Module 4 - Public Enterprise
Module 4 - Public Enterprise
General instruction: Read the content of the module carefully. This will help you
understand the topic for each module and will greatly help you answer the
exercises or activities at the end of each module. Each module is assigned within
a specific time period. You are expected to finish the module within the period
allotted. Should you have any queries and clarification regarding the module,
use the contact information available above. Kindly reach the instructor during
working hours from Monday to Friday. Do not forget to be courteous when
addressing your questions.
Overview:
Once the government created a public enterprise, there is a pressing need to
specify its relationship and define the interface. Nevertheless, the government
often has a problem in determining such relationship in definite terms. One of the
most difficult questions in the field of public enterprise is, therefore, to determine
the degree and character of its relationship with the government. In developing
countries in particular, the relationship is not formal and definite. Actually, public
enterprises in these countries are not treated very differently from government
departments and they are tightly controlled. On the other end, one may find
some instances in developing countries where public enterprises are enjoying
almost total independence and where government monitoring and control is not
effective enough. Neither of the two extremes is justifiable or consistent with the
rationale of creating public enterprises.
Too much or total control denies the corporate status of the enterprise, defeating
the very purpose for which they were created. To the contrary, too little control
will place public enterprises outside the democratic regime; hence the demand
for complete autonomy of enterprises is not fully acceptable. Whatever the
government is willing to provide autonomy of public enterprises, it still holds, and
should do so, certain prerogative and power over enterprises. What is required is
therefore to maintain the right balance between the level of interventions and
control of the government in the affairs of public enterprises and the operational
1
autonomy or freedom of such enterprises. Although fixing the extent and aspects
of the relationship is the problem that lies at the heart of public enterprises'
management, optimization of the linkage can provide a sound foundation for the
success of an enterprise.
I. LEARNING OUTCOMES
At the end of this Chapter, you are expected to:
1. identify public enterprise-regulatory agencies structure and
relationships;
2. examine the role of the supervisory ministry; and
3. determine and identify the areas of government intervention.
II. TOPICS
Lesson 1: The Public Enterprise-Regulatory Agencies Structure and
Relationships
Lesson 2: Role of Supervisory Ministry
Lesson 3: Areas of Intervention
III. REFERENCES
Ali, Jamal, “Meaning, Characteristics and Rationales of Public Enterprises”, Jigliga University,
July 2016.
2
Unlike the traditional hierarchical model, the government and the enterprise are
not placed only in a vertical juxtaposition (arrangement), but also in a more
constructive horizontal relationship. Public enterprises do have relations with one
or more constituents of the government in different aspects. Some of the
relationships between each government organization represented in the chart
and the public enterprise could simply be expressed in the following exemplary
stakes:
MINISTRY OF FINANCE
Behaviorally, the attitude of the Ministry of Finance flows out of its national
responsibilities. Since it is vitally responsible for national financial stability and
solvency, it is natural that its prime concern is that public enterprises should be
financially viable, should provide returns from invested capital, should pay
dividends to government, and should be a major means of resource mobilization.
The voice of the ministry of finance is that of government as a shareholder. So far
as public enterprises are concerned, the ministry of finance exercises
interventionist power in areas such as:
MINISTRY OF PLANNING
The Ministry of planning, sometimes organized as "Planning Commission" or
"National Planning Board", has the overall responsibility of designing the national
development plan; preparing a gigantic national input-output table, and a
national matrix of economic activity. Therefore, the role and performance of
public enterprises is a matter of great concern to the ministry of planning as they
are the major, perhaps the dominant, sources and instruments for the successful
execution of the national plan. In practical terms, the influence of the ministry of
planning over public enterprises would be the following:
3
Behaviorally, the ministry of planning wouldn't see public enterprises as
autonomous business firms. Rather, it views them as the building blocks of the
national plan, and looks at their investments with frame of reference of social or
economic profitability at the national level, instead of a single enterprise level.
MINISTRY OF INDUSTRY
The responsibility of this ministry is to promote industrialization in the country. Since
the substantive numbers of public enterprises are in the industrial sector, the
ministry is deeply concerned about them as factors of industrialization. It affects
public enterprises in the following areas:
Behaviorally, the ministry of industry may not differentiate between the public and
domestic private enterprises, rather threats both of them as instruments of
industrialization.
MINISTRY OF LABOR
The main concern of the ministry of labor is the welfare of workers. Hence it
promotes legislation for the protection of workers' rights covering issues like job
protection, working hours, hazardous employment conditions, labor disputes and
labor unions. While this ministry has no direct control over public enterprises, its
policies have major impacts on enterprises in matters such as:
MINISTRY OF COMMERCE
This ministry, sometimes called "Ministry of Foreign Trade", is responsible to preside
over the country's foreign commercial transactions, to stabilize the balance of
payments position by promoting exports and controlling imports. Although
policies of the ministry of commerce do not distinguish between the public and
private sectors, public enterprises are generally affected by the ministry's control
over:
Import licensing
Foreign exchange releases
4
Export promotion and quotas
Tariff protection
In general, Figure-1 simply portrays the various points of contact between the
public enterprises and the government represented by its ministries, and implies
the multiplicity of signals coming to the enterprise from the government agencies
in various issues. In other words, a public enterprise could have relations with one
or more of the ministries in addition to the supervising agency. Each organ has its
own stake with public enterprises and demands certain requirements from its own
perspectives. Now, one can be able to see the complex situations that public
enterprises are facing with in terms of responding to this multiplicity of demands,
in terms of interpreting what the government really wants, and in terms of striving
to survive in this maze (confusion). Although relations with such agencies could
have their own effects on the success or failure of public enterprise, the most
decisive influence comes from supervising agencies. Therefore, it would be more
important to explain the roles and functions of the supervising agencies and the
aspects of interventions in the affairs of public enterprises.
What are supervisory ministries or agencies, and why do we need them vis-à-vis
the activities of public enterprises in the first place? What are the fundamental
functions of these agencies? What are the major areas of supervision? These
questions need genuine answers free from any unfair bias, but with reference to
the effectiveness of public enterprises. A supervisory ministry or agency is a
controlling body or as it is sometimes described, a parent ministry. Decisions
involving government interest over public enterprises such as those of financial,
personnel, operational, and procedural policies are expressed through the
supervisory agency. This ministry or agency is commonly called upon to give
formal approval to certain kinds of decisions such as new investments or
expansion projects, prices, dividends, personnel recruitments, wages and salaries,
labor relations, and so on.
The administrative or supervisory ministry has the responsibility for monitoring and
coordinating the public enterprise attached to it. A supervisory ministry or agency
is expected to make decisions, not only to express the government's supervisory
responsibility but also to assure the consonance and harmony of the public
enterprise's activities with those of the development plans and the overall public
purpose for which it is created. Two models of the supervisory ministry have
emerged in the developing world (Praxy Fernandes 1986:41). Some countries
have attempted to establish one or a single ministry to supervise the functions of
all public enterprises like The Ministry of Production in Pakistan, The Ministry of
Public Enterprises in Malaysia, The Ministry of Industry in Egypt, and Public
Enterprises' Controlling Authority in Ethiopia. However, this model is criticized as
being impractical or ineffective to place all public enterprise under the control of
a single agency.
5
The other model, which is more commonly found, is to entrust the affairs of public
enterprises to different technical or sectoral ministries. This pattern has three major
advantages:
The effectiveness of the system will of course depend on the nature of the
relationship between the supervisory ministry and the enterprise, the demarcation
of the roles of the two parties, the nature and content of the inter-linkage, and
above all, the ability of the supervisory ministry to function as the enterprises'
intermediary with the rest of the system. The following are generally
recommended as the guiding principles for ministerial powers in relation to public
enterprises (Mathur, 1999:83-85):
(i) The authority of the minister or officer of the government who exercises
power over public enterprises should be clearly defined. It is generally
agreed that day-to-day operations should be protected against political
interrogations and interferences.
(ii) Ministers should be concerned with securing that enterprises operate in
the public interest.
(iii) Ministers should seek to ensure the efficiency of enterprises by exercising
a board oversight of them, but should not involve in management.
(iv) The methods of ministerial control or supervision should be mainly
strategic rather than tactical; the industries can have clear idea of what
the government requires of them if they are not subject to frequent tactical
control. In other words, the supervisory ministry should be responsible for the
formulation of policy and the management should be for the
implementation of that policy, and the interaction between them should
be to facilitate the overall governmental supervision without impairing the
efficiency of the operations of an enterprise and promote decentralized
decision-making within the enterprise.
(v) The proper and fruitful supervisory control depends on the attitude and
ability of both ministers and members of the board.
6
(i) Sponsoring the creation of a public enterprise through new investment
proposals
(ii) Screening and piloting investment proposals for expansion and
diversification made by an existing public enterprise, foreign exchange
expenditure, borrowing, and distribution of profits
(iii) Approving major foreign technology contracts and joint venture
proposals
(iv) Appointing the board of directors and the chief executive
(v) Approving the salary and wage structure and the system of recruitment
(vi) Defining the corporate objectives, screening and approving corporate
plans of the enterprise, ratifying the deployment of surpluses
(vii) Conveying directives on matters of public policy or public interest
(viii) Approving, in sensitive cases and particularly in monopoly situations,
pricing policy
(ix) Monitoring periodically the progress of enterprises
The execution of some of these functions may be beyond the competence and
authority of the supervisory ministry and may involve the jurisdiction of other
ministries or government agencies.
In this case, the supervisory ministry is called upon to play an intermediary role.
Managers of public enterprises are well aware of the limitations and competence
problems of supervisory agencies. Unfortunately, even the theoretical concept of
the autonomy of public enterprises doesn't seem to have been followed in spirit
in developing countries. The supervising or controlling agency normally issues
numerous instructions on matters, which could be considered "unimportant" or
even "trivial" and should legitimately fall within the domain of the enterprise's
decision-making jurisdictions.
7
Figure 2. Basic Model of Government-Public Enterprise relations
The above model of relationship can be further explained as the government has
the right and prerogative to:
Area-1: define the "mission" of the enterprise and to specify its goals and
objectives
Area-2; determine and approve the enterprise's investment plans,
decisions, and major capital expenditures
Area-3: approve, endorse and sanction the corporate plans of the
enterprise
Area-4: nominate the board of directors of the enterprise
Area-5: appoint the chief executive of the enterprise
Area-6: issue directives to the enterprise on matters relating to the national
security
Area-7: issue instructions to the enterprise on matters affecting the public
interest
Area-8: being fully informed about the activities of the enterprise, monitor
and review its progress and audit its transactions and accounts
Area-9: evaluate the performance of the enterprise.
APPROVAL OF INVESTMENT
Since part of the funds required for investments of public enterprises come from
the public exchequer (treasury), it is reasonable to assume that the government
will determine how and where the investment will be made. Indeed many of the
investment decisions are taken even before the enterprise comes into existence.
The prudence (carefulness) with which public investments are made has a
determining influence on the subsequent viability and performance of public
enterprises. The failure of many public enterprises is often traceable to a disastrous
8
investment decisions, and the trouble with such mistakes is that they are not
remediable in most cases.
The existing practices of developing countries reveal that while some of them
tend to make public investment decisions unwisely without critically and
thoughtfully assessing the existing reality and the possible consequences, many
others do so such decisions astutely, practice high degree of sophistication in
investment planning, prioritization and analysis.
(i) Defining the mission: seeking for answers for the classical questions such
as "what business are we in?" and "what do we want to achieve in the long-
run?"
9
profile of the enterprise, while financial plan is a corporate goal to produce
financial surpluses and provide a return on invested capital. To achieve this
desirable result, the enterprise would need to look into the elements such
as capital structure, planned levels of profitability, pricing policy, cost-
effectiveness, and utilization of surplus when making financial planning.
(iv) Dealing with inter-linkages: the enterprise has relationships and inter-
linkages with external organizations, agencies and interests although
corporate plan is mainly internal to the enterprise. Indeed the health,
success, and image of the enterprise will largely depend on the
optimization of these external relationships, managing the inter-linkages.
10
government not to retrench surplus staff, not to fire a particular individual, to
purchase machinery from a particular country, to make contract with a particular
company, and so on.
PERFORMANCE EVALUATION
Government always wants to make sure that public enterprises are doing right by
evaluating their performances, and this is in fact the ultimate concern that lies at
the very objectives and motives of creating them. As it will be discussed in the
next chapter, performance evaluation of public enterprises is another
problematic area of government's involvement. In other words, although
governments do have common practices in terms of evaluating the performance
of public enterprises, the problem of how to assess such performances seems to
defy solutions. There are very few countries, which set yardsticks by which
performance of public enterprises would be measured, develop criteria of
evaluation, and employ methodologies and mechanisms. Hence, public
enterprises are hemmed in by a multiplicity of judgments. Furthermore, regardless
of the universal interest and practice of the government in evaluating the
performance of public enterprises, there can be little hope of improving their
performances unless there is an agreement on what constitutes "good
performance".
11