0% found this document useful (0 votes)
47 views8 pages

Comparative Statics: Introduction: M C C - C S 1

The document provides an introduction to comparative statics. Comparative statics examines how the solution or equilibrium of an economic model changes when a parameter is varied. The ISLM model finds the equilibrium level of output (y) and interest rate (r) based on government spending (G) and the money supply (M). Comparative statics can then show how y and r change as G and M change. Implicit differentiation is often used to find how an implicitly defined dependent variable changes in response to changes in independent variables.

Uploaded by

Gonza N
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
47 views8 pages

Comparative Statics: Introduction: M C C - C S 1

The document provides an introduction to comparative statics. Comparative statics examines how the solution or equilibrium of an economic model changes when a parameter is varied. The ISLM model finds the equilibrium level of output (y) and interest rate (r) based on government spending (G) and the money supply (M). Comparative statics can then show how y and r change as G and M change. Implicit differentiation is often used to find how an implicitly defined dependent variable changes in response to changes in independent variables.

Uploaded by

Gonza N
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 8

Comparative Statics: Introduction

In many economic problems, the solution, or equilibrium, depends on one or more parameters, and
we want to know how the solution changes when a parameter changes

This exercise is called Comparative Statics

• In the ISLM model we find a solution for output y and the interest rate r , which depends on
government spending G and the money supply M :

y = y(G, M ), r = r(G, M )

∂y ∂r
Then and tell us how y and r change with G
∂G ∂G

M ATHS C RASH C OURSE — C OMPARATIVE S TATICS 1


Implicit Functions and Implicit Differentiation

Consider the equation F (x, y) = 0

For each value of x you could try to solve the equation, to obtain a corresponding value of y

When possible (if there’s a unique y for each x) the equation defines y as an implicit function of x

• F (x, y) = 3x2 − 2y
• F (x, y) = y + ln(y + 1) − x
• F (x, y) = x2 + y 2 − 4

Derivative of implicit function y(x) defined by F (x, y) = 0 is found by implicit differentiation. . .

. . . differentiate the whole equation wrt x, allowing for the fact that y is a function of x

 
dy 1 dy dy y+2 dy y+1
• y + ln(y + 1) = x ⇒ + =1 ⇒ =1 ⇒ =
dx y + 1 dx dx y+1 dx y+2

M ATHS C RASH C OURSE — C OMPARATIVE S TATICS 2


An Alternative Interpretation

Note that if x and y satisfy F (x, y) = 0, and there is an infinitesimal change in x and y so that the
equation is still satisfied, then the total differential dF = 0 is

dy F1(x, y)
dF = F1dx + F2dy = 0 ⇒ =−
dx F2(x, y)

x+y x+y x+y dy (ex+y + 1)


• e + x + 2y = 0 ⇒ (e + 2)dy + (e + 1)dx = 0 ⇒ = − x+y
dx (e + 2)
• If u(x, y) is a (well-behaved) utility function, we can find the slope of an indifference curve

∂u ∂u dy ∂u . ∂u
u(x, y) = c ⇒ dx + dy = 0 ⇒ =−
∂x ∂y dx ∂x ∂y

M ATHS C RASH C OURSE — C OMPARATIVE S TATICS 3


Homothetic Implicit Functions

If u(x, y) is homothetic then u(x, y) = g(f (x, y)) where f is h.o.d. r and g is monotonic

Writing ux and uy for the partial derivatives, note that ux = g 0(f )fx and uy = g 0(f )fy (so the
indifference curves are the same for any g )

The slope of an indifference curve at the point (tx, ty) is

dy ux(tx, ty) fx(tx, ty) fx(x, y)


(tx, ty) = − =− =−
dx uy (tx, ty) fy (tx, ty) fy (x, y)

so the slope is the same everywhere on a ray through the origin

M ATHS C RASH C OURSE — C OMPARATIVE S TATICS 4


The Implicit Function Theorem

Suppose x ∈ Rm, and (x∗, y ∗) is a solution to F (x, y) = 0. Suppose that F is C 1 in an open ball
around (x∗, y ∗), with ∂F ∗ ∗ 1
∂y (x , y ) 6= 0. Then there is a C function y = y(x) defined on an open
ball around x∗ such that

1. y(x∗) = y ∗

2. F (x, y(x)) = 0
∂y ∂F . ∂F
3. (x, y) = −
∂xi ∂xi ∂y

Implication: If F (x, y) = 0 has a solution y ∗ for a particular x∗, then it is legitimate to think of y as
a function of x around that point, and you can determine how y changes from y ∗ when x changes
a little from x∗ by implicitly differentiating

• x2 + y 2 = 10 has a solution x = 3, y = −1. What is dy/dx at this point?

Now 2xdx + 2ydy = 0 ⇒ dy/dx = −x/y = 3

M ATHS C RASH C OURSE — C OMPARATIVE S TATICS 5


The Implicit Function Theorem with Several Functions of Several Variables

Consider the system of n equations in n + m variables:

F1(x1, x2, . . . , xm; y1, y2, . . . , yn) = 0 y1 = y1(x1, x2, . . . , xm)


F2(x1, x2, . . . , xm; y1, y2, . . . , yn) = 0 y2 = y2(x1, x2, . . . , xm)
... suggesting: ...
Fn(x1, x2, . . . , xm; y1, y2, . . . , yn) = 0 yn = yn(x1, x2, . . . , xm)

We can write this as


m+n n
F(x, y) = 0 where F:R →R

Suppose (x∗, y∗) is a solution to F(x, y) = 0 and that each Fi is C 1 around this point, then a
generalisation of the Implicit Function Theorem above allows you to determine how yk changes
from yk∗ when xj changes a little from x∗j . Implicitly differentiating the ith equation wrt xj

∂Fi ∂Fi ∂y1 ∂Fi ∂y2 ∂Fi ∂yn


+ + + ··· + =0
∂xj ∂y1 ∂xj ∂y2 ∂xj ∂yn ∂xj

M ATHS C RASH C OURSE — C OMPARATIVE S TATICS 6


Several Functions Continued

Writing this in matrix form:


   ∂y   ∂F 
∂F1 ∂F1 ∂F1 1 1
...
∂y1 ∂y2 ∂yn   ∂xj  ∂xj
  ∂y2
  
∂F2 ∂F2 ∂F2  ∂F2
...
  
  ∂xj
⇒ ∂y1 ∂y2 ∂yn  = −  ∂x. j
   

 ... ... ...  .
  ..   ..


    
∂Fn ∂Fn ∂Fn ∂yn ∂Fn
∂y1 ∂y2 ... ∂yn ∂xj
∂xj

and provided the Jacobian matrix is non-singular you can solve or use Cramer’s rule

More generally, you can allow for all the xj s to change by taking the total differential:
   X ∂F 
∂F1 ∂F1 ∂F1 1
dxj
...
 
∂y1 ∂y2 ∂yn dy1  Xj ∂xj
∂F2
  
∂F2 ∂F2 ∂F2
...   dy2 dxj
    
⇒ ∂y1 ∂y2 ∂yn  = − j ∂xj
   
... ... ...   .. ...
 .
 
   
   X 
∂Fn ∂Fn ∂Fn dyn ∂F n
∂y1 ∂y2 ... ∂yn ∂x dxj
j j

M ATHS C RASH C OURSE — C OMPARATIVE S TATICS 7


Worked Example

Consider a model of the market for umbrellas. . .

Supply: QS = S(P − t), where t is a per unit tax; S is an increasing function

Demand: QD = D(P, r), where r is rainfall; D1 < 0, D2 > 0

How do changes in r and t affect equilibrium price and quantity?

 −1
∂P ∂S ∂QS ∂S ∂P
= D2 − D1 >0 ⇒ e.g. = >0
∂r ∂P ∂r ∂P ∂r
 −1
∂P 0 ∂S ∂QD ∂P
= S − D1 >0 ⇒ e.g. = D1 <0
∂t ∂P ∂t ∂t

M ATHS C RASH C OURSE — C OMPARATIVE S TATICS 8

You might also like