Lecture 2 Market Prices and Present Value Printout Final
Lecture 2 Market Prices and Present Value Printout Final
Key Concepts
■ State-space model for time and risk
■ Arbitrage pricing
■ Present value and future value
■ Nominal vs. real cash flows and returns
Key Concepts
■ State-space model for time and risk
■ Arbitrage pricing
■ Present value and future value
■ Nominal vs. real cash flows and returns
State-space model
■ Assume frictionless financial market for 𝑋𝑋1𝑖𝑖 , 𝑝𝑝1
simplicity.
𝑋𝑋2𝑖𝑖 , 𝑝𝑝2
■ Assets can be traded at time 𝑡𝑡 = 0 with
𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 𝑖𝑖 ⦙
payoffs at time 𝑡𝑡 = 1.
𝑖𝑖
■ The price of an asset is 𝑃𝑃 at 𝑡𝑡 = 0 with 𝑋𝑋𝑁𝑁−1 , 𝑝𝑝𝑁𝑁−1
payoff 𝑋𝑋 = (𝑋𝑋1 , … , 𝑋𝑋𝑁𝑁 ) at 𝑡𝑡 = 1. 𝑋𝑋𝑁𝑁𝑖𝑖 , 𝑝𝑝𝑁𝑁
■ 𝑋𝑋 is a random variable.
State prices
■ Consider primitive state-contingent claims 0
(Arrow-Debreu securities) that pay $1 in a
single state and nothing otherwise. ⦙
Key Concepts
■ State-space model for time and risk
■ Arbitrage pricing
■ Present value and future value
■ Nominal vs. real cash flows and returns
Arbitrage pricing
■ With the prices of A-D securities, we can price other assets/securities.
■ Consider a two-state economy (𝑁𝑁 = 2) with three assets:
1 0
■ A-D securities, paying and ,
0 1
3
■ Asset 𝑋𝑋 paying .
5
■ How is the price of the third asset related to the prices of the first two?
■ Think of the third asset as a portfolio of the first two assets:
3 1 0
=3× +5×
5 0 1
■ Claim: price of asset 𝑋𝑋 is:
𝑃𝑃 = 3 × 𝜙𝜙1 + 5 × 𝜙𝜙2
Arbitrage pricing
■ The third asset can be replicated as a portfolio of A-D securities: 3 units of
A-D security 1, and 5 units of A-D security 2.
■ By no arbitrage, its price must equal the price of the replication portfolio:
■ No arbitrage requires:
𝑃𝑃 = 3 𝜙𝜙1 + 5 𝜙𝜙2
■ If not, agents can generate arbitrage profits. How?
■ Law of One Price: Two assets with the same payoff must have the same
market price.
■ If we have the prices of A-D securities, we can price all other securities: just
replicate them as portfolios of A-D securities.
■ What if we have prices of a bunch of “composite” securities?
Arbitrage pricing
Example. (Concept check)
Suppose there are two economic states next year.
■ Safe government bond pays an interest rate of 5%;
■ A stock with price $100 yields the following payoff next year: (90,120).
Arbitrage pricing
Example. (Concept check)
■ Suppose there are two states next year. The payoff of a share of stock and
the probabilities of the states are:
[($90, $110); (0.4, 0.6)]
■ The state prices for the two states are:
𝜙𝜙1 , 𝜙𝜙2 = (0.5, 0.4)
Questions:
1. What is the stock price today?
2. What is the expected rate of return of the stock?
Arbitrage pricing
Example (cont’d).
■ Stock price today:
𝑃𝑃 = 𝜙𝜙1 𝑋𝑋1 + 𝜙𝜙2 𝑋𝑋2 = 0.5 90 + 0.4 110 = 89
■ Expected rate of return on the stock, 𝑟𝑟:̅
Arbitrage pricing
■ In general, in a complete market we can value any cash flow by the no-
arbitrage principle (P1).
■ Suppose the firm is considering a project yielding time-1 cash flow:
𝑋𝑋 = 𝑋𝑋1 , 𝑋𝑋2 , … , 𝑋𝑋𝑁𝑁
■ Using prices of A-D securities, we can attach value to this cash flow as
𝑃𝑃 = 𝜙𝜙1 𝑋𝑋1 + ⋯ + 𝜙𝜙𝑁𝑁 𝑋𝑋𝑁𝑁 = 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃
■ This valuation formula encapsulates the arbitrage/relative pricing principle.
■ PV is the present value of the project/asset/CF.
■ PV is also given by the expected payoff and the expected rate of return.
■ Key idea: Find traded assets with similar cash flows (in timing and risk),
use their price/expected return to value the given asset.
Key Concepts
■ State-space model for time and risk
■ Arbitrage pricing
■ Present value and future value
■ Nominal vs. real cash flows and returns
A potential buyer of the risky CF also expects 20% return. Let the price be P.
Then:
𝑃𝑃 1 + 0.20 = $1,000
Thus, the present value of the risky CF is:
$1,000
𝑃𝑃 = = $833
1.20
Observation: Present value properly adjusts for risk.
𝐸𝐸[𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶]
𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃 =
1 + 𝑟𝑟̅
Thus,
■ the value of an asset (cash flow) is determined by the financial market
(via the discount rate/expected rate of return/required rate of return);
■ the discount rate properly adjusts for time and risk;
■ the discount rate is also called the opportunity cost of capital (COC) –
return offered by similar assets traded in the market.
𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝑇𝑇
𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝑇𝑇 =
(1 + 𝑟𝑟)𝑇𝑇
From now on, for simplicity, we will use 𝑟𝑟 (instead of 𝑟𝑟)̅ to denote discount
rates (unless noted otherwise).
PV of $1 Received In Year t
$1.0
r = 0.04 r = 0.08 r = 0.12
$0.8
$0.6
$0.4
$0.2
$0.0
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30
Year when $1 is received
PV vs FV
1.8
1.3
0.8
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Example. Drug company has developed a new flu vaccine and needs to
choose between two strategies:
■ Strategy A: To bring to market in 1 year, invest $1B (billion) now and
returns $500M (million), $400M and $300M in years 1, 2 and 3,
respectively.
■ Strategy B: To bring to market in 2 years, invest $200M in years 0 and 1,
and returns $300M in years 2 and 3.
How to value/compare the two strategies (i.e., their CFs)?
■ Strategy B:
Time 0 1 2 3
Cash Flow -200 -200.0 300.0 300.0
Present Value -200 -190.5 272.1 259.2
Total PV 140.8
Firm should choose strategy B, and its value would increase by $140.8M (vs.
$98.2M for strategy A).
Key Concepts
■ State-space model for time and risk
■ Arbitrage pricing
■ Present value and future value
■ Nominal vs. real cash flows and returns
■ http://www.tradingeconomics.com/country-list/inflation-rate
Example.
■ $1.00 invested at a 6% interest rate grows to $1.06 next year.
■ If inflation is 4% per year, then its real value is
$1.06
= 1.019
1.04
■ The real rate of return is 1.9%.
1 + 𝑟𝑟nominal
𝑟𝑟real = − 1 ≈ 𝑟𝑟nominal − 𝑖𝑖
1 + 𝑖𝑖
Summary
■ State-space model for time and risk
■ Arbitrage/relative pricing
■ Present value and future value
■ Nominal and real cash flows and returns