Trade in Services and Human Development: A First Look at The Links
Trade in Services and Human Development: A First Look at The Links
Trade in Services and Human Development: A First Look at The Links
No. 268
March 2011
The Working Paper series is a continuation of the formerly named Discussion Paper series;
the numbering of the papers continued without interruption or change. ADBI’s working
papers reflect initial ideas on a topic and are posted online for discussion. ADBI encourages
readers to post their comments on the main page for each working paper (given in the
citation below). Some working papers may develop into other forms of publication.
Suggested citation:
Shepherd, B., and G. Pasadilla. 2011. Trade in Services and Human Development: A First
Look at the Links. ADBI Working Paper 268. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute.
Available: http://www.adbi.org/working-paper/2011/03/10/4485.trade.services.human.dev/
Tel: +81-3-3593-5500
Fax: +81-3-3593-5571
URL: www.adbi.org
E-mail: [email protected]
Abstract
Some services directly produce outputs that are important for human development, such as
basic human services. Many other services are important inputs into the production and
distribution of goods that are necessary for human development purposes. A more efficient
services sector should mean that such goods and services can be made available to poor
people more cost effectively and more broadly. In line with this reasoning, we find in the data
that less restrictive services trade policies are associated with better human development
outcomes across a range of sectors. Appropriate services trade liberalization can therefore
promote human development directly through improved outcomes, in addition to indirectly
effects through the income channel.
Contents
1. Introduction .................................................................................................................... 1
4. Conclusion ................................................................................................................... 26
References ......................................................................................................................... 28
1. INTRODUCTION
The services sector is becoming increasingly important in modern economies: In many of the
most developed, it can represent two thirds or even three quarters of all economic activity.
International trade in services is also increasing in importance, and has been growing more
rapidly than goods trade over recent years (World Trade Organization (WTO), 2008). It has
also proved more resilient to the global financial crisis and resulting trade collapse (Borchert
and Mattoo, 2009).
Existing work on services trade has largely concentrated on two questions that do not
directly relate to human development. The first is the determinants of international trade
flows. Using methodologies such as the gravity model, researchers have investigated the
range of factors that can promote or inhibit trade in services. In general, they have found that
many of the factors known to impact goods trade—geographical distance, market size, and
cultural or historical factors—also exert a strong influence on services trade (Kimura and
Lee, 2006).
The second strand of research on services trade has examined its implications for economic
efficiency. These studies tend to have shown that a more restrictive services environment is
associated with less efficient and lower-quality service provision, inefficient resource
allocation, and slower economic growth (Arvis et al., 2010; Eschenbach and Hoekman,
2006; and Findlay and Warren, 2000). Because services are often important inputs in the
production of manufactured goods, an inefficient services sector can have economy-wide
implications—including a loss of competitiveness for manufacturers and exporters (Arnold,
Mattoo, and Narciso, 2008).
It has long been recognized that services trade can influence economic and social outcomes
through a variety of mechanisms. On the one hand, the economic gains from reform are
significant (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. (OECD), 2003;
World Bank, 2002), and thus have the potential to promote human development by
increasing per capita incomes. 1 We refer to this linkage as the income channel. However,
there has been considerable controversy as to possible incompatibilities between openness
to services trade and the provision of human development-related services such as
electricity, water, and telecommunications. More broadly, a tension has emerged in the
human development literature between the economic case for liberalizing services markets,
and a perceived social case for maintaining stricter regulations in order to promote human
development objectives (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD),
2005; United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), 2006).
This paper will bring some of the first empirical evidence to bear on the direct links between
services sector regulation and human development, going beyond the income channel. From
an economic point of view, there are good reasons to believe that services liberalization
might be positively—not negatively—associated with at least some human development
outcomes. The reason is that more efficient provision of public and private services that are
important for development can lead to lower prices for consumers, and more widespread
availability of human development-related goods and services. For instance, Chile’s
liberalization and privatization of its telecommunications sector, along with its use of “smart”
subsidies, led to a strong increase in availability of telecommunications services, and thus an
increase in the general population’s ability to access information and participate in political
and social life (Wellenius, 2002).
A second example of the links between openness to services trade and human development
outcomes is the role that the distribution sector plays in reducing the cost of moving vital
goods to the hinterland of poor countries (Sarley, Allain, and Akkihal, 2005). Examples
include basic foodstuffs, medicines, and mosquito nets. Only with a relatively well-developed
and efficient distribution sector is it possible to ensure that these types of products reach
1
That per capita income is an important determinant of overall human development outcomes is reflected in the
fact that the Human Development Index includes income as one of its components.
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
those who need them at lowest possible private and public cost. For instance, (Sarley, Allain,
and Akkihal, 2005) found that the logistics cost of moving bed nets from port to hinterland in
Liberia amounts to nearly half the cost of the product. Reducing the logistics cost wedge
clearly has great potential to help bring more bed nets to those who need them.
In this paper, we examine the association between human development and services trade
using simple nonparametric and parametric regression techniques. Our approach is to use
an indicator of human development as the dependent variable, and (at least) per capita
income and a measure of services sector policy restrictions as the independent variables.
Our measures of policy restrictiveness vary at the sector level, so we run separate
regressions using sector-specific measures of human development. Controlling for gross
domestic product (GDP) per capita means that we take account of the fact that it is an
important determinant of human development, and that it tends to be strongly inversely
correlated with service sector restrictiveness. We face formidable data constraints, however,
and are generally unable to include a wide range of other control variables due to small
sample size. The best we can do is to pool observations from three sectors, and use country
and sector fixed effects to control for other influences. Our results should therefore be
interpreted as providing a first indication of some important correlations in the data. In
particular, they should be interpreted in terms of associations between variables rather than
as evidence of causal links.
The paper proceeds as follows. In the next section, we discuss our methodology and data in
more detail. The section after that presents and discusses our results. We cover education,
distribution, engineering, and telecommunications services, as well as pooled results across
all sectors. The final section concludes with some policy implications and suggestions for
further research.
2
Ideally, we would also like to include health services in the above list. However, data constraints mean that it is
currently impossible to do so. The appendix, instead, discusses the human development dilemma involved in
health services, and gives a somewhat more descriptive analysis of possible correlation of health services with
human development outcomes such as equity and access.
2
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
For each of these hypotheses, our dependent variable is a particular measure of human
development performance. Most data are sourced from the World Bank’s World
Development Indicators and the Human Development Report. For data on democracy and
political voice and accountability, we use Freedom House and the World Governance
Indicators respectively. As our main independent variable, we use sector-specific measures
of policy restrictiveness sourced from the Australian Productivity Commission (APC). 3 These
data are currently available for a single year only (2000), which we take as our base year for
all empirical work. The database includes two main measures per sector, each of which is a
numerical summary of a wide range of underlying policy information. The first (“domestic”)
index represents the entry barriers and ongoing cost burdens to which domestic firms in a
particular sector are subject. The second (“foreign”) index contains the same information in
respect of foreign firms. The difference between the two represents the extent to which trade
policy is discriminatory vis-à-vis overseas operators.
Our methodology proceeds in two steps. First, we use a common nonparametric technique,
the multivariate Locally Weighted Scatterplot Smoother, to examine graphically the
correlations among the variables of interest. The advantage of this method is that it allows us
to analyze the relationship between the dependent and independent variables without
imposing any particular functional form. It proceeds by running an ordinary least squares
(OLS) regression separately for each data point, using a centered 80% sample of the
original data as an estimating window. In the second step of our methodology, we run
standard OLS regressions using the same independent and dependent variables to confirm
the impressions given by the nonparametric regressions.
3
The Restrictions on Trade in Services Database is available online at http://www.pc.gov.au/research/
researchmemorandum/servicesrestriction
4
We use restrictions on tertiary education services. The reason for this choice is that the collected restrictions on
tertiary education across countries in the study by the Australian Productivity Commission are more
comprehensive, while those for elementary and secondary education services are incomplete. The sample
consists of 20 countries.
3
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
discussed above. Finally, because education increases social and political awareness, it
should help develop a more robust democracy. The converse of the above is that restrictions
in services trade, therefore, restrict democracy, restrain income growth, and dampen the
overall achievement of better human development.
Unlike the other service sectors used in the rest of this paper, the APC study provides a
breakdown of restrictions in education services trade by mode of supply. To take advantage
of this wealth of information, we regress each of the modal restrictions on the different
human development outcomes to understand which of the mode of supply restrictions
exercise greater influence on human development. We also made a simple average of the
different modal restriction indices to come up with a foreign restriction index, 5 which we also
regress against each of the other chosen dependent variables to make the results for
education services comparable with those of other service sectors below. But unlike the rest
of the paper, we do not examine the domestic restriction index’s effect on human
development outcomes because data on domestic modal restrictions in the original APC
study on education services are highly incomplete. 6
The results show strong links between selected human development indicators and
restrictions in education services. Significantly, of the four modes of supply, restrictions on
commercial presence appear to have greater influence in affecting human development
outcomes than restrictions in cross-border trade, consumption abroad, or movements of
natural persons.
Nonparametric estimates using the HDI education index 7 show that foreign restrictions on
commercial presence in education services have a more pronounced negative effect than
restrictions on other modes of supply. Figure 1 shows that while restriction indices on
consumption abroad, cross-border supply, and movement of natural persons have
ambiguous relationships with education outcomes, the relationship in the case of commercial
presence restrictions is clearly negative. Using the overall HDI index yields similar results as
shown in Figure 1.
5
The limitation with taking the simple average of the modes of supply restrictions is that each of the modes is
assumed to have equal weight or importance in the overall restrictions to trade in education services.
Nonetheless, we try this simple method to be consistent with the rest of the paper, which uses overall foreign
restriction indices.
6
For details of the restriction index construction for education services, see Nguyen-Hong and Wells (2003).
7
The HDI education index is comprised of literacy rates and school enrolment rates.
4
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Table 1 corroborates the statistically strong negative correlation between foreign restrictions
on commercial presence and the HDI. 8 Per capita GDP (in log form) strongly and positively
correlates with the HDI indices, while restrictions on the commercial presence mode of
supplying education services correlate negatively. The correlation is slightly weaker with the
HDI than with the HDI education index, which is to be expected in light of the broader range
of influences for which the former accounts. We also regress the simple average of the
modal restrictions, the foreign restriction index, on the HDI and the HDI education index, but
this yields no statistically significant results. This perhaps reflects the fact that the three other
modes of supply—consumption abroad, cross-border, and movement of natural persons—
have been found to have insignificant relationships with the HDI indices.
8
The HDI is comprised of both education and health indicators. Education indicators include enrolment and
literacy rates, while health indicators include life expectancy and income.
5
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
We next tried other human development indicators like per capita income and a democracy
index as dependent variables. Non-parametric estimates with the democracy index and log
per capita GDP as dependent variables yield a different result from that of HDI indices. In
these non-parametric regressions, all modes of supply restrictions show a significantly
negative correlation with per capita income (Figure 2) and a positive correlation with the
democracy index. The democracy index represents a worsening of democratic conditions as
the index rises, hence the positive relationship with education services restrictions (Figure
3).
6
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Data Source: UNDP (2005); World Bank (2002); Nguyen-Hong and Wells (2003).
7
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Data Source: UNDP (2005); World Bank (2002); Nguyen-Hong and Wells (2003).
Table 2 validates the results from the non-parametric estimates. 9 Least squares regression
results show that all modes of supply restrictiveness indices have negative signs and strong
statistical significance. Regressions with the democracy index as the dependent variable
likewise yields a significantly positive correlation. The result shows that greater restriction on
education services, in all modes of supply, is correlated with a worsening of democracy.
We also tried regressing poverty rates, the Gini inequality index, and the cost of tertiary
9
We are conscious that the per capita GDP regressions exclude a number of variables usually included in
income and growth regressions. The reason is our very small sample size. These results should be taken as
indicative only.
8
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
education on the restriction indices. The poverty rates regressions yielded no statistically
significant correlation with any of the restriction indices for education services. This is
surprising as one would immediately associate greater provision and efficiency of education
services with opening opportunities to a wider population and thus reducing poverty, but the
result is not sufficiently conclusive. One reason might be that we are using restrictions in the
tertiary education sector, due to unavailability of data for the more poverty-relevant primary
and secondary sectors. Using the Gini coefficient as the dependent variable yielded
significant results for restrictions in commercial presence, but with a positive sign. This
means that, instead of education supplied via commercial presence reducing inequality, it
instead worsens it. Again, this might be linked to our use of tertiary education data. The
regression of cost of education, 10 however, yielded a significant negative correlation with
restrictions on commercial presence. That is, education services that are open to foreign
commercial presence are associated with a lower cost of education.
Table 2: Regressions on Income and Democracy
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
Dependent
Log of gross domestic product (GDP) per capita Democracy Index
Variable:
10
The cost of education is represented by expenditure per student in tertiary education as a percentage of per
capita GDP. Poverty rates are the percentage of the population living below $1.25/day. For the poverty
equation, we used tobit regression due to the many zeros in the dependent variable representing developed
country situations.
9
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Notes: All regressions are estimated using ordinary least squares. Standard errors are reported in parentheses.
Statistical significance is indicated by: * (10%), ** (5%), and *** (1%).
Data Source: Freedom House (www.freedomhouse.org) for the Democracy Index; World Development Indicators
(WDI) online database of the World Bank for GDP per capita and population growth; and Nguyen-Hong and Wells
(2003) for the foreign restrictiveness indices in higher education.
Using individual components of the HDI as dependent variables, however, surprisingly did
not yield the predicted results. For example, regressions with life expectancy, adult literacy
rates, and gross enrolment in tertiary education as dependent variables did not give
significant correlations with the restrictiveness index. Neither did restrictions in education
services show a correlation with the size of the college-educated labor force. However,
restrictions in consumption abroad (mode 2), cross-border supply (mode 1), and movement
of natural persons (mode 4) are negatively correlated with the life satisfaction index (Table
3). 11
In summary, our results show that restrictions on education services are not only associated
with poorer human development results, but also that some restrictions on modes of supply
have a greater impact than others. In particular, it appears that restrictions on commercial
presence take on greater importance for human development than restrictions on other
11
Detailed regression results used in Table 3 are available from the authors upon request.
10
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
modes of supply. But for democracy and per capita income, all modes of supply restrictions
are significantly associated with these outcomes. The life satisfaction index is negatively
correlated with restrictions on all modes of supply except commercial presence, while the
Gini coefficient regression seems to suggest that restrictions in commercial presence,
surprisingly, lessen inequality.
12
Public procurement policies are also likely to affect the vaccination outcomes we are interested in here.
However, we do not have data with which to measure such policies in the same way as we can measure
restrictions on trade in distribution services.
11
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Data source: World Development Indicators online database of the World Bank; Australian Productivity Commission’s
database of restrictions to services trade for the restrictiveness indices.
Data source: World Development Indicators online database of the World Bank; Australian Productivity Commission’s
database of restrictions to services trade for the restrictiveness indices.
12
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Evidence from standard OLS regressions confirms these insights (Table 4). 13 Of course,
results need to be interpreted cautiously in light of the simplicity of the model and the very
small number of observations. But the first indications are that a more restrictive set of
distribution sector regulations is associated with lower immunization rates: both regressions
using the domestic restrictiveness index show negative and statistically significant
coefficients. This result is robust to the inclusion of per capita GDP as a control variable.
This last point is important because of the strong role played by income in determining
human development outcomes such as vaccination rates. Our results show that even after
controlling for income, more liberal distribution sector regulations are linked to stronger
immunization outcomes.
Interestingly, it is only the regressions using the domestic restrictiveness index that produce
significant results (columns 1 and 3). Neither regression using the foreign restrictiveness
index has a statistically significant coefficient (columns 2 and 4). This result suggests that it
is the overall quality of regulation that matters for distribution sector performance, not just the
degree of discrimination against foreign service providers.
13
Results are qualitatively identical if we use a fractional logit model to take account of the fact that the
dependent variable is bound between zero and unity (Papke and Wooldridge, 1996).
13
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
For this sector, we can also adopt an alternative empirical strategy that allows us to greatly
increase the number of observations in our sample. To do so, we use one component of the
World Bank’s Logistics Performance Index (LPI 2007) as a measure of sectoral performance
in place of the Australian Productivity Commission regulatory indicators. The LPI is based on
a survey administered to around 1,000 logistics professionals around the world. By asking
them to rate performance in a number of countries with which they trade, the overall sample
size is increased to around 5,000 observations. The LPI itself is a composite of six indices
based on average responses to survey questions. The component we use here asks
respondents to rate on a one to five scale the quality and competence of logistics services in
a given country.
Although a valid measure of the performance of service providers in this area, the LPI data
clearly differ from the policy restrictiveness measures used elsewhere in this paper in that
they measure private sector development rather than public sector regulation. Nonetheless,
using the LPI data makes it possible to greatly expand the sample, and thus to include
additional explanatory variables that help demonstrate the robustness of our results. In
particular, we include controls for the total spend on health in GDP—to account for the fact
that a higher level of health spending should produce higher vaccination rates—and the
14
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
overall level of government effectiveness, i.e. the quality of public services, the quality of the
civil service and the degree of its independence from political pressures, the quality of policy
formulation and implementation, and the credibility of the government's commitment to such
policies. We also include an interaction term between the LPI services component and per
capita GDP, to account for the possibility that logistics affects vaccination rates differently in
developed versus developing countries.
Results using OLS are in Table 5. 14 The signs of all control variables are as expected:
countries at higher incomes, those that spend more on health, and those with more effective
governments tend to have higher levels of immunization for DPT and measles. All control
variables have coefficients that are statistically significant at the 1% level. In addition, the LPI
services component has a positive and 1% significant coefficient: in line with the smaller
sample results presented above, better logistics performance is associated with higher
immunization rates. Interestingly, the interaction term is negative and 1% statistically
significant, which indicates that the link between performance in logistics services and
vaccination rates becomes weaker as countries get richer. This result highlights the main
argument of this paper, namely that getting service delivery right is particularly important for
poor people in developing countries.
14
Again, we obtain qualitatively identical results using the fractional logit model.
15
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
(0.006) (0.062)
Government Effectiveness
0.072*** 0.071**
Index
(0.007) (0.014)
Constant -0.611 -0.546
(0.139) (0.146)
Observations 142 142
2
R 0.355 0.305
Notes: All regressions are estimated using ordinary least squares with robust standard errors. Prob. values are
reported in parentheses. Statistical significance is indicated by: * (10%), ** (5%), and *** (1%).
Data Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) online database of the World Bank for immunization rates, GDP
per capita, and total spending on health as a percentage of GDP; the World Governance Indicators for the index of
government effectiveness; and the World Bank’s Logistics Performance Index for the LPI services component.
16
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Data Source: World Development Indicators online database of the World Bank; Australian Productivity Commission
database of restrictions to services trade.
17
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Data Source: World Development Indicators online database of the World Bank; Australian Productivity Commission
database of restrictions to services trade.
18
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Data Source: World Development Indicators online database of the World Bank; Australian Productivity Commission
database of restrictions to services trade.
Results from OLS regressions are similar to those from the nonparametric exercise (Table
6). We find that after controlling for per capita income, the restrictiveness of regulation in the
engineering sector is associated with weaker outcomes in terms of telephone users (foreign
index, column 4) and Internet users (domestic index, column 1). The same is true for road
network density using the foreign index (column 6). Whereas in distribution services it is only
the domestic index that matters for performance, here we find evidence that general
regulation and the degree of discrimination vis-à-vis foreign service providers are both
important.
19
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
20
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Data Source: World Development Indicators online database of the World Bank; Australian Productivity
Commission’s database of restrictions to services trade.
21
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Figure 10: Non-parametric Regression of the Number of Telephone Users per 100
Population on per capita Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and an Index of
Telecommunication Services Restrictiveness
Data Source: World Development Indicators database of the World Bank; Australian Productivity Commission
database of restrictions to services trade.
Data Source: Human development index website; Australian Productivity Commission database of restrictions to
services trade.
22
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
Data Source: World Development Indicators online database of the World Bank; World Governance Indicators;
Australian Productivity Commission database of restrictions to services trade for the restrictiveness indices.
Parametric OLS regressions confirm these insights (Table 7). As in Table 5 above (LPI
regressions), the expanded sample size available with the telecommunications data makes it
possible to include some additional control variables, namely: overall government
effectiveness (as defined above); and total government spending as a percentage of GDP,
as an indicator of the extent to which the state is involved in service provision. The control
variables generally have the expected signs, but they are not always statistically significant.
In all eight regressions, however, the indices of regulatory restrictiveness are negatively and
1% statistically significantly associated with our various development outcome measures, i.e.
access to the Internet and telephony, education, and voice and accountability in government.
Together, these results provide strong evidence in favor of our core hypothesis.
23
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
24
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
This approach allows us to include fixed effects by country and by sector. The fixed effects
clean out all external influences that vary in the country or sector dimensions, thereby
relieving to a large extent the omitted variable bias that might be suspected in our previous
results. For instance, the fixed effects control for influences such as government
effectiveness, or the composition of government spending. In terms of the data, we proceed
by selecting one human development indicator per sector: the DPT immunization rate for
distribution; Internet users per 100 population for engineering; and phone users per 100
population for telecoms. At this stage, we do not include education in the panel estimates
because of the different structure of the regulatory indicators, which measure restrictiveness
by mode of supply rather than on an aggregate domestic or foreign basis, as in the other
sectors.
The first two columns of Table 8 present estimation results for the pooled model using data
for all three sectors. Results strongly support our contention: the domestic and foreign
restrictiveness indices both have negative and statistically significant coefficients (1% and
5% respectively). The difference in magnitude between the two coefficients suggests, as
noted above, that it is usually the restrictiveness of domestic regulation that makes most
difference in terms of human development outcomes.
In the last two columns of Table 8, we exclude the telecom sector from our dataset. The
reason for doing so is that it strongly dominates the other sectors in terms of the number of
data points available. Although the domestic and foreign restrictiveness indices both have
the expected negative coefficients, they are no longer statistically significant once we
exclude the telecom sector. Our results in columns 1–2 are therefore being driven to a
significant degree by a close link between regulation and human development outcomes in
that sector. In part, this is a consequence of data limitations: our human development data
are much more closely related to sectoral economic performance in telecom than in the
other sectors. The greatly reduced sample size is also a constraint: our regressions in
columns 3–4 have only 71 observations but a total of 39 dummy variables to account for
country- and sector-level influences. The last two regressions are therefore pushing the data
to their limits, and it is perhaps not surprising that our results lose precision.
25
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
4. CONCLUSION
This paper has presented some first empirical evidence on the links between services trade
and human development. The data generally show that a more restrictive services trade
policy environment is correlated with worse human development outcomes. This finding is
consistent with a mechanism in which more restrictive services policies result in higher
prices of basic goods and services for consumers. It has long been argued that trade policy
in services sectors can lead to higher national income, which in turn can promote human
development. Our results go one step further in isolating a direct connection between service
sector restrictiveness and development, which acts independently of the income channel.
One implication of our results is that the tension between service sector openness and
human development outcomes, which is apparent in some of the development policy
literature, has perhaps been overstated. At the very least, our results suggest that there is no
systematic association between greater policy restrictiveness and better outcomes. Rather,
open and efficient services sectors can help promote human development. Reducing the
restrictiveness of service sector policies through well-designed liberalization programs can
be one element of a successful approach to promoting economic and human development
together.
There is considerable room for future research to expand on our approach and results. The
main difficulty we have confronted relates to the availability of data on applied policy settings
in services sectors. As data for more countries and years become available, it will be
possible to expand the sample size used here, and perhaps even move to a genuine panel
26
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
data framework. Both steps are important in ensuring that our results are robust to the
exclusion of additional country- and sector-specific factors from the regressions.
27
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
REFERENCES
Arnold, J., A. Mattoo, and G. Narciso. 2008. Services Inputs and Firm Productivity in Sub-
Saharan Africa: Evidence from Firm-Level Data. Journal of African Economies 17(4):
578–599.
Arvis, J., M. Mustra, L. Ojala, D. Saslavsky, and B. Shepherd. 2010. Connecting to Compete
2010: Trade Logistics in the Global Economy. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Benhabib, J., and M. Spiegel. 1994. The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development:
Evidence from Aggregate Cross-Country Data. Journal of Monetary Economics
34(2): 143–173.
Bjørnskov, C., A. Dreher, and J. Fischer. 2008. Cross-Country Determinants of Life
Satisfaction: Exploring Different Determinants Across Groups in Society. Social
Choice and Welfare. Springer 30(1): 119–173
Blouin, C., N. Drager, and R. Smith. 2006. International Trade in Health Services and the
GATS: Current Issues and Debates. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Borchert, M., and A. Mattoo. 2009. The Crisis Resilience of Services Trade, Policy Research
Working Paper No. 4917. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Eschenbach, F., and B. Hoekman. 2006. Services Policy Reform and Economic Growth in
Transition Economies. Review of World Economics 142(4): 746–764.
Findlay, C., and T. Warren, eds. 2000. Impediments to Trade in Services: Measurement and
Policy Implications. London: Routledge.
Kimura, F., and H. Lee. 2006. The Gravity Equation in International Trade in Services.
Review of World Economics 142(1): 92–121.
Nguyen-Hong, D., and R. Wells. 2003. Restrictions on Trade in Education Services: Some
Basic Indexes. Staff Working Paper. Melbourne, Australia: Australian Productivity
Commission.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2003. Quantifying the
Benefits of Liberalizing Trade in Services. Paris: OECD.
Papke, L., and J. Wooldridge. 1996. Econometric Methods for Fractional Response
Variables with an Application to 401(k) Plan Participation Rates. Journal of Applied
Econometrics 11: 619–632.
Sarley, D., L. Allain, and A. Akkihal. 2005. Estimating the Global In-Country Supply Chain
Costs of Meeting the MDGs by 2015. Arlington, VA: United States Agency for
International Development.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD). 2005. Trade in Services
and Development Implications Document No. TD/B/COM.1/71. Geneva, Switzerland:
UNCTAD.
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP). 2006. International Trade and Human
Development: Lao PDR. Vientiane: UNDP National Statistics Center.
Wellenius, B. 2002. Closing the Gap in Access to Rural Communications: Chile 1995–2002.
Discussion Paper No. 430. Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Bank. 2002. Global Economic Prospects. Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Trade Organization (WTO). 2008. World Trade Report. Geneva, Switzerland: WTO.
28
ADBI Working Paper 268 Shepherd and Pasadilla
29