Solutions of Linear Differential Equations: Appendixa
Solutions of Linear Differential Equations: Appendixa
Solutions of Linear
Differential Equations
y = y*+y\ (A.3)
where y* is any other particular solution to (A.2) and y^ is a suitable
solution to the homogeneous equation. Therefore, solving (A.2) involves
(a) finding all the solutions to the homogeneous equation, caUed the gen-
eral solution, and (b) finding a particular solution to the given equation.
364 A. Solutions of Linear Differential Equations
The rest of these notes indicate how to solve these two problems.
Given (A.l) the auxiliary equation is
p{m) = mP + aim^'^ + ... + an-im + an = 0, (A.4)
In other words, p{m) is obtained from p{D) by replacing D by m. The
auxiliary equation is an ordinary polynomial of nth degree and has n real
or complex roots, counting multiple roots according to their multiplicity.
We will see that, given these roots, we can write the general solution
forms of homogeneous Unear differential equations.
= e^*(Cie^^ + C2e-^^)
or
- e"^(Cie^^* + C2e-'^^)
or
or
or
2. ( D - 3 ) 2 ( D + 5 ) 3 ( D 2 - 4 D + 5)2y=0 2/(t)-e3*(Ci+C2t)
+ e - 5 t ( C 3 + C4t + C5t2)
+e2*[(C6+C7)sin t
^ ( C s + CgOoos t]
+(C4-f-C5t-f C6t2)cos i]
(i)c 0 A
(2) h{t) 0 X
Notation.
(a) In the forcing function column, p, q, and c are given constants and h{t) is a
given polynomial of degree s.
(b) In the p>articular integral column, A and B are coefficients to be determined
and
Rules.
(a) If the number in the K column is not a root of the auxiliary equation p(m) = 0,
then the proper guess for the particular integral is as shown.
(b) If the number in the K colimin is a root of the auxiliary equation of degree r,
then multiply the guess in the last column by t^.
1.2/'"-32/" = 5 At^
2. y'" - 3y" = l + 3t + 5t^ t^Ao + Ait + A2t'^)
3. 2 / " - V + 42/ = 3 - i 2 Ao + Ait + A2t^
2/' + ay = / ( i ) . (A.5)
0 1 0 .. 0 zi 0
4 0 0 1 .. 0 ^2 0
+
0 0 0 .. 1 Zn-1 0
z' = Az + b (A.10)
with the obvious definitions obtained by comparing (A.9) and (A. 10).
We will present two ways of solving the first-order system (A. 10).
The first method involves the matrix exponential function e*"* defined
by the power series
/2 42
E A;!
(A.11)
By analogy with Section A.6, we try e^* as the integrating factor for
(A. 10) to obtain
370 A. Solutions of Linear Differential Equations
dV '
Integrating from 0 to i gives
TA
b{r)dT.
Jo
Evaluating and solving, we have
.-TA
z{t) = e'^z{0) + e'^ r b{T)dr, (A.13)
Jo
The analogy between this equation and (A.6) is clear.
Although (A.13) represents a formal expression for the solution of
(A. 10), it does not provide a computationally convenient way of getting
explicit solutions. In order to demonstrate such a method we assimie
that the matrix A is diagonalizable, i.e., that there exists a nonsingtilar
square matrix P such that
P-^AP = A. (A.14)
Ai 0 ••• 0
0 A2 ••• 0
A = (A.15)
0 0 An
Pw' = APw + b,
vJ = p-^APw + p-^b,
The solution is
which is the formal solution to (A. 10). Since well-known algorithms are
available for finding eigenvalues and eigenvectors of a matrix, the solution
to (A.22) can be found in a straightforward manner.
372 A. Solutions of Linear Differential Equations
X 11 An X hi
+ (A.23)
21 A22 A 62 J
with boundary conditions
The solution of this system will be of the form (A.22), which can be
restated as
after suitable partial derivatives have been taken, then the result is a
partial differentiable equation.
Ekjuation
^[k-l)h{x-y)-ay)Y^^^-')
(11) bcux + acuy + abuz = 0 u =: fi{ax - by) ^ f2(by - cz) + fsicz - ax)
(17) Uxx — 0^{Uyy 4 - Uzz) = 0 u = fi(y + ax) + f2{y - ax)-\- h{z + ax)
+f4{z-ax)
functions. The general case of this problem is too difficult to treat here.
We consider only the case in which the forcing functions are separable,
i.e., can be written as a sum of functions each involving only one of the
independent variables. In solving such problems we can make use of the
solutions to ordinary differential equations considered earlier.
Ux + Uy = 3x + e^.
Solution. We know from the previous section that the general solution
to the homogeneous equation is of the form f{x—y). To get the particular
solutions we solve separately the ordinary equations
A^ = f(k). (A.32)
One can easily show that
fc4 = fc(i)+7/c(2)+6fc(3)+fcW,
k^ = fc(i) + 15fc(2) + 25fc(^) + lOfcW + fc(^).
SO that
AA^ = -k + 6,X^ = 0.
A^ = -(l/2)fc(2) + 5fcW + c,
EXERCISES FOR A P P E N D I X A
3 2 5 0 1 1
A . l If ^ = show that A andF =
2 3 0 2 1 -1
Use (A.22) to solve (A. 10) for this data, given that ^(O) =
3 3 6 0 1 3
A.2 If A , show that A = andP =
2 4 0 1 1 -2
0
Use (A.22) to solve (A. 10) for this data, given that z{0) =
5
0 T
8J = = / {9xV + 9xf])dt = 0,
de =0 ^0
382 B. Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory
= [9x- •:^9x]vdt = 0.
de zzo Jo dt
We now use the fundamental lemma of the calculus of variations
which states that if /i is a continuous fimction and /Q h(t)rj{t)dt = 0 for
every continuous function r]{t)^ then h{t) — 0 for all t G [0, T]. The reason
that this lemma holds, without going into details of a rigorous proof
which is available in Gelfand and Fomin (1963), is as follows. Suppose
that h(t) ^ 0 for some t G [0,T]. Since h{t) is continuous, there is,
therefore, an interval (^1, ^2) C [0, T] over which h is nonzero and has the
same sign. Now selecting r/(t) such
>0, te{ti,t2)
r]{t) is <
0, otherwise,
9x - -Tjgx = 0 (B.5)
The boimdary conditions for this equation are obviously the end-point
conditions x{0) = XQ and x{T) = x^-
B.3. The Shortest Distance Between Two Points on the Plane 383
j^9^ = 0, (B.6)
gx = constant. (B.7)
j^{9-i9x)-9t = 0. (B.8)
g-xgx = C, (B.9)
imn
Jo
subject to
XT-XQ
x{t) = t + Xo,
T
which is the straight line passing through XQ and XT-
We wish to minimize
^^ ds
Jo Jo V
where v represents velocity, and ST is the final displacement measured
on the curve. We can write
ds = \ / l + x'^dt
v = V2^ax,
, 1 f'/*! h 1+x^
min^TT- / \l—- dt
\2aJo V X
where x = dx/dt (note that t does not denote time), and x(0) = 0 and
x{l) = 1. Since a is a constant, we can rewrite the problem as
Since g does not depend explicitly on f, the problem belongs to the third
special case. Using the first integral (B.9) of the Euler equation for this
case, we have
1/2
i;2[x(l+i2)]-i/2 1+x^ = Ci (a constant).
X
•^xdx
dt
^ l ""x
386 B. Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory
and substitute
26>i - - I = sin20i-cos26>i.
X = 0.573(1-cos 20),
t = 0.573(0-sin0),
The greatest lower bound for J(x) for smooth x = x{t) satisfying the
boimdary conditions is obviously zero. Yet there is no x € C-^[—1,1]
with x(—l) = 0 and x{l) = 1, which achieves this value of J(x). In fact,
the minimum is achieved for the curve
This will require a slightly modified version of formula (B.4) for writ-
ing out the variations; see pp. 55-56 in Gelfand and Fomin (1963). Equat-
ing the sum of variations
SJ = SJi +SJ2 = 0
388 B. Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory
for x{t) to be an extremal and using the fact that x{t) must be continuous
at t = r imphes
g^l^- = g^l^^ , (B.12)
[9 - igxlr- = [9- i9x]T+' (B.13)
These conditions are called Weierstrass-Erdmann corner conditions,
which must hold at the point r where the extremal has a corner.
In each of the interval [0, r ) and (r, t], the extremal x must satisfy the
Euler equation (B.5). Solving these two equations will provide us with
four constants of integration since the Euler equations are second-order
differential equations. These constants can be foiind from the end-point
conditions (B.l) and Weierstrass-Erdmann conditions (B.12) and (B.13).
d^V{e) PT
/ {9xxrj^ + '^gxxm + 9xxf]^)dt < 0. (B.15)
de'^ JO
e=0
Integrating the middle term by parts and using (B.3), we can transform
(B.15) into a more convenient form
small in [0, T] if f]{t) is small in [0, T], The converse is not true, however,
since it is easy to construct r]{t) which is small but has a large derivative
7]{t) in [0,r]. Thus, Pfj^ plays the dominant role in (B.16); i.e., Pif
can be much larger than Qrf but it cannot be much smaller (provided
P 7^ 0). Therefore, it might be expected that the sign of the fimctional
in (B.6) is determined by the sign of the coefficient P(t), i.e., (B.16)
implies (B.14). For a rigorous proof, see Gelfand and Fomin (1963).
We note that the strengthened Legendre condition (i.e., with a strict
inequahty in (B.14)), the Euler equation, and one other condition called
strengthened Jacobi condition are sufficient for a maximum. The reader
can consult Chapter 5 of Gelfand and Fomin (1963) for details.
subject to
The Hamiltonian is
d
A
dt 9x'
This equation with (B.20) implies
9x - ^9x = 0,
H{x,t,X,t) >H{x,v,\t),
which means that the right-hand sides must be continuous with respect to
time, i.e., even across corners. These are precisely Weierstrass-Erdmann
corner conditions.
Appendix C
An Alternative Derivation
of the Maximum Principle
max {J = cx(T)}
u{t)en{t)
subject to
(C.l)
X = f{x,U,t), x{0) =Xo,
394 C. An Alternative Derivation of the Maximum Principle
•-> t
6 T-8 T T
^-> t
0 T-s T r
V eft, t e (r — s,r],
u{t) = I (C.2)
u*{t), otherwise.
This is called a needle-shaped YSuYiaXion as shown in Figure C.l. It
is a jump function and is different from variations in the calculus of
variations (see Appendix B). Also the difference v —u* is finite and need
not be small. However, since the variation is on a small time interval, its
influence on the subsequent state trajectory can be proved to be 'small'.
This is done in the following.
Let the subsequent motion be denoted by x{t) ^ x*{t) for t > r — s,
In Figure 0.2, we have sketched x{t) corresponding to u{t).
Let
6x{t) = x{t) - a;*(i), t>T-e,
denote the change in the state variables. Obviously 6X{T — S) = 0.
Clearly,
Sx{T)^e[x{s)-x\s)], (C.3)
where s denotes some intermediate time in the interval (r — e^r]. In
particular, we can write (C.3) as
Since the initial difference SX(T) is small and since U*{T) does not change
from t > T on, we may conclude that Sx{t) will be small for aU t > r .
Being small, the law of variation of Sx{t) can be foimd from linear equa-
tions for small changes in the state variables. These are called variational
equations. From the state equation in (C.l), we have
or,
^ + ^^fix\u*,t)+fjx (C.7)
396 C. An Alternative Derivation of the Maximum Principle
or using (C.l),
SJ=^X*{T)SX{T)<0, (C.15)
But Sx{r) is supphed in (C.5). Noting that £ > 0, we can rewrite (C.15)
as
X*{T)f[x*(T),v,T]-X*(r)f[x*iT),u*iT),T]<0. (C.16)
Defining the Hamiltonian for the Mayer form as
Since this can be done for almost every r, we have the required Hamil-
tonian maximizing condition.
The differential equation form of the adjoint equation (C.14) can be
obtained by taking its derivative with respect to r. Thus,
-C/X[X'(T),M'(T),T]. (0.19)
^ ^ ^ = -$(i,r)/,[x*(r),«*(r),T],
rfA(r) rT
^^ - j cU[x*{t),u*{t),t]^{t,T)U[x*{Tlu*{r),T]dt
-cU[x*{T)X{r),T]. (C.20)
398 C. An Alternative Derivation of the Maximum Principle
^ = -A(r)/,[x*(r),«*(r),r]
This completes the derivation of the maximum principle along with the
adjoint equation using the direct method.
First, we define
A(r) = c, (C.23)
which makes it possible to write (C.22) as
*^ = ^i^^^(^) = A(r)6^(T).
Now, X(T)Sx{T) is the change in the objective fimction due to a
change Sx{T) at the terminal time T. That is, A(T) is the marginal
return or the marginal change in the objective function per unit change
in the state at time T. But Sx{T) cannot be known without integrating
(C.8). We do know, however, the value of the change SX{T) at time r
which caused the terminal change Sx(T) via (C.8).
We would therefore like to pose the problem of obtaining the change
6J in the objective function in terms of the known value SX{T); see
FeFdbaimi (1965). Simply stated, we would like to obtain the marginal
return A(r) per unit change in state at time r . Thus,
or in other words,
It turns out that the differential equation which X{t) must satisfy can
be easily foimd. From (C.27),
In this appendix we will discuss three specialized topics. These are linear-
quadratic problems, second-order variations, and singular control. These
topics are referred to but not discussed in the main body of the text
because of their advanced nature. While we shall not be able to go into
a great detail, we will provide an adequate description of these topics
and list relevant references.
subject to
x = Ax + Bu, x{Q) =- XQ. (D.2)
Since (D.8) must hold for all x, it implies the following matrix differential
equation
S + SA + A^S - SBD'^B^S + C = 0, (D.9)
called a matrix Riccati equation, with the boundary condition
S(T) = G. (D.IO)
1 T C N X
J = -x^ Gx + dt. (D.12)
jf'^^"^) N^ D u
where
X = Ax + Bu + w,
where
E[w{t)] = 0, E[w{t)w{Tf] = Q{t)6{t - r ) ,
404 D. Special Topics in Optimal Control
( \
C N ' X
max < J = E ^x'^Gx + ^{x^,u^) dt\
iV^ D ^ [u]
Assume further that x cannot be directly measured and the measure-
ment process is given by (13.21), i.e.,
y{t) = H{t)x{t)+v{t),
The above procedure has received two different names in the liter-
ature. In economics it is called the certainty equivalence principle; see
Simon (1956). In engineering and mathematics literature it is called the
separation principle, Joseph and Tou (1961). When we call it the cer-
tainty equivalence principle, we are emphasizing the fact that x(t) can be
used for the purposes of optimal feedback control as if it were the certain
value of the state variable x{t). Whereas the term separation principle
emphasizes the fact that the process of determining the optimal control
can be broken down into two steps: first, estimate x by using the optimal
filter; second, use that estimate in the optimal feedback control formula
for the deterministic problem.
D,2. Second-Order Variations 405
subject to
X = f{x^ u, t), x{0) = xo> (D.16)
From Chapter 2, we know that the first-order necessary conditions
for this problem are given by
Hu = 0, (D.18)
where the Hamiltonian H is given by
H = F + Xf, (D.19)
dux
—rr = fx^x + fu^'^i 6x{0) specified, (D.21)
do
^x
dt
^ 2 Jo
8u
(D.24)
subject to
d8x
= fxSx + fuSu^ 6x{0) specified. (D.25)
IT
Since we are interested in a neighboring extremal path, we must deter-
mine 6u{t) so as to maximize 6^J subject to (D.25). This problem is
a linear-quadratic problem discussed in the previous section. For this
problem, the optimal control 6u*{t) is given by the formula (D.14), pro-
vided Huu{i) is nonsingular for 0 < t < T. The case when Huuify is
singular for a finite time interval is treated in Section D.3. Thus, rec-
ognizing that G = ^xx, C = Hxx, N = H^u, D = Huu, A = fx, and
B = fu, we have
where
(P^Hu
(-')'!; <0, it = 0,1,2,.... (D.30)
dfi^
{—ir^?
max \ j = - - I x\dt \ (D.31)
subject to
The optimal control is bang-bang plus singular. Singular arcs must sat-
isfy
if = Ai - A2 = 0 (D.37)
for a finite time interval. The optimal control can, therefore, be obtained
by
^ = A i - A 2 = :ci+Ai = 0. (D.38)
2 = xi + \i = X2 + u + xi = Q,
which implies
u = -{xi+X2) (D.39)
along the singular arc. We now verify for the example, the generalized
Legendre-Clebsch condition (D.30) for fc = 1:
Appendix E
Answers t o Selected
Exercises
Chapter 1
Chapter 2
2 if 0 < t < 2 - h i 2 . 5 ,
0 ift>2-ln2.5.
410 E. Answers to Selected Exercises
Chapter 3
3.11 A(i) = t - 1.
0 if ii: - 300,
1, 0<t<l-T,
(c) u* = <
0, l-T <t<T.
(e) J = - ( 1 / 8 + 1/8K).
(f) J = - 1 / 8 .
Chapter 5
5, t < l + 61n0.99«0.94,
5.1 (a) u*{t)
0, t > 0.094.
J* = 34,420.
Chapter 6
2, 7/3 <t< 3,
6.12 M*(i) = {
-1, 3 < ^ < 13/3,
0, 13/3 <t<6.
-fi+|, t€[0,l],
6.13 /xi = <
0, tG{0,3].
0, i e [0,1.8),
f^2= \
- i i + f, i e [1.8,3].
0, tG[0,l)U(1.8,3],
77= <
-fi+|, « € [1,1.8).
E. Answers to Selected Exercises 413
-1 for t G [0,1.8),
6.14 (a) v*{t) = {
1 for i e (1.8,3].
-1 for t G [0,1/2],
0, for0<i<ii,
6.17 u*(t) = \
h(t-ti)/c, ioiti<t<T,
Chapter 7
-X + (p + S)X = 7r'{G).
7.17 (b)
1 1 Xo _, 1 . X-X^
h
rQ + 6 n —
: l x^ , t2 = rQ„ + S. In •X — XT
7.18
+1 ifA'=+i6>l,
0 if iX^+^b] < 1.
E. Answers to Selected Exercises 415
Chapter 9
9.1 t' = 5.25, T = 11.
9.3 T = i* = 2.47.
9.4 t^ = 0, T = 30.
l2
9.5 u*{t) = sat[0,1;u^{t)], where u^{t) = \2 - e005(t-34.8)|'/(i + i),
ti^S;t2-T = 34.8.
Chapter 10
10.3 X = 0.734.
10.4 (a)
X Sep
X =
(-^i)W('-^i) + prX
e^').
p p Zp:(-'
Chapter 12
12.5 0 < T + ;^ ha(l - ^) = i.
12.8 ti = r / 2 .
Chapter 13
13.5 q*{x) = j^^^,c*ix) = j^{p-r0-i^)x,
Bibliography
[3] Abad, P.L. (1987). A hierarchical optimal control model for coordina-
tion of functional decisions in a firm, European Journal of Operational
Research, 32, 62-75.
[5] Abad, P.L. and Sweeney, D.J. (1982). Decentralized planning with an
interdependent marketing-production system. Omega, 10, 353-359.
[7] Alam, M., Lynn, J.W. and Sarma, V.V.S. (1976). Optimal maintenance
policy for equipment subject to random deterioration and random failure,
International Journal of Systems Science, 7, 1071-1080.
[8] Alam, M. and Sarma, V.V.S. (1974). Optimal maintenance policy for
equipment subject to deterioration and random failure, IEEE Transac-
tions on System, Man, and Cybernetics SMC-4, 172-175.
[16] Aronson, J.E. and Thompson, G.L. (1984). A survey on forward methods
in mathematical programming. Journal of Large Scale Systems, 7, 1-16.
[17] Arora, S.R. and Lele, P.T. (1970). A note on optimal maintenance policy
and sale date of a machine. Management Science, 17, 170-173.
[19] Arrow, K.J. and Chang, S. (1980). Optimal pricing, use, and exploration
of uncertain natural resource stocks, in Dynamic Optimization in Math-
ematical Economics, P.-T. Liu (Ed.), Plenum Press, New York.
[20] Arrow, K.J. and Kurz, M. (1970). Public Investment, The Rate of Return,
and Optimal Fiscal Policy, The John Hopkins Press, Baltimore.
[21] Arthur, W.B. and McNicoll, G. (1977). Optimal time paths with age
dependence: a theory of population policy. Review of Economic Studies,
44, 111-123.
[22] Arutyunov, A.V. and Aseev, S.M. (1977). Investigation of the degeneracy
phenomenon of the maximum principle for optimal control problems with
state constraints, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 35, 3,
930-952.
[27] Basar, T. and Olsder, G.J. (1982). Dynamic Noncooperative Game The-
ory, Academic Press, London.
[28] Bass, F.M. (1969). A new product growth model for consumer durables,
Management Science, 15, 5, 215-227.
[29] Bass, F.M. and Bultez, A.V. (1969). A note on optimal strategic pricing
of technological innovations. Marketing Science, 1, 371-378.
[30] Bean, J.C. and Smith, R.L. (1984). Conditions for the existence of plan-
ning horizons. Mathematics of Operations Research, 9, 3, 391-401.
[31] Bell, D.J. and Jacobson, D.H. (1975). Singular Optimal Control, Aca-
demic Press, New York.
[33] Bellman, R.E. and Kalaba, R.E. (1965a). Quasi linearization and Bound-
ary Value Problems, Elsevier, New York.
[34] Bellman, R.E. and Kalaba, R.E. (1965b). Dynamic Programming and
Modern Control Theory, Academic Press, New York.
[35] Bensoussan, A., Bultez, A.V. and Naert, P.A. (1978). Leader's dynamic
marketing behavior in oligopoly, in TIMS Studies in the Management
Sciences, A. Bensoussan et al., (Eds.), Vol. 9, North-Holland, Amster-
dam, 123-145.
[36] Bensoussan, A., Crouhy, M. and Proth, J.-M. (1983). Mathematical The-
ory of Production Planning, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
[37] Bensoussan, A., Hurst, Jr., E.G. and Naslund, B. (1974). Management
Applications of Modern Control Theory, Elsevier, New York.
[42] Bensoussan, A. and Lions, J.L. (1984). Impulse Control and Quasi-
Variational Inequalities, Bordas, Paris.
[43] Bensoussan, A., Nissen, G. and Tapiero, C.S. (1975). Optimum inventory
and product quality control with deterministic and stochastic deteriora-
tion - an application of distributed parameter control systems, IEEE
Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-20, 407-412.
[44] Bensoussan, A., Sethi, S.P., Vickson, R.G. and Derzko, N. A. (1984).
Stochastic production planning with production constraints, SI AM Jour-
nal on Control and Optimization, 22, 6, 920-935.
[47] Berkovitz, L.D. and Dreyfus, S.E. (1965). The equivalence of some nec-
essary conditions for optimal control in problems with bounded state
variables. Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 10, 275-
283.
[48] Bertsekas, D.P. and Shreve, S.E. (1996). Stochastic Optimal Control: The
Discrete-Time Case, Athena Scientific, New York.
[49] Bes, C. and Sethi, S.P. (1988). Concepts of forecast and decision horizons:
applications to dynamic stochastic optimization problems. Mathematics
of Operations Research, 13, 2, 295-310.
[50] Bes, C. and Sethi, S.P. (1989). Solution of a class of stochastic linear-
convex control problems using deterministic equivalents. Journal of Op-
timization Theory and Applications, 62, 1, 17-27.
Bibliography 421
[51] Beyer, D. and Sethi, S.R (1998). A proof of the EOQ formula using quasi-
variational inequalities. The International Journal of Systems Science^
29, 11, 1295-99.
[52] Bhaskaran, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1981). Planning horizons for the wheat
trading model. Proceedings of AMS SI Conference^ 5: Life, Men, and
Societies, 197-201.
[53] Bhaskaran, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1983). Planning horizon research - the
dynamic programming/control theory interface, Proceedings of Interna-
tional AMSE Winter Symposium, Bermuda, 155-160.
[54] Bhaskaran, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1987). Decision and forecast horizons in a
stochastic environment: a survey. Optimal Control Applications & Meth-
ods, 8, 201-217.
[55] Bhaskaran, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1988). The dynamic lot size model with
stochastic demands: a planning horizon study. Information Systems and
Operational Research, 26, 3, 213-224.
[56] Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973). The pricing of options and corporate
liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 8 1 , 637-659.
[58] Blaquiere, A. (1985). Impulsive optimal control with finite or infinite time
horizon. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 46, 431-439.
[61] Bookbinder, J.H. and Sethi, S.P. (1980). The dynamic transportation
problem: a survey. Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 27, 65-87.
[62] Bourguignon, F. and Sethi, S.P. (1981). Dynamic optimal pricing and
(possibly) advertising in the face of various kinds of potential entrants,
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 3, 119-140.
[64] Brekke, K.A. and 0ksendal, B.K. (1994). Optimal switching in an eco-
nomic activity under uncertainty, SIAM Journal on Control and Opti-
mization, 32, 4, 1021-1036.
[65] Brito, D.L. and Oakland, W.H. (1977). Some properties of the optimal
income tax. International Economic Review, 18, 407-423.
[68] Bryant, G.F. and Mayne, D.Q. (1974). The maximum principle. Inter-
national Journal of Control, 20, 1021-1054.
[70] Bryson, Jr., A.E. and Ho, Y.-C. (1969). Applied Optimal Control, Blais-
dell, Waltham, MA.
[71] Buchanan, L.F. and Norton, F.E. (1971). Optimal control applications in
economic systems, in Advances in Control Systems, C.T. Leondes (Ed.),
Vol. 8 in the series. Academic Press, New York, 141-187.
[73] Bulirsch, R., Oetth, W. and Stoer, J. (Eds.) (1975). Optimization and Op-
timal Control, Lecture Notes in Mathematics, Vol. 477, Springer-Verlag,
Berlin.
[74] Bultez, A.V. and Naert, P.A. (1979). Does lag structure really matter in
optimizing advertising spending, Management Science, 25, 5, 454-465.
[75] Bultez, A.V. and Naert, P.A. (1988). When does lag structure really
matter...indeed?. Management Science, 34, 7, 909-916.
[76] Burdet, C.A. and Sethi, S.P. (1976). On the maximum principle for a
class of discrete dynamical system with lags, Journal Of Optimization
Theory & Applications, 19, 445-454.
[79] Bylka, S. and Sethi, S.R (1992). Existence of solution and forecast hori-
zons in dynamic lot size model with nondecreasing holding costs, Pro-
duction and Operations Management, 1, 2, 212-224.
[80] Bylka, S., Sethi, S.R and Sorger, G. (1992). Minimal forecast horizons
in equipment replacement models with multiple technologies and general
switching costs, Naval Research Logistics, 39, 487-507.
[81] Caines, R, Sethi, S.R and Brotherton, T. (1977). Impulse response iden-
tification and casualty detection for the Lydia Pinkham data. Annals of
Economic and Social Measurement, 6, 2, 147-163.
[84] Carlson, D.A. (1986b). The existence of finitely optimal solutions for in-
finite horizon optimal control problems, Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 51, 1, 41-62.
[87] Carlson, D.A. (1988). Sufficient conditions for optimality and supported
trajectories for optimal control problems governed by Volterra integral
equations, in Advances in Optimization and Control, Lecture. Notes in
Econ. and Math. Sys., 302, Springer-Verlag. New York, 274-282.
[88] Carlson, D.A. (1989). Some concepts of optimality for infinite horizon
control and their interrelationships, in Modern Optimal Control; A Con-
ference in Honor of Solomon Lefschetz and Joseph P. LaSalle, E.O. Roxin
(Ed.), Marcel Dekker, Inc., New York, 13-22.
[89] Carlson, D.A. (1990a). Uniform overtaking and weakly overtaking opti-
mal solutions in optimal control: when optimal solutions are agreeable,
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 64, 1, 55-69.
[91] Carlson, D.A. (1990c). Infinite horizon optimal controls for problems gov-
erned by a Volterra integral equation with a state and control dependent
discount factor, Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 66, 2,
311-336.
[95] Carlson, D.A. (1997). Overtaking optimal solutions for convex Lagrange
problems with time delay, J. Math. Appl, 208, 31-48.
[96] Carlson, D.A. and Haurie, A. (1987a). Infinite Horizon Optimal Control
Theory and Applications, Lecture. Notes in Econ. and Math. Sys., 290,
Springer-Verlag, New York.
[97] Carlson, D.A. and Haurie, A. (1987b). Optimization with Unbounded
Time Interval for a Class of Non Linear Systems, Springer-Verlag, Berhn.
[98] Carlson, D.A. and Haurie, A. (1992). Control theoretic models of
environment-economy interactions, The Proceedings of the 31st IEEE
Conference on Decision and Control, 2860-2861.
[99] Carlson, D.A. and Haurie, A. (1995). A turnpike theory for infinite hori-
zon open-loop differential games with decoupled dynamics. New Trends
in Dynamic Games and Applications^ Annals of the International Society
of Dynamic Games, 3, Birkhauser, Boston, 353-376.
[100] Carlson, D.A. and Haurie, A. (1996). A turnpike theory for infinite hori-
zon competitive processes, SI AM Journal on Optimization and Control,
34, 4.
[101] Carlson, D.A., Haurie, A. and Jabrane, A. (1987). Existence of overtaking
solutions to infinite dimensional control problems on unbounded time
intervals, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 25, 6, 1517-1541.
[102] Carlson, D.A., Haurie, A. and Leizarowitz, A. (1991). Infinite Horizon
Optimal Control: Deterministic and Stochastic Systems, Second Edition,
Springer-Verlag, New York.
Bibliography 425
[104] Carraro, C. and Filar, J. (Eds.), (1995). Control and Game Theoretic
Models of the Environment, Birkhauser, Boston.
[106] Case, J.H. (1979). Economics and the Competitive Process, New York
University Press, New York.
[109] Chand, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1982). Planning horizon procedures for ma-
chine replacement models with several possible replacement alternatives,
Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 29, 3, 483-493,
[110] Chand, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1983). Finite production rate inventory models
with first and second shift setups, Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 30,
401-414.
[Ill] Chand, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1990). A dynamic lot size model with learning
in setups, Operations Research, 38, 4, 644-655.
[112] Chand, S., Sethi, S.P. and Proth, J.-M. (1990). Existence of forecast hori-
zons in undiscounted discrete time lot size models, Operations Research,
38, 5, 884-892.
[113] Chand, S., Sethi, S.P. and Sorger, G. (1992). Forecast horizons in the
discounted dynamic lot size model. Management Science, 38, 7, 1034-
1048.
[116] Chiarella, C , Kemp, M.C., Long, N.V. and Okuguchi, K. (1984). On the
economics of international fisheries. International Economic Review^ 25,
85-92.
[121] Chintagunta, P.K. and Jain, D. (1995). Dynamic duopoly models of ad-
vertising competition: estimation and a specification tests. Journal of
Economics and Management Strategy, 4, 1, 109-131.
[123] Chintagunta, P.K. and Vilcassim, N.J. (1994). Marketing investment de-
cisions in a dynamic duopoly: a model and empirical analysis. Interna-
tional J. Res. Marketing, 1 1 , 3, 287-306.
[124] Chow, G.C. (1975). Analysis and Control of Dynamic Economic Systems,
Wiley, New York.
[129] Clarke, F.H. (1976). Necessary conditions for a general control problem,
in Calculus of Variations and Control Theory, D.L. Russell (Ed.), Aca-
demic Press, New York.
[132] Clarke, F.H., Darrough, M.N. and Heineke, J.M. (1982). Optimal pricing
policy in the presence of experience effects, Journal of Business, 55, 517-
530.
[133] Clarke, F.H., and Loewen, P.D. (1987). State constraints in optimal con-
trol: a case study in proximal normal analysis, SI AM Journal of Control
and Optimization, 25, 1440-1456.
[134] Clemhout, S. and Wan, Jr., H.Y. (1985). Dynamic common property
resources and environmental problems. Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 46, 471-481.
[135] Coddington, E.A. and Levinson, N.L. (1955). Theory of Ordinary Differ-
ential Equations, McGraw-Hill, New York.
[136] Cohen, K.J. and Cyert, R.M. (1965). Theory of the Firm: Resource Al-
location in a Market Economy, Prentice-Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
[139] Conrad, K. (1985). Quality, advertising and the formation of goodwill un-
der dynamic conditions, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Anal-
ysis, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), Vol. 2, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 215-234.
[141] Dantzig, G.B. (1966). Linear control processes and mathematical pro-
gramming, SIAM Journal on Control, 4, 56-60.
[142] Dantzig, G.B. and Sethi, S.P. (1981). Linear optimal control problems
and generalized linear programs. Journal of Operational Research Society,
32, 467-476.
428 Bibliography
[143] Dasgupta, P. and Heal, G.M. (1974). The optimal depletion of ex-
haustible resources, The Review of Economic Studies, 4 1 , 3-28.
[145] Davis, B.E. (1970). Investment and rate of return for the regulated firm,
The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 1, 245-270.
[146] Davis, B.E. and Elzinga, D.J. (1972). The solution of an optimal control
problem in financial modeling. Operations Research, 19, 1419-1433.
[147] Davis, M.H.A. (1993). Markov Models and Optimization, Chapman &
Hall, New York.
[150] Dawid, H., Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (Eds.) (1999). Special Issue on
Optimal control and differential games. Annals of Operations Research,
88.
[153] Deal, K.R., Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1979) A bilinear-quadratic
differential game in advertising, in Control Theory in Mathematical Eco-
nomics, P.-T. Liu and J.G. Sutinen (Eds.), Marcel Dekker, Inc., New
York, 91-109.
[154] Deger, S. and Sen, S.K.(1984). Optimal control and differential game
models of military expenditure in less developed countries, J. of Eco-
nomic Dynamics and Control, 7, 153-169.
[159] Derzko, N.A. and Sethi, S.P. (1981a). Optimal exploration and consump-
tion of a natural resource: stochastic case. International J. of Policy
Analysis, 5, 3, 185-200.
[160] Derzko, N.A. and Sethi, S.P. (1981b). Optimal exploration and consump-
tion of a natural resource: deterministic case. Optimal Control Applica-
tions & Methods, 2, 1, 1-21.
[161] Derzko, N.A., Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1980). Distributed pa-
rameter systems approach to the optimal cattle ranching problem. Opti-
mal Control Applications & Methods, 1, 3-10.
[162] Derzko, N.A., Sethi, S.P. and Thompson,G.L. (1984). Necessary and suf-
ficient conditions for optimal control of quasilinear partial differential
systems. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 43, 89-101.
[163] Dhrymes, P.J. (1962). On optimal advertising capital and research ex-
penditures under dynamic conditions, Economica, 39, 275-279.
[164] Dixit, A.K. and Pindyck, R.S. (1994). Investment Under Uncertainty,
Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
[170] Dockner, E.J. and J0rgensen, S., (1984). Cooperative and non-
cooperative differential game solutions to an investment and pricing prob-
lem, Journal of Operational Research Society^ 35, 731-739.
[171] Dockner, E.J. and J0rgensen, S., (1986). Dynamic advertising and pricing
in an oligopoly: a Nash equilibrium approach, in Dynamic Games and
Applications in Economics, T. Basar (Ed.), Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 238-
251.
[172] Dockner, E.J. and J0rgensen, S., (1988). Optimal advertising policies for
diffusion models of new product innovation in monopolistic situations,
Management Science, 34, 1, 119-130.
[173] Dockner, E.J. and J0rgensen, S., (1992). New product advertising in
dynamic oligopolies, Zeitschrift fur Operations Research, 36, 5, 459-473.
[174] Dockner, E.J., J0rgensen, S., Long, N.V. and Sorger, G. (2000). Differ-
ential Games in Economics and Management Science, Cambridge Uni-
versity Press, Cambridge, UK.
[176] Dolan, R.J. and Jeuland, A.P., (1981). Experience curves and dynamic
demand models: implications of optimal pricing strategies, J. Marketing,
45, 52-73.
[177] Dolan, R.J. and Muller, E., (1986). Models of new product diffusion:
extension to competition against existing and potential firms over time,
in Innovation Diffusion Models of New Product Acceptance, V. Mahajan
and Y. Wind (Eds.), Ballinger, Cambridge, MA, 117-150.
[180] Drews, W., Hartberger, R.J. and Segers, R. (1974). On continuous math-
ematical programming in Optimization Methods for Resource Allocation,
R.W. Cottle and J. Krarup (Eds.), The English University Press, London.
[181] Dubovitskii, A.Y. and Milyutin, A.A. (1963). Extremum problems with
constraints, Soviet Math. Dokl, 4, 452-455.
[182] Dunn, J.C. and Bertsekas, D.P. (1989). Efficient dynamic programming
implementations of Newton's method for unconstrained optimal control
problems. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 6 3 , 1 , 23-38.
Bibliography 431
[189] Fan, L.T. and Wang, C.-S. (1964). An application of the discrete maxi-
mum principle to a transportation problem. Journal of Mathematics and
Physics, 43, 255-260.
[192] Feichtinger, G. (1982c). Optimal repair policy for a machine service prob-
lem, Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 3, 15-22.
[207] Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (1985a). Optimal pricing and production
in an inventory model, European Journal of Operational Research, 19,
45-56.
[208] Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (1985b). On the use of Hamiltonian and
maximized Hamiltonian in non-differentiable control theory, Journal of
Optimization Theory & Applications, 46, 493-504.
Bibliography 433
[210] Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (Eds.) (1992). Nonlinear methods in eco-
nomic dynamics and optimal control, Annals of Operations Research, 37,
Baltzer, Basel.
[211] Feichtinger, G., Hartl, R.F., Haunschmied, J. and Kort, RM. (1998).
Optimal enforcement policies (crackdowns) on a drug market. Optimal
Control Applications & Methods, 19, 169-184.
[212] Feichtinger, G., Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1994). Dynamic optimal con-
trol models in advertising: recent developments. Management Science,
40, 2, 195-226.
[215] Feichtinger, G., Kaitala, V.T. and Novak, A. (1992). Stable resource-
employment limit cycles in an optimally regulated fishery, in Dynamic
Economic Models and Optimal Control, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-
Holland, Amsterdam, 163-184.
[216] Feichtinger, G., Luhmer, A. and Sorger, G. (1988). Optimal price and
advertising policy in convenience goods retailing. Marketing Science, 7,
187-201.
[221] Feichtinger, G., Novak, A. and Wirl, F. (1994). Limit cycles in intertem-
poral adjustment models - theory and applications, Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, 18, 353-380.
[225] Feinberg, F.M. (1992). Pulsing policies for aggregate advertising models,
Marketing Science, 11, 3, 221-234.
[226] Fel'dbaum, A.A. (1965). Optimal Control Systems, Academic Press, New
York.
[227] Ferreira, M.M.A. and Vinter, R.B. (1994). When is the maximum prin-
ciple for state constrained problems nondegenerate?. Journal of Mathe-
matical Analysis and Applications, 187, 438-467.
[228] Ferreyra, G. (1990). The optimal control problem for the Vidale-Wolfe
advertising model revisited, Optimal Control Applications & Methods,
11, 363-368.
[231] Fleming, W.H. and Rishel, R.W. (1975). Deterministic and Stochastic
Optimal Control, Springer-Verlag. New York.
[232] Fleming, W.H. and Soner, H.M. (1992). Controlled Markov Processes and
Viscosity Solutions, Springer-Verlag, New York.
[235] Forster, B.A. (1977). On a one state variable optimal control problem:
consumption-pollution trade-offs, in Applications of Control Theory to
Economic Analysis, J.D. Pitchford and S.J. Turnovsky (Eds.), North-
Holland, Amsterdam.
[237] Francis, P.J. (1997). Dynamic epidemiology and the market for vaccina-
tions, Journal of Public Economics, 63, 3, 383-406.
[238] Frankena, J.F. (1975). Optimal control problems with delay, the maxi-
mum principle and necessary conditions. Journal of Eng. Math., 9, 53-64.
[244] Fruchter, G.E. (1999). Oligopoly advertising strategies with market ex-
pansion, Optimal Control Application & Methods, 20, 199-211.
[246] Fuller, D. and Vickson, R.G. (1987). The optimal construction of new
plants for oil from the Alberta tar sands, Operations Research, 35, 5,
704-715.
[251] Gaimon, C. (1986b). The optimal times and levels of impulsive acquisi-
tion of automation. Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 7, 259-270.
[252] Gaimon, C. (1986c). The optimal acquisition of new technology and its
impact on dynamic pricing policies. Studies in Management Science and
Systems, B. Lev (Ed.), 13, 187-206.
[257] Gaimon, C. and Thompson, G.L. (1984a). Optimal preventive and repair
maintenance of a machine subject to failure. Optimal Control Applica-
tions & Methods, 5, 57-67.
[259] Gaimon, C. and Thompson, G.L. (1989). Optimal preventive and repair
maintenance of a machine subject to failure and a declining resale value,
Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 10, 211-228.
[262] Gaskins, Jr., D.W. (1971). Dynamic limit pricing: optimal pricing under
threat of entry. Journal of Economic Theory, 3, 306-322.
Bibliography 437
[264] Gelfand, I.M. and Fomin, S.V. (1963). Calculus of Variations, Prentice-
Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
[267] Gihman, LI. and Skorohod, A.V. (1972). Stochastic Differential Equa-
tions, Springer-Verlag, New York.
[271] Goh, B.-S., Leitmann, G. and Vincent, T.L. (1974). Optimal control of
a prey-predator system. Mathematical Biosciences, 19, 263-286.
[273] Goldstine, H.H. (1980). A History of the Calculus of Variations from the
17th through the 19th Century, Springer-Verlag, New York.
[276] Gordon, M.J. (1962). The Investment, Financing and Valuation of the
Corporation, Richard D. Irwin, Inc., Homewood, 111.
[277] Gould, J.P. (1970). Diffusion processes and optimal advertising policy,
in Microeconomic Foundation of Employment and Inflation Theory, E.S.
Phelps et al. (Eds.), Norton, New York, 338-368.
438 Bibliography
[278] Grimm, W., Well, K.H. and Oberle, H.J. (1986). Periodic control for
Minimum-fuel aircraft trajectories, Journal of Guidance, 9, 169-174.
[281] Hahn, M. and Hyun, J.S. (1991). Advertising cost interpretations and
the optimality of pulsing. Management Science, 37, 2, 157-169.
[282] Halkin, H. (1966). A maximum principle of the Pontryagin type for sys-
tems described by nonlinear difference equations, SI AM Journal on Con-
trol, 4, 90-111.
[283] Halkin, H. (1967). On the necessary condition for optimal control of non-
linear systems, in Topics in Optimization, G. Leitmann (Ed.), Academic
Press, New York.
[285] Hamalainen, R.P., Haurie, A. and Kaitala, V.T. (1985). Equilibria and
threats in a fishery management game. Optimal Control Applications &
Methods, 6, 315-333.
[286] Hamalainen, R.P., Ruusunen, J. and Kaitala, V.T. (1986). Myopic Stack-
elberg equilibria and social coordination in a share contract fishery. Ma-
rine Resource Economics, 3, 3, 209-235.
<j, %^, ^ ,
[287] Hamalainen, R.P., Ruusunen, J. and Kaitala, V.T. (1990). Cartels and
dynamic contracts in sharefishing, Journal of Environmental Economics
and Management, 19, 175-192.
[288] Han, M., Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (1994). Nonconcavity and
proper optimal periodic control. Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control, 18, 976-990.
[289] Hanssens, D.M., Parsons, L.J. and Schultz, R. L. (1990). Market Re-
sponse Models: Econometric and Time Series Analysis, Kluwer Aca-
demic Publishers, Boston.
[290] Harris, F.W. (1913). How many parts to make at once. Factory, The
Magazine of Management, 10, 135-136, 152.
Bibliography 439
[291] Harris, H. (1976). Optimal planning under transaction costs: the demand
for money and other assets, Journal of Economic Theory, 12, 298-314.
[292] Harrison, J.M. and Pliska, S.R. (1981). Martingales, stochastic integrals,
and continuous trading, Stochastic Process. Appl, 11, 215-260.
[296] Hartl, R.F. (1982c). Optimal control of concave economic models with
two control instruments, in Operations Research in Progress, G. Fe-
ichtinger and P. Kail (Eds.), D. Reidel Publishing Company, Dordrecht,
Holland, 227-245.
[298] Hartl, R.F. (1983b). Optimal maintenance and production rates for a
machine: a nonlinear economic control problem. Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, 6, 281-306.
[299] Hartl, R.F. (1984). Optimal dynamic advertising policies for hereditary
processes. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 43, 1, 51-72.
[300] Hartl, R.F. (1986a). A forward algorithm for a generalized wheat trading
model, Zeitschrift filr Operations Research, 30, A 135-A 144.
[301] Hartl, R.F. (1986b). Arrow-type sufficient optimality conditions for non-
difFerentiable optimal control problems with state constraints, Applied
Mathematics & Optimization, 14, 229-247.
[302] Hartl, R.F. (1987). A simple proof of the monotonicity of the state tra-
jectories in autonomous control problems. Journal of Economic Theory,
40, 211-215.
[303] Hartl, R.F. (1988a). A wheat trading model with demand and spoilage,
in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis, G. Feichtinger (Ed.),
Vol. 3, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 235-244.
440 Bibliography
[304] Hartl, R.F. (1988b). A dynamic activity analysis for a monopolistic firm,
Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 9, 253-272.
[305] Hartl, R.F. (1988c). The control of environmental pollution and opti-
mal investment and employment decisions: a comment, Optimal Control
Applications & Methods, 9, 337-339.
[306] Hartl, R.F. (1989a). On forward algorithms for a generalized wheat trad-
ing model, in Progress in Inventory Research (Proceedings of 4th Interna-
tional Symposium on Inventories), A. Chikan (Ed.), Hungarian Academy
of Science, Budapest.
[307] Hartl, R.F. (1989b). Most rapid approach paths in dynamic economic
problems, in Methods of Operations Research 58 (Proceedings of SOR
12, 1987), P. Kleinschmidt et al. (Eds.), Athenaun, 397-410.
[311] Hartl, R.F. and Feichtinger, G. (1987). A new sufficient condition for most
rapid approach paths. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications,
54, 2, 403-411.
[312] Hartl, R.F., Feichtinger, G. and Kirakossian, G.T. (1992). Optimal re-
cycling of tailings for the production of building materials, Czechoslovak
Journal of Operations Research, 1,3, 181-192.
[313] Hartl, R.F. and J0rgensen, S. (1985). Optimal manpower policies in a dy-
namic staff-maximizing bureau, Optimal Control Application & Methods,
6, 1, 57-64.
[316] Hartl, R.F. and Kort, P.M. (1996a). Marketable permits in a stochastic
dynamic model of the firm. Journal of Optimization Theory and Appli-
cations, 89, 1, 129-155.
Bibliography 441
[317] Hartl, R.F. and Kort, P.M. (1996b). Capital accumulation of a firm facing
an environmental tax scheme, Journal of Economics, 63, 1, 1-23.
[318] Hartl, R.F. and Kort, P.M. (1996c). Capital accumulation of a firm facing
environmental constraints. Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 17,
253-266.
[319] Hartl, R.F. and Kort, P.M. (1997). Optimal input substitution of a firm
facing an environmental constraint, European Journal of Operational Re-
search, 99, 1.
[320] Hartl, R.F., Kort, P.M. and Novak, A. (1999). Optimal investment facing
possible accidents. Annals of Operations Research, 88, 99-117.
[321] Hartl, R.F. and Krauth, J. (1989). Optimal production mix. Journal of
Optimization Theory and Applications, 66, 255-273.
[325] Hartl, R.F. and Mehlmann, A. (1984). Optimal seducing policies for dy-
namic continuous lovers under risk of being killed by a rival. Cybernetics
& Systems: An Intern. J., 15, 119-126.
[327] Hartl, R.F., Mehlmann, A. and Novak, A. (1992). Cycles of fear: opti-
mal periodic blood-sucking rates for vampires. Journal of Optimization
Theory and Applications, 75, 3, 559-568.
[328] Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1983). A note on the free terminal time
transversality condition, Zeitschrift fur Operations Research^ Series:
Theory, 27, 5, 203-208.
[329] Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1984a). Optimal control problems with
differential inclusions: sufficiency conditions and an application to a
production-inventory model. Optimal Control Applications & Methods,
5, 4, 289-307.
442 Bihliography
[330] Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1984b). Optimal control of a class of systems
with continuous lags: dynamic programming approach and economic in-
terpretations, Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 43, 1,
73-88.
[331] Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1985a). Solution of generalized linear optimal
control problems using a simplex-like method in continuous-time I: the-
ory, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis 2, G. Feichtinger,
(Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 45-62.
[332] Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1985b). Solution of generalized linear op-
timal control problems using a simplex-like method in continuous-time
H: examples, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis 2, G.
Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 63-87.
[333] Hartl, R.F., Sethi, S.P. and Vickson, R.G. (1995). A survey of the max-
imum principles for optimal control problems with state constraints,
SIAM Review, 37, 2, 181-218.
[334] Harvey, A.C. (1994). Forecasting, Structural Time Series Models and the
Kalman Filter, Cambridge University Press, New York.
[335] Haurie, A. (1976). Optimal control on an infinite time horizon: the turn-
pike approach, J. Math. Economics, 3, 81-102.
[336] Haurie, A. and Hung, N.M. (1977). Turnpike properties for the optimal
use of a natural resource. Review of Economic Studies, 44, 329-336.
[338] Haurie, A. and Sethi, S.P. (1984). Decision and forecast horizons, agree-
able plans, and the maximum principle for infinite horizon control prob-
lems, Operations Research Letters, 3, 5, 261-265.
[339] Haurie, A., Sethi, S.P. and Hartl, R.F. (1984). Optimal control of an age-
structured population model with applications to social services planning,
J. of Large Scale Systems, 6, 133-158.
[342] Heal, G.M. (1976). The relationship between price and extraction cost
for a resource with a backstop technology, Bell Journal of Economics, 7,
371-378.
[344] Heckman, J. (1976). A Hfe cycle model of earnings, learning, and con-
sumption, Journal of Political Economy, 84, 511-544.
[345] Hestenes, M.R. (1966). Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control The-
ory, Wiley, New York.
[346] Ho, Y.-C. (1970). Differential games, dynamic optimization and general-
ized control theory. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 6,
179-209.
[347] Hoffmann, K.H. and Krabs, W. (1984). Optimal Control of Partial Dif-
ferential Equations, Birkhauser, Basel.
[348] Holly, S., Riistem, B. and Zarrop, M.B. (Eds.) (1979). Optimal Control
for Econometric Models. An Approach to Economic Policy Formulation,
Macmillan, London.
[349] Holt, C.C, Modigliani, F., Muth, J.F. and Simon, H.A. (1960). Planning
Production^ Inventories and Workforce, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs,
NJ.
[350] Holtzman, J.M. (1966). On the maximum principle for nonlinear discrete-
time systems, IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-11, 273-
274.
[353] Horsky, D. and Simon, L.S. (1983). Advertising and the diffusion of new
products. Marketing Science, 2, 1, 1-17.
[356] Hwang, C.L., Fan, L.T. and Erickson, L.E. (1967), Optimal production
planning by the maximum principle, Management Science, 13, 750-755.
444 Bibliography
[358] Ijiri, Y. and Thompson, G.L. (1972). Mathematical control theory solu-
tion of an interactive accounting flows model. Naval Research Logistics
Quarterly, 19, 411-422.
[361] Intriligator, M.D. and Smith, B.L.R. (1966). Some aspects of the allo-
cation of scientific effort between teaching and research, American Eco-
nomic Review, 6 1 , 494-507.
[362] loffe, A.D. and Tihomirov, V.M. (1979). Theory of Extremal Problems,
North-Holland, Amsterdam.
[364] Isaacs, R. (1969). Differential games: their scope, nature, and future,
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 3, 283-295.
[365] Jacobson, D.H., Lele, M.M. and Speyer, J.L. (1971) New necessary con-
ditions of optimality for control problems with state-variable inequality
constraints, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 35, 255-
284.
[366] Jacquemin, A.P. (1973). Optimal control and advertising policy, Metro-
Economica, 25, 200-207.
[367] Jacquemin, A.R and Thisse, J. (1972). Strategy of the firm and market
structure: an application of optimal control theory, in Market Structure
and Corporate Behavior, K. Cowling (Ed.), Gray-Mills, London, 61-84.
[370] Jazwinski, A.H. (1970). Stochastic Processes and Filtering Theory, Aca-
demic Press, New York.
Bibliography 445
[372] Jennings, L.S., Sethi, S.P. and Teo, K.L. (1997). Computation of optimal
production plans for manufacturing systems. Nonlinear Analysis^ Theory^
Methods & Applications, 30, 7, 4329-4338.
[373] Jennings, L.S. and Teo, K.L. (1997). Computation of manufacturing sys-
tems using an enhancing control, in IPMM'97: Australiasia-Pacific Fo-
rum on Intelligent Processing & Manufacturing of Materials, Vol. 1, T.
Chandra, S.R. Leclair, J.A. Meech, B. Verma, M. Smith, and B. Bal-
achandran (Eds.), Watson Ferguson & Co., Brisbane, Australia.
[374] Jeuland, A.P. and Dolan, R.J. (1982). An aspect of new product plan-
ning: dynamic pricing, in Marketing Planning Models, TIMS Studies in
the Management Science, A.A. Zoltners (Ed.), Vol. 18, North-Holland,
Amsterdam, 1-21.
[375] Jiang, J. and Sethi, S.P. (1991). A state aggregation approach to man-
ufacturing systems having machine states with weak and strong interac-
tions, Operations Research, 39, 6, 970-978.
[380] J0rgensen, S., (1983). Optimal control of a diffusion model of new product
acceptance with price-dependent total market potential. Optimal Control
Application & Methods, 4, 3, 269-276.
[386] J0rgensen, S. and Dockner, E.J. (1985). Optimal consumption and re-
plenishment policies for a renewable resource, in Optimal Control Theory
and Economic Analysis 2, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amster-
dam, 647-664.
[387] J0rgensen, S. and Kort, P.M. (1993). Optimal dynamic investment poli-
cies under concave-convex adjustment costs, Journal of Economic Dy-
namics and Control, 17, 1/2, 153-180.
[388] J0rgensen, S. and Kort, P.M. (1997). Optimal investment and finance
in renewable resource harvesting, Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control, 2 1 , 603-630.
[389] J0rgensen, S., Kort, P.M. and Zaccour, G., (1999). Production, inventory,
and pricing under cost and demand learning effects, European Journal of
Operational Research, 117, 382-395.
[390] Joseph, P.D. and Tou, J.T. (1961). On hnear control theory. Trans.
AIEE, Part II, 80, 193-196.
[393] Kalish, S. (1983). Monopolist pricing with dynamic demand and produc-
tion cost. Marketing Science, 2, 2, 135-159.
[394] Kalish, S. (1985). A new product adoption model with price, advertising,
and uncertainty. Marketing Science, 3 1 , 12, 1569-1585.
[395] Kalish, S. and Lilien, G.L. (1983). Optimal price subsidy policy for ac-
celerating the diffusion of innovation. Marketing Science, 2, 4, 407-420.
Bibliography 447
[396] Kalish, S. and Sen, S.K. (1986). Diffusion models and the marketing mix
for single products, in Series in Econometrics and Management Science:
Innovation Diffusion Models of New Products Acceptance^ V. Mahajan
and Y. Wind (Eds.), Ballinger, Cambridge, MA, Vol. V, 87-116.
[397] Kalman, R.E. (1960a). A new approach to linear filtering and prediction
problems. Trans. ASME Ser. D: J. Basic Eng., 82, 35-45.
[399] Kalman, R.E. and Bucy, R. (1961). New results in linear filtering and
prediction theory. Trans. ASME Ser. D: J. Basic Eng., 83, 95-108.
[400] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1971a). Optimal maintenance and sale
age for a machine subject to failure. Management Science^ 17, 427-449.
[401] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1971b). Limit pricing and uncertain
entry, Econometrica, 39, 441-454.
[402] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1978). Optimal exhaustible resource
depletion with endogenous technical change. Review of Economic Studies,
45, 179-196.
[403] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1982a). Market Structure and Innova-
tion, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
[404] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1982b). The role of common property
resources in optimal planning models with exhaustible resources, in Ex-
plorations in Natural Resource Economics, V.K. Smith and J.V. Krutilla
(Eds.), John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, Maryland, 47-71.
[405] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1998). Dynamic Optimization: The
Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control in Economics and Manage-
ment, Second Edition, Fourth Impression, North-Holland, New York.
[407] Karatzas, I., Lehoczky, J.P., Sethi, S.P. and Shreve, S.E. (1986). Explicit
solution of a general consumption/investment problem. Mathematics of
Operations Research, 11, 2, 261-294.
[408] Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S.E. (1997). Brownian Motion and Stochastic
Calculus, Second Edition, Springer-Verlag, New York.
[410] Keeler, E., Spence, M. and Zeckhauser, R.J. (1971). The optimal control
of pollution. Journal of Economic Theory^ 4, 19-34.
[411] Keller, H.B. (1968). Numerical Methods for Two-Point Boundary Value
Problems, Blaisdell, Waltham, Mass.
[412] Kemp, M.C. and Long, N.V. (1977). Optimal control problems with inte-
grands discontinuous with respect to time, Economic Record, 53, 405-420.
[413] Kemp, M.C. and Long, N.V. (Eds.) (1980). Exhaustible Resources, Opti-
mality, and Trade, North-Holland, Amsterdam,
[420] Kirby, B.J. (Ed.) (1974). Optimal Control Theory and its Applications,
Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, Part I k, H,
Vols. 105 & 106, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.
[422] Klein, C.F. and Gruver, W.A. (1978). On the optimal control of a single-
server queueing system: comment. Journal of Optimization Theory and
Applications,2%, 457-462.
[424] Kleindorfer, P.R., Kriebel, C.H., Thompson, G.L. and Kleindorfer, G.B.
(1975). Discrete optimal control of production plans, Management Sci-
ence, 22, 261-273.
[425] Kleindorfer, P.R. and Lieber, Z. (1979). Algorithms and planning horizon
results for production planning problems with separable costs. Operations
Research, 27, 874-887.
[429] Kogan, K., Khmelnitsky, E., Shtub, A. and Maimon, O. (1997). Optimal
flow control of flexible manufacturing systems: setup localization by an
iterative procedure. International Journal of Production Economics, 51,
37-46.
[433] Krelle, W. (1984). Economic growth with exhaustible resources and en-
vironmental protection, Zeitschrift fiir ges. Staatswiss, 140, 399-429.
[434] Krichagina, E., Lou, S., Sethi, S.P. and Taksar, M.I. (1993). Production
control in a failure-prone manufacturing system: diffusion approximation
and asymptotic optimality. Annals of Applied Probability, 3, 2, 421-453.
[435] Krichagina, E., Lou, S., Sethi, S.P. and Taksar, M.I. (1995). Diffusion
approximation for a controlled stochastic manufacturing system with av-
erage cost minimization. Mathematics of Operations Research, 20, 4, 895-
922.
[436] Krouse, C.G. (1972). Optimal financing and capital structure programs
for the firm. Journal of Finance, 27, 1057-1071.
450 Bibliography
[437] Krouse, C.G. and Lee, W.Y. (1973). Optimal equity financing of the
corporation, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 8, 539-563.
[438] Kugelmann, B. and Pesch, H.J. (1990). New general guidance method
in constrained optimal control, part 1: numerical method. Journal of
Optimization Theory and Applications, 67, 3, 421-435.
[440] Kurcyusz, S. and Zowe, J. (1979). Regularity and stability for the math-
ematical programming problem in Banach spaces. Applied Mathematics
& Optimization, 5, 49-62.
[443] Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.G. (1977). Rules rather than discretion:
the inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85,
473-493.
[445] Lansdowne, Z.F. (1970). The theory and applications of generalized lin-
ear control processes, technical report no. 10, Department of Operations
Research, Stanford University.
[446] Lasdon, L.S., Mitter, S.K., and Warren, A.D. (1967). The conjugate
gradient method for optimal control problems, IEEE Transactions on
Automatic Control, AC-12, 132-138.
[448] Lee, E.B. and Markus, L. (1968). Foundations of Optimal Control Theory,
Wiley, New York.
[449] Legey, L., Ripper, M. and Varaiya, P.P. (1973). Effects of congestion on
the shape of the city. Journal of Economic Theory, 6,162-179.
[450] Lehoczky, J.P., Sethi, S.P., Soner H.M. and Taksar, M.L (1991). An
asymptotic analysis of hierarchical control of manufacturing systems un-
der uncertainty. Mathematics of Operations Research, 16, 3, 596-608.
Bibliography 451
[458] Leitmann, G. and Liu, P.-T. (1974). A differential game model of labor-
management negotiation during a strike. Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 13, 427-444.
[459] Leland, H.E. (1972). The dynamics of a revenue maximizing firm, Inter-
national Economic Review, 13, 376-385.
[460] Lele, M.M., Jacobson, D.H. and McCabe, J.L. (1971). Qualitative ap-
plication of a result in control theory to problems of economic growth,
International Economic Review, 12, 209-226.
[461] Leonard, D. and Long, N.V.(1992). Optimal Control Theory and Static
Optimization in Economics, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,
UK.
[463] Lesourne, J. and Leban, R. (1982). Control theory and the dynamics of
the firm: a survey, OR-Spektrum, 4, 1-14.
[464] Levine, J. and Thepot, J. (1982). Open loop and closed loop equilibria in
a dynamic duopoly, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis,
G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 143-156.
[466] Lewis, T.R. and Schmalensee, R. (1979). Non-convexity and optimal har-
vesting strategies for renewable resources, Canadian J. of Economics, 12,
677-691.
[467] Lewis, T.R. and Schmalensee, R. (1982). Optimal use of renewable re-
sources with nonconvexities in production, in Essays in the Economics
of Renewable Resources, L.J. Mirman and P.F. Spulber (Eds.), North-
Holland, Amsterdam, 95-111.
[468] Li, G. and Rajagopalan, S. (1997). A learning curve model with knowl-
edge depreciation, European Journal of Operational Research, 105, 1,
143-154.
[473] Lintner, J. (1963). The cost of capital and optimal financing of corporate
growth. Journal of Finance, 23, 292-310.
[474] Lions, J.L. (1971). Optimal Control of Systems Governed by Partial Dif-
ferential Equations, Springer-Verlag, New York.
[475] Little, J.D.C. (1979). Aggregate advertising models: the state of the art,
Operations Res., 27, 4, 629-667.
[476] Little, J.D.C. (1986). Comment on "Advertising pulsing policies..." by
V. Mahajan and E. Muller, Marketing Science, 5, 2, 107-108.
[477] Liu, P.-T. (1980). Dynamic Optimization and Mathematical Economics,
Plenum Press, New York.
[478] Liu, P.-T. and Roxin, E.G. (Eds.) (1979). Differential Games and Control
Theory III, Marcel Dekker, Inc., New York.
[479] Liu, P.-T. and Sutinen, J.G. (Eds.) (1979). Control Theory in Mathemat-
ical Economics, Marcel Dekker, Inc., New York.
[480] Long, N.V. and Vousden, N. (1977). Optimal control theorems, in Appli-
cations of Control Theory in Economic Analysis, J.D. Pitchford and S.J.
Turnovsky (Eds.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 11-34.
Bibliography 453
[481] Loon, P.J.J.M., van (1983). A Dynamic Theory of the Firm: Production,
Finance and Investment, Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical
Systems, Vol. 218, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.
[482] Lou, S., Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1994). Optimal feedback produc-
tion planning in a stochastic two-machine fiowshop, European Journal of
Operational Research, 73, 331-345.
[483] Lucas, Jr., R.E. (1971). Optimal management of a research and develop-
ment project. Management Science, 17, 679-697.
[484] Lucas, Jr., R.E. (1981). Optimal investment with rational expectations,
in Rational Expectations and Economic Practice, R.E. Lucas, Jr. and T.J.
Sargent (Eds.), G. Allen & Unwin, London, 55-66.
[490] Luhmer, A., Steindl, A., Feichtinger, G., Hartl, R.F. and Sorger, G.
(1988). ADPULS in continuous time, European Journal of Operational
Research, 34, 2, 171-177.
[491] Lundin, R.A. and Morton, T.E. (1975). Planning horizons for the dy-
namic lot size model: protective procedures and computational results,
Operations Research, 23, 711-734.
[492] Luptacik, M. (1982). Optimal price and advertising policy under atom-
istic competition, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 4, 57-71.
[496] Magat, W.A., McCann, J.M. and Morey, R.C. (1986). When does lag
structure really matter in optimizing advertising expenditures?, Man-
agement Science, 32, 2, 182-193.
[497] Magat, W.A., McCann, J.M. and Morey, R.C. (1988). Reply to when
does lag structure really matter ... Indeed?, Management Science, 34, 7,
917-918.
[499] Mahajan, V. and Muller, E. (1979). Innovation diffusion and new product
growth models in marketing. Journal Marketing, 43, 55-68.
[500] Mahajan, V. and Muller, E. (1986). Advertising pulsing policies for gen-
erating awareness for new products. Marketing Science, 5, 2, 89-111.
[502] Mahajan, V. and Peterson, R.A. (1985). Models for Innovation Diffusion,
Sage, Beverly Hills.
[504] Maimon, O., Khmelnitsky, E. and Kogan, K. (1998). Optimal Flow Con-
trol in Manufacturing Systems, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.
[507] Malliaris, A.G. and Brock, W.A. (1982). Stochastic Methods in Eco-
nomics and Finance, North-Holland, Elsevier Science Publishers, New
York.
Bibliography 455
[508] Mangasarian, O.L. (1966). Sufficient conditions for the optimal control
of nonlinear systems, SI AM Journal on Control^ 4, 139-152.
[517] Maurer, H. (1981). First and second order sufficient optimality conditions
in mathematical programming and optimal control. Math. Programming
Stud., 14, 163-177.
[521] Mayne, D.Q. and Polak, E. (1987). An exact penalty function algorithm
for control problems with state and control constraints, IEEE Transac-
tions on Automatic Control, 32, 380-387.
[524] Mehra, R.K. and Davis, R.E. (1972). Generahzed gradient method for
optimal control problems with inequality constraint and singular arcs,
IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-17, 69-79.
[529] Merton, R.C. (1969). Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: the
continuous-time case. Rev. Economics & Statistics, 51, 247-257.
[534] Mesak, H.I. and Darrat, A.F. (1992). On comparing alternative advertis-
ing policies for pulsation. Decision Sciences, 23, 541-564.
Bibliography 457
[535] Michel, P. (1981). Choice of projects and their starting dates: an exten-
sion of Pontryagin's maximum principle to a case which allows choice
among different possible evolution equations, Journal of Economic Dy-
namics and Control, 3, 97-118.
[539] Miller, M.H. and Modigliani, F. (1961). Dividend policy, growth, and
valuation of shares, The Journal of Business, 34, 411-433.
[541] Mirman, L.J. and Spulber, P.F. (Eds.) (1982). Essays in the Economics
of Renewable Resources, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
[546] Monahan, G.E. (1984). A pure birth model of optimal advertising with
word-of-mouth, Marketing Sc, 3, 2, 169-178.
[549] Morton, T.E. (1978). Universal planning horizons for generalized convex
production scheduling, Operations Research, 26, 1046-1057.
[553] Murray, D.M. and Yakowitz, S.J. (1984). Differential dynamic program-
ming and Newton's methods for discrete optimal control problems, Jour-
nal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 43, 3, 395-414.
[555] Nahorski, Z., Ravn, H.F. and Vidal, R.V.V. (1984). The discrete-time
maximum principle: a survey and some new results. International J. of
Control, 40, 533-554.
[556] Naik, RA., Mantrala, M.K. and Sawyer, A. (1998). Planning pulsing
media schedules in the presence of dynamic advertising quality. Marketing
Science, 17, 3, 214-235.
[558] Naslund, B. (1969). Optimal rotation and thinning. Forest Science, 15,
466-451.
[561] Neck, R. (1984). Stochastic control theory and operational research, Eu-
ropean Journal of Operational Research, 17, 283-301.
[564] Nerlove, M. and Arrow, K.J. (1962). Optimal advertising policy under
dynamic conditions, Economica, 29, 129-142.
[567] Norstrom, C.J. (1978). The continuous wheat trading model reconsid-
ered. An application of mathematical control theory with a state con-
straint, W.P. 58-77-78, GSIA, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh,
Pa.
[570] Oberle, H.J. (1986). Numerical solution of minimax optimal control prob-
lems by multiple shooting technique. Journal of Optimization Theory and
Applications, 50, 331-358.
[571] Oberle, H.J. and Grimm, W. (1989). BNDSCO: A Program for the Nu-
merical Solution of Optimal Control Problems, Report 515, Institut for
Flight Systems Dynamics, German Aerospace Research Establishment
DLR, OberpfafFenhofen, Germany.
[573] Oguztoreh, M.N. and Stein, R.B. (1983). Optimal control or antagonistic
muscles, Biol. Cybern., 48, 91-99.
[574] Oksendal, B.K. (1998). Stochastic Differential Equations: An Introduc-
tion With Applications, Springer-Verlag, New York.
[575] Olsder, G.J. (1976). Some thoughts about simple advertising models as
dijBFerential games and the structure of coalitions, in Directions in Large-
Scale Systems, Many-Person Optimization and Decentralized Control, Y.-
C. Ho and S.K. Mitter (Eds.), Plenum Press, New York, 187-205.
460 Bibliography
[577] Oren, S.S. and Powell, S.G. (1985). Optimal supply of a depletable re-
source with a backstop technology. Operations Research, 33, 277-292.
[581] Pantoja, J.F. and Mayne, D.Q. (1991). Sequential quadratic program-
ming algorithm for discrete optimal control problems with control in-
equality constraints. International Journal on Control, 53, 4, 823-836.
[582] Parlar, M. (1983). Optimal forest fire control with limited reinforcements,
Optimal Control Application & Methods, 4, 185-191.
[583] Parlar, M. (1984). Optimal dynamic service rate control in time depen-
dent M/M/S/N queues, International Journal of Systems Science, 15,
107-118.
[585] Parlar, M. and Vickson, R.G. (1980). An optimal control problem with
piecewise quadratic cost functional containing a 'dead zone'. Optimal
Control Application & Methods, 1, 361-372.
[586] Parlar, M. and Vickson, R.G. (1982). Optimal forest fire control: an
extension of Park's model. Forest Science, 28, 345-355.
[594] Pesch, H.J. (1989). Real-time computation of feedback controls for con-
strained optimal control problems, part 1: neighboring extremals. Opti-
mal Control Applications & Methods, 10, 2, 129-145.
[595] Pesch, H.J. (1989). Real-time computation of feedback controls for con-
strained optimal control problems, part 2: a correction method based
on multiple shooting. Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 10, 2,
147-171.
[596] Pesch, H.J. (1994). A practical guide to the solution of real-life optimal
control problems. Control and Cybernetics, 23, 1/2, 7-60.
[597] Pesch, H.J. and Bulirsch, R. (1994). The maximum principle. Bellman's
equation, and Canatheodory's Work, Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 80, 1, 203-229.
[599] Peterson, D.W. and Zalkin, J.H. (1978). A review of direct sufficient
conditions in optimal control theory. International Journal Control, 28,
589-610.
[600] Peterson, P.M. and Fisher, A.C. (1977). The exploitation of extractive
resources: a survey. Economic Journal, 87, 681-721.
[602] Pierskalla, W.P. and Voelker, J.A. (1976). Survey of maintenance mod-
els: the control and surveillance of deteriorating systems. Naval Research
Logistics Quarterly 23, 353-388.
[603] Pindyck, R.S. (Ed.) (1978a). Advances in the Economics of Energy and
Resources, I I , J.A.I. Press, Greenwich, Conn.
462 Bibliography
[604] Pindyck, R.S. (1978b). The optimal exploration and production of non-
renewable resources, Journal of Political Economy, 86, 841-862.
[605] Pindyck, R.S. (1978c). Gains to producers from the cartelization of ex-
haustible resources. Rev. Economics & Statistics, 60, 238-251.
[606] Pindyck, R.S. (1978b). The optimal exploration and production of non-
renewable resources. Journal of Political Economy, 86, 841-862.
[607] Pindyck, R.S. (1982). Adjustment costs, uncertainty, and the behavior
of the firm, American Economic Review, 72, 3, 415-427.
[608] Pitchford, J.D. and Turnovsky, S.J. (Eds.) (1977). Applications of Control
Theory to Economic Analysis, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
[612] Polak, E., Yang, T.H. and Mayne, D.Q. (1993). A method of centers
based on barrier functions for solving optimal control problems with
continuous state and control constraints, SIAM Journal on Control and
Optimization, 3 1 , 159-179.
[614] Presman, E., Sethi, S.P. and Suo, W. (1997a). Optimal feedback produc-
tion planning in stochastic dynamic jobshops, in Mathematics of Stochas-
tic Manufacturing Systems, G. Yin and Q. Zhang (Eds.); Lectures in Ap-
plied Mathematics, Vol. 33, American Mathematical Society, Providence,
RI, 235-252.
[615] Presman, E., Sethi, S.P. and Suo, W. (1997b). Existence of optimal feed-
back production plans in stochastic iV-machine flowshops with limited
buffers, Automatica, 33, 4, 1899-1903.
[616] Presman, E., Sethi, S.P., Zhang, H. and Zhang, Q. (1998a). Analysis of
average cost optimality for an unreliable two-machine flowshop. Proceed-
ings of the Fourth International Conference on Optimization Techniques
and Applications, Curtin University of Technology, Perth, Australia, 94-
112.
Bibliography 463
[617] Presman, E., Sethi, S.R, Zhang, H. and Zhang, Q. (1998b). Optimahty
of zero-inventory poHcies for an unreliable manufacturing system pro-
ducing two part types, Dynamics of Continuous, Discrete and Impulsive
Systems, 4, 4, 485-496.
[618] Presman, E., Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1995). Optimal feedback pro-
duction planning in a stochastic TV-machine flowshop, Automatica, 3 1 ,
9, 1325-1332.
[620] Pytlak, R., and Vinter, R.B. (1993). PH2S0L Solver: An 0(N) Imple-
mentation of an Optimization Algorithm for a General Optimal Control
Problem, Research Report C93-36, Centre for Process Systems Engineer-
ing, Imperial College, London, United Kingdom.
[621] Pytlak, R., and Vinter, R.B. (1999). Feasible direction algorithm for opti-
mal control problems with state and control constraints: implementation,
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 101, 3, 623-649.
[625] Rao, R.C. (1970). Quantitative Theories in Advertising, Wiley, New York.
[627] Rao, R.C. (1985). A note on optimal and near optimal price and adver-
tising strategies. Management Science, 3 1 , 3, 376-377.
[631] Rapp, B. (1974). Models for Optimal Investment and Maintenance Deci-
sions, Almqvist & Wiksell, Stockholm; Wiley, New York.
[633] Raviv, A. (1979). The design of an optimal insurance policy. The Amer-
ican Economic Review, 69, 84-96.
[638] Rempala, R. (1986). Horizon for the dynamic family of wheat trading
problems. Proceedings Fourth International Symposium on Inventories,
Budapest.
[639] Rempala, R. and Sethi, S.R (1988). Forecast horizons in single product
inventory models, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis 3,
G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 225-233.
[640] Rempala, R. and Sethi, S.R (1992). Decision and forecast horizons for
one-dimensional optimal control problems: existence results and appli-
cations, Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 13, 179-192.
[641] Richard, S.F. (1979). A generalized capital asset pricing model, TIMS
Studies in the Management Sciences, 11, 215-232.
[643] Rishel, R.W. (1965). An extended Pontryagin principle for control sys-
tems whose control laws contain measures, Journal of Soc. Industrial &
AppL Math. Control, 3, 191-205.
[645] Roberts, S.M. and Shipman, J.S. (1972). Two-Point Boundary Value
Problems: Shooting Methods, Elsevier, New York.
[646] Robinson, B. and Lakhani, C. (1975). Dynamic price models for new-
product planning. Management Science, 2 1 , 10, 1113-1122.
[647] Robson, A.J. (1981). Sufficiency of the Pontryagin conditions for optimal
control when the time horizon is free. Journal of Economic Theory, 24,
438-445.
[648] Robson, A.J. (1985). Optimal control of systems governed by partial dif-
ferential equations: economic applications, in Optimal Control Theory
and Economic Analysis 2, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amster-
dam, 105-118.
[651] Russak, B. (1976). Relations among the multipliers for problems with
bounded state constraints, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization,
14, 1151-1155.
[652] Russell, D.L. (1965). Penalty functions and bounded phase coordinates,
SIAM Journal on Control, 2, 409-422.
[655] Samuelson, P.A. (1972). The general saddle point property of optimal-
control motions. Journal of Economic Theory, 5, 102-120.
[656] Sarma, V.V.S. and Alam, M. (1975). Optimal maintenance policies for
machines subject to deterioration and intermittent breakdowns, IEEE
Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, SMC-5, 396-398.
466 Bibliography
[660] Scalzo, R.C. (1974). N person linear quadratic differential games with
constraints, SIAM Journal on Control, 12, 419-425.
[663] Seidman, T.L, Sethi, S.P. and Derzko, N.A. (1987). Dynamics and opti-
mization of a sales advertising model with population migration. Journal
of Optimization Theory and Applications, 52, 3, 443-462.
[668] Seierstad, A. and Sydsaeter, K. (1987). Optimal Control Theory with Eco-
nomic Applications, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
[673] Sethi, S.P. (1973d). A note on modeling simple dynamic cash balance
problems. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 8, 685-687.
[674] Sethi, S.P. (1974a). Sufficient conditions for the optimal control of a
class of systems with continuous lags. Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 13, 542-552.
[675] Sethi, S.P. (1974b). Some explanatory remarks on the optimal control of
the Vidale-Wolfe advertising model. Operations Research, 22, 1119-1120.
[679] Sethi, S.P. (1977b). Nearest feasible paths in optimal control problems:
theory, examples, and counterexamples. Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 23, 4, 563-579.
[680] Sethi, S.P. (1977c). Optimal advertising for the Nerlove-Arrow model
under a budget constraint. Operational Research Quarterly, 28, 3, 683-
693.
[681] Sethi, S.P. (1977d). A linear bang-bang model of firm behavior and water
quality, IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-22, 706-714.
[683] Sethi, S.P. (1978b). Optimal equity financing model of Krouse and Lee:
corrections and extensions. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Anal-
ysis, 13, 3, 487-505.
468 Bibliography
[684] Sethi, S.P. (1978c). A note on modeling simple dynamic cash balance
problem: errata, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 13,
585-586.
[685] Sethi, S.P. (1978d). Optimal quarantine programs for controlling an epi-
demic spread, Journal of Operational Research Society, 29, 3, 265-268.
[686] Sethi, S.P. (1979a). Optimal depletion of exhaustible resources. Applied
Mathematical Modelling, 3, 367-378.
[687] Sethi, S.P. (1979b). Optimal pilfering policy for dynamic continuous
thieves, Management Science, 25, 6, 535-542.
[688] Sethi, S.P. (1979c). Optimal advertising policy with the contagion model,
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 29, 4, 615-627.
[689] Sethi, S.P. (1979d). A note on the Nerlove-Arrow model under uncer-
tainty, Operations Research, 27, 4, 839-842; Erratum, 28, 4, July-August
1980, 1026-1027.
[690] Sethi, S.P. (1983a). Optimal long-run equilibrium advertising level for
the Blattberg-Jeuland model. Management Science, 29, 12, 1436-1443.
[691] Sethi, S.P. (1983b). Deterministic and stochastic optimization of a dy-
namic advertising model. Optimal Control Application and Methods, 4,
2, 179-184.
[692] Sethi, S.P. (1983c). Applications of optimal control to management sci-
ence problems, Proceedings of the 1983 World Conference on Systems,
Caracas, Venezuela.
[693] Sethi, S.P. (1984). Application of the maximum principle to production
and inventory problems, Proceedings Third International Symposium On
Inventories, Budapest, 753-756.
[694] Sethi, S.P. (1990). Decision and forecast horizons in dynamic optimiza-
tion, Systems and Control Encyclopedia Supplementary, M.G. Singh
(Ed.), Pergamon Press, Oxford, U.K., Vol. 1, 192-198.
[695] Sethi, S.P. (1996). When does the share price equal the present value of
future dividends? - a modified dividend approach. Economic Theory, 8,
307-319.
[696] Sethi, S.P. (1997a). Optimal Consumption and Investment with
Bankruptcy, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.
[697] Sethi, S.P. (1997b). Some insights into near-optimal plans for stochastic
manufacturing systems, Mathematics of Stochastic Manufacturing Sys-
tems, G. Yin and Q. Zhang (Eds.); Lectures in Applied Mathematics,
Vol. 33, American Mathematical Society, Providence, RI, 287-315.
Bibliography 469
[699] Sethi, S.P. and Chand, S. (1979). Planning horizon procedures in machine
replacement models. Management Science, 25, 140-151; Erratum, 26, 3,
1980, 342.
[700] Sethi, S.P. and Chand, S. (1981). Multiple finite production rate dynamic
lot size inventory models. Operations Research, 29, 5, 931-944.
[701] Sethi, S.P., Derzko, N.A. and Lehoczky, J.P. (1982). Mathematical anal-
ysis of the Miller-Modigliani theory, O.R. Letters, 1, 148-152.
[702] Sethi, S.P. and Lee, S.C. (1981). Optimal advertising for the Nerlove-
Arrow Model under a replenishable budget. Optimal Control Applications
& Methods, 2, 2, 165-173.
[703] Sethi, S.P. and Lehoczky, J.P. (1981). A comparison of Ito and
Stratonovich formulations of problems in finance. Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, 3, 343-356.
[704] Sethi, S.P. and McGuire, T.W. (1977). Optimal skill mix: an application
of the maximum principle for systems with retarded controls. Journal of
Optimization Theory and Applications, 23, 245-275.
[705] Sethi, S.P. and Morton, T.E. (1972). A mixed optimization technique for
the generalized machine replacement problem. Naval Research Logistics
QuaHerly, 19, 471-481.
[708] Sethi, S.P. and Sorger, G. (1991). A theory of rolling horizon decision
making. Annals of O.R., 29, 387-416.
[709] Sethi, S.P. and Staats, P.W. (1978). Optimal control of some simple
deterministic epidemic models. Journal of Operational Research Society,
29, 2, 129-136.
[710] Sethi, S.P., Suo, W., Taksar, M.L and Yan, H. (1998). Optimal produc-
tion planning in a multiproduct stochastic manufacturing systems with
long-run average cost. Discrete Event Dynamic Systems, 8, 1, 37-54.
470 Bibliography
[711] Sethi, S.R, Suo, W., Taksar, M.I. and Zhang, Q. (1997). Optimal produc-
tion planning in a stochastic manufacturing system with long-run average
cost, Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 92, 1, 161-188.
[712] Sethi, S.P. and Taksar, M.I. (1988). Deterministic and stochastic control
problems with identical optimal cost functions, Analysis and Optimiza-
tion of Systems, A. Bensoussan and J.L. Lions (Eds.), Lecture Notes in
Control and Information Sciences, Springer-Verlag, New York, 641-645.
[713] Sethi, S.P. and Taksar, M.I. (1990). Deterministic equivalent for a
continuous-time linear-convex stochastic control problem. Journal of Op-
timization Theory and Applications, 64, 1, 169-181.
[715] Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1977). Christmas toy manufacturer's
problem: an application of the stochastic maximum principle, Opsearch,
14, 161-173.
[716] Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1981). Simple models in stochastic
production planning, in Applied Stochastic Control in Econometrics and
Management Science, A. Bensoussan, P.R. Kleindorfer and C.S. Tapiero
(Eds), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 295-304.
[717] Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1981). A tutorial on optimal control
theory. Information Systems and Operational Research, 19, 4, 279-291.
[718] Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1982). Planning and forecast horizons
in a simple wheat trading model. Operations Research in Progress, G. Fe-
ichtinger and P. Kail (Eds.), D. Reidel Publishing Company, Dordrecht,
Holland, 203-214.
[719] Sethi, S.P., Thompson, G.L. and Udayabhanu, V. (1985). Profit max-
imization models for exponential decay processes, European Journal of
Operational Research, 22, 101-115.
[720] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, H. (1999a). Average-cost optimal policies for an
unreliable flexible multiproduct machine, I.J.F.M.S., 1 1 , 147-157.
[721] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, H. (1999b). Hierarchical production controls for a
stochastic manufacturing system with long-run average cost: asymptotic
optimality, in Stochastic Analysis, Control, Optimization and Applica-
tions: A Volume in Honor of W.H. Fleming, W.M. McEneaney, G. Yin
and Q. Zhang (Eds.), Birkhauser, Boston, 621-637.
Bibliography 471
[727] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1995a). Hierarchical production and setup
scheduling in stochastic manufacturing systems, IEEE Transactions on
Automatic Control, 40, 5, 924-930.
[728] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1995b). Multilevel hierarchical decision mak-
ing in stochastic marketing - production systems, SIAM Journal on Con-
trol and Optimization, 33, 2, 538-553.
[730] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1998b). Optimal control of dynamic systems
by decomposition and aggregation, Journal of Optimization Theory and
Applications, 99, 1, 1-22.
[731] Sethi, S.R, Zhang, Q. and Zhou, X. (1997). Hierarchical production con-
trols in a stochastic two-machine flowshop with a finite internal buffer,
IEEE Transactions on Robotics and Automation, 13, 1, 1-13.
[732] Sethi, S.P. and Zhou, X. (1996a). Optimal feedback controls in determin-
istic dynamic two-machine flowshops, O. R. Letters, 19, 5, 225-35.
[733] Sethi, S.R and Zhou, X. (1996b). Asymptotic optimal feedback con-
trols in stochastic dynamic two-machine flowshops, in Recent Advances
in Control and Optimization of Manufacturing Systems, Lecture Notes
in Control and Information Sciences, Vol. 214, G. Yin and Q. Zhang
(Eds.), Springer-Verlag, New York, 147-180.
472 Bibliography
[739] Silva, G.N. and Vinter, R.B. (1997). Necessary conditions for optimal
impulsive control problems, SI AM Journal on Control and Optimization,
35, 6, 1829-1846.
[741] Simon, H.A. (1982). ADPULS: an advertising model with wearout and
pulsation. Journal of Marketing Research, 19, 352-363.
[747] Snower, D.J. (1982). Macroeconomic policy and the optimal destruction
of vampires. Journal of Political Economy, 90, 647-655.
[749] Solow, R.M. and Wan, F.Y. (1976). Extraction costs in the theory of
exhaustible resources, Bell Journal of Economics, 7, 359-370.
[753] Spence, M. (1981). The learning curve and competition. Bell Journal of
Economics, 12, 49-70.
[754] Spiegel, M.R. (1971). Schaum's Outline of Theory and Problems of Cal-
culus of Finite Differences and Difference Equations, McGraw-Hill, New
York.
[759] Starr, A.W. and Ho, Y.-C. (1969). Nonzero-sum differential games. Jour-
nal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 3, 184-206.
[760] Steindl, A., Feichtinger, G., Hartl, R.F. and Sorger, G. (1986). On the
optimality of cyclical employment policies: a numerical investigation,
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 10, 457-466.
[763] Stiglitz, J.E. and Dasgupta, P. (1982). Market structure and the resource
depletion: a contribution to the theory of intertemporal monopoHstic
competition, Journal of Economic Theory^ 28, 128-164.
[768] Sydsaeter, K. (1978). Optimal control theory and economics: some critical
remarks on the literature, Scand. Journal of Economics, 80, 113-117.
[770] Sweeney, D.J., Abad, P.L. and Dornoff, R.J. (1974). Finding an optimal
dynamic advertising policy. International Journal of Systems Science, 5,
10, 987-994.
[772] Tan, K.C. and Bennett, R.J. (1984). Optimal Control of Spatial Systems,
George Allen Sz Unwin, London.
[776] Tapiero, C.S. (1978). Optimum advertising and goodwill under uncer-
tainty, Operations Research, 26, 3, 450-463.
[777] Tapiero, C.S. (1981). Optimum product quality and advertising. Infor-
mation Systems and Operational Research, 19, 4, 311-318.
Bibliography 475
[780] Tapiero, C.S. (1983). Stochastic diffusion models with advertising and
word-of-mouth effects, European Journal of Operational Research, 12, 4,
348-356.
[781] Tapiero, C.S. (1988). Applied Stochastic Models and Control in Manage-
ment, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
[782] Tapiero, C.S., Eliashberg, J. and Wind, Y. (1987). Risk behaviour and
optimum advertising with a stochastic dynamic sales response. Optimal
Control Applications & Methods, 8, 3, 299-304.
[783] Tapiero, C.S. and Farley, J.U. (1975). Optimal control of sales force effort
in time. Management Science, 21, 9, 976-985.
[784] Tapiero, C.S. and Farley, J.U. (1981). Using an uncertainty model to
assess sales response to advertising. Decision Science, 12, 441-455.
[785] Tapiero, C.S. and Soliman, M.A. (1972). Multi- commodities transporta-
tion schedules over time. Networks, 2, 311-327.
[786] Tapiero, C.S. and Venezia, I. (1979). A mean variance approach to the
optimal machine maintenance and replacement problem. Journal of Op-
erational Research Society, 30, 457-466.
[789] Taylor, J.G., (1974). Lanchester-type models of warfare and optimal con-
trol, Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 21, 79-106.
[790] Teng, J.-T. and Thompson, G.L. (1983). Oligopoly models for optimal
advertising when production costs obey a learning curve. Management
Science, 29, 9, 1087-1101.
[791] Teng, J.-T. and Thompson, G.L. (1985). Optimal strategies for general
price-advertising models, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Anal-
ysis 2, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 183-195.
476 Bibliography
[792] Teng, J.-T., Thompson, G.L. and Sethi, S.R (1984). Strong decision
and forecast horizons in a convex production planning problem, Optimal
Control Applications & Methods^ 5, 4, 319-330.
[793] Teo, K.L., Goh, C.J. and Wong, K.H. (1991). A Unified Computational
Approach to Optimal Control Problems^ Longman Scientific & Technical,
E^ssex, England.
[794] Teo, K.L. and Moore, E.J. (1977). Necessary conditions for optimality for
control problems with time delays appearing in both state and control
variables. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 23, 413-427.
[798] Thompson, G.L. (1968). Optimal maintenance policy and sale date of a
machine. Management Science, 14, 543-550.
[802] Thompson, G.L. and Sethi, S.P. (1980). Turnpike horizons for production
planning. Management Science, 26, 229-241.
[803] Thompson, G.L., Sethi, S.P. and Teng, J.-T. (1984). Strong planning and
forecast horizons for a model with simultaneous price and production
decisions, European Journal of Operational Research, 16, 378-388.
[804] Thompson, G.L. and Teng, J.-T. (1984). Optimal pricing and advertising
policies for new product oligopoly models. Marketing Science, 3, 2, 148-
168.
Bibliography 477
[810] Tragler, G., Caulkins, J.R and Feichtinger, G. (2000). The impact of
enforcement and treatment on illicit drug consumption. Operations Re-
search, forthcoming.
[811] Treadway, A.B. (1970). Adjustment costs and variable inputs in the the-
ory of the competitive firm. Journal of Economic Theory, 2, 329-347.
[812] Troch, I. (Ed.) (1978). Simulation of Control Systems with Special Em-
phasis on Modelling and Redundancy, Proceedings of the IMACS Sym-
posium, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
[816] Turner, R.E. and Neuman, C.P. (1976). Dynamic advertising strategy: a
managerial approach. Journal of Business Administration, 7, 1-21.
[817] Turnovsky, S.J. (1981). The optimal intertemporal choice of inflation and
unemployment. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 3, 357-384.
[819] Uhler, R.S. (1979). The rate of petroleum exploration and extraction,
in Advances in the Economics of Energy and Resources^ R.S,. Pindyck
(Ed.), Vol. 2, JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, 93-118.
[820] Valentine, F.A. (1937). The problem of Lagrange with differential in-
equalities as added side conditions, in Contributions to the Theory of the
Calculus of Variations, 1933-1937, University Chicago Press, Chicago,
IL.
[821] Van Hilten, O., Kort, P.M. and Van Loon, P.J.J.M. (1993). Dynamic
Policies of the Firm: An Optimal Control Approach, Springer-Verlag,
New York.
[823] Varaiya, P.P. (1970). N-person nonzero-sum differential games with linear
dynamics, SIAM Journal on Control, 8, 441-449.
[824] Verheyen, P. A. (1985). A dynamic theory of the firm and the reaction on
governmental policy, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis,
G. Feichtinger (Ed.), Vol. 2, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 313-329.
[825] Vickson, R.G. (1981). Schedule control for randomly drifting production
sequences. Information Systems and Operational Research, 19, 330-346.
[828] Vickson, R.G. (1986/7). A single product cycling problem under Brown-
ian motion demand, erscheint in Management Science.
[829] Vidale, M.L. and Wolfe, H.B. (1957). An operations research study of
sales response to advertising. Operations Research, 5, 3, 370-381.
[832] Vinter, R.B. (1983). New global optimality conditions in optimal control
theory, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 2 1 , 235-245.
Bibliography 479
[834] Wagner, H.M. and Whitin, T.M. (1958). Dynamic version of the economic
lot size model. Management Science, 5, 89-96.
[840] Weinstein, M.C. and Zeckhauser, R.J. (1975). The optimum consumption
of depletable natural resources. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 89,
371-392.
[842] Welam, U.P. (1982). Optimal and near optimal price and advertising
strategies for finite and infinite horizons. Management Science, 28, 11,
1313-1327.
[845] Wickwire, K. (1977). Mathematical models for the control of pests and
infectious diseases: a survey. Theoretical Population Biology, 11, 182-238.
[847] Wirl, F. (1984). Sensitivity analysis of OPEC pricing polices, OPEC Rev.,
8, 321-331.
[848] Wirl, F. (1985). Stable and volatile prices: and explanation by dynamic
demand, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis 2, G. Fe-
ichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 263-277.
[852] Yang, J., Yan, H. and Sethi, S.P. (1999). Optimal production planning in
pull flow lines with multiple products, European Journal of Operational
Research, 119, 3, 26-48.
[854] Young, L.C. (1969). Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory,
W.B. Saunders Co., Philadelphia, Pa.
[855] Zeidan, V. (1984a). Extended Jacobi sufficiency criterion for optimal con-
trol, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 22, 294-301.
[857] Zhou, X. and Sethi, S.P. (1994). A sufficient condition for near optimal
stochastic controls and its application to manufacturing systems. Applied
Mathematics & Optimization, 29, 67-92.
[858] Ziemba, W.T. and Vickson, R.G. (Eds.) (1975). Stochastic Optimization
Models in Finance, Academic Press, New York.
[860] Zimin, I.N. and Ivanilov, Y.P. (1971). Solution of network planning prob-
lems by reducing them to optimal control problems, Zhurnal Vychifli-
teVnoi Matematiki i Matematichefkoi Fiziki (in Russian), 1 1 , 3.
Bibliography 481
[861] Zoltners, A.A. (Ed.) (1982). Marketing Planning Models, TIMS Studies
in the Management Sciences, Vol. 18, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
Index
Abad, P.L., 417, 474 Axsater, S., 418
adjoint equation, 31, 32, 36, 230
adjoint function, 322 Baar, T., 425
adjoint variables, 10, 32 backlogging of demand, 5, 348
adjoint vector, 30, 33 Bagchi, A., 419
admissible control, 24 Balachandran, B., 445
advertising model, 5, 6 Balakrishman, A.V., 455
affine function, 19 bang function, 16
Agnew, C.E., 417 bang-bang, 42, 78, 84, 85, 87,
Alam, M., 249, 265, 417, 465 122, 132, 135, 190, 194,
AUen, K.R., 286, 417 232, 244, 247, 257, 258,
Amit, R., 154, 279, 418 313, 322, 328, 329, 333,
Amoroso-Robinson relation, 187 334, 408
Anderson, R.M., 418 bankruptcy, 358
anti-difference operator, 376 Bamea, A., 452
Aoki, M., 345, 418 Basar, T., 308, 419, 420, 430,
applications to biomedicine, 295 446
applications to finance, 119 Bass, F.M., 419
applications to marketing, 185 Bayes theorem, 342
Arnold, L., 344, 347, 348, 418 Bean, J . C , 182, 419
Aronson, J.E., 418, 471 begiiming game, 321
Arora, S.R., 243, 418 Bell, D.J., 42, 407, 419
Arrow, K.J., 10, 46, 58, 81, 82, Belhnan, R.E., 9, 27, 419
186, 188, 289, 290, 360, Bennett, R.J., 474
418, 456, 459 Bensoussan, A., 10, 58, 88, 154,
Arthur, W.B., 304, 418 173, 182, 191, 315, 322,
Arugaslan, O., viii 324, 360, 419, 420, 444,
Arutyunov, A.V., 103, 418 461, 470
Aseev, S.M., 103, 418 bequest function, 7, 355
Aubin, J.-R, 418, 466 Berkovitz, L.D., 10, 27, 308, 420
autocorrelation function, 343 Bernoulli, Jacob, 8, 9, 384
autonomous, 52, 81 Bernoulli, Johann, 8, 9, 384
484 Index
Bertsekas, D.P., 236, 346, 420, Bulirsch, R., 9, 108, 422, 461,
430 474
Bes, C , 173, 182, 420 Bullinger, H.J., 479
Beyer, D., viii, 421 Bultez, A.V., 315, 419, 422
Bharucha-Reid, A.T., 480 Burdet, C.A., 236, 239, 422
Bhaskaran, S., 182, 421 Burmeister, E., 290, 291, 422
bionomic eqmlibrium, 269, 314 Buskens, C., 455
Black, F., 355, 421 Butkowskiy, A.G., 317, 422
Blaquiere, A., 325, 326, 331, 421, Bylka, S., 182, 254, 423
464, 473
BUss point, 306 Gaines, P., 423
BUss, G.A., 9 calculus of variations, 8, 379
Boiteux problem, 241 Canon, M.D., 235, 423
Boiteux, M., 241, 421 canonical adjoints, 33
Boltyanskii, V.G., 9, 27, 421, canonical system of equations,
462 33
Bolza, 9 capital accumulation model, 290
Bolza form, 25, 26, 229, 235, 239 Caratheodory, C., 9
Bookbinder, J.H., vi, 10, 304, Carlson, D.A., 10, 82, 423-425
421 Carraro, C , 315, 425
boundary conditions, 61, 350 Carrillo, J., 154, 425
boundary interval, 105 Case, J.H., 308, 325, 425
Bourguignon, F., 421 Cass, D., 425
Brachistochrone problem, 8, 9, Cassandras, C.G., 236, 461
384 cattle ranching problem, 318
Breakwell, J.V., 190, 421 Caulkins, J.P., 477
Brekke, K.A., 360, 422 CeUina, A., 418
Brito, D.L., 304, 422 certainty equivalence, 403, 404
Brock, W.A., 360, 454 Cesari, L., 26, 425
Brockhoff, K., 420 chain of forests model, 276-278
broken extremal, 387 chain of machines, 254
Brotherton, T., 423 Chand, S., 182, 254, 425, 469
Brown, R.G., 164, 422 Chandra, T., 445
Brownian Motion, 356 Chang, S., 360, 418
Bryant, G.F., 27, 422 Charnes, A., 304, 425
Bryson, Jr., A.E., 33, 87, 105, Chatterjee, R., 463
108, 341, 401, 403, 404, Chen, S.F., 425
406, 422 Cheng, F., viii
Buchanan, L.F., 345, 422 Chiarella, C , 426
Bucy, R., 345, 447 Chichilinsky, G., 426
Index 485
6.1
Optimal Production and Inventory Levels 161
Solution of Example 6.1 with IQ = 10
6.2 163
Solution of Example 6.1 with IQ = 50
6.3 164
6.4
Solution of Example 6.1 with Io=^30 165
6.5
The Price Trajectory (6.49) 168
6.6
Adjoint Variable, Optimal Policy and Inventory in the
Wheat Trading Model 169
6.7 Adjoint Trajectory and Optimal Policy for the Wheat
Trading Model 173
6.8 Decision Horizon and Optimal Policy for the Wheat
Trading Model 175
6.9 Optimal Policy and Horizons for the Wheat Trading
Model with Warehouse Constraint 177
6.10 Optimal Policy and Horizons for Example 6.3 179
6.11 Optimal Policy and Horizons for Example 6.4 180
6.12 The Flow Chart for Exercise 6.9 183
10.1 Optimal Policy for the Sole Owner Fishery Model 271
10.2 Singular Usable Timber Volume x{t) 275
10.3 Optimal Policy for the Forest Thinning Model when
XQ < x{to) 276
10.4 Optimal Policy for the Chain of Forests Model when
T>i 277
10.5 Optimal Policy for the Chain of Forests Model when
T<i 279
10.6 The Demand Function 281
10.7 The Profit Function 282
10.8 Optimal Price Trajectory for T > f 285
10.9 Optimal Price Trajectory for T < f 285