Theory of Pricing
Theory of Pricing
Theory of Pricing
In this figure LMC and LMR intersect each other at the point
E and after that LMC goes on rising. Thus, OQ production is
determined and OP is the price. But average cost is SQ. So,
profit per unit is RS and at OQ output the total profit is PTSR.
Under Perfect Competition AR =MR, where-as under
Monopoly MR <AR.
Under perfect competition price is determined by the
interaction of total demand and supply. This price is
acceptable to all the firms in the industry. No firm can change
this price. So, average revenue and marginal revenue, at every
level of production, will be constant and equal. Their curves
are parallel to X-axis.
Under Monopoly, to sell every additional unit of the
commodity price will have to be lower. In this way, with the
sale of every additional unit, average and marginal income
goes on falling. But the decrease in average revenue is
relatively less sharp than the decrease in marginal revenue, it
is because marginal revenue is limited to one unit, whereas in
case of average revenue, the decrease price is divided by the
number of units. Therefore, the fall in average revenue has
relatively less slope. That is the reason why marginal revenue
is less than average revenue.
COMPARISON OF PRICE DETERMINATION UNDER PERFECT
COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY:
The key points of comparison of price determination under Perfect
Competition and Monopoly is as below:
(iv) The firm is in long-run equilibrium (iv) The firm is in long-run equilibrium
at the minimum point of the long-run at the point where AC curve is still
AC curve. declining and has not reached the
minimum point.
(v) The firm is in equilibrium at the level (v) The firm is in equilibrium at the level
of output at which MC curve is rising, of output at which MR curve is sloping
and is cutting MR curve from below. downwards, and MC curve is cutting it
from below or above.
(vi) In the long run, the firm is earning (vi) The firm can earn abnormal or
normal profit. There may be super supernormal profit even in the long run,
normal profit in the short run but they as there is no competitor in the
will be swept away in the long run, as industry.
new firms entered into the industry.
(vii) Price can be set lower at greater (vii) Price is set higher and output
output in case of constant-cost and smaller by the monopolist.
decreasing-cost industries.
Monopolistic Competition:
In monopolistic competition, the market has features of both perfect
competition and monopoly. A monopolistic competition is more
common than pure competition or pure monopoly.
This market has a mix of both perfect competition and monopoly and is
a classic example of monopolistic competition.
1. MC = MR
2. The MC curve cuts the MR curve from below.
In Fig. 1, we can see that the MC curve cuts the MR curve at point E.
At this point,
From Fig. 2, we can see that the per unit cost is higher than the price
of the firm. Therefore,
In case of losses in the short-run, the firms making a loss will exit
from the market. This continues until the remaining firms make
normal profits only.
Oligopoly:
The word Oligopoly is derived from two Greek words – ‘Oligi’
meaning ‘few’ and ‘Polein’ meaning ‘to sell’. An Oligopoly market
situation is also called ‘competition among the few’. Oligopoly is
either perfect or imperfect/differentiated. In India, some examples of
an oligopolistic market are automobiles, cement, steel, aluminium,
etc.
Characteristics of oligopoly:
• There are large few firms although exact number of firms is
undefined
• A firm can earn super-normal profits in the long run as there are
barriers to entry
• Firms try to avoid price competition due to fear of price wars in
the oligopoly
CLASSIFICATION OF OLIGOPOLY:
The oligopolistic industries are classified in a number of ways:
(a) Duopoly: If there are two giant firms in an industry it is called duopoly. Duopoly
is further classified as below:
• (i) Perfect or Pure Duopoly: If the duopolists in an industry are
producing identical products it is called perfect or pure duopoly.
• (ii) Imperfect or Impure Duopoly: If the duopolists in an industry are
producing differentiated products it is called imperfect or impure duopoly.
(b) Oligopoly: If there are more than two firms in an industry and each firm takes
consideration the reactions of the rival firms in formulating its own price policy it is
called oligopoly. Oligopoly is further classified as below:
• (i) Perfect or Pure Oligopoly: If the oligopolists in an industry are
producing identical products it is called perfect or pure oligopoly.
• (ii) Imperfect or Impure Oligopoly: If the oligopolists in an industry are
producing differentiated products it is called imperfect or impure oligopoly.
PRICE DETERMINATION UNDER OLIGOPOLY:
The price and output behaviour of the firms operating in oligopolistic or duopolistic
market condition can be studied under two main heads:
COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY:
The degree of imperfect competition in a market is influenced not just by the number
and size of firms but by how they behave. When only a few firms operate in a
market, they see what their rivals are doing and react. ‘Strategic interaction’ is a term
that describes how each firm’s business strategy depends upon its rivals’ business
behaviour.
When there are only a small number of firms in a market, they have a choice
between ‘cooperative’ and ‘non-cooperative’ behaviour:
• Firms act non-cooperatively when they act on their own without any explicit
or implicit agreement with other firms. That’s what produces ‘price wars’.
• Firms operate in a cooperative mode when they try to minimise competition
between them. When firms in an oligopoly actively cooperate with each other,
they engage in ‘collusion’. Collusion is an oligopolistic situation in which two or
more firms jointly set their prices or outputs, divide the market among them, or
make other business decisions jointly.
The above diagram illustrates the situation of oligopolist A and his demand curve
DaDa assuming that the other firms all follow firm A’s lead in raising and lowering
prices. Thus the firm’s demand curve has the same elasticity as the industry’s DD
curve. The optimum price for the collusive oligopolist is shown at point G on DaDa
just above point E. This price is identical to the monopoly price, it is well above
marginal cost and earns the colluding oligopolists a handsome monopoly profit.
PRICE DETERMINATION MODELS OF OLIGOPOLY:
1. Kinky Demand Curve: The kinky demand curve model tries to explain that in
non-collusive oligopolistic industries there are not frequent changes in the market
prices of the products. The demand curve is drawn on the assumption that the kink
in the curve is always at the ruling price. The reason is that a firm in the market
supplies a significant share of the product and has a powerful influence in the
prevailing price of the commodity. Under oligopoly, a firm has two choices:
(a) The first choice is that the firm increases the price of the product. Each
firm in the industry is fully aware of the fact that if it increases the price of the
product, it will lose most of its customers to its rival. In such a case, the upper
part of demand curve is more elastic than the part of the curve lying below the
kink.
(b) The second option for the firm is to decrease the price. In case the firm
lowers the price, its total sales will increase, but it cannot push up its sales
very much because the rival firms also follow suit with a price cut. If the rival
firms make larger price cut than the one which initiated it, the firm which first
started the price cut will suffer a lot and may finish up with decreased
sales. The oligopolists, therefore avoid cutting price, and try to sell their
products at the prevailing market price. These firms, however, compete with
one another on the basis of quality, product design, after-sales services,
advertising, discounts, gifts, warrantees, special offers, etc.
In the above diagram, we shall notice that there is a discontinuity in the marginal
revenue curve just below the point corresponding to the kink.During this discontinuity
the marginal cost curve is drawn. This is because of the fact that the firm is in
equilibrium at output ON where the MC curve is intersecting the MR curve from
below.
In the above diagram, the demand curve is made up of two segments DB and
BD’. The demand curve is kinked at point B. When the price is Rs. 10 per unit, a firm
sells 120 units of output. If a firm decides to charge Rs. 12 per unit, it loses a large
part of the market and its sales come down to 40 units with a loss of 80 units. In
case, the producer lowers the price to Rs. 4 per unit, its competitors in the industry
will match the price cut. Its sales with a big price cut of Rs. 6 increases the sale by
only 40 units. The firm does not gain as its total revenue decreases with the price
cut.
2. Price Leadership Model: Under price leadership, one firm assumes the role of a
price leader and fixes the price of the product for the entire industry. The other firms
in the industry simply follow the price leader and accept the price fixed by him and
adjust their output to this price. The price leader is generally a very large or dominant
firm or a firm with the lowest cost of production. It often happens that price
leadership is established as a result of price war in which one firm emerges as the
winner.
In oligopolistic market situation, it is very rare that prices are set independently and
there is usually some understanding among the oligopolists operating in the
industry. This agreement may be either tacit or explicit.
Types of Price Leadership: There are several types of price leadership. The
following are the principal types:
(a) Price leadership of a dominant firm, i.e., the firm which produces the
bulk of the product of the industry. It sets the price and rest of the firms simply
accepts this price.
(b) Barometric price leadership, i.e., the price leadership of an old,
experienced and the largest firm assumes the role of a leader, but undertakes
also to protect the interest of all firms instead of promoting its own interests as
in the case of price leadership of a dominant firm.
(c) Exploitative or Aggressive price leadership, i.e., one big firm built its
supremacy in the market by following aggressive price leadership. It compels
other firms to follow it and accept the price fixed by it. In case the other firms
show any independence, this firm threatens them and coerces them to follow
its leadership.
(a) There are only two firms A and B and firm A has a lower cost of
production than the firm B.
(b) The product is homogenous or identical so that the customers are
indifferent as between the firms.
(c) Both A and B have equal share in the market, i.e., they are facing the
same demand curve which will be the half of the total demand curve.
In the above diagram, MCa is the marginal cost curve of firm A and MCb is the
marginal cost curve of firm B. Since we have assumed that the firm A has a lower
cost of production than the firm B, therefore, the MCa is drawn below MCb.
Now let us take the firm A first, firm A will be maximising its profit by selling OM level
of output at price MP, because at output OM the firm A will be in equilibrium as its
marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue at point E. Whereas the firm B will be in
equilibrium at point F, selling ON level of output at price NK, which is higher than the
price MP. Two firms have to charge the same price in order to survive in the
industry. Therefore, the firm B has to accept and follow the price set by firm A. This
shows that firm A is the price leader and firm B is the follower.
Since the demand curve faced by both firms is the same, therefore, the firm B will
produce OM level of output instead of ON. Since the marginal cost of firm B is
greater than the marginal cost of firm A, therefore, the profit earned by firm B will be
lesser than the profit earned by firm A.
Objectives of Pricing:
The task of fixing reasonable value of any product or services is called pricing.
To fulfill this task all the costs and profits should be included. Various expenses
are included under production cost. They may be direct and indirect expenses.
Mark-up percentage (M) is fixed in which AFC and net profit margin
(NPM) are covered.
ii. For determining average variable cost, the first step is to fix prices.
This is done by estimating the volume of the output for a given period
of time. The planned output or normal level of production is taken
into account to estimate the output.
c. For example, the product is sold for Rs. 500 whose cost was Rs.
400. The mark up as a percentage to cost is equal to (100/400) *100
=25. The mark up as a percentage of the selling price equals
(100/500) *100= 20.
Demand-based Pricing:
Demand-based pricing refers to a pricing method in which the price of
a product is finalized according to its demand. If the demand of a
product is more, an organization prefers to set high prices for products
to gain profit; whereas, if the demand of a product is less, the low
prices are charged to attract the customers.
Competition-based Pricing:
Competition-based pricing refers to a method in which an
organization considers the prices of competitors’ products to set the
prices of its own products. The organization may charge higher,
lower, or equal prices as compared to the prices of its competitors.
On the other hand, extensive form games are the one in which the
description of game is done in the form of a decision tree. Extensive
form games help in the representation of events that can occur by
chance. These games consist of a tree-like structure in which the
names of players are represented on different nodes.
In addition, in this structure, the feasible actions and pay offs of each
players are also given. Let us understand the concept of extensive
form games with the help of an example. Suppose organization A
wants to enter a new market, while organization B is the existing
organization in that market.
If they both get into the price war, then both of them would suffer the
loss of 3. On the other hand, if organization B cooperates, then both
of them would earn equal profits. In this case, the best option would
be that organization A enters the market and organization B
cooperates.
The same example can also be used for the explanation of sequential
move games. Suppose organization X is the first one to decide
whether it should outsource the marketing activities or not.
Moreover, in zero sum game, the gain of one player is always equal to
the loss of the other player. On the other hand, non-zero sum game are
the games in which sum of the outcomes of all the players is not zero.
On the other hand, asymmetric games are the one in which strategies
adopted by players are different. In asymmetric games, the strategy
that provides benefit to one player may not be equally beneficial for
the other player. However, decision making in asymmetric games
depends on the different types of strategies and decision of players.
Example of asymmetric game is entry of new organization in a market
because different organizations adopt different strategies to enter in
the same market.
Impact on Economics and Business
Game theory brought about a revolution in economics by addressing
crucial problems in prior mathematical economic models. For
instance, neoclassical economics struggled to understand
entrepreneurial anticipation and could not handle the imperfect
competition. Game theory turned attention away from steady-state
equilibrium toward the market process.
In game theory, the following are the outcomes players can expect:
3. Equivalent Outcome
4. Intransitive Outcome
Both the terms are similar but slightly different. Nash equilibrium
states that nothing is gained if any of the players change their strategy
if all other players maintain their strategy. Dominant strategy asserts
that a player will choose a strategy that will lead to the best outcome
regardless of the strategies that other plays have chosen. Dominant
strategy can be included in Nash equilibrium whereas a Nash
equilibrium may not be the best strategy in a game.
If you revealed Sam's strategy to Tom and vice versa, you see that no
player deviates from the original choice. Knowing the other player's
move means little and doesn't change either player's behaviour.
Outcome A represents a Nash equilibrium.
The classic prisoner’s dilemma goes like this: two members of a gang
of bank robbers, Dave and Henry, have been arrested and are being
interrogated in separate rooms. The authorities have no other
witnesses, and can only prove the case against them if they can
convince at least one of the robbers to betray his accomplice and
testify to the crime. Each bank robber is faced with the choice to
cooperate with his accomplice and remain silent or to defect from the
gang and testify for the prosecution. If they both co-operate and
remain silent, then the authorities will only be able to convict them on
a lesser charge of loitering, which will mean one year in jail each (1
year for Dave + 1 year for Henry = 2 years total jail time). If one
testifies and the other does not, then the one who testifies will go free
and the other will get three years (0 years for the one who defects + 3
for the one convicted = 3 years total). However, if both testify against
the other, each will get two years in jail for being partly responsible
for the robbery (2 years for Dave + 2 years for Henry = 4 years total
jail time).