Valuation of Tropical Coastal Resources:: Theory and Application of Linear Programming
Valuation of Tropical Coastal Resources:: Theory and Application of Linear Programming
207
SR76
#25
c.1 Valuation of Tropical
Coastal Resources:
Theory and Application
of Linear Programming
Edited by
Annabelle Cruz-Trinidad
-d~
~
~ ... :f~- .:..:. :--:-::
" IIA ft
118
.".".' @~I' .
r\71
International Center for Living Aquatic
Resources Management
C
Valuation of Tropical Coastal Resources:
~ h k o and
r ~ Application of Linear Programming
Edited by
Annabelle Cruz-Trinidad
Edited by
ANNABELLE
CRUZ-TRINIDAD
1996
Published by the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC),
Casilla 179-D, Santiago, Chile; and the International Center for Living Aquatic Resources Management (ICLARM),
MCPO Box 263 1, 07 18 Makati City, Philippines
ICLARM's technical services were developed in response to the lack of existing publishing
outlets for longer papers on tropical fisheries research.
The ICLARM Studies and Reviews series consist of cimcise documents providing thorough
coverage of topics of interest to the Center, which are undertaken by staff or by external specialists
on commission.
Essentially, all documents in the series are carefully peer reviewed externally and internally.
A number have been rejected. Those published are thus primary literature. Between 600 and 1,000
copies of each title are disseminated - sold or provided in exchange or free of charge.
Cruz-Trinidad. A,, Editor 1996. Valuation of tropical coastal resources: theory and application of linear
progmmming. ARM Stud. Rev. 25, 108 p.
AF
Cover. An abstmction of the multiactivity feature of the coastal zone. Lines represent the diverse resource use
and the hatched (shaded) area, the optimal allocation of resources. Illustration by Chris Bunao.
constraints
ISSN 01 15-4389
ISBN 97 18709-72-X
Optimization of Economic Benefits from Fishery, Forestry and Tourism in Bio-Bio, Chile
E. Araneda, A. Cruz-Trinidad, I.: Morales and A. Arellano ............................................................ 32
This volume marks the culmination of ICLARM and ECLAC's collaboration which started in 1990
via the project entitled "Socioeconomic Valuation of Coastal Resources in Southwest Latin America."
The worldwide trend in environmental degradation has not spared Latin America, particularly that
involving large-scale mangrove conversion into shrimp ponds, and conflicting use of aquatic resources
such as by fisheries and by other industries. The project aims to derive appropriate social and economic
values for selected coastal resources in order to help rationalize their present use and management. The
project's important achievements include a linear programming software package, OPUS; applications
of linear programming models to four selected sites in Latin America and the Philippines; and a review
of existing valuation methods for environmental and natural resources. The essence of the work done
by ICLARM and ECLAC is fully captured in this volume.
We would like researchers and managers to use and review our work in order to better understand
the dynamics of coastal management problems and to appreciate decision tools such as OPUS. We
commend all the authors including ICLARM and ECLAC staff who contributed their efforts to this
book.
MERYL
J. WILLIAMS AXELDOUROJEANNI
Director General Chiej Division of Natural
ICLARM Resources and Energy
ECLAC- United Nations
Foreword
This book concludes a joint project on "Socioeconomic Valuation of Coastal Resources in Southwest
Latin America" between the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean
(ECLAC), Santiago, Chile, and the International Center for Living Aquatic Resources Management
(ICLARM), Manila, Philippines, initiated in 1990, but whose antecedents reach much deeper. One key
starting point was the doctoral thesis of the leader of that project, Dr. Max Agiiero, on Chilean fisheries,
which used Linear Programming (LP) as its major tool. Dr. Max Agiiero joined ICLARM in March
1986 and had soon convinced his colleagues that LP could serve as framework for studies of complex
biosocioeconornic systems such as the pelagic fisheries of Peru, or the floodplain fisheries of Bangladesh,
studied in the context of a Ph.D. thesis that he supervised.
It was logical thus to assume that LP would also be applicable to the study of coastal areas, whose
apparent complexity then seemed to defy formal analysis, allowing only conceptual description. A
project to test the suitability of LP-based approaches for the analysis of intersectoral interaction and the
valuation of coastal resources was thus conceived, and ECLAC identified as the best possible partner
for such venture.
Dr. M. Agiiero relocated from Manila to Santiago in April 1990, and immediately built a team
consisting of young researchers and a programmer to develop and test suitable LP software, and to
apply the LP approach to various sites in Chile and the Ecuadorian coast.
For the project to have developed its own LP software ("OPUS", see below) may appear unnecessary,
as commercial packages exist - as stand alone applications, or as part of spreadsheet programs (e.g.,
Microsoft Excel, Quattro Pro) - which can handle such problems. However, spreadsheets with LP
applications did not exist when the project started, and were not anticipated.
One particular problem which the project had to tackle was the costing of nonmarket goods and
services, i.e., the "internalization" of (or: explicitly accounting for) what economists call "externalities".
The contributions in this book provide some practical approaches for doing this. Still, this vexing problem
is going to continue to be with us and continue to be a major cause for environmental degradation and
pollution.
The ICLARM-ECLAC Coastal Valuation Project was foreseen to have two phases, Phase I for
concept and software development and Phase 11, for their application to various sites in Chile and
elsewhere in South America. In June 1992, an external review panel led by Dr. L. Fallon-Scura concluded
that the project was "technically sound, the methods developed potentially useful, is compatible with
the future ICLARM and therefore, should continue with Phase II". Unfortunately, ICLARM did not
have the core funds required for Phase I1 of the project.
Ms. Abbie Cruz-Trinidad, an ICLARM researcher who had previously collaborated with Dr. Agiiero,
took over the task of completing and editing the publication from the numerous internal reports prepared
during Phase I of the project, and thus documenting the application of OPUS to various sites in Chile
and Ecuador. Moreover, she teamed up with staff from two other ICLARM research projects - one
covering San Miguel Bay, the other, Lingayen Gulf, both in the Philippines, to show that the LP approach
developed by the ICLARM-ECLAC team also would work in the Southeast Asian context.
We take the success of this transfer from South America to Southeast Asia as implying that the
approach documented in this book can be applied to any coastline. However, we do not suggest that this
approach should ever be used alone: the complexities within and among sectoral interactions occurring
along the coastlines of the world cannot be described, let alone predicted by the variables - however
numerous they may be - of any single model. This implies that wherever possible, a wide variety of
methodological approaches should be used with the one presented in this book being one among others.
I congratulate the authors of the contributions included in this book, especially Dr. Max Agiiero, for
their daring to quantify and thus render available for analysis coastal interactions which others would
have only talked about, and Ms. Abbie Cruz-Trinidad, for rising to the challenge of editing this volume.
Finally, I thank the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC) for
being a gracious host to the project that led to this book, and for its help in maintaining communications
between the editors and the now scattered contributors.
DANIELPAULY
Principal Science Advisol; ICLARM
vii
Preface
This volume contains seven papers, two of which tackle the conceptual elements of Linear
Programming and resources valuation; four are application papers while the last is the users' manual in
support of OPUS, the LP software developed by this project. Two application papers are from Latin
America: one from the Bio-Bio region in Chile and the other from the Gulf of Guayaquil, Ecuador. The
other two are from the Philippines: San Miguel Bay, in Bicol province, for which ICLARM conducted
multidisciplinary studies in 1980 and 1992; and Lingayen Gulf, also the site of ICLARM7scoastal area
management project (1986- 1991) and later, Geographic Information Systems (GIs) applications. The
LP tableaus used for these application papers are available in spreadsheet form and are described in
Agiiero et al. (this vol.)
I examine in many ways the limitations posed by LP and the importance one must must give to the
data used by the model. But then, every model, no matter how elaborate, has its limitations. It is how we
interpret the models and their outputs that matters. As for the usefulness of this exercise, I invite the
readers to decide.
I leave for last that which I relish most-to give credit to those who made this volume possible. I
thank Mr. Alexis Fabunan who painstakingly reconstructed the LP tableaus under the most constraining
circumstances (a 286 computer with some 4 megabytes of RAM to handle a 780 x 560 matrix!); Mr.
Alvin Catalan who helped me complete the bibliographic entries, developed the glossary of technical
terms, and finalized the indices; Mr. F.S.B. Torres, Jr. for helping me with the species index and the
Appendix to the paper by Araneda et al.; Dr. William Sunderlin, former ICLARM staff, now with the
Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR) who helped me reconstruct the species appendix
for the forestry sector of Bio-Bio; Mr. F.C. Gayanilo, Jr. and Mr. Eli Garnace for reviewing the software
and for revising the user's manual; Ms. Merly Medina for her assistance in the typing and printing of
manuscripts and tables; Drs. Robert Pomeroy and Mahfuz Ahmed, for taking time out to read the
concept papers and for freely providing some constructive comments; and Dr. Meryl Williams, for her
support of the whole project.
This work would not have been possible without the foresight, industry and talent of Dr. Max
Agiiero and his team of experts from the ICLARM-ECLAC project, specifically Ms. Fabiola Bell, Ms.
Angelica Arellano, Mr. Edgardo Araneda, Mr. Francisco Morales, all authors of the papers in this
volume. I thank my co-authors, specifically, Ms. Zoraida Alojado and Mr. Len Garces of ICLARM and
Ms. Agnes Grace Cargamento of the National Economic and Development Authority of the Philippines
(NEDA-Region I) for their cooperation despite the short notice and extremely tight schedules.
I thank Dr. Daniel Pauly whose unfailing support and encouragement I began to experience in 1986
when he was then Director of the Resource Assessment and Management Program, later to become the
Capture Fisheries Management Program. I thank him most especially because as a scientist from another
discipline, he did not hamper my professional and intellectual interests in the 'other' sciences (i.e.,
economics) and had in fact encouraged me to produce work that I am very proud of today.
ANNABELLE
CRUZ-TRINIDAD
Research Associate, ICLARM
The Integrated Functional Coefficients
including: optimal development strategies for
Method for Coastal Resources Valuation* mangroves in the Gulf of Guayaquil, Ecuador (Bell
and Cruz-Trinidad, this vol.) and land use in the
MAX A G ~ ~ E R ICLARM-ECLAC
O', Project on the Lingayen Gulf area, Philippines (Cruz-Trinidad et al.,
Socioeconomic Valuationof Coastal Resources in Southwest this vol.); optimal fleet allocation in San Miguel Bay,
Latin America, Casilla 179-0, Santiago, Chile
Philippines (Cruz-Trinidad and Garces, this vol.); and
optimal production and marketing strategies for
ANNABELLE CRUZ-TRINIDAD, International Centerfor Living fisheries and forestry in Bio-Bio, Chile (Araneda et
Aquatic Resources Management (ICLARM), MCPO Box
al., this vol.).
2631, 0718 Makati City, Philippines
The IFC method was designed to consolidate all
negative (costs) and positive (revenues) flows resulting
EXEQUEL
GONZALEZ~,
ICLARM-ECLAC Project on the
Socioeconomic Valuation of Coastal Resources in Southwest from different levels of resource exploitation activities
Latin America, Casilla 179-0, Santiago, Chile into a single numeraire, i.e., economic value. The IFC
method derived its name from its features, namely: (i)
FABIOLA
BELL^, ICLARM-ECLAC Project on the the highly integrated approach to management of
Socioeconomic Valuation of Coastal Resources in Southwest resource systems and (ii) the use of functional
Latin America, Casilla 179-0, Santiago, Chile coefficients to represent input-output efficiency.
Table 1. Example of some coastal resourceslactivities and related influences and impacts.
Resourceslactivities' MG AQ CF CR SG AG MN OG SP SM HB UD CV
Programming
Equation (1) is the objective function, here, a
on indicates that for a particular
maximization problem. The X's are the unknowns or
1decisions are to be made. This
decision variables while the P's are the relative
:of possible tools to enable the
contribution of each variable to the value of the
ve at a decision and further objective function. The a,llll'srepresent the amount of
used by changes in resource resource b needed by activity or sector, X. The bill's are
e interrelationships between
the upper or lower limit of a resource use and in an LP
In variable. tableau are usually referred to as the right-hand 4ide
(RHS) limits. Equations (2) to (4) are the constraints;
Equation (5) is the nonnegativity clause. The above
formulation is also called the pr~malproblem.
g (LP) is an operations research The dual, which is the converse of the primal, is
the 1940s for use in military formulated as follows:
widely used in business and
cations of the method assumed Minimize
wior, a single-period planning
:ration for risk and uncertainty. blwl+ b2w2+.... + blllwlll
nents, however, proved that
in be more realistic and flexible. subject to
xhniques include multiperiod
multi-objective modeling, allWl+ a,,w, + ..... + al,,lw,ll'= PI
ng, game theory models and
>= P2
a,,w, + a,,w, + ..... + a,ll?_WI1l
g (Hazell and Norton 1986).
ss a single, linear objective
zd subject to a set of rigid linear
15). Assumptions implicit in the
resources and activities in the q n w ,+ a,l,w, + ..... + a,lll,wlll
>= Pll
node1 include: optimization,
determinism, homogeneity, Wl, W >,...,Will >= 0.
tionality (Hazell and Norton
tion of a linear program is as Note that the dual formulation is actually equivalent
to the primal, i.e., the maximization problem (primal)
and the inverse of the minimum (dual) are one and the
same. The solution to the primal problem provides the
optimizing values of the variables and the resulting
PnXn ...1) value of the objective function.
The existence of the dual solution in any
conventional LP formulation is one of the more
important reasons for its popularity. The dual can be
- alllxn<= b, -2) interpreted as shadow price or opportunity cost of a
particular resource. As such, it is also a measure of the
t a2,,Xn<= '32 -3 marginal increase in the objective function given an
4
increase in the availability of the resource. Sensitivity The applications of programming models to
analysis permits further analysis by varying coefficients economic-environmental systems are diverse, ranging
in both the objective and input-output matrices, right- from forest management, environmental quality
hand side limits, and the inclusion of a new goal or models, petroleum refining and electric power
constraint. This was done for the San Miguel Bay study, generation, to complex regional and national models
i.e., level of fishery net revenues as affected by changes for optimal utilization of water resources (Hufschmidt
in total allowable catch rates and minimum wage rates et al. 1983).
(Cruz-Trinidad and Garces, this vol.). Despite the fast-paced development in mathe-
matical programming techniques, LP applications in
Applications developing countries in both fisheries and coastal
environments are few. Two have been identified in the
Linear programming was first applied to fisheries literature, the works of Padilla (1991), using
by Rothschild and Balsiger (1971) to allocate the catch multiobjective programming to determine optimal
of sockeye salmon during a run in Bristol Bay. Siege1 effort in the small pelagics fishery in the Guimaras
et al. (1979) used LP to maximize catches of the New Strait, Western Visayas, Philippines, and Ahmed
England otter trawl fishery subject to total allowable (199 I), using price endogenous linear programming
catch, processing and harvesting capacity, based on an to estimate net social benefits of different types of
earlier work by Mueller (1976). Agiiero (1987) used fisheries, i.e., hilsa, prawn, catfish and carp in the
LP to model the Peruvian fishery and utilized six floodplains of Bangladesh. The latter also involved
sequential activity blocks beginning from harvesting segmentation of both objective function and constraints
to processing, storage, transport, marketing and sales into harvesting, postharvest and marketing blocks. The
to arrive at, among other things, optimal rates of apparent underutilization of mathematical program-
resource exploitation, plant rated capacities and prices. ming and its enormous potential for use in fisheries
Subsequent developments permit the incorporation and coastal systems in developing economies, show
of multiple-planning periods, risk and uncertainty into that the applications in this volume, and the use of
the model. McCarl and Spreen (1980) have suggested OPUS, the LP software developed for this purpose,
that price need not be an exogenous variable in LP can be a significant contribution to the literature.
formulations while Shepherd and Garrod (1980)
developed a method of cautious nonlinear optimization Potentially Applicable Techniques
which resolves the tendency of LP results to be
"extreme, sparse and ruthless" and which "considers Hufschmidt e t a l . ( 1 9 8 3 ) suggested t w o
the initial state of the system when seeking the analytical frameworks for multiactivity economic-
optimum". These improvements are incorporated via environmental models: linear programming and
a composite objective function which consists of input-output (1-0) models. The latter was developed
penalties for (i) failing to conform to one or more by Leontief (1936) [thus, the alternate term, Leontief
constraints, i.e., quota allocations and (ii) a penalty for matrix] and emphasizes the interrelationships
departing from the status quo, i.e. historical average between production activities. Each productive
catch rates, and (iii) one or more objectives to be activity assumes dual roles: first, as a supplier of
minimized. Huppert and Squires (1986) applied this output to other activities and final buyers and
technique to the Pacific coast groundfish trawl fishery second, as a buyer of inputs including land, labor,
and estimated maximum economic surplus and optimal capital and the outputs of other activities. As in
fleet configuration. standard economic systems, the final demand for
Further development in the area of mathematical goods and services determines the 1-0 coefficients
programming has resulted in dynamic optimization as of economic-environmental models. 1 - 0 analysis
used by Dow (I 993) in the regulation of bowhead whales permits the decisionmaker to simulate changes in
and Kennedy and Watkins (1986) in the southern bluefin economic and environmental quality variables
tuna fishery. Wallace and Brekke (1986) used stochastic related to different economic development scenarios
optimization in the Norwegian purse seiner and summer and/or changes in final demand for goods and
capelin fishery in the Barents Sea. services (Hufschmidt et al. 1983).
The following analytical techniques are extracted The IFC Method and Its Implementation
from a list provided by Hyman and Stiftel (1988) for
Environmental Impact Assessment @A), which we have The integrated functional coefficients method was
identified to be relevant to coastal resources as well. designed to determine the social and economic value
Sorenson (1971) devised a network or stepped matrix for of coastal resources within an integrated concept of
which the primary focus is the environmental cost of the coastal ecosystem and its functions. The elements
coastal land uses. Fifty-five coastal zone uses are entered are the same as that of standard LP formulation except
in the matrix rows. The columns represent i) causal factors, that the definitions are largely expansive. The objective
i.e., specific activities associated with particular land uses; function (Net Social Benefit Function) is structured in
ii) initial conditions; iii) secondary impacts; iv) ultimate terms of the Total Economic Value concept (Randall
environmental effects and v) management interventions. 1987) allowing externalities and nonmarket goods,
The Sorenson network has been applied to commercial, services and functions to be considered. Unit cost
residential and transportation development in the coefficients and prices are exogenous to the model and
Californian coastal zone. determined using statistical techniques andlor
Hill (1968) developed the multiple objective analysis econometrics, whichever is applicable. The resulting
or goals achievementmatrix. This procedure involves the measure of net revenue is a measure of Net Social
definition of important objectives and the subsequent Benefit valued at the best alternative use given the
assignment of weights. The crucial step is the anticipation constraints imposed on the system.
of impacts of each objective. Hill and Alterman (1974) Each activity is constrained by resources
used multiple objective analysis to assess alternativesites availability, technological efficiency, cost structures,
for power plants. A related procedure is decision analysis input and output market conditions and institutional
(Keeney and Raffia 1976) although this technique places factors. The methodology is derived from the
greater emphasis on systems modeling and evaluation integration of several sources of value under several
under risk and uncertainty. The first step is the restraining conditions.
identification of objectives and assignment of "attributes" The elements of an IFC linear program as applied
per objective. The next steps involve prediction of future in a coastal resource system are as follows:
values for each alternative plan and selection of
preferences among the various alternatives. (i) Objective Function
Decisionmakers base their final decision on the alternative
which maximizes utility. Decision analysis was used to
predict the impact of a nuclear power plant on salmonid
Maximize n
stocks (Keeney and Robilliard 1977).
The United States Fish and Wildlife Service (1980)
developed a Habitat Evaluation Procedure (HEP),
which evaluates the effects of development on a single
aspect of the environment -fish and wildlife habitats. where
The HEP enables decisionmakers to select among
different project alternatives and to design mitigation n = net social benefit function
and compensation measures. First, the habitat types in
the area are mapped out and indicator species identified 'ijklmnop
= good or service corresponding to
on the basis of economic or social importance,
sensitivity to proposed actions, role in nutrient cycling i = spatial location of the resource, i.e.,
and energy flows, and representativeness in various country, region, zone, subzone;
ecological niches. The decision rule is then based on
potential changes in "habitat units" (habitat area j = economlc sector, i.e., fisheries, tourism,
multiplied by habitat sustainability index). forestry, mining, aquaculture;
6
k = economic activity, i.e, harvesting, An additional standard restriction is the
processing, transporting, storage, nonnegativity constraint which provides for all
marketing, consumption; Xijklmnop's
to be positive or equal to zero.
The mathematical programming problem is
1 = resource, i.e., fish, tree, mangrove, solved by means of the simplex algorithm (Revised
beach, coral reef; Simplex Method) using OPUS, a computer software
package (see Agiiero et al., this vol.). The optimization
m = product, i.e., in the fishery, fishmeal, oil, process, i.e., the search for the best (optimal) value of
frozen fish; from the forestry sector, the control variables (level of resource uselexploitation)
boards, chips, pulp; from tourism, within the feasible set of alternatives, determines the
recreational facilities, hotels, beach economic value of each resource in its best alternative
resort; use. The vector of shadow prices indicates how the net
social benefits change as one additional unit of a
n = technology, i.e., capital intensive, labor resource is made available, reflecting in this way, its
intensive; social value.
o = scale, i.e., large scale, medium scale, Use and Implementation of the IFC Method
small scale; and
Modeling the coastal ecosystem for valuation
p = gear or equipment, i.e., in the fishery, purposes under a mathematical programming structure
net, boat, hook, harpoon; in the forestry requires a sound knowledge and understanding of the
sector, axe, electric chain; and in the various resources, activities and processes taking place
tourism industry, car, bicycle, train. in the coastal area. It is essential to fully understand
the various interactions to establish the limits defining
Pijklmnop
and Cijklmnop
= price and cost estimates each system and their linkages with each other.
of each variable. The use of the IFC method involves two phases:
(i) conceptual formulation and (ii) application of
Further specifications to distinguish features of mathematical programming. Conceptual formulation
the resource, products or markets can be made, e.g., is the more critical of the tasks and involves steps 1 to
distinguishing frozen fish in blocks (round or fillets) 6 in the list provided below. This phase entails
or boxes of different weights or grade. Similarly, understanding the human and natural dynamics of the
markets can be distinguished as local, domestic and coastal zone, determining the sources of economic
foreign, etc. Because of the numerous options to value and its components, and assigning appropriate
disaggregate any one variable, each application paper measures of value. These elements, when translated
in this volume provides a detailed explanation of the into algebraic terms, become the elements of the LP
LP elements. tableau. The programming application, especially with
\ the use of available software, i.e., OPUS, becomes
purely mechanical.
(ii) Functional Restrictions The following is a list of steps necessary to
accomplish this task.
1. Characterize the coastal system. This is done
AX.I <= bj by preparing a "profile" or description of the
coastal area. The profile describes the macro-
AX.I indicates technical coefficients associated to environment, both natural and human, in
the Xtil;llnnp> which the relevant economic sectors operate.
Some examples of profiles are those
b. indicates resource endowments, yield at .prepared by the ASEANIUS Coastal
differknt levels of use, demand for different price Resources Management Project in Brunei
ranges, installed capacities, balance indicators, etc. (Chua et al. 1987), South Johore, Malaysia
7
(ASEANIUS CRMP 199I), Lingayen Gulf, of economic (primal) as well as social (dual-
Philippines (McManus and Chua 1990), Ban shadow vector) values. Sensitivity analysis
Don Bay and Phangnga Bay, Thailand (Paw measures the effect of exogenous changes
et al. 1988), Segara Anakan-Cilacap, in prices and resources availability on the
Indonesia (White et al. 1989). net social benefit (Value of the Objective
Determine relevant sectors and activities. Function) and those of the variables.
Economic activities should be based on the
following factors: output (production in Discussion
physical and monetary terms); yield (net
natural growth per unit of input); em- There are no hard and fast rules in the use of IFC
ployment (per category of skills required); methods especially when applied to diverse environ-
income (per location, category of em- ments such as coastal zones. The list shown above,
ployment; locallforeign); spatial location, though uncomfortably loose, provides the basic
and impact on other sectors. elements for the analysis and application of the
Identify variables that either contribute to or technique. This is borne by the four application papers
minimize economic value and determine in this volume which may have varied applications but
thereafter, the activities or elements which, nevertheless, manifest all these elements.
influencing such. For example, if the relevant A critical, though exogenous, aspect of this
sectors are aquaculture and forestry, the exercise is the use of appropriate price coefficients,
variables that add to economic value may especially when imperfect market conditions exist or
include shrimps and logs, respectively. The when nonmarket transactions occur. The whole area
export of shrimp would require the following of valuation and applicable techniques are discussed
activities: clearing of mangroves, stocking in Agiiero and Flores (this vol.).
of ponds, harvesting, processing, trans- This volume does not attempt to break new
porting, and marketing, each of which is ground in methodological development; rather, the
characterized by different price vectors as emphasis is on using tested techniques on broader
well as constraints. applications. Thus, the development of the conceptual
Collect data required, including market and issues is of greater weight than the application of the
nonmarket prices, production levels, technique itself. Complementarily, we invoke Holling's
technological capacities and magnitude of (1978) caveat on the use of mathematical programming
externalities. techniques: while we should not be slaves of the model,
Establish functional relationships among the it offers a sensible start for analytical and predictive
components, determining production, yield purposes.
and demand functions.
Construct the mathematical programming
tableau structure including the objective References
function, input-output matrix, and restriction
vector (right-hand side). Agiiero, M. 1987. A bioeconomic model of the Peruvian pelagic fishery,
Feed the tableau and conduct preliminary p. 307-324. In D. Pauly and I. Tsukayama (eds.) The Peruvian
anchoveta and its upwelling ecosystem: three decades of change.
consistency tests, i.e., degeneracy, ICLARM Stud. Rev. 15, 35 1 p.
unboundness, etc. 'Ahmed, M. 1991. A model to determine benefits obtainable from the
Run OPUS and determine necessary management of riverine fisheries of Bangladesh. ICLARM Tech.
Rep. 28, 133 p.
improvements in data quality. 'ASEANIUS CRMP. 1991. The coastal environmental profile of South
Analyze and validate results. Verify that Johore, Malaysia. ICLARM Tech. Rep. 24, 65 p.
results obtained in actual application are 'Chua, T.E., L.M. Chou and M.S.M Sadorra, Editors. 1987. The coastal
environmental profile of Brunei Darossalam: resource assessment
consistent with theory and the control factors and management issues. ICLARM Tech. Rep. 18, 193 p.
pre-established for this purpose JDixon, J.A. 1989. Coastal resources: assessing alternatives, p. 153-162.
In T.-E. Chua and D. Pauly (eds.) Coastal area management in
Interpret final results and conduct sensitivity Southeast Asia: policies, management strategies and case studies.
analvsis. The final results ~ r o v i d eestimates
-2 --- - -
ICLARM Conf. k o c . 19,254 p.
8
Dow, J.P., Jr. 1993. Dynamic regulation of fisheries: the case of the k c M a n u s , L.T. and T.-E. Chua. Editors. 1990. The coastal
bowhead whale. Mar. Res. Econ. 8:145-154. environmental profile of Lingayen Gulf, Philippines. ICLARM
Hazell, B.R. and R.D. Norton. 1986. Mathematical programming for Tech. Rep. 22, 69 p.
economic analysis in agriculture. Macmillan, New York. Mueller, J.J. 1976. A linear programming discussion model for
Hill, M. 1968. A goal achievement matrix for evaluating alternative maximizing the net revenues from a multispecies fishery. US
plans." J. Am. Inst. Planners 34:19-28. National Marine Fisheries Service. 13 p.
Hill, M. and R. Alterman. 1974. Power plant site evaluation: the case of Padilla, J.E. 1991. Managing tropical multispecies fisheries with
the Sharon plant in Israel." J. Env. Econ. Manage. 2:179-196. multiple objectives. Simon Fraser University, Canada. PhD
Holling, C., Editor. 1978. Adaptive environmental assessment and J dissertation.
management. Wiley-Interscience, New York. Paw, J.N., S. Bunpapong, A.T. White and M.S.M. Sadorra, Editors.
Hufschmidt, M.M., D.E. James, A.D. Meister, B.T. Bower and J.A. 1988. The coastal environmental profile of Ban Don Bay and
Dixon. 1983. Environment, natural systems, and development: Phangnga Bay, Thailand. ICLARM Tech. Rep. 20, 78 p.
an economic valuation guide. John Hopkins Press Ltd., London. Randall, A. 1987. Total economic value as a basis for policy. Trans.
Huppert D.D. and D. Squires. 1986. Potential economic benefits of Am. Fish. Soc. 116:325.
limited access in the Pacific coast trawl fishery: a linear Rothschild, B.J. and J.W. Balsiger. 1971. A linear programming
programming approach. Administrative Report LJ-86-01. US
Southwest Fisheries Center, NOAA, California. 59 p. j Scura,solution to salmon management. U.S. Fish. Bull. 69:117-139.
L.F., T.-B. Chua, M.D. Pido and J.N. Paw. 1992. Lessons for
Hyman, E.L. and B. Stiftel. 1988. Combining facts and values in integrated coastal zone management: the ASEAN experience, p.
environmental impact assessment: theories and techniques. 1-70. In T.-E. Chua and L.F. Scura (eds.) Integrative framework
Westview Press, London. and methods for coastal area management. ICLARM Conf. Proc.
ignizio, J.P. 1985. Introduction to linear goal programming. Sage 37, 169 p.
Publications, California. Sheperd, J.G. and D.J. Garrod. 1980. Modeling the response of a
Keeney, R. and H. Raffia. 1976. Decision with multiple objectives: fishing fleet to changing circumstances, using cautious non-linear
preferences and value tradeoffs. Wiley, New York. optimization. 1. Cons. CIEM 39:231-238.
Keeney, R. and G. Robilliard. 1977. Assessing and evaluating Siegel, R.A., J.J. Mueller and B.J. Rothschild. 1979. A linear
environmental impacts at proposed nuclear power plant sites. J. programming approach to determining harvesting capacity: a
Env. Econ. Manage. 4:153-166. multiple species fishery. U S . Fish. Bull. 77:425-433.
Kennedy, J. 0 . S. and J. W. Watkins. 1986. Time-dependent quotas for the Sorenson, J. 1971. A framework for identification and control of
southem bluefin tuna fishery. Mar. Res. Econ. 2 (4):293-313. resource degradation and conflict in the multiple use of the
Laszlo, E. 1972. Introduction to systems philosophy - towards a new coastal zone. University of California, Department of Landscape
paradigm of contemporary thought. Gordon and Breach Science Architecture, Berkeley.
Publishers, New York. United States Fish and Wildlife Service. 1980. Habitat evaluation
Leontief, W.W. 1936. Quantitative input and output relations in the economic procedures. Revised ed. Documents ESM 101 t o 104.
system of the United States. Rev. Econ. Stat. 28(3):105-125. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC.
Mattessich, R., 1984. The systems approach: its variety of aspects. General Wallace, S.W. and K. Brekke. 1986. Optimal fleet size when national
Systems 18:3-12. J quotas can be traded. Mar. Res. Econ. 2:315-330.
l , and T.H.Spreen. 1980. Price endogenous
~ c ~ a rB.A. - mathematical White, A.T., P. Martosubroto ahd M.S.M. Sadorra, Editors. 1989. The
programming as a tool for sector analysis. Am. J. Ag. - Econ. coastal environmental profile of Segara Anakan-Cilacav, South
62(i):87-10< Java, Indonesia. ICLARM Tech. ~ e i 25, . 82 p.
Valuation Concepts and Techniques effectiveness of resource exploitation activities. As a
with Applications to Coastal Resources* consequence, developing nations are increasingly
viewing the exploitation of their coastal renewable
MAXAGUERO' FLORES',
AND XIMENA ICLARM-ECLAC
resources as a source of foreign exchange, employment
Collaborative Project on the Socioeconomic Valuation of and food supply. In fact, most government policies of
Coastal Resources in Southwest Latin America, Casilla 179- developing countries, in one way or another, promote
D, Santiago, Chile coastal exploitation to solve pressing social needs.
The limits to which these resources can be
AGUERO, M. and X. FLORES. 1996. Valuation concepts and techniques exploited on sustained basis, however, are not yet well
with applications to coastal resources, p. 9- 16. In A. Cruz-Trinidad known or understood, but decreasing yields in many
(ed.) Valuation of tropical coastal resources: theory and application
of linear programming. ICLARM Stud. Rev. 25, 108 p.
renewable resources such as fish stocks, indicate that
very probably, they are already being overexploited
(Garcia and Newton 1995).
Abstract One of the causes of the abovementioned problem
is the absence of well developed markets for many
Overexploitation of natural resources is linked to the use of valuation
goods, services and functions performed by coastal
techniques that do not consider nonmarket environmental goods and
services. The Total Economic Value (TEV) concept is discussed and its resources like mangroves and coral reefs. The failure
relevance to natural resources valuation is highlighted. Lastly, techniques of existing methods to properly account for them results
for resources valuation are presented. along with an example referring to
the mangroves around the Gulf of Guayaquil, Ecuador.
in undervaluation of total benefits and consequently, a
bias towards overexploitation or conversion of
resources to alternative options. Examples of this
Introduction
process are the increasing tendency to convert
mangrove areas into shrimp ponds, the increasing
Coastal ecosystems and their resources throughout degradation of the environment (pollution,
the developing world are being increasingly mis-
sedimentation, etc.) and discharge of urban waste into
managed and exploited beyond the limits of their the ocean without prior treatment. The overall result is
sustainability. Furthermore, destructive techniques for
rent dissipation and resource degradation (Fig. 1).
resource exploitation are proliferating in many poor Moreover, coastal resources exploitation does not
coastal areas where both resources and the functional take place in isolation. The allocation of inputs to a
integrity of the ecosystem are being seriously threatened
specific process prevents its use in others, changing
by illegal or uncontrolled human activities (Chua and their relative availability to alternative activities. Also,
Fallon-Scura 1992).
exploitation activities generate several residuals and
In recent times, research efforts and policy analysis
spill-over effects affecting the performance of others.
emphasize the need to properly manage and preserve
These effects, better known as "externalities", are
natural resources and the environment. Abundant
generally not accounted for by their generating source,
literature from all disciplines has been produced
but borne by society without due compensation. A
describing, quantifying and denouncing undesirable
divergence between social and private costs is thus
human interventions in the ecosystem, namely, those
created with misleading signals for an efficient resource
related to pollution, waste disposal and other global
allocation process. These signals, namely, unrealistic
environmental damage (Panayotou 1993; Pearce and
high profit margins and larger expected long-term
Moran 1994).
yields, by default do not account for resource users'
Moreover, population growth and higher incomes,
costs (value of fish in the water, clean air, etc.) nor for
especially in developed nations, have increased trade
negative externalities imposed on society (like water
opportunities for developing coastal nations with rich
pollution from fishmeal plants, siltation/sedimentation
renewable resources. Increased technological
from logging, and solid wastes from tourism). When
efficiency, on the other hand, has improved the cost
the outputs of these resource exploitation activities are
exported to markets with very high price elasticities,
*ICLARM Contribution No. 12 18.
'Present address: International Center for Sustainable Ecological e.g., fishmeal, considerable rents are transferred to the
Development (ICSED), Casilla 27004, Santiago, Chile. importing country, creating a paradoxical flow of value
ecosystems (Aylward and Barbier 1992). Valuation then
becomes an interface between ecology and economics
because of the use of certain commonalities from two
otherwise divergent realms. First is the equivalence of
what economists would refer to as "goods" to the
structural component of an ecosystem, i.e., wood, fish,
and water, and what economists would refer to as
"services" with environmental functions such as natural
protection from storms and breeding grounds for fish.
Actual valuation is the next step and can be defined
as a quantitative assessment of the value of these
"goods" and "services". Money is usually used as a
numeraire for this purpose, since it allows aggregation
and comparison of heterogenous elements through a
common unit. It is then possible to compare values of
fishery resources with forestry or industrial output for
example. Furthermore, it allows consistency in ranking
priorities for investment decisions and policy design.
Several criteria are used for this purpose, but
relative scarcity and human appreciation of the resource
are most relevant. For valuation purposes, coastal
resources are viewed in their capacity to generate a
flow of goods, services and ecological functions that
can satisfy human needs of various kinds, whether
directly or indirectly. In this capacity, they are valued
by individuals and society according to the net benefits
they provide. In other words, natural resources are
considered in economic terms only in their capacity to
Fig. 1 . Nonaccountability of externalities and other nonuse values satisfy human needs and therefore, valued as far as they
results in exploitation beyond economically optimum levels (MEY)
in A: the divergence between MEY and OAE, or the downward
enter in human preference scales. This approach is also
shift of supply curve, S1 to S2, results in rent dissipation equivalent shared in cost-benefit analysis, in which scarcity is also
to lJKL in B. considered as a determining factor.
Although the concept of value, indicating worth,
has been analyzed and formalized in various ways and
given several interpretations over time, it is becoming
(a sort of subsidy) from poor to rich countries. The well accepted now within the concept of Total
increasing rate of resource exploitation now taking Economic Value (TEV). This concept was first
place in many developing countries is a clear evidence articulated by Weisbrod ( 1964) and Krutilla (1 967)
of the above problem. It also shows the urgent need to stating that the total value of a resource includes its
incorporate new valuation techniques to improve use and nonuse values.
resource management. The total value of a private good is usually defined
as the maximum amount of money an individual is
Valuation Concepts and Techniques willing to pay for it over and above the consumer
surplus. For a natural resource, however, the total
Total Economic Value economic value IS defined as "use value" plus "nonuse
value". Use value is referred to costs and benefits of a
Interest in natural resources valuation stems from resource for which a market exists; it can be direct (in
the realization that the economic sector is part of a wider situ) or indirect use. Direct use may be "consumptive"
arena that consists of multiple life-supporting (that is, usedlenjoyed by someone, thus, depriving
11
others of its use) or nonconsumptive, meaning that Gregory (1987) found it useful to assess the
others may also enjoy its benefits. nonmonetary benefits of extramarkets of environmental
The concept of nonuse value has received special services, albeit their inclusion in TEV was not
attention in recent years due to the growing concern considered.
for the environment and sustainable use of resources, Although these preservation and nonuse values are
as it applies to the value individuals place on resources, not clearly attached to any particular component of a
regardless of their presentlfuture or consumptive/ given resource, they tend to be associated with it as a
nonconsumptive use. Several categories are included, whole. Thus, the role of a resource (like mangroves) in
namely, existence value (value of a resource for just preserving biodiversity or the role in determining the
knowing it exists or will be preserved); option value uniqueness to culture and heritage (the condor in Chile,
(willingness to pay for the option of using/consuming the bald eagle in the USA, the Pirineos in Europe, etc.)
the resource in the future); quasi-option (willingness contribute to the existence, bequest and option value
to pay to have the option of deciding in the future about that individuals attach to preservation.
its use); and bequest/heritage and preservation value The TEV concept was applied by Spurgeon (1 992)
(value to know future generations will have the on coral reefs. Use values were classified as extractive
opportunity to use the resource). or nonextractive. Among the extractive values are those
Hyman and Stiftel (1988) pointed out five of fishing, pharmaceutical, and construction and the
alternative uses of option value: risk aversion; quasi- nonextractive are tourism, education and social value.
option demand; existence value; vicarious use value; Among the techniques listed that use market or pseudo-
and beq~iestvalue which altogether possess some market prices are cost-benefit analysis, change in
interchangeable features. productivity and measures of consumer surplus.
Still another category of resource use, the indirect Simulated markets are used in contingent valuation
~tsefor which the valuation depends on the "processes" methods (CVM) and travel cost (TC) technique to
that ultimately provide economic value, was proposed evaluate value of tourism spots, for example. As for
by Aylward and Barbier (1992). Some indirect uses of the indirect uses of coral reefs, like biological support,
wetlands include groundwater recharge or discharge, the author suggested the use of change in productivity
flood and flow control, shoreline or bank stabilization, in "with or without the reef' situations and a percentage
sediment retention and nutrient retention (Barbier dependence technique for which the biological support
1989).These environmental functions must be analyzed value is the value of the supported activity multiplied
wlthin the broader framework of biological diversity by an estimated percentage dependence of that activity
as this implies a corresponding analysis of the linkages on the reef's presence. For nonuse values, such as
In the ecological chain and how changes within the existence and option value, an extensive CVM survey
system affect the environmental functions supported is suggested as was implemented by Hundloe (1989)
by it. in the estimation of the vicarious value (option plus
Measures of indirect uses are based on whether existence value) of the Great Barrier Reef which
such functions support economic production or protect amounted to AUS $ 4 5 millionlyear.
the conduct of economic activity. A measure of the The application of TEV in this volume has been
consumer's willingness to pay (WTP) or willingness slightly modified in the net social benefit function of
to accept (WTA) may take the form of changes in the "integrated functional coefficient method" to
product~vity,alternative/substitute costs, or actual capture the net value (positive or negative) of
expenditures. Valuation techniques used to estimate externalities (Fig. 2).
WTA mclude preventive expenditure, damage costs Aylward and Barbier (1992) pointed out some
avoided, alternative or substitute cost and relocation caveats in the use of the TEV especially with respect
costs. In both cases, an immense amount of data is to double accounting of goods and services. This occurs
requ~redespecially in developing-country situations. when the direct use of the resource is valued in addition
Moreover, some measures may prove irrelevant due to to themdirect functions that support these direct uses.
the absence of technology that would, for instance, For example, mangrove forest litter that provides food
restore the nutrient retention capabilities of mangroves. for fish and shrimp larvae is an environmental function
NBSF = C (TR-TC)
= '* saro * Pso- C X s a r o *saro
C
+ ' saro
*ECsaro+ x X saro* F Bsr
Subject to: NBSF = net benefit P = price
Biomass abundance social function C = cost of production
Infrastructure capacity TR = total revenue EC = environmental cost
Capital availability TC = total cost FB = foregone benefits
Labor availability X = quantity of goods1
Environmental carrying capacity service produced
where
Sectors (s) 1 Fishery Forestry Tourism Environment
Fig. 2. A typical objective function characterizing a multiresource coastal zone and elaboration of coefficients.
which "can" be valued. However, if goods such as erences for closely related goods that differ marginally
shrimps are valued likewise, some double accounting in the quantity or quality of their attribute.
may occur. Likewise, some ambiguities arise as to the Classification of valuation techniques as discussed
classification of option value which can be classified here will be based on three market categories:
as a nonuse value, because it is not actually used, at conventional, implicit or artificial although other
present. Again, we invoke the influence of neoclassical authors have developed additional levels of
economics on natural resources valuation, i.e., that classification. For example, Munasinghe and Lutz
individual satisfaction is paramount. (1993) also used actual versus potential behavior while
Dixon et al. (1988) used the categories: generally
applicable, potentially applicable, survey-based and
Valuation Techniques nonwillingness to pay-based methods.
Valuation techniques based on conventional
Many techniques for ~~aluation of nonmarket goods markets are based on market prices. These techniques
and services are based on the hedonic price theory of are particularly useful when environmental impacts
consumer choice. Goods are not valued in and of have direct effects on goods and services which are
themselves but rather as a composite of different priced. Under perfect competition, market prices
attributes. Thus, the valuation of each of these attributes indicate the real value to both consumers and suppliers.
can be computed backwards if the market value of the However, when market conditions are imperfect (i.e.,
product is known or if the market value of related goods monopoly, collusion), or do not exist (i.e., environ-
and services is known. The derived demand curve can mental goods and services), or exist but fail (i.e., public
thus be constructed by comparing each attribute with goods and externalities), market prices may not be an
comparisons of actual expenditures or survey pref- appropriate measure. A proposed alternative is the use
13
of shadow pricing which can be used in impact mitigate environmental impacts, e.g., wastewater
assessment of environmental services (Hyman and treatment facilities. In this case, the value of water
Stiftel 1988) and when compensating for distortions pollution is taken to be the equivalent of preventing it
in the costs of capital, foreign exchange, land and labor. by way of technological costs. Replacement cost is the
All techniques, whether they be survey based or cost of substituting particular features of a resource to
otherwise, attempt to capture the willingness to pay approximate its natural characteristic. For example,
(WTP) [in some cases, willingness to accept (WTA) Folke and Karberger (199 1) estimated replacement
<compensation>] criteria discussed above as the costs for loss of wetland productivity while Araneda
ultimate measure of utility. A societal demand curve is et al. (this vol.) used the value of freshwater needed to
then constructed by horizontally summing up the dilute polluted bay waters to acceptable levels.
individual demand curves as discussed below. Randall
(1987) suggests that a cross-corroboration technique IMPLICIT MARKETS
is desirable in nonmarket valuation.
A taxonomy of valuation techniques based on
Valuation techniques falling under this category
market category is presented in Table I .
are based on the premise that some market goods can
be related to particular environmental attributes that
Table 1. Techniques currently used for natural resources valuation
according to market category. are not priced. Thus, property values and wage
differences, both hedonic methods, are approximations
Conventional Implicit Constructed of the overall environmental quality. Property values,
Change of productivity Travel cost Artificial market for example, are dependent on the environmental
quality of a particular housing site, e.g., a polluted site
Loss of earnings Wage differences n.a. causes a drop in assessment rate; for the same reason,
Defensive expenditures Property values n.a.
this same polluted site would have to offer higher wages
Replacement cost n.a. Contingent to attract labor. Bell (1989) used the land value
Shadow project n.a. valuation
approach in the valuation of Florida fisheries. The
travel cost method is commonly used for determining
CONVENTIONAL MARKETS
the value of a recreational site. Travel expenses, fees
paid on site, and the opportunity cost of travel time are
taken to represent "entrance fees". This information
When environmental functions result in measurable
will allow the researcher to construct a demand
changes in the production or productive capacity of a
schedule based on the number of potential vacationists
certain good or service, conventional market techniques
as a function of travel cost; thus, consumer surplus can
can be used, i.e., the WTP is taken to be equal to the
be estimated. The travel cost method was applied by
market price. In cases where noncompetitive markets
Costanza et al. (1989) in the valuation of wetlands and
exist, the shadow price or opportunity cost is taken in
by Hundloe (1 989) in the Great Barrier Reef.
lieu of current price.
Change in prod~~ctivity estimates changes in
production arising from a particular intervention or CONSTRUCTED MARKETS
Fig. 3. Use and nonuse values of mangroves in the Gulf of Guayaquil, Ecuador; associated levels of tangibility and potentially useful valuation techniques.
16
on the same site. The goods and services listed are the Global Trends, 14-16 June 1994. Seattle, USA. 63 p.
dominant uses of mangrove resources in the area. Glass, R.J. and R.M. Muth. 1987. Pitfalls and limitations in the use of
fishery valuation techniques. Trans. Am. Fish. Soc. 116:381-389.
Option, bequest and existence values are distinct but Gregory, R. 1987. Nonmonetary measures of nonmarket fishery resource
are all based on the deferment of direct and indirect benefits. Trans. Am. Fish. Soc. 116 (3):374-380.
uses for varying reasons (and thus values). 4odgson, Ci. and l. Dixon 1988. Measuring economic losses due to sediment
pollution: logging versus tourism and fisheries. Trop. Coast. Area
An argument has been made that, to a large extent, Manage. 3(1):5-8.
worldwide trends in resources overexploitation is an Hodgson, G. and J. Dixon. 1992. Sedimentation damage to marine
effect of flawed techniques for resources valuation. The resources: environmental and economic analysis, p. 421-446. In J.B.
Marsh (ed.) Resources and environment in Asia's marine sector. Taylor
imperfections stem from rigidities in traditional and Francis, Wishington.
valuation techniques to account for the following Hufschmidt, M. and E. Hyman, Editors. 1982. Economic approaches to
features: market failures caused by externalities and natural resource and environmental quality analysis. Tycooly Press,
Dublin.
public goods; nonmarket goods and services; inter- and Hundloe, T. 1989. Measuring the value of the great barrier reef. Australian
intra-generational equity; and discounting to name a Parks and Recreation 3: 11- 15.
few. However, the strong linkages fostered between the Hyman, E.L. and B. Stiftel. 1988. Combining facts and value in
environmental impact assessment. Westview Press, London.
fields of economics, the biological sciences, and public Keeney, R. 1977. A utility function for examining policy affecting the
policy have led to the development of techniques as salmon in the Skeena River. J. Fish. Res. Board Can. 34:49-63.
discussed. The work that has led to these techniques Krutilla, J.V. 1967. Conservation reconsidered. Am. Econ. Rev. 57:777-
786.
implies a new consciousness. The next step is using Lazo, J.K., W.D. Schulze, G.H. McClelland and J.K. Doyle. 1992. Can
these measures properly, and communicating the contingent valuation measure nonuse values? Am. J. Agric. Econ.
implications of the resulting studies to policymakers. 74:1126-1132.
Munasinghe, M. and E. Lutz. 1992. Environmental-economic valuation
of projects and policies for sustainable development. Environment
References Working Paper 42. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Panayotou, T. 1993. The environment in Southeast Asia: problems and
Aylward, B. and E.B. Barbier. 1992. Valuing environmental functions in policies. Environ. Sci. Technol. 27:2270-2274.
developing countries. Biodivers. Conserv. 1:34-50. Pearce, D. and D. Moran. 1994. The economic value of biodiversity. IUCN,
Barbier, E.B. 1989. The economic value of ecosystems: 1 - tropical The World Conservation Union. Earthscan Publications, London.
wetlands, LEEC Gatekeeper Series No. GK89-02, IIEDNCL Londod Pearce, D.W., D. Markandya and E.B. Barbier. 1989. Blueprint for a green
Environmental Economic Centre, London. economy. Earthscan Publications, London.
Barton, D.N. 1994. Economic factors and valuation of tropical coastal Raffia, H. 1982. The art and science of negotiation. Harvard University
resources. SMR Report 14/94. Universitetet I Bergen Senter for Miljo- Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Og Ressursstudier, Norway. Randall, A. 1987. Total economic value as a basis for policy. Trans. Am.
Bell, F.W. 1989. Application of wetland valuation theory to Floridafisheries. Fish. Soc. 116:325-335.
Florida Sea Grant College and Department of Economics, Florida Ruitenbeek, H.J. 1992. Mangrove management: an economic analysis of
State University, Florida. 95 p. management options with a focus on Bintuni Bay, Irian Jaya.
Environmental Management Development in Indonesia Project
Bishop, R.C., K.J. Boyle and M.P. Welsh. 1987. Toward total economic
(EMDI). EMDI Environmental Reports No. 8.
valuation of Great Lakes fishery resources. Trans. Am. Fish. Soc.
Sawyer, D.A. 1992. Taka bone rate: management, development, and resource
116:339-345.
valuation of an Indonesian Atoll. Dalhousie University, Canada.
Buhyoff, G. and J. Wellman. 1980. The specification of a nonlinear
Master's thesis.
psychophysical function for usual landscape dimensions. J. Leisure
Schurnan, H. and M. Johnson. 1976. Attitudes and behavior. Ann. Rev. Sociol.
J Res.12:257-272.
2:161-207.
Chua, T.-E. and L. Fallon-Scura, Editors. 1992. Integrative framework
Scott, A. 1965. The valuation of game resources: some theoretical aspects.
and methods for coastal area management. ICLARM Conf. Proc.
Can. Fish. Rep. 4.
37, 169 p.
Spindler, J. 1975. The accuracy of consumer surveys in describing markets
Costanza, R., S.C. Farber and J. Maxwell. 1989. Valuation and management
for hypothetical goods. Rand Corporation, Santa Cruz, California.
of wetland ecosystems. Ecol. Econ. 1:335-361.
Spurgeon, J.P.G. 1992. The economic valuation of coral reefs. Mar. Pollut.
Dixon., J.A., R.A. Carpenter, L.A. Fallon, P.B. Sherman and S. Manopimoke.
Bull. 24:529-536.
1988. Economic analysis of the environmental impacts of
Ulvila, J. and W. Snyder. 1980. Negotiationson internationaltimber standards:
development projects. Earthscan Publications, London.
an application of multiattribute value theory. Operations Res. 28:81-
Edwards, W. 1977. How to use multiathibute utility measurement for social
96.
decision valuing. IEEE (Institute of Electrical and Electronics
Engineers) Transactions, Systems, Man and Cybernetics 7: 326-340. von Winterfeldt, D. and W. Edwards. 1986. Decision analysis and behavioral
Fischhoff, B. and L. Furby. 1988. Measuring values: aconceptual framework research. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
for interpreting transactions with special reference to contingent Walker, K., B. Rettig, and R. Hilbom. 1983. Analysis of multiple objectives
valuation of visibility. J. Risk and Uncertainty 1:147-184. in Oregon coho salmon policy. Can. J. Fish. Aquat. Sci. 40:580-587.
Folke, C. and T. Karberger, Editors. 1991. Linking the natural environment Weisbrod, B.A. 1964. Collective-consumptive services of individual-
and the economy: essays from the Eco-Eco Group. 2nd ed. Kluwer consumption goods. Q. J. Econ. 78:471-477.
Academic Publishers, Dordrecht. Whitehead, J.C. 1993. Total economic values for coastal and marine wildlife:
Garcia, S.M. and C. Newton. 1995. Current situation, trends and prospects specification, validity, and valuation issues. Mar. Res. Econ. 8: 119-
in world capture fisheries. Conference on Fisheries Management: 132.
Options for Mangrove Management surface water. These oceanographic characteristics are
in the Gulf of Guayaquil, Ecuador* seasonal in nature and dependent on the intensity and
permanence of the front. The coastal areas of Ecuador
likewise experience& El Niiio phenomenon, an event
FAB~OLA
BELL',ICURM-ECLAC Collaborative Project on
the Socioecononzic Valuation of Coastal Resources in generally occurring every 3-7 years, characterized by
Sout17west Latin America, Casilla 179-0, Santiago, Chile high water temperatures for periods ranging from 6 to
18 months, and heavy rains.
ANNABELLE CRUZ-TRINIDAD, International Centerfor Living According to the Koppen classification, Guayas
Aquatic Resources Management (ICLARM), MCPO Box has three climate types which distinguish the north from
2631, 0718 Makati City, Philippines the south: semi arid or steppe climate, with rainfall
lower than 250 mm annually; arid, with rainfall lower
BELL, F. and A. CRUZ-TRINIDAD. 1996. Options for mangrove than 500 mm from the months of January to April. In
management in the Gulf of Guayaquil, Ecuador, p. 17-3 1. In A. Cruz- the zone of the Guayas River, the climate is tropical
Trinidad (ed.) Valuation of tropical coastal resources: theory and humid and savannah.
application of linear programming. ICLARM Stud Rev. 25, 108 p.
Fishery
Weight (g) 23-35 18-21.5 15-18 A model was constructed which seeks to
none only in final stage throughout cycle
optimize Total Economic Value (TEV) derived
Supplementary
feeding oflifecycle Feeding ratio: 1.3-2 from the mangrove ecosystem in Guayas,
Ecuador. Optimum TEV is arrived at by
Fertilizers none Yes Yes
combining development strategies (see Fig. 3),
Breeding tanks none Yes Yes ranging from the extreme options of conservation
(40-45 days) or conversion, or an intermediate option, i.e.,
Water management seawater pumped aeration partial removal of mangrove and sustained
exploitation of the remainder.
Area (ha) > loo >1,000 Conservation does not yield any form of
% of use in Ecuador 35 55 10 goods but generates benefits via services and
functions (discussed in previous section).
Source. McPadden (1985); Espinoza (1989).
Sustainable exploitation involves the extraction
of forestry and fishery goods in a fashion that assures
future generations of the same quality of life (World
Commission on Environment and Development 1987).
This includes the indirect benefits associated with
mangroves such as the services and ecological functions
Cultured shrimp production reached 77,800 t in derived from them. Conversion involves a partial or
1988 with a value amounting to US$322 million. Total complete alteration of the geophysical attributes of the
production by both capture and culture amounts to resource. We consider only the conversion to shrimp
about US$416 millionlyear, which is about 4.2% of ponds because its prevalence in our project site has
GNP and 28.3% of primary production (FEDECAM elevated it to a management concern. Conversion results
1989). The export market, notably the United States, in a particular commodity, shrimps, and incurs costs
absorbs 92% of total production while the remaining associated with operati& shrimp farms and costs
is absorbed by the domestic market. attributed to loss of mangrove resource, scarcity costs
Production has declined in recent years. In 1989 and compensation costs.
and 1990, only 64,000 and 69,000 t of shrimp, The model consists of the objective function, the
respectively, were produced by the aquaculture sector; constraints and the technical coefficients. The mathema-
64% of total production is accounted for by the semi- tical formulation of these components are discussed and
intensive farms and the remainder is produced by summarized as a representative tableau (Fig. 4).
extensive farms. The objective function consists of decision variables
To date, the most critical factor that affects the which affect the maximization objective either positively
viability of shrimp culture as a whole, and the or negatively depending on the value and sign of the
hatcheries, in particular, is the availability of natural coefficient and on the magnitude of the decision variable.
larvae for stocking in grow-out ponds and for breeding The decision variables in our objective function are
in hatcheries. In 1988, for example, the aquaculture influenced by two broad development options, conversion
sector utilized a total of 9.10y larvae, 72% of which and sustainable exploitation, and their respective costs
was provided by the artisanal fishery. A record of and benefits.
operational shrimp farms in 1988 ranged from
61,000 ha to 123,000ha, respectively. In Guayas, where A general formulation is:
there are a total of 88,000 ha, roughly 48,000 ha or
53% is operational (Meltzoff and LiPuma 1986). MaxZ = C NBq+C NB,
23
1 1
Conservation Susta~nableexplo~tat~on
Conversion
I I I
I
,
Benetlts Beneflts Cost
r--l
I I I
l-'--l Sewlces
Sew~ces Environment Goods Ennronment Goods
4'7
Tourlsm Transport
4 FY
Forest Flshery Tour~sm Transpolt
cost of
exiractlon
cap~tal
and
Benetlts
I
Goods
Costs
I
Production cost
charcoal flsh
p~le shrmps and fry
operatlons
cost (shnmp) .
.
construct~on
operatlons
posts monuscs
tannm crustaceans
Fig. 3. Potential uses of mangroves and associated costs and benefits per category of usage.
where NB, is the net benefit associated with shrimp coefficients of the objective function and assume values
culture and NB, is the net benefit associated with pertaining to costs or prices.
sustainable development of the mangrove. The subindices represent:
1) a = land use, a = {C,M);
The mathematical formulation of the LP model C = area devoted to construction of shrimp
is: ponds; and
M = area devoted to conservation of
mangrove, sustainable exploitation.
2) b = use of resources, b = {G, S, F, FV);
G = resources used for the production of
goods;
S t U V W Y
S = resources used for the delivery of
services;
F = resources used for the maintenance of
ecological functions; and
The principal subindices define the variable
FV= resources devoted for future use,
according to the option of conservation or conversion
existence value, and other values not
to shrimp farms, the area or zone of exploitation, type
previously considered.
of use of the resource and ecosystem based on its source
3) c = productive sector; c = {F, P, A ) ;
of value, the productive sector, level of conversion,
F = forestry;
technology applied, resources used and final products.
P = fishery; and
The nomenclature adopted for decision variables
A = aquaculture.
has the form:
Note that the subindex c, for the aquaculture sector,
is not written; instead is assumed implicit in all
X . * *The t y p d var~ablesIn the model start w ~ t hthe letter X and refer to
abc'A jN klrnn quantltles (e g , hectarage, number of postlarvae, h e r s of tannln) Cases
where the var~ablebeglns w ~ t ha letter other than X represent sltuatlons
where such variable is a component of mother or apercentage of mother:
'abci~ ,Nklmn and CabciAjNHmn
refer to the these vanables take on a value between 0 and I
24
activities concerning shrimp farming, or where For the forestry sector, it was assumed thatAvicennia
subindex a=c. is the only species extracted from Area 1 and from Area
4) i = processing activity, i = ( 1,....s) 2, the red mangrove. The frnal products are firewood from
For the productive sector, the numbering of Avicennia trees 0, piles from red mangrove trees (P),
activities is based on the chronology: extraction, and tannin from red mangrove trees (T).
transport, processing and sales. In the fishery, the final products include molluscs,
5) A, = area where activity i occurs crabs, shrimp fry, adult shrimps and fish. These
The A,'s are the different zones of the mangrove products, as defined, assume no need for further
as outlined below. The delineations are based on processing. We assume a certain percentage loss for
different ecological functions. cleaning, for example, in the case of headless shrimps.
Zone A: open seas, with high saline concentration
Zone B: swamps and estuaries where salinity is Constraints
intermediate
Zone C: coastal fringes, frequently inundated, Constraints include resource constraints and others
dominant species is the red mangrove related to linear programming, including balance
Zone D: interior zone of the mangrove which is equations, convex equations and counters. The
inundated less frequently than Zone C, dominant constraints are formulated as equalities or inequalities
species are black mangrove and white mangrove in which the right-hand side (RHS) determines the limit.
Zone E: salt flats, rarely inundated and no existing The coefficients are referred to as input-output
vegetation coefficients or technical coefficients and represent the
Zone F: higherlsloping grounds, never inundated, amount of each resource required by each decision
generally used by agriculture variable.
level of conversion of mangrove The relevant resource constraints are:
area, k = { 1,..4} (see Table 4) 1) Land
level of technology (Table 5)
(EJ} , m = ( l,..4}, m is stocking
density
extensive culture system
semi-intensive culture system
natural resource1 final product for all types of land area j = (1,...4)
Conversion Zone
level (k) C D C&D
Table 5. Assumed levels of stocking density and effort for forestry and aquaculture corresponding to various
levels of technology.
Decision land area converted area converted quantlty of quantity of land forest area quantity of Fishing effort quantity of <=Aj
variables area to shrmp farms to shrimp farms shrimp shrimp area exploited trees felled per zone and fishery and <=LA
with references harvested sold per species forestry <=LF
to technology products <=Lp
sold <=PI
<=Pr
<=Ps
<=QF
<=QP
<=F
<=K,
<=Ks
Balance equations
Convex equations
Counters
t u v w y
the maximum biomass of species Z Z Z ~ X c s c l ~ j <=
~w m j, N~) + CPL
PLM(A
n, for type of conversion N,, Aj,l Nk=ll=l m=l n=l
given by level of technology 1and
effort level m CPL = capacity of hatcheries
PLM (A,, Nk) = availability of seeds from the wild
is the density of resource or as a function of area and level of
species n, per type of mangrove conversion
zone A,, given conversion level
N,, and level of technology 1and 5 ) Labor
effort level m
'' '
t u
*
k ~l ~mj ~n k l m n<=
X ~ ~ ~ l ~ j ~ R Y*
I
The coefficients of the objective function reflect
the contribution of a particular activity to the value of
the objective function (VOF). Thus, costs tend to
depress VOF while revenues increase it.
initial investment (infrastructure and The costs considered include those of land
other operating costs) for shrimp farms conversion (construction of shrimp tanks), shrimp
located in area A, operating under fry, and extraction and processing cost for forestry
system 1 and fishing. The prices refer to those of finished
amount of credit available for products which include shrimps f r o m the
investments in technology system 1. aquaculture sector (whole and headless); from the
forestry sector, firewood, posts and tannin; and from
Balance Equations, Counters and Convex Sets the fishery sector, molluscs, c r a b s , shrimp
postlarvae, adult shrimps and fish. Prices of finished
Balance equations were set up for successive products and that of production inputs are based on
activities in the production process. With these we are current market prices.
Construction costs range from US$100 to Table 6. Average costs and market prices of products derived from the
US$10,400.ha-I depending on the mangrove zone and mangrove of Guayas, Ecuador.
areal coverage. Development costs are higher in salt Exploitation/
flats and sloping grounds than in Zones A to D. For Commodities processing costs' Market price
example, conversion costs in Zone A for a 10,000 ha
Aquaculture US$.t-'
farm costs US$SOO.ha I as compared to 60,000 ha in whole n.a. 7,500
Zone E which costs US$9,150.ha-I. Costs are generally headless n.a. 6,700
Fishery US$.tP
higher for the same level of areal conversion in Zone E. clams 1,000 2,000
Construction costs of extensive farms is crabs 1,000 4,000
US$8,490+ha-'while that of semi-intensive farms is postlarvae 10,000 8,600
shrimps 5,000 6,700
US$32,460.ha1 which remains constant despite fish 5,000 2,500
different stocking regimes. An important determinant Forestry US$m '
of stocking is the cost of postlarvae (PL) and related firewood 5 50
posts 3 10
operational costs associated with feeding and air and tannin 5 150
water management. These costs range from
'For foresty products.
US$8.6.thousand-' PL (extensive, 10,000 ha) to Source: FPVM (1987); FEDECAM (1989).
US$16.9.thousand-' PL (extensive, 125,000 ha).
Harvesting cost is US$6OO.t-I and is uniform for all
types of operations and areal coverage. Total net benefits that would accrue to
Sustainable exploitation of the mangrove forest simultaneous conversion and exploitation of Guayas
involves costs of extraction and processing. Extraction mangroves amount to US$174.106.year-' . Of the total,
costs for Avicennia in Zone D with area of 10,000 ha US$106. 106is accounted for by sustainable exploitation
ranges from US$300.ha1 to 700.ha-' while for red of the mangrove: US$18-to6from the forestry sector,
mangrove in Zone C, same areal coverage, ranges from US$88.106 from the fishery, and US$68.10"rom the
US$225.ha-' to 525.ha-'. aquaculture sector, in which US$2.5.106 represents the
In the fishery, collection of clams and crabs occurs costs of transforming the mangrove.
In Zone C; that of shrimp fry in Zone B; and for adult The above estimates are based on the sustainable
shrimps and fish, in Zone A, or open seas. Collection exploitation of 119.5.1O3 ha of mangroves distributed
costs for these products as well as market prices of in Zones C (46%) and D (54%) and the conversion of
mangrove-derived commodities are shown in Table 6. 5.5.103ha preferably sited in Zone C because of the
lower costs (construction and opportunity costs)
TECHNICAL COEFFICIENTSAND RHS VALUES
incurred. Optimal area of shrimp farm is 49.1O3 ha with
areal distribution as follows: mangroves, 11%; salt flats,
In the case of a resource constraint, the technical 64%; and the remaining 25%, sloping grounds. The
coefficients represent the contribution of a particular distribution of shrimp farms according to mode of
resource, i.e., labor, to a particular decision variable operation is 37.103 ha for extensive farms, 84% of
included in the maximand. which are located in salt flats, and 13.103ha for semi-
Right hand side values define the limits of the intensive farms, all located in sloping grounds.
restrictions enumerated above or, in the case of resource Operations in mangrove areas are extensive. Though
constraints, the supply or availability of the resource. less in area, semi-intensive farms would provide
approximately 45 million t of shrimps (heads-on) or
Results and Discussion 64% of total production.
Comparing the parameter estimates with actual
Solutions to the Primal Problem values shows that mangrove conversion has clearly
gone beyond sustainable levels, i.e., by about 200%.
The solutions to the primal problem are provided in The estimates furthermore show the preference of siting
Table 7. These include the optimal value of the objective ponds in mangroves rather than in salt flats and sloping
function and the values of the decision variables. grounds which are both underutilized.
Table 7. Parameter estimates of the primal LP problem for three alternative uses of mangroves in Guayas, Ecuador
Option: Aquaculture
Extensive shrimp farms ha. lo3
Semi-intensive shrimp farms
Shrimp farms, mangrove area 1
Shrimp farms, mangrove area 2
Total area of shrimp farms, mangrove
Extensive shrimp farms, salt flats
Semi-intensive shrimp farms, salt flats
Total area of shrimp farms, salt flats
Semi-intensive shrimp farms, sloping ground
Total area of shrimp farms, sloping ground
Total extensive shrimp farms
Total semi-intensive shrimp farms
Total shrimp farms
Shrimp fry sourced from the wild PL.~O~
Shrimp fry sourced from labs
Total fry used
Production, extensive systems t.103
Production, semi-intensive systems
Total shrimp production (heads-on)
Sales of shrimp, heads-on
Sales of shrimp, headless
Total costs US$ 1O6.year'
Gross income
Net income
Option: sustainable exploitation
Mangrove area in Zone 1 ha.103
Mangrove area in Zone 2
Total mangrove area
Sector: forestry
Avicennia felled cu.m lo3
Rhizophora felled
Sale of firewood
Sale of posts
Sale of tannin 1.10'
Total costs US$ 1O3.year1
Gross income
Net income
Sector: fishery
Sale of molluscs t.103
Sale of crabs - bundles lo3
Sale of fry PL. I 03
Sale of shrimps, heads-on t.103
Sale of fish
Total costs US$ 10"yearl
Gross income
Net income
Net benefits, service and function
Total cost of conservation
Net income of conservation
Net benefit
Total net benefit
*Based on 66% of total figures for Ecuador given that Guayas accounts for same % mangrove.
'k*Only for capture PL.
Solutions to the Dual Problem interpretation as the rate of change in the VOF given a
corresponding change in resource availability has
The dual formulation of the linear programming immense economic implications: the dual values
problem resulted in the same level of net benefits, i.e., provide measures of opportunity costs for intermediate
value of the objective function (VOF). Its mathematical goods and services such as labor while in the case of
29
final goods, dual values represent the consumer's Table 8. Parameter estimates of the dual LP problem for the mangroves of
Guayas, Ecuador.
willingness to pay (Table 8).
In the case of land, the dual value is the value of Parameter Dual value Unit
foregone production if the land were used alternatively.
Thus, the VOF is estimated to increase by US$344 and Mangrove area, Zone 3
US$294 for every hectare converted into shrimp ponds Mangrove area, Zone 4
Shrimps farms, Zone 5
in Zones C and D, respectively. The ecological Avicennia
functions performed in Zone C resulted in a higher Rhizophora
shadow price than Zone D. Results show that each Firewood
Posts
additional hectare of shrimp farm in Zone E, salt flats, Tannin
would add an average of US$677 to total net benefits Molluscs
notwithstanding the fact that it has already reached Crab
Shrimp fry
suboptimum levels. This is due to the fact that more Shrimps
than 90% of shrimp production is derived from this Fish
Fry sourced from wild
zone. Fry destined for hatcheries
The dual values estimated for forestry and fishery Capital, extensive system
products approximate their market prices. The higher Capital, intensive system
shadow prices assigned to fishery products, especially
that of shrimp fry, emphasizes the role of the mangrove
2) changes in the supply of natural fry as a
in the sustenance of coastal marine resources. Another function of El Nifio occurrences;
possible justification is that forestry products can be
3) availability of capital for investment in the
sourced from nonmangrove forests including aquaculture sector. An increase in investment can be
dipterocarp and hardwood forests; thus, the lower interpreted as a technological breakthrough or infusion
shadow price. of foreign investment.
Fry obtained from the wild have a positive shadow In Scenarios 1 and 2, the area converted to shrimp
price but that obtained from the hatcheries have a zero farms in Zone C was assumed to increase with the
shadow price indicating that the resource is nonscarce, additional area being released from Zone F (higher
i.e., the demand is less than the installed capacity. grounds) and from the area originally intended for
Results further indicate that packaging and freezing sustainable management. In both cases, total net benefit
capacity of the aquaculture sector as well as sawmilling
is lower than the base situation. In the case of
capacity in forestry are in excess of demand, i.e.,
aquaculture, the decline in net income is greater in
shadow price is zero. Likewise, there is a surplus of
Scenario 2 due to the additional assumption of a drop
available labor in aquaculture, forestry and the artisanal
in the supply of natural fry. Net income from the forestry
fishery relative to the exploitable resource. Thus, sector dropped because of a decrease in exploitable
increasing labor supply will not result in any change in
area for red mangroves, and thus, firewood sales,
the optimal benefits provided by mangrove conversion
whereas sales of shrimp larvae and of adult shrimp
and/or sustainable exploitation. caused the slide in the fishery sector.
In Scenario 3, the increase in naturally supplied
Sensitivity Analysis fry compensates for the total loss of hatchery fry.
resulting in a net income higher than the base situation.
A sensitivity analysis was conducted to determine Net income from the fishery is likewise improved
the effect of altering vital parameters on the net benefit mainly through higher sales of shrimp larvae. However,
(Table 9). The base scenario represents the primal an increase in natural fry was not shown to impact on
problem while the additional seven scenarios the supply of adult shrimp and that of finfish, in general.
considered are based on the following: Scenarios 4 and 5 have a strong conservationist bias
1) relaxation of the restriction pertaining to the but nevertheless resulted in net incomes higher than the
location of fish farms, particularly, to assess the base situation. Scenarios 4 and 5 assume changes in the
feasibility of locating in other mangrove zones; siting of shrimp ponds in Zones E and F and with no
30
Table 9. Sensitivity analysis of primal problem parameter for five scenarios and effects on total net benefits.
Scenarios
Base 1 2 3 4 5
Aquaculture sector
Zone E conversion (ha1 03)
Zone F conversion (ha1 0')
Shrimp farms in salt flats (ha,103)
Shrimp farms in hilly grounds (halo3)
Natural fry (PL.1 09)
Hatchery fry (PL.109)
Shrimp production head-on (,lo3)
Net income (US$106.year1)
Sustainable exploitation
Forestry sector
Zone 3 conservation (halo3)
Zone 4 conservation (ha1 O")
Sales of firewood (m3.1O3)
Sales of posts (m3.1W)
Sales of tannin (m3.10')
Net income (US$1O6.year1)
Fishery sector
Sales of molluscs (t.10')
Sales of crabs (t. 10')
Sales of larvae (t. lo3)
Sales of shrimp, head-off (t.103)
Sales of fish (t. LO')
Net income (US$lO"yearl)
Net benefit (services, function) (US$lOh.year
Net benefit mangrove (US$lOh,year-')
Total net benefit ([email protected])
conversion in Zones C and D which are mangrove areas. detriment of the environment which is being viewed as
Scenario 4 resulted in a 22% increase in total net benefit, being "subservient to immediate individual economic
the increase being accounted for by increased production objectives ". Possession of shrimp farms is, furthermore,
of the aquaculture sector. Scenario 5 resulted in a 57% considered to be a status symbol, in the same way as
increase in total net benefit because of the additional possessing a hacienda. The financial sector complements
assumption of peak production of natural fry. Both this with its preference for short-term businesses (fast
scenarios also resulted in an increase in net income from payback period) with low start-up as well as operating
the fishery sector, from sales of larvae and shrimps, albeit costs (i.e., shrimp ponds).
to a greater extent for Scenario 5. This confirms the Preference for short-term gains, especially in relation
important ecological functions of mangroves and their to conservation, can be perceived as rational given the
complex linkages with the entire cycle of shrimp growth lack of information,uncertainty and risk involved in long-
and maturation, which also affects production both from term investments (including investing in the environment).
trawl fisheries and aquaculture (McPadden 1985; Pauly Furthermore, such behavior is not a distinguishing
and Ingles 1988). characteristic of shrimp farmers in Ecuador.When choices
between development and conservation have to be made,
Conclusion expressing the resulting options in numbers, preferably
in currency terms, permits the decisionmaker to assess
In Ecuador, the phenomena1 growth of shrimp short-term gains vis-a-vis ecological integrity which
mariculture has been observed by Meltzoff and LiPuma minimizes risk, uncertainty and absence of information.
(1 986) to be consistent with the nation's social character LP is one of several available techniques that
and financial environment. The authors point out a enables quantification of total benefits arising from
tendency for business to value short-term gains to the simultaneous use of resources. The LP exercise is useful
31
in three ways: 1) in developing the LP tableau, the FPVM (Fundacion Pedro Vicente Maldonado). 1987. Ecuador. Perfil de
resource system, its different components and their FPVMsus(Fundacion recursos costeros. PMRC. Guayaquil, Ecuador. 269 p.
Pedro Vicente Maldonado). 1989. Ecuador. Vision
interlinkages, is structured and quantified; 2) through global del desarrollo de la costa. PMRC. Guayaquil, Ecuador. 241 p.
the primal and dual solution, benchmarks for Holling, C.S., Editor. 1978. Adaptive environmental assessment and
decisionmakers are provided; and 3) through sensitivity Horna,management. Wiley Interscience, New York.
R. 1980. Relacion suelo mangle, p. 195-214. En Estudio Cientifico
analysis, alternative environmental and economic e Impacto Humano en el Ecosistema de Manglares. Memorias Del
scenarios are simulated. In this exercise, we proved Seminario Organizado Por Unesco, Con el Auspicio Del Gobierno
de Colombia (Cali, 27 de Noviembre a1 10 de Diciembre de 1978),
the compatibility between economics and ecology by
Oficina Regional de Ciencia y Tecnologia Para America Latina y el
showing that conservationist approaches to mangrove Caribe, Montevideo, Uruguay.
management would result in greater net benefits. More Horna, R. 1983. Diagnostic0 del ecosistema de Manglares Ecuador, p.
importantly, we have shown how the short-term gains 321-328. En Trabajos Presentados a la Conferencia Internacional
Sobre Recursos Marinos Del Pacifico, 16-20 Mayo 1983, Vina Del
of mangrove conversion to shrimp ponds can be wiped Mar, Chile.
out by severe declines in larval production, its most J ~ e n z - ~ o l l a n dB., and M. Volland. 1992. Distribuci6n geogrifica y
critical input. This has been done given the interlinkages tkcnicas de la pesca en la Costa Ecuatoriana durante el period0
colonial [Geographic distribution and gears of the Ecuadorian
between ecological parameters specified in the objective fisheries during the colonial period], p. 92-113. In M. Aguero
function. (ed.) Contribuciones para el estudio de la pesca artesanal en
Our approach is a form of 'adaptive management' America Latina. ICLARM Conf. Proc. 35, 113 p.
McPadden, C.A. 1985. A brief review of the Ecuadorian shrimp fishery.
(Holling 1978), which emphasizes variability in time Tec. Inst. Nac. Pesca Ecuador 8(1):1-68.
and space boundaries as well as uncertainties. Thus, Meltzoff, S.K. and E. LiPuma. 1986. The social and political economy of
what others perceive to be rational appears to be a case coastal zone management: shrimp mariculture in Ecuador. Coastal
,/ Zone Manage. J. 14(4):349-380.
of misinformed decisionmaking. We have shown Pauly, D. and J. Ingles. 1988. The relationship between shrimp yields and
through this exercise how it is possible to depict an intertidal vegetation (mangrove) areas, p. 277-283. In A.
array of options that span long-term as well as short- Yaiiez-Arancibiaand D. Pauly (eds.) Proceedings of the IREPIOSLR
Workshop on the Recruitment of Coastal Demersal Communities,
term planning horizons and thus, make rational 21-25 April 1986, Campeche, Mexico. IOC (UNESCO)
decisions on the basis of perfect information. Supplementary Papers Workshop Rep. No. 44.
jPaw, J.N and T.-E Chua. 1991. An assessment of the ecological and
References economic impact of mangrove conversion in Southeast Asia, p. 201-
212.1nL.M. Chou, T.-E. Chua, H.W. Khoo, P.E. Lim, J.N. Paw,G.T.
Aguero. M. and E. GonzBlez. 1991. Una industria millonaria. Ecuador: el Silvestre, M.J. Valencia, A.T. White and P.K. Wong (eds.) Towards
hooni camaronero de AmCrica Latina, cultivo, divisas y empleo. [A an integrated management of tropical coastal resources. ICLARM
millionaire industry. Ecuador: Latin America shrimp farming boom, Conf. Proc. 22,455 p.
culture, foreign exchange and employment]. Aquanoticias Rollet, B. 1986. Ordenacion integrada de manglares. Sintesis de Siete
lnternacional 3(10):31-43. Seminaries Nacionales en America Latina. FO: MISC18614. FAO,
Aquacop. 1979. Penaeid reared brood stock: closing the cycle of P. Roma, Italia. 100 p.
morzodon, P. s/ylirostris and P: vannurnei. Proc. World Maricult. Soc. Snedaker, S.C. et al. 1988. Ubicacion de piscinas camaronem y altemativas
10:445-452. de manejo en ecosistemas de manglares en el Ecuador. Proyecto de
Cintrbn, G. and Y. Schaefer. 1983. Introduccion a la ecologia dei manglar. Manejo de Recursos Costeros. Serie de Estudios No. 2. Fundacion
Oficina Regional de Ciencia y Tecnologia de la UNESCO para Pedro Vicente Maldonado. Guayaquil, Ecuador. 86 p.
AmCrica Latina y el Caribe. Montevideo, Uruguay. Solorzano, C. 1989. La industria del camaron en Ecuador. Instituto
CLIRSEN. 1987. Estudio multitemporal de 10s manglares, camaroneras y Centroamericano de Administration de Empresas INCAE.
areas salinas de In costa ecuatoriana mediante informacion de sensores Terchunian, A,, V. Klemas and A. Segovia. 1986. Mangrove mapping in
remotos. Memoria Tecnica. Quito, Ecuador. 35 p. Ecuador: the impact of shrimp pond construction. Environ. Manage.
Cun. M. and C. Marin. 1982. Estudio de 10s desembarques del camaron lO(3): 345-350.
(gen. Penueus) en el Golfo de Guayaquil (1965-1979). Boletin Twilley, R. 1989. Impacts of shrimps mariculture practices on the
Cientifico y TCcnico S(3). Instituto Nacional de Pesca, Guayaquil, ecology of coastal ecosystems in Ecuador, p. 91-120. In Olsen
Ecuadoc et al. (ed.) A sustainable shrimp mariculture industry for Ecuador.
Espinoza, F. 1989. Situaci6n actual de la maricultura del camar6n en el Technical Report Series TR-E-6. International Resources
Ecuador y estrategias para su desarollo sostenido. Memorias del Management Project, USA.
Seminario y Documento TCcnico. lnstituto de Estrategias Velasco, A. 1987. Socioeconomic aspect of mangrove management, p. 67-
Agropecuarias. Doc. Tec. No. 2 1, 2 13 p. 73. In State of the art: mangrove research. Philippine Council for
FEDECAM. 1989. Serie: analisis sectorial. Doc. No. 10. La production Agriculture, Forestry, and Natural Resources Research and
camnronera en Ecuador. Octubre, 1989. Eduardo Egas Pena. Development, Los Bafios, Laguna, Philippines.
Optimization of Economic Benefits Description of Study Site
from Fishery and Forestry in Bio-Bio, Chile*
Physical Attributes
EDGARDO
ARANEDA',
ICLARM-ECLAC Collaborative
Project on the Socioeconomic Valuation of Coastal
LOCATION AND TOPOGRAPHY
Resources in Southwest Latin America, Casilla 179-0,
Santiago, Chile
Bio-Bio is one of Chile's thirteen political and
ANNABELLE CRUZ-TRINIDAD, International Centerfor Living administrative districts. This region covers a total area
Aquatic Resources Management (ICLARM), MCPO Box of 36,820 km2 and consists of 49 municipalities
2631, 0718 Makati City, Philippines including ~ u b l e Bio-Bio,
, Arauco, Talcahuano and
Concepcion, the capital. Also included are the islands
FRANCISCO
MORALES',
ICLARM-ECLAC Collaborative of Quiriquina, Mocha and Santa Maria (Fig. 1).
Project on the Socioeconomic Valuation of Coastal The major topographical features of the region
Resources in Southwest Latin America, Casilla 179-0, include:
Santiago, Chile 1) Andean mountain range: heights reach over
2,000 m, dotted with numerous volcanoes and the snow-
ANGELICA
ARE LLANO^, ICLARM-ECLAC Collaborative
capped Mt. ChillBn (3,122 m), Antuco (2,985 m) and
Project on the Socioeconomic Valuation of Coastal
Resources in Southwest Latin America, Casilla 179-0,
Callaqui (3,080 m);
Santiago, Chile 2) mountains situated between the intermediate
depression and the Andean mountain range;
ARANEDA, E., A. CRUZ-TRINIDAD, F. MORALES and A. ARELLANO. 3) an intermediate depression in the northern part
1996. Optimization of economic benefits from fishery and forestry of the region, approximately 100 km latitude from
in Bio-Bio, Chile, p. 32-62. In A. Cruz-T~inidad(ed.) Valuation of
tropical coastal resources: theory and applications of linear Chillfin and rolling plains south of the Bio-Bio River;
programming. ICLARM Stud. Rev. 25, 108 p. 4) a coastal range north of the region which
weakens to a series of ridges with intermediate
Abstract catchment areas; to the south of the Bio-Bio River, the
coastal range sharply increases to a height of 1,000 m
and acquires a wall-like feature, the Nahuelbuta Range;
The net economic value of fishery and forestry in Bio-Bio, Chile was
estimated with the environment as a third sector accounting for positive 5 ) rocky coast to the north of the Bio-Bio River
and negative externalities. with minor coastal plains; in contrast, south of the river
The main produce of the pelagic fishery is jack mackerel (Trachurus
niurphyi) and is caught mostly by small boats and barges while hake
is the smooth Arauco-Caiiete plain with an average
(Merluccius jiuyi) is targetted by purse seines. An average of 95% of fishery width of 25 km;
production is converted into fishmeal 50% of which is sold to foreign 6) continental shelf: contiguous and parallel to the
markets. From the forestry sector, the pine (Pinus r-udiuta) is transformed
into logs for sawmilling and pulp. coast extending 70 km towards the Tumbes peninsula
Optimum net economic value is estimated at US$1.37 billion.year~' and from Concepcion, decreasing to 40 km towards
87% of which is accounted for by the forestry sector. Exports of wood
chips from eucalyptus trees as well as logs and other wood products from
Arauco; and
pine contribute the bulk of earnings of this sector. The fishery sector 7) continental slope: the zone arising from the
contributed US$171 million mainly through the exports of fishmeal. continental trench up to the continental shelf.
However, water pollution caused by fishmeal plants diminished total
economic value by at least US$20 million.year-l.
The coastal zone includes the 49 municipalities in
Fig. 1, the coastal cordilleras, the littoral plains, the Bio-
Bio estuarine system and the coastal system of the
Arauco Gulf and the Bay of San Vicente. The Bio-Bio
estuary is a brackish interphase between the river
*ICLARM Contribution No. 1219.
'Present address: JosC Manuel Infante No 2802, Nuiioa, Santiago, system and the Arauco Gulf. Parallel to the Bio-Bio
Chile. estuarine system is the Bay of San VicenteIArauco Gulf
'Present address: Calk Edipo Rey 5751, Las Condes, Santiago, Chile.
'Present address: Stationary Sources Emissions Central Program
system, characterized by the influx of equatorial waters
(PROCEFF), Olivares 1229, 6 Piso, Santiago, Chile. during spring and summer.
33
CLIMATE AND OCEANIC CURRENTS
POPULATION CHARACTERISTICS
Fig. 1. The Chilean coastline and location of Region VIII, Bio-Bio (left), and the
coastal municipalities bordering Arauco Gulf and Bay of San Vicente (right). Region VIII is the second most
populated region of the country with estimates for
1990 at 1.7 million, about 13% of Chile's total
population. Densely populated cities include
Concepcion (48%), ~ u b l e(25%) and Bio-Bio
HYDROGRAPHY
(19%). Population density is 45 persons.km-' at the
regional level with variation between towns, i.e.,
Concepcion (231 p e r ~ o n s . k m - ~ and
) Bio-Bio (20
The region's hydrographic network is shaped by p e r s ~ n s . k m - ~Regional
). population growth is 1 . I %,
both the Andean range and river systems. The Andean
less than the national average of 1.6%. Almost 80%
rivers, namely, the Bio-Bio, ~ u b l eand
, Laja, originate
of the region's population live in urban areas.
from the internal areas of the Andean mountain range,
i.e, from the melting of snow which results in a larger
volume during the end of spring. The nonAndean rivers, INCOME AND EMPLOYMENT
include: artisanal and industrial fishing, industrial wood Fig. 3. The coastal area of Region VIII, Bio-Bio, Chile and the
plants (Cia. Chilena de Astillas in Schwager and various resource-dependent economic activitjes situated here.
ASTEX in Colcura), mines (Cia. Carbonifera in
Schwager and ENACAR in Puerto Lota), beaches in The marine species of commercial importance
Playa Blanca, Colcura, Chivilingo and Laraquete, and number about 125 (IFOP 1988), 64 of which are
sawmills and thermoelectric plants in Puerto Coronel. captured in Region VIII and which include fish (34),
Artisanal fishing communities and tourist beaches molluscs (12), crustaceans (9), algae (7) and
ar~escattered over the Arauco coastline in the towns of echinoderms (1) (see Annex 1 for a complete list). The
Arauco, Llico, Tubul and Punta Lavapie. The town of bulk of regional landings consists of fish species which
Arauco is the site of forest plantations and related include Trachurus murphyii (Chilean jack mackerel;
industries, i.e., Forestal Arauco, Forestal Carampangue local name, jurel), Sardinops sagax (South American
and Celulosa Arauco y Constitucion. pilchard; local name, sardina espaiiola),and Engraulis
ringens (Peruvian anchovy; local name, anchoveta).
Fisheries Fig. 4 depicts the historical trend in the total
landings of important pelagic species in the Talcahuano
Fishery resource distribution in Chile is heterogenous area. Note the sharp increase in jack mackerel landings
due to the wide range of environmental conditions that beginning in the 1970s against the drop in sardines and
determine productivity. The waters of Region VIII, anchoveta. Presently, the fisheries deemed fully
especially in the Gulf of Arauco, support the highest exploited include jack mackerel among the pelagics,
catches; the total landings of marine resources reached and hake and lobsters among the demersals.
3.2 million t in 1991 representing 53% of the national On average, 95% of the total fish catch are
landings. processed into fishmeal while the rest is processed
36
into canned and frozen fish; molluscs are mostly jack mackerel, the South American pilchard, and
canned while crustaceans are marketed in frozen Clupea bentincki Araucanian herring (local name,
form (Table 1). sardina comlin); these stocks are mainly exploited by
the purse seine fleet; 2) the demersal fishery which
TYPES OF FISHERIES includes the following species: Merluccius gayi hake
(merluza c o m h ) , Genypterus maculatus black cusk-
eel (congrio negro) and Dissostichus eleginoides
Four types of fisheries operate in the region: I) the
Patagonian toothfish (bacalao de profundidad); these
pelagic fishery for which the major species include the
stocks are mainly exploited by the trawler fleet; 3) the
crustaceans which are likewise exploited by the trawler
fleet with major species including the lobsters,
Pleuroncodes monodon red squat lobster (langostino
colorado) and Cervimunida johni yellow lobster
(langostino amarillo) and shrimps, Heterocarpus reedi
Chilean nylon shrimp (Camardn nailon); and 4 ) the
benthic fishery which is an artisanal one and which
exploits the molluscs Gari solida (culengue), Ensis
macha (huepo) and Tagelus dombeii (navajuela).
Fig. 5 shows the location and distribution of three
important pelagic species: the Peruvian anchovy;
Spanish sardines; and jack mackerel. The distribution
of mackerel extends from the Galhpagos Islands in
Ecuador to the Straits of Magallanes (IFOP 1988). It
extends lengthwise to around 1500 miles in the Chilean
coast and corresponds to a total area of 1 million square
miles (IFOP 1988). The depth distribution is to 300 m
in the south, but closer to the shore, where the upwelling
is more pronounced, the depth is between 20 and 60 m.
The distribution of the common sardine is from
Coquimbo up to Isla Mocha and possibly extending to
Chi106 to a depth of 50 m.
The fishery in Region VIII can be classified into
artisanal and industrial subsectors. Artisanal fishing is
Year defined by the General Law of Fishery and Aquaculture
as conducted within 5 miles from the coastline while
Fig. 4. Landings of major pelagic species in the Talcahuano area,
1963-1984,
the industrial fishery goes beyond this limit, extending
to the territorial seas and the EEZ. The industrial fishery
also includes the harvesting of fish and/or the
Table I . Utilization of catch in Region VIII, Chile, 1991, in tonnes.
processing of such into finished products.
Region VIII contributes, on the average, half of
Type of resource the catches of the artisanal and industrial sectors (Table
Product type Fish Molluscs Crustaceans Others 2). Anchoveta and jack mackerel are the most important
species caught by the artisanal and industrial fishery,
Fresh 1,027 19
Frozen 57,694 830 1,112 534
respectively. The high volume of fish landings in the
Saltedldried 3,582 65 artisanal sector, roughly 64% of national fish catch
Smoked 34 levels, and the proliferation of fishing communities
Canned 119,791 3,439
Fishmeal 3,010,812 along the coast, prove the enormous social and
Dehydrated 413 economic impact of fisheries in the region. During the
Total 3,192,940 4,288 1,112 1,012 explosive growth period of 1980-90, average landings
37
Table 2. National and regional landings of the artisanal and industrial fishery (in
Longitude i o W ) tonnes) by maior species, and production of the industrial fishery, by product type,
1989.
Artisanal Industrial
Fish
Peruvian anchovy 183,315 152,840 1,504,039 84,226
Araucanian herring 53,17 1 46,899 106,479 106,454
Chilean jack mackerel 16,879 10,235 2,372,982 1,751,486
Hake 10,909 3,276
Patagonian grenadier 2,744 2,676 207,209 207,157
South American pilchard - 1,564,674 28,437
Others 86,838 12,37 1 99,950 33,544
Molluscs
Snails
Cockle
Clam
Mussels
Others
Crustaceans
Shrimps 5,575 1,196
Crab 3,288 453
Conch 1,193 328
Prawns 573 573
Algae 178,480 24,036
Other species 28.887 1,110 4,541 1,769
Product type
Fishmeal
Species distribution Mojor fisheries
Oil
Canned
Frozen
Fig. 5. Distribution of anchoveta (A), sardines (B) and
Total 676,178 256,501 7,615,102 2,883,707
jack mackerel (C) along the Chilean coast, and location
of the main fisheries.
of the artisanal sector increased from 33 t to 151 t but crew cabins. The mode of propulsion may either be
this is nevertheless a minor percentage relative to the inboard motor, outboard motor or oar. Crew size is
growth in the industrial sector. usually 2 to 4 people. The gears often used include gill
Artisanal. Artisanal fishing communities are nets, trammel nets, longlines, compressed air diving
distributed along the coast of the Bay of San Vicente and traps.
but most especially along the Gulf of Arauco due to Barges are longer than 10 m, and generally have
the diversity of marine resources landed here. The crew cabins and wheelhouses, with an inboard motor
major fishing towns are Concepcion, San Vicente and and a crew of 4 to 10 people. Barges use mechanized
Coliumo, Gulf of Arauco, Santa Maria Island and equipment such as sonar and radar. The gears usually
between Lebu and Isla Mocha (Fig. 6). Boats usually used are longlines, gill nets and trammel nets. The fish
fish within 5 km from the coastline reaching a targetted by artisanal vessels are shown in Table 3.
maximum of 100 km depending on the kind of boat Barges account for 89% of the catches of large pelagics
and on the species targetted. and offshore demersals while the smaller boats (both
The artisanal fleet is comprised of two types of mechanized and nonmechanized) target coastal
fishing vessels: boats and barges. Boats are generally demersals such as hake and grouper. A characterization
made of wood with a length of 10 m or less and without of the artisanal capture fishery according to target
The communities of San Vicente and Lo Rojas have
the largest number of vessels, with barges and sail-
powered boats accounting for the largest share.
Medium-size vessels (boats with inboard and outboard
motors) are more prevalent in the communities of Tubul
and Laraquete.
Fish landed at the ports of San Vicente and Lota
are consumed fresh by the adjacent communities while
those landed at the port of Coronel are used as inputs
for fishmeal factories in the area. A small percentage
of the fishery catch is processed, i.e., smoked, dried/
salted or salted.
ZndustriaE. The industrial fishery consists of two
major components: capture fishery and processing. The
capture fishery is conducted in various fishing grounds
depending on the fleet and on the target species. On
the average, the trawler fleet reaches a distance of 20
to 25 km from the coast while the purse seine fleet
operates from Isla Mocha up to San Antonio and further
up to a distance of 130 km.
Target species include the hake, black cusk-eel and
Fig. 6. Location of the artisanal fishing communities in the Bay of
Patagonian toothfish. Jack mackerel landings of the
San Vicente and Gulf of Arauco area, Chile. industrial sector account for 94 to 96% of the total
volume of landings at the national level with the region
Table 3. Type and number of artisanal fishing crafts and target species contributing 38% to the total.
in the Bay of San Vicente, Concepcion, Chile. The industrial fishery uses fishing vessels of weight
Target species Barge Motor boat Sail boat greater than 50 GT and includes purse seiners and
trawlers. Gears used and operational regimes vary
Large pelagics and offshore
demersals (albacore.
according to targetted resources (Table 6).
deepsea cod, golden eel) 39 Industrial processing consists of the reduction of
fish into meal and/or oil, canned and frozen fish. In
Small pelagics (Spanish
sardine, common sardine, 1989, the country produced 1.8 million t of fish
anchovy. Chilean jack products, 77% of which was fishmeal. Region VIII
mackerel) 3
accounts for an average of 38% of total fishmeal
Medium pelagics (grunt. production (Table 2). Major species processed as
chub mackerel. bonito. fishmeal ~ncludeChilean jack mackerel, sardines and
eel. bream) 2 5 I
anchovies. These species are also canned in addition
Benthic invertebrates to molluscs.
(squids, snails, mussels, Most of the fishmeal factories are found in the
crabs) 17 8
landing centers of the industrial fleet including the ports
Coastal demersals (hake, of Talcahuano (27), San Vicente (6), Coronel (8) and
grouper) Tom6 (I), where most of the fishmeal factories are
Other co:lstal resources found (Table 7). Table 8 shows pertinent characteristics
(algae. red fish. silversides) 4 7 of fish processing activities in the region.
Fishing
Species Fishing vessel Engine Equipment Fishing gear distance
Type Useful HP Useful Type Useful Type Useful (miles)
Length life life life life
(meters) (years) (years) (years) (years)
5. Shellfish Sailboat -
<7 8-10 25-40 5
Table 5. Vessels used by the artisanal fishing fleet, per locality, 1990.
San Vicente
Lenga
Boca Sur
Maule
Lo Rojas
Pueblo H.
El Morro
La Conchilla
El Blanco
Lota
Colcura
Laraquete
Arauco
Tubu12
Llico
Punta Lavapie
-
'Twenty-one vessels land in Lo Rojas; the remaining vessels, in
Coronel.
?Also includes Las Pefias.
Table 6. Characteristics of the industrial capture fishery, by target species.
<I ,200
- 61-70 30 -
<2,800 Purse seine 2-5 16
Plantation species
Pine Pino California All regions
Eucalyptus Eucalypto Australia Coastal areas and
central plains
Native species
Rauli beech Ruuli Endemic Regions VII to X
Coigue Coihue Endemic Regions VI to XI;
very common; found
around lakes and
rivers
processing line. The simplest form of hauling is done operations, technology, products and yield. Sawmills
using oxen while the mechanized forms include forest can be classified as either mechanized, nonmechanized,
tractors and logging turrets. and/or temporary. Mechanized sawmills attain an
The regional contribution of the industrial forestry average production of 50,000 m3.year3 and utilize
sector is the most important in the country with sophisticated technology. Temporary sawmills use old
cellulose and paper production contributing 77% to machineries which are manually operated; average
national production; lumber, 55%; and fiberboard, 100%. annual production is 10,000 m3. In the intermediate
Industrial forestry can be divided into two are the traditional nonmechanized sawmills with
categories: I ) that which manufactures wood without average production ranging from 10,000 to 50,000
altering its structure (chips, pulpwood, logs, sawable m3.year-I.
wood, serrated wood, etc.); and 2) that which applies The yield of sawmills depend on a host of factors
chemical processes in the wood for the extraction of such as: the state of mechanization, i.e., (type of saws,
cellulose and its derivatives. Regional production for chipping machines, etc.); the system of felling; and the
both categories is shown in Table 11 and general state of raw material. Sawdust is a by-product of sawed
descriptions follow. timber and commands the lowest price in the market;
Sawmilling. The pine Pinus radiata is the main thus, the efficiency of sawmilling is gauged by the
species used in sawmilling. The sawmilling industry production of sawdust which should be kept at a
in Chile is highly heterogenous in terms of scale of minimum.
Boards and plywood industry. The particleboard
industry is formed by four factories, two of which are
located in Region VIII. Both belong to the Wood and
Table I I. Production of forest~ysector in Region VIII. Synthethic Enterprises S.A. (MASISA). These are:
Product 1989 (m'. LO3)
Wood and Panel Plant S.A. (MAPAL), in Concepcion,
and the MASISA plant in Chiguayante. MAPAL is
Category I known to be a very efficient producer, even on the
Wood pulp
Logs national level, with an average input of 2.45 m3/board
Wood chips ton. MASISA Chiguayante ranks next with average
Lumber input of 3.03 m3/board ton.
Sawdust
Others Only one fiberboard factory exists in the whole
country: Pressed Woods CHOLGUAN S.A., which is
Category 2
Cellulose
located in the Yungay commune. The products of
Newsprint CHOLGUAN factory fall under the distinctly hard
Others fiberboard classification, with a density of 1 t.m-3.
43
Table 12. Names and important characteristics of wood chip centers in Region VIII, Bio-Bio. Chile. The veneer and nonveneer
Annual
industry is composed of six enter-
production prises, of which one is found in
Establishment Technology (m3) Species Market Region VIII, the Agricultural and
Asseradero San Lorenzo Drum Pine Export
Forestal Society COLCURA in
Lota. The veneer industry utilizes,
Asetmdero Copihue Disc Pine Export except for the eucalyptus species
Astillas Exportaciones Disc Pine, eucalyptus Eucalyptus globulus, only
native species Export indigenous species. The installed
Native species
capacity of the COLCURA plant
Astillas J.C.E. Ltda. Blade
is 450,000 m3.year-' of veneer.
Bosques Arauco S.A. Disc Pine Domestic Wood chips. Nine firms
Cia. Astillas Concepcion Disc Eucalyptus and
produce wood chips in the region.
native species Export All factories use stationary
equipment but different technolo-
Cia. Chilena Astillas Disc Eucalyptus and
native species Export gies, level of production, species
used and market (Table 12).
Forestal Coronel S.A. Disc Native species Export
Cellulose and paper. The
Gonzalez Huepe Maria E. Blade Eucalyptus and industry consists of six enterprises
native species Export which operate seven plants in the
region. Table 13 lists these
enterprises, their annual production,
species used and final product.
Tourist Resources
Table 13. Paper and cellulose plants in Region VIII, Bio-Bio, Chile and selected characteristics. Region VIII offers a diverse
Annual
range of tourist attractions: urban
Species production Market Final centers, rivers, snow-capped
Firm used (t) orientation product mountains, hot springs, industrial
Celulosa Arauco y parks, beaches and ports, and sites
Constitucidn of historical and cultural impor-
Planta Arauco I Pino radiata 150,000-200,000 Export Kraft cellulose tance. The benefits produced by
Planta Arauco I1 Pino radiata > 300,000 Export Kraft cellulose
the tourism sector include foreign
Celulosa del PaciAco exchange generation, savings (via
Planta Mininco Pino radiata > 300,000 Export Kraft cellulose
"invisible export" of native
Compania Manufacturer products) and employment
de Papeles y Cartones generation, all of which contribute
Planta Laja Pino radiata > 300,000 Export Kraft cellulose,
Eucalipto printing paper, significantly t o regional and
packing paper national development. The tourism
Forestal e Industrial industry, however, contributes
Sta. Fe S.A.
Planta Nacimiento Eucalipto 200,000-250,000 Domestic and Kraft cellulose, minimally to regional income and
export white paper employment, the latter averaging
lndustrias Forestales
no more than 0.5%.This potential
Planta Nacimiento Pino radiata 100,000- 150,000 Export Mechanical pulp, is threatened by pollution from
newsprint industry, mainly from fishmeal
Papeles Bio-Bio S.A
Planta San Pedro Pino radiata 100,000-150,000 Domestic and plants and cellulose and paper
export factories.
44
The tourist attractions can be classified metropolis which is considered a historical, cultural,
geographically as: folkloric and gastronomic center and boasts of major
infrastructure including hotels and transportation
1) Andean zone facilities.
Table 14. Location and characteristics of beaches in the coastal zone of Region VIII.
-
Tom6 Slaughterhouse Cut meat None Water with blood, grease, excrements
Textile industry Spun cotton None Solids (fibers), maltose, glucose,
solvents, caustic soda, colorings,
auxiliary chemical substances.
Fishing indushy Flour, oil and Glue water Organic matter (Glue water,
frozen fish concentration oils, blood water)
Panco Porcelain factory Porcelain, sanitary - Clays, colorings, anilines
wares
El Morro Fishing industry Flour, frozen oil and Glue and blood Organic matter
canned fish and water concentration
shellfish.
Isla Rocuant Fishing industry Flour, canned None Organic matter
fish in oil
Lirquen Glass industry Glasses and crystals - Fine sand, china clay
Talcahuano Dockyards Heat, Calcium hydroxide,
Sodium hydroxide, Sodium carbonate,
Sulphuric acid, Hydrocarbons.
Mercantile ships, Spilled petroleum, oils, food residues.
petroleum retailers
fishers and launches
San Pedro Paper factory Organic matter (fibers, bark), talc,
china clay, aluminum sulfate, fungicides.
Laja Paper factory Cellulose fibers (organic matter),
Sodium lignite, chlorine lignine, Mercury.
Chiguallante Textile factory Sodium sulfide, hypochlorite sulfite,
sulfuric acid, formic acid, starch,
glucose, wax, pectins, alcohols, fixatives,
acetic acid, detergents, soaps, organic tints.
Brewery Beer Liquid presser and aquarelle tint,
yeast, starch, alcohol, chromium salts.
Table 16. Principal contaminants originating from liquid effluents dumped into the Bay of San Vicente.
Talcahuano Iron and steel Iron ingots, Sedimentation Iron sheet, ammonia, phenols.
mill laminated steel and neutralization ferrous salts, cyanid oils;
lubricants.
Petrochemical Polychloride Sedimentation Hydrochloric acid, chloride,
vinyl (Pvc), Neutralization salts, oils, lubricants,
chloride vinyl hydrocarbon chlorates
Dychlorotene
hydrochloric acid
polyethylene
Petrochemical Chlorine, caustic Sedimentation Chlorine compounds, mercury
soda and other Neutralization
by-products
San Vicente Fishing industry Flour, canned Glue water Organic matter
fish in oil concentration
Wood chips Chips Chips
Wire factory Wire Small iron sheets, sulphuric
acid, hydrochloric acid, soap
Cement factory Cement Heat, sediments
Mercantile ships Spilled petroleum, oils,
Petroleum retailers food residues
and launches
San Vicente Sewage and waste Detergents, soaps,
and Talcahuano disposal coliforms, excrements, grease
oils, food residues, urea
46
merchant vessels and oil tankers;
it also serves as a repository of Pumpingwater
the public waste system in the
+-
towns of Talcahuano and San
Vkente. In the Bay of Concepcion, Recovery Separation of Recovery of
pumping station blood water
are abattoirs and textile mills in I I
Tomi, fishmeal plants in Tom@,
El Morro and Isla Rocuant,
sawmills in Talcahuano, and a
paper factory in Laja.
The environmental problems
L--% Coagulation
Deodorized water 4f
Boca Sur
Maule
Lo Rojas
Pueblo Hundido
El Morro
La Conchilla
El Blanco
Lota
Colcura
Laraquete
Arauco
Las Peiias X
Tubul X
Llico X
Punta Lavapie
The basic structure consists of three elements: the We first elaborate the nomenclature to provide
objective function, the constraints, and the coefficients clarity in the design and to aid us in the identification
of the matrix. of the variables used.
The objective function is the maximization of net
benefits accruing from forestry and fishery. The tourism
sector was not considered in model formulation because Nomenclature
of its insignificant contribution to total revenues. The
constraints may theoretically include biological limits Objective function variables can either be cost or
such as biomass for fishery and maximum allowable revenue variables with the respective specifications:
cut for forestry or technological limits as in plant Cost: Xestgra
processing capacity. However, our model does not deal Revenue: Xemp
with real resource constraints but rather with balance Cost variables are further characterized as either a
and convexity equations which makes the interpretation financial cost, Xestgraf,
or as an environmental cost. The
of matrix coefficients quite different. This is discussed cost variable ranges are as follows:
in greater detail in the relevant section. A = activities or stages of production required
Lastly, the matrix coefficients are input-output to reach the final product stage (Fig. 10 and
ratios, i.e., the amount of resource i that is needed by section below);
process x. The valuation of environmental externalities R = resources;
and its incorporation in model-building is discussed G = gear or method used, which may be specific
separately. to the type of resource being exploited;
THE OBJECTIVE FUNCTION
Fishery Forestry
+
zone. Environmental externalities are also
considered as cost items in the objective function.
Processing The general form of the objective function is:
where
LIkl Sales
Fig. 10. Activity stages for fishery and forestry. Note that capture fishery
activities ranging from i to E; and
Ci = costs associated with economic
activities previously defined.
is equivalent to harvesting in the forestry sector; otherwise all other
activities are the same. The computational form is given as:
Warehouse Mackerel
Sardine
Spanish sardine
Container "Merluza de cola"
Warehouse Mackerel
Sardine
Spanish sardine
Anchoveta
Fishmeal "Merluza de cola"
Sackstwarehouse Mackerel
Sardine
Spanish sardine
~nchoveta
Bottles Fish oil
Transport Small Labor Human hauling Black crab
intensive Mackerel
Common hake
Animals Black crab
Mackerel
Common hake
Capital TrucWvan Mackerel
intensive Anchoveta
Sardine
Barges Black crab
Mackerel
Common hake
Albacore
Large Capital Refrigerated Black crab
intensive trucks Mackerel
Common hake
Albacore
Shrimp
Trucks Mackerel
Shellfish
Anchoveta
Sardine
Tankers Bulk 011
Ship Fishmeal sacks
Bulk meal
Cans
Frozen items
Table 19. Assumed sequence of production activities in the forestry sector, characterization,resources used and fmal products.
Harvesting costs
Resources y, y 2 y3 y 4 y5 Y6
Fresh
Frozen
Meal A
Meal B
Dried
Canned
Table 23. Assumed storage, transport and marketing costs (in US$.t-') per Yield (Y)
type of processed fish product.
Sustained
~ i e i
A
p f3 y
I B
Costs
Price
Species
Fresh Frozen Meal A Meal B Oil A Oil B Dried Canned
Eel
Hake
Jack mackerel
Mollusc
Spanish sardine
Anchovy
Toothfish
Swordfish
Grenadier
Shrimp
Algae
Common sardine 59 1 400 450 138 150 1,000
Market distribution
Domestic 0 5 45 62
Export 100% 95 55 38
Table 25. Plantation, culture and harvesting cost (in US$.ha-l) of pine at various stocking densities.
Table 26. Processing, transport and storage costs (in US$.m3) for wood products derived from pine and
corresponding market prices.
Price
Product type Processing Transport (pine) Storage International Domestic
Price
Product type Processing Transport (pine) Storage International Domestic
Table 28. Estimates of net benefit per sector from LP 5) Land availability
exercise.
Net benefit
Ap + Aa <= Total Area
Economic sector (US$.103.year-I)
The only real resource constraint used in the model
Fishery 171,358
is the availability of land for forest plantation. The area
Mackerel 120,177
Common hake 21,551 planted to pine and eucalyptus must be less than or
Others 29,630 equal to total plantation area.
Forestry 1,186,410
Pine
THE MATRIX COEFFICIENTS
Eucalyptus
or
( l/Qrai) * Qra <= 1 ' as measured by dissolved oxygen (DO) levels. Oxygen
is removed from the water as the organic matter in it
decays. According to IFOP (19881, liquid effluents of
coef (Qrai) * Qra <= 1 -8) fishmeal plants reach BDO7 levels equal to 0.57 kg.t-I
of fish processed. In order to maintain an acceptable
This equation indicates that each activity can be standard (BD07 10 mg.1-',as in Spain), it is necessary
taken as a segment of the total demand curve, thus, the to dilute the affected area by 57,000 1 for every tonne
restriction <= 1. of fish processed.
56
To implement this, a constant in the objective practices. Logs constitute a major use of pines and the
function was added, i.e., imputing the cost of freshwater, optimum level of export was estimated at 1,384 m3
here assumed to be US$l.t-l. The constraint row merely (Table 31). In addition to wood products and wood
summed up total fish processed and is similar in form to chips, eucalyptus is also used for veneer and firewood.
the balance equations enumerated above. Wood chips constitute the major export and is valued
at an average price of US$60.t-'. No pulpwood is
Results and Discussion extracted from both species.
The optimum net benefits are diminished by a total
of US$20 million considering the environmental
Results externalities attributed to pollutants from fishmeal
plants. This represents the cost of pumping in
The solution to the linear programming problem freshwater to improve the DO levels. The estimate of
is the estimate of total net benefit generated by fishery optimum net benefits should be lower due to a larger
and forestry. In the process, the solution identifies the number of externalities which could not be quantified.
optimum values of the variables which vary from one While real resource constraints were missing and
sector to another. In the fishery, the variable is the that many variables were exogenously determined, the
amount of fish "handled" at each activity level while emphasis of this application is the linkage between
in the forestry sector, the quantity of wood and/or wood different activities within each sector to arrive at an
products. The algorithm used in linear programming optimum quantity. Thus, the optimum quantity
essentially estimates dual values as well as right-hand harvested is not based on biomass constraints or effort
side and objective function coefficient ranges, but due constraints alone but also by demand conditions for
to the absence of real resource constraints the dual the final product.
values as well as the right-hand side ranges are not The relevance of coastal zone management and
analyzed. the "systems approach" espoused in Agiiero et al.
Total net benefit amounts to US$1.36 billion.year-', (this vol.) is highlighted by the interconnectedness
87% of which is accounted for by forestry; the fishery of economic activities in the fishery and forestry:
contributes US$17 1 million (Table 29). The Chilean A succinct example is the determination of optimal
jack mackerel, which is sold at international and catch levels in the capture fishery which was shown
national markets as frozen, fishmeal and oil, contributed to be an indirect function of final market demand
70% of sectoral revenue while hake, marketed only as and constrained by prevailing capacities in the
frozen, ranked second (Table 30). The optimum annual transport, storage and processing sectors. Without
harvesting levels for jack mackerel and hake are 1.9 such framework, optimal catch levels would be
million t and 37,000 t, respectively. These levels are based, for example, on either MSY or MEY, which
contingent on several factors including final market are purely biological parameters. Even the latter,
demand, transport, processing and storage capacity, as which at best considers appropriate measures of
well as current levels of effort in the industrial capture opportunity costs of the factors of production,
fishery. thereby incorporating macroeconomic factors, is
The large-scale sector contributes a major portion relatively myopic and still quite limited to the
of catch for hake, jack mackerel, Spanish sardine, capture fishery sector.
anchoveta and Patagonian grenadier whereas the small- This framework has the potential of estimating the
scale sector dominates the capture of eels, molluscs, impact of factors outside the capture fishery sector on
bacalao, albacore and algae. itself, e.g.,changes in storage fees or in increased demand
In the forestry sector, the optimum areas planted for substitute products. Unfortunately, this particular
to pine and eucalyptus are 50,000 and 30,000 ha, application, though not of linear programming in general,
respectively. All areas planted to pine are based on a did not deal with real resource constraints. A useful
stocking density of 3,280 seedlings.ha-I. No planting sensitivity analysis would have emerged if hypothetical
is involved in the case of eucalyptus. cases of increased or decreased resource endowments
Total quantity of timber is based on the amount could be measured against potential economic benefits
harvested and/or thinned, as part of silvicultural and on the values of the variables.
Table 29. Optimum levels of production (in t. 103year') resulting from LP exercise, by product type, activity and major species.
-
Jack Spanish
Actlvitv Crabs Hake mackerel Molluscs sardine Anchovy Toothfish Swordfish Grenadier Shrimp Algae
Caprure 3.00 37.00 1,898.96 4.00 40.00 115.04 2.90 0.60 103.98 0.14 16.00
Large scale 0.90 35.52 1,898.96 39.60 78.20 0.00 102.94 0.14 0.00
Small scale 2.10 1.48 4.00 0.40 36.90 2.90 0.60 1.04 16.00
Processing
Fresh
Before processing 0.01 0.40 0.03 0.01 0.04
After processing 0.01 0.36 0.02 0.01 0.04
Frozen
Before processing 2.99 37.00 13.48 1.10 2.12 2.89 0.56 0.42 0.14
After processing 1.59 17.76 5.53 0.22 1.42 1.53 0.36 0.13 0.14
Fishmeal and oil
Before processing 1,773.43 37.85 114.62 103.56
Fishmeal A 620.70 13.25 40.12 36.25
Fishmeal B 1,152.12 24.60 74.51 67.32
After processing
Fishrneal A 136.55 3.05 8.83 7.25
Fish Oil A 27.93 0.60 1.81 1.63
Fishmeal B 253.60 5.66 16.39 13.46
Fish Oil B 69.16 1.48 4.47 4.04
Dried
Before processing 16.00
After processing 15.20
Canned
Before processing 108.62 2.89 0.03
After processing 42.36 0.58 0.01
Storage
Fiesh 0.01 0.36 0.02 0.04
Frozen 1.59 17.76 5.53 0.22 1.42 0.36 0.13 0.03
Fishmeal A 136.55 3.05 8.83 7.25
Fishmeal B 253.60 5.66 16.39 13.46
Dried 15.20
Canned fish 42.36 0.58 .- 0.01
Transport
Fresh 0.01 0.02 0.04
Frozen 1.59 17.76 5.53 1.42 0.36 0.13 0.03
Fishmeal A 136.55 3.05 8.83 7.25
Fishmeal B 253.60 5.66 16.39 13.46
Dried 15.20
Canned fish 42.36 0.01
Marketing
Fresh 0.01 0.36 0.02 0.04
Frozen 1.59 17.76 5.53 1.42 0.36 0.13 0.03
Fishrneal A 136.55 3.05 8.83 7.25
Fishmeal B 253.60 5.66 16.39 13.46
Dried 15.20 VI
Canned fish 42.36 0.01 4
continued
Table 29. continued
Jack Spanish
Activ~ty Crabs Hake mackerel Molluscs sardine Anchovy Toothfish Swordfish Grenadier Shrimp Algae
Sales
Fresh
International
Domestic
Frozen
International
Domestic
Fishmeal A
International
Domestic
Fishmeal B
International
Domestic
Fish oil A
International
Domestic
Fish oil B
International
Domestic
Dried
International
Domestic
Canned
International
Domestic
- - - -
-
Net benefit (US$.103) 1,600.8 21,550.81 120,176.84 5,065.87 2,286.37 5,207.66 7,459.51 2,299.04 4,658.38 21.39 1,030.73
Table 30. Optimum estimates (in m'.103) of LP exercise for forestry sector, by product type, activity and species.
Fish
Acha Kyhosus analogus
Agujilla Scomberesox saurus
Albacora Xiphias gladius
Anchoveta Engraulis ringens
Anguila Ophictus spp.
Apaiiado Hernilutjanus macrophthalmos
Atin uleta umurilla Thunnus albacares
Atun aleta largu Thunnus alalunga
Atlin de ojo grande Thunnus obesus
Ayunque Cynoscion analis
Azulejo Prionace glauca
Bacalao de profitndidad Dissostichus eleginoides
Baculuo o mero Polyprion spp.
Blanquillo Prolatilus jugularis
Bonito Sarda chiliensis
Brecu Acantholatris payi
Brcitula Salilota australis
Caballu Scomber japonicus
Cubinzu lsacia conceptionis
Cabrilla Sebastes oculatus
Cabrilla c o m h Paralabrax humeralis
Cuch~wretu Katsuwonus pelamis
Cuzcin Galeorhinus ziopterus
Chanchurro Helicolenus lengerichi
Cojinobu del norte Seriolella violaceu
Cojinobu moteada Seriolella porosa
Cojinobu clel Sur Seriolella cuerulea
Congr-io colorado Genypterus chilensis
Congrio dorado Genypterus blacodes
Congrio nepro Genypterus mculatus
Corvina Cilus montti
Doradu Coryphaena hippurus
Jurel Trachurus murphyi
Lenplrudo de ojos chicos Puralichthys microps
Lenpuudo de ojos prandes Hippoghsina macrops
Lisa Mugil spp.
Muchuelo Ethmidium muculatum
Morrujo Isurus gluucus
Merluza del sur Merluccius uustralis
Merluza de cola Macruronus mugellanic~~s
Merluzu de tres uletus Micromesistius austrulis
Merluza comun Merluccius p y i
Mulatu Graus nigra
Nunue Girellops nebulosus
Palometa Paronu signutu
Puntpunito Stromateus stellatus
Pejegallo Callorhinchus cullorhinchus
Pejeperro Pimelometopon maculatus
Pejerrutu Coelorhynchus spp.
Pejerrey de nzur Odonteshes spp.
Peje.rapo Sicyuses sanguineus
Pejeiorro Alopius vulpinus
Peto Acunthocybiurn solundri
Ruy Raja spp.
Reinetu Lepidotus austrulis
R(jbulo E/eginol~sn~uc/ovinus
Rolli7o Mu&ides chilensis
Ronurcho Sciaenu spp.
Sulnzdn del Puc@co Oncorhyncluis spp.
Salnzcin clel Atldntico Salmo salur
'"Indicates presence of species. continued ...
Annex I. continued
6 1. Sardinu Sardinops s a g a
62. Surdina comlin Clupea bentincki
63. Sargo Anisotremus scapularis
64. Sierru Thyrsites atun
65. Tdlo Mustelus mentu
66. Tomoyo Labrisomus philipii
67. Trucha urco iris Salmo gairdneri
68. Trucku cuf'i Salmo trutta
69. Truclzu de armyo Sulvelinus fontinalis
70. VidriokI Seriola mazatlanu
Molluscs
I. Almeju (tucu) Venus antiqua
2. Almeju Protothuca thuca
3. Culamur Loligo gahi
4. C ~ r u c o locate
l Thais chocoluta
5. Carcrcol trumul(.o Chorus giganteus
6. Carucol r e p l a Tegula utra
7. Clrochu Calyptraea rroch1forme.s
8. Cholgu Aulacomya ater
9. Chorito Mytilus chilensis
10. ChOrO ZU/>Uf(J ChOrO~Zytil~S chorus
I I. Culerzg~~e Gari solidu
12. Jibia Dosidicus tunicatu
13. Ltrpus Fissurella spp.
14. Loco Concholepas concholelm
15. Mnchm Mesodesmu donacium
16. Nuvuju de )tzar Solen gaudichaudi
17. Navuju de mar Ensis machu
18. N m ~ ~ j ~ ~ e l u Tugelus dombeii
19. O.rtio'ndel riorte Chlumys purpuratu
20. Ostirin clel sur Chlamys patagonica
21. Ostru Ostreu chilensis
22. Ostru del Puc~fico Cmssostrea gigas
23. Piyuihue Odontocymbiola magellanica
24. Pulpo Octopus vulgaris
Crustaceans
I . Camtr,dn de roca Rhynchocinetes typus
2. Cumurrin nuilon Heterocarpus reedi
3. Centolla Lithodes antarticus
4. CerztollBn Paralomis granulosa
5. Gamhu Haliporoides diomedeae
6. .Itriba Cancer edwurdsii
7. Juibo limtin Cuncer porteri
8. .Itriba mom Homaluspis plana
9. Juibu peludu Cancer setosus
10. Juiba reirza Cuncer coronatus
11. Krill Euphuusia superba
12. Lungo.stc~de Juun Ferndndez Jasus .fiwntalis
13. Ltuzgostcl de Isla cle Puscua Panulirus pascuensis
14. Lungo~finoumctrillo Cervimunida johni
15. Langostino colorado PkurOncOdeS monodon
16. Langostirzo de lox cunules Munida subrugosu
17. Picoroco Megabalanus psittacus
Algae
I. Gelidium rex
2. Gymnogongrus furcellatus
3. Lessonia nigrescens
continued.
Annex 1. continued
Echinoderms
Erizo Loxechinus albus
Hemichordate
Piure Pyura chilensis *
Annex 2. Principal native forest species of Chile and Region VIII (*)
continued.
*indicate presence of species.
Annex 2. continued
L ingoy en G u l f
Hundred
Islands
) Rosario
7,.
Fabian
I I
120 5
Longitude (OW)
Municipalities Grassland Mangrove1 Ricefield, Fishponds Beach Riverwash Freshwater Salt Total
nipa irrigated sand swamp beds
Alaminos
Anda
Bani
Bolinno
Sun1
Labmdor
Lingayen
Binmaley
San Fabian
Dagupan
Agoo
Aringay
Bauang
Caba
Rosario
San Fernando
Sto. Tomas
Total
Change Alaminos Anda Bani Bolinao Sual Labrador Lingayen Binmaley San Dagupan Agoo Aringay Bauang San Sto. Total
Fabian Fernando Tomas
Total 1,114.40 1,239.90 2,956.30 279.20 224.20 304.70 2,414.10 3,429.70 65.80 2,998.00 26.90 607.90 131.50 253.90 375.00 16,421.50
72
and built-up areas. Grasslands have been converted to i.e., milkfish ponds, shrimp ponds and maintenance of
rice paddies, especially in the municipalities of Anda and existing use. "Maintenance" use includes both
Sual, and into shrublands and secondary forests. Table 5 productive and nonproductive use of land.
also indicates that suitable areas for aquaculture Productive and salinized ricelands can be converted
conversion are minimal: some 7.5 ha of riceland, 3 ha of to ponds at a development cost of Pl00,OOO.ha-I.
grassland in San Fabian and 13.4 ha of shrubland in Conversion costs of grasslands is P200,OOO ha-', twice
Bolinao. the cost of ricelands due to the absence of paddy
Substantial mangrove and nipa swamps including structures. Mangrove conversion cost is estimated at
ricelands were converted to aquaculture farms with P500,OOO.ha-' (A. Cargamento, pers. comm.) and
mangrove conversion having begun during the 1950s includes the construction of dikes and the clearing of
(Dannhaeuser 1986; Paw and Palma 1991). Present forests. Operating costs for all types of ponds
aggregate area of brackishwater ponds is 14,589 ha with irrespective of initial land type is held constant at
about 1,566 ha located in La Union, the rest being P1OO,OOO.ha-' (Primavera 1993).
distributed among the municipalities of Binmaley, Average milkfish production is assumed to be
Dagupan, Bani, and Lingayen in Pangasinan. Paw et higher than the current average to reflect the thrust
al. (1 994) showed the conversion rate of different land towards semi-intensive pond operation. Minimum
use types to brackishwater ponds from 1986 to 1990 to production level for milkfish is 5,000 kgsha-'.year-' for
total 6,534 ha or an average of 1,300 ha.year-I. productive ricelands and grasslands but is assumed to
be higher, i.e., 7,500 kg.ha-'.year-'for salinized ricelands
Costs and Benefits of Altering Land Use as an effect of saltwater intrusion. The production level
for shrimp is based on estimates used by Primavera
(1993) for semi-intensive farms. As in the case of
Monetary milkfish, production levels for shrimps from salinized
farms are increased to 5,000 kg.ha-'.year1.Production
Table 6 lists four types of land use types and levels for both shrimps and milkfish are considerably
corresponding parameters reflecting alternative uses, increased in the case of conversion from mangroves
Table 6 Cost and revenue parameters of different land use types in Lingayen
due to its favorable physical and ecological
Gulf area. attributes.
Ricelands yield net revenues if maintained as
Alternative use
Existing land use Milkfish Shrimp No
such. Production for a two cropping period is
and parameters ponds ponds conversion 9,200 kg.year-' (C.R. de la Cruz, pers. comm.) and
operating cost is P1O,OOO.year-l. Operating cost
Productive licelands
Conversion cost (P.ha-I) includes cost of seeds, fertilizers, and labor and is
Operating cost (P,ha-'.year1) assumed similar for salinized ricelands. Average
Production (kg.year-')
Average net revenue'
production for the latter, however, was assumed to
Salinized ricelands be 7,000 kg.year-I due to the effect of saltwater
Conversion cost (P.ha~') intrusion.
Operating cost (P.ha-'.year1)
Production (kg.yearl)
Grasslands would yield no revenue if maintained
Average net revenue in their existing form because no directly
Grasslands marketable goods and services arise from their use.
Conversion cost (P.ha-I)
Operating cost (P.ha-'.year-') Society would, in fact, incur a cost equivalent to
Production (kg.yewl) their current assessed value.
Average net revenue The value of mangroves was based on PIDS
Mangroves
Conversion cost (P.ha-') (1994), which did valuation work for two mangrove
Operating cost (P.ha~'.year1) ecosystems, i.e., Pagbilao Bay in Quezon Province
Production (kg.year-')
Average net revenue
and Ulugan Bay in Palawan. The value used for
Lingayen Gulf was based on the former because of
'Based on farmgate price of P120.kg~'for shrimps, P75,kg-' for milkfish and similar areas, i.e., 350 ha for Pagbilao and 227 ha
P6.kg ' for rice.
'Based on assessed value and represents foregone earnings. for Lingayen as opposed to 1,800 ha for Ulugan
'Based on mangrove valuation in Pagbilao, Quezon. Bay, as well as status of exploitation. The value
73
was based on summation of direct (fish, invertebrates ricelands and grasslands also have a role in flood
and juveniles) and indirect goods (litterfall). prevention.
The conversion option results in average net Mangrove is a very critical resource found in the
revenue based on a 10-year cash flow where conversion coastal area. Aside from the directly marketable goods
costs are reflected only for the first year. Thus, net and services such as forest resources (charcoal,
revenue resulting from mangrove conversion are the firewood, tannin), wildlife, fisheries, forage and water
highest among all alternatives despite high conversion supply, mangroves have important ecological functions.
costs. Net revenue resulting from the conversion of Zamora (1989) points out that once a mangrove area is
grasslands is the lowest. The status quo results in net converted into a fishpond, it no longer functions as a
revenue for productive and salinized ricelands, albeit natural system and ceases to contribute to the
lower fur the latter. Net revenue accruing to mangroves productivity of the nearby nearshore ecosystem.
is minimal but positive because no costs are incurred, Furthermore, mangrove conversion results in the loss
while grasslands result in a net loss because no of all standing biomass as well as the total disruption
marketable goods and services result from its nonuse. of soil, preventing natural regeneration.
A straightforward comparison of the net revenue Adverse effects of mangrove conversion include
resulting from three land use options shows that, based decreases in catches of mature and juvenile fish and
on economic efficiency objectives and in the absence shrimp (Martosubroto and Naamin 1977; Camacho and
of fixed (e.g., land availability) as well as exogenous Bagarinao 1986). The loss of nursery grounds and
limits (conversion limits), all mangroves would be eventual scarcity of shrimp fry also affect aquaculture
converted to ponds and none of the existing land types operations as documented in Bell and Cruz-Trinidad
would be retained. The LP exercise allows us to (this vol.).
determine the optimal land use mix without compromising
these limits. Linear Programming Application
Objective Function
Environmental
The objective function is the maximization of net
Use of the TEV approach necessitates the identifi- revenue arising from the use of four types of land for
cation of use and nonuse values of land types as three possible options. Net revenue per option is
presented in Table 7. Ricelands and grasslands found dependent on two components: I ) area of land devoted
in the Lingayen Gulf area have two direct uses: for a particular purpose; and 2) net revenue resulting
agriculture and human settlements. Moreover, ricelands from the production of marketable products including
and grasslands play an important role of providing rice, shrimps, ponds. Component 2 is computed based
vegetative cover thus preventing soil erosion and on prices and estimated production levels.
decreasing the amount of sediments reaching the Gulf. The solution to the objective function includes
Granting that the Lingayen Gulf area is flood prone, optimal land use mix and the resulting level of total
Table 7. Use and nonuse values of land types in coastal areas of Lingayen Gulf, Philippines.
Nr..'I = TR,, - CC..'1 - OC, Using a direct cost and revenues approach, the areal
where distribution for different land types across three land
Tr.. = Total revenue, product of price, P, and use options is summarized in Table 8. Productive
1'
quantity of production, Q,; ricelands are maintained but all salinized ricelands are
Cc, = Conversion cost of land type i into option converted to ponds. Milkfish ponds account for 63%
of the total area of salinized ricelands while the
j;
= Operating cost of land type i used for remaining amount is devoted to shrimp ponds. Due to
05, the limits imposed on area of shrimp and milkfish
option j;
where ponds, only 4,161 ha of grasslands resulted from
k = 1,...3 optimal conversion rates, while the remaining area
1 = rice; would be retained despite the low returns. This scenario
2 = milkfish; and supports the total conversion of the remaining 227 ha
3 = shrimp of mangroves to milkfish ponds. Potential benefits
resulting from this land use mix amount to P7.4
Constraints billion.yearl which is about 50% of the estimated Gross
Value Added in agriculture and forestry of PI 5.3 billion
1) Land use constraints in current prices (NSCB 1995).
The optimal distribution changes when the TEV
...3) approach is used. This approach involves the estimation
of Future Value (FV)* and the incorporation of
...4)
...5 ) foregone benefits. The latter is estimated by subtracting
...6) from potential net revenues the corresponding amount
foregone by maintaining the land in its existing form.
The above constraints are the existing area of the
four types of land which is the *An analog of the Present Value (PV) criterion, the use of FV ernphas~us
maximum allowable level of conversion. the importance of future rather than present benefits.
75
Table 8. Optimal land use allocation (ha) using adirect costs and revenues based on a 10-year planning scenario and a discount
approach (Case 1) and a Total Economic Value (TEV) approach (Case 2).
rate of 3%. The optimal land use mix resulting from
Case I Alternatives said approach is as follows: 1) productive ricelands are
maintained as such while more than 60% of salinized
Milkfish Shrimp Existing
ponds ponds use ricelands are better off being converted to milkfish
ponds; 2) of the total grasslands area, 10,000 ha are
Productive ricelands 0 0 36,428
Salinized ricelands 9,773 5,839 0
proposed for conversion to shrimp ponds; and 3) no
Grasslands 0 4,161 42,061 mangroves are to be converted to ponds. This optimal
Mangroves 227 0 0 land use mix results in a net benefit of P35 billion.
Net benefits 7.4.1Oy
Conclusion
Table 9. Estimation of net revenue based on aTotal Economic Value (TEV)
approach, in pesos.
- -- -
The LP was used to determine optimal land use
Land type Milkfish Shrimp Existing use based on two conflicting scenarios. The first uses a
Productive ricelands 219,800 324,800 317,500 direct cost and revenue approach and results in an
Salinized ricelands 422,500 460,000 47 1,250 optimal mix which maximizes net revenue but has an
Grasslands 255,000 360,000 307,500
Mangroves 600,000 570,000 6,120,394
inherent bias towards short-term gains. Thus, Case 1
results in a total conversion of mangroves. The second
76
Table 10. Sensitivity analysis of optimal land allocation applied to two
cases and resulting benefits: Case I , pond conversion cut by half; Case 2,
References
incrcasr: in milkfish production' (land use in ha, total benefit in pesos).
Agiiero, M. and A.V. Cruz. 1991. The economic impact of alternative
Local distribution investment and marketing decisions under varying conditions: a case
Land typc Milkfish Shrimp Existing use of fish culture in the Philippines, p. 26-276. In L.M. Chou, T.-E.
Chua, H.W. Khoo, P.E. Lim, J.N. Paw, G.T. Silvestre, M.J. Valencia,
Case I A.T. White and P.K. Wong (eds.) Towards an integrated management
Productive riceland 0 0 36,428 of tropical coastal resources. ICLARM Conf. Proc. 22, 455 p.
Salinized riceland 4,773 5.000 5,839
Alojado, Z.N., J.N. Paw and K.Q. Casuga. 1994. Identification for
Grassland 0 0 46,222
reforestation in Lingayen Gulf area, Philippines. GISCAMP Tech.
Mangroves 227 0 0
Rep. Part 11.
Total benefit 3.1.10'
BSWM (Bureau of Soils and Water Management). 1986. Physical land
resources of the province of La Union. Land Resources Evaluation
Casc 2
Productive riceland 0 0 36,428 Project. Bureau of Soils and Water Management, Department of
Salin~rcdriceland 0 9,773 5,839 Agriculture, Manila, Philippines.
G~~asslantl 10,000 0 36,222 Camacho, A S . and T. Bagarinao. 1986. Impact of fishpond development
Mangrove 0 227 0 on the mangrove ecosystem in the Philippines, p. 383-405. In
Total benefit 9.8.10" Mangroves of Asia and the Pacific: status and management. Tech.
Rep. UNDPIUNESCO Research and Training Pilot Programme on
lProductive riceland, salinized riceland and grassland to 10,000 kg.ha-'; Mangrove Ecosystems in Asia and the Pacific. Natural Resources
mangroves to 15.000 kg.ha '. Management Center, Philippines.
US$ I zP25.40 (July 1992 to June 1993) Cargamento, A.G. and N. Rillon. 1994. Impact of human settlement
development and expansion in the coastal area. GISCAMP Tech.
Rep. Part 11.
case is an adaptation of the TEV approach and
Cargamento, A.G., E. Cacanindin and K.Q. Casuga. 1994. Identification
~ncorporatesall possible sources of value. Case 2 and assessment of coastal tourism areas in Lingayen Gulf. GISCAMP
emphasizes the future earnings of a particular land use Tech. Rep. P a t 11.
and accounts for all foregone earnings as well. The Cruz, A.V. and G. Silvestre. 1988. Economic analysis of medium trawlers
in the Lingayen Gulf. Fish. Res. J. Phil. 13(1&2):1-14.
distribution of land use based on Case 2 shows a bias Dannhaeuser, N. 1986. Aquaculture and land reform: incongruous
towards maintaining land in its present state, especially conditions in the Philippines. Hum. Organ. 45(3):254-260.
for land with large foregone earnlngs as in the case of 'Ferrer, E.M., C. Aiionuevo, G. Castillo, R. Catelo, H. Chan, R. Rivera and
S. Rodriguez. 1988. Marketing studies of selected communities in
productive ricelands, or as in the case of mangroves, Lingayen Gulf. Terminal report submitted to the International Center
large ~ndirectand nonuse values. The resulting net for Living Aquatic Resources Management for the ASEANIUS
revenue is hlgher in Case 2 despite the fact that large Coastal Resources Management Project.
Fox, P. 1986. A manual of rapid appraisal techniques for Philippine coastal
earnings from shrimp and milkfish culture are foregone fisheries. Bureau of Fisheries and Aquatic Resources Research
in the short-run. Division, Manila.
The exercise results in recommendations that are only Martosubroto, P. and N. Naamin. 1977. Relationship between tidal forests
(mangroves) and commercial shrimp production in Indonesia. Mar.
as good as the values used. The value assigned to a j Res. Indones. 18231.86.
particular resource is dependent first on the knowledge McManus, L.T. and T.E. Chua, Editors. 1990. The coastal environmental
and appreciation of its natural function and next on the profile of Lingayen Gulf, Philippines. ICLARM Tech. Rep. 22,69 p.
'McMmus, L.T. and R A . Rivera. 1990 Population and socioeconomics.
valuation procedure used. The critical role of valuation is p. 38-43. In L.T. McManus and T.E. Chua (eds.) The coastal
emphasized in Aguero et al. (this vol.) as being the environmental profile of Lingayen Gulf, Philippines. ICLARM Tech.
essential inputs of the Linear Program (LP). More Rep. 22,69 p.
Mines, A.N. 1986. Assessment of the fisheries of Lingayen Gulf. Final
theoretical and applied work in natural resources valuation Report. Philippine Council for Agriculture and Resources Research
is obviously required in order to establish guidelines for and Development, and College of Fisheries, University of the
applicability, especially pertaining to issues of double- Philippines, Quezon City, Philippines. 55 p.
NSCB (National Statistical Coordination Board). 1995. 1995 Philippine
counting and appropriate use of discount rates. statistical yearbook. National Statistical Coordination Board, Manila,
Furthermore, a more effective interface between the 1 Philippines.
biological sciences and resource economics should be NEDA, Region I (National Economic Development Authority, Region 1,
Philippines). 1992. The Lingayen Gulf coastal area management plan.
fostered to determine the linkages of ecological functions
ICLARM Tech. Rep. 32.87 p.
to marketable goods and services. j
Pauly, D. 1990. On Malthusian overfishing. Naga, ICLARM Q 13(1):3-4.
The procedure used, however, has proven to be J ~ a w ,J . and A. Palma, Editors. 1991. Action plan for aquaculture
management. ASEAN/US Coastal Resources Management Project,
useful in policy setting in this fast-growth region where
Manila, Philippines.
excessive pressures on coastal land use may compro- Paw, J.N., F. Domingo, Z.N. Alojadoand J.C. Guiang. 1994. Land resource
mise sustalnability objectives. assessment for brackishwater aquaculture development in Lingayen
77
Gulf area, Philippines. GlSCAMP Tech. Rep. Part 11. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations,
PIDS (Philippine Institute for Development Studies). 1994. Philippine Bangkok.
mangrove resource valuation project. Accomplishment Report, Silvestre, G.T. 1986. Assessment of the multispecies demersal stock of the
September 1994. PIDS, Makati City, Philippines. Samar Sea, Philippines. Dept. Mar. Fish. Tech. Rep. 7,65 p. University
Primavera, J.H.1993. A critical review of shrimp pond culture in the of the Philippines in the Visayas, Iloilo, Philippines.
Philippines. Rev. Fish. Sci. l(2): 15 1-201. &vestre, G.T. and A.L. Palma. 1990. Economic sector, p. 15-31. In L.T.
Signey, L.O. 1987. Consequences of excessive fishing effort in McManus and T.E. Chua (eds.) The coastal environmental profile of
Lingayen Gulf. Philippines, p. 208-217. In IPFC Symposium on Lingayen Gulf, Philippines. ICLARM Tech. Rep. 22.69 p.
the Exploitation and Management of Marine Fishery Resources Zamora, P.M. 1989. Philippine mangroves: their depletion, conversion and
in Southeast Asia, 16-19 February 1987, Darwin, Australia. decreasing productivity. Wallaceana 58: 1-5
RAPA Rep.: 1987/10. Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific,
Optimal Fleet Configuration in San Miguel followed (e.g., Warfel and Manacop 1950; Legasto et
Bay, Philippines: A Simple Linear al. 1975; Simpson 1978) which were wholly or partly
Programming Approach* on the Bay's fisheries. Detailed assessment conducted
by the Institute of Fisheries Development and Research
(IFDR) of the University of the Philippines, College
ANNABELLE CRUZ-TRINIDAD A N D LEN R. GARCES,
of Fisheries and the International Center for Living
International Center for Living Aquatic Resources
Management (ICLARM), MCPO Box 2631, 0718 Makati Aquatic Resources Management (ICLARM) in the area
City, Philippines in 1979-81 summarized these works (Bailey l982a,
1982b; Pauly and Mines 1982; Smith and Mines 1982;
CRUZ-TRINIDAD, A . and L.R. GARCES. 1996. Optimal fleet Smith et al. 1983), presented a diagnosis of the status
configuration in San Miguel Bay, Philippines: a simple linear of the fisheries, which were characterized by
programming approach, p. 78-86. In A. Cruz-Trinidad (ed.)
Valuation of tropical coastal resources: theory and application of
overexploitation and distributional inequity, and
linear programming. ICLARM Stud. Rev. 25, 108 p. provided appropriate management options. The area
was revisited by ICLARM in 1992-93 via a Resource
Abstract and Ecological Assessment (REA) study under the
auspices of the Philippine Department of Agriculture's
(DA) Fisheries Sector Program (FSP). Data were
Three alternative scenarios were used to estimate fishery net
revenues in San Miguel Bay, Philippines, using a constrained collected in the San Miguel Bay area during July 1992
maximization approach. The constraints included total allowable catch, - June 1993 based on three data generation activities:
catch distribution and crew wages. The scenario which closely
approximated the existing effort levels in the fishery resulted in net
1) inventory of fishing gears, from January to June
revenues amounting to P6.3. IOh.yearlor US$248.103.year~'. A scenario 1993; 2) monitoring of commercial and municipal
which accommodated an increased number of fish corrals but diminished fisheries, from July 1992 to June 1993; and 3)
"baby" trawlers by almost 3070, resulted in a net revenue increase to
P19.4. 10"year~'.The latter scenario's bias towards small-scale gears monitoring of fishing operations from July 1992 to June
resulted in the highest level of net revenues, thus maintaining a 1993 (Silvestre et al. 1995).
congruence between efficiency and equity objectives. Wages, which were Thus far, the REA study is the most comprehensive,
observed to be greater than prevailing opportunity costs, were deemed
unsustainable if catch constraints were to be met dealing with physical and biological oceanography,
fisheries stock assessment and threatened ecosystems.
The socioeconomic components included cost and
Introduction returns of different types of gears, fishing dynamics,
Table 1. Comparison of fishing effort and catch per gear type in San Miguel Bay from 1980-81 to 1992-93
Trawlers
Large 30 103~ 2,389 12.5" 35 125" 25 0.14
Medium 17 38 308 1.7
Small 72 9,29lC 48.6' 50 3,905 22
Mini 188 191 260 202 1,901 10.7
Other gears
Gill nets 1,345 156 4,854 25 2,670 171 7,550 42
Lift net 171 53 624 3 60 115 1,021 6
Filter net 60 225 295 1.5 260 240 967 5
Scissor net 834 150 476 2.5 245 168 823 5
"Allothers
"Large and medium
Small or (baby) and mini
80
GILL NETS later; the process is repeated for harvest the following-
morning. Target species include sergestid and penaeid
The study identified 24 types of gill nets totalling shrimps and anchovies.
to 2,670 units. Gill nets are named according to mode
of operation ( e g , drift gill net, bottom set gill net) or Catch and Species Composition
target species (e.g., shrimp gill net, lait; crab gill net,
pangasag) but the most common is the ordinary gill Total landings were estimated to be about 17,750 t
net, panke. Characteristics of gill nets in Table I from July 1992 to June 1993 (Silvestre et al. 1995).
actually refer to an index based on panke units. About 35% were landed by trawls, 42% by gill nets
and the remaining 23% by the other gears.
PUSH NETS A total of 175 species distributed among 1 I 0 genera
and 70 families were observed to occur in the catch
Silvestre et al. (1995) described push nets or scissor (Cinco et al. 1995). Croakers (Sciaenidae), slipmouths
nets (hud-hud) as consisting of collapsible, triangularly- (Leiognathidae), penaeid shrimps (Penaeidae),
framed netting material mounted over two criss-crossed sergestid shrimps (Sergestidae), crabs (Portunidae) and
bamboo poles. Operations usually involve a single anchovies (Engraulidae) dominate the landings,
fisher pushing the gear along the bottom within wading collectively accounting for 58.5% of the total landings
depth but they have been recently observed to be during the period. A detailed breakdown of species
mounted in front of bancas powered by 10-16 hp composition per gear type is provided in Silvestre et
gasoline engines. al. (1995).
Stationary gears include fish corrals, lift nets and A comparison of key physical indicators by major
filter nets. The descriptions provided below are based gear types between the 1980-81 and 1992-93 studies is
on Silvestre et al. (1995). presented in Table 1. Except for the smallhaby trawlers,
Fish corrals, sagkad, are semi-permanent gears all gears increased in numbers. Moreover, there is also
used for guiding and trapping fish. The gear consists a marked increase in the frequency of trips per gear
of a guiding barrier, two to three playground areas, and tYPe.
a bunt or catching area. The bunt is usually set in the In addition to increased fishing effort are other
evening; harvesting using scoop nets occurs the parameters that point to a worsening of the status of
following morning. Operations involve two to three exploitation in the Bay including: excessive fishing
fishers who are transported by a nonmotorized banca. pressure, changes in species composition, and changing
Target species are pelagics but usually include small economic performance.
demersals and shrimps. EXCESSIVE FISHING PRESSURE
Lift nets, bukatot, are square-shaped nets attached
by pull ropes to four bases made of bamboo or coconut Excessive (fishing pressure continues to be an
trunks planted on the seabed. Lift nets are operated in overriding issue confronting the fisheries of San Miguel
waters of about 10-20 m depth usually near the mouth Bay despite the reallocation of effort (Silvestre et al.
of the Bay and were observed in the towns of Mercedes, 1995). A comparison of relative indices of total catch,
Siruma and Basud. They are only used during the dark aggregate trawl horsepower, number of fishers and
phases of the moon and have kerosene lamps to attract trawlable biomass shows that trawlable biomass has
fishes. Operations involve about four to five fishers declined by about 80% from its 1940 levels (Fig. 2).
who raise the net via the pullropes. Target fishes are The decline in catch rates is most abrupt for trawlers,
slipmouths and clupeids. i.e., 11,700 t in 1980 to about 6,100 t in 1992-93, in
Filter nets, biakus, are conical bags of netting set view of the strict enforcement of the 7 km, 7 fathom
against the tidal currents near the mouth of rivers. The ban, the decline in number of small trawl units, and
net is usually lowered at dusk and retrieved 4 hours reduced catch rates of mini trawls.
81
Trawable biomass
Number of municipal fisheries
Aggregate hp of trawlers
Total catch
- CHANGE IN ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
the catch of gillnets; this figure was down to 20% Tetraodontidae Relative increase Species replacement
in 1992-93 with other species such as shrimp, Apogonidae
manta rays, and hairtails occurring. Liftnets still Recruitment overfishing
Sphyraenidae Relative decrease
catch anchovies (dilis) but none of the minor Drepanidae
catches such as herrings, crevalles and squids are Synodontidae
known to presently occur in the catch; instead, Engraulidae Relative increase Technological
there has been replacement by other species Trichiuridae improvement (higher
including croakers, slipmouths and sergestid trawl opening and
Carangidae speed)
shrimps. Scombridae
Table 3a. Comparison of key economic indicators between 1980-gland 1992-93 San Miguel Bay studies.
Monthly
catch value Derived wage rates* Pure profit for all units
(Peso) ROIs Peso.day-' (thousand P)
Fixed gears
Fish corral 10,622 190.8 8,257 101.1 36.1 80.7 1,295 5,700
Filter net 2,669 35.2 2,301 190.2 53.0 60.7 308 1,793
Lift net 15,947 (1.8) 7,391 (1.7) 23.3 31.0 (3,074) (648)
Trawlers
Mini 15,236 83.6 8,357 78.4 92.0 93.4 6,115 4,397
Smallhaby 25,908 63.6 8,781 12.9 114.7 54.7 8,635 (30)
Large 0.2 66.2
Other gears
Gill nets 12,524 25.6 5,974 46.6 47.7 61.8 899 1,934
Push nets 148 14.8 247 145.8 (108) 764
"Unskilled crew.
Source: Padilla et al. (1995).
cost requirements had tilted in favor of gill nets with Pure profit, the economic benefit from fishing, net
initial outlay amounting to 5 1%, 60% and 70% that of of the opportunity costs of the factors of production,
lift nets, fish corrals and mini trawls, respectively. was taken to represent economic rent. Fish corrals,
Wage rates were derived by Padilla et al. (1995) filter nets and gill nets experienced a large
based on total payments to labor (cash and in-kind). improvement in pure profits while mini trawlers
Only master fishers of trawlers and the unskilled crew suffered a 28% decline. Baby trawlers, which had
of fish corrals and mini trawlers were observed to earn the largest level of pure profits in 1980-81 reflected
wages that are higher than the agricultural (nonplantation) losses in 1993.
rate. However, all fishers earned wages that were above Despite indications of overexploitation, total
the region's opportunity wage rate of P35.day-I pure profit for the San Miguel Bay fishery for 1992-
( US$l=P25.4 July 1992-June 1993). Table 3b shows 93 was positive and greater than 1980-81 levels. This
that wage rates increased between 1980-8 1 and 1992- can be explained by the evolution of the fleet into
93 for fixed gears and gillnets but declined by almost its present configuration thereby minimizing losses.
50% for baby trawls. Another hypothesis is the worsening quality of life
Table 3b. Comparison of key economic indicators between 1980-81and 1992-93 San Miguel Bay studies
n= TR-TC
8
n = cr c ( ~ , -o c , ) * x i }- {LC,* wI}l
i= 1
where the coefficients include: The present distribution of total catch should be
maintained with gill nets, stationary gears and trawlers
TR = total revenue; contributing 42%, 35% and 23%, respectively. This is
to ensure that in the search of maximum revenues,
TC = total costs; equity objectives are not compromised.
Number of units
Fish corral 123
Filter nets 260
Lift nets 60
Minl trawls 260
Baby trawls 50
Large trawls 1
Gill nets 1,554
Push nets 245
Net revenues (Peso) P6.3 million P8.4 million P19.4 million (PI4 million)
revenues given alternative fleet configuration and wage configurations would increase net revenues
structures. Scenario A is the closest approximation to substantially but would provide reason to eradicate the
the existing situation in San Miguel Bay minus the small-scale, mostly unprofitable, gears.
constraints. The exercise shows that had these This situation was resolved by incorporating catch
constraints been in force, the fishery would gain P6.3 distribution ratios as constraints. In this exercise, there
million per year or 6% of operating and labor costs. It seems to be a congruence between economic efficiency
seems rational to assume that existing net revenues are and equity objectives given that Scenario C, which has
larger given that no catch limits are in force; this is an inherent bias towards small gears resulted in a fishery
corroborated by the work of Padilla et al. (1995) who revenue that was also the highest. This observation
estimated positive pure profits amounting to P13 seems to augur well for future management initiatives
million. especially in effort reduction because this will tend to
Linear programming is another economic technique minimize potential conflicts.
that uses economic efficiency as its sole numeraire, Simulating alternative wage levels indicates the
i.e., equity considerations are not considered. In fact, increasing volatility of the labor market in the region.
in situations where catch distribution limits were not Current wage payments coupled with catch constraints
applied, the resulting fleet structure consisted solely resulted in a nonfeasible solution as in Scenario D, i.e.,
of large trawlers. Likewise, the institution of catch net revenues were negative. Clearly, wages cannot be
distribution limits as well as limits on the number of maintained by specific gear types if catch or effort limits
trawlers caused the phenomenal increase in the number were simultaneously enforced. Thus, resource
of fish corrals simply because it had, relative to the overexploitation can be viewed as an indirect result of
other stationary gears, the largest average profit. Both maintaining current wage rates because if labor were
86
paid rates higher than prevailing opportunity costs, then JPadilla, J.E., M.L. Ddusung and 0.8. Calica. 1995. Economics of capture
fisheries in San Miguel Bay. I n G. Silvestre, C. Luna, and J. Padilla
due to open access, more fugitive labor is attracted to (eds.) Multidisciplinary assessment of the fisheries in San Miguel
the fishery. The fishery resource would be subsidizing Bay, Philippines (1992-1993). ICLARM Tech. Rep. 47. CD-ROM.
labor that is being used inefficiently. Thus, it is often ICLARM, Manila.
' ~ a u l ~ ,D. and A.N. Mines, Editors. 1982. Small-scale fisheries of San
the case that in overexploited fisheries, e.g., Lingayen Miguel Bay, Philippines: biology and stock assessment. ICLARM
Gulf (Cruz and Silvestre 1988) and Philippine small Tech. Rep. 7, 124 p.
pelagics fishery (Trinidad et al. 1993), labor earns pure '~ilvestre, G., E. Cinco, R. Gatchalian and J. Diaz. 1995. Catch and effort
in the San Miguel Bay fisheries. I n G. Silvestre, C. Luna and J. Padilla
profit even if entrepreneurs sustain economic losses. (eds.) Multidisciplinary assessment of the fisheries in San Miguel
On the other hand, if access were limited by any of the Bay, Philippines (1992-93). ICLARM Tech. Rep. 47. CD-ROM.
ICLARM, Manila.
constraints incorporated in the linear program, current Simpson, A. 1978. Report of the BFARISCS workshop on the fishery
wage rates could not possibly be maintained. resources of the Pacific coast of the Philippines. South China Sea
This theoretical exercise provides a useful tool for Development and Coordination Programme, Manila. SCSlGENl78,
J . 48 P.
policy setting and while the estimates may never attain Smrth, I.R. and A.N. Mines, Editors. 1982. Small-scale fisheries of San
point accuracy, the method certainly contributes Miguel Bay, Philippines: economics of production and marketing.
appropriate benchmarks for decisionmaking. ICLARM Tech. Rep. 8, 143 p.
JSmith, I.R., D. Pauly and A.N. Mines. 1983. Small-scale fisheries of San
Miguel Bay, Philippines: options for management and research.
ICLARM Tech. Rep. 11,80 p.
Acknowledgements Aunderlin, W.D. 1 9 9 5 . Livelihood options for fishing families in San
Miguel Bay. I n G . Silvestre, C. Luna, and J. Padilla (eds.)
Multidisciplinary assessment of the fisheries in San Miguel Bay,
Many thanks to Ms. Madz Dalusung, Mr. Gerry T. Philippines (1992.1993). ICLARM Tech. Rep. 47. CD-ROM.
Silvestre, Dr. John McManus, Dr. Hal McArthur and ICLARM, Manila.
Dr. Madan Dey, who shared with us some of their views JSunderlin, W.D. 199%. Socioeconomic characteristics of communities and
fishing households bordering San Miguel Bay. In G. Silvestre, C.
and materials for this paper. Luna and J. Padilla (eds.) Multidisciplinary assessment of the fisheries
in San Miguel Bay, Philippines (1992-93). ICLARM Tech. Rep. 47.
CD-ROM. ICLARM, Manila.
References JSupanga, N.C. 1982. Costs and earnings of Cabusao pushnets, p. 61-63.
I n I.R. Smith and A.N. Mines (eds.) Small-scale fisheries of San
Miguel Bay, Philippines: economics of production and marketing.
J13ailey. C.. Editor, 1982a. Small-scale fisheries of S m Miguel Bay, ICLARM Tech. Rep. 8, I43 p.
Philippines: social aspects of production and marketing. ICLARM Supanga, N.C. and I.R. Smith. 1982. Costs and returns of Cabusao
Tech. Rep. 9, 57 p. stationary gears, p. 45-60. I n I.R. Smith and A.N. Mines (eds.) Small-
'Bailey, C.. Editor. 1982b Small-scale fisheries of S m Miguel Bay, scale fisheries of San Miguel Bay, Philippines: economics of
Philippines: occupational and geographic mobility. ICLARM Tech. production and marketing. ICLARM Tech. Rep. 8, 143 p.
'klCLARM Contribution No. 1221. This section lists the hardware and software
'International Center for Sustainable Ecological Development required to install OPUS. It describes the contents of
(ICSED), Casilla 27004. Santiago. Chile.
'United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the the diskettes including configuration parameters and
Caribbean (ECLAC). Casilla 179-D, Santiago, Chile. installation procedure.
88
System Requirements
OPUS can operate in two languages, English To select the number of variables of the model,
or Spanish. To select the language interface, less the slack and artificial variables, press <Enter> to
press <Fa> and then choose the language using replace new inputs or move with the arrow keys.
the arrow keys (see Fig. 4). Press <Enter>
once you have selected or < E s o if you want Data Entry/Edit
to keep the language selected before.
To terminate OPUS and exit to DOS, press The data entryledit routine allows the configuration
<F10>. To temporarily exit to the DOS of the tableau in a matrix form. The screen format used
environment, press <F9>. On a temporary exit for this purpose is shown in Fig. 6 and the main
to DOS, once you have finished working in components are as follows:
DOS, enter 'EXIT' from the DOS prompt to
1. Heading: On the first two lines of the screen,
return to the OPUS environment.
OPUS shows the file identification and the objective,
Parameter Setting i.e., minimize or maximize. The data that may be
enteredledited here are:
This routine allows you to: Data filename
select the kind of optimization that will be carried Kind of process (maximize or minimize)
out with the data; Number of constraints in the tableau
fix the control points to run the program; and Number of variables (without considering slack
define data ranges for calibration. and artificial variables)
The required data for this screen are as follows Active edition sector in the tableau (objective
(see Fig. 5): function, constraints coefficients and the right-hand side
To begin the maximization process, type MAX, of the constraints)
otherwise type MIN. Press <Enter> to go to the next Cursor position in the tableau
field, or move with the arrow keys. 2.Data tableau: OPUS uses its own coordinate
To select the number of restrictive equations system. It utilizes the columns identified through a
(rows) that your model will have, press <Enter> to go sequence of alphabetic characters that are located
to the next field and replace with new inputs or move immediately under the screen heading. The constraints
with the arrow keys. are enumerated at the left side of the tableau.
Fig. 5. Variable number entry screen.
OPUS gives default names for the objective The edit feature in the tableau is done by sector.
function variables (XI, X2, X3 ...etc.), however, these The first sector consists of the coefficients of
labels can be altered. To edit the names of these the objective function, which are edited on the first
variables, press <F5> (see Fig. 7). A window is row of the tableau, and is denominated as row "Fx".
displayed and you can enter the new names. If you have The second sector consists of the constraints
more than eighteen variables, you can use the <PgUp>, coefficients and are edited in the matrix located
<PgDn> keys to go forwards or backwards in the immediately under the objective function.
window. To exit this window, press <Ex>. The third sector consists of the right-hand side
OPUS gives default names for constraints (Y 1,
Y2, ... etc), which can be edited and changed by (RHS) values of each constraint, together with the
pressing <F6>. The screen used for this purpose has relation that conditions them (Rel), which are edited
the same format as the one shown in Fig. 7. in the columns located at the right side of the screen.
Fig. 7. Variable name entry screen.
To move within the tableau, use the <Tab> key To see the results of a previous execution (View),
and arrow keys. press <F4>. This operation displays the outputs of a
3. Functions menu: The functions menu provides process, if any.
alternatives and facilities to execute the process. 4. Multiplying data: To change the values of the
To save your data in the data directory, press objective function and/or the constraint's coefficients,
<F2>. While the data are being saved, a message and/or the right-hand side in a proportional way, i.e.,
appears at the right corner of the screen which indicates multiplying each group by a constant, press
this. <Alb+<M> and a window will be displayed for you
To execute the process, press <F3>. Processing to enter the options (see Fig. 9). If you enter an option,
time depends on the size of data and speed of computer. the program prompts for the ranges and for the
Hence, it is advisable to first save the data (see below) multiplicative factor. Press <F2> to proceed or < E s o
before pressing <F3> (see Fig. 8). to Exit.
the menu that will allow you to use one of print options Selecting the options : To select the results of the
(see Fig. 10): process, the following may be followed:
1.Print the variables and coefficients of the objective 1st. Set the cursor on top of the kind of result you
function. For that, you have to enter the range you want want to obtain.
to print, or use the range given by default if you want 2nd. Mark this result pressing <Space>
to print the objective function completely. 3rd. Repeat steps one and two to select the results
2. Print the constraint coefficients and, optionally, of interest.
print the objective function coefficients and the right To complete the selection procedure, press cF2>.
side of the tableau. Exit results menu: To exit the results selection
screen, press <Ex>.
To print part of the coefficients matrix, enter the
coordinates of the upper left corner and the lower right outputs
corner.
3. Print only the values of the right-hand side of OFUS can generate a set of reports from the final
the tableau and its relational operators. In case the results of the process. As an option, OPUS generates
printer is not enabled, an error message is displayed. a report with the partial results in each iteration that
Press <F2> to proceed or < E s o to Exit you specify.
95
Final results OPUS allows you to print results selectively. To
The report with the final results that you selected is do that, a special menu is displayed that is activated by
shown in a special screen which provides a set of options pressing the <F7> key. This function allows you to select
that, among other things, allows you to print selected from a menu (see Fig. 13), the kinds of results you want
results (Fig. 1I). and the variable range to print. menu.
To move from one place to another in the To activate the results printing process, press
results report (Fig. 12), use the <PgUp>, <PgDn>, <FS>.
To exit this screen and go back to the previous
and arrow keys. one, press <F10>, otherwise press <Ex>.
Acknowledgements Reference
J
Pauly, D. 1993. Data-rich books. HioSc~encc43(3): 167-I68
Tlic assistance of ICLARM programmers, Eli
Garnace and Felimon C. Gayanilo, Jr. as well as the
supervision from Daniel Pauly are acknowledged
gratefully.
97
Appendix 1. Documentation of LP tableaus. the pooling of information, to formal arrangement
within cartel organizations where sanctions are
In the tradition of data-rich books (Pauly 1993), imposed on defectors.
this appendix is written for users who may want to constrained maximization approach - the
test, verify and update the data used in the linear maximization of an objective function where the choice
programming tableaus (Araneda et al., this vol.; Bell variables are subject to some constraints.
and Cruz-Trinidad, this vol.; Cruz-Trinidad et al., this constraints - restrictions to which the objective
vol.; and Cruz-Trinidad and Garces, this vol.). function is subjected; usually a mathematical
The files used in these application papers are relationship between the choice variables of an
available in spreadsheet format. Files Bio.wbl and optimization problem, in which some function of the
Fabio.wb1, having been validated using LP88, are variable (e.g., a linear function) is not equal to a
available in L P format. Files Linga.wb1 and constant. An example is a budget constraint on the
Sanmig.wb1 have been validated using the LP routine maximization of utility.
of a commercial spreadsheet package. contingent valuation - a nonmarket valuation
All files can be accessed and processed in OPUS technique which tries to obtain information on
software or any other LP program that is available. consumers' preferences by posing direct questions
about willingness to pay. What is sought are personal
File Name File Size (KB) valuations of the respondent for increases or decreases
1. Fabio.wb1 31,200 in the quantity of some good, contingent upon a
2. Bio.wb1 115,652 hypothetical market.
3. Linga.wb1 6,736 datafiles - set of stored data, containing the inputs
4. Sanmigwbl 34,264 given by the users, grouped together under a unique
file name.
defensive expenditure - one approach in eliciting
Appendix 2. Glossary of technical terms. willingness to pay based on direct effects valued on
artificial market - a market that could be conventional markets. Individuals, firms, and
constructed for experimental purposes, to determine governments undertake a variety of "defensive
consumer willingness to pay for a good or service. For expenditures7' in order to avoid or reduce unwanted
example, a home water purifier kit might be marketed environmental effects. Environmental damages are
at various price levels or access to a game reserve might often difficult to assess, but information on defensive
be offered on the basis of different admission fees, expenditures may be available or can be obtained at
thereby facilitating the estimation of the value placed lesser cost than direct valuations of the environmental
by individuals on water purity or on the use of good in question. Such actual expenditures can then
recreational facility, respectively. be interpreted as a minimum valuation of benefits.
backup - security copy for effective recovery in dual - the minimization associated with each linear
the event of loss of service from some other resource. programming problem in standard form, i.e.,
balance equations - constraint equations used in mathematically,
the stepwise linearization process. given LP1: Max ctx
basic solution - augmented corner-point such that Ax I b
(infeasible) solution. x 20
bequest value - value that people derive from then the LP given by
knowing that others (perhaps their own offspring) will LP2: Min b'y
be able to benefit from the resource in the future (also such that Aty 2 c
heritage or preservation value). y > -0
coefficient - constant value for variables in the is called the dual of LPI and LP1 is called the
various equations and/or objective function. primal.
collusion - agreement between firms to cooperate elasticity - a measure of the percentage change in
to avoid mutually damaging rivalry which may involve one variable with respect to a percentage change in
informal or tacit agreement. arising.
u " . for instance., from
-- another variable. Measures of elasticity tend to be
98
carried out for very small changes in the variable enjoyment by anyone else.
causing the response (e.g., a percentage change in monopoly - in the strictest sense of the term, a
quantity due to a very small change in price). firm is a monopoly if it is the only supplier of a
existence value - the perceived value of an homogeneous product for which there are no
environmental asset unrelated either to current or substitutes and many buyers.
optional use; that is, simply because the resource exists. multiperiod linear programming - activities are
externality - externalities are variously known as repeated in a number of periods and constraints are
external effects, external economies and diseconomies, progressively modified over time so that the optimal
spillovers and neighborhood effects. Externalities exist solution within periods varies.
when the production or consumption of a good or nonlinear programming - in contrast to linear
service by one economic unit has a direct effort on the programming, this involves an optimization framework
welfare of producers or consumers from another unit. that can handle nonlinear objective functions as well
fziture value - the value in the future of an amount as nonlinear inequality constraints.
to be received or paid in the current period. This is nonuse value - value attributed to a resource for
determined by multiplying the present value of income its use by future generations (bequest value), its future
by the discount factor 1 t (1 + i)". direct and indirect use by present generations (option
game theory models - models using a theory of and quasi-option value), and its present utility because
individual rational decisions under conditions of less
of the knowledge of its existence (existence value).
than full information concerning the outcomes of those
objective function - a function relating the
decisions. The theory examines the interaction of
objective (the variable to be optimized) to the choice
individual decisions given certain assumptions
variable in an optimization problem.
concerning decisions made under risk, the general
option value - the value of a resource based on
environment, and the cooperative or uncooperative
how much individuals are willing to pay today for the
behavior of other individuals.
option of preserving the asset for future (personal)
indirect use value - value of an ecosystem in the
direct and indirect use.
provision of a number of biological life support
functions that are generally public goods (e.g., coral
perfect competition - a market structure is perfectly
reefs provide biological support in the form of nutrients competitive if the following conditions hold: 1) a large
and habitat for coral fisheries, and coastline protection number of buyers and sellers; 2) homogenous products;
functions). 3) availability of perfect information; and 4) free entry.
input-output models - models utilizing a method pivot element - coefficient located in the intersection
of analysis in which the economy is represented by a of the entering basic variable and the leaving basic
set of linear production functions, describing the variable.
interrelationships between all sectors. primal - (see dual).
linear programming - a technique for the property value - also referred to as a "hedonic
formalization and analysis of constrained optimization price" technique, the property value method is based
problems in which the objective function is a linear on the general land value approach. The objective is
function, and is to be maximized or minimized subject to determine the implicit prices of certain
to a number of linear inequality constraints. characteristics of properties. In the environmental area,
market failure - the inability of a system of private for instance, the aim of the method is to place a value
markets to provide certain goods at the most desirable or on the benefits of environmental quality improvements,
'optimal' levels. In general, market failures arise because or to estimate the costs of a deterioration (for example,
of 1) nonexcludability; andlor 2) nonrival consumption the effects of air pollution in certain areas).
of a good. Nonexcludability means that individuals who pure profit - a residual sum left over when we have
have not paid for a good cannot be prevented from subtracted from the revenue generated by some activity
enjoying its benefits. A good is nonrival if its all of the opportunity costs of production, the normal
consumption by one person does not preclude its profit required to keep the producer in business.
99
reduced cost/return - feasible range given to the another, till the optimal one is reached.
costlreturn variables in the optimization process. slack variables - variables that are introduced to
replacement cost - under this approach, the costs convert the functional inequality constraints into
that would have to be incurred in order to replace a equivalent equality constraints.
damaged asset are estimated. The estimate is not a swap - computational techniques that involve
measure of benefit of avoiding the damage in the first transferring data to another storage media while it is
place, since the damage costs may be higher or lower not being used to maximize RAM memory.
than the replacement cost. However, it is an appropriate tableau - a tabular form to record the essential
technique if there is some compelling reason as to why information in a linear programming problem, namely,
the damage should be restored, or certainty that this the coefficients of the variables, the constants on the
will occur. right-hand side of the equations, and the basic variables
right-hand side (RHS) - constant value located for each equation.
at the right-hand side of the equation (constraint). Total Economic Value (TEV) - sum of total use
sensitivity analysis - involves changing the value and nonuse values of the environment when
parameters of a decision problem and studying how viewed as an asset.
this affects the outcome. It is particularly associated travel cost - the travel cost method measures the
with cost-benefit analysis, where the most common benefits produced by recreation sites (parks, lakes,
form is the use of alternative discount rates. The forests, wilderness). A related method can also be used
purpose of the analysis is to identify the important to value "travel time" in projects dealing with fuelwood
assumptions upon which the analysis is based - those and water collection.
to which the outcome is sensitive. use value - associated with both direct extractive
shadow price - an imputed valuation of a uses (e.g., of fish, coral) and nonextractive direct uses
commodity or service which has no market price. (e.g., recreation) of the environment as an asset.
Shadow prices are used in cost-benefit analysis and in virtual disk - a store management system in which
the application of mathematical programming to a a user is able to use the storage resources of a computer
planned economy. They represent the opportunity cost without regard to constraints imposed by a limited main
of producing or consuming a commodity which is store, and the requirements of other applications which
generally not traded in the economy. Even in a market may be using the system.
economy certain outputs such as health, education, and wage difference - this method is based on the
environmental quality do not attract a market price. A theory that in a competitive market the demand for
set of shadow prices representing consumers' marginal labor equals the value of the marginal product and that
rates of substitution or producers' marginal rates of the supply of labor varies with working and living
transformation between such commodities may be conditions in an area. A higher wage is therefore
calculated reflecting the marginal costs of production necessary to attract workers to locate in polluted areas
or the marginal value of their use as inputs. To the or to undertake more risky occupations. Again, as in
extent that market prices do not reflect opportunity the case of property value, the wage differential can
costs, cost-benefit analysis may substitute shadow only be used if the labor market is very competitive.
prices. willingness to pay ( W T P ) - a measure of
shadow price vector - represents the (maximum) consumer's surplus, it is the amount a consumer is
change in value that the objective function can take if willing to pay over and above current consumption of
an additional unit of a constraining factor is available. a particular good or service.
simplex algorithm - a simplex is a sort of working directory - directory configured by the user
n-dimensional analog of a triangle, with corners that to save swap files, communication files between the data
represent extreme points, and the simplex method manager module and the solution algorithm module, and
provides a systematic procedure whereby we can move output files. The default working directory, if the user
from one extreme point of the feasible region to does not configure one, is the data directory.
Authormame Index
Agiiero, M. vi, viii, 1,4, 6-7, 9, 20, 31, 52, 56, 59, 68, 76, 83, Domingo, F. 64,68-69,72,74,76
86-87 Dourojeanni, A. v
Ahmed, M. viii, 4, 7 Dow, J.P., Jr. 4, 8
Alojado, Z. 1-2,64, 68-69,72,74,76,97 Doyle, J.K. 14, 16
Alterman, R. 5, 8 Edwards, W. 14.16
Aiionuevo, C. 65,76 Espinoza, F. 22, 31
Aquacop 2 1 , 31 Fabunan, A. viii
Araneda, E. viii, 1-2, 13, 32, 97 Fallon, L.A. 12, 16
Arellano, A. viii, 1-2, 13, 32, 97 Fallon-Scura, L. vi, 9, 16
ASEANIUS CRMP 7 Farber, S.C. 13, 16
Aylward, B. 10- 11, 16 FEDECAM 27,31
Bagarinao, T. 73, 76 Ferrer, E.M. 65, 76
Bailey, C. 78, 86 Fischhoff, B. 14, 16
Balsiger, J.W. 4, 8 Flores, X. 7.9
Barbier, E.B. 10-11, 14, 16 Folke, C. 13, 15
Barton, D.N. 14, 16 Fox, P. 68,76
Bell, F.W. vi, viii, 1-2, 6, 16-17, 56, 83.97 FPVM 27,31
Binudin, C. viii Furby, L. 14, 16
Bishop, R.C. 14, 16 Garces, L. 1, 3-4,78,97
Bower, B.T. 4. 8 Garcia, S.M. 9, 16
Boyle, K.J. 14, 16 Garnace, E. viii, 96
Brekke, K. 4. 8 Garrod, D.J. 4, 8
BSWM 69,76 Gatchalian, R. 78, 80-83, 86
Buhyoff, G. 14, 16 Gayanilo, F.C., Jr. viii, 96
Bunpapong, S. 7-8 Glass, R.J. 14, 16
Cacanindin, E. 64, 69, 76 Gonzalez, E. vi, viii, 1.6, 20, 31, 56, 76, 83
Calica, G.B. 83-86 Gregory, R. 11, 14, 16
Carnacho, AS. 73.76 Guiang, J.C. 64, 68-69, 72,74, 76
Cargarnento, A.G.C. 1-2, 64, 69, 72.76, 97 Haywood, K. 2
Carpenter, K.E. 78, 86 Hazel], B.R. 3, 8
Carpenter, R.A. 12, 16 Hilborn, B. 14, 16
Castillo, G. 65, 76 Hill, M. 5, 8
Casuga, K.Q. 64.69, 76 Hodgson, G. 13, 16
Catalan. A. viii Holling, C. 7-8,3 1
Catelo, R. 65. 76 Horna, R. 19-21.3 1
CEPAL 59 Hufschrnidt, M. 4, 8, 14, 16
Chan. H. 65-76 Hundloe, T. 11, 13, 16
Chou, L.M. 6-7, 3 1, 76 Hupert, D.D. 4, 8
Chua, T.-E. 1,6-9, 16, 18, 31, 64, 76-77 Hyrnan, E.I. 5, 8, 11, 13-14, 16
Cinco, E. 78, 80-83, 86 IFOP 36,59
Cintrh, G. 17, 31 Ignizio, J.P. 3, 8
CLIRSEN 17.3 1 Ingles, J. 30-31
COREMA 46.59 James, D.E. 4, 8
Corpuz. P.V. 86 Johnson, M. 14, 16
Costanza, R. 13, I6 Karberger, T. 13, 16
Cruz. A.V. 68. 76. 86 Keeney, R. 5,8, 14, 16
Cruz-Trinidad. A.V. vi. vii, viii, 1-4, 6, 9, 13, 17, 19, 3 1-32, 56, Kennedy, J.O.S. 4.8
64. 73. 76, 78, 83, 87, 97 Khoo, H.W. 31.76
Cun.M. 19.31 Klemas, V. 17, 21, 3 1
Dalusung. M.L. 8 1-86 Krutilla, J.V. 10, 16
Dannhaeuser. N. 72. 76 Laszlo, E. 2, 8
de la Cruz. C.R. 72 Lazo, J.K. 14, 16
del Mundo. C.M. 78, 86 Legasto, R.M. 78.86
Dey. M. 86 Lenz-Volland, B. 20. 3 1
Diaz. J.C. 78. 80-83, 86 Leontief, W.W. 4.8
Dixon, J.A. 2.4.7-8, 12-13, 16 Lim, P.E. 31.76
LiPuma, E. 21-22, 30-31 Sawyer, D.A. 13, 16
Luna, C. 86 Schaefer, Y. 17, 3 1
Lutz, E. 12, 16 Schulze, W.D. 14, 16
Manacop, P.R. 78, 86 Schuman, H. 14-15
Manopimoke, S. 12, 16 Scott, A. 14, 16
Marin, C. 19, 3 1 Scura, L.F. 1, 8 see ulso Fallon-Scura, L.
Markandya, D. 14, 16 Segovia, A. 17, 21, 3 1
Marsh, J.B. 16 Shepherd, J.G. 4, 8
Martosuboro, P. 7-8, 73, 76 Sherman, P.B. 12, 16
Matessich, R. 2, 8 Sia, Q.P. 111 80-8 1, 86
Maxwell, J. 13, 16 Siegel, R.A. 4, 8
McAlthur, H. 86 Signey, L.O. 68,77
McCnrl, B.A. 4, 8 Silvestre, G.T. 31, 68, 76-78, 80-83, 86
McClelland, G.H. 14, 16 Simpson, A. 78, 86
McManus, J. 86 Smith, I.R. 78, 81, 86
McManus, L.T. 7-8, 64-65, 76-77 Snedaker, S.C. 21, 3 1
McPadden. C.A. 22, 30-31 Snyder, W. 14, 16
Medina, M , viii Solorzano, C. 20, 3 1
Meister, A.D. 4, 8 Sorenson, J. 5, 8
Meltzoff, S.K. 21-22, 30-31 Spindler, J. 14, 16
Mines, A.N. 64, 76, 78, 86 Spreen, T.H. 4, 8
Morales, F. 1-2, 13, 32, 97 Spurgeon, J.P.G. 11, 16
Moran, D. 9, 16 Squires, D. 4, 8
Muellel., J.J. 4, 8 Stiftel, B. 5, 8, 11, 13, 16
Munasinghe, M. 12, 16 Sunderlin, W. viii, 79, 86
Muth, R.M. 14, 16 Supanga, N.C. 81, 86
Naamin. N. 73. 76 Terchunian, A. 17, 21, 3 1
NEDA 64.76 Torres. F.S.B., Jr. viii
Newton, C. 9, 16 Trinidad, A.C. 86 see ulso Cruz-Trinidad, A.
NOI-ton.R.D. 3, 8 Tsukayama, 1. 7, 59
NSCR 74. 76 Tulay, E. 8 1, 86
NSO 78. 86 Twilley, R. 18, 3 1
Pndilln, J.E. 4, 8, 81, 83-86 Ulvila, J. 14. 16
Palma, A. 68. 72, 76-77 Umali, A.F. 78. 86
Panayotou. T 9. I6 United States Fish and Wildlife Service 5, 8
Pauly, 11. vii, viii, 7. 30-31, 59. 68, 77-78, 86, 96-97 Valencia, M.J. 3 1, 76
Paw. J.N. 1 . 7-8, 18. 31, 64, 68-69, 72. 74. 76 Velasco. A. 18. 3 1
Per~rcc.i1.W. 9, 14, 16 Volland, M. 20, 3 1
I ' I ~ o . M.11 I , X Walker. K B. 14, 16
P!DS 72, 77 Wallace. S.W. 4. 8
I'omeroy. It, wii. 86 Warfel, H.E. 78. 86
PI-imnvera. J.H. 72, 77 Watkins, J.W. 4, 8
Raffia. 1-1. 5. 8. 14. 16 Weisbrod, B.A. 10, 16
I<c~ndnll,A. 5 , 8. 13, 16 Wellman, J. 14, 16
liettig. B. 14. 16 Welsh, M.P. 14, I6
Rillon. N. 64-65, 69. 76 White, A.T. 7-8, 86
Rivera. R.A. 65. 76 Whitehead, J.C. 14. 16
Robillinrd, G. 5. 8 Williams, M.J. viii. v
Rodr~gucz,S. 65, 76 Winterfeldt, D. von 14, 16
I<ollet, R . 19, 3 1 Wong, PK. 31.76
Rothschild. B.J. 4, 8 Yafiez-Arancibia. 4 . 3 1
Ruitenbcek. H.J. 13. 16 Yater. F. 8 1 . 86
Satlorra. M.S.M 6-8 Zamora, P.M. 73. 77
Geographic Index
crustacean(s) 2. 15. 19, 35-37 see also crah(s) hake 32, 35-38, 40, 52-54, 56-58 see ulso Merl;.~cru.sguyi; merluzc~
Cr~/~roc.trry rrlbri 63 comurz
Crrlrrr::~rc~36, 6 1 see also Gari sohdu common 49-50, 55
C~wosc~iori trritriis 60 Hr~iiporo~cle,~ iliornerleae 6 1
cyprinid 14 .see also Notropis c.hry~oceplzulc~s Helicolenus lenjierichi 60
Dir.syihyllrrni drcrc~ar1thoic1e.s62 Hemichordate 62
tlcmersals 80 Hen~ilutjanusnzucrop1zthalmo.s 60
rlr1i.r 8 1 .setJanchovies herring 81
~i.r.\wcrrc.Ir~r.s eleg~nordes 36 see buculao rle profundidad; Araucanian 36-37 see also Clupen bentincki; surdirzu t,onlu'rz
toothfish, Patagonian Heterocnrl~usreed 36, 61 see Camarcin nailon; shrimp, Chilean
Dr.s.ro.stic~1i1r.seleginoides 60 nylon
t)or.irt/o 60 hilsa 4
13r1srclic~~r.s tirnic~uru 61 Hippogloxsina mucrops 60
Drepanidae.8 1 Homalaspis planu 6 1
~ ! ~ . S62
~ I - I I ~~l.inreri Hualo 63
L)~rri.rliretrtrrrtrrrctica 62 huepo 36 see also Ensis macha
eagle. bald I I Huiro 62
Echinodems 35, 62 Iridaea ciliuta 62
ecl(s) 38. 53-54. 56 Isaciu conceptionis 60
hlnck cusk- 36. 38 .see also Genyptems muculatus 1.surcrs g1uuccr.s 60
Clc,girio/~.s11itrc1ovinu.s60 Jaibu 19, 6 1 see crab
clephnnt fishes.40 limcin 6 1
1lml~othr.i~rni coccineum 62 moru 61
E~lgraulidae 80-81 see anchovies peluda 61
Ilriwr111r.sriri,qerr.s 35, 60 see anchovy, Peruvian; anchoveta reina 61
lIrr\r.s mtrc,hu 36. 61 see huepo Jasus fkontu1i.s 6 1
Errx 62 Jeli prieto 19
E r p w 62 Jibia 6 1
Eth~nrdr~~rri r~icrculat~nn60 Jubuea chilensis 62
Ell( Ulrptfl 43 jurel 35,60 see mackerel, jack
Or~.trlypto 42 Kugeneckia oblongu 63
Kutsuwonus pelamis 60 embra 19
Krill 6 1 guaner 19
Kyhosus unulogus 60 a c k ~19
Lubrisomus philipii 61 ojo 19
hgunculuria 18-19 see mangrove salado 19
rucemosa 20 mangrove 20
spp. 17 black 17,24
h n g o s t u de Isla de Pascua 6 1 red 17, 20, 24, 27 see also Rhizophora spp.
Lungostu cle Juun Fernandez 6 1 white 20, 24
lungostino amurillo 36, 6 1 see also Cervimunida johni; lobster, Manio de Hojas Cortas 62
yellow Manio de Hojus Largas 62
Lungoxtino colomdo 36, 61 lobster, red squat; Pleuroncodes Manio de Hojas Punzantes 62
Marrujo 60
Mastocarpus papillatus 62
Lupus 6 1 Maytenus boaria 62
LuureI 63 Megabalanus psittucus 61
Laurehu l~hilippiuna 63 Meli 63
Merluccius australis 60
Merluccius guyi 32, 36,60 see hake
Leiognathidae 80-8 1 see slipmouths Merluza 39
Lengu 63 comlin 36, 49, 60 see hake; Merluccius gayi
Lenguaclo de q o s chicos 60 de cola 49-50, 60
Lenguado de ojos grundes 60 de tres aletas 60
del sur 60
Lessonia nigrescens 6 1 Mesodesma donacium 6 1
Lingue 62 Micromesistius australis 60
Liyuen prnoso 62 milkfish 3, 64, 68, 72, 74-76 see also Chanos chanos
Lisa 19, 60 see mullet Molle 63
Lithodes antarticus 6 1 mollusc(s) 15, 19, 24, 26, 29, 36-37.52-54, 56-58, 61, see al.~o
Lithrma crrc~stica 62 Anadara grandis; Anadara similis; Anadara
Litre 62 tuberculosa; Callinectes toxotes; Mytella guayanensis:
Lleciyue 62 Ostrea cohmbiensis
lobster(s) 20, 35-36 Mugil spp. 60
red squat 36 Pleuroncodes mOnOdOn; k~ngostinocohrado curema 19 see mullet
yellow 36 see also Cervimunida johni Mugiloides chilensis 60
Loco 6 1 Mulata 60
Loligo gahi 6 1 mullet 19 see also liza; Mugil curema
Lomafin hirsuta 63 Munida subrugosu 6 1
Loxec/nnu.~d/~ll.Y 62 mussel(s) 18, 37-38
Luche 62 Mustelus mentu 6 1
Myrceugeniu exsucca' 63
Mytella guayanensis 19 see molluscs
apiculatcr 63 Mytilus chilensis 61
Mucha 6 1 Nanue 60
Muc/zue/r~60 Naranjillo 62
mackerel 40, 55, 49-50 Navaja de mar 6 1
Chilean jack 35, 37-38 see also Trachurus murphyi Navajuela 36, 6 1 see Tagelus dombeii
chub 38 nipa 67, 69,72 see also Nipa,fiuticans
jack 32, 35-37, 52-54, 56-58 see also Trachurus murphyi Nipa,fruticans 67
Mncrocystis pyr~fera 62 Nothofa gus 4 1
alessundri 63
alpina 41-42, 63
antarctica 63
betuloides 63
dombeyi 41-42, 63
glauca 63
nitida 63
obliqua 41, 63
pumilio 63
Notro 62 Piquihue 61
Notropis chrysocephalus 14 see also cyprinid Pitra 63
Rirre 63 Piure 62
Octopus vulgaris 61 Pleuroncodes monodon 36, 61 see lobster, red squat; langostino
Odonteshes spp. 60 colorado
Odontocymbiola mugellanica 61 Podocarpus andinus 62
Olivillo 62 Podocarpus nubigemus 62
Oncorhynchus spp. 60 Podocarpus salignus 62
Ophictus spp. 60 Polyprion spp. 60
Ostirin del norte 6 1 Portunidae 80 see crab(s)
Ostirin del sur 6 1 prawn(s) 4, 37
Ostra 61 Prionace glauca 60
del Pactfico 6 1 Pristidae 81
Ostrea chilensis 61 Prolatilus jugularis 60
Ostreu columbiensis 19 see molluscs Prosopis chilensis 62
otter 4 Prosopis tamarugo 62
oyster(s) 18, 68 Protothaca thaca 61
l~agotpot 8 1 see croaker(s); aho Pulpo 61
Pulma Chilena 62 Pyura chilensis 62
Palometa 60 Qeule 63
Pampanito 60 Quillaja saponaria 62
Panulirus pascuensis 61 Quillay 62
Paralabrax humeralis 60 Radal 63
Puralichthys microps 60 Raja spp. 60
Paralomis grunulosa 61 Rauli 63
Puronu signata 60 Rauli beech 42
Putagua 63 ray, manta 81
Pejegallo 60 Raya 60
Pejeperro 60 redfish 38
Pejerrata 60 Reineta 60
Pejerrey de mar 60 Rhizophora spp. 17-18, 28-29 see also mangrove, red
Pejesapo 60 harrisonii 19 see also mangrove
Pejezorro 60 mangle 19-20 see also mangrove
pelagic(s) 80 racemosa 19 see also mangrove
Pelillo 62 Rhynchocinetes typus 6 1
Pelu 62 Rbbalo 60
penaeid 31 Roble 63
shrimp 17 Rollizo 60
Penaeidae 80 see shrimp(s), penaeid Roncacho 60
Penaeus 19 see shrimp Ruil 63
Penaeu.~ca1ifi)rniensis 19 Salilnta australis 60
Prnueus monodon 3 1 Salix chilensis 62
Pe~zueusoccidentalis 19 Salmo guirdneri 6 1
Pertueu.~sQlirostris 19, 21, 31 Salmo salar 60
Penaeus vannamei 19, 2 1, 3 1 Salmo truttu 61
Petseu l i n ~ u e62 Salmcin del Atlantico 60
Peto 60 Salmo'n del Pacifico 60
Pei~nio 63 salmon, ccho 14, 16
Peumus boldus 63 salmonid stocks 5
Pholphyr~columbinu 62 Salvelinus ,fontinah 6 1
Picoroco 6 1 Sarda chiliensis 60
pilchard, South American 35-37 see also Surdinops sagax Sardinu 6 1
Pilgerotlendron ur(f2rurn 62 comlin 36, 61 see also Clupeu bentincki; herring,
Pirnelonzetopon muculutus 60 Araucanian
Pimiento 62 espafiola 35 see pilchard, South American; Surdinops
pine 32, 41-43, 48, 52, 54-56, 59 sagax
P f ~ l 042 sardine(s) 36-38, 39, 49-50
rudiatu 41, 43 common 38, 40, 49, 52-54
Pinus rudiuta 32, 41-42, 48 Spanish 36, 38, 40, 49-50, 52-54, 56-58
10s
.%rrdmo]~rrt~$yrx 35, 61 cee p~lchard,South Amencan, rardina squid(s) 38, 81
erpufiolu Stromateus stellatus 60
.'%I,go 6 1 swordfish 39, 52-54, 57-58
Suut a Cluleno 62 Synodontidae 8 1
Suxejiotlzueu on g7icuu 62 Tugelus dombeii 36, 6 1 see nuvujuela
St hrnur krt~folrur 63 Tumarugo 62
St hlnur tnolle 62 Tegula atru 6 1
St iaenu spp 60 Tepu 63
Scraenldae 80 Tetraodontidae 8 1
St om he^ juponrt ur 60 T h i s chocohtu 6 1
St ornbererox \uw~ur 60 Thunnus ululungu 60
Scomb~~dae 81 Thunnus ulbacures 60
Seburter oc ulutur 60 Thunnus obesus 60
Sergrt~dae80 ree shrrmp(s), sergest~d Thyrsites atun 6 1
Serlolt~mtr7t1thnu 6 1 Tiacu 63
Ser rolellu t uer uleu 60 Tineo 62
S ~rolcllu
I ~ ~ o r o r60
u Tollo 6 1
Ser rolella violuteu 60 firnoyo 61
\hark($) 81 toothfish 54, 57-58
shellfish 39. 49-50 Patagonian 36, 38, 52-53 see also Dissostichus eleginoides
shl~mp(r)v, 2-3, 9, 11-12, 17-18, 19-24, 26-31, 36-37, 40, 49-50, Truchurus murphyi(i) 32, 35, 60 see mackerel, jack;
52-54, 57-58, 64, 68, 72-76, 80-81 ree ulro Penueur mackerel, Chilean jack
tulrforrzienur, Penueur occidentahr, Penueur
Trevo 62
rrylrrortr ir, Penueur vunnamei
Trichiuridae 8 1
Ch~leannylon 36 w e ulso Cumarcin nudon, Heterocarpur
Truchu arco iris 6 1
reed
Trucha caf4 6 1
whlte 21
Truchu de urroyo 6 1
penae~d 20, 80-8 1
tuna, bluefin 8
{ergestld 79-81 ree ulro Penaeidae
tuna, southern bluefin 4
tiger 68
Uca spp. 19 see crab(s)
Srt vurer rnnjiulneur 60
Ucides spp. 19 see crab(s)
Srerru 61
Ulmo 63
s~ganld 68
Ulva lactuca 62
srlvers~de(s)38
rhpmouth(s) 80-81 Tee ulro Lelognath~dae Venus antiqua 61
\nn~l(\)37-38 Vidriolu 6 1
\napper(<) 68 Villurezia mucronatu 62
Solen yuud~huudi 6 I Weinmanniu trichosperm 62
Sopkor u nncr ophvllu 62 whale(s), bowhead 4, 8
Sphy~aen~dae 81 Xiphius gludius 60
1
TITLESOF RELATEDINTEREST
HOW TO ORDER
Forbook prices and more publication information, please contact:
The Editor
ICLARM
MCPO Box2631,0718Makatl City,Philippines
Tel.nos. (63-2) 812-8641, 818-0466ext.ll 0 '
Fax no. (63-2) 816-3183
E-mail:[email protected]