Unit-1: Importance of International Business
Unit-1: Importance of International Business
Unit-1: Importance of International Business
Definition
“International business consists of transactions that are devised and carried out across national
borders to satisfy the objectives of the individuals, companies and organisations. These transactions
take on various forms which are often interrelated.” – Michael R. Czinkota
Market Expansion
International businesses are opened to perform business in different countries across the globe. These business
keeps on expanding its activities and explore new markets for selling more and more products. The
international business earns high amount of profits which helps them in expanding their market share.
Economies Of Scale
These business are able to enjoy economies of scale due to their large scale production. International
businesses produce large amount of goods for selling in different countries. With the increase in amount of
production, per unit cost of producing goods goes down which helps them in earning large profits.
Cost Advantage
International business takes cost advantage over its competitors by producing goods in one country and
exporting them in another country. They carry on their production in a country where factors of production are
easily and cheaply available. This helps in minimizing the cost of product and earn huge profits by selling
them at better prices in other countries.
Government Support
These businesses also enjoy government support for carrying out their operations and expanding their size. The
government provides tax and financial benefits to these businesses as they earn a large amount of foreign
reserves for the country.
International trade that takes place without barriers such as tariff, quotas and foreign exchange controls is
called free trade. Thus, under free trade, goods and services flow between countries freely. In other
words, free trade implies absence of governmental intervention on international exchange among different
countries of the world.
Secondly, because of unrestricted trade, global output increases since specialisation, efficiency, etc. make
production large scale. Free trade enables countries to obtain goods at a cheaper price. This leads to a rise
in the standard of living of people of the world. Thus, free trade leads to higher production, higher
consumption and higher all-round international prosperity.
Thirdly, free trade keeps the spirit of competition of the economy. As there exists the possibility of
intense foreign competition under free trade, domestic producers do not want to lose their grounds.
Competition enhances efficiency. Moreover, it tends to prevent domestic monopolies and free the
consumers from exploitation.
Fourthly, free trade enables each country to get commodities which it cannot produce at all or can only
produce inefficiently. Commodities and raw materials unavailable domestically can be procured through
free movement even at a low price.
Fifthly, free trade safeguards against discrimination. Under free trade, there is no scope for cornering raw
materials or commodities by any country. Free trade can, thus, promote international peace and stability
through economic and political cooperation.
Finally, free trade is free from bureaucratic interferences. Bureaucracy and corruption are very much as-
sociated with unrestricted trade.
In brief, restricted trade prevents a nation from reaping the benefits of specialisation, forces it to adopt
less efficient production techniques and forces consumers to pay higher prices for the products of
protected industries.
Secondly, it may ruin domestic industries. Because of free trade, imported goods become available at a
cheaper price. Thus, an unfair and cut-throat competition develops between domestic and foreign
industries. In the process, domestic industries are wiped out. Indian handicrafts industries suffered
tremendously during the British regime.
Thirdly, free trade cannot bring all-round development of industries. Comparative cost principle states
that a country specialises in the production of a few commodities. On the other hand, inefficient industries
remain neglected. Thus, under free trade, an all-round development is ruled out.
Fourthly, free trade brings in the danger of dependence. A country may face economic depression if its
international trading partner suffers from it. The Great Depression that sparked off in 1929-30 in the US
economy swept all over the world and all countries suffered badly even if their economies were not
caught in the grip of depression. Such overdependence following free trade becomes also catastrophic
during war.
Finally, a country may have to change its consumption habits. Because of free trade, even harmful
commodities (like drugs, etc.) enter the domestic market. To prevent such, restrictions on trade are
required to be imposed.
In view of all these arguments against free trade, governments of less developed coun tries in the post-
Second World War period were encouraged to resort to some kind of trade restrictions to safeguard
national interest.
II. Protection:
By protection we mean restricted trade. Foreign trade of a country may be free or restricted. Free trade
eliminates tariff while protective trade imposes tariff or duty. When tariffs, duties and quotas are imposed
to restrict the inflow of imports then we have protected trade. This means that government intervenes in
trading activities.
Thus, protection is the anti-thesis of free trade or unrestricted trade. Government imposes tariffs on ad
valorem basis or imposes quota on the volume of goods to be imported. Sometimes, export taxes and
subsidies are given to domestic goods to protect them from foreign competition. These are the various
forms of protection used by modern governments to restrict trade.
Now an important question arises what forces the government to protect trade? What are the chief
arguments for protection? Can protection deliver all the goods that a nation needs?
The concept of protection is not a post-Second World War development. Its origin can be traced to the
days of mercantilism (i.e., 16th century). Since then various arguments have been made in favour of
protection.
The case for protection for the developing countries received a strong support from Argentine economist
R. D. Prebisch and Hans Singer in the 1950s.
Perhaps the oldest as well as the cogent argument for protection is the infant industry argument. When the
industry is first established its costs will be higher. It is too immature to reap econo mies of scale at its
infancy. Workers are not only inexperienced but also less efficient. If this infant industry is allowed to
grow independently, surely it will be unable to compete effectively with the already established industries
of other countries.
Thus, an infant industry needs protection of a temporary nature and over time will experience some sort
of ‘learning effect’. Given time to develop an industry, it is quite likely that in the near future it will be
able to develop a comparative advantage, withstand foreign competition and survive without protection.
It is something like the dictum: Nurse the baby, protect the child, and free the adult. Once an embryonic
industry gets matured it can withstand competition. Competition improves efficiency. Once efficiency is
attained, protection may be withdrawn. Thus, an underdeveloped country attempting to have rapid
industrialisation needs protection of certain industries.
However, in actual practice, the infant industry argument, even in LDCs, loses some strength. Some
economists suggest production subsidy rather than protection of certain infant industries. Protection, once
granted to an industry, continues for a long time. On the other hand, subsidy is a temporary measure since
continuance of it in the next year requires approval of the legislature.
Above all, expenditure on subsidy is subject to financial audit. Thus, protection is something like a “gift”.
Secondly, protection saps the self-sufficiency outlook of the protected industries. Once protection is
granted, it becomes difficult to withdraw it even after attaining maturity. That means infant industries,
even after maturity, get ‘old age pension’.
In other words, infant industries become too much dependent on tariffs and other countries. Thirdly, it is
difficult to identify potential comparative advantage industries. A time period of 5 to 10 years may be
required by an industry to achieve maturity or self-sufficiency. Under the circumstances, infant industry
argument loses force.
In view of these criticisms, it is said by experts that the argument “boils down to a case for the removal of
obstacles to the growth of the infants. It does not demonstrate that a tariff is the most efficient means of
attaining the objective.”
These counter-arguments, however, do not deter us to support the growth of infant industries in less
developed countries by means of tariff, rather than subsidies.
As free trade increases specialisation, so protected trade brings in diversified industrial structure. By
setting up newer and variety of industries through protective means, a country mini mises the risk in
production. Comparative advantage principle dictates narrow specialisation in production.
This sort of specialisation is not only undesirable from the viewpoint of economic development, but also a
risky proposition. Efficiency in production in some products by some countries (e.g., coffee of Brazil,
milk product of New Zealand, oil of Middle East countries) results in overdependence on these products.
If war breaks out, or if political relations between countries change, or if recessionary demand condition
for the product grows up abroad, the economies of these industries will be greatly injured. Above all, this
sort of unbalanced industrial growth goes against the spirit of national self-sufficiency. Protection is the
answer to this problem. A government encourages diverse industries to develop through protective means.
However, a counter-argument runs. Politics, rather than economics, may be the criterion for the selection
of industries to be protected in order to produce diversification at a reasonable cost. But, one must not
ignore economics of protection.
Protection can raise the level of employment. Tariffs may reduce import and, in the process, import-com-
peting industries flourish. In addition, import- substituting industries—the substitution of domestic
production for imports of manufactures—develop. The strategy of import-substituting industrialisation
promotes domestic industry at the expense of foreign industries.
Thus, employment potential under protective regime is quite favourable. In brief, tariff stimulates
investment in import-competing and import substitution industries. Such investment produces favourable
employment multiplier.
But cut in imports following import substituting industrialisation strategy may ultimately cause our
exports to decline.
(d) Balance of payments argument:
A deficit in the balance of payments can be cured by curtailing imports. However, imports will decline
following a rise in tariff rate provided other trading partners do not retaliate by im posing tariff on a
country’s export. However, import restrictions through tariff may be uncalled for if the balance of
payments crisis becomes serious and chronic. In view of this and other associated problems of tariff, it is
said that tariff is a second best policy.
Usually, we hear about unfair competition from firms of low-cost countries. One particular form of un fair
competition is dumping which is outlawed by international trade pacts, such as WTO. Dumping is a form
of price discrimination that occurs in trade. Dumping occurs when a country sells a product abroad at a
low price because of competition and at a high price in the home market because of monopoly power.
In other words, dumping is a kind of subsidy given to export goods. This unfair practice can be prevented
by imposing tariff. Otherwise, workers and firms competing with the dumped products will be hit hard.
It is argued that tariffs and other import restrictions create a strategic advantage in producing some new
products having potential for generating some net profit. There are some large firms who prevent entry of
new firms because of the economies of large scale production. Thus, these large firms reap pure profits
over the long run during which new firms may not dare enough to compete with these established large
firms. Thus, the large scale economies themselves prevent entry of new firms.
But as far as new products are concerned, a new firm may develop and market these products and reap
substantial profit. Ultimately, successful new firms producing new products become one of the few
established firms in the industry. New firms showing potential for the future must be protected. “If
protection in the domestic market can increase the chance that one of the protected domestic firms will
become one of the established firms in the international market, the protection may pay off.”
There are some industries which may be inefficient by birth or high cost due to many reasons and must be
protected. This logic may apply to the production of national defence goods or necessary food items.
Whatever the cost may be, there is no question of compromise for the defence industry since ‘defence is
more important than opulence’. Dependence on foreign countries regarding supply of basic food items as
well as defence products is absolutely unwise.
However, objections against this argument may be cited here. It is difficult to identify a particular item as
a defence industry item because we have seen that many industries— from garlic to clothespin—applied
for protection on defence grounds. Candlestick-maker (for emergency lighting) and toothpick-maker (to
have good dental hygiene for the troops) demanded protection at different times at different places. A
nation which builds up its military strength through tariff protection does not sound convincing. Thus,
tariff is a second-best solution.
(b) Miscellaneous arguments against protection:
There are some good ‘side effects’ or ‘spillover effects’ of protection. This means that it produces some
undesirable effects on the economy and the basic objective of protection can be attained rather in a
costless manner by other direct means other than protection. That is, protection is never more than a
second-best solution.
Firstly, protection distorts the comparative advantage in production. This means that specialisation in
production may be lost if a country imposes tariff. All these lead to squeezing of trade. Secondly, it im -
poses a cost on the society since consumers buy goods at a high price. Thirdly, often weak declining
industries having no potential future stay on the economy under the protective umbrella. Fourthly,
international tension often escalates, particularly when tariff war begins.
Usually, a foreign country retaliates by imposing tariff on its imports from the tariff-imposing country.
Once the retaliatory attitude (i.e., ‘beggar-my-neighbour policy’) develops, benefits from protection will
be lost. Finally, protection encourages bureaucracy. Increase in trade restrictions means expansion of
governmental activity and, hence, rise in administrative cost. Bureaucracy ultimately leads to corruption
Crowd Funding
One major trend that seems to have a bright future in international business is
Crowd funding. It is the best way to finance new business ventures by
collecting a small sum of capital from a large group of individuals.
It employs a vast network of people via social media and creates Crowd
funding websites to form a direct link between the investor and the
entrepreneur. Currently, there are several online portals available which are
providing the service of project funding.
Remote Employment
Another prevailing global trend in international business is the remote
workforce. The progressive modes of communication like webinars, video
calls have increased connectivity that facilitates companies to hire employees
remotely.
This mode of employment is much faster than the traditional hiring methods
and helps employers to hire resources from any part of the world. It is greatly
beneficial for startups because they get a wider pool of talent to choose from
without needing to pay tax returns. Remote employment builds a win-win
situation for both the employer and the employee as the employees get online
jobs on their convenience and employers have access to an efficient
workforce.
These were some trends that will massively impact International Business
Environment in 2019. An understanding of these macro-level trends will
improve your company’s functionality.