
To give only one example, an elabórate study by the
European Coal and Steel Community, undertaken in
1960/61, provided precise quantitative answers to virtu-
ally every question anyone might have wished to ask about
fuel and energy in the Common Market countries up to
1975. I had occasion to review this report shortly after
publication, and it may not be out of place to quote a
few passages from this review ¡^
124
thc future are bettcr than none. To produce figures about
the unknown, the current method is to make a guess about
—
something or other called an "assumption" and to derive —
an estímate from it by subtle calculation. The estímate is
then presented as the result of scíentific reasoníng, some-
thLng far superior to mere guesswork. This is a pernícious
practice whích can only lead to the most colossal planníng
crrors, because ít offers a bogus answer where, ín fact, an
entrepreneurial judgment is required.
The study here under review employs a vast array of
arbitrary assumptions, which are then, as it were, put into a
calculating machine to produce a "scientific" result. It would
havc been cheaper, and indeed more honest, simply to
assume the result.
125
knowledge of the current situation and there were per-
fectly reasonable and realistic estimates of future trends.
But the policy-makers were incapable of drawing correcta
conclusions frora what they knew to be true. The argu-
ments of those who pointed to the likelihood of severe
energy shortages in the foreseeable future were not taken
up and refuted by counter-arguments but simply derided
or ignored. did not require a great deal of insight to
It
enough for forty years and total oil reserves for 200 years
— at the current rate ofconsumption. Unfortunately, how-
ever, the rate of consumption is not stable but has a long
history of growth at a rate of six or seven per cent a year.
Indeed, if this growth stopped from now on, there could be
no question of oil displacing coal; and everybody appears
to be quite confident that the growth of oil —
we are speaking
on a world scale —
^will continué at the established rate.
127
ment. Ten years, however, is a very short time when we are
dealing with problems of fuel supply. So let us look at the
following ten years leading up to about 1980. If ^1 con-
sumption continued to grow at roughly seven per cent per
annum, it would rise to about 4000 million tons a year in
1980. The total take during this second decade would be
roughly 30,000 million tons. If the "life" of pro ved reserves
were to be maintained at twenty years and few people —
would care to engage in big investments without being able
to look to at least twenty years for writing them off it —
would not suffice merely to replace the take of 30,000 million
tons; it would be necessary to end up with proved reserves
at 80,000 million tons (twenty times 4000). New discoveries
during that second decade would therefore have to amount
to not less than 70,000 million tons. Such a figure, I sug-
gest, already looks pretty fantastic. What is more, by that
time we would have used up about 45,000 million tons out of
our original 200,000 million tons total. The remaining
155,000 million tons, and not-yet-discovered,
discovered
would allow a continuation of the 1980 rate of consump-
tion for than forty years. No further arithmetical
less
dcmonstration needed to make us realise that a continua-
is
128
hígh; but thc relation of current take to remaining reserves
is such that it may now be impossible for it to grow any
further.
As far as Britain is concemed —a highly industríalised
country with a high rate of consumption but without oil
indigenous supplies the oil —
crisis will come, not when
all the world's oil is exhausted, but when world oil sup-
129
industry safely through the difficult years that lie ahead,
maintaining as well as possible its power to produce efficiently
something of the order of 200 million tons of coal a year.
Even if from time to time it may look as if less coal and
more imported oil were cheaper or more convenient for
certain users or for the economy as a whole, it is the longer-
term prospect that must rule national fuel policy. And this
longer-term prospect must be seen against such world-wide
developments as population growth and industrialisation. The
indications are that by the 1980s we shall have a world
population at least one-third bigger than now and a level of
world industrial production at least two-and-a-half times
as high as today, with fuel use more than doubled. To
pennit a doubling of total fuel consumption it will be
necessary to increase oil fourfold; to double hydroelectricity;
to maintain natural gas production at least at the present
level; to obtain a substantial (though still modest) contribu-
tion from nuclear energy, and to get roughly twenty per
cent more coal than now. No doubt, many things will happen
during the next twenty years which we cannot foresee today.
Some may increase the need for coal and some may decrease
it. Policy cannot be based on the unforeseen or unforesee-
130
Even today, soothsayers are still at work suggesting that
there is no problem. During the 1960s, it was the oil
companies who were the main dispensers of bland assur-
ances, although the figures they provided totally disproved
their case. Now, and much
after nearly half the capacity
more than workable reserves of the western
half the
European coal industries have been destroyed, they have
changed their tune. It used to be said that O.P.E.C. the —
Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries would —
never amount to anything, because Arabs could never
agree with each other, let alone with non- Arabs; today it
is clear that O.P.E.C. is the greatest cartel-monopoly the
world has ever seen. It used to be said that the oil export-
ing countries depended on the oil importing countries just
as much depended on the former; today it is
as the latter
clear that this is based on nothing but wishful thinking,
because the need of the oil consuméis is so great and their
demand so inelastic that the oil exporting countries, acting
in unisón, can in fact raise their revenues by the simple
device of curtailing output. There are still people who say
that if oil prices rose too much (whatever that may mean)
oil would price itself out of the market; but it is perfectly
obvious that there is no ready substitute for oil to take its
131
dependent economies to a situation —which is absolutely
certain to arise within the lifetime of most people living
—
today when oil will be scarce and very dear. The greatest
danger to both is a continuation of rapid growth in oil
production and consumption throughout the world.
Catastrophic developments on the oil front could be
avoided only if the basic harmony of the long-term inter-
ests of both groups of countries carne to be fully realised
and concerted action were taken to stabilise and gradually
reduce the annual flow of oil into consumption.
As far as the oil importing countries are concemed, the
problem is obviously most serious for westem Europe and
Japan. These two áreas are in danger of becoming the
"residuary legatees" for oil imports. No elabórate com-
puter studies are required to establish this stark fact. Until
westem Europe lived in the comfortable
quite recently,
"we are entering the age of limitless, cheap
illusion that
energy" and famous scientists, among others, gave it as
their considered opinión that in future "energy will
be a
drug on the market." The British White Paper on Fuel
Policy, issued in November 1967, proclaimed that
132
hausted, but it is increasingly recognised that their life is
133
4
Nuclear Energy —
Salvation or Damnation?
134
developed over míllions of years must be considered to havc
some merit. Anything so complicated as a planet, inhabited
by more than a million and a half species of plants and
animáis, all of them living together in a more or less balanced
equilibríum in which they continuously use and re-use the
same molecules of the soil and air, cannot be improved by
aimless and uninformed tinkering. All changes in a complex
mechanism involve some risk and should be undertaken only
after careful study of all the facts available. Changes should
be made on a small se ale first so as to provide a test before
they are widely applied. When
Information is incomplete,
changes should stay cióse to the natural processes which
have in their favour the indisputable evidence of having
supported life for a very long time."i
135
accepts big liabilities.^ Yet, insured or not, the hazard
remains, and such is the thraldom of the religión of eco-
nomics that the only question that appears to interest
either goveraments or the public is whether *'it pays."
It is not as if there were any lack of authoritative voices
136
tion. Wherever there is life, radioactive substances are
absorbed into the biological cycle. Within hours of deposit-
ing these materials in water, the great bulk of them can be
found in living organisms. Plankton, algae, and many sea
animáis have the power of concentrating these substances
by a factor of 1000 and in some cases even a million. As
one organism feeds on another, the radioactive materials
climb up the ladder of life and find their way back to
man.''
No interaational agreement has yet been reached on
The conference of the Interaational Atomic
waste disposal.
Energy Organisation at Monaco, in November 1959,
ended in disagreement, mainly on account of the violent
objections raised by the majority of countries against the
American and British practice of disposal into the
oceans.s "High level" wastes continué to be dumped into
the sea, while quantities of so-called "intermediate" and
"low-level" wastes are discharged into rivers or directly
into the ground. An A.E.C. report observes laconically that
the liquid wastes "work their way slowly into ground
water, leaving all or part [sicl] of their radioactivity held
either chemically or physically in the soil."®
The most massive wastes are, of course, the nuclear
reactors themselves aftcr they have become unserviceable.
There is a lot of discussion on the trivial economic question
of whether they will last for twenty, twenty-five, or thirty
years. No one discusses the humanly vital point that they
cannot be dismantled and cannot be shifted but have to
be left standing where they are, probably for centuries,
perhaps for thousands of years, an active menace to all
life, silently leaking radioactivity into air, water and soil.
137
nothing but tranquillity, from now on, stretches before
—
him, or else that the future counts as nothing compared
with the slightest economic gain now.
Meanwhile, a number of authorities are engaged in
"máximum permissible concentrations" (MPCs)
defining
and "máximum permissible levéis" (MPLs) for various
radioactive elements. The MPC
purports to define the
quantity of a given radioactvie substance that the human
body can be allowed to accumulate. But it is known that
any accumulation produces biological damage. "Since we
don't know that these effects can be completely recovered
from," observes the U.S. Naval Radiological Laboratory,
"we have to fall back on an arbitf ary decisión about how
much we will put up with; Le. what is "acceptable" or "per-
missible" —
not a scientific finding, but an administrative
decision."^^^ We can hardly be surprised when men of
outstanding intelligence and integrity, such as Albert
Schweitzer, refuse to accept such administrative decisions
with equanimity: "Who has given them the right to do this?
Who is even entitled to give such a permission?"^^ The
history of these decisions is, to say the least, disquieting.
The British Medical Research Council noted some twelve
years ago that
138
We must be careful, however, not to get lost in the
jungle of controversy that has grown up in this field. The
point is that very serious have already been
hazards
created by the "peacefiil uses of atomic energy," affect-
ing not merely the people alive today but all future
generations, although so far nuclear energy is being used
only on a statistically insignificant scale. The real develop-
ment is yet to come, on a scale which few people are
capable of imagining. If this is really going to happen,
there will be a continuous traffic of radioactive sub-
stances from the "hot" chemical plants to the nuclear
stations and back again; from the stations to waste-
processing plants; and from there to disposal sites. A
serious accident, whether during transport or production,
can cause a major catastrophe; and the radiation levéis
throughout the world will rise relentlessiy from generation
to generation. Unless all living geneticists are in error,
there will be an equally relentless, though no doubt some-
what delayed, increase in the number of harmful muta-
tions. K. Z. Morgan, of the Oak Ridge Laboratory,
emphasises that the damage can be very subtle, a
deterioration of all kinds of organic qualities, such as
mobility, fertility, and the efficiency of sensory organs. "If
a small dose has any effect at all at any stage of the life
cycle of an organism, then chronic radiation at this level
can be more damaging than a single massive dose. . . .
139
'
:
;
energy supplies —
a problem which is in no way acute at
present;^^ and leading students of strategic and political
problems, at the same time, have warned us that there is
really no hope of preventing the proliferation of the atom
bomb, if there is a spread of plutonium capacity, such as
was "spectacularly launched by President Eisenhower in
his 'atoms for peace proposals* of 8th December,
1953."i8
Yet all these weighty opinions play no part in the debate
on whether we should go immediately for a large "second I
140
[this or that innovation] is in any way deleterious, it
141
more choice, whether we can cope with the hazards or
not.
It is clear that certain scientific and technological
advances of the last thirty years have produced, and are
continuing to produce, hazards of an altogether intolerable
kind. At the Fourth National Cáncer Conference in Amer-
ica in September 1960, Lester Breslow of the California
State Department of Public Health reported that tens of
thousands of trout in westem hatcheries suddenly acquired
liver cancers, and continued thus:
142
violence rather than violence; towards an harmonious
cooperation with nature rather than a warfare against
nature; towards the noiseless, low-energy, elegant, and
economical solutions normally applied in nature rather
than the noisy, high-energy, brutal, wasteful, and clumsy
solutions of our present-day sciences.
The continuation of scientific advance in the direction
of ever-increasing violence, culminating in nuclear fission
and moving on to nuclear fusión, is a prospect of terror
threatening the abolition of man. Yet it is not written in
the stars that this must be the direction. There is also a
life-giving and life-enhancing possibility, the conscious
exploration and cultivation of all relatively non-violent,
harmonious, organic methods of cooperating with that
enormous, wonderful, incomprehensible system of God-
given nature, of which we are a part and which we cer-
tainly have not made ourselves.
This statement, which was part of a lecture given before
the National Society for Clean Air in October 1967, was
received with thoughtful applause by a highly responsible
audience, but was subsequently ferociously attacked by
the authorities as "the height of irresponsibility." The most
priceless remark was reportedly made by Richard Marsh,
then Her Majesty's Minister of Power, who felt it neces-
sary to "rebuke" the author. The lecture, he said, was one
of the more extraordinary and least profitable contribu-
tions to the current debate on nuclear and coal cosí.
{Daily Telegraphy 21 October 1967.)
However, times change. A report on the Control of
PoUution, presented in February 1972 to the Secretary of
State for the Environment by an oñicially appointed
Working Party, published by Her Majesty's Stationery
Office and entitled PoUution: Nuisance or Nemesis? has y
this to say:
143
provides only one per cent of the total electricity generated
in the worid. By the year 2000, if present plans go aheád,
this will have increased to well over fifty per cent and the
equivalent of two new 500 reactorsMWeeach of the —
size of the one at Trawsfynydd in Snowdonia — will be
open every day.25
The evident danger is that man may have put all his eggs
in the nuclear basket before he discovers that a solution
cannot be found. There would then be powerful political
pressures to ignore the radiation üazards and continué using
the reactors which had been built. It wuld be only prudent
to slow down the nuclear power programme until we have
solved the waste disposal problem. Many responsible . . .
144
reactora should be built until we know how to control their
wastes.
145
—
5
Technology with a
Human Face
146
man dominated by technology and specialisation. Technol-
ogy recognises no self-limiting principie in terms, for —
instance, of size, speed, or violence. It therefore does not
possess the virtues of being self-balancing, self-adjusting,
and self-cleansing. In the subtle system of natura, tech-
nology, and in particular the super-technology of the-
modem world, acts like a foreign body, and there are
now numerous signs of rejection.
Suddenly, if not altogether surprisingly, the modem
world, shaped by modem technology, finds itself involved
in three crises simultaneously. First, human nature revolts
against inhuman technological, organisational, and politi-
cal pattems, which it experiences as suffocating and
debilitating; second, the living environment which supports
human life aches and groans and gives signs of partial
breakdown; and, third, it is clear to anyone fully knowl-
edgeable in the subject matter that the inroads being made
into the non-renewable resources, particularly
world's
those of fossil fuels, are such that serious bottlenecks and
virtual exhaustion loom ahead in the quite foreseeable
future.
Any one of these three crises or illnesses can tum out
to be deadly. I do not know which of the three is the most
likely to be the direcl cause of collapse. What is quite
clear is that a way of life that bases itself on
materialism, i.e. on permanent, limitless expansionism in a
finite environment, cannot last long, and that its life
147
to mention the problem of unemployment which already
reaches levéis like thirty per cent in many so-called
developing countries, and now threatens to become
endemic also in many of the rich countries. In any case,
the apparent yet illusory successes of the last twenty-five
years cannot be repeated: the threefold crisis ©f which I
148
fact remains that theburden of living rests much more
lightly on than on ours.
their shoulders
The question of what technology actually does for us is
therefore worthy of investí gation. It obviously greatly
work while it increases other kinds.
reduces sorae kinds of
The type of work which modem technology is most suc-
cessful in reducing or even eliminating is skilful, produc-
tive work of human hands,in touch with real materials of
one kind or another. In an advanced industrial society,
such work has become exceedingly rare, and to make a
decent living by doing such work has become virtually
impossible. A great part of the modem neurosis may be
due to this very fact; for the human being, defined by
Thomas Aquinas as a being with brains and hands,
enjoys nothing more than to be creatively, usefully, pro-
ductively engaged with both his hands and his brains.
Today, a person has to be wealthy to be able to enjoy this
simple thing, this very great luxury: he has to be able to
afford space and good tools; he has to be lucky enough
to find a good teacher and plenty of free time to leam
and practise. He really has to be rich enough not to need
a Job; for the number of jobs that would be satisfactory
in these respects is very small indeed.
The extent to which modem technology has taken over
the work of human hands may be illustrated as follows.
We may ask how much of **total social time" —that is to
say, the time all of us have together, twenty-four hours a
—
day each ^is actually engaged in real production. Rather
less than one-half of the total population of this country is,
as they say, gainfully occupied, and about one-third of
these are actual producéis in agriculture, mining, con-
struction, and industry. I do mean actual producers^ not
149
production; on average, each of them supports five oíhers
beside himself, of which two are gainfully employed on
things other than real production and three are not gain-
fully employed. Now, a fully employed person, allowing
for holidays, sickness, and other absence, spends about
one-fifth of bis total time on his job. It foUows that the
proportion of "total social time" spent on actual produc-
tion —
in the narrow sense in which I am using the term
— roughly, one-fifth of one-third of one-half, /.e. 3 Vi
is,
per cent. The other 96Vi per cent of "total social time" is
spent in other ways, including sieeping, eating, watching
televisión, doing jobs that are not directly productive, or
just killing time more or less humanely.
Although this bit of figuring work need not be taken
too literally, it quite adequately serves to show what
technology has enabled us to do: namely, to. reduce the
amount of time actually spent on production in its most
elementary sense to such a tiny percentage of total social
time that it pales into insignificance, that it carnes no real
150
We may say, therefore, that modera technology has
deprived man of the kind of work that he enjoys most,
Creative, useful work with hands and brains, and given
him plenty of work of a fragmented kind, most of which he
does not enjoy at all. It has multiplied the number of
people who are exceedingly busy doing kinds of work
which, if it is all, is so only in an indirect or
productive at
**roundabout" way, and much of which would not be
necessary at all if technology were i^ather less modem.
Karl Marx appears to have foreseen much of this when he
wrote: "They want production to be limited to useful
things, but they forget that the production of too many
useful things results in too many useless people,** to which
we might add: particularly when the processes of produc-
tion are joyless and boring. All this confirms our suspicion
that modera technology, the way it has developed, is
151
direction — to mercase it sixfold, to about twenty per cent,
so that twenty per cent of total social time would be used
for actually producing things, employing hands and brains
and, naturally, excellent tools. An incredible thoughtl
Even children would be allowed to make themselves use-
ful, even oíd people. At one-sixth of present-day produc-
tivity, we should be producing as much as at present.
There would be six times as much time for any piece of
work we chose to undertake —enough to make a really
good Job of it, to enjoy oneself, to produce real quality,
even to make things beautiful. Think of the therapeutic
valué of real work; think of its educational valué. No one
would then want to raise the school-leaving age or to
lower the retirement age, so as to keep people off the
labour market. Everybody would be welcome to lend a
hand. Everybody would be admitted to what is now the
rarest privilege, the opportunity of working usefully, crea-
tively, with his own hands and brains, in his own time, at
his own pace —
and with excellent tools. Would this mean
an enormous extensión of working hours? No, people
who work in this way do not know the difference between
work and leisure. Unless they sleep or eat or occasionally
choose to do nothing at all, they are always agreeably,
productively engaged. Many of the "on-cost jobs" would
simply disappear; I leave it to the reader's imagination to
identify them. There would be little need for mindless
entertainment or other drugs, and unquestionably much
less illness.
Now, it might be said that this is a romantic, a utopian,
visión. True enough. What we have today, in modem
industrial society, is not romantic and certainly not
utopian, as we have it right here. But it is in very deep
trouble and holds no promise of survival. We jolly well
have to have the courage to dream if we want to survive
and give our children a chance of survival. The threefold
crisis of which I have spoken will not go away if we sim-
ply carry on as before. It will become worse and end in
152
disaster, until or unless we develop a new life-stylc
with the health of living nature around us, and with the
resource endowment of the world.
Now, this is indeed a tall order, not because a new life-
one. And it could save us; for the poverty of the poor
makes it in any case impossible for them successfuUy to
adopt our technology. Of course, they often try to do so,
and then have to bear the most diré consequences in terms
of mass unemployment, mass migration into cities, rural
decay, and intolerable social tensions. They need, in fact,
the very thing I am talking about, which we also need: a
different kind of technology, a technology with a human
making human hands and brains
face, which, instead of
redundant, helps them to become far more productivo
than they have ever been before.
As Gandhi said, the poor of the world cannot be helped
by mass production, only by production by the masses.
The system of mass production, based on sophisticated,
highly capital-intensive, high energy-input dependent, and
human labour-saving technology, presupposes that you are
already rich, for a great deal of capital investment is
153
a
154
while genuinely trying to help others, we may also gain
knowledge and experience of how to help ourselves.
I think we can already see the conflict of attitudes
which will decide our future. On the one side, I see the
people who
think they can cope with our threefold crisis
by the methods current, only more so; I cali them the
people of the forward stampede. On the other side, there
are people in search of a new who
life-style, seek to retum
to certain basic truths about man and his worid; I cali
155
into the newspaper headlines every day with the message,
*'abreakthrough a day keeps the crisis at bay."
And what about the other side? This is made up of
people who are deeply convinced that technological devel-
opment has taken a wrong tum and needs to be redi-
rected. The term "home-comer" has, of course, a reli-
gious connotation. For it takes a good deal of courage to
say "no" to the fashions and fascinations of the age and to
question the presuppositions of a civilisation which appears
destined to conquer the whole world; the requisita
strength can be derived only from deep convictions. If it
were derived from nothing more than fear of the futura,
it would be likely to disappear at the decisive moment
156
long to make this connection? It is not difficult to díscern
what these beatitudes may mean for us today:
small is beautiful.
—We must concern ourselves with and justice see right
prevail.
—^And all onlythis, can enable us
this, become to
peacemakers.
157
in this great cónflict. To "leave it to the experts*' means to
side with the people of the forward stampede. It is widely
accepted that politics is too important a matter to be left
to experts. Today, the main contení of politics is eco-
nomics, and the main content of economics is technology.
If politics cannot be left to the experts, neither can
158
modem technological progress. Their methods bear the
mark of non-violence and humility towards the infinitely
subtle system of natural harmony, and this stands in oppo-
sition to the life-style of the modem world. But if we
now realise that the modem life-style is putting us inte
mortal danger, we may find it in our hearts to support
and even join these pioneers rather than to ignore or
ridicule them.
On the industrial side, there is the Intemiediate Tech-
nology Development Group. It is engaged in the system-
atic study on how to help people to help themselves. While
its work is primarily concemed with giving technical
assistance to the Third World, the results of its research
are attracting increasing attention alsofrom those who
are concemed about the future of the rich societies. For
they show that an interaaediate technology, a technology
with a human face, is in fact possible; that it is viable;
and that it reintegrates the human being, with his skilful
hands and creative brain, into the productive process. It
serves production by the masses instead of mass produc-
tion. Like the Soil Association, it is a prívate, voluntary
organisation depending on public support.
I have no doubt that it is possible to give a new direo-
tion to technological development, a direction that shall
lead back to the real needs of man, and that also
it
159
1
PART 1 1
163
concentrated on the countries where the promise of suc-
cess seems most credible. Not surprisingly, this proposal
has failed to win general acceptance.
One of the unhealthy and disniptive tendencies in virtu-
ally all the developing countries is the emergence, in an
ever more accentuated form, of the "dual economy," in
which there are two different pattems of living as widely
separated from each other as two different worlds. It is
not a matter of some people being rich and others being
poor, both being united by a common way of life: it is a
matter of two ways of life existing side by sidc in such a
manner that even the humblest member of the one dis-
poses of a daily income which is a high múltiple of the
income acctning to even the hardest working member of
the other. The social and political tensions arising from
the dual economy are too obvious to require description.
In the dual economy of a typical developing country,
we may find fifteen per cent of the population in the
modera sector, mainly confined to one or two big cities.
The other eighty-five per cent exists in the rural áreas
and small towns. For reasons which will be discussed, most
of the development effort goes into the big sities, which
means that eighty-five per cent of the population are
largely bypassed. What isbecome of them? Simply to
to
assume that the modera sector in the big cities will grow
until it has absorbed almost the entire population —which
is, of course, what has happened in many of the highly
—
developed countries is utterly imrealistic. Even the rich-
est countries are groaning under the burden which such a
maldistribution of population inevitably imposes.
In every branch of modera thought, the concept of
"evolution" plays a central role. Not so in development
economics, although the words "development" and "evolu-
tion'* would seem to be virtually synonymous. Whatever
may be the merit of the theory of evolution in specific
cases, it certainly reflects our experience of economic and
technical development. Let us imagine a visit to a modera
164
industrial establishment, say, a great refinery. As we walk
around in its vastness, through all its fantastic complexity,
we might well wonder how it was possible for the human
mind to conceive such a thing. What an immensity of
knowledge, ingenuity, and experience is here incaraated in
equipment! How is it possible? The answer is that it did
not spring ready-made out of any person's mind it came —
by a process of evolution. It started quite simply, then
this was added and that was modifíed, and so the whole
thing became more and more complex. But even what
we actually see in this refinery is only, as we might say, the
tip of an iceberg.
What we cannot see on our visit is far greatcr than what
we can see: the immensity and compiexity of the arrange-
ments that allow crude oil to flow into the refinery and
ensure that a muhitude of consignments of refined prod-
ucts, properly prepared, packed and labelled, reaches
innumerable consumers through a most elabórate distríbu-
tion system. All this we cannot see. Ñor can we see the
intellectual achievements behind the planning, the organis-
ing, the financing and marketing. Least of all can we see
the great educational background which is the precondition
of all, extending from primary schools to universities and
specialised research establishments, and without which
nothing of what we actually see would be there. As I said,
the visitor sees only the tip of the iceberg: there is ten
times as much somewhere else, which he cannot see, and
[without the "ten," the "one" is worthless. And if the "ten"
is not supplied by the country or society in which the
Refinery has been erected, either the refinery simply does
not work or it is, in fact, a foreign body depending for
most of its life on some other society. Now, all this is
easily forgotten, because the modem tendency is to see
and become conscious of only the visible and to forget
the invisible things that are making the visible possible and
keep it going.
Could it be that the relatíve failure of aid, or at least
165
our disappointment with the efFectiveness of aid, has some-
thing to do with our materialist philosophy which makes iis
Hable to overlook the most important preconditions of
success, which are generally invisible? Or if we do not
entirely overlook them, we tend to treat them just as we
treat material things —things that can be planned and
scheduled and purchased with money according to some
all-comprehensive development plan. In other words, we
tend to think of development, not in terms of evolution,
but in terms of creation.
Our scientists incessantly tell us with the utmost assur-
ance that everything around us has evolved by small muta-
tions sieved out through natural selection. Even the
Almighty is not credited with having been able to créate
anything complex. Every complexity, we are told, is the
result of evolution. Yet our development planners seem to
think that they can do better than the Almighty, that they
can créate the most complex things at one throw by a pro-
cess called planning, letting Athene spring, not out of the
head of Zeus, but out of nothingness, fuUy armed,
resplendent, and viable.
Now, of course, extraordinary and imfitting things can
occasionally be done. One can successfuUy carfy out a
project here or there. always possible to créate small
It is
166
large pockets of poverty-stricken people, "drop-outs,**
unemployed and unemployables.
Until recently, the development experts rarely referred
to the dual economy and its twin evils of mass imemploy-
ment and mass migration into cities. When they did so,
they merely deplored them and treated them as transi-
tíonal. Meanwhile, it has become widely recognised that
time alone will not be the healer. On the contrary, the
dual economy, unless consciously counteracted, produces
what I have called a "process of mutual poisoning,**
whereby successful industrial development in the cities
destroys the cconomic stnicture of the hinterland, and the
hinterland takes its revenge by mass migration into the
cities, poisoning them and making them utterly unman-
167
—
of rural life, since the great majority of their poverty-
stricken peoples live in rural áreas.
The starting point of all our considerations is poverty,
or rather, a degree of poverty which raeans misery, and
degrades and stultifies the human person; and our first
task is to recognise and understand the boundaries and
limitations which this degree of poverty imposes. Again,
our crudely materialistic philosophy makes us Hable to see
only "the material opportunities" (to use the words of the
White Paper which I have already quoted) and to over-
look the immaterial factors. Among the causes of poverty,
I am sure, the material factors are entirely secondary
such things as a lack of natural wealth, or a lack of capi-
tal, or an insufficiency of infrastructure. The primary
causes of extreme poverty are immaterial, they lie in
certain deficíencies in education, organisation, and
discipline.
Development does not start with goods; it starts with
people and their education, organisation, and discipline.
Without these three, all resources remain latent, untapped,
potential. There are prosperous societies with but the
scantiest basis of natural wealth, and we have had plenty
of opportunity to observe the primacy of the invisible
factors after the war. Every country, no matter how
devastated, which had a high level of education, organisa-
tion, and discipline, produced an "economic miracle." In
fact, these were miracles only for people whose attention
is focused on the tip of the iceberg. The tip had been
168
tion does not "jump"; ¡t is a gradual process of great
subtlety. Organisation does not **jump"; must gradually
it
169
ever. If they are left out, if they are pushed around by
170
—
2
Social and Economic Problems
Calling for the Development of
Intermedíate Technology
INTRODUCTION
In many places in the world today the poor are getting
poorer while the rich are getting richer, and the estab-
lished processes of foreign aid and development planning
appear to be unable to overeóme this tendency. In fact,
they often seem to promote it, for it is always easier to
help those who can help themselves than to help the
helpless. Nearly all the so-called developing countries have
a modem sector where the pattems of living and working
are similar to those of the developed countries, but they
also have a non-modem sector, accounting for the vast
majority of the total population, where the pattems of liv-
ing and working are not only profoundly unsatisfactory but
also in a process of accelerating decay.
I am concemed here exclusively with the problem of
helping the people in the non-modem sector. This does
not imply the suggestion that constmctive work in the
modem sector should be discontinued, and there can be
no doubt that it will continué in any case. But it does
imply the conviction that all successes in the modem sec-
tor are likely to be illusory unless there is also a healthy
growth—or at least a healthy condition of stability
171
among the very great numbers of people today whose lífe
is characterised not only by dire poverty but also by
hopelessness.
172
mass migration into cities, leading to a rate of urban
growth which would tax the resources of even the richest
societies. Rural unemployment becomes urban unemploy-
ment.
173
It ¡s important that there should be enough work for all
174
.
175
high skills are minimised, not only in the
production process itself but also in matters
of organisation, raw material supply, finano
ing, marketing, and so forth.
Fourth, that production should be mainly from local
materiais and mainly for local use.
176
A may be drawn from Italy, a rela-
further illustration
tivelywealthy country. Southern Italy and Sicily do not
develop merely as a result of successful economic growth
in "Italy-as-a-whole." Italian industry is concentrated
mainly in the north of the country, and its rapid growth
does not diminish, but on the contrary tends to intensify,
the problem of the south. Nothing succeeds like success
and, equally, nothing fails like failure.Competition from
the north destroys production in the south and drains all
talented and enterprising men out of.it. Conscious efforts
have to be made to counteract these tendencies, for if the
population of any región within a country is by-passed by
development it becomes actually worse off than before, is
thrown into mass unemployment, and forced into mass
migration. The evidence of this truth can be found all
over the world, even in the most highly developed
countries.
In this matter is not possible to give hard and fast
it
177
—
bigger the country, the greater is the need for internal
178
determined by quite other, much more powerful criteria,
such as raw material base, markets, entrepreneurial inter-
est, etc. The cholee of industry is one thing; but the choice
179
In fact, the current attempt of the developing countries
to infíltrate the £ 1 000-technoIogy into their economies
inevitably kills off the £.l-technology at an alarming rate,
destroying traditional workplaces much faster than mod-
ero workplaces can be created, and thus leaves the poor
in a more desperate and helpless position than ever before.
If effective help is to be brought to those who need it
most, a technology is required which would range in some
intermedíate position between the <£ 1 -technology and the
—
£1 000-technology. Let us cali it again symbolically
speaking —a £ 1 00-technology.
Such an intermediate technology would be inmiensely
more productive than the indigenous technology (which is
180
"demonstration effect**; on
contrary, as can be
the
observed all over the world,
"demonstration effect" is
its
181
Their argument runs as follows: The amount of available
capital is given, Now, you may concéntrate it on a small
number of highly capitalised workplaces, or you may
spread it thinly over a large number of cheap workplaces.
If you do the latter, you obtain less total output than if
you do the former; you therefore fail' to achieve the
quickest possible rate of economic growth. Dr. Kaldor,
for instance, claims that "research has shown that the
most modern machinery produces much more output per
unit of capital invested than less sophisticated machinery
which employs more people."^ Not only "capital" but also
"wages goods" are held to be a given quantity, and this
quantity determines "the limits on wages employment in
any country at any given time."
182
output ratios as technological facts, when they are so
largely dependent on quite other factors.
The question must be asked, moreover, whether there
¡s such a law, as Dr. Kaldor asserts, that the capital/
output ratio grows if capital is concentrated on fewer
workplaces. No one with the slightest industrial experience
would ever claim to have noticed the existence of such a
"law," ñor is there any foundation for it in any science.
Mechanisation and automation are introduced to increase
the productivity of labour, Le. the worker/ output ratio,
and their effect on the capital/ output ratio may just as
183
moving Job has to be done in an área of high unemploy-
ment. There is a wide choice of technologies, ranging
from the most modem earth-moving equipment to purely
manual work without tools of any kind. The "output" is
^ed by the nature of the job, and it is quite clear that
tflfe capital/ output ratio will be highest if the input of
"capital" is kept lowest. If the job were done without any
tools, the capital/ output ratio would be inftnitely large,
but the productivity per man would be exceedingly low.
If the job were done at the highest level of modem tech-
nology, the capital /output ratio would be low and pro-
ductivity per man very high. Neither of these extremes is
184
This leads to thc next objection which has been raised
against the ¡dea of intermediate technology. It is argued
required talent.
Two further arguments have been advanced against the
idea of intermediate technology —
products would
that its
would be unsuit-
require protection within the country and
able for export. Both arguments are based on mere
surmise. In fact a considerable number of design studies
185
and costings, made for specific producís in specific dis-
tricts,have universally demonstrated that the producís of
an intelligently chosen intermediate technology could actu-
al ly be cheaper than those of modera faetones in the
186
as the much bigger and more capital-intensive refineries
corresponding to conventional design. The second example
relates to "package plants" for ammonia production, also
recently designed for small markets. According to some
provisional data, the investment cost per ton in a "package
plant" with a sixty-tons-a-day capacity may be about 30,000
dollars,whereas a conventionally designed unit, with a daily
capacity of 100 tons [which is, for a conventional plant, very
small] would require an investment of approximately 50,000
dollars per ton.5
187
be of assistance to those who want to follow a similar
road but do not know how to get started. They exist, as
it were, outside the mainstream of official and popular
interest. 'The catalogue issued by the European or United
States exporter of machinery is still the prime source of
technical assistance"* and the institutional arrangements
for dispensing aid are generally such that there is an
unsurmountable bias in favour of large-scale projects on
the level of the most modem technology.
If we could tum oflBcial and popular interest away from
the grandiose projects and to the real needs of the poor,
the battle could be won. A study of intermedíate technol-
ogies as they exist today already would disclose that there
is enough knowledge and experience to set everybody to
work, and where there are gaps, new design studies could
be made very quickly. Professor Gadgil, director of the
Gokhale Instituto of Politics and Economics at Poona, has
outlined three possible approaches to the development of
intermedíate technology, as follows:
188
the limiting economic circumstances. These are chiefly the
aimed at and the relative costs oí capital
scale of operations
and labour and the scale of their inputs poísible or dssir-—
able,Such direct effort at establishing intermedíate technol-
ogy would undoubtedly be conducíed against the background
of knowlcdge of advanced technology in the field. However,
it could cover a much wider range of posaibilities than the
effort through the adjustment and adaptation approach.
189
by making available to them a technology that recog-
economic boundaries and limitations of poverty
nises the
—an intermedíate technology.
4. Action programmes on a national and supranational
basis are needed to develop intermedíate technologies
suitable for the promotion of full employment in devel-
oping countries.
190
—
3
Two Million Villages
191
ríase no problems of communication. When the emphasls
is on people, Communications problems become para-
mount. Who are the helpers and who are those to be
helped? The helpers, by and large, are rich, educated (in
a somewhat specialised sense), and town-based. Those
who most need help are poor, uneducated, and rurally
based. This means that three tremendous gulfs sepárate
the former from the latter: the gulf between rich and
poor; the gulf between educated and uneducated; and the
gulf between city-men and country-folk, which includes
that between industry and agriculture. The first problem
of development aid is how to bridge these three gulfs. A
great effort of imagination, study, and compassion is
needed to do so. The methods of production, the pattems
of consumption, the systems of ideas and of valúes that
suit relatively affluent and educated city people are
unlikely to suit poor, semi-illiterate peasants. Poor peas-
ants cannot suddenly acquire the outlook and habits of
sophisticated city people. If the people cannot adapt them-
selves to the methods, then the methods must be adapted
to the people. This is the whole crux of the matter.
There are, moreover, many features of the rich man*s
economy which are so questionable in themselves and, in
any case, so inappropriate for poor communities that
successful adaptation of the people to these features would
spell ruin. If the nature of change is such that nothing is
left for the fathers to teach their sons, or for the sons to
accept from their fathers, family life collapses. The life,
192
—
losses —though may be an idle reflection, since eco-
this
nomic growth normally inhibited by them.
is
lems as such. (Ñor did they play the slightest part in the
actual development of the rich countries!) Aid can be
considered successful only if it helps to mobilise the
labour-power of the masses in the receiving country and
raises productivity without "saving" labour. The common
criterion of success, namely the growth of GNP, is utteriy
193
misleading and, in fact, must of necessity lead to phenom-
ena which can only be described as neocolonialism.
I hesitate to use this term because it has a nasty sound
194
standards, allequipment had to be imported from the
his
most advanced the sophisticated equipment
countries;
demandad that all higher management and maintenance
personnel had to be imported. Even the raw materials had
to be imported because the locally grown cotton was too
short for top quality yarn and the postulated standards
demanded the use of a high percentage of man-made
fibres. This is not an untypical case. Anyone who has
tak'en the trouble to look systematically at actual "devel-
—
opment" projects instead of merely studying development
plans and econometric models —
knows of countless such
cases: soap faetones producing luxury soap by such sensi-
tive processes that only highly refined materials can be
used, which must be imported at high pnces while the
local raw materials are exported at low prices; food-
processing plants; packing stations; motorisation, and so
—
on all on the rich man's pattem. In many cases, local
fnilt goes to waste because the consumer allegedly
demands quality standards which relate solely to eye-
appeal and can be met only by fniit imported from
Australia or California, where the application of an
immense science and a fantastic technology ensures that
every apple is of the same size and without the slightest
visible blemish. The examples could be multiplied without
end. Poor countries slip —
and are pushed into the adop- —
tion of production methods and consumption standards
which destroy the possibilities of self-reliance and self-
help. The results are untntentional neocolonialism and
hopelessness for the poor.
How, then, is it possible to help these two million
villages? First, the quantitative aspect. If we take the total
of westem aid, after eliminating certain items which have
nothing to do with development, and divide it by the
number of people living in the developing countries, we
arrive at a per-head figure of rather less than £.2 a year.
Considered as an income supplement, this is, of course,
negligible and derisory. Many people therefore plead that
195
—
the rich countries ought to make a much bigger financial
effort —and would be perverse to refuse to support this
it
196
own limited field of experience. In other words, the neces-
sary knowledge, by and large, exists; but it does not exist
in an organised, readily accessible form. It is scattered,
unsystematic, unorganised, and no doubt also incomplete.
The best aid to give is intellectual aid, a gift of useful
knowledge. A gift of knowledge is infinitely preferable to
197
making money go a very long way. For £100 you may
be able to equip one man with certain means of produc-
tion; but for the same money you may well be able to
teach a hundred men to equip themselves. Perhaps a little
"pump-priming" by way of material goods will in some
cases be helpful to speed the process; but this would be
purely incidental and secondary, and if the goods are
rightly chosen, those who need them can probably pay for
them.
A fundamental reorientation of aid in the direction I
advócate would require only a marginal reallocation of
funds. If Britain is currently giving aid to the tune of
about £250 million a year, the diversión of merely one
per cent of this sum to the organisation and mobilisation
of "gifts of knowledge" would, I am certain, change all
prospects and open a new and much more hopeful era in
the history of "development." One per cent, after all, is
—
about £2Vi million a sum of money which would go a
very, very long way for this purpose if intelligently
employed. And it might make the other ninety-nine per
cent immensely more fruitful.
Once we see the task of aid as primarily one of supply-
ing relevant knowledge, experience, know-how, etc. — that
is to say, intellectual rather than material goods — it is
198
obviously be good for the poor. As I have argued above,
this assumption is wrong, or at least, only very partially
right and preponderantly wrong.
So we get back to our two million villages and have to
see how we can make relevant knowledge available to
them. To do so, we must first possess this knowledge
ourselves. Before we can we must
talk about giving aid,
have something to give. We
do not have thousands of
poverty-stricken villages in our country; so what do we
know about effective methods of self-help in such circum-
stances? The beginning of wisdom is the admission of
one'sown lack of knowledge. As long as we think we
know, when in fact we do not, we shall continué to go to
the poor and demónstrate to them all the marvellous
things they could do if they were already rich. This has
been the main failure of aid to date.
But we do know something about the organisation and
we do have
systematisation of knowledge and experience;
facilities to do almost any job, provided only that we
clearly understand what it is. If the job is, for instance, to
assemble an effective guide to methods and materials for
low-cost building in tropical countríes, and, with the
aid of such a guide, to train local builders in developing
countríes in the appropriate technologies and methodolo-
gies, there is no doubt we can do this, or — to say the least
— that we can inmiediately take the steps which will
enable us to do this in two or three years' time. Similarly,
if we cleariy understand that one of the basic needs in
199
requirements and activities that they want assistance. If
they were not capable of self-help and self-reliance, they
would not survive today. But their own methods are all
200
ability, and Lnclination to think, write, and communicate.
Development work is far too difficult to be done succcss-
fully by any one of these three groups working in isola-
tion. Both in the donor countries and in the recipient
countries it is necessary to achieve what I cali the A-B-C
combination, where A stands for administrators; B stands
for businessmen; and C stands for communicators that is, —
intellectual workers, professionals of various descriptions.
It is only when this A-B-C combination is effectively
201
ods of organisation are required, because the policy is in
the imple mentation.
To implement the approach here advocated, action
groups need to be formed not only in the donor coun-
tries but also, and this is most important, in the developing
—
The function of Communications to enable each field
worker or group of field workers to know what other
work is going on in the geographical or "functional'*
territory in which they are engaged, so as to facilitate the
direct exchange of Information.
The function of information brokerage — to assemble
on a systematic basis and to disseminate relevant infor-
mation on appropriate technologies for developing coun-
202
tries, particularly on low-cost methods relating to build-
ing, water and power, crop-storage and processing,
small-scale manufacturing, health services, transporta-
tion and so forth. Here the essence of the matter is not
to hold all the information in one centre but to hold
"information on information" or "know-how on know-
how.'*
The function of "feed-back," that is to say, the trans-
mission of technical problems from the field workers in
developing coimtries to those places in the advanced
coimtries where suitable facilities for their solution exist.
The function of creating and coordinating "sub-struc-
tures," that is to say, action groups and verification
centres in the developing countries themselves.
203
producer, today threatens all countries throughout the
world, the rich even more than To restore a the poor.
proper balance between city and rural life is perhaps the
greatest task in front of modem man. It is not simply a
matter of raising agricultura! yields so as to avoid world
hunger. There is no answer to the evils of mass unemploy-
ment and mass migration into cities, unless the whole
level of rural life can be raised, and this requires the
development of an agro-industrial culture, so that each
district, each community, can offer a colourful variety of
occupations to its members.
The crucial task of this decade, therefore, is to make
the development effort appropriate and thereby more
effective, so that it will reach down to the heartland of
world poverty, to two million villages. If the disintegration
of rural life continúes, there is no way out —no matter
how much money is being spent. But if the rural people of
the developing countries are helped to help themselves, I
have no doubt that a genuine development will ensue,
without vast shanty towns and misery belts around every
big city and without the cruel frustrations of bloody
revolution. The task is formidable indeed, but the
resources that are waiting to be mobilised are also
formidable.
Economic development is something much wider and
deeper than economics, let alone econometrics. Its roots
he outside the economic sphere, in education, organisa-
beyond that, in political independence
tion, discipline and,
and a national consciousness of self-reliance. It cannot
be "produced" by skilful grafting operations carried out
by foreign technicians or an indigenous élite that has lost
contact with the ordinary people. It can succeed only if it
is carried forward as a broad, popular "movement of
reconstruction" with primary emphasis on the full utilisa-
204
form of magic produced by scientists, technicians, or
economic planners. It can come only through a process of
growth involving the education, organisation, and disci-
pline of the whole population. Anything less than thi5 must
end in failure.
205
4
The Probiem of
Unemployment in India
206
better themselves, but they do not know how to do it. So
we come to the question of know-how. If there are mil-
lions of people who want to better themselves but do not
know how to do it, who is going to show them? Consider
the size of the problem in India. We are not talking about
a few thousands or a few millions, but rather about a few
hundred millions of people. The size of the problem puts
it beyond any kind of little amelioration, any little reform,
207
when he wrote: "I sit on a man*s back, choking him, and
making him carry me, and yet assure myself and others
that I am very sorry for him and wish to ease his lot by
any means possible, except getting off his back." So this is
the first question I suggest we have to face. Can we
establish an ideology, or whatever you like to cali it, which
insists that the educated have taken upon themselves an
obligation and have not simply acquired a "passport to
privilege"? This ideology is of course well supported by all
the higher teachings of mankind. As a Christian, I may be
permitted to quote from St. Luke: "Much will be expected
of the man to whom much has been given. More will be
asked of him because he was entmsted with more." It is,
you might well say, an elementary matter of justice.
If this ideology does not prevail, if it is taken for
granted that education is a passport to privilege, then the
content of education will not primarily be something to
serve the people, but something to serve ourselves, the
educated. The privileged minority will wish to be edu-
cated in amanner that sets them apart and will inevitably
learn and teach the wrong things, that is to say, things
that do set them apart, with a contempt for manual
labour, a contempt for primary production, a contempt
for rural life, etc., etc. Unless virtually all educated people
see themselves as servants of their country —and that
means after all as servants of the common —
people ^there
cannot possibly be enough leadership and enough com-
munication of know-how to solve this problem of unem-
ployment or unproductive employment in the half million
villages of India. It is a matter of 500 million people. For
helping people to help themselves you need at least two
persons to look after 100 and that means an obligation to
raise ten million that is, the whole educated
helpers,
population of India. Now
you may say this is impossible,
but if it is, it is not so because of any laws of the universe,
but because of a certain inbred, ingrained selfishness on
the part of the people who are quite prepared to receive
208
and not prepared to give. As a matter of fact, there is
evidence thatthis probiem is not insoluble; but it can be
solved only at the political level.
Now let me tura to the third factor, after motivation
and after know-how, the factor I have called capital,
which is of course closely related to the matter of know-
how. According to my estimates there is in India an
immediate need for something like fifty million new jobs.
If we agree that people cannot do productive work unless
they have some capital —
in the form of equipment and
also of working capital —
the question arises: how much
capital can you afford to establish one new job? If it costs
£10 to establish a job you need £500 million for fifty
million jobs. If it costs £100 to establish a job you need
£5000 million, and if it costs £5000 per job, which is
what it might cost in Britain and the U.S.A., to set up
fifty million jobs you require £250,000 million.
you are lucky if you can make it five per cent. Therefore,
if you have five per cent of £15,000 million for ten years
209
And you say: "Only the best is good enough; we want
if
210
the Ford Motor Company. The Ford Motor Company
was set up on 16 June 1903 with an authorised capital of
$150,000, of which $100,000 were issued but only $28,500
were paid for in cash. So the total cash which went into
this enterprise was of the order of $30,000. They set up
in June 1903 and the first car to reach the market
appeared in October 1903, that is to say, after four
months. The employment in 1903, of course, was small
— 125 people, and the capital investment per workplace
was somewhat below £100. That was in 1903. If we now
move sixty years forward, to 1963, we find that the Ford
Motor Company decided to produce a new model, the
Mustang. The preparation required three and a half years.
Engineering and styling costs were $9 million; the costs
of tooling up for this new model were $50 million. Mean-
while the assets employed by the Company were $6000
million, which works out at almost £10,000 per person
employed, about a hundred times as much as sixty years
earlier.
211
few hours." If they now try to change even one screw, it
takes that many months. Fourth, increasingly specialised
manpower, not only on the machinery, but also on the
planning, the foreseeing of the future in the uttermost
detall. Fifth, a vastly different type of organisation to
intégrate all numerous specialists, none of whom
these
can do anything more than just one small task inside the
complicated whole. "So complex, indeed, will be the job
for organising specialists that there will be specialists of
organisation. More even than machinery, massive and
complex business organisations are being tangible manifes-
tations of advanced technology." Finally, the necessity for
long-range planning, which, I can assure you, is a highly
sophisticated job, and also highly frustrating. Galbraith
comments: "In the early days of Ford, the future was very
nearat hand. Only days elapsed between the commitment
of machinery and materials to production and their
appearance as a car. If the future is near at hand, it can
be assumed to be very much like the present," and the
planning and forecasting is not very difficult.
Now what is the upshot of all this? The upshot is that
the more sophisticated the technology, the greater in gen-
eral willbe the foregoing requirements. When the simple
things of life, which is all I am concerned with, are pro-
212
over the last fifty or sixty years in fact involves a quantum
jump. Everything was quite continuous in human history
till about the beginning of this century; but in the last
half-century there has been a quantum jump, the sort of
jump as with the capitalisation of Ford, from $30,000 to
$6000 million.
In a developing country enough to get
it is difficult
214
I.T.D.G. set itself the task to find out what are the tech-
nological choices. I will only give one example out of the
many activities of this purely prívate group. Take foundry
work and woodworking, metal and wood being the two
basic raw materíals of industry. Now, what are the alter-
native technologies that can be employed, arranged the m
order of capital intensity from the most primitive, when
people work with the simplest tools, to the most compli-
cated? This is shown in what we cali an industrial profile,
215
tion with exports, as far as I can see. One is real; the
other not so good. I shall first talk about the second one.
It is really a hangover of the economic thinking of the
duce for export into a rich country, I can take the avalla-
bility of purchasing power for granted, becarse my owi
little production is as nothing compared with what exists
already. But if I start new production in a poor country
there can be no local market for my products untess
divert the flow of purchasing power from some othei
product to mine. A dozen different productions should al
be started together: then for every one of the twelví
producéis the other eleven would be his market. There
would be additional purchasing power to absorb th(
additional output. But it is extremely diflBcult to start many
different activities at once. So the conventional advice is:
"Only production for export is proper development.*'
Such production is not only highly limited in scope, its
216
employment extremely limited. To compete
effect is also
in world markets, normally necessary to employ the
it is
217
Everything sounds very difficult and in a sense it is very
the most natural thing in the world. Only one must not be
blocked by being too damn clever about it. We are always
having all sorts of clever ideas about optimising something
before it even exists. I think the stupid man who says
"something is better than nothing" is much more intelli-
gent than the clever chap who will not touch anything
unless it is optimal. What is stopping us? Theories, plan-
ning. I have come across planners at the Planning Com-
mission who have convinced themselves that even within
fifteen years it is not possible to put the wUling labour
power of India to work. If they say it is not possible in
fifteen months, I accept that, because it takes time to get
around. But to throw up the sponge and say it is not
possible to do the most elementary thing within fifteen
years, this is just a sort of degeneracy of the intellect.
What is the argument behind it? Oh! the argument is very
clever, a spiendid piece of model building. They have
ascertained that in order to put a man to work you need
on average so much electricity, so much cement, and so
much Steel. This isshould like to remind you
absurd. I
218
mind, that unless you can have the latest you can't do
anything at all, and this is the thing that has to be over-
eóme.) You may say, again, this is not an economic
problem, but basically a political problem. It is basically
a problem of compassion with the ordinary people of the
world. It is basically a problem, not of conscripting the
ordinary people, but of getting a kind of voluntary con-
scription of the educated.
Another example: we are told by theorists and planners
that the number of people you can put to work depends
upon the amount of capital you have, as if you could not
put people to work to produce capital goods. We are told
there is no choice of technology, as if production had
started in the year 1971. We are told that it cannot be
economic to use anything but the latest methods, as if any-
thing could be more uneconomic than having people doing
absolutely nothing. We are told that it is necessary to
"eliminate the human factor."
The greatest deprivation anyone can suffer is to have no
chance of looking after himself and making a livelihood.
There is no conflict between growth and employment. Not
even a conflict as between the present and the future. You
will have to construct a very absurd example to demón-
strate that by letting people work you créate a conflict
between the present and the future. No country that has
developed has been able to develop without letting the
people work. On the one hand, it is quite true to say that
these things are diíficult: on the other hand, let us never
lose sight of the fact that we are talking about man*s
most elementary needs and that we must not be prevented
by all these high-faluting and very diíficult considerations
from doing the most elementary and direct things.
Now, at the risk of being misunderstood, I will give you
the simplest of all possible examples of self-help. The
Good Lord has not disinherited any of his children and as
far as India is concemed he has given her a variety of
trees unsurpassed anywhere in the world. There are trees
219
for almost all human needs. One of the greatest teachers
of India was the Buddha, who included in his teachmg
the obligation of every good Buddhist that he should plant
and see to the establishment of one tree at least every five
years. As long as this was observed, the whole large área
of India was covered with trees, free of dust, with plenty
of water, plenty of shade, plenty of food and materials.
Just imagine you could establish an ideology which would
make it obligatory for every able-bodied person in India,
man, woman and child, to do that little thing to plant —
and see to the establishment of one tree a year, five years
running. This, in a five-year period, would give you 2000
mUlion established trees. Anyone can work it out on the
back of an envelope that the economic valué of such an
enterprise, intelligently conducted, would be greater than
anything that has ever been promised by any of India*s
five-year plans. It could be done without a penny of for-
eign aid; there is no problem of savings and investment
It would produce foodstuffs, fibres, building material,
shade, water, almost anything that man really needs.
I just leave this as a thought, not as the final answer to
India's enormous problems. But I ask: what sort of an
education is this if it prevents us from thinking of things
ready to be done immediately? What makes us think we
need electricity, cement, and steel before we can do any-
thing at all? The really helpful things will not be done
from the centre; they cannot be done by big organisations;
but they can be done by the people themselves. If we can
recover the sense that it is the most natural thing for
every person bom into this world to use his hands in a
productive way and that it is not beyond the wit of nian to
make this possible, then I think the problem of unem-
ployment will disappear and we soon be asking our-
shall
selves how we can get all the work done that needs to be
done.
220
PART IV
Organisation and
Ownership
7
A Machine to Foretell
the Future?
223
them. While the Greeks — and
suppose most other natíons
I
—went to living oracles, to Pythias, Cassandras,
their
prophets and seers, the Chínese, remarkably, went to a
book and necessary pattera of
setting out the universal
changes, the very Laws of Heaven
to which all nature
conforms inevitably and to which man will conform freely
as a result of insight gained either from wisdom or from
suffering. Modem man goes to the computer.
Tempting as it may be to compare the ancient oracles
and the modem computer, only a comparison by contrast
is possible. The former deal exclusively with qualities; the
latter, with quantities. The inscription over the Delphic
temple was "Know Thyself," while the inscription on an
electronic computer is more likely to be: "Know Me,"
that "Study the Operating Instructions before Plugging
is,
224
these human beings, whom I have endowed with pretty
good brains, will undoubtedly learn to predict everything,
and they will thereupon have no motive to do anything at
all, because they will recognise that the future is totally
225
casting, budgeting, about surveys, programmes, targets,
and so forth, and we tend to use these terms as if they
were freely interchangeable and as if everybody would
automatically know what was meant The result is a great
deal of confusión, because it is in fact necessary to make a
number of fundamental distinctions. The terms we use
may refer to the past or to the future; they may refer to
acts or to events; and they may signify certainty or uncer-
tainty. The number of combinations possible when there
are three pairs of this kind is 2^, or 8, and we really
ought to have eight different terms to be quite certain
of what we are talking about. Our language, however, is
not as perfect as that. The most important distinction is
generally that between acts and events. The eight possible
cases may therefore be ordered as follows:
1.
—
to be necessary for our purpose, because, in fact, words
like "plan" or "estímate" are being used to refer to either.
If I say: "I shall not visit París without a plan," this can
mean: "I shall arm myseK with a street plan for orienta-
tion" and would therefore refer to case 5. Or it can mean:
"I shall arm myself with a plan which outlines in ad vanee
where I am going to go and how I am going to spend my
time and money" —
case 2 or 4. If someone claims that
"to have a plan is indispensable," it is not without interest
to find out whether he means the former or the latter.
The two are essentially diíferent.
Similarly, the word "estímate," which denotes uncer-
tainty, may apply to the past or to the future. In an ideal
world, it would not be necessary to make estimates about
things that had already happened. But in the actual
world, there is much even about matters
uncertainty
which, in principie, could be fuUy ascertained. Cases 3,
4, 7, and 8 represent four different types of estimates.
Case 3 relates to something I have done in the past; case 7,
to something that has happened in the past. Case 4 relates
to something I plan to do in the future, while case 8
relates to something I expect to happen in the future.
Case 8, in fact, is a forecast in the proper sense of the
term and has nothing whatever to do with "planning."
How often, however, are forecasts presented as if they
—
were plans and vice versal The British "National Plan"
of 1965 provides an outstanding example and, not sur-
prisingly, came to nothing.
Can we ever speak of future acts or events as certain
(cases 2 and 6)? If I have made a plan with full knowl-
edge of all the relevant facts, being inflexibly resolved to
carry it through — case 2 — I may, in this respect, consider
my future actions as certain. Similarly, in laboratory sci-
ence, dealing with carefully isolated deterministic systems,
future events may be described as certain. The real world,
however, is not a deterministic system; we may be able
to talk with certainty about acts or events of the past
227
cases 1 or 5 —but we can do so ahout future events only
on the basis of assumptions. In other words, we can for-
múlate conditional statements about the future, such as:
*7/ such and such a trend of events continued for another
X is where it would take us." This is not a fore-
years, this
cast or prediction, which must always be uncertain in the
real world, but an exploratory calculation, which, being
conditional, has the virtue of mathematical certainty.
Endless confusión results from the semantic muddle in
which we find ourselves today. As mentioned before,
"plans" are put forward which upon inspection tum out
to relate to events totally outside the control of the
planner. "Forecasts" are offered which upon inspection
tum out to be conditional sentences, in other words,
exploratory calculations. The latter are misinterpreted as
if they were forecasts or predictions. "Estimates" are put
forward which upon inspection tum out to be plans. And
so on and so forth. Our academic teachers would perform
a most necessary and really helpful task if they taught
their students to make the distinctions discussed above
and developed a tenninology which fixed them in words.
Predictability
228
of the future there enters that mysterious and irrepressible
factor called human freedom. It is the freedom of a being
of which it has been said that it was made in the image of
God the Creator: the freedom of creativity.
Strange to say, under the mfluence of laboratory science
many people today seem to use their freedom only for the
purpose of denying its existence. Men and women of great
gifts find their purest delight in magnifying every "mecha-
nism," every "inevitability," everything where human free-
dom does not enter or does not appear to enter. great A
shout of triumph goes up whenever anybody has found
—
some further evidence in physiology or psychology or
sociology or economics or politics —of unfreedom, some
further indication that people cannot help being what they
are and doing what they are doing, no matter how inhu-
man their actions might be. The denial of freedom, of
course, is a denial of responsibility: there are no acts, but
only events; everything simply happens; no one is respon-
sible. And this is no doubt the main cause of the semantic
229
economist, Professor Morgenstern, approvingly, as
foUows:
230
outcome. Yet all really important innovations and
changes normally start from tiny minorities of people who
do use their creative freedom.
It is true that social phenomena acquire a certain steadi-
ness and predictability from the non-use of freedom, which
means that the great majority of people responds to a
given situation in a way that does not alter greatly in
time, unless there are really overpowering new causes.
We can therefore distinguish as follows:
Short'Term Forecasts
231
It is good to know of all the different possibilities of
232
from the current picture. This having been done, the
'
233
Crude methods of forecasting — after the current pie-
ture has been corrected for abnormalities — are not likely
to lead into the errors of spurious verisimilitude and
spurious detailing — the two greatest vices of the statisti-
cian. Once you have a formula and an electronic Com-
puter, there an awful temptation to squeeze the lemon
is
Planning
234
a plan, that is to say, that he should use power deliber-
235
must be clear that, change being a function of time, the
longe^-term future iseven less predictable than the short-
term. In fact, aU long-term forecasting is somewhat pre-
sumptuous and absurd, unless it is of so general a kind
that it merely states the obvious. All the same, there is
236
could not solve his equations unless he introduced assump-
tions which transcended all bounds of reasonable probabU-
ity. This might prove highly instructive. It might conceiv-
237
facilitated by more mechanical aids such as electronic
computers. Personally, I am inclined to doubt it. It seems
238
rule and a set of compound interest tables are not quite
sufiicient for the purpose.
239
world economic equilibria, even in the longer nin, are
highly dependent on political and social changes; and that
the sophisticated and ingenious methods of forecasting
employed by Mr. Clark merely served to produce a work
of spurious verisimilitude.
Conclusión
240
2
Towards a Theory of
Large-Scale Organisation
241
But the only really effective communication is from man
to man, face to face. Frank Kafka's nightmarish novel,
The Castle, depicls the devastating effects of remote con-
trol. Mr. K., the land surveyor, has been hired by the
authorities, but nobody quite knows how and why. He
tries to get his position clarified, because the people he
meets all tell him: "Unfortunately we have no need of a
land surveyor. There would not be the least use for one
here.*'
So, making every effort to meet authority face to face,
Mr. K. approaches various people who evidently carry
some weight; but others tell him: "You haven't once up
till now come into real contact with our authorities. All
these contacts are merely illusory, but owing to your
ignorañce . you take them to be real."
. .
242
encounters such oppositesy each of them with persuasivc
arguments in its favour, it is worth looking into the depth
of the problem for something more than compromise,
more than a half-and-half solution. Maybe what we really
need is not either-or but the-one'and-the-other'Ot'the
same-time.
This very familiar problem pervades the whole of real
life, although it is highly impopular with people who spend
most of their time on laboratory problems from which all
extraneous factors have been carefuUy eliminated. For
whatever we do in real life, we must try to do justice to a
situation which includes all so-called extraneous factors.
And we always have to face the simultaneous requirement
for order and freedom.
In any organisation, large or small, there must be a cer-
tain claríty and orderllness; if things fall into disorder,
nothing can be accomplished. Yet, orderliness, as such, is
static and lifeless; so there must also be plenty of elbow-
room and scope for breaking through the established
order, to do the thing never done before, never antici-
pated by the guardians of orderliness, the new, unpre-
dicted and unpredictable outcome of a man's creative
idea.
Therefore any organisation has to strive continuously
for the orderliness of order and the disorderliness of
creative freedom. And the specific danger inherent in
large-scale organisation is that its natural bias and tend-
ency favour order, at the expense of creative freedom.
We can associate many further pairs of opposites with
this basic pair of order and freedom. Centralisation is
mainly an idea of order; decentralisation, one of freedom.
The man of order is typically the accountant and, gen-
erally, the administrator; while the man of creative free-
dom is the entrepreneur, Order requires intelligence and
is conducive to efficiency; while freedom calis for, and
opens the door to, intuition and leads to innovation.
The larger an organisation, the more obvious and ines-
243
capable is the need for order. But if this need is looked
244
The opposites of centralising and decentralising are
now far behind us: the Principie of Subsidiary Function
teaches us that the centre will gain in authority and effec-
tiveness if the freedom and responsibility of the lower
245
prises under the heading of diversification. The
falling
board*s primary activity, deep-mined coal-getting, has
been organised in seventeen áreas, each of them with the
status of a quasi-firm. The source already quoted describes
the results of such a structurisation as foUows: "Thereby
[the centre] will more freely, powerfully and effectively
do all those things which belong to it alone because it
alone can do them: directing, watching, urging, restrain-
ing, as occasion requires and necessity demands."
For central control to be meaningful and effective, a
second principie has to be applied, which we shall cali
The Principie of Vindication. To vindícate means: to
defend against reproach or accusation; to prove to be tnie
and valid; to justify; to uphold; so this principie describes
very well one of the most important duties of the central
authority towards the lower formations. Good govern-
ment is always govemment by exception. Except for
exceptional cases, the subsidiary unit must be defended
against reproach and upheld. This means that the excep-
tion must be sufficiently cleariy defined, so that the quasi-
firm is able to know without doubt whether or not it is
performing satisfactorily.
Administrators taken as a pure type, namely as men of
orderiiness, are happy when they have everything under
control. Armed with computéis, they can indeed now do
so and can insist on accountability with regard to an
almost infinite number of items — output, productivity,
many dijfferent cost items, non-operational expenditure,
and so on, leading up to profit or loss. This is logical
enough: but real life is bigger than logic. If a large num-
ber of Gritería is laid down for accountability, every
on one item or another;
subsidiary unit can be faulted
govemment by exception becomes a mockery, and no one
can ever be sure how his unit stands.
In its ideal application, the Principie of Vindication
would permit only one criterion for accountability in a
conmiercial organisation, namely profitability. Of course,
246
such a criterion would be subject to the quasi-firm*s
observing general rules and policies laid down by the
centre. Ideáis can rarely be attained in the real world, but
they are none the less meaningful. They imply that any
departure from the ideal has to be specially argued and
Unless the number of criteria for accountability
justified.
247
occurs when the centre and the subsidiary unit cannot
come to a free agreement on the rent or subsidy, as the
case may be, which is to be applied. In such circumstances
the centre has to undertake a full efficiency audit Of the
unit to obtain an objective assessment of the unifs real
potential. The second opportunity arises when the unit
fails to eam a profit, after allowing for rent or subsidy.
The management of the unit is then in a precarious posi-
tion: if the centre*s eflSciency audit produces highly
unfavourable evidence, the management may have to be
changed.
The third principie is The Principie of Identification.
Each subsidiary unit or quasi-firm must have both a profit
and loss account and a balance sheet. From the point of
view of orderiiness a profit and loss statement is quite
sufficient, sincefrom this one can know whether or not
the unit is contributing financially to the organization. But
for the entrepreneur, a balance sheet is essential, even if it
is used only for interaal purposes. Why is it not sufficient
248
concerned to follow the effect of operations qn substance.
Profits and losses are carried forward and not wiped out.
Therefore, every quasi-firm should have its sepárate bal-
ance sheet, in which profits can appear as loans to the
centre and losses as loans from the centre. This is a mat-
ter of great psychological importance.
I now tum to the fourth principie, which can be called
The of Motivation. It is a trite and obvious
Principie
truism that people act in accordance with their motives.
All the same, for a large organisation, with its bureaucra-
cies, its remote and impersonal controls, its many abstract
rules and regulations, and above all the relative incom-
prehensibility that stems from its very size, motivation is
the central problem. At the top, the management has no
problem of motivation, but going down the scale, the
,
249
those who have no desire to be in it." Many have no
desire to be in because their work does not interest
it,
250
nation rushing in where bureaucratic angels fear to tread
—without this, life is a mockery and a disgrace.
The centre can easily look after order: it is not so easy
to look after freedom and The centre has the
creativity.
power to establish order, but no amount of power evokes
the Creative contribution. How, then, can top management
at the centre work for progress and innovation? Assuming
that it knows what ought to be done: how can the man-
agement get it done throughout the organísation? This is
where the Principie of the Middle Axiom comes in.
An axiom is a self-evident truth which is assented to as
soon as enunciated. The centre can enunciate the truth it
has discovered —
that this or that is "the right thing to do."
Soma years ago, the most important truth to be enunci-
ated by the National Coal Board was concentration of
output, that is, to concéntrate coal-getting on fewer coal-
faces, with a higher output from each. Everybody, of
course, immediately assented to it, but, not surprisingly,
very little happened.
A change of this kind requires a lot of work, a lot of
new thinking and planning at every coUiery, with many
natural obstacles and difl&culties to be overeóme. How is
251
—
instruction meets the requirements of the case. What is
252
carry through its creative ideas without impairing the
freedom and responsibility of the lower formations.
I have expounded five principies which I believe to be
253
—
3
Socialism
254
The bourgeoisie, wherever it has got the upper hand, has
put an end to all and has
feudal, patriarchal, idyllic relations
Icft no other nexus between man and maw than naked self-
interest. ...
The bourgeoisie, by the rapid improvement of all instru-
ments of production, by the immensely facilitated means of
communication, draws all, even the most barbarían, nations
into civilisation. [Communist Manifestó]
alternaíive.
It is no accident that successful businesmen are often
astonishingly primitive; they live in a world made primi-
tive by this process of reduction. They fit into this simpli-
255
fied versión of the world and are satisfied with it. And
when the real world occasionally makes its existence
known and attempts to forcé upon their attention a dif-
ferent one of its facets, one not provided for in their
philosophy, they tend to become quite helpless and con-
fused. They feel exposed to incalculable dangers and
"unsound" forces and freely predict general disaster. As a
result, their judgements on actions dictated by a more
comprehensive outlook on the meaning and purpose of life
are generally quite worthless. It is a foregone conclusión
for them that a different scheme of things, a business,
for instance, that is not based on prívate owhership, can-
not possibly succeed. If it succeeds all the same, there
—
must be a sinister explanation "exploitation of the con-
sumer," "hidden subsidies,'* "forced labour," "monopoly,"
"dumping," or some dark and dreadful accumulation of a
debit account which the future will suddenly present.
But this is a digression. The point is that the real
strength of the theory of prívate enterprise lies in this
which fits so admirably also into the
ruthless simplification,
mental pattems created by the phenomenal successes of
science. The strength of science, too, deríves from a
"reduction" of reality to one or the other of its many
aspects, primarily the reduction of quality to quantity. But
just as the powerful concentration of nineteenth-century
scienceon the mechanical aspects of reality had to be
'
256
really have to do; we try to preserve the beauty of the
countiyside; we engage in research that may not pay off,"
etc., etc. All these claims are very familiar; sometimes
holders.
Qearly, the protagonists of capitalism cannot have it
both ways. They cannot say "We are all socialists now"
and maintain at the same time that socialism cannot possi-
bly work. If they themselves pursue objectives other than
that of profít-making, then they cannot very well argüe
that it becomes impossible to administer the nation*s
means of production efficiently as soon as considerations
other than those of profit-making are allowed to enter. If
they can manage without the crude yardstick of money-
making, so can nationalised industry.
On the other hand, if all this is rather a sham and prí-
vate enterpríse works for profit and (practicaUy) nothing
else; if its pursuit of other objectives is in fact solely
dependent on profít-making and constitutes merely its own
cholee of what to do with some of the profits, then the
sooner this is made clear the better. In that case, prívate
enterpríse could still claim to possess the power of sim-
plicity. Its case against public enterpríse would be that the
latter is bound to be inefficient precisely because it
257
—
attempts to pursue several objectives at the same time,
and the case of socialists against the former would be the
traditional case, which is not primarily an economic one,
namely, that it degrades life by its very simplicity, by
258
least for a period, to find a middie way that reconciles the
opposites without degrading them both.
The same applies to the choice of objectives in business
life.One of the opposites —represented by prívate enter-
prise "oíd style" — is the need for simplicíty and measura-
bility, which is best fulfilled by a strict limitation of
outlook to "profitability" and nothing else. The other
opposite' —represented by the original "idealistic" concep-
tion of public enterprise — is the need for a comprehensive
and broad humanity in the conduct of economic affairs.
The former, if exclusively adhered to, leads to the total
destruction of the dignity of man; the latter, to a chaotic
kind of inefficiency.
There are no "final solutions" to this kind of problem.
There is only a living solution achieved day by day on a
basis of a clear recognition that both opposites are valid,
Ownership, whether public or prívate, is merely an
element of framework. It does not by itself settle the kind
of objectives to be pursued within the framework. From
this point of view it is correct to say that ownership is not
the decisive question. But it is also necessary to recognise
that ownership of the means of production is
prívate
severely limited in its freedom of choice of objectives,
because it is compelled to be profit-seeking, and tends to
take a narrow and selfish view of things. Public ownership
gives complete freedom in the choice of objectives and
can therefore be used for any purpose that may be chosen.
While prívate ownership an instniment that by itself
is
259
—
260
Socialists should insist on using the nationalised indus-
tries not simply to out-capitalisethe capitalists —
an
attempt in which they may or may not succeed —but to
evolve a more democratic and dignified system of indus-
trial administration, a more humane employment of
machinery, and a more intelligent utilisation of the fniits
of human ingenuity and efiíort If they can do that, they
have the future in their hands. If they cannot, they have
nothing to offer that is worthy of the sweat of free-bora
men.
261
4
Ownership
262
fateful propensity that rejoices in the fact that •'what were
luxuríes to our fathers have become necessitíes for us."
Systems are never more ñor less than incarnations of
man*s most basic altitudes. Some incamations, indeed, are
more perfect than others. General evidence of material
progress would suggest that the modern prívate enterprise
system is —or has been— the most perfect instrument for
the pursuit of personal enríchment. The modern prívate
enterpríse system ingeniously employs the human urges of
greed and envy as its motive power, but manages to over-
263
parasitically on the work of others. This basic distinction
was clearly seen by Tawney, who followed that "it is idle,
264
achievement not of the owner but of the whole orga-
nisation. It is therefore unjust and socially disruptive
265
not and cannot be prívate in any real sense. Again, R. H.
Tawney saw this with complete clarity:
with the rights which secure tbe owner the produce of bis
toil, but is the opposite of them.
To sum up:
266
render of privilege to the wider group of actual workers
— as in the case of Scott Bader & Co. I td. Such an act
of generosity may be unlikely when there is a large
number of anonymous shareholders, but legislation could
pave the way even then.
3. prívate ownership is a
In large-scale enterprise,
fiction for the purpose of enabling functionless owners
to live parasitically on the labour of others. It is not
only unjust but also an irrational element which distorts
all relationships within the enterprise. To quote Tawney
again:
known and the claims are admitted, that is all they can
quarrel about. . . . But in industry the claims are not all
267
!k
—
those who desire to maintain the system under which industry
¡s carried on, not as a profcssion serving the public, but for
the advantage of shareholders, attack nationalisation on the
ground that State management is necessaríly inefficient
268
the remcdy for over-centralisation is not the maintenance of
functionless property in prívate hands, but the decentralised
ownership of public property.
269
nationalised enterprise should be concemed only with
profits, as if it worked for prívate shareholders, while the
interpretation of the public interest could be left to gov-
emment alone. This idea has únfortimately invaded the
theory of how to run nationalised industries in Brítain, so
that these industries are expected to work only for profit
and to deviate from this principie only if instnicted by
govemment to do so and compensated by govemment for
doing so. This tidy división of functions may commend
itself to theoreticians but hasno merit in the real worid,
for it destroys the very ethos of management within the
nationalised industries. "Serving the public interest in all
respects'* means nothing unless it permeates the everyday
behaviour of management, and this cannot and should not
be controlled, let alone financially compensated, by gov-
emment. That there may be occasional conflicts between
pijpfit-seekingand serving the public interest cannot be
denied. But this simply means that the task of running a
nationalised industry makes higher demands than that of
running private enterprise. The idea that a better society
could be achieved without making higher demands is self-
contradictory and chimerical.
Fourth, to enable the "public interest" to be recognised
and to be safeguarded in nationalised industries, there is
need for arrangements by which all legitímate interests
can find expression and exercise influence, namely, those
of the employees, the local community, the consumers,
and also the competitors, particularly if the last-named
are themselves nationalised industries. To implement this
principie effectively still requires a good deal of experi-
mentation. No perfect "models" are available anywhere.
The problem is always one of safeguarding these interests
without unduly impairing management's ability to manage.
Finally, the chief danger to nationalisation is the plan-
ner's addiction to over-centralisation. In general, small
enterprises are to be preferred to large ones. Instead of
creating a large enterprise by nationalisation — as has
270
invariably been the practice hitherto — and then attempt-
ing to decentralise power and responsibility to smaller
formations, normally better to créate semi-autono-
¡t is
271
5
New Patterns of Ownership
272
an endless battie of wits between tax collectors
this leads to
and in which the rich, with the help of highly
citizens,
paid tax experts, normally do very much better than the
poor. In an effort to stop "loopholes" the tax laws become
ever more complicated and the demand for —
and there-
fore the income of —
tax consultants becomes ever larger.
As the taxpayers feel that something they have earned is
being taken away from them, they not only try to exploit
every possibility of legal tax avoidance, not to mention
practices of ülegal tax evasión, they also raise an insistent
cry in favour of the curtailment of public expenditure.
"More taxation for more public expenditure" would not
be a vote-catching slogan in an election campaign, no
matter how glaring may be the discrepancy between prí-
vate affluence and public squalor.
There is no way out of this dilemma unless the need for
public expenditure is recognised in the structure of owner-
ship of themeans of production.
not merely a question of public squalor, such as the
It is
273
which prívate enterprise does not pay directly as a matter
of course, but only indirectly by way of taxes, which, as
already mentioned, are resisted, resented, campaigned
against, and often skilfully avoided. It is highly illogical
and leads to endless complications and mystifications, that
payment for benefits obtained by prívate enterprise from
the "infrastructure" cannot be exacted by the public
authorities by a direct participation in profits but only
after the prívate appropriation of profits has taken place.
Prívate enterprise claims that its profits are being eamed
by its own efforts, and that a substantial part of them is
274
exceeding £72,000. Having started with virtually nothing,
he and his family had become prosperous. His firm had
I established itself as a leading producer of polyester resins
and also manufactured otber sophisticated producís, such
as alkyds, polymers, and plasticisers. As a young man he
had been deeply dissatisfied with his prospects of life as an
employee; he had rasen ted the very ideas of a "labour
market" and a "wages system," and particularly the
thought that capital employed men, instead of men
employing capital. Finding himself now in the position of
employer, he never forgot that his success and prosperity
were the achievements not of himself alone but of all his
collaborators and decidedly also of the society within
which he was privileged to opérate. To quote his own
words:
275
in which he vested (in two steps: ninety per cent in 1951
and the remaining ten per cent in 1963) the ownership
of his firm, Scott Bader Co. Ltd. To implement the sec-
ond, he agreed with his new partners, that is to say, the
members of the Commonwealth, his former employees, to
establish a constitution not only to define the distribution
of the "bundle of powers" which prívate ownership implies,
but also to impose the following restrictions on the finn's
freedom of action:
276
one-half of the appropriated profits to the payment of
bonuses to those working within the operating company
and the other half to charítable purposes outside the
Scott Bader organisation.
And finally, none of the products of Scott Bader Co.
Ltd. shall be sold to customers who are known to use
them for war-related purposes.
277
nary commercial practice. In other words, the Bader
"system" overcomes the reductionism of the prívate
ownership system and uses industrial organisation as a
servant of man, instead of allowing it to use men simply
as means to the enrichment of the owners of capital. To
quote Eraest Bader:
278
Commonwealth; but it ís neither legally ñor existcntially
true to say that the Commonwealth members, as indi-
viduáis, establish any kind of ownership in the Conmion-
wealth. In truth, ownership has been replaced by specific
rightsand responsibilities in the administration of assets.
Second, while no one has acquired any property, Mr.
Bader and his family have nonetheless depríved them-
selves of their property. They have volimtarily abandoned
the chance of becoming inordinately rich. Now, one does
not have to be a believer in total equality, whatever that
may mean, to be able to see that the existence of inordi-
nately rich people in any society today is a very great evü.
Some of wealth and income are no doubt
inequalities
and functionally justifiable, and there are few
"natural**
people who do not spontaneously recognise this. But here
again, as in all human affaírs, it is a matter of scale.
Excessive wealth, like power, tends to corrupt. Even if the
rich are not "idle rich,*' even when they work harder than
anyone else, they work differently, apply different stand-
ards, and are set apart from common himianity. They
corrupt themselves by practising greed, and they corrupt
the rest of society by provoking envy. Mr. Bader drew
the consequences of these insights and refused to become
inordinately rich and thus made it possible to build a real
community.
Third, while the Scott Bader experiment demonstrates
with the utmost clarity that a transformation of ownership
is essential —without it everything remains make-believe
— ^it also demonstrates that the transformation of owner-
ship is merely, so to speak, an enabling act: it is a neces-
sary, but not a sufficient, condition for the attainment of
higher aims. The Commonwealth, accordingly, recognised
that the tasks of a business organisation m society are not
simply to make profits and to grow
and to maximise profits
and to become powerful: the Commonwealth recognised
four tasks, all of equal importance:
279
: — ,
280
—
281
between the democratic and the ñmctional organs of the
organisatíon.
As mentioned at the beginning of this account, Mr.
Emest Bader set out to make "revolutionary changes** in
his firm, but "to do this by ways and means that could be
generaUy acceptable to the prívate sector of industry.'* His
revoIutíoQ has been bloodless; no one has come to gríef,
not even Mr. Bader or his family; with plenty of strikes
all around them, the Scott Bader people can proudly
282
New Methods of Socialisation
283
:
1. Freedom 5. Totalitarianisra
Market Economy Market Economy
Prívate Ownership Prívate Ownership
2. Freedom 6. Totalitarianisra
Planning Planning
Prívate Ownership Prívate Ownership
3. Freedom 7. Totalitarianisra
Market Economy Market Economy
CoUectivised Ownership Ownership
Collectivised
4. Freedom 8. Totalitarianisra
Planning Planning
Collectivised Ownership Collectivised Ownership
284
I have already argued that prívate enterprise in a
so-called advanced society derives very large benefits
from the infrastructure —
both visible and invisible which —
such a society has built up through public expenditure.
But the public hand, although it defrays a considerable
part of the cost of prívate enterprise, does not directly
particípate in its profits; all these profits are initially pri-
vately appropriated, and the public hand then has to try
to cover its own financial requirements by extracting a
part of these profits from prívate pockets. The modem
busínessman never of claiming and complainíng that,
tires
to a large extent, he "works for the state," that the state
is hís partner, inasmuch as profit taxes absorb a substan-
285
these companies into no-par shares after the American
pattem.
4. The niimber of shares issued, including preference
shares and any other pieces of paper which represent
equity, should be doubled by the issue of an eqnivalent
number of new shares, these new shares to be hdd by
"the public hand" so that for every privately held oíd
share one new share with identical ríghts will be held
publidy.
286
tralisation of public participation and the integration of
business enterprises with the social organism within whicb
they opérate and from which they derive incalculable
benefits. Thus, the half-share in the equity of a business
operating within District X should be held by a local body
generally representative of the populaíion of District X.
However, neither the locally elected (political) personali-
ties ñor the local civil servants are necessarily the most
287
with the new, publicly-owned equity shares would nor-
mally remain a mere possibility in the background and
could becorae a reality only as a result of certain specific,
formal, and public steps baving been taken by the "public
hand." And even when in exceptional cases these steps
have been taken and the voting rights of the publicly-
owned shares have beren activated, the new situation
would persist only for a short time, so that there should
be no doubt as to what was to be considered a normal or
an abnormal división of functions.
It is often thought that "the public interest'* can be safe-
288
Having thus briefly sketched the rights and duties asso-
ciated with the new shares, we can now retum to the
question oí personnel. The general aim of the scheme is to
intégrate large-scale business enterprises as closely as
possible with their social surroundings, and this aim must
govem also our solution of the personnel question. The
exercise of the pecuniary and manageríal ríghts and duties
arísing from industrial ownership should certainly be kept
out of party political controversy. At the same time, it
should not fall to civil servants, who have been appointed
for quite different purposes. I suggest, therefore, that it
289
that such interventionswould be the exception rather than
the rul^ and that in normal circumstanccs the Social
all
290
man is always tempted to argüe that "the Exchequer will
291
aüi& so forth. They are all perfectly soluble in accordance
with the principies already stated. In the case of wind-
ings-up, whether in bankruptcy or othenvise, the equity
holdings of the public hand would, of course, receive
same treatment as those in prívate hands.
exactly the
The above proposals may be taken as nothing more
than an exercise in the art of "constitution-making." Such
a scheme would be perfectly feasible; it would restructure
large-scale industrial ownership without revolution, expro-
priation, centralisation, or the substitution of bureaucratic
ponderousness for prívate flexibility. It could be intro-
duced in an experímental and evolutionary manner by —
starting with the biggest enterprises and gradually working
down the scale, until it was felt that the public interest
had been given sufficient weight in the citadels of business
enterpríse. All the indications are that the present struc-
ture of large-scale industríal enterprise, in spite of heavy
taxation and an endless proliferation of legislation, is not
conducive to the public welf are.
292
Epilogue
293
added unto you." They shall be added, we are told, here
on earth where we need them, not simply in an after-life
beyond our imagination. Today, however, this message
reaches us not solely from the sages and saints but from
the actual course of physical events. It speaks to us in the
language of terrorism, genocide, breakdown, pollution,
exhaustion. We live, it seems, in a unique period of
convergence. It is becoming apparent that there is not
and more from the Truth, it can also be said that on all sides
the Truth is closing in more and more upon man. It might
almost be said that, in order to receive'a touch of It, which
in the past required a lifetime of effort, all that is asked
of him now is not to shrink back. And yet how difl&cult
that is!i
294
The "logic of production** is neither the logic of life ñor
that of society. a small and subservient part of both.
It is
295
— —
296
tion is. The pre-eminencc of prudcncc means that so-called
"good intentions" and so-caUed "meaning well** by no means
sufiBce. Realisation of the good presupposes that our actiona
are appropríate to the real sítuation, that is to the concrete
which form the "cnvironment" of a concrete human
realities
action; and that we therefore take this concrete reality
seriously, with clear-eyed object¡vity.«
297
Notes and Acknowledgments
4. BuDDHisT Economics
First published in Asia: A Handbooky edited by Guy Wint,
published by Anthony Blond Ltd., London, 1966.
1. The New Burma (Economic and Social Board, Gov-
ernment of the Union of Burma, 1954)
2. Ibid.
3. Ibid.
4. Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith
5. Art and Swadeshi by Ananda K. Coomaraswamy
(Ganesh & Co., Madras)
299
6. Economy of Permanence by J. C. Kumarappa (Sarva-
Seva Sangh Publicatíon, Rajghat, Kashi, 4th edn., 1958)
7. The Affluent Society by John Kenneth Galbraith
(Penguin Books Ltd., 1962)
8. A Philosophy of Indian Economic Development by
Richard B. Gregg (Navajivan Publishíng House, Ahmeda-
bad, India, 1958)
9. The Challenge of Man's Future by Hanison Brown
(The Viking Press, New York, 1954)
5. A. QUESTION OF SlZE
Based on a lecture given in London, August 1968, and first
PART n. RESOURCES
1. The Greatest Resource —Education
1. Note: Incidentally, the Second Law of TTiermo-
dynamics states that heat cannot of ¡tself paas from a
colder to a hotter body, or, more vulgarly, that "You
cannot warm yourself on something that is colder than
—
you" a familiar though not very inspiríng idea, which has
been quite illegitimately extended to the pseudo-scientific
notion that the universe must necessarily end in a kind of
**heat death** when all temperature differences will have
ceased.
300
2. The Propep. Use op Land
1. Topsoil and Civilisation by Tora Dale and Vernon
Gilí Cárter (University of Oklahoma Press, Norman, Okla.,
1955)
2. Man and His Future, edited by Gordon Wolsten-
holme (A Giba Foundation Volume, J. & A. Churchill Ltd.,
London, 1963)
3. The Soul of a PeopU by R
Ficlding HaU (Mao-
millan & Co., Ltd., London, 1920)
4. Our Accelerating Century by Dr. S. L. Mansholt
(The Roya] Dutch/Shell Lectures on Industry and Society,
London, 1967)
5. A Future far European Agriculture by D. Bergmann,
M. Rossí-Doría, N. Kaldor, J. A. Schnittker, H. B. Krohn,
C. Thomsen, J. S. March, H. Wilbrandt, Fierre Uri (The
Atlantic Institute, París, 1970)
6. Ibid,
7. Ibid,
8. Ibid,
9. Ibid.
10. Our SyntheticEnvironment by Murray Bookchin (Joña»
tfaan Cape Ltd., London, 1963)
11. ¡bid.
12. Op.ciU
13. Op, cit.
301
2. "Die Haftung für Strahlenscháden in Grossbrítan-
nicn" by C. T. Highton, in Die Átomwirtschaft: Zeitschrift
für wirtschaftliche Fragen der Kemumwandlung, 1959
3. Radiarion: What it h
and How It Affects You by
Jack Schubert and Ralph Lapp (The Vikíng Press, New
York. 1957). Also, Die Strahlengefáhrdung des Menschen
durch Atomenergie by Hans Marquardt and Gerhard Schu-
bert (Hamburg, 1959); Vol. XI oí Proceedings of thc
International Conference on the Peaceful Uses of Atomic
Energy, Geneva, 1955; and Vol. XXII of Proceedings oí
the Second United Nations International Conference on
the Peaceful Uses of Atomic Energy, Geneva, 1958
4. "Changing Genes: Their Effects on Evolution** by
H. J. Muller, in Bulletin of the Atomic ScientistSy 1947
5. Statement by G. Failla, Hearings before the Special
schaft, 1960
9. U.S. Atomic Energy Commission, Annual Report to
302
That Must Be Conaidered in the Disposal oí Radioactive
Wastes** by K. Z. Morgan, in Industrial Radioactive Dis-
posal, Vol. m
15. und künstliche Erbandcnmgcn- by H.
**Natürliche
Marquardt, in Probleme der Mutationsforschung (Ham-
burg. 1957)
16. Schubert and Lapp, op. ciL
17. 'Today's Rcvolutíon" by A. M. Wcinbcrg, in BuUetin
of the Aíomic Scientists, 1956
18. Must the Bomb Spread? by Leonard Beatón (Pengiiin
Books Ltd., in association with the Institute of Strategic
Studies, London, 1966)
19. "From Bomb to Man" by W. O. Caster, in Fallout,
edited by John M. Fowler (Basic Books, New York, 1960)
20. Op. cit.
303
The Economic Commission for Latín America, Santiago,
Chile, September 1965.
1. "A Plan for FuU Employment in the Developing
Countríes" by Gabriel Ardant, in International Labour Re-
view, 1963
2. "Wages and Employment in the Labor-Surplus Econ-
omy" by L. G. Reynolds, in American Economic Review,
1965
3. ¡ndustrialisation in Developing Countries, edited by
Ronald Robinson (Cambridge University Overseaa Studies
Conmiittee, Cambridge, 1965)
4. Ibid.
5. Ibid., quoted from **Notes on Latín American Indus-
trial Development" by Ñuño F. de Figueíredo
6. Ibid.
7. 'Technologies Appropriate for the Total Develop-
ment Plan" by D. R. Gadgil, in Appropriate Technologies
for Iridian Industry (SIET Instítute, Hyderabad, India,
1964)
304
2. TowARDs A Theory of Laroe-Scale Organtsation
First published in "Management Decisión," Quarterly Re-
view of Management Technology, London, Autumn 1967.
1. Encyclical "Quadragesimo Anno"
2. Selected Works by Mao Tse-tung, Vol. m
3. SOCIALISM
4. OWNERSHIP
All quotations ín this chaptcr are from The Acquisitive
Society by R. H. Tawney.
Epilogue
1. Ancient Beliefs and Modern Superstitions by Martin
Lings (Perennial Books, Lx)ndon, 1964)
2. Pollution: Nuisance or Nemesis? (HMSO, London,
1972)
3. Ibid,
4. Ibid.
5. Ibid.
6. Prudence by Joseph Pieper, translatcd by Richard
and Clara Winston (Faber and Faber Ltd., London, 1960)
7. Fortitude and Temperjance by Joseph Pieper, trans-
latcd by Daniel F. Coogan (Faber and Faber Ltd., London,
1955)
8. Justice by Joseph Pieper, translated by Lawrence E.
305
ECONOMICS
E. F Schumocher
SMALL IS BEAUTIFUL
Economics os lí People Mottered
Introduction byTheodore Roszok
Gandhi.capitalismandBuddhism.scienceandpsychology."
-PETER BARNES, The New Republic
j
Tperennialubrary
HARPER & ROW, PUBLISHERS ISBN D" D b - D ñD 3 SE'S
Cover design by Randall Richmond DflD3ñG75