The Costs of Activity-Based Management
The Costs of Activity-Based Management
by
Peter Armstrong
Deleted: Department of
Management¶
University of Keele¶
¶
Address for correspondence:¶
Department of Management¶
Acknowledgement. The Author would like to acknowledge the valuable comments of Keele University¶
Staffordshire ST5 5BG¶
Tel 01782 583601¶
Dave Dugdale, Colwyn Jones, Rolland Munro and Anthony Hopwood. The errors and Fax 01782 584272¶
e-mail
omissions which remain are entirely the author’s own. [email protected]¶
Abstract
Activity-based costing and management are now the stock-in-trade of a lucrative
industry, with at least one Big Six consultancy operation devoted wholly to their
corporation, into a zone previously defined in accounting terms as fixed overhead. The
activity volumes thus creating pressures for the casualisation of staff employment. The
activity frame of reference, particularly when linked with ‘value analysis’, also
encourages the stripping-out of all staff work which cannot be accommodated within its
These arguments are concretised through an examination of the ABM treatment of one of
its favoured targets: the purchasing function. The contrast between this and the supply
chain management approach advocated by practitioners and academics who take the
visualise the working population as engaged in a ‘search for shelters’. The shelters she
had in mind were of two kinds: the systems of employment protection created by trade
unions and professional associations and internal labour markets within the capitalist
corporation itself, which existed as a result of the incomplete development of its systems
to the disciplines of budgetary control and standard costing 1, staff departments, such as
through the discursive medium of the management committee. The result was a marked
contrast between conditions inside and outside the regime of management accountancy.
On the one hand, the wages of the production worker, and to some extent, those of the
adjusted in line with output, so far as was permitted by trade unionism and government
regulation (Armstrong, 1994; Armstrong, Marginson, Edwards & Purcell, 1996, in press).
Employment in the staff department, on the other hand, remained relatively secure,
depending on the abilities of its representatives to convince the rest of the management
team of the importance of the services which it provided. Specimens of the rhetorics of
1985), and some from the purchasing function are given later in this paper (page 28).
For those who felt that they were the ones who bore the cost (and absorption costing
systems could have been designed to confirm the suspicions of line managers in this
regard), the comparative lack of accountability within staff departments fuelled the
2
‘Work expands to fill the time available for its completion.’ and ‘[Staff numbers increase]
irrespective of variations in the amount of work (if any) to be done.’ (1965, p. 11, 20).
For those who could hack it into a staff position through the thickets of credentialism and
the staff appraisal process the prize was a predictable career progression, topped off with
a pension at the end. The resulting stable core of ‘knowledge workers’ was accepted as
commentators alike (Atkinson, 1984; Gordon, Edwards and Reich, 1982). In a sense, too,
the indispensability of these core employees was written into the accounting system, in
that their wage and salary costs were treated as fixed overhead, to be absorbed by
products and processes. Like the stomach in Coriolanus, the security of the staff was
supposed to work for the benefit of all. In justice therefore, all should bear the cost. Fixed
overhead both coincided with, and defined, a zone of unaccountability, hedged about by
There were, however, mutterings. From the economic point of view, the escalation of
fixed overhead had been the subject of concern from the days when the accepted
terminology was that of ‘office costs’ (Curtown, 1960). From the functional point of
view, there were those like the shopfloor worker interviewed by the author in the late
1970s who wondered, ‘what the hell are they doing all day up there in those offices?’ The
gut instinct that the privileges enjoyed by staff departments were an unjustifiable burden
management academia as well as the works canteen (Child et al, 1983). As the recession
of the early 1980s added bite to the question of whether fixed costs really were fixed,
there were reports that senior managements were responding out of the same instincts,
3
(Torrington and Mackay, 1986). Though fixed overhead remained a shelter there was ill-
will enough on the outside to create a market for some means of undermining it.
except, perhaps, for the production-centred mindset which propelled its development. As
lump, to be allocated to product lines on a single volume-related base, often direct labour.
As a consequence, costs which were ‘really’ driven by variety, activity changes or some
and under-allocated to short-run capital intensive specialist items 2. The result was said to
specialist niche markets rather than head-to-head competition in the world’s mass markets
It was at this point, that the advocacy of ABC connected with long-standing concerns
about the growth of fixed overhead as a proportion of total costs. In discovering the
activities through which overhead could be allocated, ABC could also claim to have
located the levers through which it could be controlled. Johnson and Kaplan’s promise of
a means of tackling the ‘problem [of the] growth in support personnel’ (1987, p. 244)
might be read as an answer to the Earl of Curtown’s plaint about ‘rising office costs’
made at a Summer School of the Institute of Chartered Accountants, England and Wales
costs may have been endorsed and exacerbated by two strands of 1970s managerial
doctrine. The first was a heavy emphasis on strategic management, with its insistence on
questioning ‘the business we are in’ (e.g. Argenti, 1968). This encouraged a continual,
4
not to say neurotic, scrutiny of the profitability of all product lines (as distorted by
agenda. The second was the then fashionable doctrine of ‘flexible specialisation’,
according to which the corporate winners in the ‘Second Industrial Divide’ would be
those who succeeded in the creation and pursuit of increasingly sophisticated and
dynamic consumer demands (Piore & Sabel, 1984). This school of thought may have
further prejudiced senior managements against continuing to compete in the world’s mass
markets.
ABC was not an isolated development, but one strand of a complex productivist reaction
to the managerial thinking outlined above. As an intellectual movement, this reaction was
prominent in the Harvard Business School of the early 1980s. In reaction to the increasing
penetration of Far Eastern manufactures into US mass markets, there was a new emphasis
Kaplan, 1991, p. 396) together with a corresponding rejection of the tendency of strategic
management to seek refuge in softer markets (Hayes and Abernathy, 1980 ). These
messages connected with a receptive audience: the Hayes-Abernathy paper was one of
ideas (1985) was first published in a reader co-edited by Hayes. Outside Harvard
Business School, ABC’s message 3 that America’s mass products were actually more
profitable than had previously been thought chimed well with the new ‘stand and fight
which glorified the prime cost monitoring systems developed by line managers, whilst
name of inventory valuation (Johnson and Kaplan, 1987, Chs. 2, 3 and 6), the message of
5
the new costing fell on receptive ears. In the UK, the roadshow ‘An Evening with Robert
Kaplan’ was a (very expensive) sell-out amongst line managers who did not like
In its detailed technology too, ABC was attractive to the line or production manager.
Firstly, it made overhead costs behave as production managers thought they ought to (e.g.
Bhimani and Pigott, 1992; Ruhl and Bailey, 1994; Cooper, 1990a). As has been pointed
important determinant of the direction of cost accounting evolution. More important were
the implicit messages of ABC about the relationships which ought to obtain between staff
and line departments. By distributing the costs of staff departments through the activities
which they performed ‘for’ products and processes, ABC articulated the belief that these
are the only valid staff activities. In its prescription of multi-functional committees as a
means of implementation (e.g. Cooper et al, 1992, Innes and Mitchell, 1990), moreover,
ABC promised the production function a major say in determining the services of which
it bore the cost. As part of the same deal, the scrutiny of staff departments through which
its activities were to be established could be used to reveal any which were ‘non value-
added’ (e.g. Hixon, 1995), thus creating a respectable front for the productivist suspicion
that quite a lot of staff activity is of no value at all. It is no accident that some of the most
1987b, p. 297; Lyne and Freidman, 1996) and also no accident that some applications
have resulted in job losses in the staff departments (Pattison and Gavan, 1994; Groot,
accountability, if not actually to manufacturing managers, was in terms which they could
accept as valid.
6
Although ABC has subsequently been applied in a variety of settings, such as financial
services (Adams, 1996), education (Acton and Cotton, 1997) and health care (Aird,
1996), and to a variety of cost-objects other than products, such as market segments
(Adams, 1996), the suppliers of goods and services (Lere and Saraph, 1995) and the
(Cooper et al, 1992), the view which it takes of staff activity has remained true to its
productivist origins. Whatever the setting, the staff department is defined as a ‘service
function’ (e.g. Innes and Mitchell, 1990, p. 5), its workers are ‘support personnel’
(Johnson and Kaplan, 1987, p. 244) and the services performed are taken to be ‘for’ the
cost-object.
If ABC began the process of dismantling the ‘shelter’ of fixed overhead, by specifying
and costing the services for which it was paying, its mutation into activity-based
management (ABM) promises to complete it. The key manoeuvre in this transformation
each activity (the cost driver) to generate a cost rate which could be used not only
to cost production but also as a performance measure for the activity concerned.
Once the activities through which ABC distributes indirect costs are regarded as non-
financial indicators of performance for the staff department, its destruction as an enclave
made in terms of the projected and actual levels of each activity, so that the department is
opened up to a variant of standard costing. The implications for the future of the staff
department as an employment shelter have been forcefully spelt out from the security of a
tenured professorship at Harvard Business School. This is ‘Kaplan’s first law of fixed and
variable costs’:
7
‘If there is more than one person in a department, it is a variable cost. If there is
more than one machine in a department, machines are a variable cost. If there is
more than one of any resource, it has got to be a variable cost resource.’
heart of it. In this respect, its promotion by accounting academics and consultants is a
prime example of the politics of the capitalist agency relationship (Armstrong, 1991). On
this view of the modern corporation, managerial hierarchies consist, not only of a
relationships, in which subordinates are necessarily trusted to act in the interests of their
superiors (i.e., as their agents). Senior managers, however, have a choice as to who they
will trust. Since there are managerial occupations which profess techniques through
which others can be monitored and controlled, senior managers can choose to trust these
as an alternative to trusting the managers of the functions concerned. From this point of
view, ABM, in its most ambitious expositions, constitutes a claim that management
accountancy can now construct regimes of accountability applicable to all staff functions.
Besides the implications for the future security of staff employment in what even the
employment, ABM will have consequences for the way in which staff functions are
actually performed.
It has previously been argued (Armstrong and Tomes, 1996; Armstrong, in press) that
activities to which they are applied (the aesthetic design of products was the example
given). This is not just a question of the slippage between performance and performance
indicator (activity and cost-driver in the case of ABC); rather it is a question of the
8
redefinition of performance itself, as it undergoes translation from the culture of the
suspicion rather than one of understanding. This, it will be argued, is precisely the spirit
in which ABM approaches the staff department. Instead of seeking to grasp the larger
purpose behind its activities, ABM simply assumes that these activities are (and should
be) separable repeated acts performed ‘for’ products or processes. Anything which does
not fit into this framework is regarded as a prima facia candidate for the chop. Where
ABM is ‘successfully’ implemented, this image of the staff function may become a self-
fulfilling prophecy in that it the department’s activities may actually be reduced to routine
technical or clerical services. The loss, to the extent that spokespersons for the staff
functions are to be believed, will be the prospective value added through developments
within the staff functions themselves, markets, human resources or, in the case discussed
in this paper, the supply chain. The abolition of the staff department as an employment
shelter, therefore, may have a downside, quite apart from its human cost. The case for
reconceptualisation of the nature of indirect costs. The original objective was to correct
the ‘distortions’ of single-based absorption costing, and it was on the promise of a gain in
accuracy that ABC gained its initial purchase on managerial practice. In the process, the
complexity of the activities which ‘really’ connected them to products and processes. If
this complexity could be adequately modelled in a practical cost control system, it would
9
be possible to monitor and control staff activity exactly as had been achieved for
Both developments - the initial adoption of ABC, and the possibility of its extension into
context in which this first occurred, albeit implicitly, was the insistent claim that ABC is
more accurate than absorption costing. Recent examples include Cooper (1990b), Roehm,
Critchfield and Castellano (1992), Cooper et al (1992), Banker and Johnston (1993),
Babad and Balachandran (1993), Borjesson (1994), Datar and Gupta (1994), Danilenko
(1994), Letza and Gadd (1994), Lawson (1994), Marshall (1995), Adams (1996) and
West et al (1996).
The more one reflects upon these claims, the stranger they appear. If the definition of
indirect costs is taken seriously - as those which ‘cannot be traced directly to cost objects’
(Wilson and Chua, p. 82) - in what sense can one method of allocation be more accurate
than another? If correct allocations cannot exist, even in principle, there can be no
standard by which accuracy can be judged. Typically, the response of the activity costers
is that of busy people who have no time for such conceptual niceties: they produce
simply by showing that single-base absorption costing gives different result (e.g. Kaplan,
1987, p. 7.20; Innes and Mitchell, 1990, p. 14; Adams, 1996). That this simple-minded
tactic appears to convince its protagonists points towards a fundamentalist mindset within
which the relative merits of ABC and absorption costing are not really a matter for
argumentation.
Underlying the controversies over the supposed accuracy of activity-based costing, there
are uncertainties about the ontological status of allocated costs which fail to be articulated
within the language of cost accounting practice. For the sake of exposition, let us take the
10
ontological starting point of cost accounting to be one in which direct costs are real, in the
sense that they are external to cost accounting as a practice 4. That is, their calculation and
their association with particular cost objects does not depend on the particular approach to
costing which is adopted. The question then arises of whether or not allocated indirect
costs are real in the same sense. Discussions of traditional absorption costing are mightily
If the definition of indirect costs quoted above is taken at all seriously, allocations of them
can never be real. Because they vary according to the allocation base, the resulting
convention. Ontologically, they are intellectual constructs. It follows that claims for them
are meaningless 5.
The problem with this position is that costing claims to be a practical art. Whilst it may be
this cannot be the case with management decisions based upon them. Because the
Consider the following statement from Wilson and Chua (1993, p. 82):
‘By definition, indirect costs cannot be traced directly to cost objects which will
mean that the resulting full (or ‘absorbed’) cost is inaccurate to an unknown
extent.’
The contradiction lurking within this statement lies in the fact that inaccuracy, even of
unknown extent, implies that a true allocation of indirect costs is possible in principle.
The same authors’ definition of indirect costs, on the other hand, implies that it is not. It
follows that the extent of the inaccuracy is unknowable (as well as unknown), in which
11
case it is not inaccuracy at all, but a recognition that there is a difference between
convention and knowledge. Wilson and Chua are clearly sensitive to this issue:
‘ . . . the real answer is both unknown and unknowable, given that there is no
definitive basis for apportioning or absorbing indirect costs. However some bases
costs may be near enough to the ‘truth’ for practical people. From this point, it becomes
possible to assert that some bases of cost allocation give better approximations than
others, although the grounds on which such claims are made are necessarily left imprecise
(‘necessarily’, because if clearly articulated they would, again, contradict the definition of
indirect costs 6). Having mooted the notion that there are variations in the appropriateness
of allocation bases, Wilson and Chua arrive, a few pages later, at the familiar starting
inappropriate base for recovering indirect costs. Any approximation of full cost
that is built up from an indirect cost element based on direct labour is unlikely to
be an acceptable approximation . . . ‘
More sophisticated than most, Wilson and Chua’s discussion is entirely typical of the
manner in which the ontological basis of indirect cost allocation hovers between realism
and idealism. It could be that these ambiguities are an evolved response to the social
12
pressures upon cost accounting. As has been shown by Ernest Gellner (1970), the
contradictions lurking within certain everyday concepts may serve important social
functions. So it may be with cost allocation. On the one hand, the concept of
approximation serves to legitimate the arbitrary allocation of costs as the only possibility
in the face of an unknowable truth. On the other hand it asserts the informational value of
these allocations. So it is that a gesture of faith, albeit one which has accumulated the
Activity-based costing, at least in its core expositions, marks a decisive break from these
ambiguities. Although the advocates of ABC continue to use the term ‘indirect costs’,
they do not really believe in them. They sense, though they do not always clearly
articulate, that all costs are, or should be, direct. Indeed ABC’s best-known slogan:
‘Activities cause costs and products consume activities’ is nothing more than a working
fact and a programme of action. If all costs are really direct, the task of (relevant) cost
accounting is to uncover that directness. This is the classic realist enterprise. Underlying
the complexities of empirical situations, it is believed that there are real relationships to
be uncovered between product (or process) and (direct) cost 7. ABC proposes to achieve
this by identifying the real activities which contribute to the product and by computing
the real (direct) cost of each. That this real relationship between product and cost may be
very complex does not alter the fact that it is calculable in principle. And if this is the
model it. Approximation here does not stand for arbitrariness: rather it is a matter of
choosing cost drivers to proxy for them which are a compromise between representational
13
In this manner, indirect costs are reconceptualised within ABC as the direct costs of real
activities. It is this ontological foundation which underpins both the claims of superior
accuracy made for ABC and the development of ABM as a means of evaluating and
A first question which needs to be asked of the ABC/ABM programme is how far it
as well as ontology.
search for the activities which connect costs to products and processes, and for the cost
drivers which proxy for them, needs to compromise between representational accuracy
and manageability. The result is that some indirect costs - hopefully a small proportion of
the total - are virtually bound to be excluded from the cost-pools associated with a
practical set of cost drivers. Whether this is felt to be a consequence of their inherent
processes (and two views on this are considered on page 21), the consequence is that
This much is openly acknowledged and there can be no quarrel with reasonable
approximation in the cause of managerial practicality. The problem with the ABC/ABM
project of recasting indirect costs as direct is not so much that it cannot be completed in
practice but that many of the costs which are identified as the direct costs of activities are
The procedure begins with a census of the activities which staff departments perform,
usually for products and processes, though sometimes for customers or markets (e.g.
Cooper et al, 1992, Ch. 5.) Each activity is then costed according to its occupancy of staff
14
time and other resources. For clarity in the discussion which follows, the cost objects will
be taken to be products and the costs to be traced to them will be assumed to be only
those of staff time. Similar arguments would apply to other cost objects and to the
The costing of activities according to their consumption of staff time means that the staff
department is treated as a mass producer of activities for whom all labour costs are
direct. Computationally speaking, this is similar to the charge-out systems used for cost
explicitly recognise the allocation of indirect costs. The procedure for costing activities in
ABC on the other hand, forces the staff manager to account for all - or most - of the staff
hours as direct labour 8. The result will be that any labour time which is ‘really’ indirect in
relation to the defined activities will be judgementally allocated by the manager to one or
another of these activities, as a means of coping with the imposed form of accountability.
In consequence the apparent direct costs of the activities identified in the process of ABC
implementation will contain concealed allocations of indirect labour costs. The question
of the superior accuracy of ABC as compared to absorption costing then hinges on the
proportion of these concealed indirect costs relative to the whole. The greater the
proportion of true direct costs, i.e. nearer the staff department is to a labour-only-
subcontractor, the more convincing will be the case for the accuracy of ABC. Conversely,
the more the department resembles a solicitor’s office, where the common costs of non-
specific research are charged out on a direct labour basis, the less realism can be claimed
for activity costs. To put the matter another way, the more of the labour within a staff
department which is indirect in terms of its output activities, the greater will be the
15
How great is this proportion likely to be in practice? A difficulty here lies in an
imprecision within the notion of direct cost, or, what is equivalent, in the idea that costs
are ‘caused’ by particular events or activities (Piper and Whalley, 1990). Consider a
favourite example of the advocates of ABC, that of placing a purchase order. Only a
small fraction of the staff time attributed to this activity by the departmental manager will
be taken up with actually writing out and dispatching the order. A larger proportion will
that the order can be made, whilst the rest will be consumed in updating that stock of
information in the light of the order. Details of the purchase will need to be recorded, for
example, so that the incoming goods and the invoice can be checked against them. If the
procedures for doing so are well-designed, the activity of ‘checking goods inwards’ will
be simple and cheap. If, on the other hand, the records are inaccessible, or otherwise user-
unfriendly, ‘checking goods inwards’ will appear time-consuming and expensive. Most of
in that they both draw upon information deposited in the course of previous activities and
involve the deposition of information needed for future activities. In cost terms, the
between them becomes arbitrary. To the extent that staff departments approximate to this
model, the costs of record-maintenance will account for most of the total, and should be
treated as common.
Where this is the case, treating the cost of the staff time devoted to an activity as its real
(direct) cost, really amounts to a re-allocation of the common costs of record maintenance
on the assumption that each activity should bear a quantum of this cost exactly equal to
that which it consumes. It is assumed, in effect, that activities which contribute a lot to
record-keeping also depend on a lot of record-keeping, that there are no activities which
depend on a lot of paper work but do not themselves involve very much.
16
Where these allocated common costs are a substantial proportion of the whole, ABC may
fail to model the behaviour of the costs of staff departments when products are dropped or
analysis demonstrates that the correct modelling of costs in such circumstances requires
that the costs in each cost pool should depend on a single activity, a condition which is
clearly violated where the ‘direct’ cost of each activity includes the cost of maintaining
These considerations reflect badly on Argyris and Kaplan’s (1994) claim that ABC is
now established as an internally consistent technical theory. Whilst there may be staff
departments in which all costs are the direct costs of their activities, this cannot be the
general case. It follows that the project of reworking all or most of the costs of staff
flawed by the presence of concealed allocations of indirect costs within ABC. Also
eroded is the ground on which stands the claim that ABC is more accurate than other
methods of cost allocation. To the extent that the costs of activities are not, after all, direct
costs, there is no reason to suppose that the allocation procedure by which they are
The validity of the truth claims made for ABC is one thing; its social consequences are
another. As the sociologist W.I. Thomas pointed out some time ago (1957, p. 42), people
do not act according to the situation but according to their definition of it. So has been
with belief in the reality of activity-based costings. It is this belief which defines the
Numerically, of course, (putatively real) activity based cost allocations can be reproduced
the rhetorical framing differs - a fact which has led some commentators to the conclusion
that there is no essential difference between ABC and multiple base absorption costing
17
(e.g. Noreen, 1991; Kennedy, 1995). The rhetoric, however, is precisely the point. The
cardinal virtue claimed for activity-based costing is that its allocation of costs is real. This
reality depends not only on the reality claimed for the costs of the activities (discussed
above), but also upon the claim that the activities through which they are distributed are
those actually performed for the production process (or for customers or markets). This
realist ontology was crucial to the development of ABC into activity-based management.
only on the question of its accuracy. The revelation that all costs were really direct,
however, opened up a whole new project of organisational control for the advocates of
ABC. If the activities identified in the course of implementing the product costing system
were real rather than notional bases of allocation, it became thinkable to control staff
which begat ABC, ‘Products consume activities’, it made sense to manage staff
departments, and perhaps the entire organisation, in terms of these activities. Thus:
support.’
(Hixon, 1995)
It was on the basis of its realist ontology, therefore, that ABC evolved ABM. In the
process, the cost-drivers originally devised as a means of allocating indirect costs were
(Morrow and Hazell, 1992; Cooper et al, 1993; Hobdy, Thompson and Sharman, 1994;
Clarke, 1994; Clarke and Bellis-Jones, 1996; Aird, 1996; Lindahl, 1997). Although the
intellectual and political origins of ABC were very different from those of ‘accountable
18
management’ in public sector services (Humphrey, Miller and Scapens, 1993), its basic
principle to those currently being promoted in the public sector (see, for example,
Cochrane, 1993; Gray and Jenkins, 1993; Ezzamel and Willmott, 1993; Laughlin,
Broadbent and Willig-Atherton, 1994; Lawrence, Manzurul and Lowe, 1994: Chua and
Preston, 1994; Ogden, 1995). Both developments, moreover, were propelled by a kind of
add ‘customer value’, and with minimising the unit costs of those which did.
The difference in the contexts, however, is important: where the public demand for
services such as education and health is highly elastic, that for staff services within a
capitalist enterprise is not. Evidence from companies which have installed ABC systems
indicates that the enthusiasm of manufacturing managers has much to do with the
prospect of reducing the burden of overhead and little to do with enhancing the quality of
service (Pattison and Gavan, 1994). Where the indices of public service performance
allow, in principle at least, for expenditures aimed at increasing the quality of output, the
function more like expenditure caps. This means that ABM is really nothing more than an
The potency of ABM in this respect is considerably amplified when it is mated with
‘value analysis’, a procedure animated by the belief that it is possible to make some
determination of the value added by particular activities (Adams, 1996). The basis on
which this is done is quite obscure 9, and may have much to do with the prejudices of
those making the determination. In one of the case studies by Cooper et al (1992) only
two of the seven activities identified in an ‘Accounts Payable’ section (40% of staff time)
were accepted as representing the actual business of processing accounts (1992, p. 141-2).
The rest, including the 35% of staff time taken up with ‘process management’ were not.
19
A leader of the ABC implementation team spelt out the implications for future staffing
levels: ‘The accounts payable data revealed how expensive we were. I see now how we
In general, ABC produces, as a by-product, a list of staff activities which is handy for the
purpose of value analysis. Since ‘low value-added’ can mean little else but ‘dispensable’,
it is fairly obvious that it is primarily a means targeting staff reductions (See, for example,
Cooper et al, 1992, Ch. 7; Sephton and Ward, 1990; Steimer, 1990). Given this, it is
scarcely surprising that ‘value-added’ tends to become the oval ball in an organisational
reported by Cooper et al (1992), attempts to rank activities according to their value added
‘surprising’ that the staff managers in one implementation considered only 4% of their
own department’s activities to be of ‘low value’ (Cooper et al, p. 138), an outcome which
indicated to the implementation team that steps should be taken to ensure that in future
value would be judged from the point of view of the corporation as a whole.
( New Para) The identification of indirect costs with activities in ABC also exposes their
potential for variability in ABM. If the consumption of activities varies, either as a result
redesign, so, also, should the cost of performing them (Morrow and Connolly, 1991). The
standard costs which open up the black box of the staff department, just as Scientific
Management and standard costing once broke open the black box of craft production
(Braverman, 1974, Miller and O’Leary, 1987). This new regime of accountability exposes
the staff department to precisely the same insecurities and pressures for labour
intensification as manufacturing (e.g. Pattison and Gavan, 1994, Hobdy, Thompson and
20
Sharman, 1994) 10. The destruction of the staff department as an employment shelter is not
an unintended consequence of ABM; it is precisely the point, and there are signs that
those on the receiving end are becoming aware of it. Dugdale (1990) has reported that
some ABC implementations have only been allowed to proceed on condition that
Despite their formal similarities as monitoring systems, there are important differences
between the terms on which ABM proposes to open up the labour process as compared
offers no positive guide to the revision of working practices. Its ‘standard costs’ are not
those of activities which have actually been redesigned in standardised form. Rather,
they are the expression of a belief that staff activities already are, or should be, of this
(Steimer, 1990, Armitage and Russell 1993, Letza and Gadd, K 1994, Thomas and
Mackey, 1994; Clarke and Bellis-Jones, 1996), the most it can actually achieve is re-
the claims made for its scope. In general, it is the more creative, least routine staff
activities, those which least fit its framework of accountability, which are under most
approach. In the related debates on the scope of ABC, there is a considerable body of
opinion which accepts that there are activities which cannot, and perhaps should not, be
The programme of the ‘comprehensive’ view of ABC was set out by Kaplan in 1987
(Kaplan, 1987, p. 7.27). ‘The scope of the product cost system is the entire value chain.
21
All of the costs of the organisation are included in product costs.’ Similarly Johnson
(1988); ‘In principle, all activities in an organisation supply output to meet customer’s
recommended by Innes and Mitchell (1990, p. 8.): ‘When the work-time of all of the staff
is fully accounted for, it is reasonably certain that the activity listing is comprehensive.’
By 1988, however, Kaplan had reconsidered, suggesting that the costs of unused capacity
should be excluded on the grounds that these are period expenses and that those of
enterprise as a whole (Kaplan, 1988: 65). Other arguments against the ‘inclusive’ view
are that there are costs which cannot be identified with particular activities (Staubus,
1990), that it is cannot be meaningful to allocate costs down to product level when they
are not controllable at that level (Sephton and Ward, 1990), and that cost behaviour will
not be correctly modelled by ABC systems when the cost pools include the fixed costs of
In practice, the difference between these positions is not as extreme as the polarisation of
their arguments suggests. Those who believe that ABC ought to form a comprehensive
system of cost allocation are quite prepared to make arbitrary allocations of costs which
prove difficult to trace to particular objects. In Innes and Mitchell’s illustration of the
allocation of purchasing costs, for example, the costs of supervision are distributed
For ABC, the issue of scope may be a minor one in any case, since it concerns only that
proportion of indirect costs which is difficult to identify with accessible drivers. From the
point of view of cost allocation, it makes little difference whether small proportions of
indirect cost are allocated through approximate cost drivers, whether they are recognised
as period costs and allocated arbitrarily or whether they are not allocated at all. When the
22
cost drivers of ABC are regarded as performance indicators, as in ABM, the
consequences may be more serious. To the extent that particular cost drivers fail to
capture the meaning of staff activity, they create pressures to misdirect that activity, and
In contrast to the debates on the scope of ABC, few, if any, discussions of ABM have
confronted the issue of whether or not there are limits to its applicability. On the contrary,
comprehensive approach to the management of staff functions at all levels. Typical is the
following definition from the leaders of Ernst and Young’s specialist ABM
consultancy 11:
‘[ABM is] A way in which an organisation can direct, measure and control its
aim for enhanced performance. This is achieved by the creation and use of an
If this means what it says, the implication is that divisional and corporate-level staff
functions as well as the support services at level of the operating site are candidates for
at first sight, to be both reasonable and participative. The usual procedure begins with an
interview with the manager concerned (Cooper, 1990a; Cooper et al, 1992: 16; Innes and
Mitchell, 1990, p. 8). Multidisciplinary teams which include, but are not necessarily
dominated by, management accountants ask managers to list the activities which they
perform for products and processes, to estimate the proportion of staff time and other
23
resources expended on each activity and to agree a cost-driver which will stand for a unit
performance of it. Interviews of this kind are said to be both quick and cheap, taking
between 30 minutes and two hours per manager (Cooper et al, 1992, p. 16).
particular view of their own functions. As a method of cost allocation, ABC can only
work by reducing the work of staff departments to a set of separable activities - separable
because each must have an identifiable cost. When such a view is carried forward into
ABM, the staff department is seen as the producer of repeated acts of service, usually for
production, each of which gives off a countable signal (as, for example, the ordering of
material is signified by a form). Such an atomised view of the staff function is virtually
guaranteed to miss the point. It completely ignores the question of whether there ought to
be some larger purpose behind the activities, and whether it might be more appropriate to
hold the department accountable in terms of this purpose. As has already been recognised
within the literature of ABC, one effect of this substitution of activity for purpose is to
performance monitoring systems which prioritise the ratio of activity outputs to cost,
managers find ways of doing their bit which have nothing at all to do with either
efficiency or effectiveness. Innes and Mitchell (1990, p. 26) give the example of splitting
‘produced’.
However reasonable it may appear to the productivist mind-set, not all of staff activity
can be reduced to routine services performed for other functions. By threatening to reduce
expenditure to levels which can be justified in such terms ABM threatens to deny space
for developmental activities indigenous to the staff department. To take concrete cases,
the concepts of policy and strategy as applied to human resource management and
24
R&D creates the potential for new products (e.g. Tyson, 1985; Saunders, 1997). Recall
too that Kaplan (1988, p. 65) advocated the exemption of R&D expenses from allocation
on the grounds that it is an investment in future products, not a cost of present products.
The same argument could equally apply to the recruitment and training of effective
personnel, or to the development of the supply chain. The problem with ABM is that it is
programmed to deny and annihilate anything which is not on its list of routine activities,
The irony is that the diffusion of ABC/ABM appears to be hampered by exactly the
mentality which it seeks to operationalise in the form of accounting controls. Line and
senior managers tend to regard accounting as a service providing routine (and not very
accounting departments were run down during the 1980s, so that a major obstacle to the
development of improved costing systems is now the lack of staff time (Innes, Mitchell
and Cobb, 1992, p. 9). Would there, one wonders, be time in an accounting department
activities as valid during the interview phase, and in shepherding them through the cull of
value analysis, these activities, or rather their cost-drivers, are likely to become fossilised
within the activity monitoring system, especially when this is written into software. It is
all very well for management consultants to argue that ABM should ‘describe, regularly
and in detail, what the organisation does’ (Evans and Ashworth, 1995, italics added), but
one of the problems with ABM is that it is expensive in staff time to install (Innes,
Mitchell, and Cobb, 1992). By the same token, it will be expensive to update. The
25
conceals the fact that they do so as a consequence of managerial decisions (e.g.
facilitates the management of activities, in the sense of exerting pressure on the resources
devoted to them, it discourages activity management in the sense of searching for better
ways of accomplishing their purpose. In any case, such a search would (again) create
If the foregoing is true, one would expect some show of resistance from staff subjected to
the ABM frame of reference. Reports of the staff view of things, it has to be said, are not
a frequent feature of implementation case studies. Many of these lack ethnographic detail
and they tend, in any case, to be written up by consultants and/or an implementation team,
chosen for their prior commitment to the ABM project (e.g. Bhimani and Pigott, 1992).
Generally the voices of the subjects are suppressed. It is well established, however, that
The recommendation of Lammert and Ehrsam (1987) on this point is an ‘intense program
performance measurement system (see also Argyris and Kaplan, 1994). This expenditure
of effort on re-education can only mean that passive resistance on the part of some of
those affected is the norm rather than the exception. There are, in addition, some direct
staffing levels (Pattison, and Gavan, 1994), adverse effects on incentive payments
(Lammert and Ehrsam 1987) or the embarrassment and threat experienced by managers
whose products or practices are newly revealed as unprofitable (Lammert and Ehrsam
1987; Shields and Young, 1989; Argyris and Kaplan, 1994). Occasionally resistance to
26
ABM is stripped of its rationality altogether and dropped into a conceptual black hole
Unusually, the staff managers speak in one of the case studies by Cooper et al, (1992, p.
133):
‘Our office environment is difficult to quantify, tasks are less repetitive, and
It could be that the main evidence of staff resistance to the conceptual framework
imposed upon staff activities is indirect. Horngren (1990), for example, reports the failure
costs which could not be traced to products. It needs to be remembered that there is an
irreducible social element in the construction of ABM systems and ‘could not’ in this
case is likely to express the outcome of a negotiation between the implementation team
According to Innes, Mitchell, and Cobb (1992) it is common to find that the initial list of
activities obtained from staff managers is too extensive to fit into a feasible system, whilst
Pattison and Gavan (1994) report that there have been failures of implementation due to
complexity of their tasks within a frame of reference which insists that these are made up
of discrete acts of service. Where there is resistance of this kind, the typical
approximation. To the implementation team, the final list of activities and their cost
27
approximate in the sense that much of the meaning of their work has escaped the model
altogether.
The previous section has argued that ABM proposes a degradation of other staff
functions. This thesis will now be illustrated on one of the chosen grounds of ABC: that
of the purchasing function. For some reason ABC gurus have it in for the purchasing
department:
‘It should not cost us much more to order a $10,000 dollar part than a $10 dollar
part. Typing the extra zeros on the check is not very expensive. Why [should]
and Morrow (1989), Innes and Mitchell (1990), Roehm, Critchfield, and Castellano,
The procedure will be to compare the account of purchasing given in recent textbooks on
the subject with its representation in activity-based management. The potential biases in
both accounts need to be borne in mind. Purchasing enthusiasts are just as likely to
produce expansionary accounts of their field of study as ABC advocates are to reduce it
management’ (Saunders, 1997). The name says much. ‘Supply chain’ is evidently a
28
suggests that the function needs to be represented at board level. In other words, we are
parallels, in many respects, that of management accounting (see page 5). There is the
same invocation of competition from the Far East, coupled with the same threats of loss
‘[There is a] huge gap in performance between the best performers in Japan and
the others elsewhere in the world ... Purchasing and supply chain management
practices have played a part in the superiority of these companies and they need to
There are even parallels with the case made for ABC in the references to changes in the
cost structure of the modern corporation. Where ABC advocates make much of the
increasing proportion of costs now accounted for by fixed overhead, the case for
increasing the emphasis on supply chain management is argued, in part, from the rising
proportion of total costs accounted for by purchasing decisions (Gadde and Håkansson,
1993, p. 4).
The animating insight behind the supply chain management approach is that the lowest-
price supplier may not be the lowest cost supplier. There is a ‘revenue improvement’ term
‘[Which] means suppliers provide additional services such as product design and
development’ (Saunders, 1997, p. 307) so adding value to the final product and reducing
internal costs such as inspection and handling (see also Gadde and Håkansson, 1993, p.
165, 172ff.). In order to realise these benefits, the role of the purchasing function needs to
29
There is, unfortunately, much to be done. ‘In many companies, purchasing suffers from
low status.’ (Gadde and Håkansson, 1993, p. 31), a problem it appears to have in common
with management accounting (Lyne and Freidman, 1996). Most managing directors, it
seems, ‘remain stunningly oblivious to the benefits which effective practice can bring.’
whilst ‘... senior managers outside the function need to alter their perception of the scope
and potential of purchasing and supply chain management’ ’ (Saunders, 1997, p. 310-
311).
Saunders’ prescription for repositioning the purchasing function begins with its
representation of at board level, so that supply strategies can be integrated into company
strategy as a whole. It also calls for an expansion of the function and the development of
its staff, not only so that the supply chain can be adequately managed, but also so that its
The first step is to produce a list of activities performed by the function. Innes and
have drawn up this list in consultation with the department manager. They are careful to
emphasis this participative aspect: ‘It is important that the department manager (given his
(sic) local knowledge) and not the management accountant selects the relevant activities.’
In order to assist the department manager in this task, they suggest that ‘A useful
30
approach at this stage is to question the manager on the purpose for having each member
of staff.’ A little later, they amplify the kind of questions which might be asked:
If this sounds a little aggressive, consider the following Socratic dialogue on the same
‘Do not believe someone who says “We have 11 people in this department, but it
is a fixed cost.” Ask why this function cannot be handled with one person. He
says, “We cannot do it with one.” Why not? “Because there is too much work for
one person to do by herself.” Aha, now comes the important question, “What kind
of work?” Find out what creates work for the department that one person cannot
One is left to imagine what goes through the minds of staff managers when they are
questioning process. This insists that the agreed activities must account for the whole of
staff time and equipment usage (Innes and Mitchell, 1990, p. 8 ). What counts as an
activity, moreover is defined in a very particular way. Firstly activities must be relatively
homogenous repeated acts. Secondly, and recalling that purchasing has been defined as a
manufacturing 12. A meeting to consider purchasing strategy, for example, would fail to
qualify as an activity on both counts. The list of activities which emerges from the
31
consultation process, therefore, is a picture of the purchasing function which is decisively
shaped by the core assumption behind the questions: that all of the staff time and
Innes and Mitchell’s illustrative table of activities for a purchasing department, and their
associated cost drivers is reproduced in Table 1 (minus the notional figures for the
Table 1
ACTIVITY COST DRIVERS
The receipt of purchase requests No. of requests
Vetting alternative suppliers No. of supplier orders
No. of suppliers
No. of new parts
Ordering items No. of supplier orders
No. of items
No. of suppliers
Expediting delivery No. of deliveries
The approval of payment No. of deliveries
Supervision All of above drivers
Having produced a list of activities and their cost drivers, the next step is to produce a
unit cost for each driver by dividing the total cost of the activities associated with it by the
number of its occurrences. The whole of the costs of the purchasing department can then
be assigned to products (or processes) by multiplying this unit cost by the number of cost-
driver occurrences associated with each product (or process). In this manner, the
procedure expresses, now in calculative form, the assumption with which it began: that all
of the costs within the purchasing department (with the exception of supervision, in Innes
and Mitchell’s example) are, or ought to be, the direct costs of its activities, either of
32
Innes and Mitchell (1990) present their notional treatment of purchasing purely as an
exercise in cost allocation. Left at that, it would have no immediate consequences for the
way in which the function is actually managed. Later, however, they argue the case for
managing on the basis of activity-based cost information, although the argument is made
in general terms rather with reference to their notional purchasing department. Thus:
‘Management is facilitated through the selection of activity based cost drivers for each
cost pool which (a) provide a set of activity volume based non-financial measures of
performance which can provide useful routine feedback on process efficiency; (b) help in
the identification of activities which are non-volume added and/or waste resources;. . . .’.
Referring to their table of purchasing activities, it is clear that this amounts to managing
orderings, expeditings and payment approvals. It is further assumed that the efficiency
with which each activity is carried out can usefully be monitored by comparing its current
unit cost against a set of established standards. It also implies that activities which are not
associated with the defined cost drivers should be considered for elimination as
superfluities.
Clearly these activity-based indices of efficiency are not even capable of indicating the
effectiveness with which the purchasing function carries out its traditional role of
securing supplies at minimum cost. Also completely ignored are the function’s
performance in co-ordinating with other functions, policy development and planning and
forecasting, all of which are extensively discussed in Baily and Farmer (1990). The
contrast between the ABC image of purchasing and the supply chain management
approach is even more stark. Joint developmental work undertaken with the suppliers of
33
handling, for example, is quite simply beyond its conceptual horizon. More, since none of
these activities are likely to trigger occurrences of the cost drivers identified in an ABC
exercise, any expenditure upon them will tend to be regarded as non-value added. In this
manner, the application of ABM to purchasing would create pressures against any
written as if management accountants were the first to consider the question of measuring
its performance. Yet the matter is considered at length even in Baily and Farmer’s
traditional treatment of the subject (1990). The following might be read as a comment on
‘In purchasing, the calculation of the number of requisitions dealt with by a buyer
in one day may tell us something about his (sic) efficiency in passing paper. The
number of items received on time and the number of items which fail to meet the
effectiveness may be more concerned with establishing vendors who have the
potential to supply for many years to come - competitively. Also with, e.g.,
Since this was written, the techniques of measuring purchasing performance have moved
forward, with developments aimed at modelling some of the benefits of supply chain
management. The key concept is that of the ‘Total costs of ownership’ (TCO). The idea is
inspection, returns, re-working etc.) to each supplier so that the benefits of using a higher-
34
quality supplier can be offset against the higher cost (Burt, Norquist and Anklesaria,
1990; Cavatino, 1992; Carr and Ittner, 1992; Ellram and Siferd, 1993; Ellram, 1993;
Of course this does not capture the whole of the benefits claimed for the supply chain
approach. Like ABC, TCO is simply a form of cost allocation, and, as such, cannot place
programmes. Despite this limitation, it remains interesting that the development – which
thinkers and practitioners rather than management accountants. Of the 11 case studies of
the approach reported by Ellram (1995) only 3 involved the accounting finance function
at all and only in one case was it the prime mover. In 10 out of 11 of the cases, moreover,
the information used for the TCO implementation was captured outside the firm’s normal
accounting systems.
In view of this, and because the TCO approach is relatively recent, it is perhaps
understandable that the purchasing applications of ABC/ABM so far reported have failed
to engage with it 13. More striking, is their failure even to consider that there might be a
‘purchasing view’ of what its functions ought to be and how the performance of these
could be that the integrity of the ABC/ABM approach depends upon this kind of failure
of awareness.
Conclusion
The relevance ‘regained’ in ABC was really an operationalisation in costing form of a
productivist view of staff activities: that their main justification lies in their contribution
to company outputs. It was this quasi moral view of the functional interdependencies
within the corporation which underlay the distribution of staff costs to products and
35
process according to their consumption of staff activities. In order to build this basis of
cost allocation into a practical system, it had to be assumed that staff activities are
standardised and countable acts, a view which was probably congenial to the productivist
Both the technical apparatus and the world-view of ABC carried into ABM. If the value
of staff activity lay in its contribution to products and processes, it followed that staff
departments ought be accountable in terms of that contribution and that staff costs should
be controlled according to it. The activities identified by ABC offered a technology for
achieving both, since they were claimed to be the real functional connection between the
staff department and company outputs, not just conventional bases of cost allocation. In
this respect, the realist ontology of ABC was crucial to the development of ABM. It
meant that the staff activities initially identified for the purpose of cost allocation could
pressed into service as performance indicators. Standard costs for these activities could be
established and used as the basis for budgetary planning and control. In this manner the
technology of ABM could connect with long-standing concerns over the lack of
accountability within staff departments and the continued escalation of staff costs.
For the consultancies now engaged in the promotion of ABM, its consequences for
connection between staff activities and company outputs implies the short-run variability
of payroll costs, is precisely the point, and is nothing more than manufacturing
departments have experienced for several generations. If ABM threatens to ‘go and ruin
more life in the plush offices of support staff’ (to quote a reviewer of an earlier version of
this paper), that is no problem at all. That this may be achieved at the cost of degrading
36
The problem originates in the concept of activity on which both ABC and ABM are
founded. Neither can function unless an activity is defined as a routine act performed
‘for’ the cost-object. Whilst certain services approximate to this pattern, it is clearly
flawed and myopic as a total view of the work of staff departments. Strategic
developments in the supply chain, in human resources, in marketing capability - and even
capitalist enterprise. None of them, however, would qualify as activities as the term is
defined within ABC and ABM. Although the staff functions of the modern corporation
are as susceptible as any other human activity to pretentious inflation in the cause of
individual and group self interest, it would be hard to find a successful company which
consists solely of a core function backed up by routine services. Yet this is the picture
assumed in ABM.
The threat posed by ABM to the functionality of the staff department is illustrated by the
contrast between the treatment of the purchasing function in modern textbooks and that in
favour the activity-based approach since the purchasing application has become a
favourite illustration of its potential. The differences are striking. Where purchasing
textbooks emphasise the potential for adding value through the such activities as co-
ordinating supply and production schedules and joint customer- supplier development
services. Whilst some of the claims made for ‘supply chain management’ may well be
inflated, and whilst there may be a gulf between purchasing prescription and practice, it is
hard, in the light of this comparison, to see the ABM approach as anything other than
tunnel-vision cost-cutting. Because its conception of activities cannot encompass the non-
routine work involved in the management of the supply chain - still less the work
involved in developing the capability for doing so - ABM, where it is implemented, may
37
succeed in imposing budgetary restrictions on the purchasing function which reduce it to
the routine service stereotype assumed at the outset. In this aspect, it could be argued
against ABM that it makes short-termism respectable, a conclusion which is truly ironic
in view of Johnson and Kaplan’s (1987) strictures against the short-termism encouraged
Endnotes
1
The time-scale of these developments varies enormously from company to company. On the one hand
companies such as Renold Chains were experimenting with standard cost systems before the First World war
(Bougen, 1989). On the other hand, some prominent UK motors companies were still operating in ignorance
2
When practiced by Japanese managers, apparently, direct labour-based absorption costing posesses the
important virtue of encouraging automation (Hiromoto, 1988; Dugdale, 1990). In the USA, on the other
hand, it merely fosters a form of financial gamesmanship in which reductions in direct labour are made for
the purpose of redirecting overhead elsewhere in the company (Johnson and Kaplan, 1987).
3
In much of this paper, ABC and ABM are written about as if they were active subjects. This is simply a
shorthand for such usages such as ‘the advocates of ABC’ which would become awkward with repetition. It
should not be read as an attempt to reify either technique as a social agent (cf. Mouzelis, 1995, p. 15) -
4
In its full philosophical sense, of course, realism refers to the belief that there are objects which exist
independently of our perception of them. In this sense, all costs are intellectual constructs sustained by social
convention. The exposition in the main text takes direct costs to be real relative to the practice of cost
5
These claims are also attacked from the position that there are ‘different costs for different purposes’, but
that is a question of the different cost objects or decisions to which costs can be attached, not whether these
6
An example is the argument against the allocation of indirect costs on a direct labour cost base quoted from
Wilson and Chua below (see also Johnson and Kaplan, 1987). In logic, the fact that direct labour accounts
for only a small proportion of total costs in many modern production processes is irrelevant to its
38
appropriateness as an allocation base. If the merit of an allocation base were determined by its magnitude as
a proportion total costs, the value of bought-in materials and components would be the automatic choice in
many factories. Really the argument rests on a gut feeling that the destination of large chunks of overhead
cannot possibly depend on the distribution of a small element of total cost. Whilst not quite a claim of know
the truth of overhead allocation, this is still a claim to know the territory in which it lies.
7
The terminology is intended to evoke Bhaskar’s (1986) realist social theory, in which the real is taken to
consist of ‘mechanisms’ which manifest themselves, not directly, but through the empirical. Thus in ABC
the simplicities of a real ‘mechanism’ (Products consume activities and activities cause costs) are assumed to
8
In practice, the labour of superintendance is often excluded, and distributed arbitrarily amongst other
activities (e.g. Innes and Mitchell, 1990). The point made in the main text is that some of the labour counted
9
Where, as is to be hoped, there are synergies between activities, the isolation of the value added by any one
of them is actually impossible, for the same reason that it is impossible to assign income to particular assets.
10
It was a difference in the tacit assumptions as to the variability of indirect costs gave rise to a recent
controversy over ABC. To Piper and Whalley (1990, 1991) ABC fails to model cost behaviour because
overhead costs do not necessarily vary with activity volume. Cooper’s reply (1990b) was that ABC is a
resource consumption model, not an expenditure model. He then added the immediate corollary that
‘management must take actions to bring spending in line with resource consumption.’ In other words, ABC
is an expenditure model, and it correctly models the variation of indirect costs with activity volume only
11
Similar claims have appeared from KPMG Management Consulting (Morrow and Hazell, 1992) and from
a senior consultant with Coopers and Lybrand (Hixon, 1995). A quotation from Hixon is given on page 18.
12
Given the complex interdependencies of modern organizations, the question of whether activities are
performed ‘for’ other functions is one for rhetoric and argument rather than appeal to the ‘facts’. At the
margin, this may mean that what qualifies as an activity may have much to do with the relative negotiating
39
13
Ironically, there are signs that TCO may be in the process of reinvention as an extension of ABC, in which
the costs of the activities associated with ownership are traced to individual suppliers (Clarke, 1994).
14
I am indebted to Rolland Munro for this observation.
References
Acton, D.D. and Cotton, W.D.J. (1997) Activity-based costing in a university setting.
Journal of Cost Management, (USA), Mar/Apr., Vol. 11, No. 2, pp. 32-38.
Adams, M. (1996) Activity-Based Costing (ABC) and the Life-Insurance Industry.
Service Industries Journal, Vol. 16, No., pp. 511-526.
Aird, B. (1996) Activity-based cost management in health care - another fad?
International Journal of Health Care Quality Assurance, (UK), Vol. 9, No. 4, pp. 16-19
Argenti, J. (1968) Corporate Planning: a Practical Guide. London. Allen & Unwin.
Argyris, C. and Kaplan, R.S. (1994) Implementing New Knowledge: the Case of
Activity-Based Costing. Accounting Horizons, Vol. 8, No. 3, Sept. pp. 83-105.
Armitage, H. and Russell, G. (1993) Activity-based management information: TQM's
missing link. CMA Magazine, (Canada), Vol. 67, No. 2 Mar. p. 7.
Armstrong, P. (1984) Competition between the Organisational Professions and the
Evolution of Management Control Strategies. Chapter 7 in Thompson, K (Ed.) Work,
Employment and Unemployment Milton Keynes, Open University Press. pp., 97-120.
Armstrong, P. (1985) Changing Management Control Strategies - the role of competition
between Accountancy and other organisational professions. Accounting, Organizations
and Society. 10, 2 pp. 129-148
Armstrong, P. (1991) Contradictions and Social Dynamics in the Capitalist Agency
Relationship. Accounting, Organizations and Society Vol. 16, No 1, pp. 1-25.
Armstrong, P. (1994) Corporate Control in Large British Companies: the intersection of
management accounting and industrial relations in postwar Britain. Chapter 8 in
Accounting as a Social and Institutional Practice. Eds. Hopwood, A. and Miller, P.
Cambridge University Press. pp. 190-211.
Armstrong, P. (1995) Why do Accountants Write Plays About Direct Costing? Advances
in Public Interest Accounting Vol. 6. pp. 1-18.
Armstrong, P. in press Designer Accountability: the Managerial Semiotics Project.
Forthcoming in Critical Perspectives on Accounting.
Armstrong, P., Marginson, P., Edwards, P. and Purcell, J. (1996a) Budgetary Control And
The Labour Force: Findings From A Survey Of Large British Companies. Management
Accounting Research. Vol. 7 No 1. pp. 1-23.
Armstrong, P. and Tomes, A. (1996b) Art and Accountability: the Languages of Design
and Managerial Control. Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal. Vol. 9, No. 5.
pp. 114-125.
Armstrong, P., Marginson, P., Edwards, P. and Purcell, J. (1999) Accounting for
Insecurity. Forthcoming in Critical Perspectives on Accounting.
40
Atkinson, J. (1984) Manpower Strategies for Flexible Organizations Personnel
Management. August. pp. 28-31
Babad, Y.M., Balachandran, B.V. (1993) Cost Driver Optimization in Activity-Based
Costing. Accounting Review, Vol. 68, No., pp. 563-575.
Baily, P. and Farmer, D. (1990) Purchasing Principles and Management. London.
Pitman. (6th edition).
Banker, R.D. and Johnston, H.H. (1993) An Empirical Study of Cost Drivers in the
United-States Airline Industry. Accounting Review, Vol. 68, No. 3, pp. 576-601.
Bhaskar, R. (1986) Scientific Realism and Human Emancipation. London. Verso.
Bhimani, A. and Pigott, D. (1992) Implementing ABC: a Case Study of the
Organisational Consequences. Management Accounting Research, Vol. 3, pp. 119-132.
Borjesson, S. (1994) What Kind Of Activity-Based Information Does Your Purpose
Require - 2 Case Studies. International Journal of Operations & Production
Management, Vol.14, No.12, pp.79-99.
Bougen, P. (1989) The Emergence, Roles and Consequences of an Accounting-Industrial
Relations Interaction. Accounting, Organisations and Society. Vol 14. No. 3. pp. 203-234.
Braverman, H (1974) Labor and Monopoly Capital. New York. Monthly Review Press.
Burt, D.N., Norquist, W.E. and Anklesaria, J. (1990) Zero Based Pricing. Chicago Ill.
Probus Publishing.
Carr, L.P. and Ittner, C.D. (1992) Measuring the Cost of Ownership. Journal of Cost
Management. Fall pp. 42-51.
Cavatino, J.L. (1992) A Total Cost/Value Model for Supply Chain Competitiveness.
Journal of Business Logistics. Vol. 13, No. 2, pp. 285-301.
Child, J., Fores, M., Glover, I. and Lawrence, P. (1983) A Price to Pay? Professionalism
and Work Organisation in Britain and West Germany. Sociology, Vol 17, No 1 pp. 63-78
Chua, W.F. and Preston, A. (1994) Worrying about Acounting in Health Care
Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal. Vol 7 No 3 pp. 4-17.
Clarke P. and Bellis-Jones, R. (1996) Activity-based cost management in the management
of change. The TQM Magazine, (UK), Vol. 8, No 2, pp. 43-48
Clarke, P.J. (1994) Activity-based cost management Accountancy Ireland, (Ireland), Oct.
Vol. 26, No. 5, pp. 16-17.
Cochrane, A. (1993) From Financial Control to Strategic Management: the Changing
Face of Accountability in British Local Government. Accounting, Auditing and
Accountability Journal. Vol 6, No 3. pp 30-51
Cooper, R. and Kaplan, R.S. (1991) The Design of Cost Management Systems: Text,
Cases and Readings. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey. Prentice-Hall.
Cooper, R. (1990a) Implementing an Activity-Based Costing System. Journal of Cost
Management (Spring) pp. 33-42. Reprinted in Cooper and Kaplan (1991) pp. 386-395.
Cooper, R. (1990b) Explicating the Logic of ABC. Management Accounting (CIMA) Vol
68 No. 10. (Nov.) pp. 58-60.
Cooper, R., Kaplan, R.S., Maisel, L.S., Morrisey, E. and Oehm, R.M. (1992)
Implementing activity-Based Cost Management: Moving from Analysis to Action:
41
experiences at eight companies. Institute of Management Accountants (USA)/Peat
Marwick.
Curtown, Earl of (1960) Address to the 11th Summer School of the Institute of
Chartered Accountants, England and Wales. The Cost Accountant. Nov. pp. 394-401
Danilenko, G. (1994) Activity-Based Costing for Services - The Corporate Information
Center. Special Libraries, Vol.85, No.1, pp.24-29.
Datar, S. and Gupta, M. (1994) Aggregation, Specification and Measurement Errors in
Product Costing. Accounting Review, Vol.69, No.4, pp.567-591.
Dugdale, D. (1990) Costing Systems in Transition: a Review of Recent Developments.
Management Accounting (CIMA) Vol 68, No. 1. (Jan) pp. 38-41.
Ellram, L.M. (1993) Total Cost of Ownership: Element and Implementation.
International Journal of Purchasing and Materials Management. Vol. 29, No. 4, pp. 3-
11.
Ellram, L.M. (1995) Activity-Based Costing and Total Cost of Ownership: a Critical
Linkage. Journal of Cost Management, Vol. 8, No. 4. pp. 22-30.
Ellram, L.M. and Maltz, A.B. (1995) The Use of Total Cost of Ownership to Model the
Outsourcing Decision. The International Journal of Logistics Management. Vol. 6, No. 2,
p. 55.
Ellram, L.M. and Siferd, S.P. (1993) Purchasing: The Cornerstone of the Total Cost of
Ownership Concept. Journal of Business Logistics. Vol. 14 No 1.
Evans, H. and Ashworth, G. (1995) Activity-based management: moving beyond
adolescence. Management Accounting (CIMA), Vol. 73, No. 11, Dec. pp. 26-30.
Ezzamel, M. and Willmott, H. (1993) Corporate Governance and Financial
Accountability: Recent reforms in the UK Public Sector Accounting, Auditing and
Accountability Journal. Vol 6, No 3. pp 109-132
Freedman, M. (1976) The Search for Shelters Labor Markets, Segmentation and Shelters.
New York. Allanhead, Osman/Universal Books. Ch. 7. Reprinted as Ch. 4 pp. 55-66. in
in Thompson, K (ed.) Work, Employment and Unemployment. Milton Keynes, Open
University Press.
Gadde, L-E and Håkansson, H. (1993) Professional Purchasing. London. Routledge.
Gellner, E. (1970) Concepts and Society. Ch 2 pp. 18-49 in Wilson, B. R. (ed)
Rationality. Oxford. Blackwell.
Gordon, D.M., Edwards, R.C. and Reich, M. (1982) Segmented Work, Divided Workers:
the Historical Transformation of Labor in the United States. Cambridge. Cambridge
University Press.
Gray, A. and Jenkins, W. (1993) Codes of Accountability in the New Public Sector.
Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal. Vol 6, No 3. pp 52-67
Groot, T.L.C.M. (1997) When Activity-Based Management Leads to the Abolition of
Activity-Based Costing. Working paper. Vrije Universiteit. Quoted in Lindahl, F. W.
(1997) Activity-based costing implementation and adaptation. Human Resource
Planning, (USA), Vol. 20, No 2, pp. 62-66.
Hayes. R.H. and Abernathy, W.J. (1980) Managing Our Way to Economic Decline.
Harvard Business Review. July-Aug. pp 67-77.
42
Hiromoto, T. (1988) Another Hidden Edge: Japanese Management Accounting. Harvard
Business Review. Reprinted in Cooper and Kaplan (1991) pp. 461-465.
Hixon, M. (1995) Activity-based management: its purpose and benefits. Management
Accounting (CIMA), Vol. 73, No. 6, pp. 30-31.
Hobdy ,T., Thomson, J. and Sharman, P. (1994) Activity-based management at AT&T.
Management Accounting, (USA), Apr. Vol. 75, No. 10, pp. 35-39
Hollis, M. (1970) The Limits of Irrationality. Ch 10 in Wilson, B. R. (ed) Rationality.
Oxford. Blackwell.
Horngren, C.T. (1990) First Discussant. Journal of Management Accounting Research.
Fall. pp. 21-24.
Humphrey, C., Miller, P. and Scapens, R. (1993) Accountability and Accountable
Management in the UK Public Sector Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal.
Vol 6, No 3. pp 7-29
Innes, J. and Mitchell, F. (1990) Activity Based Costing: a Review with Case Studies.
London. The Chartered Institute of Management Accountants.
Innes, J. and Mitchell, F. (1990) Activity-Based Costing Research. Management
Accounting (CIMA) Vol 68 No. 5. (May) pp. 28-29.
Innes, J., Mitchell, F. and Cobb, I. (1992) Activity-Based Costing: Problems in Practice.
London. CIMA.
Jeans, M and Morrow, M (1989) The Practicalities of Using Activity-Based Costing.
Management Accounting. Nov. p. 42-44
Johnson, H.T. (1988) Activity-Based Information: a Blueprint for World-Class
Management Accounting. Management Accounting (US) June pp. 23-30. Reprinted in
Cooper and Kaplan (1991) pp. 257-266.
Johnson, H.T. and Kaplan, R.S. (1987) Relevance Lost: the Rise and Fall of Management
Acounting. Boston Massachusetts. Harvard Business School Press.
Kaplan, R.S. (1985) Accounting Lag: the Obsolescence of Cost Accounting Systems in
Clark, K.B., Hayes, R.H. and Lorenz, C.L. (Eds.) The Uneasy Alliance: Managing th
Productivity-Technology Dilemma. Reprinted in Cooper and Kaplan (1991). pp. 63-79.
Kaplan, R.S. (1987b) John Deere Component Works (A). Reprinted in Prentice-Hall. pp.
291-303.
Kaplan, R.S. (1987a) Regaining Relevance. Session 7 in Capettini, R. and Lang, D.K.
(eds.) Cost Accounting, Robotics and the New Manufacturing Environment. Edited papers
from the 1st Annual Management Accounting symposium. Sarasota, Florida . American
Accounting Association. pp. 7.1-7.29
Kaplan, R.S. (1988) One Cost System isn’t Enough. Harvard Business Review. Vol 68,
No. 1, pp. 61-66.
Kennedy, A. (1995) ABC Basics. Management Accounting (CIMA) June. pp. 23-24.
Lammert, T.B. and Ehrsam, R. (1987) The Human Element: the Real Challenge in
Modernising Cost Systems. Reprinted in Cooper and Kaplan (1991) pp. 445-449.
Laughlin, R., Broadbent, J. and Willing-Atherton, H. (1994) Recent Financial and
Administrative Changes in GP Practices in the UK: Initial Experiences and Effects.
Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal. Vol 7 No 3. pp. 96-124
43
Lawrence, S., Manzurul, A. and Lowe, A. (1994) The Great Experiment: Financial
Management Reform in the NZ Health Sector Accounting, Auditing and Accountability
Journal. Vol 7 No 3. pp. 68-95
Lawson, R.A. (1994) Activity-based costing systems for hospital management. CMA
Magazine, (Canada), June, Vol. 68, No. 5, pp. 31-35
Lere, J.C. and Saraph, J.V. (1995) Activity-based costing for purchasing managers' cost
and pricing determinations. International Journal of Purchasing and Materials
Management, (USA), Autumn, Vol. 31, No. 4, pp. 25-31
Letza, S.R. and Gadd, K. (1994) Activity-based costing as the method of choice for total
quality organizations? The TQM Magazine, (UK), Vol 6 No 5, pp. 57-63
Lindahl, F. W. (1997) Activity-based costing implementation and adaptation. Human
Resource Planning, (USA), Vol. 20, No 2, pp. 62-66.
Lyne, S. and Friedman, A. (1996) Activity-based techniques and the 'new management
accountant' Management Accounting, (CIMA), Jul/Aug. Vol. 74, No. 7, pp. 34-35.
Marshall, B. (1995) Activity-based costing at Wavin. Management Accounting, (UK),
May, Vol. 73, No. 5, pp. 28 -30.
Merton, R.K. (1940) Bureaucratic Structure and Personality. Social Forces. Vol. 18, pp.
560-568.
Miller, P. and O'Leary, T. (1987) Accounting and the Construction of the Governable
Person. Accounting, Organisations and Society. Vol 12. No 3. pp. 235-265.
Morrow, M. and Connolly, T. (1991) The Emergence of Activity-Based Budgeting.
Management Accounting (UK) February. pp. 38-41.
Morrow, M. and Hazell, M. (1992) Activity Mapping for Business Process Redesign.
Management Accounting, (UK), Feb Vol. 70, No. 2, pp. 36-38.
Mouzelis, N. (1995) Sociological Theory: What Went Wrong? Diagnosis and Remedies.
London. Routledge.
Noreen, E. (1991) Conditions Under Which Activity-Based Costing Systems Provide
Relevant Costs. Journal of Management Accounting Research. Vol. 3, Fall. pp. 159-168.
Ogden, S. (1995) Transforming Frameworks of Accountability: the Case of Water
Privatisation. Accounting, Organisations and Society, Vol 20 Nos 2/3 pp. 193-218
Parkinson, C.N. (1965) Parkinson's Law or the Pursuit of Progress. Harmondsworth.
Penguin.
Pattison, D.D. and Gavan, Arendt C. (1994) Activity-based costing: it doesn't work all the
time Management Accounting, (USA), Apr. Vol. 75, No. 10, pp. 55-62
Piore, M.J. and Sabel, C.F. (1984) The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for
Prosperity. New York. Basic Books.
Piper, J.A. and Walley, P. (1990) Testing ABC Logic. Management Accounting (CIMA)
Vol 68 No. 8. (Sept.) pp. 37, 42.
Piper, J.A. and Walley, P. (1991) ABC Relevance Not Found. Management Accounting
(CIMA) Vol 69 No. 3. (March.) pp. 42, 44, 54.
Roehm, H.A., Critchfield, M.A. and Castellano, J.F. (1992) Yes, ABC Works With
Purchasing, Too. Journal of Accountancy, Vol.174, No.5, pp.58-62.
44
Ruhl, J.M. and Bailey, T.A. (1994) Activity-based costing for the total business. The CPA
Journal, (USA), Feb. Vol. 64, No. 2, pp. 34-38
Saunders, M. (1997) Strategic Purchasing and Supply Chain Management. 2nd ed.
London. Pitman
Sephton, M. and Ward, T. (1990) ABC in Retail Financial Services Management
Accounting (CIMA) April. pp 32-33
Shields, M.D. (1995) An Experimental Analysis of Firm’s Experiences with Activity-
Based Costing. Journal of Management Accounting Research. Vol. 7, pp. 148-166.
Shields, M.D. and Young, S.M. (1989) A Behavioural Model for Implementing Cost
Management Systems. Journal of Cost Management (Winter) pp. 17-27. Reprinted in
Cooper and Kaplan (1991) pp. 450-460.
Skinner, W. (1985) Manufacturing - the Formidable Competitive Weapon. New York.
John Wiley.
Smytka, D.L. and Clemens, M.W. (1993) Total Cost Supplier Selection Model.
International Journal of Purchasing and Materials Management. Vol. 29, No. 1 (Winter),
p. 42.
Staubus, G.J. (1990) Activity Costing Twenty Years On. Managment Accounting
Research. Vol. 1, pp. 249-264.
Steimer, T.E. (1990) Activity-based accounting for total quality. Management
Accounting, (USA), Oct. Vol. 72, No. 4, pp. 39-42
Thomas, M. F. and Mackey, J.T. (1994) Activity-based cost variances for just-in-times.
Management Accounting, (USA), Apr. Vol. 75, No. 10, pp. 49-54
Thomas, W.I. (1957) The Unadjusted Girl: with Cases and Standpoint for Behaviour
Analysis. Little Brown.
Torrington, D and Mackay, L. (1986) Will Consultants Take over the Personnel
Function? Personnel Management. February. pp. 34-7.
Tyson S. (1985) Is this the Very Model of a Modern Personnel Manager? Personnel
Management, Vol. 7, No. 5, pp. 10-16
West, D.A., Hicks, L.L., Balas, E.A. and West, T.D. (1996) Profitable Capitation
Requires Accurate Costing. Nursing Economics, Vol.14, No.3, p.162.
Wilson, R.M.S. and Chua, W.F. (1993) Management Accounting: Method and Meaning
London. Chapman and Hall
Winch, P. (1970) Understanding a Primitive Society. Ch 5 pp. 78-111 in Wilson, B. R.
(ed) Rationality. Oxford. Blackwell.
45