0% found this document useful (0 votes)
144 views138 pages

Solutions of Linear Differential Equations: Appendixa

1. This document discusses methods for solving linear differential equations with constant coefficients. It begins by defining the forms of such equations and their auxiliary equations. 2. It then provides the general solution forms for homogeneous linear differential equations of orders one, two, and n. Real and complex roots of the auxiliary equation lead to different solution forms. 3. Methods are described for finding the particular solution to an inhomogeneous equation by guessing a form based on the type of forcing function and verifying it. 4. Additional topics covered include using an integrating factor to solve first-order linear equations and reducing higher-order equations to systems of first-order equations.

Uploaded by

Lynnie Ella
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
144 views138 pages

Solutions of Linear Differential Equations: Appendixa

1. This document discusses methods for solving linear differential equations with constant coefficients. It begins by defining the forms of such equations and their auxiliary equations. 2. It then provides the general solution forms for homogeneous linear differential equations of orders one, two, and n. Real and complex roots of the auxiliary equation lead to different solution forms. 3. Methods are described for finding the particular solution to an inhomogeneous equation by guessing a form based on the type of forcing function and verifying it. 4. Additional topics covered include using an integrating factor to solve first-order linear equations and reducing higher-order equations to systems of first-order equations.

Uploaded by

Lynnie Ella
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 138

Appendix A

Solutions of Linear
Differential Equations

A.l Linear Differential Equations with


Constant Coefficients
Linear diflFerential equations with constant coefficients are usually writ-
ten as
2/("> + ai2/("-i) + ... + a„_i2/(i) + anV = g, (A.l)
where a^, fc = 1,..., n, are numbers, y^^^ = ^ , and g = g{t) is a known
function of t. We shall denote hy D = ^ the derivative operator^ so that
the differential equation now becomes

p{D)y = (D^ + a i D ^ - i + ... + a^_iD + an)y = g. (A.2)

If g(t) = 0, the equation is said to be homogeneous. If g{t) ^ 0, then the


homogeneous or reduced equation is obtained from (A.2) by replacing g
byO.
If y and y* are two different solutions of (A.2), then it is easy to
show that y — y* solves the reduced equation of (A.2). Hence, if y is any
solution to (A.2), it can be written as

y = y*+y\ (A.3)
where y* is any other particular solution to (A.2) and y^ is a suitable
solution to the homogeneous equation. Therefore, solving (A.2) involves
(a) finding all the solutions to the homogeneous equation, caUed the gen-
eral solution, and (b) finding a particular solution to the given equation.
364 A. Solutions of Linear Differential Equations

The rest of these notes indicate how to solve these two problems.
Given (A.l) the auxiliary equation is
p{m) = mP + aim^'^ + ... + an-im + an = 0, (A.4)
In other words, p{m) is obtained from p{D) by replacing D by m. The
auxiliary equation is an ordinary polynomial of nth degree and has n real
or complex roots, counting multiple roots according to their multiplicity.
We will see that, given these roots, we can write the general solution
forms of homogeneous Unear differential equations.

A.2 Homogeneous Equations of Order One


Here the equation is
(D - a)y = y'-ay = 0,
which has y = Ce^^ as its general solution form.

A.3 Homogeneous Equations of Order Two


Here the differential equation can be factored (using the quadratic for-
mula) as
(D-mi)(Z)-m2)2/-0,
where m\ and m^ can be real or complex. Examples are given in Table
A.l and the solution forms are given in Table A.2.

Differential Equation General Solution Form

1. y"-Ay' + Ay = Q y{t) = e2*(Ci + Cit)

2. y" - % ' + 3y = 0 y{t)


= e2*(Di sinh t) + D2 sinh t)

3. y" - 4y' + 5y = 0 y{t)


= e^\Disva. t + Di cos t)

Table A.l: Examples of Homogeneous Equations of Order Two


A.4. Homogeneous Equations of Order n 365

Root General Solution Form

^ 1 7^ ^2? real y{t) = C i e ^ i * + C2e^2t

= e^*(Cie^^ + C2e-^^)

or

m i = a + 6, 1712 = a — b y(t) = e"*(Ci sinh 6t + C2 cosh bt)

mi = 7722 = ^^ y{t) = iCi+C2t)e^'

^ 1 7^ ^ 2 J complex y(t) = C i e ^ i * + C2e^2t

- e"^(Cie^^* + C2e-'^^)

or

m i = a + bi^ m2 = a — bi y(^) 3.: e"^(Di sin 6t + D2 cos bt)

or

y(^) = e^'^lEi sm{bt + ^2)]

or

y{t) = e''^[Ficos{bt + F2)] |

Table A.2: General Solution Forms for Second-Order Linear


Homogeneous Equations, Constant Coefficients

A.4 Homogeneous Equations of Order n

When (A.2) is of order n, the auxiliary equation p(m) = 0 has n roots,


when multiple roots are coimted according to their multiplicity. Also,
complex roots occur in conjugate pairs. The general solutions of the
homogeneous equations is the sum of the solutions associated with each
multiple root. They can be foimd in Table A.4 for each root and should
be added together to form the general solution. First, we give some
examples in Table A.3.
366 A. Solutions of Linear Differential Equations

Differential Equation General Solution Form

1. D 2 ( 2 ) 2 _ 4 D + 4 ) 2 / - 0 y(t) = Ci + C2i + e2*(C3 + C^t)

2. ( D - 3 ) 2 ( D + 5 ) 3 ( D 2 - 4 D + 5)2y=0 2/(t)-e3*(Ci+C2t)

+ e - 5 t ( C 3 + C4t + C5t2)

+e2*[(C6+C7)sin t

^ ( C s + CgOoos t]

3. ( D 2 -2D-\- 2 ) 3 ( D 2 - 2D -- 3)^2/ = 0 2/(i) = e*[(Ci -f C2* + C3t2) sin t

+(C4-f-C5t-f C6t2)cos i]

+(C7 + Cst)e^^ + (Cg + Ciot)e-^

Table A.3: Examples of Homogeneous Equations of Order n

Root Multiplicity General Solution Form

r,=l yj{t) = Ce'^J^

rrij, real rj > 1 yj{t) = (Ci 4- C2* + . . . + Crjf-J -i)e"^i*

Complex Conjugate r,=l e'^J*(Ci sin 6jt + C2 cos 6jt)

aj lb bj2 0>1 e^i*[Ci + C2t + . . . + Cr^-Ti - ^ ) s i n 6jt]

+(Cr^- + l + Cr^+2t + . . . + C2r,-r:'' - ^ ) COS bjt]

Table A.4: General Solution Forms for Multiple Roots of Auxiliary


Equation

A.5 Particular Solutions of Linear D . E . with


Constant Coefficients
The particular solution to the inhomogeneous equation (A.2) can usually
be found by guessing the form of the answer and then verifying the
guess by substitution. Table A.5 shows the correct forms for guessing
for various kinds of forcing fimctions g(t). Note that the form of the
guess depends on whether certain nimibers are roots of the auxiliary
equation. Table A.6 gives examples of differential equations along with
their particular integrals.
A,5. Particular Solutions of Linear D,E, — Constant Coefficients 367

Forcing Function, g{t) K Particular Integral, y{t)

(i)c 0 A

(2) h{t) 0 X

(3) csin qt or ccos qt 9 A sin qt — B cos qt

(4) ce"* 9 Ae<i*

(5) ce^* sin qt or ce^* cos qt p + iq AeP* sin ^t - Be^* cos ^i

(6) /i(i)e«* Q Xe«*

(7) /i(t) sin ^t or /i(f) cos qt iq X sin gi + y cos qfi

(8) /i(t)eP*sin gt or /i(i)eP*cos gt p + iq XeP*sin ^i + FeP^cos qt

Notation.

(a) In the forcing function column, p, q, and c are given constants and h{t) is a
given polynomial of degree s.
(b) In the p>articular integral column, A and B are coefficients to be determined
and

X = ^ 0 + Alt + . . . + Ast\ Y = Bo-\-Bit+ ... + Bst^

are s degree polynomials whose coefficients are to be determined.

Rules.

(a) If the number in the K column is not a root of the auxiliary equation p(m) = 0,
then the proper guess for the particular integral is as shown.
(b) If the number in the K colimin is a root of the auxiliary equation of degree r,
then multiply the guess in the last column by t^.

Table A.5: Particular Solution Forms for Various Forcing Functions

If the forcing function g{t) is the sum of several functions, 9^=91 +


g2 + *"+9ky each having one of the forms in the table, then solve for each
Qi separately and add the results together to get the complete solution.
In the next table, we wiU apply the formulas and the rules in Table
A.6 to obtain particular integrals in specific examples.
368 A. Solutions of Linear Differential Equations

Differential Equation Particular Integral

1.2/'"-32/" = 5 At^
2. y'" - 3y" = l + 3t + 5t^ t^Ao + Ait + A2t'^)
3. 2 / " - V + 42/ = 3 - i 2 Ao + Ait + A2t^

4. y" -4y' + 4y = 2sm t Asm t + Bcos t

5. 2 / " - 4 3 / ' + 42/= 5sin 2t Asm 2t + Bcos 2t

6. 2/" - 42/' + 4y = lOe^* Ae'^


7. 2/" - 4y' + 42/ = lOe^* i2(Ae2«)

8. 2/" - 42/' + 52/ = e^* cos t t{Ae^^ sin t + Be^* cos t)

9. 2/"-42/' + 52/ = t^sin f X^r_o(^r^'^ sin i + B^V cos i)

10. y" - 42/' + 5y = i^e^* cos t * Er=o(^r*''e2* sin « + B^fe^* cos


*)J
Table A.6: Particular Integrals in Specific Examples

A.6 Integrating Factor


Consider the first-order linear equation

2/' + ay = / ( i ) . (A.5)

If we multiply both sides of the equation by the integrating factor e"*,


we get
d
^(ye«')=j/'e"*+aye«* = e"V(i). (A.6)

Integrating from 0 to t we have

y{t) = y{0)e--' + T e'^(--^)/(T)rfr, (A.7)


Jo
which is the complete solution (homogeneous solution plus particular
solution) to the equation.
A, 7. Reduction of Higher-Order to First-Order Linear Equations 369

A.7 Reduction of Higher-Order Linear


Equations t o Systems of First-Order
Linear Equations
Another way of solving equation (A.l) is to convert it into a system of
first-order linear equations. We use the transformations

zi = y, Z2 = y^^\...,zn = y^'' ^\ (A.8)

so that (A.l) can be written as

0 1 0 .. 0 zi 0

4 0 0 1 .. 0 ^2 0

+
0 0 0 .. 1 Zn-1 0

Z^ —dn -an- -1 -CLn- - 2 • ai Zn 9J


(A.9)
In vector form this equation reads

z' = Az + b (A.10)

with the obvious definitions obtained by comparing (A.9) and (A. 10).
We will present two ways of solving the first-order system (A. 10).
The first method involves the matrix exponential function e*"* defined
by the power series
/2 42
E A;!
(A.11)

It can be shown that this series converges (component by component)


for all values of t. Also it is differentiable (component by component)
for all values of t and satisfies

^(e*^) = Ae'^ = {e'^)A. (A.12)

By analogy with Section A.6, we try e^* as the integrating factor for
(A. 10) to obtain
370 A. Solutions of Linear Differential Equations

(Note that the order of matrix multiphcation here is important.) Using


the product rule for matrix multiphcation of fimctions, which can be
shown to be vahd, the above equation becomes

dV '
Integrating from 0 to i gives

TA
b{r)dT.
Jo
Evaluating and solving, we have

.-TA
z{t) = e'^z{0) + e'^ r b{T)dr, (A.13)
Jo
The analogy between this equation and (A.6) is clear.
Although (A.13) represents a formal expression for the solution of
(A. 10), it does not provide a computationally convenient way of getting
explicit solutions. In order to demonstrate such a method we assimie
that the matrix A is diagonalizable, i.e., that there exists a nonsingtilar
square matrix P such that

P-^AP = A. (A.14)

Here A is the diagonal matrix

Ai 0 ••• 0

0 A2 ••• 0
A = (A.15)

0 0 An

where the diagonal elements, A i , . . . , A^i, are eigenvalues of A, The ith


colunm of P is the column eigenvector associated with the eigenvalue A^
(to see this multiply both sides of (A.14) by P on the left). By looking
at (A.ll) it is easy to see that
p-l^tAp^^tA^ (A.16)

Suppose we make the following definitions:


z = Pw, z(0) = Pw{Q), z' = Pw\ (A.17)
A. 7. Reduction of Higher-Order to First-Order Linear Equations 371

These in turn imply

w = P-^Z, w{0) = P-h{0), w' = p-^z\ (A.18)

Substituting (A. 17) into (A. 10) gives

Pw' = APw + b,
vJ = p-^APw + p-^b,

which by using (A. 14) gives

w' = Aw + p-^b. (A.19)

Since A is a diagonal matrix, it is easy to solve the homogeneous part of


(A.19), which is
w' = Aw. (A.20)

The solution is

Wi = Wi{0)e~^^^ for i = 1,..., n.

We solve (A.19) completely by multiplying through by the integrating


factor e~*^:

^(e-'^w) = e'^w' - e-^^Aw = e'^^p-^b.


at

Integrating this equation from 0 to ^ gives

w{t) = e^^w(0) + e^^ f e-^^p-^b{T)dT. (A.21)


Jo
Using the substitutions (A.18) yields

z{t) = {Pe^^p-^)z{0) + Pe^^ f e-^^p-^b{r)dT, (A.22)


Jo

which is the formal solution to (A. 10). Since well-known algorithms are
available for finding eigenvalues and eigenvectors of a matrix, the solution
to (A.22) can be found in a straightforward manner.
372 A. Solutions of Linear Differential Equations

A.8 Solution of Linear Two-Point Boundary


Value Problems
In linear-quadratic control problems with linear salvage values (e.g., the
production-inventory problem in Section 6.1) we require the solution of
linear two-point boundary value problems of the form

X 11 An X hi
+ (A.23)
21 A22 A 62 J
with boundary conditions

a;(0) = XQ and A(T) = Ay. (A.24)

The solution of this system will be of the form (A.22), which can be
restated as

x{t) Quit) Quit) rr(O) Rx{t)


+ (A.25)
m Q2l{t) Q22{t)
. ^(°^ . Mt)
where the A(0) is a vector of unknowns. They can be determined by
setting
AT = Q2i{T)x{0) + Q22(T)A(0) + R^iT), (A.26)
which is a system of linear equations for the variables A(0).

A.9 Homogeneous Partial Differential


Equations
A homogeneous partial differential equation is an equation containing
one or more partial derivatives of an unknown function with respect to
its independent variables. If the highest partial derivative appearing ex-
plicitly in the equation has order n, then the partial differential equation
is said to be of order n.
As we saw in the previous sections, the general solutions of ordinary
differential equations involve expressions containing arbitrary constants.
Similarly, the solutions of partial differential equations are expressions
containing arbitrary (differentiable) functions. Conversely, when arbi-
trary fimctions can be eliminated algebraically from a given expression,
A.9, Homogeneous Partial Differential Equations 373

after suitable partial derivatives have been taken, then the result is a
partial differentiable equation.

Example A , l Eliminate the arbitrary function / from the expression


u = f{ax — by), where a and b are non-zero constants.

Solution. Taking partial derivatives, we have


Ux = af and Uy = —bf
so that
fru^ + auy = abf - abf = 0. (A.27)
Here u = f{ax — by) is a, solution for the equation bux + aUy = 0.
To show that any solution u = g{x, y) can be written in this form,
we set s = ax — by, and define
\s + by
G{s,y) = g .y = 9{^^y)'

Then, gx = Gs% = aGs and gy = G , ^ + Gy = -bGs + Gy.


Since we assume g solves the equation bux + aUy = 0, we have
Q = bgx- agy = abGg - abGs + aGy = 0, (A.28)
but this implies Gy = 0 so that G is a function oi s = ax — by only,
and hence g{x, y) = G{s) = G{ax — by) is of the required form. We
conclude that u = f(ax — by) is a general solution form for bux +auy = 0.

Example A.2 Eliminate the arbitrary fimctions / i and /2 from the


expression u = fi{x)f2{y).

Solution. Taking partial derivatives, we have

"^x = / i / 2 , Uy = /1/2, and Uxy = /I/2


so that
uuxy - UxUy = /i/2/{/2 - /i/2/1/2 = 0-
As in Example A.l we conclude that u = h{^)f2{y) is the general solu-
tion form of the equation uUxy — UxUy = 0.
The subject of partial differential equations is too vast to even sur-
vey here. However, Table A.7 gives general solution forms for all the
homogeneous partial differential equations we will consider in this book,
as well as others.
374 A. Solutions of Linear Differential Equations

Partial Differential General Solution Form

Ekjuation

(1) bux + auy = 0 u = f(ax — by)

(2) XUx + yUy = 0 , X y/^0 u = f{y/x)

(3) xux — yUy == 0 u = fi^y)


(4) Ux -\-Uy =^ au u = h{x- y)e^ + f2{x - y)e''y

(5) Uz-\-Uy = au^, k ^ 1 u^[{k-\){h{x-y)-ax)Y/^^-'^

^[k-l)h{x-y)-ay)Y^^^-')

(6) ^xx ^ yy — ^ u=:fi{y + ax) + hiy - ax)

(7) Uxx + CL^Uyy = 0 u = fi{y + iax) -\- f2(y- iax), i = y/^

(8) Uxy =0 u = fi(x) - f2(y)

(9) UUxy —UxUy =0 u= fi(x)f2(y)

(10) UUxy +UxUy=0 u= Mx)/f2{y)

(11) bcux + acuy + abuz = 0 u =: fi{ax - by) ^ f2(by - cz) + fsicz - ax)

(12) xUx + yuy 4- zuz = 0 u= fi(x/y)-\-f2{y/z)

(13) xUx — yUy -1- xuz = 0 u= fi(xy)-\-f2{yz)

(15) U^Uxyz — UxUyUz = 0 u= Mx)f2(y)f3(z)

(16) ^txy^ = 0 u=-fi{x)-\-f2iy)-\-f3{z)

(17) Uxx — 0^{Uyy 4 - Uzz) = 0 u = fi(y + ax) + f2{y - ax)-\- h{z + ax)

+f4{z-ax)

(18) Ux -\- Uy + Uz = au u = h{x- y)e^ + h{y- ^)e"^ + h{z - ^)e"' [

N o t e . The function fi are arbitrary differentiable functions of a single variable;


a, 6, c , . . . stand for arbitrary (non-zero) constants.

Table A.7: General Solution Forms for Some Homogeneous Partial


Differential Equations

A. 10 Inhomogeneous Partial Differential


Equations
As in the ordinary case, an inhomogeneous partial differential equation
is obtained from a homogeneous one by adding one or more forcing
A.iJ. Solutions of Finite Difference Equations 375

functions. The general case of this problem is too difficult to treat here.
We consider only the case in which the forcing functions are separable,
i.e., can be written as a sum of functions each involving only one of the
independent variables. In solving such problems we can make use of the
solutions to ordinary differential equations considered earlier.

Example A.3 Solve the partial differential equation

Ux + Uy = 3x + e^.

Solution. We know from the previous section that the general solution
to the homogeneous equation is of the form f{x—y). To get the particular
solutions we solve separately the ordinary equations

Ux = Sx^ and Uy = e^^

obtaining solutions x^ and e^. Therefore, the general solution to the


original equation is
u = f{x-y)+x^ + e^.
Generally speaking, the above philosophy of finding particular solu-
tions to separable partial differential equations (when it works) follows
the same method of "dividing and conquering." Other methods involve
the use of series. We will not go further here for lack of space.

A. 11 Solutions of Finite Difference Equations


In this book we will have uses for finite difference equations only in
Chapters 8 and 9. For that reason we will give only a brief introduction
to solution techniques for them. Readers who wish more details can
consult one of several texts on difference equations; see, e.g., Goldberg
(1986) or Spiegel (1971).
If f{k) is a real function of time, then the difference operator applied
to / is defined as

A/(fc) = /(fc + l ) - / ( f c ) . (A.29)


The factorial power of k is defined as

A;(") = k{k - l)ik -2)...{k-{n- 1)). (A.30)


It is easy to show that
Aifc("> = nfc("-i). (A.31)
376 A. Solutions of Linear Differential Equations

Because this formula is similar to the corresponding formula for the


derivative d{k'^)/dk^ the factorial powers of k play an analogous role
for finite differences that the ordinary powers of k play for differential
calculus.
K /(fc) is a real function of time, then the anti-difference operator
A~-^ applied to / is defined as another fimction g — A~^f{k) with the
property that

A^ = f(k). (A.32)
One can easily show that

A-ifcW - ( l / ( n + l))fc(^+i) + c, (A.33)


where c is an arbitrary constant. Equation (A.33) corresponds to the
integration formula for powers of k in calculus.
Note that formulas (A.31) and (A.33) are similar to, respectively,
differentiation and integration of the power function k"^ in calculus. By
analogy with calculus, therefore, we can solve difference equations in-
volving polynomials in ordinary powers of k by first rewriting them as
polynomials involving factorial powers of k so that (A.31) and (A.33)
can be used. We show next how to do this.

A . 11.1 C h a n g i n g P o l y n o m i a l s in P o w e r s of k into Facto-


rial P o w e r s of k
We first give an abbreviated list of formulas that show how to change
powers of k into factorial powers of k:
fcO =fc(o)= 1 (by definition),
k'=k('\

fc4 = fc(i)+7/c(2)+6fc(3)+fcW,
k^ = fc(i) + 15fc(2) + 25fc(^) + lOfcW + fc(^).

The coefficients of the factorial powers on the right-hand sides of these


equations are called Stirling numbers of the second kind, after the
person who first derived them. This list can be extended by using a
A,ll. Solutions of Finite Difference Equations 377

more complete table of these nimibers, which can be found in books on


difference equations cited earlier.

Example A.4 Express A;^ — 3fc + 4 in terms of factorial powers.

Solution. Using the equations above we have

k^ = fed) + 7fc(2) + 6fc(3) + fcW, -3k = -3fc(i), 4 = 4,

SO that

Example A.5 Solve the following difference equation in Example 8.7:

AA^ = -k + 6,X^ = 0.

Solution. We first change the right-hand side into factorial powers so


that it becomes
AA^ = -fc(^) + 5.
Applying (A.33), we obtain

A^ = -(l/2)fc(2) + 5fcW + c,

where c is a constant. Applying the condition A^ = 0, we find that


c= —15, so that the solution is

A^ = -(l/2)fc(2) + 5fc(^) - 15. (A.34)


However, we would like the answer to be in ordinary powers of fc.
The way to do that is discussed in the next section.

A . 11.2 C h a n g i n g Factorial P o w e r s of k i n t o Ordinary


P o w e r s of k
In order to change factorial powers of k into ordinary powers of fc, we
make use of the following formulas:
fc(i) = k,
ki'^) = ^k + k\
fc(3) = 2k- 3A;2 + k^,
k^^) = -6k + llfc2 _ 6^3 ^ ^4^
378 A. Solutions of Linear Difkrential Equations

fc(5) = 24k - 50A;2 + 35k^ - lOJt^ + k^.

The coefficients of the factorial powers on the right-hand sides of these


equations are called Stirling numbers of the first kind. This list can also
be extended by using a more complete table of these nimibers, which
can be found in books on difference equations.

Solution of Example A.5 Continued. By substituting the first two


of the above formulas into (A.34), we see that the desired answer is

A'^ = -(1/2)A;2 + (n/2)k - 15, (A.35)


which is the solution needed for Example 8.7.

EXERCISES FOR A P P E N D I X A

3 2 5 0 1 1
A . l If ^ = show that A andF =
2 3 0 2 1 -1

Use (A.22) to solve (A. 10) for this data, given that ^(O) =

3 3 6 0 1 3
A.2 If A , show that A = andP =
2 4 0 1 1 -2

0
Use (A.22) to solve (A. 10) for this data, given that z{0) =
5

A . 3 After you have read Section 6.1, re-solve the production-inventory


example stated in equations (6.1) and (6.2), (ignoring the control
constraint ( P > 0) by the method of Section A.8. The linear
two-point boundary value problem is stated in equations (6.6) and
(6.7).
Appendix B

Calculus of Variations and


Optimal Control Theory

Here we introduce the subject of the calculus oi variations by analogy


with the classical topic of maximization and miniiir:zation in calculus;
see Gelfand and Fomin (1963), Young (1969), and Leitmann (1981) for
rigorous treatments of the subject. The problem of the calculus of varia-
tions is that of determining a function that maximizes a given functional,
the objective fimction. An analogous problem in calculus is that of de-
termining a point at which a specific function, the objective function, is
maximum. This, of course, is done by taking the first derivative of the
function and equating it to zero. This is what is called the first-order
condition for a maximum. A similar procedure will be employed to de-
rive the first-order condition for the variational problem. The analogy
with classical optimization extends also to the second-order maximiza.-
tion condition of calculus. Finally, we will show the relationship between
the maximum principle of optimal control theory and the necessary con-
ditions of the calculus of variations. It is noted that this relationship is
similar to the one between the Kuhn-Tucker conditions in mathematical
programming and the first-order conditions in classical optimization.
We start with the "simplest" variational problem in the next section.

B.l The Simplest Variational Problem


Assume a function x : C-^[0^t] —> E^, where C^[O^T] is a class of func-
tions defined over the interval [0,T] with continuous first derivatives.
(For simplicity in exposition, assimie x to be a scalar fimction. The
380 B. Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory

extension to a vector function is straightforward.) Assume further that


a function in this class is termed admissible if it satisfies the terminal
conditions
x{0) = xo and x{T) = XT- (B.l)
We are thus dealing with a fixed-end-point problem. Examples of admis-
sible functions for the problem are shown in Figure B.l; see Section 6 and
Chapters 2 and 3 of Gelfand and Fomin (1963) for problems other than
the simplest problem, i.e., the problems with other kinds of conditions
for the end points.

0 T

Figure B.l: Examples of Admissible Functions for the Problem

The problem under consideration is to obtain the admissible function


X* for which the fimctional
fT
J{x) = / g{x^x^t)dt (B.2)
Jo
has a relative maximum. We will assume that all first and second partial
derivatives of the function g : E^ x E^ x E^ —^ E^ are continuous.

B.2 The Euler Equation


The necessary first-order conditions in classical optimization were ob-
tained by considering small changes about the solution point. For the
B.2, The Euler Equation 381

variational problem, we consider small variations about the solution func-


tion. Let x{t) be the solution and let
y{t)=x{t) + sri{t),
where T]{t) : C^[0,T] —» E^ is an arbitrary continuously differentiable
function satisfying
r){0) = r,{T) = 0, (B.3)
and £ > 0 is a small number. A sketch of these functions is shown in
Figure B.2.

Figure B.2: Variation about the Solution Function

The value of the objective functional associated with y{t) can be


considered a fimction of s, i.e.,
fT
V{e) = J{y) = g{x + erj, x + ef],, t)dt
Jo
However, x(t) is a solution and therefore V{e) must have a maximum at
£ = 0. This means
A dV\
-0,
de e=Q
where 8J is known as the variation 8J in J. Differentiating V{e) with
respect to e and setting e — Q yields

8J = = / {9xV + 9xf])dt = 0,
de =0 ^0
382 B. Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory

which after integrating the second term by parts provides

«5^ = - ^ 1 = j ^ 9xVdt + {9iv)\o - I Jt^9i)vdt = 0. (B.4)

Because of the end conditions on 77, the expression simplifies to

= [9x- •:^9x]vdt = 0.
de zzo Jo dt
We now use the fundamental lemma of the calculus of variations
which states that if /i is a continuous fimction and /Q h(t)rj{t)dt = 0 for
every continuous function r]{t)^ then h{t) — 0 for all t G [0, T]. The reason
that this lemma holds, without going into details of a rigorous proof
which is available in Gelfand and Fomin (1963), is as follows. Suppose
that h(t) ^ 0 for some t G [0,T]. Since h{t) is continuous, there is,
therefore, an interval (^1, ^2) C [0, T] over which h is nonzero and has the
same sign. Now selecting r/(t) such

>0, te{ti,t2)
r]{t) is <
0, otherwise,

it is possible to make the integral /Q h(t)r){t)dt 7^ 0. Thus, by contrar-


diction, h{t) must be identically zero over the entire interval [0,T].
By using the fimdamental lemma, we have the necessary condition

9x - -Tjgx = 0 (B.5)

known as the Euler equation, which must be satisfied by a maximal


solution X*,
We note that the Euler equation is a second-order ordinary differen-
tial equation. This can be seen by taking the total time derivative of QX
and collecting terms:

^9xx + i^9xx + {9tx - 9x) = 0.

The boimdary conditions for this equation are obviously the end-point
conditions x{0) = XQ and x{T) = x^-
B.3. The Shortest Distance Between Two Points on the Plane 383

Special Case (i) When g does not depend explicitly on x.

In this case, the Enler equation (B.5) reduces to

which is nothing but the first-order condition of classical optimization.


In this case, the dynamic problem is a succession of static classical
optimization problems.

Special Case (ii) When g does not depend explicitly on x.

The Euler equation reduces to

j^9^ = 0, (B.6)

which we can integrate as

gx = constant. (B.7)

Special Case (iii) When g does not depend explicitly on t,

Finally, we have the important special case in which g is explicitly


independent of t. In this case, we write the Euler equation (B.5) as

j^{9-i9x)-9t = 0. (B.8)

But gt = 0 and therefore we can solve the above equation as

g-xgx = C, (B.9)

where C is the constant of the integration.

B.3 The Shortest Distance Between Two Points


on the Plane
The problem is to show that the straight line passing through two points
on a plane is the shortest distance between the two points. The problem
384 B. Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory

can be stated as follows:

imn
Jo
subject to

x(0) = xo and x{T) = XT-

Here t refers to distance rather than time. Since g = — v T + ^ does not


depend explicitly on x^ we are in the second special case and the first
integral (B.7) of the Euler equation is

This implies that i is a constant, which results in the solution

x{t) = Cit + C2,

where Ci and C2 are constants. These can be evaluated by imposing


boimdary conditions which give Ci — {XT — xo)/T and C2 = XQ. Thus,

XT-XQ
x{t) = t + Xo,
T
which is the straight line passing through XQ and XT-

B.4 The Brachistochrone Problem


The problem arises from the search for the shape of a wire along which
a bead will slide in the least time from a given point to another, imder
the influence of gravity; see Figure 1.1.
The Brachistochrone problem has a long history. It was first studied
(incorrectly) by Galileo in 1630. The problem was correctly posed by
Johann Bernoulli in 1696 and later solved by Johann Bernoulli, Jacob
Bernoulli, Newton, and L'Hospital. Note that Euler deduced the Euler's
equation in 1744, and we will solve the Brachistochrone problem using
Euler's equation. But first we must formulate the problem.
Assimie the bead slides with no friction. Let m denote the mass of the
bead, s denote the arc length, t denote the horizontal axis, x denote the
vertical axis (measured vertically down), and r denote the time. Assimie
^0 = 0, rr(io) = 0, T - l , x{T) = l.
B.4. The Brachistochrone Problem 385

We wish to minimize
^^ ds
Jo Jo V
where v represents velocity, and ST is the final displacement measured
on the curve. We can write

ds = \ / l + x'^dt

and, from elementary physics, it is known that if v{to = 0) — 0 and a


denotes the gravitational acceleration constant, then

v = V2^ax,

Therefore, the variational problem can be stated as

, 1 f'/*! h 1+x^
min^TT- / \l—- dt
\2aJo V X

where x = dx/dt (note that t does not denote time), and x(0) = 0 and
x{l) = 1. Since a is a constant, we can rewrite the problem as

mm J{x) = / g(x^x,t)dt= / \ dt> .

Since g does not depend explicitly on f, the problem belongs to the third
special case. Using the first integral (B.9) of the Euler equation for this
case, we have
1/2
i;2[x(l+i2)]-i/2 1+x^ = Ci (a constant).
X

We can reduce this to


dx
dt y xCf
To solve this equation, we separate the variables as

•^xdx
dt
^ l ""x
386 B. Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory

and substitute

X = (sin^ e)/Cl = (1 - cos 26)/Cl (B.IO)

The resulting expression can be integrated to yield

t=[e- (1/2) sm2e]/Cf + C2. (B.ll)

The condition ^ = 0 at ^ = 0 implies C2 = 0 providing Cf > 0. The


value of Cl can be obtained in terms of the value of 6 at t = 1; let this
be 9i. Then, since a; = 1 at ^ = 1, we have Ci = sin 6, where Oi satisfies

26>i - - I = sin20i-cos26>i.

This equation must be solved nimierically. An iterative numerical pro-


cedure yields 0i = 1.206 and therefore Cf = 0.873. Defining 0 = 26, we
can write (B.IO) and (B.ll) as

X = 0.573(1-cos 20),
t = 0.573(0-sin0),

which are equations of a cycloid in the parametric form. The shape of


the curve is shown in Figure 1.1 in Chapter 1.

B.5 The Weierstrass-Erdmann Corner


Conditions
So far we have only considered functionals defined for smooth curves.
This is, however, a restricted class of curves which qualify as solutions,
since it is easy to give examples of variational problems which have no
solution in this class. Consider, for example, the objective functional

min h{x) = I x'^il - xfdt\ , x ( - l ) = 0, x{l) = 1.

The greatest lower bound for J(x) for smooth x = x{t) satisfying the
boimdary conditions is obviously zero. Yet there is no x € C-^[—1,1]
with x(—l) = 0 and x{l) = 1, which achieves this value of J(x). In fact,
the minimum is achieved for the curve

0, - 1 < < < 0,


x(t)
t, 0<t<l,
B.5. The Weierstrass-Erdmann Corner Conditions 387

which has a comer (i.e., a discontinuous first derivative) at t = 0, Such


a piecewise smooth extremal with corners is called a broken extremal
We now enlarge the class of admissible functions by relaxing the
requirement that they be smooth everywhere. The larger class is the class
of piecewise continuous functions which are continuously differentiable
almost everywhere in [0,r], i.e., except at some points in [0, T].
Let x{t) be an extremal with a corner at r G [0, T]. Let us decompose
J{x) as
rT PT PT
J{x) = / g{x,x^t)dt= / g{x,x,t)dt+ / g{x^x,t)dt
Jo Jo JT
= Ji{x)+J2{x),
It is clear that on each of the intervals [0, r) and {r^T], the Euler equation
must hold.
To compute variations SJi and SJ2, we must recognize that the two
'pieces' oi x are not fixed-end-point problems. We must require that the
two pieces of x join continuously at ^ = r; the point t = T can, however,
move freely as shown in Figure B.3.

Figure B.3: A Broken Extremal with Corner at r

This will require a slightly modified version of formula (B.4) for writ-
ing out the variations; see pp. 55-56 in Gelfand and Fomin (1963). Equat-
ing the sum of variations
SJ = SJi +SJ2 = 0
388 B. Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory

for x{t) to be an extremal and using the fact that x{t) must be continuous
at t = r imphes
g^l^- = g^l^^ , (B.12)
[9 - igxlr- = [9- i9x]T+' (B.13)
These conditions are called Weierstrass-Erdmann corner conditions,
which must hold at the point r where the extremal has a corner.
In each of the interval [0, r ) and (r, t], the extremal x must satisfy the
Euler equation (B.5). Solving these two equations will provide us with
four constants of integration since the Euler equations are second-order
differential equations. These constants can be foiind from the end-point
conditions (B.l) and Weierstrass-Erdmann conditions (B.12) and (B.13).

B.6 Legendre's Conditions: The Second


Variation
The Euler equation is a necessary conditions analogous to the first-order
condition for a maximum (or minimimi) in the classical optimization
problems of calculus. The condition analogous to the second-order nec-
essary condition for a maximum is the Legendre condition

9xx < 0. (B.14)

To obtain this condition, we use the second-order condition of classical


optimization on function V(e) to be a maximum at e = 0, i.e.,

d^V{e) PT
/ {9xxrj^ + '^gxxm + 9xxf]^)dt < 0. (B.15)
de'^ JO
e=0

Integrating the middle term by parts and using (B.3), we can transform
(B.15) into a more convenient form

/ {Qri^ + Pfi^)dt<Q, (B.16)


Jo
where
Q = Q{t) = 9xx --^9xx and P = P{t) =^ g^j^.

While it is possible to rigorously obtain (B.14) from (B.16), we will


only provide a qualitative argument for this. If we consider the quadratic
functional (B.16) for functions r]{t) satisfying 77(0) = 0, then r]{t) will be
B.7, Necessary Condition for a Strong Maximum 389

small in [0, T] if f]{t) is small in [0, T], The converse is not true, however,
since it is easy to construct r]{t) which is small but has a large derivative
7]{t) in [0,r]. Thus, Pfj^ plays the dominant role in (B.16); i.e., Pif
can be much larger than Qrf but it cannot be much smaller (provided
P 7^ 0). Therefore, it might be expected that the sign of the fimctional
in (B.6) is determined by the sign of the coefficient P(t), i.e., (B.16)
implies (B.14). For a rigorous proof, see Gelfand and Fomin (1963).
We note that the strengthened Legendre condition (i.e., with a strict
inequahty in (B.14)), the Euler equation, and one other condition called
strengthened Jacobi condition are sufficient for a maximum. The reader
can consult Chapter 5 of Gelfand and Fomin (1963) for details.

B.7 Necessary Condition for a Strong


Maximum
So far we have discussed necessary conditions for a weak maximum. By
weak maximum we mean that the candidate extremals are smooth or
piecewise smooth functions. The concept of a strong m>axim.um, on the
other hand requires that the candidate extremal need only be continuous
functions. Without going into details, which are available in Gelfand and
Fomin (1963), we state a necessary condition for a strong maximum. This
is called the Weierstrass necessary condition. The condition is analogous
to the one in the static case that the objective function be concave. It
states that if the fimctional (B.2) has a strong maximum for the extremal
7 satisfying (B.l), then
E{x,x,t,v) <0 (B.17)
along 7 for every finite v, where E is the Weierstrass Excess Function
defined as
E{x^ i , t, v) = g{x^ v^ t) — g{x^ i , t) — gxi^i ^, t){'^ — x), (B.18)
Note that this condition is always met if g{x^x^t) is concave in x.
The proof of (B.17) is by contradiction. Suppose there exists a r G
[0, T] and a vector q such that
E{T,x{T),x{T),q) >0,
where x = x(t) is the equation of the extremal 7. It is then possible to
suitably modify 7 to /? which is close to 7 in C^[0,T] such that

^J — I g{x^x^t)dt— / g{x^x^t)dt > 0,


JB J-i
390 B. Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory

contradicting the hypothesis that J{x) has a strong maximum for 7.

B.8 Relation to the Optimal Control Theory


It is possible to derive the necessary conditions of the calculus of varia-
tions from the maximum principle. This is strongly reminiscent of the
relationship between the first-order conditions of classical optimization
and the Kuhn-Tucker conditions of mathematical progranmiing.
First, we note that the calculus of variations problem can be stated
as an optimal control problem as follows:

max J—j g{x,u^t)dt >

subject to

X = n, x(0) = xo, x(T) = XT^

The Hamiltonian is

H(x^ u^ A, t) = g(x^ u, t) + Xu (B.19)

with the adjoint variable A satisfying

A = —Hx = —Qx- (B.20)

Maximizing the Hamiltonian with respect to u yields

Hu = 9x + ^=> ^ = -Qx- (B.21)

Differentiating with respect to time, we have

d
A
dt 9x'
This equation with (B.20) implies

9x - ^9x = 0,

which is the Euler equation of the calculus of variations.


B.8, Relation to the Optimal Control Theory 391

The second-order condition for the maximization of the Hamiltonian,


i.e.,
Huu < 0 => pi;i < 0,
which is the Legendre condition.
Again, by the maximum principle, if u is an optimal control, then

H{x,t,X,t) >H{x,v,\t),

where v is any other control. By the definition of the Hamiltonian (B.19)


and equation (B.21), we have

g{x, i , t) - QxX > g(x, v, t) - g±v,

which by transposition of terms yields the Weierstrass necessary condi-


tion
E(x^ ir, i, v) = g{x^ v^ t) — g(x^ i , t) — gx{v — i ) < 0.
We have just proved the equivalence of the maximum principle and
the Weierstrass necessary condition in the case where Q is open. In cases
when O is closed and when the optimal control is on the boundary of f2,
the Weierstrass necessary condition is no longer valid, in general. The
maximum principle still applies, however.
Finally, according to the maximum principle, both A and H are con-
tinuous functions of time. However,

A == -gx and H = g - g±x,

which means that the right-hand sides must be continuous with respect to
time, i.e., even across corners. These are precisely Weierstrass-Erdmann
corner conditions.
Appendix C

An Alternative Derivation
of the Maximum Principle

Recall that in the derivation of the maximum principle in Chapter 2, we


assumed the twice differentiability of the return function V, Looking at
(2.32), we can observe that the smoothness assumptions on the return
function do not arise in the statement of the maximum principle. Also
since it is not an exogenously given fimction, there is no a priori reason to
assume the twice differentiabihty. In many important cases as a matter
of fact, V has no derivatives at individual points, e.g., at points on
switching manifolds.
In what foUows, we wiU give an alternate derivation. This proof fol-
lows the course pointed out by Pontryagin et al. (1962) but with certain
simplifications. It appears in Fel'dbaum (1965) and, in our opinion, it
is one of the simplest proofs for the maximiim principle which is not
related to dynamic programming and thus permits the elimination of
assumptions about the differentiability of the return fimction V(t, x),
We select the Mayer form of the problem (2.5) for deriving the max-
imum principle in this section. It will be convenient to reproduce (2.5)
here as (C.l):

max {J = cx(T)}
u{t)en{t)

subject to
(C.l)
X = f{x,U,t), x{0) =Xo,
394 C. An Alternative Derivation of the Maximum Principle

C.l Needle-Shaped Variation

Let u*{t) be an optimal control with corresponding state trajectory x*{t).


We sketch u*{t) in Figure C.l and x*{t) in Figure C.2 in a scalar case.
Note that the kink in x*{t) aX t = 9 corresponds to the discontinuity in
u*{t) 8itt = e.

•-> t
6 T-8 T T

Figure C.l: Needle-Shaped Variation

Let r denote any time in the open interval ( 0 , r ) . We select a suffi-


ciently small e to insure that r — e > 0 and concentrate our attention on
this small interval (r — e^r]. We vary the control on this interval while
keeping the control on the remaining intervals [0, r — s] and (r, T] fixed.
Specifically, the modified control is

^-> t
0 T-s T r

Figure C.2: Trajectories x*{t) and x(t) in a One-Dimensional Case.


C.l. Needle-Shaped Variation 395

V eft, t e (r — s,r],
u{t) = I (C.2)
u*{t), otherwise.
This is called a needle-shaped YSuYiaXion as shown in Figure C.l. It
is a jump function and is different from variations in the calculus of
variations (see Appendix B). Also the difference v —u* is finite and need
not be small. However, since the variation is on a small time interval, its
influence on the subsequent state trajectory can be proved to be 'small'.
This is done in the following.
Let the subsequent motion be denoted by x{t) ^ x*{t) for t > r — s,
In Figure 0.2, we have sketched x{t) corresponding to u{t).
Let
6x{t) = x{t) - a;*(i), t>T-e,
denote the change in the state variables. Obviously 6X{T — S) = 0.
Clearly,
Sx{T)^e[x{s)-x\s)], (C.3)
where s denotes some intermediate time in the interval (r — e^r]. In
particular, we can write (C.3) as

6x{r) = 4H^) - ^*('^)] + ^(^)


= ^[/(x(r),^,r) - / ( x * ( r ) , u * ( r ) , r ] + o(s). (C.4)

But Sx{r) is small since / is assumed to be boimded. Furthermore, since


/ is continuous and the difference 6X{T) = X(T) — X*{T) is small, we can
rewrite (C.4) as

6x{t) « e[f{x*{T),v,T)-f{x*{r),u*iT),T)]. (C.5)

Since the initial difference SX(T) is small and since U*{T) does not change
from t > T on, we may conclude that Sx{t) will be small for aU t > r .
Being small, the law of variation of Sx{t) can be foimd from linear equa-
tions for small changes in the state variables. These are called variational
equations. From the state equation in (C.l), we have

^^El^M. = f(a:* + Sx,u*,t) (C.6)

or,
^ + ^^fix\u*,t)+fjx (C.7)
396 C. An Alternative Derivation of the Maximum Principle

or using (C.l),

-r{Sx) ^ U{x\ u*, t)6x, for t > r, (C.8)


tit/

with the initial condition 6X{T) given by (C.5).


The basic idea in deriving the maximum principle is that equations
(C.8) are linear variational equations and result in an extraordinary sim-
plification. We next obtain the adjoint equations.

C.2 Derivation of the Adjoint Equation and the


Maximum Principle
For this derivation, we employ two methods. The direct method, similar
to that of Hartberger (1973), is the consequence of directly integrating
(C.8). The indirect method avoids this integration by a trick which is
instructive.

Direct method. Integrating (C.8) we get

6x{T) = 6x{r)+ f f^[x\t),u\t),t\8x{t)dt, (C.9)

where the initial condition 6X{T) is given in (C.5).


Since 8x{T) is the change in the terminal state from the optimal state
x*(r), the change in the objective function 6J must be negative. Thus,

8J = c8x{T) = C8X{T) + f cfx[x%t),u*{t),t\8x{t)dt < 0. (CIO)

Furthermore, since (C.8) is a linear homogeneous differential equation,


we can write its general solution as

8x{t) = ^t,T)8x{T), (C.ll)

where the fundamental solution matrix or the transition matrix $(t, r ) G

^$(^,r) = Ux%t),u*m^t,r), ^T,T) ^ I, (C.12)

where / is an n x n identity matrix; see Appendix A.


C.2. Derivation of Adjoint Equation and the Maximum Principle 397

Substituting for 6x{t) from (C.ll) into (C.IO), we have

6J = C6X{T) + / cfa,[x*{t), u\t), t]^{t, T)8x{T)dt < 0. (C.13)

This induces the definition

X*(t) = J cf4x'{t),u*{t),t]^t,r)dt + c, (C.14)

which when substituted into (C.13), yields

SJ=^X*{T)SX{T)<0, (C.15)

But Sx{r) is supphed in (C.5). Noting that £ > 0, we can rewrite (C.15)
as
X*{T)f[x*(T),v,T]-X*(r)f[x*iT),u*iT),T]<0. (C.16)
Defining the Hamiltonian for the Mayer form as

H[x, u, A, t] = A/(x, u, t), (C.17)

we can rewrite (C.16) as

if[:r*(r),u*(r),A(r),r] >ff[ar*(r),t;,A(r),r]. (C.18)

Since this can be done for almost every r, we have the required Hamil-
tonian maximizing condition.
The differential equation form of the adjoint equation (C.14) can be
obtained by taking its derivative with respect to r. Thus,

-C/X[X'(T),M'(T),T]. (0.19)

It is also known that the transition matrix has the property:

^ ^ ^ = -$(i,r)/,[x*(r),«*(r),T],

which can be used in (C.19) to obtain

rfA(r) rT
^^ - j cU[x*{t),u*{t),t]^{t,T)U[x*{Tlu*{r),T]dt
-cU[x*{T)X{r),T]. (C.20)
398 C. An Alternative Derivation of the Maximum Principle

Using the definition (C.14) of A(r) in (C.20), we have

^ = -A(r)/,[x*(r),«*(r),r]

with A(T) = c, or using (C.17) and noting that r is arbitrary, we have

A = -A/^[x*,n*,t] = -H^[x*,u\\t), X(T) = c. (C.21)

This completes the derivation of the maximum principle along with the
adjoint equation using the direct method.

Indirect method. The indirect method employs a trick which simplifies


considerably the derivation. Instead of integrating (C.8) explicitly, we
now assume that the result of this integration yields cSx{T) as the change
in the state at the terminal time. As in (C.IO), we have

6J = c6x{T) < 0. (C.22)

First, we define
A(r) = c, (C.23)
which makes it possible to write (C.22) as

SJ - c6x{T) = X{T)6x(T) < 0. (C.24)

Note parenthetically that if the objective fimction J = S{x{T)), we must


define A(r) = dS[x{T)]/dx{T) giving us

*^ = ^i^^^(^) = A(r)6^(T).
Now, X(T)Sx{T) is the change in the objective fimction due to a
change Sx{T) at the terminal time T. That is, A(T) is the marginal
return or the marginal change in the objective function per unit change
in the state at time T. But Sx{T) cannot be known without integrating
(C.8). We do know, however, the value of the change SX{T) at time r
which caused the terminal change Sx(T) via (C.8).
We would therefore like to pose the problem of obtaining the change
6J in the objective function in terms of the known value SX{T); see
FeFdbaimi (1965). Simply stated, we would like to obtain the marginal
return A(r) per unit change in state at time r . Thus,

X{T)SX{T) = 6J = X{T)SX{T) < 0. (C.25)


C,2. Derivation of Adjoint Equation and the Maximum Principle 399

Obviously, knowing A(r) will make it possible to make an inference about


SJ which is directly related to the needle-shaped variation applied in the
small interval (r — e^r],
However, since r is arbitrary, our problem of finding A(r) can be
translated to one of finding A(t), t G [0,r], such that

X{t)6x{t) = \{T)6x{T), t e [0,T], (C.26)

or in other words,

X(t)Sx{t) = constant, A(r) = c. (C.27)

It turns out that the differential equation which X{t) must satisfy can
be easily foimd. From (C.27),

^^[X(t)Sx{t)] = A ^ + XSx = 0, (C.28)

which after substituting for dSx/dt from (C.8) becomes

Xfjx + X6x = (A/^ + X)Sx = 0. (C.29)

Since (C.29) is true for arbitrary 6x, we have

A = -XU = -Ha: (C.30)

using the definition (C.17) for the Hamiltonian.


The Hamiltonian maximizing condition can be obtained by substi-
tuting for 6x{r) from (C.5) into (C.25). This is the same as what we did
in (C.15) through (C.18).
The purpose of the alternative proof was to demonstrate the valid-
ity of the maximum principle for a simple problem without knowledge
of any return function. For more complex problems, one needs compli-
cated mathematical analysis to rigorously prove the maximum principle
without making use of return fimctions. A part of mathematical rigor is
in proving the existence of an optimal solution without which necessary
conditions are meaningless; see Young (1969).
Appendix D

Special Topics in Optimal


Control

In this appendix we will discuss three specialized topics. These are linear-
quadratic problems, second-order variations, and singular control. These
topics are referred to but not discussed in the main body of the text
because of their advanced nature. While we shall not be able to go into
a great detail, we will provide an adequate description of these topics
and list relevant references.

D.l Linear-Quadratic Problems


An important problem in systems theory, especially engineering sciences,
is to synthesize feedback controllers. These controllers provide optimal
control as a function of the state of the system. A usual method of ob-
taining these controllers is to solve the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman partial
differential equation (2.19). This equation is nonlinear in general, which
makes it very difficult to solve in closed form. Thus, it is not possible in
most cases to obtain optimal feedback control schemes explicitly.
It is, however, feasible in many cases to obtain perturbation feedback
control, which refers to control in the vicinity of an optimal path; see
Bryson and Ho (1969). These perturbation schemes reqiiire the approx-
imation of the problem by a linear-quadratic problem in the vicinity of
an optimal path (see Section D.2), and feedback control for the approx-
imating problem is easy to obtain.
A linear-quadratic control problem is a problem with Unear dynamics
402 D, Special Topics in Optimal Control

and quadratic objective function. More specifically, it is:

max I J = -x'^Gx + - I {x^Cx + u^Du)dt I (D.l)


u

subject to
x = Ax + Bu, x{Q) =- XQ. (D.2)

The matrices G, C, D, A, and B are in general time dependent. Fur-


thermore, the matrices G, (7, and D are assumed to be negative definite
and the superscript ^ denotes the transpose operation. Note that this
problem is a special case of Row (c) of Table 3.3.
To solve this problem for the explicit feedback controller, we write
the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation (2.19) as

0 = max[if + Vt] = max I - - ( a : ^ C x + u^Du) + V^\Ax + Bu\ -\-v\


(D.3)
with the terminal boundary condition

V{x,T) = \x^Gx. (D.4)

The maximization of the maximand in (D.3) can be carried out by taking


its derivative with respect to u and setting it to zero. Thus,

^M^ = ^ = (^Duf + V,B = 0=^u' = -V,B{D^)-\ (D.5)


au ou
Note that (D.5) is the same as the Hamiltonian maximizing condition.
Substituting (D.5) in (D.3) and simplifying, we obtain

0 = ^x^Cx + V^Ax - ^V^BD-^B^V^. (D.6)

This is a nonlinear partial differential equation of first order and it


has a solution of the form

V{x,t) = lx'^S{t)x. (D.7)

Substitution of (D.7) into (D.6) yields

0 = \x^\S + 5A + ^S - SBD-^B^S + C\x. (D.8)


D.l, Linear-Quadratic Problems 403

Since (D.8) must hold for all x, it implies the following matrix differential
equation
S + SA + A^S - SBD'^B^S + C = 0, (D.9)
called a matrix Riccati equation, with the boundary condition

S(T) = G. (D.IO)

A solution procedure for Riccati equations appears in Bryson and Ho


(1969). Once we have the solution S(t) of (D.9) and (D.IO), the optimal
feedback control can be written as

u\t) = D{t)-^B' {t)S{t)x{t), (D.ll)

A generaUzation of (D.l), which would be useful in the next section


on the second variation, is to set

1 T C N X
J = -x^ Gx + dt. (D.12)
jf'^^"^) N^ D u

The state equation is given by (D.2). It is possible to derive the optimal


control for this problem as

u*{t) = Dity^iN'^it) + B'^{t)S{t)]x{t), (D.13)

where

S+SA+A^S-{SB+N)D-^(B^S+N^)+C = 0, S{T) = G. (D.14)

For other variations and extensions of the linear-quadratic problem


(D.l) and (D.2), for which explicit feedback controllers can be developed,
the reader is referred to Bryson and Ho (1969).

D.1.1 C e r t a i n t y Equivalence or S e p a r a t i o n Principle


Suppose equation (D.2) is changed by the presence of a Gaussian white
noise w{t) and becomes

X = Ax + Bu + w,

where
E[w{t)] = 0, E[w{t)w{Tf] = Q{t)6{t - r ) ,
404 D. Special Topics in Optimal Control

and x{0) is a normal random variable with

E[x{0)] = 0, E[x{0)x{Of] = Po.

Because of the presence of uncertainty in the system equation, we must


modify the objective fimction in (D.12) as follows:

( \
C N ' X
max < J = E ^x'^Gx + ^{x^,u^) dt\
iV^ D ^ [u]
Assume further that x cannot be directly measured and the measure-
ment process is given by (13.21), i.e.,

y{t) = H{t)x{t)+v{t),

where v{t) is a white noise as defined in (12.72).


The optimal control u* (t) for this linear-quadratic stochastic optimal
control problem can be shown to be given by (D.13) with x{t) replaced
by its estimate x{t); see Bryson and Ho (1969). Thus,

n*(t) - D{t)-^[N^{t) + B^it)S{t)]x{t),

where S is given in (D.14) and x is given by the Kalman-Bucy filter.

'x = Ax + Bu*+w + K[y-Hx], :r(0) = 0,


K - PH^R-\
P = AP + PA^ -KHP + Q, P{0)^Po,

The above procedure has received two different names in the liter-
ature. In economics it is called the certainty equivalence principle; see
Simon (1956). In engineering and mathematics literature it is called the
separation principle, Joseph and Tou (1961). When we call it the cer-
tainty equivalence principle, we are emphasizing the fact that x(t) can be
used for the purposes of optimal feedback control as if it were the certain
value of the state variable x{t). Whereas the term separation principle
emphasizes the fact that the process of determining the optimal control
can be broken down into two steps: first, estimate x by using the optimal
filter; second, use that estimate in the optimal feedback control formula
for the deterministic problem.
D,2. Second-Order Variations 405

D.2 Second-Order Variations


Second-order variations in optimal control theory are analogous to the
second-order conditions in the classical optimization problem of calculus.
To discuss the second-order variational condition is difficult when the
control variable u is constrained to be in the control set fl. So we make
the simplifying assimiption that Q = R^, and thus the control u is
unconstrained. As a result, we are now dealing with the problem:

max \j=f F{x, u, t)dt + ^x{T)] \ (D.15)

subject to
X = f{x^ u, t), x{0) = xo> (D.16)
From Chapter 2, we know that the first-order necessary conditions
for this problem are given by

A = -Ha:, A(T) - 0, (D.17)

Hu = 0, (D.18)
where the Hamiltonian H is given by

H = F + Xf, (D.19)

Since u is unconstrained, these conditions may be easily derived by the


method of calculus of variations. To see this, we write the augmented
objective fimctional as

J = ^x(T)] + I [Hix, u, A, t) - Xx]dt (D.20)


Jo
Consider small perturbation from the extremal path given by (D.16) -
(D.19) as a result of small perturbations 6x{0) in the initial state. Define
the resulting perturbations in state, adjoint, and control variables by
Sx{t), <5A(i), and 6u(t), respectively. These, of course, will be obtained
by linearizing (D.16 - D.18) around the external path:

dux
—rr = fx^x + fu^'^i 6x{0) specified, (D.21)
do

^ = -{HxJxf - SXf - (H^uSu), (D.22)


406 D. Special Topics in Optimal Control

SHu = {HuxSxf + SX{HuXf + (HuuSuf


= {HuuSxf + 6Xfu + {HuuSuf = 0. (D.23)

Alternatively, we may consider an expansion of the objective function


and the state equation to second order since the first-order terms vanish
about a trajectory which satisfies (D.15 - D.18), Prom Bryson and Ho
(1969), this may be accomplished by expanding (D.20) to second order
and all the constraints to first order. Thus, we have

^x
dt
^ 2 Jo
8u
(D.24)
subject to
d8x
= fxSx + fuSu^ 6x{0) specified. (D.25)
IT
Since we are interested in a neighboring extremal path, we must deter-
mine 6u{t) so as to maximize 6^J subject to (D.25). This problem is
a linear-quadratic problem discussed in the previous section. For this
problem, the optimal control 6u*{t) is given by the formula (D.14), pro-
vided Huu{i) is nonsingular for 0 < t < T. The case when Huuify is
singular for a finite time interval is treated in Section D.3. Thus, rec-
ognizing that G = ^xx, C = Hxx, N = H^u, D = Huu, A = fx, and
B = fu, we have

6u%t) = H-^[Hux + f^S{t)]8x{t), (D.26)

where

S + Sfx + f^S-{Sfu+Hxu)H-^{f^S + Hux) + Hxx = 0, S{T) = $^^.


(D.27)
While a ntmiber of second-order conditions can be obtained by pro-
ceeding further from this manner, we shall be interested only in the
concavity condition (or strengthened Legendre-Clebsch condition). It is
possible to show that neighboring stationary paths exist (in a weak sense;
i.e., Sx and Su are small) if

Huu{t) < 0 for 0<t<T, (D.28)

or in other words, Huu{t) is negative semidefinite. First-order conditions,


conditions (D.28), and the condition that S{t) is finite for 0 < t < T
D,3. Singular Control 407

represent sufficient conditions for a trajectory to be a local maximum.


We are not being specific here because in this book we would be relying
mostly on the sufficiency conditions developed in Chapters 2-4, which are
based on certain concavity requirements. We are stating (D.28) because
of its similarity to the second-order condition for a local maximum in
the classical maximization problem.
We must note that

Hu = 0 and Huu < 0 (D.29)

form necessary conditions for a trajectory to be a local maximimi.

D.3 Singular Control


In some optimization problems including some problems treated in this
text, extremal arcs satisfying Hu = 0 occur on which the matrix Huu is
singular. Such arcs are called singular arcs. Note that these arcs sat-
isfy (D.29) but not the strengthened condition (D.28). While no general
sufficiency conditions are available for singular arcs, some additional nec-
essary conditions known as the generalized Legendre-Clebsch conditions
have been developed. A good reference on singular control is Bell and
Jacobson (1975).
We shall only discuss the case in which the Hamiltonian is linear in
one or more of the control variables. For these systems, Hu = 0 implies
that the coefficient of the linear control term in the Hamiltonian vanishes
identically along a singular arc. Thus, the control is not determined in
terms of x and A by the Hamiltonian maximizing condition Hu = 0.
Instead, the control is determined by the requirement that the coefficient
of these linear terms remain zero on the singular arc. That is, the time
derivatives of Hu must be zero. Having obtained the control by setting
dHu/dt = 0 (or by setting higher time derivatives to equal zero) along the
singular arc, we must check additional necessary conditions analogous to
the second-order condition (D.28). For a maximization problem with a
single control variable, these conditions turn out to be

(P^Hu
(-')'!; <0, it = 0,1,2,.... (D.30)
dfi^

The conditions (D.30) are called the generalized Legendre-Clebsch


conditions.
408 D. Special Topics in Optimal Control

Example D . l We present an example treated by Johnson and Gibson


(1963):

{—ir^?
max \ j = - - I x\dt \ (D.31)

subject to

xi = X2+u^ xi{Q) = a^ (D.32)


i2 = -u, a:(0) = fe, (D.33)

xi{T) - X2{T) = 0. (D.34)

Solution. We form the Hamiltonian

H = --x\ + Xi{x2 + u)+ Mi-u), (D.35)

where the adjoint equations are


Ai=xi, A2 = - A i . (D.36)

The optimal control is bang-bang plus singular. Singular arcs must sat-
isfy
if = Ai - A2 = 0 (D.37)
for a finite time interval. The optimal control can, therefore, be obtained
by
^ = A i - A 2 = :ci+Ai = 0. (D.38)

Differentiating once more with respect to time t, we obtain

2 = xi + \i = X2 + u + xi = Q,

which implies
u = -{xi+X2) (D.39)
along the singular arc. We now verify for the example, the generalized
Legendre-Clebsch condition (D.30) for fc = 1:
Appendix E

Answers t o Selected
Exercises

Completely worked solutions to all exercises in this book are contained


in a forthcoming Teachers' Manual, which wiU be made available to
instructors by the publisher when it is ready.

Chapter 1

1.1 (a) Feasible. J = -333,333.


1.2 J = 36.
1.3 (a) C = $157,861/year.
(b) J = 103.41 utils.
(c) $15,000/year.

1.4 (b) W{20) = 985,648; J = 104.34.

1.12 imp(Gi,G2;i) = (Gi - G2)e-^*.

Chapter 2

2.2 The optimal control is

2 if 0 < t < 2 - h i 2 . 5 ,

u* (t) = { undefined if i = 2 - In 2.5,

0 ift>2-ln2.5.
410 E. Answers to Selected Exercises

2.8 u* = bang(0,1; Ai - A2), where X{t) = (8e-2(*-i8), 4e-2(*-i8)).

2.10 (a) u* = bang[0,1; (giKi + 52^2)(Ai - A2)].

(c) i = T- (1/52) Hio^bi - 9ih2)/{g2 - giM-


2.12 (a) a;(100) = 30 - 20e-i° « 30.
(b) w* = 3 f o r i € [0,100].

3 for i s [0, 100-101n2],


(c) u*{t) =
0 otherwise.

2.14 (a) C*{t) = pWoe^'-P^yil - e-P^).


(b) C*it) = Kir-p).
2.17 (a) X = x + 3Aa;2, A(l) = 0, and x =-x^ + A, x{0) = 1.
2.18 X = f{x) + b{x)u, x{0) = xo, x{T) = 0.

u = [b{xfg'{x) - 2<^u{b(x)f'{x) - V{x)f{x)y\l\l(?h{x)\.

Chapter 3

3.1 X — Ml > 0, « 1 — M2 > 0, Ml > 0, 1 + M2 > 0-

3.2 X = [-1, 5].


3.7 L = F(x, v) + A/(x, M, i) + iig{x, u, t),

A = -(a/a)X - 1^, /x > 0, /x^ = 0.

3.11 A(i) = t - 1.

3.12 (a) A(i) = 10 I _g0.1(t-100)

0 if ii: - 300,

-10 2 _ gO.iCic/s-ioo) if ii: < 300,


M*(t) = bang[0,3;A + /Lt].

The problem is infeasible for K > 300.


E. Answers to Selected Exercises 411

(b) r * = niin[0, 100-K/3],


0 for t < t**,
u*{t) = I
3 iort>t**.
V

3.18 11.87 minutes.


3.19 u* = - 1 , T* = 5.
3.20 tx* = - 2 , T* = 5/2.
3.29 (a) {I, P,X} = {h - p{S - Pi), S, 2(5 - Pi)}.
(b) I = h.
Chapter 4
4.1 u*{t) = -l, iJ,i = -X = 1/2-t, H2 = 7] = 0.
4.2 One solution appears in Figure 3.1. Another solution is u(t) = 1/2
for t G [0,2]. There are many others.
4.4 (a) u* = 0.

1, 0<t<l-T,
(c) u* = <
0, l-T <t<T.

(e) J = - ( 1 / 8 + 1/8K).
(f) J = - 1 / 8 .
Chapter 5

5, t < l + 61n0.99«0.94,
5.1 (a) u*{t)
0, t > 0.094.

-5, 0 < ^ < 0.28,

0, 0.28 < t < 0.4,


(b) A2(t)/Ai(i) = e3(*'-«+i)/i2,^t*(f) = J
5, 0.4 < i < 0.93,

0, 0.93 < t < 1.0.


412 E. Answers to Selected Exercises

5.5 u* = v* = 0 for all t.

5.7 u* = 0, V* = 4/5 for t € [0,49],

u* = 0, ^;* = 0 for ^€[49,60],

J* = 34,420.

5.10 (b) /(**) = t* - 101n(l - 0.3e°-"*).

(c) t* = 1.969327, J{t*) = 19.037.

Chapter 6

6.5 Q(t) = t^ - 160*3 ^ 1740^2 _ 7350^ + 9639.

6.7 V* = sat[-F2,14; (A2 - Aip)2/?Ai].


6.9 J* = 10.56653.
6.10 y*{t) « 3e-3*, y*(t) w 1 - Se'^*.

0, 0 < i < 7/3,

2, 7/3 <t< 3,
6.12 M*(i) = {
-1, 3 < ^ < 13/3,

0, 13/3 <t<6.

-fi+|, t€[0,l],
6.13 /xi = <
0, tG{0,3].

0, i e [0,1.8),
f^2= \
- i i + f, i e [1.8,3].

0, tG[0,l)U(1.8,3],
77= <
-fi+|, « € [1,1.8).
E. Answers to Selected Exercises 413

-1 for t G [0,1.8),
6.14 (a) v*{t) = {
1 for i e (1.8,3].

(b) t;*(t) = 1 for i G [0,10].

-1 for t G [0,1/2],

0 for f G (1/2, ti], where ti = 23/12,


6.15 V* = <
+1 f o r i G ( i i , i i + l/2],

0 for t G (ii + 1/2,4].

0, for0<i<ii,
6.17 u*(t) = \
h(t-ti)/c, ioiti<t<T,

where ti=T- ^2BC/h.

Chapter 7

7.1 p* = 102.5 + 0.2G.


7.7 {u)/{pS) = {Sp)/{rj{p + S)).
7.10 G + SG = bang[0, oo; A + 1],

-X + (p + S)X = 7r'{G).

7.12 The equations corresponding to (6.28) and (6.29) can be obtained

by replacing p by p+r/r. The form of (6.30) remains imchanged.

7.17 (b)
1 1 Xo _, 1 . X-X^
h
rQ + 6 n —
: l x^ , t2 = rQ„ + S. In •X — XT

7.18

T > ^ In ^<^(1 ~ ^o) ~ ^^0 + i In f i


~ rQ + 6 r Q ( l — x^) — 6x^ 6 XT '
414 E. Answers to Selected Exercises

7.19 The reachable set is [xoe'^^, {xo - x)e-(*+'''5)^ + x],

where x = rQ/{W + rQ).


1-A
7.25 imp{A^B;t) = - r 1-B

7.26 (b) J = 0.6325.


Chapter 8

8.1 (a) y = l^z = 3.


(b) y - 2, z - 10.
8.2 (a) (1,3) is a relative maximum.
(b) (2,10) is a relative maximum.
8.3 x = 50;x = 80.
8.6 (a) a: = 4 is a local maximum.
(b) a: = 8 is a local maximimn and a: = 20 is a local and a global
maximum.
8.7 (a) (0, 0) is the nearest point.
(b) (1/2,1/2) is the nearest point.
8.8 (1/V^, 2/\/5) is the closest point.
8.9 (a) ( 2 ^ , 0 ) .
(b) (0,2).
(c) (0,2).
8.10 Xj = dF/dxJ for i = 1,2,..., n; A^+i = 1. Note that here T

denotes the terminal time, and not the transpose operation.

+1 ifA'=+i6>l,

8.14 k* -1 ifA'^+iJx-l ,whereA*= = (7 + A)^-'=A^


u

0 if iX^+^b] < 1.
E. Answers to Selected Exercises 415

Chapter 9
9.1 t' = 5.25, T = 11.
9.3 T = i* = 2.47.
9.4 t^ = 0, T = 30.
l2
9.5 u*{t) = sat[0,1;u^{t)], where u^{t) = \2 - e005(t-34.8)|'/(i + i),

ti^S;t2-T = 34.8.
Chapter 10
10.3 X = 0.734.
10.4 (a)
X Sep
X =
(-^i)W('-^i) + prX

(b) For p = 0, 5 = 220,000. Fovp = 0.1,x = 86,000. For p = oo,


X = 40,000.
10.5 [g'{x) - p]\p - c{x)] - c^{x)g{x) = 0.
10.7 [g'{x) -p\\p- c{x)] - c'{x)g{x) + p = 0.
Chapter 11
11.1 A(i) = \oe^P-^^\ where
[Koe^T + 5(1 _ g/3T)/^ _ ^^j(2p - 0)
Xo =
e/?T _ e2(/3-p)T

e^').
p p Zp:(-'
Chapter 12
12.5 0 < T + ;^ ha(l - ^) = i.
12.8 ti = r / 2 .
Chapter 13
13.5 q*{x) = j^^^,c*ix) = j^{p-r0-i^)x,
Bibliography

[1] Abad, P.L. (1982a). An optimal control approach to marketing-


production planning, Optimal Control Applications & Methods^ 3,1,1-13.

[2] Abad, P.L. (1982b). Approach to decentralized marketing-production


planning, International Journal of Systems Science, 13, 3, 227-235.

[3] Abad, P.L. (1987). A hierarchical optimal control model for coordina-
tion of functional decisions in a firm, European Journal of Operational
Research, 32, 62-75.

[4] Abad, P.L. (1989). Multi-product multi-market model for coordination


of marketing-production decisions. International Journal of Systems Sci-
ence, 20, 2011-2027.

[5] Abad, P.L. and Sweeney, D.J. (1982). Decentralized planning with an
interdependent marketing-production system. Omega, 10, 353-359.

[6] Agnew, C.E. (1976). Dynamic modeling and control of congestion-prone


systems, Operations Research, 24, 400-419.

[7] Alam, M., Lynn, J.W. and Sarma, V.V.S. (1976). Optimal maintenance
policy for equipment subject to random deterioration and random failure,
International Journal of Systems Science, 7, 1071-1080.

[8] Alam, M. and Sarma, V.V.S. (1974). Optimal maintenance policy for
equipment subject to deterioration and random failure, IEEE Transac-
tions on System, Man, and Cybernetics SMC-4, 172-175.

[9] Alam, M. and Sarma, V.V.S. (1977). An application of optimal control


theory to repairman problem with machine interference, IEEE Transac-
tions on Reliability, R-26, 121-124.

[10] Allen, K.R. (1973). Analysis of the stock-recruitment relation in Antarc-


tic fin whales, in Fish Stock and Recruitment, J. du Conseil International
pour VExploration de la Mer, Rapports et Proces-Verbaux de Reunions,
B. Parrish (Ed.), 164, 132-137.
418 Bibliography

[11] Amit, R. (1986). Petroleum reservoir exploitation: switching from pri-


mary to secondary recovery, Operations Research, 34, 4, 534-549.

[12] Amit, R. and Ilan, Y. (1990). The choice of manufacturing technology in


the presence of dynamic demand and experience effects, IIE Transactions,
22, 2, 100-111.

[13] Anderson, R.M. and May, R. M. (1992). Infectious Diseases of Humans:


Dynamics and Control, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

[14] Aoki, M. (1976). Dynamic Economics: A System Theoretic Approach to


Theory and Control, Elsevier, New York.

[15] Arnold, L. (1974). Stochastic Differential Equations: Theory and Appli-


cations, Wiley, New York.

[16] Aronson, J.E. and Thompson, G.L. (1984). A survey on forward methods
in mathematical programming. Journal of Large Scale Systems, 7, 1-16.

[17] Arora, S.R. and Lele, P.T. (1970). A note on optimal maintenance policy
and sale date of a machine. Management Science, 17, 170-173.

[18] Arrow, K.J. (1968). Applications of control theory to economic growth,


in Mathematics of the Decision Sciences, G.B. Dantzig and A.F. Veinott
(Eds.), Vol. 12 in the Series Lectures in Applied Mathematics, American
Mathematical Society, Providence, RI, 85-119.

[19] Arrow, K.J. and Chang, S. (1980). Optimal pricing, use, and exploration
of uncertain natural resource stocks, in Dynamic Optimization in Math-
ematical Economics, P.-T. Liu (Ed.), Plenum Press, New York.

[20] Arrow, K.J. and Kurz, M. (1970). Public Investment, The Rate of Return,
and Optimal Fiscal Policy, The John Hopkins Press, Baltimore.

[21] Arthur, W.B. and McNicoll, G. (1977). Optimal time paths with age
dependence: a theory of population policy. Review of Economic Studies,
44, 111-123.

[22] Arutyunov, A.V. and Aseev, S.M. (1977). Investigation of the degeneracy
phenomenon of the maximum principle for optimal control problems with
state constraints, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 35, 3,
930-952.

[23] Aubin, J.-P. and Cellina, A. (1984). Differential Inclusions: Set-Valued


Maps and Viability Theory, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

[24] Axsater, S. (1985). Control theory concepts in production and inventory


control. International Journal of Systems Science, 16, 161-169,
Bibliography 419

[25] Bagchi, A. (1984). Stackelberg Differential Games in Economic Models,


Lecture Notes in Control and Information Sciences, Vol. 64, Springer-
Verlag, Berlin.

[26] Basar, T. (1986). A tutorial on dynamic and differential games, in Dy-


namic Games and Applications in Economics, T. Basar (Ed.), Springer-
Verlag, Berlin, 1-25.

[27] Basar, T. and Olsder, G.J. (1982). Dynamic Noncooperative Game The-
ory, Academic Press, London.

[28] Bass, F.M. (1969). A new product growth model for consumer durables,
Management Science, 15, 5, 215-227.

[29] Bass, F.M. and Bultez, A.V. (1969). A note on optimal strategic pricing
of technological innovations. Marketing Science, 1, 371-378.

[30] Bean, J.C. and Smith, R.L. (1984). Conditions for the existence of plan-
ning horizons. Mathematics of Operations Research, 9, 3, 391-401.

[31] Bell, D.J. and Jacobson, D.H. (1975). Singular Optimal Control, Aca-
demic Press, New York.

[32] Bellman, R.E. (1957). Dynamic Programming, Princeton University


Press, Princeton, NJ.

[33] Bellman, R.E. and Kalaba, R.E. (1965a). Quasi linearization and Bound-
ary Value Problems, Elsevier, New York.

[34] Bellman, R.E. and Kalaba, R.E. (1965b). Dynamic Programming and
Modern Control Theory, Academic Press, New York.

[35] Bensoussan, A., Bultez, A.V. and Naert, P.A. (1978). Leader's dynamic
marketing behavior in oligopoly, in TIMS Studies in the Management
Sciences, A. Bensoussan et al., (Eds.), Vol. 9, North-Holland, Amster-
dam, 123-145.

[36] Bensoussan, A., Crouhy, M. and Proth, J.-M. (1983). Mathematical The-
ory of Production Planning, North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[37] Bensoussan, A., Hurst, Jr., E.G. and Naslund, B. (1974). Management
Applications of Modern Control Theory, Elsevier, New York.

[38] Bensoussan, A. and Lesourne, J. (1980). Optimal growth of a self-


financing firm in an uncertain environment, in Applied Stochastic Control
in Econometrics and Management Science, A. Bensoussan et al. (Eds.),
North-Holland, Amsterdam, 235-269.
420 Bibliography

[39] Bensoussaii, A. and Lesourne, J. (1981). Growth of firms: a stochastic


control theory approach, in Unternehmensplanung, K. BrockhofFand W.
Krelle (Eds.), Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 101-116.

[40] Bensoussan, A. and Lions, J.L. (1975). Nouvelles methodes en controle


impulsionnel. Applied Mathematics & Optimization, 1, 289-312.

[41] Bensoussan, A. and Lions, J.L. (1982). Application of Variational In-


equalities in Stochastic Control, North-Holland, Amsterdam, The Nether-
lands.

[42] Bensoussan, A. and Lions, J.L. (1984). Impulse Control and Quasi-
Variational Inequalities, Bordas, Paris.

[43] Bensoussan, A., Nissen, G. and Tapiero, C.S. (1975). Optimum inventory
and product quality control with deterministic and stochastic deteriora-
tion - an application of distributed parameter control systems, IEEE
Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-20, 407-412.

[44] Bensoussan, A., Sethi, S.P., Vickson, R.G. and Derzko, N. A. (1984).
Stochastic production planning with production constraints, SI AM Jour-
nal on Control and Optimization, 22, 6, 920-935.

[45] Berkovitz, L.D. (1961). Variational methods in problems of control and


programming, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 3,
145-169.

[46] Berkovitz, L.D. (1994). A theory of diflferential games, in Advances


in Dynamic Games and Applications, T. Basar and A. Haurie (Eds.),
Birkhauser, Boston, 3-22.

[47] Berkovitz, L.D. and Dreyfus, S.E. (1965). The equivalence of some nec-
essary conditions for optimal control in problems with bounded state
variables. Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 10, 275-
283.

[48] Bertsekas, D.P. and Shreve, S.E. (1996). Stochastic Optimal Control: The
Discrete-Time Case, Athena Scientific, New York.

[49] Bes, C. and Sethi, S.P. (1988). Concepts of forecast and decision horizons:
applications to dynamic stochastic optimization problems. Mathematics
of Operations Research, 13, 2, 295-310.

[50] Bes, C. and Sethi, S.P. (1989). Solution of a class of stochastic linear-
convex control problems using deterministic equivalents. Journal of Op-
timization Theory and Applications, 62, 1, 17-27.
Bibliography 421

[51] Beyer, D. and Sethi, S.R (1998). A proof of the EOQ formula using quasi-
variational inequalities. The International Journal of Systems Science^
29, 11, 1295-99.

[52] Bhaskaran, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1981). Planning horizons for the wheat
trading model. Proceedings of AMS SI Conference^ 5: Life, Men, and
Societies, 197-201.

[53] Bhaskaran, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1983). Planning horizon research - the
dynamic programming/control theory interface, Proceedings of Interna-
tional AMSE Winter Symposium, Bermuda, 155-160.

[54] Bhaskaran, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1987). Decision and forecast horizons in a
stochastic environment: a survey. Optimal Control Applications & Meth-
ods, 8, 201-217.

[55] Bhaskaran, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1988). The dynamic lot size model with
stochastic demands: a planning horizon study. Information Systems and
Operational Research, 26, 3, 213-224.

[56] Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973). The pricing of options and corporate
liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 8 1 , 637-659.

[57] Blaquiere, A. (1979). Necessary and sufficiency conditions for optimal


strategies in impulsive control, in Differential Games and Control Theory
III, Part A, P.-T. Liu and E.O. Roxin (Eds.), M. Dekker, New York, 1-28.

[58] Blaquiere, A. (1985). Impulsive optimal control with finite or infinite time
horizon. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 46, 431-439.

[59] Boiteux, M. (1955). Reflexions sur la concurrence du rail et de la route,


le declassement des lignes non rentables et le deficit du chemin de fer,
L'Economie Electrique, 2.

[60] Boltyanskii, V.G. (1971). Mathematical Methods of Optimal Control,


Holt, Rinehard & Winston, New York.

[61] Bookbinder, J.H. and Sethi, S.P. (1980). The dynamic transportation
problem: a survey. Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 27, 65-87.

[62] Bourguignon, F. and Sethi, S.P. (1981). Dynamic optimal pricing and
(possibly) advertising in the face of various kinds of potential entrants,
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 3, 119-140.

[63] Breakwell, J.V. (1968). Stochastic optimization problems in space guid-


ance, in Stochastic Optimization and Control, H.F. Karreman (Ed.), Wi-
ley, New York, 91-100.
422 Bibliography

[64] Brekke, K.A. and 0ksendal, B.K. (1994). Optimal switching in an eco-
nomic activity under uncertainty, SIAM Journal on Control and Opti-
mization, 32, 4, 1021-1036.

[65] Brito, D.L. and Oakland, W.H. (1977). Some properties of the optimal
income tax. International Economic Review, 18, 407-423.

[66] Brown, R.G. (1959). Statistical Forecasting for Inventory Control,


McGraw-Hill Book Co., New York.

[67] Brown, R.G. (1963). Smoothing, Forecasting and Prediction, Prentice-


Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

[68] Bryant, G.F. and Mayne, D.Q. (1974). The maximum principle. Inter-
national Journal of Control, 20, 1021-1054.

[69] Bryson, Jr., A.E. (1998). Dynamic Optimization, Addison-Wesley, Read-


ing, Mass.

[70] Bryson, Jr., A.E. and Ho, Y.-C. (1969). Applied Optimal Control, Blais-
dell, Waltham, MA.

[71] Buchanan, L.F. and Norton, F.E. (1971). Optimal control applications in
economic systems, in Advances in Control Systems, C.T. Leondes (Ed.),
Vol. 8 in the series. Academic Press, New York, 141-187.

[72] Bulirsch, R. and Kraft, D. (Eds.) (1994). Computational Optimal Control,


Birkhauser-Verlag, Boston.

[73] Bulirsch, R., Oetth, W. and Stoer, J. (Eds.) (1975). Optimization and Op-
timal Control, Lecture Notes in Mathematics, Vol. 477, Springer-Verlag,
Berlin.

[74] Bultez, A.V. and Naert, P.A. (1979). Does lag structure really matter in
optimizing advertising spending, Management Science, 25, 5, 454-465.

[75] Bultez, A.V. and Naert, P.A. (1988). When does lag structure really
matter...indeed?. Management Science, 34, 7, 909-916.

[76] Burdet, C.A. and Sethi, S.P. (1976). On the maximum principle for a
class of discrete dynamical system with lags, Journal Of Optimization
Theory & Applications, 19, 445-454.

[77] Burmeister, E. and Dobell, A.R. (1970). Mathematical Theories of Eco-


nomic Growth, MacMillan, London.

[78] Butkowskiy, A.G. (1969). Distributed Control Systems, Elsevier, New


York.
Bibliography 423

[79] Bylka, S. and Sethi, S.R (1992). Existence of solution and forecast hori-
zons in dynamic lot size model with nondecreasing holding costs, Pro-
duction and Operations Management, 1, 2, 212-224.

[80] Bylka, S., Sethi, S.R and Sorger, G. (1992). Minimal forecast horizons
in equipment replacement models with multiple technologies and general
switching costs, Naval Research Logistics, 39, 487-507.

[81] Caines, R, Sethi, S.R and Brotherton, T. (1977). Impulse response iden-
tification and casualty detection for the Lydia Pinkham data. Annals of
Economic and Social Measurement, 6, 2, 147-163.

[82] Canon, M.D., CuUum, C D . and Polak, E. (1970). Theory of Optimal


Control and Mathematical Programming, McGraw-Hill, New York.

[83] Carlson, D.A. (1986a). On the existence of catching up optimal solu-


tions for Lagrange problems defined on unbounded intervals. Journal of
Optimization Theory and Applications, 49, 2.

[84] Carlson, D.A. (1986b). The existence of finitely optimal solutions for in-
finite horizon optimal control problems, Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 51, 1, 41-62.

[85] Carlson, D.A. (1987a). On the existence of sporadically catching up op-


timal solutions for infinite horizon optimal control problems. Journal of
Optimization Theory and Applications, 53, 2, 219-235.

[86] Carlson, D.A. (1987b). An elementary proof of the maximum principle


for optimal control problems governed by a Volterra integral equation,
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 54, 1, 43-61.

[87] Carlson, D.A. (1988). Sufficient conditions for optimality and supported
trajectories for optimal control problems governed by Volterra integral
equations, in Advances in Optimization and Control, Lecture. Notes in
Econ. and Math. Sys., 302, Springer-Verlag. New York, 274-282.

[88] Carlson, D.A. (1989). Some concepts of optimality for infinite horizon
control and their interrelationships, in Modern Optimal Control; A Con-
ference in Honor of Solomon Lefschetz and Joseph P. LaSalle, E.O. Roxin
(Ed.), Marcel Dekker, Inc., New York, 13-22.

[89] Carlson, D.A. (1990a). Uniform overtaking and weakly overtaking opti-
mal solutions in optimal control: when optimal solutions are agreeable,
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 64, 1, 55-69.

[90] Carlson, D.A. (1990b). The existence of catching-up optimal solutions


for a class of infinite horizon optimal control problems with time delay,
SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 28, 2, 402-422.
424 Bibliography

[91] Carlson, D.A. (1990c). Infinite horizon optimal controls for problems gov-
erned by a Volterra integral equation with a state and control dependent
discount factor, Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 66, 2,
311-336.

[92] Carlson, D.A. (1991). Asymptotic stability for optimal trajectories of


infinite horizon optimal control models with state and control dependent
discounting, Proceedings of the 4th Annual Workshop in Analysis and its
Applications, 281-299.
[93] Carlson, D.A. (1993). Nonconvex and relaxed infinite horizon optimal
control problems. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 78,
3, 465-491.
[94] Carlson, D.A. (1995). An existence theorem for hereditary Lagrange
problems on an unbounded interval, in Boundary Value Problems for
Functional Differential Equation, World Scientific Publishing, Singapore,
73-83.

[95] Carlson, D.A. (1997). Overtaking optimal solutions for convex Lagrange
problems with time delay, J. Math. Appl, 208, 31-48.
[96] Carlson, D.A. and Haurie, A. (1987a). Infinite Horizon Optimal Control
Theory and Applications, Lecture. Notes in Econ. and Math. Sys., 290,
Springer-Verlag, New York.
[97] Carlson, D.A. and Haurie, A. (1987b). Optimization with Unbounded
Time Interval for a Class of Non Linear Systems, Springer-Verlag, Berhn.
[98] Carlson, D.A. and Haurie, A. (1992). Control theoretic models of
environment-economy interactions, The Proceedings of the 31st IEEE
Conference on Decision and Control, 2860-2861.

[99] Carlson, D.A. and Haurie, A. (1995). A turnpike theory for infinite hori-
zon open-loop differential games with decoupled dynamics. New Trends
in Dynamic Games and Applications^ Annals of the International Society
of Dynamic Games, 3, Birkhauser, Boston, 353-376.

[100] Carlson, D.A. and Haurie, A. (1996). A turnpike theory for infinite hori-
zon competitive processes, SI AM Journal on Optimization and Control,
34, 4.
[101] Carlson, D.A., Haurie, A. and Jabrane, A. (1987). Existence of overtaking
solutions to infinite dimensional control problems on unbounded time
intervals, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 25, 6, 1517-1541.
[102] Carlson, D.A., Haurie, A. and Leizarowitz, A. (1991). Infinite Horizon
Optimal Control: Deterministic and Stochastic Systems, Second Edition,
Springer-Verlag, New York.
Bibliography 425

[103] Carlson, D.A., Haurie, A. and Leizarowitz, A. (1994). Equilibrium points


for linear-quadratic infinite horizon differential games, in Advances in
Dynamic Games and Applications^ Annals of the International Society
of Dynamic Games, T. Baar and A. Haurie (Eds.), Vol. 1, Birkhauser,
247-268.

[104] Carraro, C. and Filar, J. (Eds.), (1995). Control and Game Theoretic
Models of the Environment, Birkhauser, Boston.

[105] Carrillo, J. and Gaimon, C. (2000). Improving manufacturing perfor-


mance through process change and knowledge creation. Management Sci-
ence, forthcoming.

[106] Case, J.H. (1979). Economics and the Competitive Process, New York
University Press, New York.

[107] Cass, D. and Shell, K. (1976). The Hamiltonian Approach to Dynamic


Economics, Academic Press, New York.

[108] Cesari, L. (1983). Optimization - Theory and Applications: Problems with


Ordinary Differential Equations, Springer-Verlag, New York.

[109] Chand, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1982). Planning horizon procedures for ma-
chine replacement models with several possible replacement alternatives,
Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 29, 3, 483-493,

[110] Chand, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1983). Finite production rate inventory models
with first and second shift setups, Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 30,
401-414.

[Ill] Chand, S. and Sethi, S.P. (1990). A dynamic lot size model with learning
in setups, Operations Research, 38, 4, 644-655.

[112] Chand, S., Sethi, S.P. and Proth, J.-M. (1990). Existence of forecast hori-
zons in undiscounted discrete time lot size models, Operations Research,
38, 5, 884-892.

[113] Chand, S., Sethi, S.P. and Sorger, G. (1992). Forecast horizons in the
discounted dynamic lot size model. Management Science, 38, 7, 1034-
1048.

[114] Charnes, A. and Kortanek, K. (1966). A note on the discrete maximum


principle and distribution problems. Journal of Mathematics and Physics,
45, 121-126.

[115] Chen, S.F. and Leitmann, G. (1980). Labour-management bargaining


modelled as a dynamic game. Optimal Control Applications & Methods,
1, 11-25.
426 Bibliography

[116] Chiarella, C , Kemp, M.C., Long, N.V. and Okuguchi, K. (1984). On the
economics of international fisheries. International Economic Review^ 25,
85-92.

[117] Chichilinsky, G. (1981). Existence and Characterization of optimal


growth paths including models with non-convexities in utilities and tech-
nologies, Review of Economic Studies, 48, 51-61.

[118] Chintagunta, P.K. (1993). Investigating the sensitivity of equilibrium


profits to advertising dynamics and competitive effects. Management Sci-
ence, 39, 9, 1146-1162.

[119] Chintagunta, P.K. and Jain, D. (1992). A dynamic model of channel


member strategies for marketing expenditures. Marketing Science, 11, 2,
168-188.

[120] Chintagunta, P.K. and Jain, D. (1994). A study of manufacturer-retailer


marketing strategies: a differential game approach. Lecture Notes in Con-
trol and Information Sciences, Springer-Verlag, New York.

[121] Chintagunta, P.K. and Jain, D. (1995). Dynamic duopoly models of ad-
vertising competition: estimation and a specification tests. Journal of
Economics and Management Strategy, 4, 1, 109-131.

[122] Chintagunta, P.K. and Vilcassim, N.J. (1992). An empirical investigation


of advertising strategies in a dynamic duopoly. Management Science, 38,
9, 1230-1244.

[123] Chintagunta, P.K. and Vilcassim, N.J. (1994). Marketing investment de-
cisions in a dynamic duopoly: a model and empirical analysis. Interna-
tional J. Res. Marketing, 1 1 , 3, 287-306.

[124] Chow, G.C. (1975). Analysis and Control of Dynamic Economic Systems,
Wiley, New York.

[125] Clark, C.W. (1973). The economics of overexploitation. Science, 181,


630-634.

[126] Clark, C.W. (1976). Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Manage-


ment of Renewal Resources, Wiley, New York.

[127] Clark, C.W. (1979). Mathematical models in the economics of renewable


resources, SIAM Review, 2 1 , 81-99.

[128] Clark, C.W. (1985). Bioeconomic Modelling and Fisheries Management,


Wiley, New York.
Bibliography 427

[129] Clarke, F.H. (1976). Necessary conditions for a general control problem,
in Calculus of Variations and Control Theory, D.L. Russell (Ed.), Aca-
demic Press, New York.

[130] Clarke, F.H. (1983). Optimization and Nonsmooth Analysis, Wiley-


Interscience, New York.

[131] Clarke, F.H. (1989). Methods of Dynamic and Nonsmooth Optimization,


Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, Philadelphia, PA.

[132] Clarke, F.H., Darrough, M.N. and Heineke, J.M. (1982). Optimal pricing
policy in the presence of experience effects, Journal of Business, 55, 517-
530.

[133] Clarke, F.H., and Loewen, P.D. (1987). State constraints in optimal con-
trol: a case study in proximal normal analysis, SI AM Journal of Control
and Optimization, 25, 1440-1456.

[134] Clemhout, S. and Wan, Jr., H.Y. (1985). Dynamic common property
resources and environmental problems. Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 46, 471-481.

[135] Coddington, E.A. and Levinson, N.L. (1955). Theory of Ordinary Differ-
ential Equations, McGraw-Hill, New York.

[136] Cohen, K.J. and Cyert, R.M. (1965). Theory of the Firm: Resource Al-
location in a Market Economy, Prentice-Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

[137] Connors, M.M. and Teichroew, D. (1967). Optimal Control of Dynamic


Operations Research Models, International Textbook, Scranton, PA.

[138] Conrad, K. (1982). Advertising, quality and informationally consistent


prices, Zeitschrift filr ges. Staatswiss, 138, 680-694.

[139] Conrad, K. (1985). Quality, advertising and the formation of goodwill un-
der dynamic conditions, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Anal-
ysis, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), Vol. 2, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 215-234.

[140] Constantinides, G.M. and Richard, S.F. (1978). Existence of optimal


simple policies for discounted cost inventory and cash management in
continuous time, Operations Research, 26, 620-636.

[141] Dantzig, G.B. (1966). Linear control processes and mathematical pro-
gramming, SIAM Journal on Control, 4, 56-60.

[142] Dantzig, G.B. and Sethi, S.P. (1981). Linear optimal control problems
and generalized linear programs. Journal of Operational Research Society,
32, 467-476.
428 Bibliography

[143] Dasgupta, P. and Heal, G.M. (1974). The optimal depletion of ex-
haustible resources, The Review of Economic Studies, 4 1 , 3-28.

[144] D'Autume, A. and Michel, P. (1985). Future investment constraints re-


duce present investment, Econometrica, 53, 203-206.

[145] Davis, B.E. (1970). Investment and rate of return for the regulated firm,
The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 1, 245-270.

[146] Davis, B.E. and Elzinga, D.J. (1972). The solution of an optimal control
problem in financial modeling. Operations Research, 19, 1419-1433.

[147] Davis, M.H.A. (1993). Markov Models and Optimization, Chapman &
Hall, New York.

[148] Dawid, H. and Feichtinger, G. (1996a). Optimal allocation of drug control


efforts: a differential game analysis, Journal of Optimization Theory and
Applications, 9 1 , 279-297.

[149] Dawid, H. and Feichtinger, G. (1996b). On the persistence of corruption,


Journal of Economics, 64, 177-193.

[150] Dawid, H., Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (Eds.) (1999). Special Issue on
Optimal control and differential games. Annals of Operations Research,
88.

[151] Dawid, H., Kopel, M. and Feichtinger, G. (1997). Complex solutions of


nonconcave dynamic optimization models, Economic Theory, 9, 427-439.

[152] Deal, K.R. (1979). Optimizing advertising expenditures in a dynamic


duopoly. Operations Research, 27, 4, 682-692.

[153] Deal, K.R., Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1979) A bilinear-quadratic
differential game in advertising, in Control Theory in Mathematical Eco-
nomics, P.-T. Liu and J.G. Sutinen (Eds.), Marcel Dekker, Inc., New
York, 91-109.

[154] Deger, S. and Sen, S.K.(1984). Optimal control and differential game
models of military expenditure in less developed countries, J. of Eco-
nomic Dynamics and Control, 7, 153-169.

[155] Deissenberg, C. (1980). Optimal control of linear econometric models


with intermittent control, Economics of Planning, 16, 1, 49-56.

[156] Deissenberg, C. (1981). A simple model of closed-loop optimal explo-


ration for oil. Policy Analysis and Information Systems, 5, 3, 167-183.
Bibliography 429

[157] Deissenberg, C. and Stoppler, S. (1982). Optimal control of LQG sys-


tems with costly observations, in Economic Applications of Optimal Con-
trol Theory, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam-New York,
301-320.

[158] Deissenberg, C. and Stoppler, S. (1983). Optimal information gathering


and planning policies of the profit-maximizing firm. International Journal
on Policy and Information, 7, 2, 49-76.

[159] Derzko, N.A. and Sethi, S.P. (1981a). Optimal exploration and consump-
tion of a natural resource: stochastic case. International J. of Policy
Analysis, 5, 3, 185-200.

[160] Derzko, N.A. and Sethi, S.P. (1981b). Optimal exploration and consump-
tion of a natural resource: deterministic case. Optimal Control Applica-
tions & Methods, 2, 1, 1-21.

[161] Derzko, N.A., Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1980). Distributed pa-
rameter systems approach to the optimal cattle ranching problem. Opti-
mal Control Applications & Methods, 1, 3-10.

[162] Derzko, N.A., Sethi, S.P. and Thompson,G.L. (1984). Necessary and suf-
ficient conditions for optimal control of quasilinear partial differential
systems. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 43, 89-101.

[163] Dhrymes, P.J. (1962). On optimal advertising capital and research ex-
penditures under dynamic conditions, Economica, 39, 275-279.

[164] Dixit, A.K. and Pindyck, R.S. (1994). Investment Under Uncertainty,
Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

[165] Dockner, E.J. (1984). Optimal pricing of a monopoly against a competi-


tive producer. Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 5, 345-351.

[166] Dockner, E.J. and Feichtinger, G. (1991). On the optimality of limit


cycles in dynamic economic systems, Journal of Economics, 53, 31-50.

[167] Dockner, E.J. and Feichtinger, G. (1993). Cyclical consumption patterns


and rational addiction, American Economic Review, 83, 256-263.

[168] Dockner, E.J., Feichtinger, G. and J0rgensen, S. (1985). Tractable classes


of nonzero-sum open-loop Nash differential games: theory and examples,
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 45, 179-197.

[169] Dockner, E.J., Feichtinger, G. and Mehlmann, A. (1993). Dynamic R


& D competition with memory. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 3,
145-152.
430 Bibliography

[170] Dockner, E.J. and J0rgensen, S., (1984). Cooperative and non-
cooperative differential game solutions to an investment and pricing prob-
lem, Journal of Operational Research Society^ 35, 731-739.

[171] Dockner, E.J. and J0rgensen, S., (1986). Dynamic advertising and pricing
in an oligopoly: a Nash equilibrium approach, in Dynamic Games and
Applications in Economics, T. Basar (Ed.), Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 238-
251.

[172] Dockner, E.J. and J0rgensen, S., (1988). Optimal advertising policies for
diffusion models of new product innovation in monopolistic situations,
Management Science, 34, 1, 119-130.

[173] Dockner, E.J. and J0rgensen, S., (1992). New product advertising in
dynamic oligopolies, Zeitschrift fur Operations Research, 36, 5, 459-473.

[174] Dockner, E.J., J0rgensen, S., Long, N.V. and Sorger, G. (2000). Differ-
ential Games in Economics and Management Science, Cambridge Uni-
versity Press, Cambridge, UK.

[175] Dohrmann, C.R. and Robinett, R.D. (1999). Dynamic programming


method for constrained discrete-time optimal control. Journal of Op-
timization Theory and Applications, 101, 2, 259-283.

[176] Dolan, R.J. and Jeuland, A.P., (1981). Experience curves and dynamic
demand models: implications of optimal pricing strategies, J. Marketing,
45, 52-73.

[177] Dolan, R.J. and Muller, E., (1986). Models of new product diffusion:
extension to competition against existing and potential firms over time,
in Innovation Diffusion Models of New Product Acceptance, V. Mahajan
and Y. Wind (Eds.), Ballinger, Cambridge, MA, 117-150.

[178] Dorfman, R. (1969). Economic interpretation of optimal control theory,


American Economic Review, 49, 817-831.
[179] Dorfman, R. and Steiner, P.O. (1954). Optimal advertising and optimal
quality, American Economic Review, 44, 826-836.

[180] Drews, W., Hartberger, R.J. and Segers, R. (1974). On continuous math-
ematical programming in Optimization Methods for Resource Allocation,
R.W. Cottle and J. Krarup (Eds.), The English University Press, London.

[181] Dubovitskii, A.Y. and Milyutin, A.A. (1963). Extremum problems with
constraints, Soviet Math. Dokl, 4, 452-455.

[182] Dunn, J.C. and Bertsekas, D.P. (1989). Efficient dynamic programming
implementations of Newton's method for unconstrained optimal control
problems. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 6 3 , 1 , 23-38.
Bibliography 431

[183] Durrett, R. (1996). Stochastic Calculus: A Practical Introduction, Second


Edition, CRC Press.

[184] El-Hodiri, M. and Takayama, A. (1981). Dynamic behavior of the firm


with adjustment costs under regularity constraint, J. of Economic Dy-
namics and Control, 3, 29-41.

[185] Ehashberg, J. and Steinberg, R. (1987). Marketing-production decisions


in an industrial channel of distribution, Management Science, 33, 8, 981-
1000.

[186] Elton, E. and Gruber, M. (1975). Finance as a Dynamic Process,


Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

[187] Erickson, G.M. (1991). Dynamic Models of Advertising Competi-


tion: Open- and Closed-Loop Extensions, Kluwer Academic Publishers,
Boston.

[188] Erickson, G.M. (1992). Empirical analysis of closed-loop duopoly adver-


tising strategies. Management Science, 38, 1732-1749.

[189] Fan, L.T. and Wang, C.-S. (1964). An application of the discrete maxi-
mum principle to a transportation problem. Journal of Mathematics and
Physics, 43, 255-260.

[190] Feichtinger, G. (1982a). Optimal pricing in a diffusion model with concave


price-dependent market potential, O.R. Letters, 1, 6, 236-240.

[191] Feichtinger, G. (1982b). Saddle-point analysis in a price-advertising


model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 4, 319-340.

[192] Feichtinger, G. (1982c). Optimal repair policy for a machine service prob-
lem, Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 3, 15-22.

[193] Feichtinger, G. (1982d). The Nash solution of a maintenance-production


differential game, European Journal of Operational Research, 10, 165-
172.

[194] Feichtinger, G. (Ed.) (1982e). Optimal Control Theory and Economic


Analysis, First Viennese Workshop on Economic Applications of Control
Theory, Vienna, October 28-30, 1981, North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[195] Feichtinger, G. (1982f). Anwendungen des Maximumprinzips im Opera-


tions Research, Teil 1 und 2, OR-Spektrum, 4, 171-190 und 195-212.

[196] Feichtinger, G. (1983a). The Nash solution of an advertising differential


game: generalization of a model by Leitmann and Schmitendorf, IEEE
Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-28, 1044-1048.
432 Bibliography

[197] Feichtinger, G. (1983b). A differential games solution to a model of com-


petition between a thief and the police, Management Science, 29, 686-
699.

[198] Feichtinger, G. (1984a). Optimal employment strategies of profit-


maximizing and labour-managed firms, Optimal Control Applications &
Methods, 5, 235-253.

[199] Feichtinger, G. (1984b). On the synergistic influence of two control vari-


ables on the state of nonlinear optimal control models. Journal of Oper-
ational Research Society, 35, 907-914.

[200] Feichtinger, G. (Ed.) (1985a). Optimal Control Theory and Economic


Analysis 2, Second Viennese Workshop on Economic Applications of Con-
trol Theory, Vienna, May 16 - 18, 1984, North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[201] Feichtinger, G. (1985b). Optimal modification of machine reliability by


maintenance and production, OR-Spektrum, 7, 43-50.

[202] Feichtinger, G. (1987). Intertemporal optimization of wine consumption


at a party: an unusual optimal control model, in Keynesian Theory Plan-
ning Models and Quantitative Economics, Essays in Memory of Vittorio
Marrama, G. Gandolfo and F. Marzano (Eds.), Vol. II, Giuffre, Milano,
777-797.

[203] Feichtinger, G. (Ed.) (1988). Optimal Control Theory and Economic


Analysis, Vol. 3, North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[204] Feichtinger, G. (1992). Optimal control of economic systems, in Auto-


matic Control Handbook, S.G. Tzafestas (Ed.), M. Dekker, New York,
1023-1044.

[205] Feichtinger, G. and Dockner, E.J. (1984). A note to J0rgensen's logarith-


mic advertising differential game, Zeitschrift fur Operations Research, 28,
B133-B153.

[206] Feichtinger, G. and Dockner, E.J. (1985). Optimal pricing in a duopoly:


a noncooperative differential games solution. Journal of Optimization
Theory and Applications, 45, 199-218.

[207] Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (1985a). Optimal pricing and production
in an inventory model, European Journal of Operational Research, 19,
45-56.

[208] Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (1985b). On the use of Hamiltonian and
maximized Hamiltonian in non-differentiable control theory, Journal of
Optimization Theory & Applications, 46, 493-504.
Bibliography 433

[209] Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (1986). Optimale Kontrolle Okonomischer


Prozesse: Anwendungen des Maximumprinzips in den Wirtschaftswis-
senschaften, Walter De Gruyter, Berlin.

[210] Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (Eds.) (1992). Nonlinear methods in eco-
nomic dynamics and optimal control, Annals of Operations Research, 37,
Baltzer, Basel.

[211] Feichtinger, G., Hartl, R.F., Haunschmied, J. and Kort, RM. (1998).
Optimal enforcement policies (crackdowns) on a drug market. Optimal
Control Applications & Methods, 19, 169-184.

[212] Feichtinger, G., Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1994). Dynamic optimal con-
trol models in advertising: recent developments. Management Science,
40, 2, 195-226.

[213] Feichtinger, G. and J0rgensen, S. (1983). Differential game models in


management science, European Journal of Operational Research, 14, 137-
155.

[214] Feichtinger, G., J0rgensen, S. and Novak, A. (1999). Petrarch's Can-


zoniere: rational addiction and amorous cycles. Journal of Mathematical
Sociology, 23, 3, 225-240.

[215] Feichtinger, G., Kaitala, V.T. and Novak, A. (1992). Stable resource-
employment limit cycles in an optimally regulated fishery, in Dynamic
Economic Models and Optimal Control, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-
Holland, Amsterdam, 163-184.

[216] Feichtinger, G., Luhmer, A. and Sorger, G. (1988). Optimal price and
advertising policy in convenience goods retailing. Marketing Science, 7,
187-201.

[217] Feichtinger, G. and Mehlmann, A. (1986). Planning the unusual: appli-


cations of control theory to non-standard problems, Acta Appl. Math., 7,
79-102.

[218] Feichtinger, G. and Novak, A. (1992a). Optimal consumption, training,


working time and leisure over the life cycle. Journal of Optimization
Theory and Applications, 75, 369-388.

[219] Feichtinger, G. and Novak, A. (1992b). A note on the optimal exploitation


of migratory fish stocks. Dynamics and Control, 2, 255-263.

[220] Feichtinger, G. and Novak, A. (1994). Optimal pulsing in an advertising


diflFusion model, Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 15, 267-276.
434 Bibliography

[221] Feichtinger, G., Novak, A. and Wirl, F. (1994). Limit cycles in intertem-
poral adjustment models - theory and applications, Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, 18, 353-380.

[222] Feichtinger, G. and Sorger, G. (1986). Optimal oscillations in control


models: how can constant demand lead to cyclical production?. Opera-
tions Research Letters, 5, 277-281.

[223] Feichtinger, G. and Sorger, G. (1988). Periodic research and development,


in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis 3, Third Viennese
Workshop on Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis, Vienna,
May 20 - 22, 1987, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam,
121-141.

[224] Feichtinger, G. and Wirl, F. (1993). A dynamic variant of the battle of


the sexes. International Journal of Game Theory, 22, 359-380.

[225] Feinberg, F.M. (1992). Pulsing policies for aggregate advertising models,
Marketing Science, 11, 3, 221-234.

[226] Fel'dbaum, A.A. (1965). Optimal Control Systems, Academic Press, New
York.

[227] Ferreira, M.M.A. and Vinter, R.B. (1994). When is the maximum prin-
ciple for state constrained problems nondegenerate?. Journal of Mathe-
matical Analysis and Applications, 187, 438-467.

[228] Ferreyra, G. (1990). The optimal control problem for the Vidale-Wolfe
advertising model revisited, Optimal Control Applications & Methods,
11, 363-368.

[229] Filipiak, J. (1982). Optimal control of store-and-forward networks. Opti-


mal Control Applications & Methods, 3, 155-176.

[230] Fischer, T. (1985). Hierarchical optimization methods for the coordina-


tion of decentralized management planning, in Optimal Control Theory
and Economic Analysis 2, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amster-
dam.

[231] Fleming, W.H. and Rishel, R.W. (1975). Deterministic and Stochastic
Optimal Control, Springer-Verlag. New York.

[232] Fleming, W.H. and Soner, H.M. (1992). Controlled Markov Processes and
Viscosity Solutions, Springer-Verlag, New York.

[233] Fletcher, R. and Reeves, C M . (1964). Function minimization by conju-


gate gradients. Computer Journal, 7, 149-154.
Bibliography 435

[234] Forster, B.A. (1973). Optimal consumption planning in a polluted envi-


ronment, Economic Record, 49, 534-545.

[235] Forster, B.A. (1977). On a one state variable optimal control problem:
consumption-pollution trade-offs, in Applications of Control Theory to
Economic Analysis, J.D. Pitchford and S.J. Turnovsky (Eds.), North-
Holland, Amsterdam.

[236] Fourgeaud, C , Lenclud, B. and Michel, P. (1982). Technological renewal


of natural resource stocks. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,
4, 1-36.

[237] Francis, P.J. (1997). Dynamic epidemiology and the market for vaccina-
tions, Journal of Public Economics, 63, 3, 383-406.

[238] Frankena, J.F. (1975). Optimal control problems with delay, the maxi-
mum principle and necessary conditions. Journal of Eng. Math., 9, 53-64.

[239] Friedman, A. (1964). Optimal control for hereditary processes. Archive


Rational Mechanics Analysis, 15, 396-416.

[240] Friedman, A. (1971). Differential Games, Wiley, New York.

[241] Friedman, A. (1977). Oligopoly and the Theory of Games, North-Holland,


Amsterdam.

[242] Friedman, A. (1986). Game Theory with Applications to Economics, Ox-


ford University Press, New York.

[243] Fruchter, G.E. (1999). The many-player advertising game. Management


Science, 45, 11, 1609-1611.

[244] Fruchter, G.E. (1999). Oligopoly advertising strategies with market ex-
pansion, Optimal Control Application & Methods, 20, 199-211.

[245] Fruchter, G.E. and S. Kalish (1997). Closed-loop advertising strategies


in a duopoly, Management Science, 43, 54-63.

[246] Fuller, D. and Vickson, R.G. (1987). The optimal construction of new
plants for oil from the Alberta tar sands, Operations Research, 35, 5,
704-715.

[247] Funke, U.H. (1976). Mathematical Models in Marketing: A Collection of


Abstracts, Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, Vol.
132, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

[248] Gaimon, C. (1985a). The acquisition of automation subject to diminish-


ing returns, HE Transactions, 17, 147-156.
436 Bibliography

[249] Gaimon, C. (1985b). The optimal acquisition of automation to enhance


the productivity of labor, Management Science^ 3 1 , 1175-1190.

[250] Gaimon, C. (1986a). An impulsive control approach to deriving the op-


timal dynamic mix of manual and automatic output, European Journal
of Operational Research, 24, 360-368.

[251] Gaimon, C. (1986b). The optimal times and levels of impulsive acquisi-
tion of automation. Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 7, 259-270.

[252] Gaimon, C. (1986c). The optimal acquisition of new technology and its
impact on dynamic pricing policies. Studies in Management Science and
Systems, B. Lev (Ed.), 13, 187-206.

[253] Gaimon, C. (1988). Simultaneous and dynamic price, production, inven-


tory, and capacity decisions, European Journal of Operational Research,
35, 426-441.

[254] Gaimon, C. (1989). Dynamic game results on the acquisition of new


technology. Operations Research, 37, 3, 410-425.

[255] Gaimon, C. (1994). Subcontracting versus capacity expansion and the


impact on the pricing of services. Naval Research Logistics, 4 1 , 7, 875-
892.

[256] Gaimon, C. (1997). Planning information technology - knowledge worker


systems. Management Science, 43, 9, 1308-1328.

[257] Gaimon, C. and Thompson, G.L. (1984a). Optimal preventive and repair
maintenance of a machine subject to failure. Optimal Control Applica-
tions & Methods, 5, 57-67.

[258] Gaimon, C. and Thompson, G.L. (1984b). A distributed parameter co-


hort personnel planning model using cross-sectional data. Management
Science, 30, 750-764.

[259] Gaimon, C. and Thompson, G.L. (1989). Optimal preventive and repair
maintenance of a machine subject to failure and a declining resale value,
Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 10, 211-228.

[260] Gamkrelidze, R.V. (1978). Principles of Optimal Control Theory, Plenum


Press, New York.

[261] Gandolfo, G. (1980). Economic Dynamics: Methods and Models, North-


Holland, Amsterdam.

[262] Gaskins, Jr., D.W. (1971). Dynamic limit pricing: optimal pricing under
threat of entry. Journal of Economic Theory, 3, 306-322.
Bibliography 437

[263] Gaugusch, J. (1984). The non-cooperative solution of a differential game:


advertising versus pricing, Optimal Control Applications & Methods^ 5,
4, 353-360.

[264] Gelfand, I.M. and Fomin, S.V. (1963). Calculus of Variations, Prentice-
Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

[265] Gerchak, Y. and Parlar, M. (1985). Optimal control analysis of a simple


criminal prosecution model, Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 6,
305-312.

[266] Gfrerer, H. (1984). Optimization of hydro energy storage plant problems


by variational methods, Zeitschrift filr Operations Research, 28, B87-
BlOl.

[267] Gihman, LI. and Skorohod, A.V. (1972). Stochastic Differential Equa-
tions, Springer-Verlag, New York.

[268] Girsanov, I.V. (1972). Lectures on Mathematical Theory of Extremum


Problems, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

[269] Glad, S.T. (1979). A combination of penalty function and multiplier


methods for solving optimal control problems. Journal of Optimization
Theory and Applications, 28, 303-329.

[270] Goh, B.-S. (1980). Management and Analysis of Biological Populations,


Elsevier, Amsterdam.

[271] Goh, B.-S., Leitmann, G. and Vincent, T.L. (1974). Optimal control of
a prey-predator system. Mathematical Biosciences, 19, 263-286.

[272] Goldberg, S. (1986). Introduction to Difference Equations, Dover Publi-


cations, New York.

[273] Goldstine, H.H. (1980). A History of the Calculus of Variations from the
17th through the 19th Century, Springer-Verlag, New York.

[274] Gopalsamy, K. (1976). Optimal control of age-dependent populations,


Math. Biosci., 32, 155-163.

[275] Gordon, H.S. (1954). Economic theory of a common-property resource:


the fishery. Journal of Political Economy, 62, 124-142.

[276] Gordon, M.J. (1962). The Investment, Financing and Valuation of the
Corporation, Richard D. Irwin, Inc., Homewood, 111.

[277] Gould, J.P. (1970). Diffusion processes and optimal advertising policy,
in Microeconomic Foundation of Employment and Inflation Theory, E.S.
Phelps et al. (Eds.), Norton, New York, 338-368.
438 Bibliography

[278] Grimm, W., Well, K.H. and Oberle, H.J. (1986). Periodic control for
Minimum-fuel aircraft trajectories, Journal of Guidance, 9, 169-174.

[279] Gross, M. and Lieber, Z. (1984). Competitive monopolistic and efficient


utilization of an exhaustible resource in the presence of habit-formation
effects and stock dependent costs, Econ. Letters, 14, 383-388.

[280] Hadley, G. and Kemp, M.C. (1971). Variational Methods in Economics,


North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[281] Hahn, M. and Hyun, J.S. (1991). Advertising cost interpretations and
the optimality of pulsing. Management Science, 37, 2, 157-169.

[282] Halkin, H. (1966). A maximum principle of the Pontryagin type for sys-
tems described by nonlinear difference equations, SI AM Journal on Con-
trol, 4, 90-111.

[283] Halkin, H. (1967). On the necessary condition for optimal control of non-
linear systems, in Topics in Optimization, G. Leitmann (Ed.), Academic
Press, New York.

[284] Hamalainen, R.P., Haurie, A. and Kaitala, V.T. (1984). Bargaining on


whales: a differential game model with Pareto optimal equilibria. Oper-
ations Research Letters, 3, 1, 5-11.

[285] Hamalainen, R.P., Haurie, A. and Kaitala, V.T. (1985). Equilibria and
threats in a fishery management game. Optimal Control Applications &
Methods, 6, 315-333.

[286] Hamalainen, R.P., Ruusunen, J. and Kaitala, V.T. (1986). Myopic Stack-
elberg equilibria and social coordination in a share contract fishery. Ma-
rine Resource Economics, 3, 3, 209-235.
<j, %^, ^ ,

[287] Hamalainen, R.P., Ruusunen, J. and Kaitala, V.T. (1990). Cartels and
dynamic contracts in sharefishing, Journal of Environmental Economics
and Management, 19, 175-192.

[288] Han, M., Feichtinger, G. and Hartl, R.F. (1994). Nonconcavity and
proper optimal periodic control. Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control, 18, 976-990.

[289] Hanssens, D.M., Parsons, L.J. and Schultz, R. L. (1990). Market Re-
sponse Models: Econometric and Time Series Analysis, Kluwer Aca-
demic Publishers, Boston.

[290] Harris, F.W. (1913). How many parts to make at once. Factory, The
Magazine of Management, 10, 135-136, 152.
Bibliography 439

[291] Harris, H. (1976). Optimal planning under transaction costs: the demand
for money and other assets, Journal of Economic Theory, 12, 298-314.

[292] Harrison, J.M. and Pliska, S.R. (1981). Martingales, stochastic integrals,
and continuous trading, Stochastic Process. Appl, 11, 215-260.

[293] Hartberger, R. J. (1973). A proof of the Pontryagin maximum principle for


initial-value problem, Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications,
11, 139-145.

[294] Hartl, R.F. (1982a). A mixed linear/nonlinear optimization model of pro-


duction and maintenance for a machine, in Optimal Control Theory and
Economic Analysis, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam,
43-58.

[295] Hartl, R.F. (1982b). Optimal control of non-linear advertising models


with replenishable budget. Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 3,
1, 53-65.

[296] Hartl, R.F. (1982c). Optimal control of concave economic models with
two control instruments, in Operations Research in Progress, G. Fe-
ichtinger and P. Kail (Eds.), D. Reidel Publishing Company, Dordrecht,
Holland, 227-245.

[297] Hartl, R.F. (1983a). Optimal allocation of resources in the production of


human capital. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 34, 599-606.

[298] Hartl, R.F. (1983b). Optimal maintenance and production rates for a
machine: a nonlinear economic control problem. Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, 6, 281-306.

[299] Hartl, R.F. (1984). Optimal dynamic advertising policies for hereditary
processes. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 43, 1, 51-72.

[300] Hartl, R.F. (1986a). A forward algorithm for a generalized wheat trading
model, Zeitschrift filr Operations Research, 30, A 135-A 144.

[301] Hartl, R.F. (1986b). Arrow-type sufficient optimality conditions for non-
difFerentiable optimal control problems with state constraints, Applied
Mathematics & Optimization, 14, 229-247.

[302] Hartl, R.F. (1987). A simple proof of the monotonicity of the state tra-
jectories in autonomous control problems. Journal of Economic Theory,
40, 211-215.

[303] Hartl, R.F. (1988a). A wheat trading model with demand and spoilage,
in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis, G. Feichtinger (Ed.),
Vol. 3, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 235-244.
440 Bibliography

[304] Hartl, R.F. (1988b). A dynamic activity analysis for a monopolistic firm,
Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 9, 253-272.

[305] Hartl, R.F. (1988c). The control of environmental pollution and opti-
mal investment and employment decisions: a comment, Optimal Control
Applications & Methods, 9, 337-339.

[306] Hartl, R.F. (1989a). On forward algorithms for a generalized wheat trad-
ing model, in Progress in Inventory Research (Proceedings of 4th Interna-
tional Symposium on Inventories), A. Chikan (Ed.), Hungarian Academy
of Science, Budapest.

[307] Hartl, R.F. (1989b). Most rapid approach paths in dynamic economic
problems, in Methods of Operations Research 58 (Proceedings of SOR
12, 1987), P. Kleinschmidt et al. (Eds.), Athenaun, 397-410.

[308] Hartl, R.F. (1992). Optimal acquisition of pollution control equipment


under uncertainty. Management Science, 38, 609-622.

[309] Hartl, R.F. (1993). On the properness of one-dimensional periodic control


problems. Systems & Control Letters, 20, 3, 393-395.

[310] Hartl, R.F. (1995). Production smoothing under environmental con-


straints, Production and Operations Management, 4, 1, 46-56.

[311] Hartl, R.F. and Feichtinger, G. (1987). A new sufficient condition for most
rapid approach paths. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications,
54, 2, 403-411.

[312] Hartl, R.F., Feichtinger, G. and Kirakossian, G.T. (1992). Optimal re-
cycling of tailings for the production of building materials, Czechoslovak
Journal of Operations Research, 1,3, 181-192.

[313] Hartl, R.F. and J0rgensen, S. (1985). Optimal manpower policies in a dy-
namic staff-maximizing bureau, Optimal Control Application & Methods,
6, 1, 57-64.

[314] Hartl, R.F. and J0rgensen, S. (1988). Aspects of optimal slidesmanship,


in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis, G. Feichtinger (Ed.),
Vol. 3, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 335-350.

[315] Hartl, R.F. and J0rgensen, S. (1990). Optimal slidesmanship in confer-


ences with unpredictable chairmen. Optimal Control Application & Meth-
ods, 1 1 , 143-155.

[316] Hartl, R.F. and Kort, P.M. (1996a). Marketable permits in a stochastic
dynamic model of the firm. Journal of Optimization Theory and Appli-
cations, 89, 1, 129-155.
Bibliography 441

[317] Hartl, R.F. and Kort, P.M. (1996b). Capital accumulation of a firm facing
an environmental tax scheme, Journal of Economics, 63, 1, 1-23.

[318] Hartl, R.F. and Kort, P.M. (1996c). Capital accumulation of a firm facing
environmental constraints. Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 17,
253-266.

[319] Hartl, R.F. and Kort, P.M. (1997). Optimal input substitution of a firm
facing an environmental constraint, European Journal of Operational Re-
search, 99, 1.

[320] Hartl, R.F., Kort, P.M. and Novak, A. (1999). Optimal investment facing
possible accidents. Annals of Operations Research, 88, 99-117.

[321] Hartl, R.F. and Krauth, J. (1989). Optimal production mix. Journal of
Optimization Theory and Applications, 66, 255-273.

[322] Hartl, R.F. and Luptacik, M. (1992). Environmental constraints and


choice of technology, Czechoslovak Journal of Operations Research, 1,
2, 107-125.

[323] Hartl, R.F. and Mehlmann, A. (1982). The Transylvanian problem of


renewable resources. Revue Prancaise d'Automatique, Informatique et de
Recherche Operationelle, 16, 379-390.

[324] Hartl, R.F. and Mehlmann, A. (1983). Convex-concave utility function:


optimal blood-consumption for vampires. Applied Mathematical Mod-
elling, 7, 83-88.

[325] Hartl, R.F. and Mehlmann, A. (1984). Optimal seducing policies for dy-
namic continuous lovers under risk of being killed by a rival. Cybernetics
& Systems: An Intern. J., 15, 119-126.

[326] Hartl, R.F. and Mehlmann, A. (1986). On remuneration patterns for


medical services. Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 7, 185-193.

[327] Hartl, R.F., Mehlmann, A. and Novak, A. (1992). Cycles of fear: opti-
mal periodic blood-sucking rates for vampires. Journal of Optimization
Theory and Applications, 75, 3, 559-568.

[328] Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1983). A note on the free terminal time
transversality condition, Zeitschrift fur Operations Research^ Series:
Theory, 27, 5, 203-208.

[329] Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1984a). Optimal control problems with
differential inclusions: sufficiency conditions and an application to a
production-inventory model. Optimal Control Applications & Methods,
5, 4, 289-307.
442 Bihliography

[330] Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1984b). Optimal control of a class of systems
with continuous lags: dynamic programming approach and economic in-
terpretations, Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 43, 1,
73-88.

[331] Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1985a). Solution of generalized linear optimal
control problems using a simplex-like method in continuous-time I: the-
ory, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis 2, G. Feichtinger,
(Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 45-62.

[332] Hartl, R.F. and Sethi, S.P. (1985b). Solution of generalized linear op-
timal control problems using a simplex-like method in continuous-time
H: examples, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis 2, G.
Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 63-87.

[333] Hartl, R.F., Sethi, S.P. and Vickson, R.G. (1995). A survey of the max-
imum principles for optimal control problems with state constraints,
SIAM Review, 37, 2, 181-218.

[334] Harvey, A.C. (1994). Forecasting, Structural Time Series Models and the
Kalman Filter, Cambridge University Press, New York.

[335] Haurie, A. (1976). Optimal control on an infinite time horizon: the turn-
pike approach, J. Math. Economics, 3, 81-102.

[336] Haurie, A. and Hung, N.M. (1977). Turnpike properties for the optimal
use of a natural resource. Review of Economic Studies, 44, 329-336.

[337] Haurie, A. and Leitmann, G. (1984). On the global asymptotic stability of


equilibrium solutions for open-loop differential games. Large Scale Syst.,
6, 107-122.

[338] Haurie, A. and Sethi, S.P. (1984). Decision and forecast horizons, agree-
able plans, and the maximum principle for infinite horizon control prob-
lems, Operations Research Letters, 3, 5, 261-265.

[339] Haurie, A., Sethi, S.P. and Hartl, R.F. (1984). Optimal control of an age-
structured population model with applications to social services planning,
J. of Large Scale Systems, 6, 133-158.

[340] Haurie, A., Tolwinski, B. and Leitmann, G. (1983). Cooperative equilib-


ria in differential games. Proceedings ACC, San Francisco.

[341] Haussmann, U. G. (1981). Some examples of optimal stochastic controls


or: the stochastic maximum principle at work, SIAM Review, 23, 292-
307.
Bibliography 443

[342] Heal, G.M. (1976). The relationship between price and extraction cost
for a resource with a backstop technology, Bell Journal of Economics, 7,
371-378.

[343] Heaps, T. (1984). The forestry maximum principle, Journal of Economic


Dynamics and Control, 7, 131-151.

[344] Heckman, J. (1976). A Hfe cycle model of earnings, learning, and con-
sumption, Journal of Political Economy, 84, 511-544.

[345] Hestenes, M.R. (1966). Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control The-
ory, Wiley, New York.

[346] Ho, Y.-C. (1970). Differential games, dynamic optimization and general-
ized control theory. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 6,
179-209.

[347] Hoffmann, K.H. and Krabs, W. (1984). Optimal Control of Partial Dif-
ferential Equations, Birkhauser, Basel.

[348] Holly, S., Riistem, B. and Zarrop, M.B. (Eds.) (1979). Optimal Control
for Econometric Models. An Approach to Economic Policy Formulation,
Macmillan, London.

[349] Holt, C.C, Modigliani, F., Muth, J.F. and Simon, H.A. (1960). Planning
Production^ Inventories and Workforce, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs,
NJ.

[350] Holtzman, J.M. (1966). On the maximum principle for nonlinear discrete-
time systems, IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-11, 273-
274.

[351] Horsky, D. (1977). An empirical analysis of the optimal advertising policy,


Management Science, 23, 10, 1037-1049.

[352] Horsky, D. and Mate, K. (1988). Dynamic advertising strategies of com-


peting durable good producers. Marketing Science, 7, 4, 356-367.

[353] Horsky, D. and Simon, L.S. (1983). Advertising and the diffusion of new
products. Marketing Science, 2, 1, 1-17.

[354] Hotelling, H. (1925). A general mathematical theory of depreciation,


Journal of Amer. Statist. Assoc, 20, 340-353.

[355] Hotelling, H. (1931). The economics of exhaustible resources. Journal of


Political Economy, 39, 137-175.

[356] Hwang, C.L., Fan, L.T. and Erickson, L.E. (1967), Optimal production
planning by the maximum principle, Management Science, 13, 750-755.
444 Bibliography

[357] Ijiri, Y. and Thompson, G.L. (1970). Applications of mathematical con-


trol theory to accounting and budgeting (the continuous wheat trading
model), The Accounting Review^ 45, 246-258.

[358] Ijiri, Y. and Thompson, G.L. (1972). Mathematical control theory solu-
tion of an interactive accounting flows model. Naval Research Logistics
Quarterly, 19, 411-422.

[359] Intriligator, M.D. (1971). Mathematical Optimization and Economic The-


ory, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

[360] Intriligator, M.D. (1980). Applications of control theory to economics, in


Analysis and Optimization of Systems, Lecture Notes in Control and
Information Sciences, A. Bensoussan and J.L. Lions (Eds.), Vol. 28,
Springer-Verlag, BerHn, 607-626.

[361] Intriligator, M.D. and Smith, B.L.R. (1966). Some aspects of the allo-
cation of scientific effort between teaching and research, American Eco-
nomic Review, 6 1 , 494-507.

[362] loffe, A.D. and Tihomirov, V.M. (1979). Theory of Extremal Problems,
North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[363] Isaacs, R. (1965). Differential Games, Wiley, New York.

[364] Isaacs, R. (1969). Differential games: their scope, nature, and future,
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 3, 283-295.

[365] Jacobson, D.H., Lele, M.M. and Speyer, J.L. (1971) New necessary con-
ditions of optimality for control problems with state-variable inequality
constraints, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 35, 255-
284.

[366] Jacquemin, A.P. (1973). Optimal control and advertising policy, Metro-
Economica, 25, 200-207.

[367] Jacquemin, A.R and Thisse, J. (1972). Strategy of the firm and market
structure: an application of optimal control theory, in Market Structure
and Corporate Behavior, K. Cowling (Ed.), Gray-Mills, London, 61-84.

[368] Jagpal, S. (1999). Marketing Strategy and Uncertainty, Oxford University


Press, New York.

[369] Jamshidi, M. (1983). Large-Scale Systems: Modelling and Control, North-


Holland, New York.

[370] Jazwinski, A.H. (1970). Stochastic Processes and Filtering Theory, Aca-
demic Press, New York.
Bibliography 445

[371] Jedidi, K., Eliashberg, J. and DeSarbo, W. (1989). Optimal advertising


and pricing for a three-stage time-lagged monopolistic diffusion model
incorporating income, Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 10, 313-
331.

[372] Jennings, L.S., Sethi, S.P. and Teo, K.L. (1997). Computation of optimal
production plans for manufacturing systems. Nonlinear Analysis^ Theory^
Methods & Applications, 30, 7, 4329-4338.

[373] Jennings, L.S. and Teo, K.L. (1997). Computation of manufacturing sys-
tems using an enhancing control, in IPMM'97: Australiasia-Pacific Fo-
rum on Intelligent Processing & Manufacturing of Materials, Vol. 1, T.
Chandra, S.R. Leclair, J.A. Meech, B. Verma, M. Smith, and B. Bal-
achandran (Eds.), Watson Ferguson & Co., Brisbane, Australia.

[374] Jeuland, A.P. and Dolan, R.J. (1982). An aspect of new product plan-
ning: dynamic pricing, in Marketing Planning Models, TIMS Studies in
the Management Science, A.A. Zoltners (Ed.), Vol. 18, North-Holland,
Amsterdam, 1-21.

[375] Jiang, J. and Sethi, S.P. (1991). A state aggregation approach to man-
ufacturing systems having machine states with weak and strong interac-
tions, Operations Research, 39, 6, 970-978.

[376] Johnson, C D . and Gibson, J.E. (1963). Singular solutions in problems of


optimal control, IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-8, 4-15.

[377] Jones, P. 1983). Analysis of a dynamic duopoly model of advertising,


Mathematics of Operations Research, 8, 1, 122-134.

[378] J0rgensen, S., (1982a). A survey of some differential games in advertising,


Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 4, 341-369.

[379] J0rgensen, S., (1982b). A differential games solution to a logarithmic


advertising model. Operations Research Soc, 33, 5, 425-432.

[380] J0rgensen, S., (1983). Optimal control of a diffusion model of new product
acceptance with price-dependent total market potential. Optimal Control
Application & Methods, 4, 3, 269-276.

[381] J0rgensen, S., (1984). A Pareto-optimal solution of a maintenance-


production differential game, European Journal of Operational Research,
18, 76-80.

[382] J0rgensen, S., (1985). An exponential differential game which admits a


simple Nash solution. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications,
45, 383-396.
446 Bibliography

[383] J0rgensen, S., (1986a). Optimal production, purchasing and pricing: a


differential games approach, European Journal of Operational Research,
24, 64-76.

[384] J0rgensen, S., (1986b). Optimal dynamic pricing in an oligopolistic mar-


ket: a survey, in Dynamic Games and Applications in Economics, T.
Basar (Ed.), Springer-Verlag, Berhn, 179-237.

[385] J0rgensen, S. (1992). The dynamics of extramarital affairs, in Dynamic


Economic Models and Optimal Control, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-
Holland, Amsterdam, 239-266.

[386] J0rgensen, S. and Dockner, E.J. (1985). Optimal consumption and re-
plenishment policies for a renewable resource, in Optimal Control Theory
and Economic Analysis 2, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amster-
dam, 647-664.

[387] J0rgensen, S. and Kort, P.M. (1993). Optimal dynamic investment poli-
cies under concave-convex adjustment costs, Journal of Economic Dy-
namics and Control, 17, 1/2, 153-180.

[388] J0rgensen, S. and Kort, P.M. (1997). Optimal investment and finance
in renewable resource harvesting, Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control, 2 1 , 603-630.

[389] J0rgensen, S., Kort, P.M. and Zaccour, G., (1999). Production, inventory,
and pricing under cost and demand learning effects, European Journal of
Operational Research, 117, 382-395.

[390] Joseph, P.D. and Tou, J.T. (1961). On hnear control theory. Trans.
AIEE, Part II, 80, 193-196.

[391] Journal of Marketing Research (1985). Special issue on competition in


marketing, 22, 3.

[392] Kaitala, V.T. (1986). Game theory models of fisheries management -


a survey, in Dynamic Games and Applications in Economics, T. Basar
(Ed.), Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 252-266.

[393] Kalish, S. (1983). Monopolist pricing with dynamic demand and produc-
tion cost. Marketing Science, 2, 2, 135-159.

[394] Kalish, S. (1985). A new product adoption model with price, advertising,
and uncertainty. Marketing Science, 3 1 , 12, 1569-1585.

[395] Kalish, S. and Lilien, G.L. (1983). Optimal price subsidy policy for ac-
celerating the diffusion of innovation. Marketing Science, 2, 4, 407-420.
Bibliography 447

[396] Kalish, S. and Sen, S.K. (1986). Diffusion models and the marketing mix
for single products, in Series in Econometrics and Management Science:
Innovation Diffusion Models of New Products Acceptance^ V. Mahajan
and Y. Wind (Eds.), Ballinger, Cambridge, MA, Vol. V, 87-116.

[397] Kalman, R.E. (1960a). A new approach to linear filtering and prediction
problems. Trans. ASME Ser. D: J. Basic Eng., 82, 35-45.

[398] Kalman, R.E. (1960b). Contributions to the theory of optimal control,


Bol. de Soc. Math. Mexicana, 102-119.

[399] Kalman, R.E. and Bucy, R. (1961). New results in linear filtering and
prediction theory. Trans. ASME Ser. D: J. Basic Eng., 83, 95-108.

[400] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1971a). Optimal maintenance and sale
age for a machine subject to failure. Management Science^ 17, 427-449.

[401] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1971b). Limit pricing and uncertain
entry, Econometrica, 39, 441-454.

[402] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1978). Optimal exhaustible resource
depletion with endogenous technical change. Review of Economic Studies,
45, 179-196.

[403] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1982a). Market Structure and Innova-
tion, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

[404] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1982b). The role of common property
resources in optimal planning models with exhaustible resources, in Ex-
plorations in Natural Resource Economics, V.K. Smith and J.V. Krutilla
(Eds.), John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, Maryland, 47-71.

[405] Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. (1998). Dynamic Optimization: The
Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control in Economics and Manage-
ment, Second Edition, Fourth Impression, North-Holland, New York.

[406] Kaplan, W. (1958). Ordinary Differential Equations, Addison-Wesley,


Reading, PA.

[407] Karatzas, I., Lehoczky, J.P., Sethi, S.P. and Shreve, S.E. (1986). Explicit
solution of a general consumption/investment problem. Mathematics of
Operations Research, 11, 2, 261-294.

[408] Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S.E. (1997). Brownian Motion and Stochastic
Calculus, Second Edition, Springer-Verlag, New York.

[409] Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S.E. (1998). Methods of Mathematical Finance,


Springer-Verlag, New York.
448 Bibliography

[410] Keeler, E., Spence, M. and Zeckhauser, R.J. (1971). The optimal control
of pollution. Journal of Economic Theory^ 4, 19-34.

[411] Keller, H.B. (1968). Numerical Methods for Two-Point Boundary Value
Problems, Blaisdell, Waltham, Mass.

[412] Kemp, M.C. and Long, N.V. (1977). Optimal control problems with inte-
grands discontinuous with respect to time, Economic Record, 53, 405-420.

[413] Kemp, M.C. and Long, N.V. (Eds.) (1980). Exhaustible Resources, Opti-
mality, and Trade, North-Holland, Amsterdam,

[414] Kendrick, D.A. (1981). Stochastic Control for Economic Models,


McGraw-Hill, New York.

[415] Khmelnitsky, E. and Kogan, K. (1994). Necessary optimality conditions


for a generalized problem of production scheduling, Optimal Control Ap-
plications & Methods, 15, 215-222.

[416] Khmelnitsky, E. and Kogan, K. (1996). Optimal policies for aggregate


production and capacity planning under an arbitrary demand. Interna-
tional Journal of Production Research, 34, 7, 1929-1941.

[417] Khmelnitsky, E., Kogan, K. and Maimon, O. (1995). A maximum prin-


ciple based combined method for scheduling in a flexible manufacturing
system. Discrete Event Dynamic Systems, 5, 343-355.

[418] Khmelnitsky, E., Kogan, K. and Maimon, O. (1997). Maximum principle-


based methods for scheduling FMS with partially sequence dependent
setups, International Journal of Production Research, 35, 10, 2701-2712.

[419] Kilkki, P. and Vaisanen, U. (1969). Determination of optimal policy for


forest stands by means of dynamic programming. Acta Forestalia Fen-
nica, 102, 100-112.

[420] Kirby, B.J. (Ed.) (1974). Optimal Control Theory and its Applications,
Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, Part I k, H,
Vols. 105 & 106, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

[421] Kirk, D.E. (1970). Optimal Control Theory: An Introduction, Prentice-


Hall, Englewood ChfFs, NJ.

[422] Klein, C.F. and Gruver, W.A. (1978). On the optimal control of a single-
server queueing system: comment. Journal of Optimization Theory and
Applications,2%, 457-462.

[423] Kleindorfer, P.R. (1978). Stochastic control models in management sci-


ence: theory and computation, TIMS Studies in the Management Sci-
ences,9, 69-88.
Bibliography 449

[424] Kleindorfer, P.R., Kriebel, C.H., Thompson, G.L. and Kleindorfer, G.B.
(1975). Discrete optimal control of production plans, Management Sci-
ence, 22, 261-273.

[425] Kleindorfer, P.R. and Lieber, Z. (1979). Algorithms and planning horizon
results for production planning problems with separable costs. Operations
Research, 27, 874-887.

[426] Knobloch, H.W. (1981). Higher Order Necessary Conditions in Optimal


Control Theory, Lecture Notes in Control and Information Sciences, Vol.
34, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

[427] Knowles, G. (1981). An Introduction to Applied Optimal Control, Aca-


demic Press, New York.

[428] Kogan, K. and Khmelnitsky, E. (1996). An optimal control model for


continuous time production and setup scheduling, International Journal
of Production Research, 34, 3, 715-725.

[429] Kogan, K., Khmelnitsky, E., Shtub, A. and Maimon, O. (1997). Optimal
flow control of flexible manufacturing systems: setup localization by an
iterative procedure. International Journal of Production Economics, 51,
37-46.

[430] Kotowitz, Y. and Mathewson, F. (1979a). Informative advertising and


welfare, American Economic Review, 69, 284-294.

[431] Kotowitz, Y. and Mathewson, F. (1979b). Advertising, consumer infor-


mation, and product quality. Bell J. Economics, 10, 566-588.

[432] Kreindler, E. (1982). Additional necessary conditions for optimal con-


trol with state-variable inequality constraints. Journal of Optimization
Theory and Applications, 38, 241-250.

[433] Krelle, W. (1984). Economic growth with exhaustible resources and en-
vironmental protection, Zeitschrift fiir ges. Staatswiss, 140, 399-429.

[434] Krichagina, E., Lou, S., Sethi, S.P. and Taksar, M.I. (1993). Production
control in a failure-prone manufacturing system: diffusion approximation
and asymptotic optimality. Annals of Applied Probability, 3, 2, 421-453.

[435] Krichagina, E., Lou, S., Sethi, S.P. and Taksar, M.I. (1995). Diffusion
approximation for a controlled stochastic manufacturing system with av-
erage cost minimization. Mathematics of Operations Research, 20, 4, 895-
922.

[436] Krouse, C.G. (1972). Optimal financing and capital structure programs
for the firm. Journal of Finance, 27, 1057-1071.
450 Bibliography

[437] Krouse, C.G. and Lee, W.Y. (1973). Optimal equity financing of the
corporation, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 8, 539-563.

[438] Kugelmann, B. and Pesch, H.J. (1990). New general guidance method
in constrained optimal control, part 1: numerical method. Journal of
Optimization Theory and Applications, 67, 3, 421-435.

[439] Kurawarwala, A.A. and Matsuo, H. (1996). Forecasting and inventory


management of short life-cycle products. Operations Research, 44, 1,
131-150.

[440] Kurcyusz, S. and Zowe, J. (1979). Regularity and stability for the math-
ematical programming problem in Banach spaces. Applied Mathematics
& Optimization, 5, 49-62.

[441] Kushner, H.J. (1971). Introduction to Stochastic Control, Holt, Rinehart


& Winston, New York.

[442] Kushner, H.J. (1977). Probability Methods for Approximations in


Stochastic Control and for Elliptic Equations, Academic Press, New York.

[443] Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.G. (1977). Rules rather than discretion:
the inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85,
473-493.

[444] Lagunov, V.N. (1985). Introduction to Differential Games and Control


Theory, Hildermann, Berlin.

[445] Lansdowne, Z.F. (1970). The theory and applications of generalized lin-
ear control processes, technical report no. 10, Department of Operations
Research, Stanford University.

[446] Lasdon, L.S., Mitter, S.K., and Warren, A.D. (1967). The conjugate
gradient method for optimal control problems, IEEE Transactions on
Automatic Control, AC-12, 132-138.

[447] Leban, R. and Lesourne, J. (1983). Adaptive strategies of the firm


through a business cycle, J. of Economic Dynamics and Control, 5, 201-
234.

[448] Lee, E.B. and Markus, L. (1968). Foundations of Optimal Control Theory,
Wiley, New York.

[449] Legey, L., Ripper, M. and Varaiya, P.P. (1973). Effects of congestion on
the shape of the city. Journal of Economic Theory, 6,162-179.

[450] Lehoczky, J.P., Sethi, S.P., Soner H.M. and Taksar, M.L (1991). An
asymptotic analysis of hierarchical control of manufacturing systems un-
der uncertainty. Mathematics of Operations Research, 16, 3, 596-608.
Bibliography 451

[451] Leitmann, G. (Ed.) (1962). Optimization Techniques with Applications


to Aerospace Systems, Academic Press, New York.

[452] Leitmann, G. (1966). An Introduction to Optimal Control, McGraw-Hill,


New York.

[453] Leitmann, G. (Ed.) (1967). Topics in Optimization, Academic Press, New


York.

[454] Leitmann, G. (1968). Sufficiency theorems for optimal control. Journal


of Optimization Theory and Applications, 2, 285-292.

[455] Leitmann, G. (1974). Cooperative and Non-Cooperative Many Players


Differential Games, Springer-Verlag, Wien.

[456] Leitmann, G. (Ed.) (1976). Multicriteria Decision Making and Differen-


tial Games, Plenum Press, New York.

[457] Leitmann, G. (1981). The Calculus of Variations and Optimal control,


Plenum Press, New York.

[458] Leitmann, G. and Liu, P.-T. (1974). A differential game model of labor-
management negotiation during a strike. Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 13, 427-444.

[459] Leland, H.E. (1972). The dynamics of a revenue maximizing firm, Inter-
national Economic Review, 13, 376-385.

[460] Lele, M.M., Jacobson, D.H. and McCabe, J.L. (1971). Qualitative ap-
plication of a result in control theory to problems of economic growth,
International Economic Review, 12, 209-226.

[461] Leonard, D. and Long, N.V.(1992). Optimal Control Theory and Static
Optimization in Economics, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,
UK.

[462] Lesourne, J. (1973). Croissance Optimale des Entreprises, Dunod, Paris.

[463] Lesourne, J. and Leban, R. (1982). Control theory and the dynamics of
the firm: a survey, OR-Spektrum, 4, 1-14.

[464] Levine, J. and Thepot, J. (1982). Open loop and closed loop equilibria in
a dynamic duopoly, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis,
G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 143-156.

[465] Lewis, T.R. and Schmalensee, R. (1977). Non-convexity and optimal


exhaustion of renewable resources. International Economic Review, 18,
535-552.
452 Bibliography

[466] Lewis, T.R. and Schmalensee, R. (1979). Non-convexity and optimal har-
vesting strategies for renewable resources, Canadian J. of Economics, 12,
677-691.

[467] Lewis, T.R. and Schmalensee, R. (1982). Optimal use of renewable re-
sources with nonconvexities in production, in Essays in the Economics
of Renewable Resources, L.J. Mirman and P.F. Spulber (Eds.), North-
Holland, Amsterdam, 95-111.

[468] Li, G. and Rajagopalan, S. (1997). A learning curve model with knowl-
edge depreciation, European Journal of Operational Research, 105, 1,
143-154.

[469] Li, G. and Rajagopalan, S. (1998). Process improvement, quality and


learning effects. Management Science, 4A, 1517-1532.
[470] Lieber Z. (1973). An extension of Modigliani and Hohn's planning horizon
results. Management Science, 20, 319-330.
[471] Lieber Z. and Barnea, A. (1977). Dynamic optimal pricing to deter entry
under constrained supply. Operations Research, 25, 696-705.
[472] Lignell, J. and Tuominen, M.P.T. (1983). An advertising control model
of two state variables, European Journal of Operations Research, 24, 1,
77-84.

[473] Lintner, J. (1963). The cost of capital and optimal financing of corporate
growth. Journal of Finance, 23, 292-310.
[474] Lions, J.L. (1971). Optimal Control of Systems Governed by Partial Dif-
ferential Equations, Springer-Verlag, New York.

[475] Little, J.D.C. (1979). Aggregate advertising models: the state of the art,
Operations Res., 27, 4, 629-667.
[476] Little, J.D.C. (1986). Comment on "Advertising pulsing policies..." by
V. Mahajan and E. Muller, Marketing Science, 5, 2, 107-108.
[477] Liu, P.-T. (1980). Dynamic Optimization and Mathematical Economics,
Plenum Press, New York.
[478] Liu, P.-T. and Roxin, E.G. (Eds.) (1979). Differential Games and Control
Theory III, Marcel Dekker, Inc., New York.
[479] Liu, P.-T. and Sutinen, J.G. (Eds.) (1979). Control Theory in Mathemat-
ical Economics, Marcel Dekker, Inc., New York.
[480] Long, N.V. and Vousden, N. (1977). Optimal control theorems, in Appli-
cations of Control Theory in Economic Analysis, J.D. Pitchford and S.J.
Turnovsky (Eds.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 11-34.
Bibliography 453

[481] Loon, P.J.J.M., van (1983). A Dynamic Theory of the Firm: Production,
Finance and Investment, Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical
Systems, Vol. 218, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

[482] Lou, S., Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1994). Optimal feedback produc-
tion planning in a stochastic two-machine fiowshop, European Journal of
Operational Research, 73, 331-345.

[483] Lucas, Jr., R.E. (1971). Optimal management of a research and develop-
ment project. Management Science, 17, 679-697.

[484] Lucas, Jr., R.E. (1981). Optimal investment with rational expectations,
in Rational Expectations and Economic Practice, R.E. Lucas, Jr. and T.J.
Sargent (Eds.), G. Allen & Unwin, London, 55-66.

[485] Luenberger, D.G. (1969). Optimization by Vector Space Methods, Wiley,


New York.

[486] Luenberger, D.G. (1972). Mathematical programming and control the-


ory: trends of interplay, in Perspectives on Optimization, A.M. Geoffrion
(Ed.), Addison-Wesley, Reading, Mass.

[487] Luenberger, D.G. (1973). Introduction to Linear and Nonlinear Program-


ming, Addison-Wesley, Reading, Mass.

[488] Luenberger, D.G. (1975). A nonlinear economic control problem with a


linear feedback solution, IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, A C -
20, 184-191.

[489] Luenberger, D.G. (1979). Introduction to Dynamic Systems: Theory,


Models, and Applications, Wiley, New York.

[490] Luhmer, A., Steindl, A., Feichtinger, G., Hartl, R.F. and Sorger, G.
(1988). ADPULS in continuous time, European Journal of Operational
Research, 34, 2, 171-177.

[491] Lundin, R.A. and Morton, T.E. (1975). Planning horizons for the dy-
namic lot size model: protective procedures and computational results,
Operations Research, 23, 711-734.

[492] Luptacik, M. (1982). Optimal price and advertising policy under atom-
istic competition, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 4, 57-71.

[493] Luptacik, M. and Schubert, U. (1982). Optimal investment policy in pro-


ductive capacity and pollution abatement processes in a growing econ-
omy, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis, G. Feichtinger
(Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 231-243.
454 Bibliography

[494] Luus, R. (1993). Piecewise linear continuous optimal control by iterative


dynamic programming, Industrial and Engineering Chemistry Research,
32, 859-865.

[495] Macki, J. and Strauss, A. (1982). Introduction to Optimal Control Theory,


Springer-Verlag, New York.

[496] Magat, W.A., McCann, J.M. and Morey, R.C. (1986). When does lag
structure really matter in optimizing advertising expenditures?, Man-
agement Science, 32, 2, 182-193.

[497] Magat, W.A., McCann, J.M. and Morey, R.C. (1988). Reply to when
does lag structure really matter ... Indeed?, Management Science, 34, 7,
917-918.

[498] Magill, M.J.P. (1970). On a General Economic Theory of Motion,


Springer-Verlag, New York.

[499] Mahajan, V. and Muller, E. (1979). Innovation diffusion and new product
growth models in marketing. Journal Marketing, 43, 55-68.

[500] Mahajan, V. and Muller, E. (1986). Advertising pulsing policies for gen-
erating awareness for new products. Marketing Science, 5, 2, 89-111.

[501] Mahajan, V. and Peterson, R.A. (1978). Innovation diffusion in a dy-


namic potential adopter population. Management Science, 24, 1589-
1597.

[502] Mahajan, V. and Peterson, R.A. (1985). Models for Innovation Diffusion,
Sage, Beverly Hills.

[503] Mahajan, V. and Wind, Y. (Eds.) (1986). Innovation Diffusion Models


of New Product Acceptance, Ballinger, Cambridge, MA.

[504] Maimon, O., Khmelnitsky, E. and Kogan, K. (1998). Optimal Flow Con-
trol in Manufacturing Systems, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.

[505] Majumdar, M. and Mitra, T. (1983). Dynamic optimization with a non-


convex technology: the case of a linear objective function. Review of
Economic Studies, 50, 143-151.

[506] Malinowski, K. (1997). Sufficient optimality conditions for optimal con-


trol problems subject to state constraints, SIAM Journal on Control and
Optimization, 35, 205-227.

[507] Malliaris, A.G. and Brock, W.A. (1982). Stochastic Methods in Eco-
nomics and Finance, North-Holland, Elsevier Science Publishers, New
York.
Bibliography 455

[508] Mangasarian, O.L. (1966). Sufficient conditions for the optimal control
of nonlinear systems, SI AM Journal on Control^ 4, 139-152.

[509] Mangasarian, O.L. (1969). Nonlinear programming, McGraw-Hill, New


York.

[510] Mangasarian, O.L. and Fromovitz, S. (1967). A maximum principle in


mathematical programming, in Mathematical Theory of Control, A.V.
Balakrishman and L.W. Neustadt (Elds.), Academic Press, New York.

[511] Manh-Hung, N. (1974). Essays on the optimal dynamic exploitation of


natural resources and the social rate of discount, Ph.D. Dissertation,
University of Toronto.

[512] Martirena-Mantel, A.M. (1971). Optimal inventory and capital policy


under certainty. Journal of Economic Theory, 3, 241-253.

[513] Masse, P. (1962). Optimal Investment Decisions, Prentice- Hall, Engle-


wood Cliffs, NJ.

[514] Maurer, H. (1976). Numerical solution of singular control problems us-


ing multiple shooting techniques. Journal of Optimization Theory and
Applications, 18, 235-257.

[515] Maurer, H. (1977). On optimal control problems with bounded state


variables and control appearing linearly, SIAM Journal on Control and
Optimization, 15, 345-362.

[516] Maurer, H. (1979). Differential stability in optimal control problems. Ap-


plied Mathematics & Optimization, 5, 283-295.

[517] Maurer, H. (1981). First and second order sufficient optimality conditions
in mathematical programming and optimal control. Math. Programming
Stud., 14, 163-177.

[518] Maurer, H. and Wiegand, M. (1992). Numerical solution of a drug dis-


placement problem with bounded state variables, Optimal Control Ap-
plications & Methods, 13, 43-55.

[519] Maurer, H., Buskens, C. and Feichtinger, G. (1998). Solution techniques


for periodic control problems: a case study in production planning. Op-
timal Control Applications & Methods, 19, 185-203.

[520] Maurer, H. and Gillessen, W. (1975). Application of multiple shooting to


the numerical solution of optimal control problems with bounded state
variables. Computing, 15, 105-126.
456 Bibliography

[521] Mayne, D.Q. and Polak, E. (1987). An exact penalty function algorithm
for control problems with state and control constraints, IEEE Transac-
tions on Automatic Control, 32, 380-387.

[522] Mclntyre, J., and Paiewonsky, B. (1967). On Optimal Control with


Bounded State Variables, in Advances in Control Systems 5, C.T. Leon-
des/indexLeondes, C.T. (Ed.), Academic Press, New York.

[523] Mehra, R.K. (1975). An optimal control approach to national settlement


system planning, RM-75-58, International Institute of Applied Systems
Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria.

[524] Mehra, R.K. and Davis, R.E. (1972). Generahzed gradient method for
optimal control problems with inequality constraint and singular arcs,
IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-17, 69-79.

[525] Mehlmann, A. (1985). State transformations and the derivation of Nash


closed-loop equilibria for non-zero-sum differential games. Applied Math-
ematical Modelling, 9, 353-357.

[526] Mehlmann, A. (1988). Applied Differential Games, Plenum, New York.

[527] Mehlmann, A. (1997). Wer Gewinnt Das Spiel? - Spieltheorie in Fabeln


und Paradoxa, Vieweg, Braunschweig.

[528] Mehrez, A. (1983). A note on the comparison of two different formulations


of a risky R & D model, O. R. Letters, 2, 249-251.

[529] Merton, R.C. (1969). Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: the
continuous-time case. Rev. Economics & Statistics, 51, 247-257.

[530] Merton, R.C. (1971). Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a


continuous-time model. Journal of Economic Theory, 3, 373-413.

[531] Merton, R.C. (1973). An intertemporal capital asset pricing model,


Econometrica, 5, 867-888.

[532] Merton, R.C. (1982). On the microeconomic theory of investment under


uncertainty, in Handbook of Mathematical Economics, K.J. Arrow and
M.D. Intriligator (Eds.), Vol. II, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 601-669.

[533] Mesak, H.I. (1985). On modeling advertising pulsing decisions. Decision


Sciences, 16, 25-42.

[534] Mesak, H.I. and Darrat, A.F. (1992). On comparing alternative advertis-
ing policies for pulsation. Decision Sciences, 23, 541-564.
Bibliography 457

[535] Michel, P. (1981). Choice of projects and their starting dates: an exten-
sion of Pontryagin's maximum principle to a case which allows choice
among different possible evolution equations, Journal of Economic Dy-
namics and Control, 3, 97-118.

[536] Michel, P. (1982). On the transversality condition in infinite horizon op-


timal control problems, Econometrica, 50, 975-985.

[537] Michel, P. (1985). Application of optimal control theory to disequilib-


rium analysis, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis 2, G.
Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 417-427.

[538] Miele, A. (1962). Extremization of linear integral equations by Green's


theorem, in Optimization Techniques, G. Leitmann (Ed.), Academic
Press, New York.

[539] Miller, M.H. and Modigliani, F. (1961). Dividend policy, growth, and
valuation of shares, The Journal of Business, 34, 411-433.

[540] Miller, R.E. (1979). Dynamic Optimization and Economic Applications,


McGraw-Hill, New York.

[541] Mirman, L.J. and Spulber, P.F. (Eds.) (1982). Essays in the Economics
of Renewable Resources, North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[542] Mirrlees, J. (1967). Optimum growth when technology is changing. Re-


view of Economic Studies, 34, 95-124.

[543] Mirrlees, J. (1972. The optimum town, Swedish J. of Economics, 74,


114-135.

[544] Modigliani, F. and Hohn, F. (1955). Production planning over time,


Econometrica, 23, 46-66.

[545] Moiseev, N.N. (1971). Numerical Methods in Optimal Control Theory,


Nauka, Moscow.

[546] Monahan, G.E. (1984). A pure birth model of optimal advertising with
word-of-mouth, Marketing Sc, 3, 2, 169-178.

[547] Mond, B. and Hanson, M. (1968). Duality for control problems, SI AM


Journal on Control, 6, 114-120.

[548] Morton, T.E., Mitchell, A. and Zemel, E. (1982). A discrete maximum


principle approach to a general dynamic market response model, TIMS
Studies in the Management Sciences, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 18,
117-140.
458 Bibliography

[549] Morton, T.E. (1978). Universal planning horizons for generalized convex
production scheduling, Operations Research, 26, 1046-1057.

[550] Motta, M. and F. Rampazzo (1996). Dynamic programming for nonUnear


systems driven by ordinary and impulsive controls, SIAM Journal on
Control and Optimization, 34, 1, 199-225.

[551] MuUer, E. (1983). Trial/awareness advertising decision: a control prob-


lem with phase diagrams with non-stationary boundaries, J. Economic
Dynamics and Control, 6, 333-350.

[552] Murata, Y. (1982). Optimal Control Methods for Linear Discrete-Time


Economic Systems, Springer-Verlag, New York.

[553] Murray, D.M. and Yakowitz, S.J. (1984). Differential dynamic program-
ming and Newton's methods for discrete optimal control problems, Jour-
nal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 43, 3, 395-414.

[554] Muzicant, J. (1980). Systeme mit verteilten Parametern in der


Biookonomie: Ein Maximumprinzip zur Kontrolle altersstrukturierter
Modelle, Diss., Inst. f. Unternehmensforschung, Techn. University Wien.

[555] Nahorski, Z., Ravn, H.F. and Vidal, R.V.V. (1984). The discrete-time
maximum principle: a survey and some new results. International J. of
Control, 40, 533-554.

[556] Naik, RA., Mantrala, M.K. and Sawyer, A. (1998). Planning pulsing
media schedules in the presence of dynamic advertising quality. Marketing
Science, 17, 3, 214-235.

[557] Naslund, B. (1966). Simultaneous determination of optimal repair policy


and service life. The Swedish Journal of Economics, 68, 63-73.

[558] Naslund, B. (1969). Optimal rotation and thinning. Forest Science, 15,
466-451.

[559] Naslund, B. (1979). Consumer behavior and optimal advertising, J. of


the Operational Research Society, 20, 237-243.

[560] Neck, R. (1982). Dynamic systems with several decision-makers, in Oper-


ations Research in Progress, G. Feichtinger and P. Kail (Eds.), D. Reidel
Publishing Company, Dordrecht, Holland, 261-284.

[561] Neck, R. (1984). Stochastic control theory and operational research, Eu-
ropean Journal of Operational Research, 17, 283-301.

[562] Nelson, R.T. (1960). Labor assignment as a dynamic control problem,


Operations Research, 14, 369-376.
Bibliography 459

[563] Nepomiastchy, P. (1970). Application of optimal control theory and


penalty function techniques to solution of a particular scheduling prob-
lem, Zhurnal VychifliteVnoi Matemtiki i Matematichefkoi Fiziki (in Rus-
sian), 10, No. 4.

[564] Nerlove, M. and Arrow, K.J. (1962). Optimal advertising policy under
dynamic conditions, Economica, 29, 129-142.

[565] Neustadt, L.W. (1976). Optimization: A Theory of Necessary Conditions,


Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

[566] Nguyen, D. (1997). Marketing Decisions under Uncertainty, Kluwer Aca-


demic Publishers, Boston.

[567] Norstrom, C.J. (1978). The continuous wheat trading model reconsid-
ered. An application of mathematical control theory with a state con-
straint, W.P. 58-77-78, GSIA, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh,
Pa.

[568] Novak, A. and Feichtinger, G. (1993). Optimal treatment of cancer dis-


eases, International Journal of Systems Science, 24, 1253-1263.

[569] Oberle, H.J. (1979). Numerical computation of singular control problems


with application to optimal heating and cooling by solar energy, AppL
Math. & Optimiz., 5, 297-314.

[570] Oberle, H.J. (1986). Numerical solution of minimax optimal control prob-
lems by multiple shooting technique. Journal of Optimization Theory and
Applications, 50, 331-358.

[571] Oberle, H.J. and Grimm, W. (1989). BNDSCO: A Program for the Nu-
merical Solution of Optimal Control Problems, Report 515, Institut for
Flight Systems Dynamics, German Aerospace Research Establishment
DLR, OberpfafFenhofen, Germany.

[572] Oberle, H.J. and Sothmann, B.(1999). Numerical computation of optimal


feed rates for a fed-batch fermentation model. Journal of Optimization
Theory and Applications, 100, 1, 1-13.

[573] Oguztoreh, M.N. and Stein, R.B. (1983). Optimal control or antagonistic
muscles, Biol. Cybern., 48, 91-99.
[574] Oksendal, B.K. (1998). Stochastic Differential Equations: An Introduc-
tion With Applications, Springer-Verlag, New York.

[575] Olsder, G.J. (1976). Some thoughts about simple advertising models as
dijBFerential games and the structure of coalitions, in Directions in Large-
Scale Systems, Many-Person Optimization and Decentralized Control, Y.-
C. Ho and S.K. Mitter (Eds.), Plenum Press, New York, 187-205.
460 Bibliography

[576] Oniki, H. (1973). comparative dynamics (sensitivity analysis) in optimal


control theory, Journal of Economic Theory, 6, 265-283.

[577] Oren, S.S. and Powell, S.G. (1985). Optimal supply of a depletable re-
source with a backstop technology. Operations Research, 33, 277-292.

[578] Osayimwese, I. (1974). Rural-urban migration and control theory. Geo-


graphical Analysis, 4, 147-161.

[579] Ozga, S. (1960). Imperfect markets through lack of knowledge. Quarterly


Journal of Economics, 74, 29-52.

[580] Palda, K.S. (1964). The Measurement of Cumulative Advertising Effects,


Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

[581] Pantoja, J.F. and Mayne, D.Q. (1991). Sequential quadratic program-
ming algorithm for discrete optimal control problems with control in-
equality constraints. International Journal on Control, 53, 4, 823-836.

[582] Parlar, M. (1983). Optimal forest fire control with limited reinforcements,
Optimal Control Application & Methods, 4, 185-191.

[583] Parlar, M. (1984). Optimal dynamic service rate control in time depen-
dent M/M/S/N queues, International Journal of Systems Science, 15,
107-118.

[584] Parlar, M. (1986). A problem in jointly optimal production and advertis-


ing decisions, International Journal Systems Science, 17, 9, 1373-1380.

[585] Parlar, M. and Vickson, R.G. (1980). An optimal control problem with
piecewise quadratic cost functional containing a 'dead zone'. Optimal
Control Application & Methods, 1, 361-372.

[586] Parlar, M. and Vickson, R.G. (1982). Optimal forest fire control: an
extension of Park's model. Forest Science, 28, 345-355.

[587] Pauwels, W. (1977). Optimal dynamic advertising policies in the presence


of continuously distributed time lags. Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 22, 1, 79-89.

[588] Pekelman, D. (1974). Simultaneous price-production decision, Operations


Research, 22, 788-794.

[589] Pekelman, D. (1975). Production smoothing with fluctuating price. Man-


agement Science, 2 1 , 576-590.

[590] Pekelman D. (1979). On optimal utihzation of production processes. Op-


erations Research, 27, 260-278.
Bibliography 461

[591] Pekelman D. and Rausser, G.C. (1978). Adaptive control: survey of


methods and applications, in Applied Optimal Control, TIMS Studies
in Management Sciences, A. Bensoussan et al. (Eds.), Vol. 9, North-
Holland, Amsterdam, 89-120.

[592] Pekelman, D. and Sethi, S.P. (1978). Advertising budgeting, wearout


and copy replacement. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 29,
651-659.

[593] Pepyne, D.L. and Cassandras, C.G. (1999). Performance optimization


of a class of discrete event dynamic systems using calculus of variations
techniques. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 100, 3,
599-622.

[594] Pesch, H.J. (1989). Real-time computation of feedback controls for con-
strained optimal control problems, part 1: neighboring extremals. Opti-
mal Control Applications & Methods, 10, 2, 129-145.

[595] Pesch, H.J. (1989). Real-time computation of feedback controls for con-
strained optimal control problems, part 2: a correction method based
on multiple shooting. Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 10, 2,
147-171.

[596] Pesch, H.J. (1994). A practical guide to the solution of real-life optimal
control problems. Control and Cybernetics, 23, 1/2, 7-60.

[597] Pesch, H.J. and Bulirsch, R. (1994). The maximum principle. Bellman's
equation, and Canatheodory's Work, Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 80, 1, 203-229.

[598] Peterson, D.W. (1973). The economic significance of auxiliary functions


in optimal control. International Economic Review, 14, 234-252.

[599] Peterson, D.W. and Zalkin, J.H. (1978). A review of direct sufficient
conditions in optimal control theory. International Journal Control, 28,
589-610.

[600] Peterson, P.M. and Fisher, A.C. (1977). The exploitation of extractive
resources: a survey. Economic Journal, 87, 681-721.

[601] Petrov, lu.P. (1968). Variational Methods in Optimum Control Theory,


Academic Press, New York.

[602] Pierskalla, W.P. and Voelker, J.A. (1976). Survey of maintenance mod-
els: the control and surveillance of deteriorating systems. Naval Research
Logistics Quarterly 23, 353-388.

[603] Pindyck, R.S. (Ed.) (1978a). Advances in the Economics of Energy and
Resources, I I , J.A.I. Press, Greenwich, Conn.
462 Bibliography

[604] Pindyck, R.S. (1978b). The optimal exploration and production of non-
renewable resources, Journal of Political Economy, 86, 841-862.

[605] Pindyck, R.S. (1978c). Gains to producers from the cartelization of ex-
haustible resources. Rev. Economics & Statistics, 60, 238-251.

[606] Pindyck, R.S. (1978b). The optimal exploration and production of non-
renewable resources. Journal of Political Economy, 86, 841-862.

[607] Pindyck, R.S. (1982). Adjustment costs, uncertainty, and the behavior
of the firm, American Economic Review, 72, 3, 415-427.

[608] Pitchford, J.D. and Turnovsky, S.J. (Eds.) (1977). Applications of Control
Theory to Economic Analysis, North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[609] Pohjola, M. (1984). Threats and bargaining in capitalism: a differential


game view. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 8, 291-302.

[610] Polak, E. (1971). Computational Methods in Optimization, Academic


Press, New York.

[611] Polak, E. (1973). A historical survey of computational methods in optimal


control, SIAM Review, 15, 553-584.

[612] Polak, E., Yang, T.H. and Mayne, D.Q. (1993). A method of centers
based on barrier functions for solving optimal control problems with
continuous state and control constraints, SIAM Journal on Control and
Optimization, 3 1 , 159-179.

[613] Pontryagin, L.S., Boltyanskii, V.G., Gamkrelidze, R.V. and Mischenko,


E.F. (1962). The mathematical theory of optimal processes, Wiley, New
York.

[614] Presman, E., Sethi, S.P. and Suo, W. (1997a). Optimal feedback produc-
tion planning in stochastic dynamic jobshops, in Mathematics of Stochas-
tic Manufacturing Systems, G. Yin and Q. Zhang (Eds.); Lectures in Ap-
plied Mathematics, Vol. 33, American Mathematical Society, Providence,
RI, 235-252.

[615] Presman, E., Sethi, S.P. and Suo, W. (1997b). Existence of optimal feed-
back production plans in stochastic iV-machine flowshops with limited
buffers, Automatica, 33, 4, 1899-1903.

[616] Presman, E., Sethi, S.P., Zhang, H. and Zhang, Q. (1998a). Analysis of
average cost optimality for an unreliable two-machine flowshop. Proceed-
ings of the Fourth International Conference on Optimization Techniques
and Applications, Curtin University of Technology, Perth, Australia, 94-
112.
Bibliography 463

[617] Presman, E., Sethi, S.R, Zhang, H. and Zhang, Q. (1998b). Optimahty
of zero-inventory poHcies for an unreliable manufacturing system pro-
ducing two part types, Dynamics of Continuous, Discrete and Impulsive
Systems, 4, 4, 485-496.

[618] Presman, E., Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1995). Optimal feedback pro-
duction planning in a stochastic TV-machine flowshop, Automatica, 3 1 ,
9, 1325-1332.

[619] Prskawetz, A., Feichtinger, G. and Luptacik, M. (1998). The accomplish-


ment of the Maastricht criteria with respect to initial debt. Journal of
Economics, 68, 93-110.

[620] Pytlak, R., and Vinter, R.B. (1993). PH2S0L Solver: An 0(N) Imple-
mentation of an Optimization Algorithm for a General Optimal Control
Problem, Research Report C93-36, Centre for Process Systems Engineer-
ing, Imperial College, London, United Kingdom.

[621] Pytlak, R., and Vinter, R.B. (1999). Feasible direction algorithm for opti-
mal control problems with state and control constraints: implementation,
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 101, 3, 623-649.

[622] Raman, K. (1990). Stochastically optimal advertising policies under dy-


namic conditions: the ratio rule, Optimal Control Applications & Meth-
ods, 1 1 , 283-288.

[623] Raman, K. and Chatterjee, R. (1995). Optimal monopolist pricing under


demand uncertainty in dynamic markets, Management Science, 4 1 , 1,
144-162.

[624] Ramsey, F.P. (1928). A mathematical theory of savings. Economic Jour-


nal, 38, 543-559.

[625] Rao, R.C. (1970). Quantitative Theories in Advertising, Wiley, New York.

[626] Rao, R.C. (1984). Advertising decisions in oligopoly: an industry equi-


librium analysis, Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 5, 4, 331-344.

[627] Rao, R.C. (1985). A note on optimal and near optimal price and adver-
tising strategies. Management Science, 3 1 , 3, 376-377.

[628] Rao, R.C. (1986). Estimating continuous time advertising-sales models,


Marketing Science, 5, 2, 125-142.

[629] Rao, R.C. (1990). Impact of competition on strategic marketing decisions,


in Interface of Marketing and Strategy, G. Day, B. Weitz and R. Wens ley
(Eds.), JAI Press, Greenwich, CT.
464 Bibliography

[630] Rapoport, A. (1980). Mathematische Methoden in den Sozialwis-


senschaften^ Physica-Verlag, Wiirzburg.

[631] Rapp, B. (1974). Models for Optimal Investment and Maintenance Deci-
sions, Almqvist & Wiksell, Stockholm; Wiley, New York.

[632] Rausser, G.C. and Hochman, E. (1979). Dynamic Agricultural systems:


Economic Prediction and Control, North-Holland, New York.

[633] Raviv, A. (1979). The design of an optimal insurance policy. The Amer-
ican Economic Review, 69, 84-96.

[634] Ray, A. and Blaquiere, A. (1981). Sufficient conditions for optimality of


threat strategies in a differential game. Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 33, 99-109,

[635] Reinganum, J.F. (1982). A dynamic game of R & D: patent protection


and competitive behavior, Econometrica, 50, 671-688.

[636] Rempala, R. (1980). On the multicommodity Arrow-Karlin inventory


model, in Proceedings First International Symposium on Inventories,
Hungarian Academy of Science, Budapest.

[637] Rempala, R. (1982). On the multicommodity Arrow-Karlin inventory


model, part H: horizon and horizontal solution, in Proceedings Second
International Symposium on Inventories, Hungarian Academy of Science,
Budapest.

[638] Rempala, R. (1986). Horizon for the dynamic family of wheat trading
problems. Proceedings Fourth International Symposium on Inventories,
Budapest.

[639] Rempala, R. and Sethi, S.R (1988). Forecast horizons in single product
inventory models, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis 3,
G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 225-233.

[640] Rempala, R. and Sethi, S.R (1992). Decision and forecast horizons for
one-dimensional optimal control problems: existence results and appli-
cations, Optimal Control Applications & Methods, 13, 179-192.

[641] Richard, S.F. (1979). A generalized capital asset pricing model, TIMS
Studies in the Management Sciences, 11, 215-232.

[642] Ringbeck, J. (1985). Mixed quality and advertising strategies under


asymmetric information, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Anal-
ysis, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), Vol. 2, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 197-214.
Bibliography 465

[643] Rishel, R.W. (1965). An extended Pontryagin principle for control sys-
tems whose control laws contain measures, Journal of Soc. Industrial &
AppL Math. Control, 3, 191-205.

[644] Rishel, R.W. (1985). A partially observed advertising model, in Optimal


Control Theory and Economic Analysis, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), 2, 253-262.

[645] Roberts, S.M. and Shipman, J.S. (1972). Two-Point Boundary Value
Problems: Shooting Methods, Elsevier, New York.

[646] Robinson, B. and Lakhani, C. (1975). Dynamic price models for new-
product planning. Management Science, 2 1 , 10, 1113-1122.

[647] Robson, A.J. (1981). Sufficiency of the Pontryagin conditions for optimal
control when the time horizon is free. Journal of Economic Theory, 24,
438-445.

[648] Robson, A.J. (1985). Optimal control of systems governed by partial dif-
ferential equations: economic applications, in Optimal Control Theory
and Economic Analysis 2, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amster-
dam, 105-118.

[649] Rockafeller, R.T. (1970). Convex Analysis, Princeton University Press,


Princeton, NJ.

[650] Rockafeller, R.T. (1972). State constraints in convex control problems of


Bolza, SIAM Journal on Control, 19, 691-715.

[651] Russak, B. (1976). Relations among the multipliers for problems with
bounded state constraints, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization,
14, 1151-1155.

[652] Russell, D.L. (1965). Penalty functions and bounded phase coordinates,
SIAM Journal on Control, 2, 409-422.

[653] Sage, A.P. (1968). Optimum Systems Control, Prentice-Hall, Englewood


Cliffs, NJ.

[654] Salukvadze, M.E. (1979). Vector-Valued Optimization Problems in Con-


trol Theory, Academic Press, New York.

[655] Samuelson, P.A. (1972). The general saddle point property of optimal-
control motions. Journal of Economic Theory, 5, 102-120.

[656] Sarma, V.V.S. and Alam, M. (1975). Optimal maintenance policies for
machines subject to deterioration and intermittent breakdowns, IEEE
Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, SMC-5, 396-398.
466 Bibliography

[657] Samaratunga, C , Sethi, S.P. and Zhou, X. (1997). Computational eval-


uation of hierarchical production policies for stochastic manufacturing
systems. Operations Research, 45, 2, 258-274.

[658] Sasieni, M. (1989). Optimal advertising strategies. Marketing Science, 8,


358-370.

[659] Schaefer, M.B. (1957). Some considerations of population dynamics and


economics in relation to the management of marine fisheries. Journal of
Fisheries Research Board of Canada, 14, 669-681.

[660] Scalzo, R.C. (1974). N person linear quadratic differential games with
constraints, SIAM Journal on Control, 12, 419-425.

[661] Schijndel, G.-J.C.Th.,van (1986). Dynamic shareholder behaviour under


personal taxation: a note, in Operations Research Proceedings 1985, L.
Streitferdt et al. (Eds.), Springer-Verlag, Berhn, 488-495.

[662] Schilling, K. (1985). On optimization principles in plant ecology, in Dy-


namics of Macrosystems, Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical
Systems, J.-P. Aubin et al. (Eds.), Vol. 257, Springer-Verlag, Berlin,
63-71.

[663] Seidman, T.L, Sethi, S.P. and Derzko, N.A. (1987). Dynamics and opti-
mization of a sales advertising model with population migration. Journal
of Optimization Theory and Applications, 52, 3, 443-462.

[664] Seierstad, A. (1982). Differentiability properties of the optimal value


function in control theory. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,
4, 303-310.

[665] Seierstad, A. (1985). Existence of an optimal control with sparse jumps


in the state variable. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications,
45, 265-293.

[666] Seierstad, A. and Sydsseter, K. (1977). Sufficient conditions in optimal


control theory. International Economic Review, 18, 367-391.

[667] Seierstad, A. and Sydsaeter, K. (1983). Sufficient conditions applied to an


optimal control problem of resource management. Journal of Economic
Theory, 3 1 , 375-382.

[668] Seierstad, A. and Sydsaeter, K. (1987). Optimal Control Theory with Eco-
nomic Applications, North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[669] Selten, R. (1975). Reexamination of the perfectness concept for equilib-


rium points in extensive games. International Journal of Game Theory,
4, 25-55.
Bibliography 467

[670] Sethi, S.R (1973a). Optimal control of the Vidale-Wolfe advertising


model, Operations Research, 2 1 , 998-1013.

[671] Sethi, S.P. (1973b). Simultaneous optimization of preventive maintenance


and replacement policy for machines: a modern control theory approach,
AIIE Transactions, 5, 2, 156-163.

[672] Sethi, S.P. (1973c). An application of optimal control theory in forest


management, Journal of Management Science and Applied Cybernetics
(New Delhi), 2, 9-16.

[673] Sethi, S.P. (1973d). A note on modeling simple dynamic cash balance
problems. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 8, 685-687.

[674] Sethi, S.P. (1974a). Sufficient conditions for the optimal control of a
class of systems with continuous lags. Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 13, 542-552.

[675] Sethi, S.P. (1974b). Some explanatory remarks on the optimal control of
the Vidale-Wolfe advertising model. Operations Research, 22, 1119-1120.

[676] Sethi, S.P. (1974c). Quantitative guidelines for communicable disease


control program: a complete synthesis. Biometrics, 30, 681-691.

[677] Sethi, S.P. (1975). Optimal control of a logarithmic advertising model,


Operations Research Quarterly, 26, 317-319.

[678] Sethi, S.P. (1977a). Dynamic optimal control models in advertising: a


survey, SIAM Review, 19, 4, 685-725.

[679] Sethi, S.P. (1977b). Nearest feasible paths in optimal control problems:
theory, examples, and counterexamples. Journal of Optimization Theory
and Applications, 23, 4, 563-579.

[680] Sethi, S.P. (1977c). Optimal advertising for the Nerlove-Arrow model
under a budget constraint. Operational Research Quarterly, 28, 3, 683-
693.

[681] Sethi, S.P. (1977d). A linear bang-bang model of firm behavior and water
quality, IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-22, 706-714.

[682] Sethi, S.P. (1978a). A survey of management science applications of the


deterministic maximum principle, TIMS Studies in the Management Sci-
ences, 9, 33-67.

[683] Sethi, S.P. (1978b). Optimal equity financing model of Krouse and Lee:
corrections and extensions. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Anal-
ysis, 13, 3, 487-505.
468 Bibliography

[684] Sethi, S.P. (1978c). A note on modeling simple dynamic cash balance
problem: errata, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 13,
585-586.
[685] Sethi, S.P. (1978d). Optimal quarantine programs for controlling an epi-
demic spread, Journal of Operational Research Society, 29, 3, 265-268.
[686] Sethi, S.P. (1979a). Optimal depletion of exhaustible resources. Applied
Mathematical Modelling, 3, 367-378.
[687] Sethi, S.P. (1979b). Optimal pilfering policy for dynamic continuous
thieves, Management Science, 25, 6, 535-542.
[688] Sethi, S.P. (1979c). Optimal advertising policy with the contagion model,
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 29, 4, 615-627.
[689] Sethi, S.P. (1979d). A note on the Nerlove-Arrow model under uncer-
tainty, Operations Research, 27, 4, 839-842; Erratum, 28, 4, July-August
1980, 1026-1027.
[690] Sethi, S.P. (1983a). Optimal long-run equilibrium advertising level for
the Blattberg-Jeuland model. Management Science, 29, 12, 1436-1443.
[691] Sethi, S.P. (1983b). Deterministic and stochastic optimization of a dy-
namic advertising model. Optimal Control Application and Methods, 4,
2, 179-184.
[692] Sethi, S.P. (1983c). Applications of optimal control to management sci-
ence problems, Proceedings of the 1983 World Conference on Systems,
Caracas, Venezuela.
[693] Sethi, S.P. (1984). Application of the maximum principle to production
and inventory problems, Proceedings Third International Symposium On
Inventories, Budapest, 753-756.
[694] Sethi, S.P. (1990). Decision and forecast horizons in dynamic optimiza-
tion, Systems and Control Encyclopedia Supplementary, M.G. Singh
(Ed.), Pergamon Press, Oxford, U.K., Vol. 1, 192-198.
[695] Sethi, S.P. (1996). When does the share price equal the present value of
future dividends? - a modified dividend approach. Economic Theory, 8,
307-319.
[696] Sethi, S.P. (1997a). Optimal Consumption and Investment with
Bankruptcy, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.
[697] Sethi, S.P. (1997b). Some insights into near-optimal plans for stochastic
manufacturing systems, Mathematics of Stochastic Manufacturing Sys-
tems, G. Yin and Q. Zhang (Eds.); Lectures in Applied Mathematics,
Vol. 33, American Mathematical Society, Providence, RI, 287-315.
Bibliography 469

[698] Sethi, S.P. (1998). Optimal consumption - investment decisions allow-


ing for bankruptcy: a survey, in Worldwide Asset and Liability Model-
ing, W.T. Ziemba and J.M. Mulvey (Eds.), Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, U.K., 387-426

[699] Sethi, S.P. and Chand, S. (1979). Planning horizon procedures in machine
replacement models. Management Science, 25, 140-151; Erratum, 26, 3,
1980, 342.

[700] Sethi, S.P. and Chand, S. (1981). Multiple finite production rate dynamic
lot size inventory models. Operations Research, 29, 5, 931-944.

[701] Sethi, S.P., Derzko, N.A. and Lehoczky, J.P. (1982). Mathematical anal-
ysis of the Miller-Modigliani theory, O.R. Letters, 1, 148-152.

[702] Sethi, S.P. and Lee, S.C. (1981). Optimal advertising for the Nerlove-
Arrow Model under a replenishable budget. Optimal Control Applications
& Methods, 2, 2, 165-173.

[703] Sethi, S.P. and Lehoczky, J.P. (1981). A comparison of Ito and
Stratonovich formulations of problems in finance. Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, 3, 343-356.

[704] Sethi, S.P. and McGuire, T.W. (1977). Optimal skill mix: an application
of the maximum principle for systems with retarded controls. Journal of
Optimization Theory and Applications, 23, 245-275.

[705] Sethi, S.P. and Morton, T.E. (1972). A mixed optimization technique for
the generalized machine replacement problem. Naval Research Logistics
QuaHerly, 19, 471-481.

[706] Sethi, S.P. and Sorger, G. (1989). Concepts of forecast horizons in


stochastic dynamic games. Proceedings of the 28th Conference on De-
cision and Control, Tampa, Florida, 195-197.

[707] Sethi, S.P. and Sorger, G. (1990). An exercise in modeling of consump-


tion, import, and export of an exhaustible resource. Optimal Control
Applications & Methods, 1 1 , 191-196.

[708] Sethi, S.P. and Sorger, G. (1991). A theory of rolling horizon decision
making. Annals of O.R., 29, 387-416.
[709] Sethi, S.P. and Staats, P.W. (1978). Optimal control of some simple
deterministic epidemic models. Journal of Operational Research Society,
29, 2, 129-136.

[710] Sethi, S.P., Suo, W., Taksar, M.L and Yan, H. (1998). Optimal produc-
tion planning in a multiproduct stochastic manufacturing systems with
long-run average cost. Discrete Event Dynamic Systems, 8, 1, 37-54.
470 Bibliography

[711] Sethi, S.R, Suo, W., Taksar, M.I. and Zhang, Q. (1997). Optimal produc-
tion planning in a stochastic manufacturing system with long-run average
cost, Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 92, 1, 161-188.

[712] Sethi, S.P. and Taksar, M.I. (1988). Deterministic and stochastic control
problems with identical optimal cost functions, Analysis and Optimiza-
tion of Systems, A. Bensoussan and J.L. Lions (Eds.), Lecture Notes in
Control and Information Sciences, Springer-Verlag, New York, 641-645.

[713] Sethi, S.P. and Taksar, M.I. (1990). Deterministic equivalent for a
continuous-time linear-convex stochastic control problem. Journal of Op-
timization Theory and Applications, 64, 1, 169-181.

[714] Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1970). Applications of mathematical


control theory to finance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,
5, 4 fe 5, 381-394.

[715] Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1977). Christmas toy manufacturer's
problem: an application of the stochastic maximum principle, Opsearch,
14, 161-173.

[716] Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1981). Simple models in stochastic
production planning, in Applied Stochastic Control in Econometrics and
Management Science, A. Bensoussan, P.R. Kleindorfer and C.S. Tapiero
(Eds), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 295-304.

[717] Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1981). A tutorial on optimal control
theory. Information Systems and Operational Research, 19, 4, 279-291.

[718] Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (1982). Planning and forecast horizons
in a simple wheat trading model. Operations Research in Progress, G. Fe-
ichtinger and P. Kail (Eds.), D. Reidel Publishing Company, Dordrecht,
Holland, 203-214.

[719] Sethi, S.P., Thompson, G.L. and Udayabhanu, V. (1985). Profit max-
imization models for exponential decay processes, European Journal of
Operational Research, 22, 101-115.

[720] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, H. (1999a). Average-cost optimal policies for an
unreliable flexible multiproduct machine, I.J.F.M.S., 1 1 , 147-157.

[721] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, H. (1999b). Hierarchical production controls for a
stochastic manufacturing system with long-run average cost: asymptotic
optimality, in Stochastic Analysis, Control, Optimization and Applica-
tions: A Volume in Honor of W.H. Fleming, W.M. McEneaney, G. Yin
and Q. Zhang (Eds.), Birkhauser, Boston, 621-637.
Bibliography 471

[722] Sethi, S.R, Zhang, H. and Zhang, Q. (1997). Hierarchical production


control in a stochastic manufacturing system with long-run average cost,
Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 214, 151-172.

[723] Sethi, S.R, Zhang, H. and Zhang, Q. (1998). Minimum average-cost


production planning in stochastic manufacturing systems. Mathematical
Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 8, 7, 1251-1276.

[724] Sethi, S.R and Zhang, Q. (1994a). Hierarchical Decision Making in


Stochastic Manufacturing Systems, in series Systems and Control: Foun-
dations and Applications, Birkhauser, Boston.

[725] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1994b). Hierarchical controls in stochastic


manufacturing systems, SIAG/CST Newsletter, 2, 1, 1-5.

[726] Sethi, S.R and Zhang, Q. (1994c). Asymptotic optimal controls in


stochastic manufacturing systems with machine failures dependent on
production rates, Stochastics and Stochastics Reports, 48, 97-121.

[727] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1995a). Hierarchical production and setup
scheduling in stochastic manufacturing systems, IEEE Transactions on
Automatic Control, 40, 5, 924-930.

[728] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1995b). Multilevel hierarchical decision mak-
ing in stochastic marketing - production systems, SIAM Journal on Con-
trol and Optimization, 33, 2, 538-553.

[729] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1998a). Asymptotic optimality of hierarchical


controls in stochastic manufacturing systems: a review, Operations Re-
search: Methods, Models, and Applications, J.E. Aronson and S. Zionts
(Eds.), Quoram Books, Westport, CT, 267-294.

[730] Sethi, S.P. and Zhang, Q. (1998b). Optimal control of dynamic systems
by decomposition and aggregation, Journal of Optimization Theory and
Applications, 99, 1, 1-22.

[731] Sethi, S.R, Zhang, Q. and Zhou, X. (1997). Hierarchical production con-
trols in a stochastic two-machine flowshop with a finite internal buffer,
IEEE Transactions on Robotics and Automation, 13, 1, 1-13.

[732] Sethi, S.P. and Zhou, X. (1996a). Optimal feedback controls in determin-
istic dynamic two-machine flowshops, O. R. Letters, 19, 5, 225-35.

[733] Sethi, S.R and Zhou, X. (1996b). Asymptotic optimal feedback con-
trols in stochastic dynamic two-machine flowshops, in Recent Advances
in Control and Optimization of Manufacturing Systems, Lecture Notes
in Control and Information Sciences, Vol. 214, G. Yin and Q. Zhang
(Eds.), Springer-Verlag, New York, 147-180.
472 Bibliography

[734] Shapiro, A. (1997). On uniqueness of Lagrange multipliers in optimiza-


tion problems subject to cone constraints, SI AM Journal on Optimiza-
tion, 7, 2, 508-518.

[735] Shapiro, C. (1982). Consumer information, product quality, and seller


reputation. Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 20-25.

[736] Shell, K. (Ed.) (1967). Essays on the Theory of Optimal Economic


Growth, The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

[737] Shell, K. (1969). Applications of Pontryagin's maximum principle to eco-


nomics, in Mathematical Systems Theory and Economics, H.W. Kuhn
and G.P. Szego (Eds.), Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

[738] Siebert, H. (1985). Economics of the Resource-Exporting Country: In-


tertemporal Theory of Supply and Trade, JAI Press, Greenwich, Conn.

[739] Silva, G.N. and Vinter, R.B. (1997). Necessary conditions for optimal
impulsive control problems, SI AM Journal on Control and Optimization,
35, 6, 1829-1846.

[740] Simaan, M. and Cruz, J.B., Jr. (1975). Formulation of Richardson's


model of arms race from a differential game viewpoint. Review of Eco-
nomic Studies, 42, 67-77.

[741] Simon, H.A. (1982). ADPULS: an advertising model with wearout and
pulsation. Journal of Marketing Research, 19, 352-363.

[742] Simon, H.A. (1956). Dynamic programming under uncertainty with a


quadratic criterion function, Econometrica, 24, 74-81.

[743] Singh, M.G. (1980). Dynamical Hierarchical Control, North-Holland,


Amsterdam.

[744] Singh, M.G., Tith, A. and Mahnowski, K. (1985). Decentralized control


design: an overview, Large Scale Systems, 9, 215-230.

[745] Skiba, A.K. (1978). Optimal growth with a convex-concave production


function, Econometrica, 46, 527-539.

[746] Smith, V.L. (1972). Dynamics of waste accumulation: disposal versus


recycling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 86, 600-616.

[747] Snower, D.J. (1982). Macroeconomic policy and the optimal destruction
of vampires. Journal of Political Economy, 90, 647-655.

[748] Solow, R.M. (1974). Intergenerational equity and exhaustible resources,


Review of Economic Studies, 4 1 , 29-45.
Bibliography 473

[749] Solow, R.M. and Wan, F.Y. (1976). Extraction costs in the theory of
exhaustible resources, Bell Journal of Economics, 7, 359-370.

[750] Sorenson, H. (1966). Kalman filtering, in Advance in Control Systems,


C.T. Leondes (Ed.), Vol. 3, Academic Press, New York, 219-292.

[751] Sorger, G. (1989). Competitive dynamic advertising: a modification of


the case game. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 13, 55-80.

[752] Southwick, L. and Zionts, S. (1974). An optimal-control-theory approach


to the education-investment decision. Operations Research, 22, 1156-
1174.

[753] Spence, M. (1981). The learning curve and competition. Bell Journal of
Economics, 12, 49-70.

[754] Spiegel, M.R. (1971). Schaum's Outline of Theory and Problems of Cal-
culus of Finite Differences and Difference Equations, McGraw-Hill, New
York.

[755] Spremann, K. (1985). The signaling of quality by reputation, in Optimal


Control Theory and Econ. Analysis, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), Vol. 2, North-
Holland, Amsterdam, 235-252.

[756] Sprzeuzkouski, A.Y. (1967). A problem in optimal stock management,


Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 1, 232-241.

[757] Srinivasan, V. (1976). Decomposition of a multi-period media scheduling


model in terms of single period equivalents. Management Science, 23,
349-360.

[758] Stalford, H. and Leitmann, G. (1973). Sufficiency conditions for Nash


equilibria in N-person differential games, in Topics in Differential Games,
A. Blaquiere (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 345-376.

[759] Starr, A.W. and Ho, Y.-C. (1969). Nonzero-sum differential games. Jour-
nal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 3, 184-206.

[760] Steindl, A., Feichtinger, G., Hartl, R.F. and Sorger, G. (1986). On the
optimality of cyclical employment policies: a numerical investigation,
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 10, 457-466.

[761] Stepan, A. (1977). An application of the discrete maximum principle to


designing ultradeep drills - the casing optimization. International Journal
of Production Research, 15, 315-327.

[762] Stern, L.E. (1984). Criteria of optimality in the infinite-time optimal


control problem. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 44,
497-508.
474 Bibliography

[763] Stiglitz, J.E. and Dasgupta, P. (1982). Market structure and the resource
depletion: a contribution to the theory of intertemporal monopoHstic
competition, Journal of Economic Theory^ 28, 128-164.

[764] Stoer, J. and Bulirsch, R. (1978). Einfuhrung in die Numerische Mathe-


matik 11^ Heidelberger Taschenbiicher, 114, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

[765] Stoppler, S. (1975). Dynamische Produktionstheorie, Westdeutscher-


Verlag, Opladen, West Germany.

[766] Stoppler, S. (1985). Der Einflufider Lagerkosten auf die Produktionsan-


passung bei zyklischem Absatz - Eine kontroUtheoretische Analyse, OR-
Spektrum, 7, 129-142.

[767] Swan, G.W. (1984). Applications of Optimal Control Theory in


Biomedicine, M. Dekker, New York.

[768] Sydsaeter, K. (1978). Optimal control theory and economics: some critical
remarks on the literature, Scand. Journal of Economics, 80, 113-117.

[769] Sydsaeter, K. (1981). Topics in Mathematical Analysis for Economists,


Academic Press, London.

[770] Sweeney, D.J., Abad, P.L. and Dornoff, R.J. (1974). Finding an optimal
dynamic advertising policy. International Journal of Systems Science, 5,
10, 987-994.

[771] Takayama, A. (1974). Mathematical Economics, The Dryden Press, Hins-


dale.

[772] Tan, K.C. and Bennett, R.J. (1984). Optimal Control of Spatial Systems,
George Allen Sz Unwin, London.

[773] Tapiero, C.S. (1971). Optimal simultaneous replacement and main-


tenance of a machine with process discontinuities. Revue francaise
d'informatique et recherche operationnelle, 2, 79-86.

[774] Tapiero, C.S. (1973). Optimal maintenance and replacement of a se-


quence of machines and technical obsolescence, Opsearch, 19, 1-13.

[775] Tapiero, C.S. (1977). Managerial Planning: An Optimum and Stochastic


Control Approach, Gordon Breach, New York.

[776] Tapiero, C.S. (1978). Optimum advertising and goodwill under uncer-
tainty, Operations Research, 26, 3, 450-463.

[777] Tapiero, C.S. (1981). Optimum product quality and advertising. Infor-
mation Systems and Operational Research, 19, 4, 311-318.
Bibliography 475

[778] Tapiero, C.S. (1982a). Optimum control of a stochastic model of advertis-


ing, in Optimal Control Theory and Econ. Analysis^ G. Feichtinger (Ed.),
North-Holland, Amsterdam, 287-300.

[779] Tapiero, C.S. (1982b). A stochastic model of consumer behavior and


optimal advertising, Management Science, 28, 9, 1054-1064.

[780] Tapiero, C.S. (1983). Stochastic diffusion models with advertising and
word-of-mouth effects, European Journal of Operational Research, 12, 4,
348-356.

[781] Tapiero, C.S. (1988). Applied Stochastic Models and Control in Manage-
ment, North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[782] Tapiero, C.S., Eliashberg, J. and Wind, Y. (1987). Risk behaviour and
optimum advertising with a stochastic dynamic sales response. Optimal
Control Applications & Methods, 8, 3, 299-304.

[783] Tapiero, C.S. and Farley, J.U. (1975). Optimal control of sales force effort
in time. Management Science, 21, 9, 976-985.

[784] Tapiero, C.S. and Farley, J.U. (1981). Using an uncertainty model to
assess sales response to advertising. Decision Science, 12, 441-455.

[785] Tapiero, C.S. and Soliman, M.A. (1972). Multi- commodities transporta-
tion schedules over time. Networks, 2, 311-327.

[786] Tapiero, C.S. and Venezia, I. (1979). A mean variance approach to the
optimal machine maintenance and replacement problem. Journal of Op-
erational Research Society, 30, 457-466.

[787] Tapiero, C.S. and Zuckermann, D. (1983). Optimal investment policy of


an insurance firm. Insurance: Mathematics & Economics, 2, 103-112.

[788] Taylor, J.G., (1972). Comments on a multiplier condition for problems


with state variable inequality constraints, IEEE Transactions on Auto-
matic Control, AC-12, 743-744.

[789] Taylor, J.G., (1974). Lanchester-type models of warfare and optimal con-
trol, Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 21, 79-106.

[790] Teng, J.-T. and Thompson, G.L. (1983). Oligopoly models for optimal
advertising when production costs obey a learning curve. Management
Science, 29, 9, 1087-1101.

[791] Teng, J.-T. and Thompson, G.L. (1985). Optimal strategies for general
price-advertising models, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Anal-
ysis 2, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 183-195.
476 Bibliography

[792] Teng, J.-T., Thompson, G.L. and Sethi, S.R (1984). Strong decision
and forecast horizons in a convex production planning problem, Optimal
Control Applications & Methods^ 5, 4, 319-330.

[793] Teo, K.L., Goh, C.J. and Wong, K.H. (1991). A Unified Computational
Approach to Optimal Control Problems^ Longman Scientific & Technical,
E^ssex, England.

[794] Teo, K.L. and Moore, E.J. (1977). Necessary conditions for optimality for
control problems with time delays appearing in both state and control
variables. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 23, 413-427.

[795] Terborgh, G. (1949). Dynamic Equipment Policy, McGraw-Hill, New


York.

[796] Thepot, J. (1983). Marketing and investment policies of duopolists in a


growing industry, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 5, 387-
404.

[797] The Review of Economic Studies (1974). Symposium on the Economics


of Exhaustible Resources, P. Dasgupta and G.M. Heal (Eds.), 4 1 .

[798] Thompson, G.L. (1968). Optimal maintenance policy and sale date of a
machine. Management Science, 14, 543-550.

[799] Thompson, G.L. (1981). An optimal control model of advertising pul-


sation and wearout, in ORSA/TIMS Special Interest Conf on Market
Measurement and Analysis, J.W. Keon (Ed.), The Institute for Manage-
ment Sciences, Providence, RI, 34-43.

[800] Thompson, G.L. (1982a). Continuous expanding and contracting


economies, in Games, Economic Dynamics, Time Series Analysis, M.
Deistler, E. Furst and G. Schwodiauer (Eds.), Physica-Verlag, Berhn,
West Germany, 145-153.

[801] Thompson, G.L. (1982b). Many country continuous expanding open


economies with multiple goods, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic
Analysis, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, New York, 157-168.

[802] Thompson, G.L. and Sethi, S.P. (1980). Turnpike horizons for production
planning. Management Science, 26, 229-241.

[803] Thompson, G.L., Sethi, S.P. and Teng, J.-T. (1984). Strong planning and
forecast horizons for a model with simultaneous price and production
decisions, European Journal of Operational Research, 16, 378-388.

[804] Thompson, G.L. and Teng, J.-T. (1984). Optimal pricing and advertising
policies for new product oligopoly models. Marketing Science, 3, 2, 148-
168.
Bibliography 477

[805] Tintner, G. (1937). Monopoly over time, Econometrica, 5, 160-170.

[806] Tintner, G. and Sengupta, J.K. (1972). Stochastic Economics: Stochastic


Processes, Control, and Programming, Academic Press, New York.

[807] Tolwinski, B. (1982). A concept of cooperative equilibrium for dynamic


games, Automatica, 18, 431-447.

[808] Tousssaint, S. (1985). The transversality condition at infinity applied to


a problem of optimal resource depletion, in Optimal Control Theory and
Economic Analysis 2, G. Feichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam,
429-440.

[809] Tracz, G. S. (1968). A selected bibliography on the application of optimal


control theory to economic and business systems, management science
and operations research, Operations Research, 16, 174-186.

[810] Tragler, G., Caulkins, J.R and Feichtinger, G. (2000). The impact of
enforcement and treatment on illicit drug consumption. Operations Re-
search, forthcoming.

[811] Treadway, A.B. (1970). Adjustment costs and variable inputs in the the-
ory of the competitive firm. Journal of Economic Theory, 2, 329-347.

[812] Troch, I. (Ed.) (1978). Simulation of Control Systems with Special Em-
phasis on Modelling and Redundancy, Proceedings of the IMACS Sym-
posium, North-Holland, Amsterdam.

[813] Tsurumi, H. and Tsurumi, Y. (1971). Simultaneous determination of


market share and advertising expenditure under dynamic conditions: the
case of a firm within the Japanese pharmaceutical industry. The Eco-
nomic Studies Quarterly, 22, 1-23.

[814] Tu, P.N.V. (1969). Optimal educational investment program in an eco-


nomic planning model, Canadian Journal of Economics, 2, 52-64.

[815] Tu, P.N.V. (1984). Introductory Optimization Dynamics, Springer-


Verlag, Berlin.

[816] Turner, R.E. and Neuman, C.P. (1976). Dynamic advertising strategy: a
managerial approach. Journal of Business Administration, 7, 1-21.

[817] Turnovsky, S.J. (1981). The optimal intertemporal choice of inflation and
unemployment. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 3, 357-384.

[818] Tzafestas, S.G. (1982). Optimal and modal control of production-


inventory systems, in Optimization and Control of Dynamic Operational
Research Models, S.G. Tzafestas (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 1-71.
478 Bibliography

[819] Uhler, R.S. (1979). The rate of petroleum exploration and extraction,
in Advances in the Economics of Energy and Resources^ R.S,. Pindyck
(Ed.), Vol. 2, JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, 93-118.

[820] Valentine, F.A. (1937). The problem of Lagrange with differential in-
equalities as added side conditions, in Contributions to the Theory of the
Calculus of Variations, 1933-1937, University Chicago Press, Chicago,
IL.

[821] Van Hilten, O., Kort, P.M. and Van Loon, P.J.J.M. (1993). Dynamic
Policies of the Firm: An Optimal Control Approach, Springer-Verlag,
New York.

[822] Vanthienen, L. (1975). Simultaneous price-reduction decision making


with production adjustment costs, in the Series Proceedings XX Inter-
national Meeting of TIMS held in Tel Aviv, Israel on June 24-29, 1973,
Jerusalem Academic Press, Jerusalem, Vol. 1, 249-254.

[823] Varaiya, P.P. (1970). N-person nonzero-sum differential games with linear
dynamics, SIAM Journal on Control, 8, 441-449.

[824] Verheyen, P. A. (1985). A dynamic theory of the firm and the reaction on
governmental policy, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis,
G. Feichtinger (Ed.), Vol. 2, North-Holland, Amsterdam, 313-329.

[825] Vickson, R.G. (1981). Schedule control for randomly drifting production
sequences. Information Systems and Operational Research, 19, 330-346.

[826] Vickson, R.G. (1982). Optimal control production sequences: a continu-


ous parameter analysis. Operations Research, 30, 659-679.

[827] Vickson, R.G. (1985). Optimal conversion to a new production technol-


ogy under learning, lEE Transactions, 17, 175-181.

[828] Vickson, R.G. (1986/7). A single product cycling problem under Brown-
ian motion demand, erscheint in Management Science.

[829] Vidale, M.L. and Wolfe, H.B. (1957). An operations research study of
sales response to advertising. Operations Research, 5, 3, 370-381.

[830] Villas-Boas, J.M. (1993). Predicting advertising policies in an oligopoly:


a model and empirical test. Marketing Science, 12, 88-102.

[831] Vinokurov, V.R. (1969). Optimal control of processes described by inte-


gral equations I, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 7, 324-336.

[832] Vinter, R.B. (1983). New global optimality conditions in optimal control
theory, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 2 1 , 235-245.
Bibliography 479

[833] Vousden, N. (1974). International trade and exhaustible resources: a


theoretical model, International Economic Review, 15, 149-167.

[834] Wagner, H.M. and Whitin, T.M. (1958). Dynamic version of the economic
lot size model. Management Science, 5, 89-96.

[835] Wang, P.K.C. (1964). Control of distributed parameter systems, in Ad-


vances in Control Systems 1, C.T. Leondes (Ed.), Academic Press, New
York, 75-170.

[836] Warga, J. (1972). Optimal Control of Differential and Functional Equa-


tions, Academic Press, New York.

[837] Warschat, J. (1985a). Optimal control of a production-inventory system


with state constraints and a quadratic cost criterion, RAIRO-OR, 19,
275-292.

[838] Warschat, J. (1985b). Optimal production planning for cascaded pro-


duction inventory systems, in Toward the Factory of the Future, H.J.
BulUnger and H.J. Warnecke (Eds.), Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 669-674.

[839] Warschat, J. and Wunderlich, H.J. (1984). Time-optimal control poli-


cies for cascaded production-inventory systems with control and state
constraints. International Journal of Systems Science, 15, 513-524.

[840] Weinstein, M.C. and Zeckhauser, R.J. (1975). The optimum consumption
of depletable natural resources. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 89,
371-392.

[841] Weizsacker, C.C. von (1980). Barriers to Entry: A Theoretical Treat-


ment, Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, Vol. 185,
Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

[842] Welam, U.P. (1982). Optimal and near optimal price and advertising
strategies for finite and infinite horizons. Management Science, 28, 11,
1313-1327.

[843] Westphal, L.C. (1974). Toward the synthesis of solutions of dynamic


games, in the Series, Advances in Control Systems, C.T. Leondes (Ed.),
Academic Press, New York, Vol. 11, 389-489.

[844] Whittle, P. (1982/3). Optimization over Time: Dynamic Programming


and Stochastic Control, Vol. I &: I I , Wiley, Chichester.

[845] Wickwire, K. (1977). Mathematical models for the control of pests and
infectious diseases: a survey. Theoretical Population Biology, 11, 182-238.

[846] Wiener, N. (1949). The Interpolation and Smoothing of Stationary Time


Series, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.
480 Bibliography

[847] Wirl, F. (1984). Sensitivity analysis of OPEC pricing polices, OPEC Rev.,
8, 321-331.

[848] Wirl, F. (1985). Stable and volatile prices: and explanation by dynamic
demand, in Optimal Control Theory and Economic Analysis 2, G. Fe-
ichtinger (Ed.), North-Holland, Amsterdam, 263-277.

[849] Wonham, W.M. (1970). Random differential equations in control theory,


in Probabilistic Methods in Applied Mathematics, Vol. 2, A.T. Bharucha-
Reid (Ed.), Academic Press, New York.

[850] Wright, C. (1974). Some political aspects of pollution control. Journal of


Environmental Economics and Management, 1, 173-186.

[851] Wright, S.J. (1993). Interior-point methods for optimal control of


discrete-time systems. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications,
77, 1, 161-187.

[852] Yang, J., Yan, H. and Sethi, S.P. (1999). Optimal production planning in
pull flow lines with multiple products, European Journal of Operational
Research, 119, 3, 26-48.

[853] Yin, G. and Zhang, Q. (1997). Continuous-Time Markov Chains and


Applications: A Singular Perturbation Approach, Springer-Verlag. New
York.

[854] Young, L.C. (1969). Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control Theory,
W.B. Saunders Co., Philadelphia, Pa.

[855] Zeidan, V. (1984a). Extended Jacobi sufficiency criterion for optimal con-
trol, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 22, 294-301.

[856] Zeidan, V. (1984b). A modified Hamilton-Jacobi approach in the gener-


alized problem of Bolza, Appl Math. & Optimiz., 1 1 , 97-109.

[857] Zhou, X. and Sethi, S.P. (1994). A sufficient condition for near optimal
stochastic controls and its application to manufacturing systems. Applied
Mathematics & Optimization, 29, 67-92.

[858] Ziemba, W.T. and Vickson, R.G. (Eds.) (1975). Stochastic Optimization
Models in Finance, Academic Press, New York.

[859] Ziolko, M. and Kozlowski, J. (1983). Evolution of body size: an optimal


control model. Math. Biosci., 64, 127-143.

[860] Zimin, I.N. and Ivanilov, Y.P. (1971). Solution of network planning prob-
lems by reducing them to optimal control problems, Zhurnal Vychifli-
teVnoi Matematiki i Matematichefkoi Fiziki (in Russian), 1 1 , 3.
Bibliography 481

[861] Zoltners, A.A. (Ed.) (1982). Marketing Planning Models, TIMS Studies
in the Management Sciences, Vol. 18, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
Index
Abad, P.L., 417, 474 Axsater, S., 418
adjoint equation, 31, 32, 36, 230
adjoint function, 322 Baar, T., 425
adjoint variables, 10, 32 backlogging of demand, 5, 348
adjoint vector, 30, 33 Bagchi, A., 419
admissible control, 24 Balachandran, B., 445
advertising model, 5, 6 Balakrishman, A.V., 455
affine function, 19 bang function, 16
Agnew, C.E., 417 bang-bang, 42, 78, 84, 85, 87,
Alam, M., 249, 265, 417, 465 122, 132, 135, 190, 194,
AUen, K.R., 286, 417 232, 244, 247, 257, 258,
Amit, R., 154, 279, 418 313, 322, 328, 329, 333,
Amoroso-Robinson relation, 187 334, 408
Anderson, R.M., 418 bankruptcy, 358
anti-difference operator, 376 Bamea, A., 452
Aoki, M., 345, 418 Basar, T., 308, 419, 420, 430,
applications to biomedicine, 295 446
applications to finance, 119 Bass, F.M., 419
applications to marketing, 185 Bayes theorem, 342
Arnold, L., 344, 347, 348, 418 Bean, J . C , 182, 419
Aronson, J.E., 418, 471 begiiming game, 321
Arora, S.R., 243, 418 Bell, D.J., 42, 407, 419
Arrow, K.J., 10, 46, 58, 81, 82, Belhnan, R.E., 9, 27, 419
186, 188, 289, 290, 360, Bennett, R.J., 474
418, 456, 459 Bensoussan, A., 10, 58, 88, 154,
Arthur, W.B., 304, 418 173, 182, 191, 315, 322,
Arugaslan, O., viii 324, 360, 419, 420, 444,
Arutyunov, A.V., 103, 418 461, 470
Aseev, S.M., 103, 418 bequest function, 7, 355
Aubin, J.-R, 418, 466 Berkovitz, L.D., 10, 27, 308, 420
autocorrelation function, 343 Bernoulli, Jacob, 8, 9, 384
autonomous, 52, 81 Bernoulli, Johann, 8, 9, 384
484 Index

Bertsekas, D.P., 236, 346, 420, Bulirsch, R., 9, 108, 422, 461,
430 474
Bes, C , 173, 182, 420 Bullinger, H.J., 479
Beyer, D., viii, 421 Bultez, A.V., 315, 419, 422
Bharucha-Reid, A.T., 480 Burdet, C.A., 236, 239, 422
Bhaskaran, S., 182, 421 Burmeister, E., 290, 291, 422
bionomic eqmlibrium, 269, 314 Buskens, C., 455
Black, F., 355, 421 Butkowskiy, A.G., 317, 422
Blaquiere, A., 325, 326, 331, 421, Bylka, S., 182, 254, 423
464, 473
BUss point, 306 Gaines, P., 423
BUss, G.A., 9 calculus of variations, 8, 379
Boiteux problem, 241 Canon, M.D., 235, 423
Boiteux, M., 241, 421 canonical adjoints, 33
Boltyanskii, V.G., 9, 27, 421, canonical system of equations,
462 33
Bolza, 9 capital accumulation model, 290
Bolza form, 25, 26, 229, 235, 239 Caratheodory, C., 9
Bookbinder, J.H., vi, 10, 304, Carlson, D.A., 10, 82, 423-425
421 Carraro, C , 315, 425
boundary conditions, 61, 350 Carrillo, J., 154, 425
boundary interval, 105 Case, J.H., 308, 325, 425
Bourguignon, F., 421 Cass, D., 425
Brachistochrone problem, 8, 9, Cassandras, C.G., 236, 461
384 cattle ranching problem, 318
Breakwell, J.V., 190, 421 Caulkins, J.P., 477
Brekke, K.A., 360, 422 CeUina, A., 418
Brito, D.L., 304, 422 certainty equivalence, 403, 404
Brock, W.A., 360, 454 Cesari, L., 26, 425
Brockhoff, K., 420 chain of forests model, 276-278
broken extremal, 387 chain of machines, 254
Brotherton, T., 423 Chand, S., 182, 254, 425, 469
Brown, R.G., 164, 422 Chandra, T., 445
Brownian Motion, 356 Chang, S., 360, 418
Bryant, G.F., 27, 422 Charnes, A., 304, 425
Bryson, Jr., A.E., 33, 87, 105, Chatterjee, R., 463
108, 341, 401, 403, 404, Chen, S.F., 425
406, 422 Cheng, F., viii
Buchanan, L.F., 345, 422 Chiarella, C , 426
Bucy, R., 345, 447 Chichilinsky, G., 426
Index 485

Chikan, A., 440 Cottle, R.W., 430


Chintagunta, P.K., 315, 426 Cowling, K., 444
Chow, G.C., 345, 426 critical points, 218
Clark, C.W., 10, 241, 267, 268, Crouhy, M., 173, 182, 419
273, 286, 312, 314, 426 Cruz, J.B., Jr., 472
Clarke, F.H., 27, 106, 167, 427 CuUum, C D . , 235, 423
Clemhout, S., 427 current-value adjoint variables,
closed-loop control, 346 70
closed-loop Nash solution, 311 current-value formulation, 58,
Coddington, E.A., 193, 427 65, 239
Cohen, K.J., 36, 187, 427 current-value functions, 67
common-property fishery re- current-value Hamiltonian, 66
sources, 312 current-value Lagrange multipli-
comparison lemma, 198 ers, 67
complimentary slackness condi- current-value Lagrangian, 66
tions, 60 current-value maximum princi-
computational methods, vii, ple, 68, 111
108, 236 cycloid, 9
concave function, 18, 64 Cyert, R.M., 36, 187, 427
Connors, M.M., 10, 427
Conrad, K., 427 D'Autimie, A., 428
Constantinides, G.M., 427 Dantzig, G.B., 418, 427
constraint of rth order, 105 Darrat, A.F., 456
constraint qualification, 60, 105, Darrough, M.N., 427
226 Dasgupta, P., 279, 428, 474, 476
constraints, 24 Davis, B.E., 119, 129, 152, 360,
consumption model, 7, 8 428
consumption-investment prob- Davis, M.H.A., 346, 428
lem, 355 Davis, R.E., 456
contact time, 105 Dawid, H., 428
continuous wheat trading model, Day, G., 463
164 DDT, 299, 300, 303
control of pest infestations, 295 Deal, K.R., 311, 315, 337, 428
control trajectory, 2, 24 decision horizon, 173, 175, 177,
control variable, 2, 24 179, 180
convex combination, 17 Deger, S., 428
convex function, 18, 64 Deissenberg, C , 428, 429
convex huU, 17 Deistler, M., 476
convex set, 17 derivative operator, 363
CorelDRAW, vii derived Hamiltonian, 45
486 Index

Derzko, N.A., 45, 130, 279, 315, dynamic efficiency condition,


317, 360, 420, 429, 466, 291
469 dynamic programming, 27, 345,
DeSarbo, W., 304, 445 393
Dhrymes, P.J., 213, 429
difference equation, 229, 341 economic applications, 289, 360
diflference operator, 375 economic interpretation, 34, 69,
differential games, 308 138, 291, 322
differentiation with scalars, 12 educational policy, 21
differentiation with vectors, 12, eigenvalues, 370, 371
13 eigenvectors, 370, 371
diffusion process, 344 El-Hodiri, M., 431
Dirac delta function, 323, 344 EUashberg, J., 304, 431, 445, 475
direct adjoining method, 100 Elton, E., 119, 431
direct contribution, 35 Elzinga, D.J., 119, 152, 428
discount factor, 6 ending correction, 158
discount rate, 6 ending game, 321
entry time, 105
discrete maximum principle,
environmental management, 315
217, 228, 229
EOQ, 153
discrete-time optimal control
epidemic control, 295
problem, 228, 229
equilibrimn relation, 36
distributed parameter maximimi
Erickson, G.M., 431
principle, 317
Erickson, L.E., 10, 154, 315, 443
distributed parameter systems,
Euler, 8, 384
315
Euler equation, 380, 382, 387,
Dixit, A.K., 429
388
Dobell, A.R., 290, 291, 422
EXCEL, vii, 48-50
Dockner, E.J., 10, 289, 304, 308, exhaustible resource model, 279
315, 429, 430, 432, 446 exit time, 105
Dohrmann, C.R., 236, 430
Dolan, R.J., 430, 445 factorial power, 375
Dorfman, R., 430 Fan, L.T., 154, 304, 431, 443
Dornoff, R.J., 474 Farley, J.U., 475
Drews, W., 430 Feichtinger, G., vi, viii, 10, 33,
Dreyfus, S.E., 420 58, 69, 81, 99, 106, 108,
dual variables, 36 113, 154, 167, 185, 194,
Dubovitskii, A.Y., 430 211, 289, 304, 322, 427-
Dunn, J . C , 236, 430 429, 431-434, 438-440,
Durrett, R., 347, 431 442, 446, 451, 453, 455,
Index 487

457^59, 463-465, 470, Furst, E., 476


473, 475^78, 480
Feinberg, F.M., 434 Gaandolfo, G., 436
Fel'dbaum, A.A., 31, 393, 398, Gaimon, C , 154, 249, 304, 322,
434 331, 425, 435, 436
Ferreira, M.M.A., 103, 434 Galileo, 384
Ferreyra, G., 434 Gamkrelidze, R.V., 9, 436, 462
Filar, J., 315, 425 Gandolfo, G., 432
Filipiak, J., 434 Gaskins, Jr., D.W., 436
filtering, 339, 341 Gaugusch, J., 437
finite diflference equations, 375 Gaussian, 341-343
first-order pure state con- Geismar, N., viii
straints, 106, 108
Gelfand, I.M., 379, 380, 382,
Fischer, T., 434
387, 389, 437
Fisher, A.C., 461
general discrete maximum prin-
fishery management, 315
ciple, 234
fishery model, 268, 312
general inequality constraints,
fishing mortality function, 314
97
fixed-end-point problem, 70
generalized bang-bang, 87, 132
Fleming, W.H., 346, 360, 434
generalized derivative, 344
Fletcher, R., 434
generalized Legendre-Clebsch
Fomin, S.V., 379, 380, 382, 387,
condition, 152, 407, 408
389, 437
forecast horizons, 173 Geoffrion, A.M., 453
forest fertilization model, 287 Gerchak, Y., 437
forest thinning model, 273, 276 Gfrerer, H., 437
forgetting coefficient, 5 Gibson, J.E., 408, 445
Forster, B.A., 435 Gihman, LI., 344, 353, 437
Fourgeaud, C , 435 Gillessen, W., 455
Francis, P.J., 295, 435 Girsanov, I.V., 437
Frankena, J.F., 435 Glad, S.T., 437
free-end-point problem, 70 goal level, 319
Friedman, A., 308, 435 GOAL SEEK, 48, 49
Fromovitz, S., 228, 455 Goh, B.-S., 108, 267, 437
Fruchter, G.E., 315, 435 Goh, C.J., 476
fuU-rank condition, 20, 60, 105, Goldberg, S., 375, 437
106 Golden Path, 82
Fuller, D., 280, 435 Golden Rule, 82, 93
fundamental lemma, 382 Goldstine, H.H., 437
Funke, U.H., 435 goodwill, 5, 186
488 Index

goodwill elasticity of demand, 304, 317, 322, 428, 432,


188 433, 438-442, 453, 473
Gopalsamy, K., 437 Harvey, A.C., 442
Gordon's formula, 145 Haunschmied, J., 304, 433
Gordon, H.S., 268, 269, 437 Haurie, A., 10, 82, 173, 308, 315,
Gordon, M.J., 145, 437 317, 322, 420, 424, 425,
Gould, J.P., 191, 210, 214, 437 438, 442
Green's theorem, 185, 196, 198, Haussmann, U.G., 442
205, 211, 214, 270, 296, Heal, G.M., 279, 428, 443, 476
297, 305, 314 Heaps, T., 241, 443
Grimm, W., 438, 459 Heckman, J., 443
Gross, M., 438 Heineke, J.M., 427
Gruber, M., 119, 431 Hestenes, M.R., 10, 58, 62, 443
Gruver, W.A., 448 higher-order constraints, 105
HJB equation, 30, 31, 354
Hadley, G., 10, 58, 289, 438 HMMS model, 153
Hahn, M., 438 Ho, Y.-C., 33, 87, 105, 308, 311,
Halkin, H., 27, 235, 438 341, 401, 403, 404, 406,
Hamalainen, R.P., 315, 438 422, 443, 459, 473
Hamilton, 9 Hochman, E., 360, 464
Hamilton-Jacobi equation, 349 Hoffmann, K.H., 443
Hamilton-Jacobi-BeUman equa- Hohn, F., 174, 457
tion, 27, 30, 345, 349 Holly, S., 443
Hamiltonian, 30, 35, 60, 230, Holt, C.C., 153, 443
291, 397 Holtzman, J.M., 235, 443
Hamiltonian maximizing condi- homogeneous equation, 363
tion, 30, 34, 397 homogeneous equations of order
Han, M., 438 n, 365
Hanson, M., 457 homogeneous equations of order
Hanssens, D.M., 438 one, 364
Harris, F.W., 153, 438 homogeneous equations of order
Harris, H., 303, 439 two, 364
Harrison, J.M., 357, 439 homogeneous function of degree
Hartberger, R.J., 27, 396, 430, one, 19
439 homogeneous partial differential
Hartl, R.F., viii, 10, 26, 27, 33, equations, 374
58, 62, 69, 81, 89, 99, Horsky, D., 443
100, 105, 106, 108, 113, Hotelling, H., 279, 443
115, 154, 167, 174, 185, Hung, N.M., 442
194, 211, 239, 243, 303, Hurst, Jr., E.G., 10, 58, 154, 419
Index 489

Hwang, C.L., 154, 443 Jazwinski, A.H., 444


Hyun, J.S., 438 Jedidi, K., 304, 445
Jennings, L.S., 445
Ijiri, Y., 153, 165, 444 Jeuland, A.P., 430, 445
Ilan, Y., 154, 418 Jiang, J., 445
imp, 17 Johnson, C D . , 408, 445
impulse control, 16, 125, 202, Jones, P., 445
204, 322, 324, 325 J0rgensen, S., viii, 10, 154, 267,
impulse control model, 88 289, 304, 308, 315, 429,
impulse Hamiltonian, 326 430, 433, 440, 445, 446
impulse maximum principle, Joseph, P.D., 341, 404, 446
326, 332 jirnip conditions, 103, 108
impulse stochastic control, 360 jump Markov processes, 360
imputed value, 219 junction times, 105
indirect adjoining method, 98,
100, 104,111 Kaitala, V.T., 315, 433, 438, 446
indirect contribution, 35 Kalaba, R.E., 419
infinite horizon, 6, 80 Kalish, S., 304, 435, 446, 447
inhomogeneous partial differen- KaU, P., 439, 458, 470
tial equation, 374 Kahnan filter, 339, 340, 342
instantaneous profit rate, 25 Kahnan, R.E., 341, 345, 447
interior interval, 105 Kaknan-Bucy filter, 339, 345
Intriligator, M.D., 290, 444, 456 Kamien, M.I., 10, 248, 253, 289,
inventory control problem, 117 303, 447
loffe, A.D., 444 Kamien-Schwartz model, 249
Isaacs, R., 9, 133, 308, 444 Kaplan, W., 447
isoperimetric profit constraint, Karatzas, I., 340, 344, 347, 359,
214 360, 447
Ito stochastic differential equa- Karreman, H.F., 421
tion, 344, 345 Keeler, E., 448
Ivanilov, Y.P., 304, 480 Keller, H.B., 299, 448
Kemp, M.C., 10, 58, 289, 426,
Jabrane, A., 424 438, 448
Jacobi, 9 Kendrick, D.A., 448
Jacobson, D.H., 42, 108, 407, Keon, J.W., 476
419, 444, 451 Khmelnitsky, E., 10, 448, 449,
Jacquemin, A.P., 188, 191, 444 454
Jagpal, S., 444 Kilkki, P., 273, 274, 448
Jain, D., 315, 426 Kirakossian, G.T., 304, 440
Jamshidi, M., 444 Kirby, B.J., 448
490 Index

Kirk, D.E., 31, 448 L'Hospital, 384


Klein, C.F., 448 Lagrange, 8
Kleindorfer, G.B., 234, 449 Lagrange form, 25
Kleindorfer, P.R., 174, 182, 234, Lagrange multipliers, 57, 218
448, 449, 470 Lagrangian, 57, 60
Kleinschmidt, P., 440 Lagtmov, V.N., 450
Knobloch, H.W., 449 Lakhani, C , 465
Knowles, G., 449 Lansdowne, Z.F., 206, 450
Kogan, K., 10, 448, 449, 454 Lasdon, L.S., 450
Kopel, M., 428 Leban, R., 10, 289, 450, 451
Kort, P.M., 10, 154, 267, 289, Leclair, S.R., 445
303, 304, 433, 440, 441, Lee, E.B., 129, 450
446, 478 Lee, S.C, 213, 469
Kortanek, K., 304, 425 Lee, W.Y., 450
Kotowitz, Y., 449 left and right limits, 15
Kozlowski, J., 480 Legendre, 8
Krabs, W., 443 Legendre's conditions, 388
Kraft, D., 108, 422 Legey, L., 304, 450
Krarup, J., 430 Lehoczky, J.P., 130, 359, 447,
Krauth, J., 304, 441 450, 469
Kreindler, E., 449 Leibniz, 8
KreUe, W., 420, 449 Leitmann, G., 27, 267, 308, 379,
Krichagina, E., 449 425, 437, 438, 442, 451,
Kriebel, C.H., 234, 449 457, 473
Kriendler, E., 108 Leizarowitz, A., 424, 425
Krouse, C O . , 129, 449, 450 Leland, H.E., 451
Krutilla, J.V., 447 Lele, M.M., 108, 444, 451
Kugelmann, B., 450 Lele, P.T., 243, 418
Kuhn, H.W., 472 Lenclud, B., 435
Kuhn-Tucker conditions, 218, Leonard, D., 10, 289, 451
220, 228 Leondes, C.T., 422, 473, 479
Kuhn-Tucker constraint qualifi- Lesourne, J., 10, 289, 360, 419,
cation, 226, 227 420, 450, 451
Kumar, S., viii Lev, B., 436
Kurawarwala, A.A., 450 Levine, J., 451
Kurcyusz, S., 103, 450 Levinson, N.L., 193, 427
Kurz, M., 10, 46, 58, 81, 82, 188, Lewis, T.R., 451, 452
289, 290, 418 Li, G., 154, 452
Kushner, H.J., 450 Lieber, Z., 174, 182, 438, 449,
Kydland, F.E., 450 452
Index 491

LigneU, J., 452 maintenance and replacement


LiUen, G.L., 304, 446 model, 241, 242, 248,
line integral, 197 331
linear differential equations, 363 Majumdar, M., 454
linear independence, 20 Malinowski, K., 115, 454, 472
linear Mayer form, 25, 26, 239 Malliaris, A.G., 360, 454
linear programming, 87, 132 Mangasarian, O.L., 46, 64, 226-
linear-quadratic case, 85 228, 455
linear-quadratic problems, 401 Manh-Hung, N., 279, 455
linearly independent, 20 Mantrala, M.K., 345, 458
Lintner, J., 452 MAPI (Machinery and Applied
Lions, J.L., 88, 317, 324, 360, Products Institute), 241
420, 444, 452, 470 MAPLE, 150
Little, J.D.C., 452 marginal cost, 36, 187
little-o notation, 15 marginal cost equals marginal
Liu, P.-T., 418, 421, 428, 451, revenue, 36
452 marginal return, 398
Loewen, P.D., 106, 427 marginal revenue, 36
logarithmic Brownian Motion, Markus, L., 450
356 martingale problems, 360
Long, N.V., 10, 289, 308, 315, Martirena-Mantel, A.M., 455
426, 430, 448, 451, 452 Marzano, P., 432
long-rim stationary equilibrium, Masse, P., 241, 455
82 Mate, K., 443
Loon, P.J.J.M., van, 453 Mathematica, 150
Lou, S., 449, 453 mathematical requirements, 1
Lucas, Jr., R.E., 304, 453 Mathewson, P., 449
Luenberger, D.G., 228, 453 matrix Riccati equation, 345,
Luhmer, A., 433, 453 403
limiped parameter systems, 315 Matsuo, H., 450
Lundin, R.A., 174, 182, 453 Maurer, H., viii, 108, 115, 118,
Luptacik, M., 303, 441, 453, 463 455
Luus, R., 454 maximized Hamiltonian, 114
Lynn, J.W., 249, 417 maximum, 388
maximum likelihood estimate,
Macki, J., 454 342
Magat, W.A., 454 maximum principle, 23, 33, 34,
Magill, M.J.P., 454 57, 58, 67, 104,113, 217,
Mahajan, V., 430, 447, 452, 454 393
Maimon, O., 10, 448, 449, 454 May, R.M., 418
492 Index

Mayer form, 25, 397 model type (b), 85-87


Mayne, D.Q., 27, 108, 236, 422, model type (c), 85
456, 460, 462 model type (d), 85
McCabe, J.L., 451 model type (e), 85, 86
McCann, J.M., 454 model type (f), 85, 86, 251
McEneaney, W.M., 470 model types, 83, 85
McGuire, T.W., 304, 469 modeling "tricks", 86
Mclntyre, J., 108, 456 Modigliani, F., 130, 153, 174,
McNicoU, G., 304, 418 443, 457
McShane, E.J., 10 Moiseev, N.N., 457
measurement noise, 340 Monahan, G.E., 457
Meech, J.A., 445 Mond, B., 457
Mehlmann, A., 304, 305, 308, Moore, E.J., 476
429, 433, 441, 456 Morey, R.C., 454
Mehra, R.K., 304, 456 Morton, T.E., vi, 174, 182, 254,
Mehrez, A., 456 259, 264, 453, 457, 458,
Merton, R.C., 355, 456 469
Mesak, H.I., 456 Motta, M., 324, 458
Michel, P., 428, 435, 457 Muller, E., 430, 452, 454, 458
middle game, 321 Mulvey, J.M., 469
Miele, A., 196, 457 Murata, Y., 458
MiUer, M.H., 130, 457 Murray, D.M., 236, 458
MiUer, R.E., 457 Muth, J.F., 153, 443
Milyutin, A.A., 430 Muzicant, J., 322, 458
minimax solution, 308, 309
minimum fuel problem, 238 Naert, P.A., 315, 419, 422
Mirman, L.J., 452, 457 Nahorski, Z., 458
Mirrlees, J., 457 Naik, P.A., 345, 458
miscellaneous applications, 303 Nash solutions, 308
Mischenko, E.F., 9, 462 Naslund, B., 10, 58, 154, 241,
MitcheU, A., 457 278, 287, 419, 458
Mitra, T., 454 natural resources, 267, 360
Mitter, S.K., 459 necessary condition, 31, 33, 228
mixed constraints, 59, 104, 106 Neck, R., 458
mixed inequality constraints, 3, needle-shaped variation, 394,
57, 58 395
mixed optimization technique, neighborhood, 15
258 Nelson, R.T., 304, 458
model type (a), 84, 85, 87, 243, Nepomiastchy, P., 304, 459
244 Nerlove, M., 186, 188, 459
Index 493

Nerlove-Love advertising model, optimal long-run stationary


186 equilibriimi, 82, 189
Neuman, C.P., 186, 477 optimal path, 25
Neustadt, L.W., 10, 455, 459 optimal thinning, 274
Newton, 8, 384 optimal trajectory, 25
Nguyen, D., 459 order of the constraint, 105
Nissen, G., 322, 420 Oren, S.S., 460
nonlinear programming, 217, Osayimwese, I., 460
218, 227 overdraft, 124
nonzero-simi games, 310 Ozga model, 214
norm, 15 Ozga, S., 214, 460
Norstrom, C.J., vi, 125, 153,
170, 459 Paiewonsky, B., 108, 456
Norton, F.E., 345, 422
Palda, K.S., 186, 460
notation, 10
Pantoja, J.F., 236, 460
Novak, A., 304, 433, 434, 441,
parametric linear programming,
459
87
Oakland, W.H., 304, 422 Parlar, M., 437, 460
Oberle, H.J., 438, 459 Parrish, B., 417
objective function, 2, 25, 398 Parsons, L.J., 438
Oettli, W., 422 partial differential equations,
Oguztoreli, M.N., 459 372
oil driller's problem, 324 partial fractions, 350
0ksendal, B.K., 344, 360, 422, particular integral, 367
459 particular solutions, 366, 367
Okuguchi, K., 426 path of least time, 8
Olsder, G.J., 419, 459 Pauwels, W., 460
one-sector model, 291 Pekelman, D., 154, 174, 182,
one-sided constraints, 71 241, 259, 460, 461
Oniki, H., 460 Pepyne, D.L., 236, 461
open access fishery, 269 Pesch, H.J., 9, 450, 461
open-loop Nash solution, 310 pessimal solution, 146
optimal consumption of an ini- Peterson, D.W., 461
tial investment, 89 Peterson, F.M., 461
optimal control problem, 25 Peterson, R.A., 454
optimal control theory, 1, 379 Petrov, lu.P., 461
optimal economic growth mod- phase diagram, 192, 293, 301
els, 289, 293 Phelps, E.S., 437
optimal financing model, 129 Pierskalla, W.P., 241, 461
494 Index

Pindyck, R.S., 279, 360, 429, rank of a matrix, 20


461, 462, 478 Rao, R.C., 315, 463
Pitchford, J.D., 435, 452, 462 Rapoport, A., 464
Pliska, S.R., 357, 439 Rapp, B., 241, 464
Pohjola, M., 462 Rausser, G.C., 360, 461, 464
Polak, E., 108, 235, 423, 456, 462 Raviv, A., 304, 464
pollution control model, 299, 302 Ravn, H.F., 458
Pontryagin, L.S., 9, 10, 23, 27, Ray, A., 464
76, 106, 393, 462 reachable set, 3, 59
Powell, S.G., 460 Reeves, CM., 434
predator-prey relationships, 267 regional allocation of invest-
Prescott, E.G., 450 ment, 52
Presman, E., 462, 463 Reinganum, J.F., 464
price elasticity of demand, 187 Rempala, R., 174, 464
price shield, 174, 175, 177 Richard, S.F., 427, 464
principle of optimality, 27, 346, Ringbeck, J., 304, 464
358 Ripper, M., 304, 450
product rule for differentiation, Rishel, R.W., 346, 434, 465
14 Roberts, S.M., 33, 465
production fimction, 292 Robinett, R.D., 236, 430
production planning model, 153, Robinson, B., 465
339 Robson, A.J., 322, 465
production smoothing, 154 Rockafeller, R.T., 465
production-inventory model, 4, Roxin, E.G., 421, 423, 452
153, 154, 234 Russak, B., 465
Proth, J.-M., 173, 182, 419, 425 Russell, D.L., 427, 465
Prskawetz, A., 463 Riistem, B., 443
pure constraints, 116 Ruusunen, J., 315, 438
pure state variable inequality Ryu, Y., viii
constraints, 3, 97, 98,
104 saddle point, 19, 309
Pytlak, R., 108, 463 Sage, A.P., 317, 465
Salukvadze, M.E., 465
quasiconcave fimction, 64 salvage value, 3, 25, 87
quasiconvex function, 64 Samaratunga, G., 466
Samuelson, P.A., 465
Rajagopalan, S., 154, 452 Sargent, T.J., 453
Raman, K., 360, 463 Sarma, V.V.S., 249, 265, 417,
Rampazzo, F., 324, 458 465
Ramsey, P.P., 69, 289, 306, 463 Sasieni, M., 466
Index 495

sat fiinction, 16 476, 480


Sawyer, A., 345, 458 Sethi-Morton model, 254, 264,
Scalzo, R.C., 466 331
Schaefer, M.B., 268, 466 shadow price, 10, 35, 219
Schijndel, G.-J.C.Th.,van, 304, Shapiro, A., 472
466 Shapiro, C , 103, 472
SchiUing, K., 466 Shell, K., 289, 425, 472
Schmalensee, R., 451, 452 Shipman, J.S., 33, 465
Scholes, M., 355, 421 shooting method, 182
Schubert, U., 303, 453 short-selling, 124
Schultz, R. L., 438 Shreve, S.E., 340, 344, 346, 347,
Schwartz, N.L., 10, 248, 253, 359, 360, 420, 447
289, 303, 447 Shtub, A., 449
Schwodiauer, G., 476 Siebert, H., 472
second-order differential equa- Silva, G.N., 324, 472
tions, 359 Simaan, M., 472
second-order variations, 388, 405 Simon, H.A., 153, 404, 443, 472
Segers, R., 430 Simon, L.S., 443
Seidman, T.I., 315, 466 simple cash balance problem,
Seierstad, A., 10, 27, 45, 58, 62, 120
64, 81, 99, 113, 289, 466 simplest variational problem,
Selten, R., 308, 466 379
Sen, S.K., 428, 447 Singh, M.G., 468, 472
Sengupta, J.K., 477 singular arcs, 407
separation principle, 403, 404 singular control, 42, 132, 140,
Sethi, S.P., 10, 26, 27, 45, 58, 297, 407
62, 89, 99,100,105, 106, Skiba, A.K., 472
108, 113, 115, 119, 129, Skorohod, A.V., 344, 353, 437
130, 150, 153, 154, 173, Smith, B.L.R., 444
174, 182, 185, 190, 194- Smith, M., 445
196, 202, 206, 213-215, Smith, R.L., 182, 419
236, 239, 241, 247, 254, Smith, V.K., 447
259, 264, 270, 271, 276, Smith, V.L., 472
278, 279, 295, 298, 303, Snower, D.J., 472
304, 311, 315, 317, 322, sole owner fishery resource
337, 340, 347, 351, 352, model, 268
354, 357-360, 420-423, Soliman, M.A., 304, 475
425, 427-429, 433, 441, Solow, R.M., 279, 472, 473
442, 445, 447, 449, 450, Soner, H.M., 360, 434, 450
453, 461-464, 466-471, Sorenson, H., 341, 473
496 Index

Sorger, G., viii, 10, 182, 254, stochastic advertising problem,


289, 308, 315, 423, 425, 352
430, 433, 434, 453, 469, stochastic calculus, 347
473 stochastic differential equations,
Sothmann, B., 459 339, 344
Southwick, L., 303, 473 stochastic manufacturing prob-
special topics, 401 lems, 360
Spence, M., 299, 448, 473 stochastic optimal control, 339,
Speyer, J.L., 108, 444 345, 346
Spiegel, M.R., 375, 473 stochastic production planning
Spremarm, K., 473 model, 347
Sprzeuzkouski, A.Y., 154, 473 stockout cost, 5
Spulber, P.F., 452, 457 Stoer, J., 422, 474
Srinivasan, V., 186, 473 stopping time, 357
Sriskandarajah, C , viii Stoppler, S., 10, 154, 429, 474
Staats, P.W., 295, 469 Strauss, A., 454
Stalford, H., 473 Streitferdt, L., 466
strengthened Jacobi condition,
standard adjoint variables, 65
389
standard Hamiltonian, 65
strengthened Legendre condi-
standard Lagrangian, 65
tion, 389
standard multipliers, 65
strengthened Legendre-Clebsch
Starr, A.W., 308, 311, 473
condition, 406
starting correction, 158
strictly concave function, 18, 64
state equation, 24 strictly convex function, 64
state trajectory, 2, 24 strong forecast horizon, 174,
state variable, 2, 24 177, 179
static efficiency condition, 291 strong maximum, 389, 390
stationarity assumption, 81 sufficiency conditions, 44, 46, 64,
Stein, R.B., 459 113, 228
Steinberg, R., 431 sufficiency transversality condi-
Steindl, A., 453, 473 tion, 159
Steiner, P.O., 430 summary of transversality con-
Stepan, A., 473 ditions, 75
Stern, L.E., 473 Suo, W., viii, 462, 469, 470
Stiglitz, J.E., 474 surveys of appfications, 10
Stirling numbers of the first Sutinen, J.G., 428, 452
kind, 378 Swan, G.W., 295, 474
StirUng numbers of the second Sweeney, D.J., 417, 474
kind, 376 switching curves, 78
Index 497

switching point, 138 Tintner, G., 477


switching time, 80 TitU, A., 472
Sydsaeter, K., 10, 27, 45, 58, 62, Tolwinski, B., 308, 442, 477
64, 81, 99,113, 289, 466, total contribution, 35
474 Tou, J.T., 341, 404, 446
synthesis of optimal controls, 76, Toussaint, S., 477
133 TPBVP, 33, 48, 50, 182, 291
system, 2 Tracz, G.S., 477
system noise, 340 Tragler, G., 477
Szego, G.P., 472 transition matrix, 396
transversality condition, 32, 62,
Takayama, A., 36, 289, 431, 474 67, 69, 75, 81
Taksar, M.I., 449, 450, 469, 470 Treadway, A.B., 303, 477
Tan, K.C., 474 Troch, I., 477
Tapiero, C.S., 10, 254, 264, 304, Tsurumi, H., 214, 477
322, 360, 420, 470, 474, Tsurumi, Y., 214, 477
475 Tu, P.N.V., 10, 303, 477
Taylor, J.G., 108, 304, 475 Tuominen, M.P.T., 452
Teichroew, D., 10, 427 Turner, R.E., 185, 477
Teng, J.-T., 182, 475, 476 Turnovsky, S.J., 435, 452, 462,
Teo, K.L., 108, 445, 476 477
Terborgh, G., 241, 476 turnpike, 82, 158, 189, 207
terminal conditions, 32, 69 two person zero-sum games, 308
terminal inequality constraints, two-point bovmdary value prob-
59 lem, 33, 48, 372
terminal time, 4, 25, 62 two-reservoir system, 116
Thepot, J., 304, 451, 476 Tzafestas, S.G., 322, 432, 477
Thisse, J., 444
Thompson's maintenance Udayabhanu, V., 470
model, 331 Uhler, R.S., 478
Thompson, G.L., 45, 119, 153, utility of consiunption, 7, 289,
165, 174, 182, 234, 241, 290, 355
249, 259, 264, 304, 311,
315, 317, 322, 331, 337, Vaisanen, U., 273, 274, 448
347, 351, 418, 428, 429, Valentine, F.A., 10, 478
436, 444, 449, 470, 475, value function, 27, 346
476 Van Hilten, O., 10, 289, 478
Tihomirov, V.M., 444 Van Loon, P.J.J.M., 10, 289, 478
time-optimal control problem, Vanthienen, L., 174, 478
76 Varaiya, P.P., 304, 308, 450, 478
498 Index

variational equations, 395 Weinstein, M.C., 279, 479


Veinott, A.F., 418 Weitz, B., 463
Venezia, I., 475 Weizsacker, C.C. von, 479
Verheyen, P.A., 304, 478 Welam, U.P., 479
Verma, B., 445 WeU, K.H., 438
Vickson, R.G., 26, 27, 58, 62, 99, Wensley, R., 463
100, 105, 106, 108, 113, Westphal, L.C., 479
115, 154, 280, 420, 435, wheat trading model with no
442, 460, 478, 480 short-selling, 170
Vidal, R.V.V., 458 Whitin, T.M., 153, 254, 479
Vidale, M.L., 186, 194, 195, 478 Whittle, P., 479
Vidale-Wolfe advertising model, Wickwire, K., 10, 295, 479
194, 353 Wiegand, M., 118, 455
Vilcassim, N.J., 315, 426 Wiener process, 344, 346, 356
Villas-Boas, J.M., 478 Wiener, N., 479
Vincent, T.L., 267, 437 Wind, Y., 430, 447, 454, 475
Vinokurov, V.R., 478 Wirl, F., 434, 480
Vinter, R.B., 103, 108, 324, 434, Wolfe, H.B., 186, 194, 195, 478
463, 472, 478 Wong, K.H., 108, 476
Voelker, J.A., 241, 461 Wonham, W.M., 480
Vousden, N., 303, 452, 479 Wright, C , 303, 480
Wright, S.J., 236, 480
Wagner, H.M., 153, 254, 479 Wunderlich, H.J., 479
Wagner-Whitin framework, 258
Wagner-Whitin solution, 262 Yakowitz, S.J., 236, 458
Wan, F.Y., 473 Yan, H., viii, 469, 480
Wan, Jr., H.Y., 427 Yang, J., 480
Wang, C.-S., 304, 431 Yang, T.H., 108, 462
Wang, P.K.C., 479 Yeh, D., viii
warehousing constraint, 175 Yin, G., 360, 462, 468, 470, 471,
Warga, J., 479 480
Warnecke, H.J., 479 Young, L.C., 379, 399, 480
Warschat, J., 479
weak forecast horizon, 174, 175 Zaccour, G., 154, 446
weak maximum, 389 Zalkin, J.H., 461
Weierstrass, 9 Zarrop, M.B., 443
Weierstrass necessary condition, Zeckhauser, R.J., 279, 299, 448,
389, 391 479
Weierstrass-Erdmann corner Zeidan, V., 480
conditions, 388 Zemel, E., 457
Index 499

Zhang, H., viii, 462, 463, 470,


471
Zhang, Q., viii, 340, 360, 453,
462, 463, 468, 470, 471,
480
Zhou, X., 466, 471, 480
Ziemba, W.T., 469, 480
Zimin, I.N., 304, 480
Ziolko, M., 480
Zionts, S., 303, 471, 473
Zoltners, A.A., 445, 481
Zowe, J., 103, 450
Zuckermann, D., 475
List of Figures

1.1 The Brachistochrone Problem 9


1.2 A Concave Function 18
1.3 An Illustration of a Saddle Point 19

2.1 An Optimal Path in the State-Time Space 28


2.2 Optimal State and Adjoint Trajectories for Example 2.1 . 38
2.3 Optimal State and Adjoint Trajectories for Example 2.2 . 39
2.4 Optimal Trajectories for Examples 2.3 and 2.4 41
2.5 Optimal Control for Example 2.5 44
2.6 Solution of TPBVP by EXCEL 50
2.7 Water Reservoir of Example 2.12 53

3.1 State and Adjoint Trajectories in Example 3.3 73


3.2 Minimum Time Optimal Response for Problem (3.63) . . 79

4.1 State and Adjoint Trajectories in Example 4.1 102


4.2 Infeasible State Space and Optimal State Trajectory
for Example 4.3 109
4.3 Adjoint Trajectory for Example 4.3 Ill
4.4 Two-Reservoir System of Exercise 4.6 116

5.1 Optimal Policy Shown in (Ai, A2) Space 123


5.2 Optimal Policy Shown in (^, A2/A1) Space 124
5.3 Adjoint Variables and Lagrange Multipliers for
Example 5.1 128
5.4 Case A: g<r 133
5.5 Case A: g > r 134
5.6 Optimal Path for Case A: g <r 139
5.7 Optimal Path for Case B: g > r 143
5.8 Solution for Exercise 5.10 150
5.9 Adjoint Trajectories for Exercise 5.11 151
502 List of Figures

6.1
Optimal Production and Inventory Levels 161
Solution of Example 6.1 with IQ = 10
6.2 163
Solution of Example 6.1 with IQ = 50
6.3 164
6.4
Solution of Example 6.1 with Io=^30 165
6.5
The Price Trajectory (6.49) 168
6.6
Adjoint Variable, Optimal Policy and Inventory in the
Wheat Trading Model 169
6.7 Adjoint Trajectory and Optimal Policy for the Wheat
Trading Model 173
6.8 Decision Horizon and Optimal Policy for the Wheat
Trading Model 175
6.9 Optimal Policy and Horizons for the Wheat Trading
Model with Warehouse Constraint 177
6.10 Optimal Policy and Horizons for Example 6.3 179
6.11 Optimal Policy and Horizons for Example 6.4 180
6.12 The Flow Chart for Exercise 6.9 183

7.1 Optimal Policies in the Nerlove-Arrow Model 189


7.2 A Case of a Time-Dependent Turnpike and the Nature
of Optimal Control 190
7.3 Phase Diagram of System (7.18) for Problem (7.13) . . . . 192
7.4 Feasible Arcs in (^, a;)-Space 197
7.5 Optimal Trajectory for Case 1: XQ < x^ and x^ > XT - - • 200
7.6 Optimal Trajectory for Case 2: XQ < x^ and x^ < XT - - - 200
7.7 Optimal Trajectory for Case 3: XQ > x^ and x^ > XT - - - 201
7.8 Optimal Trajectory for Case 4: XQ > x^ and x^ < XT • • - 201
7.9 Optimal Trajectory (Solid Lines) 202
7.10 Optimal Trajectory When T Is Small in Case 1: XQ < x^
8indxT<x^ 203
7.11 Optimal Trajectory When T Is Small in Case 2: XQ > x^
andxT<x' 203
7.12 Optimal Trajectory for Case 2 of Theorem 7.1 for Q = oo 204
7.13 Optimal Trajectories for x{0) <x 208
7.14 Optimal Trajectory for x(0) >x 209

8.1 Shortest Distance from a Point to a Semi-Circle 224


8.2 Graph of Example 8.5 224
8.3 Kuhn-Tucker Constraint Qualification 226
8.4 Discrete-Time Conventions 229
8.5 Sketch of x^ and A^ 233
List of Figures 503

9.1 Optimal Maintenance and Machine Resale Value 247


9.2 Sat Function Optimal Control 249

10.1 Optimal Policy for the Sole Owner Fishery Model 271
10.2 Singular Usable Timber Volume x{t) 275
10.3 Optimal Policy for the Forest Thinning Model when
XQ < x{to) 276
10.4 Optimal Policy for the Chain of Forests Model when
T>i 277
10.5 Optimal Policy for the Chain of Forests Model when
T<i 279
10.6 The Demand Function 281
10.7 The Profit Function 282
10.8 Optimal Price Trajectory for T > f 285
10.9 Optimal Price Trajectory for T < f 285

11.1 Phase Diagram for the Optimal Growth Model 293


11.2 Optimal Trajectory when XT > x^ 298
11.3 Optimal Trajectory when XT <x^ 298
11.4 Food Output Function 300
11.5 Phase Diagram for the Pollution Control Model 302

12.1 Region D with Boundaries Fi and r2 316


12.2 A Partition of Region D 320
12.3 Solution of Equation 12.52 323
12.4 Boundary of No-Drilling Region 328
12.5 Drilling Time 329
12.6 Value o f - Q + A ( t + ) [ l - x ( t ) ] 330
12.7 Optimal Maintenance Policy 333
12.8 Replacement Time ti and Maintenance Policy 335
12.9 The Case ^ 1 - ^ 2 336

13.1 Autocorrelation Function for a Scalar Process 343


13.2 A Sample Path of Xt with Xo = a;o > 0 and 5 > 0 . . . . 352

B.l Examples of Admissible Functions for the Problem . . . . 380


B.2 Variation about the Solution Function 381
B.3 A Broken Extremal with Corner at r 387
504 List of Figures

C.l Needle-Shaped Variation 394


C.2 Trajectories x*{t) and x{t) in a One-Dimensional Case. . . 394
List of Tables

1.1 The Product ion-Inventory Model of Example 1.1 4


1.2 The Advertising Model of Example 1.2 6
1.3 The Consumption Model of Example 1.3 8

3.1 Summary of the Transversality Conditions 75


3.2 State Trajectories and Switching Curves 78
3.3 Objective, State, and Adjoint Equations for Various
Model Types 85

5.1 Characterization of Optimal Controls 135

A.l Examples of Homogeneous Equations of Order Two . . . 364


A.2 General Solution Forms for Second-Order Linear
Homogeneous Equations, Constant Coefficients 365
A.3 Examples of Homogeneous E]quations of Order n 366
A.4 General Solution Forms for Multiple Roots of Auxiliary
Equation 366
A.5 Particular Solution Forms for Various Forcing Functions . 367
A.6 Particular Integrals in Specific Examples 368
A.7 General Solution Forms for Some Homogeneous Partial
Differential Equations 374

You might also like