Handout 7: Monopoly
Handout 7: Monopoly
Handout 7: Monopoly
100x
Handout 7: Monopoly
1 Introduction
In this handout we will explore a market under the control of a monopolist. In Handout 7, we
discussed how to get from the problem of the firm to the supply in a competitive market. Now, we
will do the same, but in a situation where firms do not take the price as given. In particular, we
assume that there is only one firm in the market, which internalizes that it can increase market price
if it reduces quantity. We first do an example where the monopolist cannot discriminate prices and
compute equilibrium outcomes and surpluses of consumers and producers. Second, we discuss price
discrimination and how the equilibrium price is related to the elasticity of demand.
2 Monopoly
Consider a monopolist that faces the market demand Q = (40 − P )/3. The cost of Q to produce
the good is given by is given by C(Q) = Q2 . The monopolist can charge only one price (no price
discrimination).
1. Find the marginal revenue and the marginal cost as a function of Q. Draw them along with the
demand curve.
2. Find the profit-maximizing price and quantity. What is the marginal cost at the profit-maximizing
quantity?
4. Calculate the producer surplus, consumer surplus and total surplus in the market. Illustrate
them in a graph.
5. What is the price elasticity of demand at the equilibrium point? What is the markup of the
Solution.
dC(Q)
MC = ⇒ M C = 2Q
dQ
1
Data, Economics, and Development Policy MicroMasters Program 14.100x
We first invert the market demand to get P = 40−3Q, multiply this by Q, and finally differentiate
MC
40
MR D
O Q
20/3 40/3
quantity
40 − 6Q∗ = 2Q∗ ⇒ Q∗ = 5
To find the price, we replace this quantity in the demand to recover: P ∗ = 40 − 3Q = 25.
3. The profit level of the monopolist is given by total revenue (price times quantity) minus total
2
Data, Economics, and Development Policy MicroMasters Program 14.100x
cost, that is
π = P ∗ Q∗ − C(Q∗ ) = 25 × 5 − 25 ⇒ π = 100
4. The consumer surplus (CS) is the are above the equilibrium price and below the demand.
Recall that the equilibrium quantity is where M C = M R, but the equilibrium price is that on
the demand at the equilibrium quantity, as shown in Figure 2. The consumer surplus is the are
The producer surplus is the area of the trapeze, which can be computed as
MC
40
CS
P ∗ = 25
10
PS
MR D
O Q
Q∗ = 5 20/3 40/3
3
Data, Economics, and Development Policy MicroMasters Program 14.100x
dQ P P
D = =−
dP Q 40 − P
Therefore, at the equilibrium price, the elasticity is −25/15 = −5/3. Remembering the formula
P −M C
for markup: P = − 1D , we get the markup 3/5. If you don’t remember the formula for
markup, here is a derivation. Consider the maximization problem of any monopolist that faces
dP (Q)
P (Q) + Q =c
dQ
Therefore:
dP Q c
1+ =
dQ P P
Note that
dP (Q) Q 1
=
dQ P D
since the derivative of the inverse of a function is the inverse of the derivative. Therefore:
P −c 1
=−
P D
3 Price Discrimination
A price discriminating monopolist sells a good for two types of consumers: young and old. Old
p
QOLD
D = 110 −
4
4
Data, Economics, and Development Policy MicroMasters Program 14.100x
p
QYDoung = 100 −
2
1. Find the equilibrium price, quantity and aggregate demand elasticity if the monopolist does not
2. Find the equilibrium prices, quantities and aggregate demand elasticities of Young and Old if
the monopolist can price discriminate between Old and Young consumers.
Solution.
1. We must first compute the aggegate demand curve. For 100 − p/2 ≥ 0, both Young and Old
consume positive amounts of the good - and we sum their demands. For 100 − p/2 ≤ 0, only Old
consumers demand the good. For 110 − p/4 ≤ 0, no consumer demands the good. Together:
210 − 43 p,
if p ≤ 200
QD = 110 − p/4, if 200 < p ≤ 440
0,
if p > 440
To find out what the price maximizing profit for the monopolist is, we must separate the three
cases above. Case 1: Sell to both Young and Old. p ≤ 200. If p < 200, the inverse demand
equation is given by
4
p = 280 − Q
3
d( (280 − 34 Q)Q
8 8
MR = = 280 − Q = 2Q = M C ⇒ 280 − Q = 2Q
dQ 3 3
Which implies Q1 = 60 (Q of the first case). Replacing at the demand, we get P1 = 280 − 43 Q =
200, which satisfies the condition that p ≤ 200 we started with. Therefore, profits in the first
5
Data, Economics, and Development Policy MicroMasters Program 14.100x
case are
Note that as π1 > 0, we do not have to consider p > 440 as a case (the third case), since it
would yield zero profits. We have only to additionally consider case 2, where 200 < p ≤ 440.
Case 2: Sell to Old Only. 200 < p ≤ 440. IThe inverse demand equation is given by
p = 440 − 4Q
d([(440 − 4Q)Q]
MR = = 440 − 8Q = 2Q = M C ⇒ 440 − 8D = 2Q
dQ
Which implies Q2 = 44 (Q of the second case). Replacing at the demand, we get P2 = 264,
which satisfies the condition that 200 < p ≤ 440 we started with. Therefore, profits in the
Conclusion. The monopolist is better off in case 2, where it excludes young people from the
market to focus solely on the old. Old consumers are willing to pay more, and thus the monopolist
can decrease quantities (and costs) and increase prices to maximize its profits. Therefore, the
equilibrium price is p = 264, the equilibrium quantity is Q = 44 and the elasticity of demand at
this point is
1 264 3
εD = − =−
4 44 2
2. The Monopolist can now offer different prices for young and old consumers. The profit maximiza-
tion problem can be written as (already writing prices as their inverted demand counterparts):
Note that we cannot solve the problem of the monopolist for young/old consumers separately.
The cost function C(Q) = Q2 is convex and, thus, the quantities produced in one market affect
6
Data, Economics, and Development Policy MicroMasters Program 14.100x
QY = 2QO − 60
Replacing it back:
Which yields: QY = 20, QO = 40. Prices come from plugging into the inverse demand curves,
and yield
1 160
εD,Y = − × = −4
2 20
1 280 7
εD,O = − × =−
4 40 4
(a) Even though in Item 1 the monopolist was only producing for the old, the quantities were
larger there than they are here. Here, the convexity of the cost implies that the production
for the young will have an impact in price/quantity decisions for the old (and vice -versa).
(b) The old consumers, which are more inelastic (i.e., elasticity) close to zero, are the ones
charged the higher price. This is consistent with our derivation of the Lerner Index in Item
5 of the first section of this handout. As will be seen later on, demand elasticity and market
3. Young consumers are better off, because without price discrimination they would be excluded
from the market. This means that price discrimination can increase total welfare not only by
7
Data, Economics, and Development Policy MicroMasters Program 14.100x
increasing the ability of the monopolist to extract rents from consumers, but also by allowing