Journal 1
Journal 1
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Palgrave Macmillan Journals is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access
to Eastern Economic Journal
Richard Carson
Carleton University
INTRODUCTION
421
quality change affects the slope of its demand curve, the firm will set a level o
that leaves this slope flatter than social optimization would require. In thi
firms do not differentiate their products enough. Thus the two sources of inef
in long-run equilibrium are the traditional tendency to price above marginal co
the tendency of each firm to under-differentiate its product. Under the add
assumption mentioned above, free entry and exit produces too many firms, th
number, or too few, depending on whether the tendency for greater compet
reduce product differentiation by already-existing firms has a greater, equal, o
impact on welfare than the increase in product diversity brought about by the
ance of a new product. Without the tendency to under-differentiate, entry w
socially efficient.
Finally, suppose product-specialized inputs are attached to specific firms,
than mobile between them. Then rent is not included in opportunity cost, and
will earn positive profit in long-run equilibrium. Because of free entry and e
profit will equal the rent on its specialized inputs. It will maximize its profit,
to say that it will find a price, output, and quality combination that maximiz
rent. Provided every firm produces efficiently, the industry will therefore re
same long-run equilibrium, with respect to outputs, prices, and quality levels,
product-specialized inputs are mobile between firms.1 If a specialized input is
firms compete for this input, and the winner must pay the maximized rent in
bid successfully for the input. Rent is therefore included in opportunity cost.
case, a monopolistic competitor must set price, quality, and output to maxim
difference between its revenue and its cost measured exclusive of rent, and this
ence is the rent on its specialized inputs.
In this paper, firms are allowed to vary quality as well as price and
monopolistic competition with quality variation is defined by three basic
[Chamberlin, 1933; Dorfman and Steiner, 1954] . (a). Owing to product di
between firms, each firm faces downward-sloping demand when quality
stant, (b). In the long-run, the industry reaches a Nash equilibrium [Na
is self-enforcing, in the sense that no one firm acting on its own can incr
by moving away from it. As a result, we can treat each firm as setting pr
independently of the others, (c). Because of free entry and exit, includ
mobility of inputs between firms, each monopolistic competitor maxim
zero in long-run equilibrium. This leads to the Chamberlinian outcome, w
erties noted above, which has been controversial [eg., Demsetz, 1959, 19
1985, 1989]. I shall outline some of the historical controversy below
relation to the present paper, although in order to do this, I must first s
model.
To this end, I shall use capital letters - X, Y, andZ - to designate speci
and small letters to denote output quantities of these products. Suppose
product monopolistic competitor sells x units of a differentiated produ
assumption that the income effects of its output and quality changes are
EQUILIBRIUM QUALITY
(3) Pr = MCr.
FIGURE 1
EQUILIBRIUM QUANTITY
(5a) px=AC*x>
while maintaining that this may be due entirely to the existence of rent on p
specialized inputs and therefore misleading. The goal here is to find condition
which rent-exclusive average cost, or ACx, will be minimized or upward-slopi
equilibrium, in the sense that AC^ > 0.
With this in mind, we note that (Px - P ) > (ACRx - AC ) must hold in
run equilibrium for the firm supplying X, where ACy - C(x,0,r)/x. Sin
ACRx, (Px - Py) < (ACRx-ACy) would imply that Py > Ac"y is possible and the
that positive economic profit could be earned in supplying Y. The additional a
tion mentioned above is then that at least one product, Z, is available, with p
which meets three conditions. First, Z is supplied under free entry and exit, w
result that Pz = ACRz in equilibrium, where ACRz is the rent-inclusive average
Z. In particular, Z may be supplied under perfect or monopolistic competition.
Z can be used together with Y, and this combination competes with X in the
Z is therefore assumed to be an imperfect substitute for X, and the same is t
other products that compete in the same industry with Z. An expansion of the
of these substitutes which puts downward pressure on Pz is also assumed to pu
ward pressure on Px.
Third, a supplier of Z is at least as cost effective as the supplier of Xin addin
to Y. If the firm supplying X would supply Y instead, its average cost would fal
Increasing q from 0 to q* raises the firm's price from Py to Px and its rent-in
average cost from ACy to ACRx. Thus suppose the supplier of X is producing an
at which ACRx is downward-sloping and that demand is such that Px = ACRx. T
meet the third condition, a supplier of Z must be able to produce an output of
at which
(7) ACRzi(ACRx-ACy\
when output units of Z are scaled in such a way that Pz =
bread example, suppose an entrepreneur markets a spread,
of the generic bread, Y, but clashes with the taste of the d
result, the combination of generic bread with spread compe
bread.
When the third condition is met and the Y-industry is
supplier of X must produce on a scale that is efficient for
with the composite good whose units consist of a unit of Z
average cost equals (ACRz + P). Any other output puts X at
suppose x is set where Px = ACRx and (Px - Py) > (ACRx -ACy) o
But then long-run equilibrium can not prevail, since equatio
is possible for any product, Z, meeting the above three cond
prospect of quasi-rents will attract entry of new competitor
Z competes, and this will put downward pressure on Pz an
ACRx or ACRz, since this entry would be foreseen. By the
(8) Py = MCy=ACy,
or at which AC = C(x,09r)/x reaches its minimum
conditions hold, differentiating a monopolistic com
its equilibrium output, since a firm supplying Y als
minimum. In addition, this is the only output at whic
specialized input equals this input's rent- that is at which
If there is no product with the properties of Z, l
where (Px-P)> (ACRx-AC ). But then there is an in
such a product, which will be viable over the long ru
run, as long as (Px - P ) > (ACRx - AC ), which impli
assumptions behind equation (7). If Z is also supplied
with its own generic alternative, W, the above analys
and X. That is, if we reverse the roles of X and Z an
third condition then holds - z* will be where AC w r
Finally, while the existence of Z allows us to ancho
equilibrium output where AC is minimized, this e
result that equilibrium under monopolistic compe
rent-exclusive average cost is minimized or upward-
on the firm's specialized input may be maximized in
FURTHER RESULTS
FIGURE 2
welfare gain or loss resulting from this is small, the same will be true of the b
stealing effect.
As a result, entry would then be socially efficient if suppliers were able to
all of Pq - or if q were fixed, as in the classic paper by Dixit and Stiglitz [1977]
cient entry arises only because in long-run equilibrium, P ^ MC . A given
may cause q to rise or fall, but as rents are squeezed by greater competition,
a tendency for q to tend to zero, and therefore for the unique element in pr
differentiation to decline and eventually vanish. Thus whether and how entry
this industry departs from the socially optimal level depends on whether and h
tendency for greater competition to reduce product differentiation by already-
firms has a greater or lesser impact on welfare than the increase in product di
brought about by the appearance of a new product with a new unique attribu
ever, if entry changes relative input prices and there are positive fixed or set-
in supplying Y, entry could alter the ratio of fixed to variable cost at any outp
thereby change the output at which C(x,0,r)/x reaches its minimum. This outp
either rise or fall, but the resulting effect on welfare would not be taken into
by an entrant, and the tendency to produce where Px > MCx would also be a so
inefficient entry.
CONCLUSION
NOTES
I wish to thank Erwei Yin, Han Li, and two anonymous referees for assistance or h
ments. Sole responsibility for errors rests with me. An earlier version of this paper
at the Southwestern Economic Association meetings in Corpus Christi on March 17,
1. An industry operating under monopolistic competition may have multiple equilibria
the equilibria will be the same regardless of whether product-specialized inputs a
tween firms, provided all firms produce efficiently.
2. In terms of earlier notation, the slope of Px(x) is P^ + Pxqq'(x) + Pxf'(x), where q'(x) an
derivatives of q{x) and r(x) with respect to x. We have seen that both P^ and Pxr are po
q and r are positive (equations (1) and (2) above), and q'{x) and/or r'(x) could be posit
scale economies in supplying q and/or r. Thus P^ + P^q'ix) + Pxrr'(x) could be non-n
Px(x\ q(x\ and r(x) are the profit-maximizing values of Px, q, and r at each given x, Px
as Demsetz' [1959] mutatis mutandis average revenue curve, MAR.
3. Demsetz [1972] only sketches his argument, but his basic idea is that, in comparing
with perfect competition, CRx is an inappropriate measure of cost. As noted below in t
is because consuming a "branded" rather than a "non-branded" version of a product
consuming X rather than Y above - saves the buyer certain costs. These are "cost
need to be incurred to ascertain the quality of the product, to establish prestigious con
some way other than by consuming branded commodities, and to be confident of c
responsibility should the product be defective in some respect. The consumer can r
costs by purchasing differentiated products, since product homogeneity makes it m
both to discern clear lines of responsibility for product quality and to consume con
[595-596] However, if X were to disappear from the market, it is unclear whether r
of X with an equal number of units of Y and incurring these costs would be a utilit
strategy for buyers. Instead, they might be better off simply adjusting their consump
Moreover, it is not obvious that product homogeneity must make it more difficult to d
lines of responsibility for product quality. Instead of these costs, I assume the exis
product, Z, introduced below.
4. Margolis [1989, 199].
5 Write C(x,q,r) as C = B(q,r) + V(x,q,r), where B is fixed cost - or cost that is independent of
output - and V(x,q,r) is cost that varies with x. We then have MCx = Vx, the partial derivative of V
with respect to x. The returns to scale embedded in C - or the firm's elasticity of production - are
given by S = ACJMCx = ClxCx = (B + V)/xVx = (R + 1)SV, where R = Bl V is the ratio of fixed to
variable cost, and Sv = V/xVx are the returns to scale embedded in V. Thus if increases in q raise
(1 + R) or Sy, they will also raise S, provided they do not reduce the other of these two components
by a larger percentage amount. Intuitively, however, it seems more natural to assume that
differentiating a product by giving it a unique attribute would reduce economies of scale, or at least
not increase them, although all three outcomes are possible.
REFERENCES
1989. 199-209.
Spence, A. M. Monopoly, quality, and regulation. Bell Journal of Economics, Autumn 1975, 4