"Analysis of The Drinking Water Policy in Tunisia: Trade-Off Between Efficiency and Equity," by Ali Bouchrika and Fakhri Issaoui
"Analysis of The Drinking Water Policy in Tunisia: Trade-Off Between Efficiency and Equity," by Ali Bouchrika and Fakhri Issaoui
"Analysis of The Drinking Water Policy in Tunisia: Trade-Off Between Efficiency and Equity," by Ali Bouchrika and Fakhri Issaoui
AND DEVELOPMENT
Copyright 2021
ANALYSIS OF THE DRINKING WATER POLICY
IN TUNISIA: TRADE-OFF BETWEEN EFFICIENCY
AND EQUITY
Introduction
*Ali Bouchrika, Assistant Professor at the Institut Supérieure de Gestion de Gabes (Univer-
sity of Gabes), received his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Tunis El Manar. His
research interests include the economics of natural resources, economic development,
economic justice, macroeconomics, and growth in transitioning economies. The author has
published more than 20 papers in various journals such as Empirical Economics, International
Journal of Sustainable Economies Management, Journal of Reviews on Global Economics, Journal
of Management Research, and Journal of Environmental Sciences & Natural Resources, as a
sampling.
Fakhri Issaoui, Affiliate in the research laboratory of Prospective, Stratégies et Développement
Durable PS2D (University of Tunis El Manar) and Full Professor at the Ecole Supérieure de
Sciences Economiques et Commerciales (University of Tunis), received his Ph.D. in econom-
ics from the University of Tunis El Manar. His research interests include public and labor
economics, economic development, economic justice, macroeconomics, and growth in
transitioning economies. The author has published more than 50 articles in journals such as
Panoeconomicus, The Journal of Energy and Development, Journal of Cyber Warfare and
Terrorism, Journal of the Knowledge Economy, International Journal of Computational Economics
and Econometrics, African Sociological Review, International Journal of Green Computing,
Economic Research Guardian, and International Journal of Sustainable Economies Management,
as a sampling.
is no wonder we see researchers and policy makers increasingly focused upon this
salient subject. In particular, we see greater emphasis on examining water resource
management in academia. Previously, water resource management had not re-
ceived this level of attention, in part due to the fact that until the 1970s the
economics of natural resources was somewhat of a marginalized topic. Today,
with increased attention on sustainable development, access to drinking water is
viewed by many as a basic human right and public policies should be enacted to
protect both the quantity and quality of drinking water. There has been a growing
consensus that water resources must be carefully managed, and that water is a
scarce good, which is difficult to replace, and its usage must be prudently
planned.
In addition to its importance as a strategic consumption good, water is also
considered to be an ecological resource strongly correlated with humanity’s well-
being (including, for example, the preservation of flora and fauna and the public
health dimension). Moreover, from an economic perspective, water can be con-
sidered as a production factor and a lack of it can threaten the levels of production
for a number of key economic sectors, most importantly agriculture.
Thus, given the potential scarcity issues surrounding this resource, the proper
management of water represents an essential challenge for sustainable develop-
ment and a major determinant for improving a nation’s standard of living. Con-
sequently, governments have had to legislate and create the legal foundations
enabling organizations to have the necessary tools for managing access to water
and control over its quality in a responsible and equitable manner.
These policies aim to lead to equitable and sustainable management of water
resources for present and future generations. The economic foundations of sus-
tainable water management necessitate that its use and depletion rate must be
compatible with its renewal rate if this resource is truly to be considered renew-
able. What we have seen in many parts of the world is that water usage is far
outpacing water replenishment, setting up a questionable future for this vital
element.
Consequently, it is imperative to modernize drinking water management and
policies by actions on both the supply and demand side. Nevertheless, it appears
that the supply policies are constrained by the quasi-fixed or limited quantities of
drinking water. In Tunisia, for example, public investment aiming to increase the
quantity of water (by building infrastructure such as dams or desalination of
seawater) almost has reached its limits.
Traditionally, effective water management has been deemed to emanate pri-
marily from demand-side policies that establish real pricing. Real pricing is
considered to be a means of both conserving water and serving as a tool for
managing water demand and, in particular, drinking water demand. This policy
can ensure an economically optimal distribution that maximizes utility and re-
duces waste.
TUNISIA: DRINKING WATER MANAGEMENT 115
as a private good and pricing is based on the goals of efficiency and profit
maximization.
Nevertheless, many countries in the world have adopted a mix of these ap-
proaches combining a set of both economic and social goals. Consequently, the
quality of services must be subject to regulation and the structure and pricing
levels are established by the government according to specific socio-economic
benchmarks.
At this stage of analysis, it is important to note that unlike direct public-sector
management where the government is responsible for service, governance, and
management, commercial management opts for decentralization and financial
autonomy. In other words, each water agency has a budget that is autonomous and
separate from the public budget, which means that they have financial autonomy.
The agencies’ revenues come from the revenues collected from consumer citizens.
However, pricing is still set by the government with the objective of achieving
simultaneously a certain degree of efficiency and equity.
The Principle of Effective Management: Given the important role of public
policy and effective water management, it is clear why theorists have focused on
this subject. For example, to achieve effective management in the water and
sanitation sectors, V. Foster proposed an analysis structure for the modernization
and reform processes.2 The author provides a typical planning model for water
management with the general objective to improve the well-being of the pop-
ulation. According to V. Foster, public administrators will have to determine the
most appropriate structure taking into consideration various dimensions such as
efficiency, accountability, and equity. Consequently, the provision of services is
decentralized with a view to efficiency, whereby services are offered to regional
agencies that are concerned with a specific and well-defined geographic area.
Other authors focus on the pricing dimension. According to P. Spiller and W.
Savedoff both governmental and consumer goals can be achieved through low
water pricing.3 However, this option has a major drawback in that low prices do
not always let the private or public operator accumulate revenues that allow them
to finance the necessary investments needed to meet demand.
Once the government chooses to apply a low-price strategy with the goal of
allowing all socio-economic groups access to water, then it has to figure out how
to compensate the operators’ costs and incentivize them to make the proper levels
of investment required from both a quality and quantity standpoint. In addition,
these governmental transfers are necessary for the operators to avoid financial
bankruptcy and support the sustainability of a low-price structure.
In the cases where society’s water demand increases and if public resources are
scarce, the management of water services will be critical, which is especially true
in urban contexts. To solve this problem, types of regional organizations are being
formed from well-designed partnerships between private companies and the
118 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
Principles of Regulation
target voluntary consumer behavior. This consists of appeals to the public through
awareness campaigns, educational programs, and similar initiatives that have
resulted in profound changes in consumer behavior and attitudes toward conser-
vation and environment protection. Nevertheless, this depends on the level of
consciousness of the users and cannot be relied upon exclusively. Lastly, there are
infrastructure-related approaches that would allow for water consumption savings
of between 10 and 30 percent, which could be achieved by reducing water loss by
promoting leak detection and repair programs, the detection of illegal connections,
the reduction of infrastructure pressure, canal lining, and improvements in
transport techniques.
Regulatory Measures: The most direct regulatory measures are to establish
standard rules for the use of water. From a financial point of view, interventions
should be governed by two important principles: the user pays and the polluter
pays. Most often these two principles are seen not only as equitable but also as
economically effective solutions. A water demand management measure attempts
to encourage efficient use to shift to more profitable uses. Water charges have
generally been viewed as a mechanism to finance the operating and maintenance
costs of the water agency.
From this perspective, the demand management approach constitutes the new
policy for water resource management. In this approach, the price instrument can
guide us to a more efficient use of water resources. Indeed, the price appears as an
incentive mechanism that drives users to consume water more efficiently. In ad-
dition, the financial reward encourages water companies to improve their quality
of services and to meet consumer preferences through technical and financial
means. Thus, prudent water resource management requires the adoption of a
pricing method that makes it possible to consistently supply water to different
users in satisfactory levels of both quantity and quality. This pricing method also
avoids any kind of overuse and resource degradation.
In general, it appears that the price of drinking water is not the only factor
explaining water consumption. Data compiled by the OECD show that the price
elasticities of water demand are between -1 and 0 for domestic consumption.4
Indeed, studies and analyzes tend to show that the demand for drinking water is
relatively price insensitive, especially in low consumption bands. This is
explained by the fact that in the first consumption band the water demand is used
to satisfy basic and essential needs.
Nevertheless, the higher the initial consumption level, the higher the price
sensitivity. In fact, high consumption, which corresponds to the satisfaction of
120 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
The aim of this approach is to find out what form of marginal or average price
actually influences consumption. Several works, such as those by D. Chicoine and
G. Ramanurthy and J. Shin, reject the hypothesis of perfect knowledge of the price
structure by households.10 In general, households, in most cases, are sensitive to
the perceived price, which depends on the margin price (MP) and on a perception
parameter k. This behavior will be presented by the following model in equation
(3):
" #
AP k
logðQÞ ¼ a0 þ a1 log MP þ a2 R þ a3 W
MP
AP
¼ a0 þ a1 logðMPÞ þ a1 klog þ a2 R þ a3 W ð3Þ
MP
M. Nieswiadomy and D. Molina show that the value of the perception pa-
rameter is different depending on whether the price scale is progressive or de-
creasing.11 However, with progressive pricing, consumers seem to be sensitive to
the marginal price, while they would be sensitive to the average price with de-
clining pricing.
According to P. Point, the analysis of demand for drinking water is mainly
focused on needs.12 The quantity of water consumed and prices depend, in par-
ticular, on the development of the population’s needs, as well as life-style. Re-
search to estimate a demand function for drinking water is rare and is mainly
122 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
exploratory as the quantities of water consumed are often disconnected from the
real costs incurred by the distributing companies.
Among the works that have focused on estimating the demand function for
drinking water we can cite the research by C. Howe and others that relate con-
sumption and price through a cross-sectional analysis.13 P. Point’s research on the
drinking water demand function highlights the problem of sharing resources be-
tween different users. This assessment divides water users into three categories:
commercial, industrial, and domestic. The results show that the price elasticity is
around -0.167 compared to the average price for the department of Gironde in
France. In addition, the research by D. Agthe and R. Billings investigates new
aspects of consumption.14 The authors estimated the demand for drinking water
supply at the country level for Tunisia and for domestic use. They reported a
function with an elasticity of around -0.42 compared to the mean price.
The management of drinking water remains a top priority for public authorities
who must ensure public health and are entrusted with promoting favorable living
conditions and societal well-being. These obligations underscore the need for
programs and policies aimed at achieving multiple objectives through regulatory
measures in terms of meeting resource quality thresholds, factoring in the various
socio-economic situations of households, and protecting the environment through
a lens of sustainable development.
The objective of drinking water regulation is to create a principle that enables
accessibility such that every user has access to a sufficient quantity of water to
meet their essential needs. This principle also must aim to provide universal ac-
cessibility to an acceptable quality of water service at a reasonable price, which
depends on the socio-economic situation of households. It should be noted that, in
practice, access to drinking water is not universal and that significant inequalities
exist. The provision of adequate and acceptable levels of drinking water is more
common in developed countries relative to developing ones and in urban settings
versus rural areas, which can face obstacles to drinking water accessibility and
other disparities.
The setting of a low price for drinking water is dependent upon the estab-
lishment of a pricing system, which can depend on the volumes of water consumed
and the socio-economic characteristics of the subscribers. Therefore, water pricing
must be used to simultaneously achieve economic, environmental, and social
objectives to meet and support sustainable development.
The Principles of Sustainable Development: Sustainable development is the
organizing principle for meeting human development goals while simultaneously
sustaining the ability of natural systems to provide the natural resources and
TUNISIA: DRINKING WATER MANAGEMENT 123
ecosystem services on which the economy and society depend. The desired result
is a state where living conditions and resources are used to continue to meet human
needs without undermining the integrity and stability of the natural system. Sus-
tainable development can be defined as development that meets the needs of the
present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own
needs. Therefore, natural resources, such as water, must be used in a way that does
not limit their long-term availability. It should be noted that the main objective of
sustainable development within the context of the supply of drinking water means
meeting humanity’s basic needs for all while supporting improved standards of
living for current and future generations.
Water resource management is the cornerstone for sustainable development.
And, although this paper focuses on Tunisia, this issue is far reaching. According
to the United Nations world water development report, one-fifth of the world’s
population lives in areas characterized by physical water scarcity. The increase of
water demand in conjunction with water scarcity is a threat for humanity that is
only expected to worsen in the future. Almost half of the world population will be
living in areas with high water stress by 2030 according to the United Nations.
Thus, potential water resources need to be monitored with care for strategic
management. Water management issues and regulatory approaches require more
attention by the research community, especially in arid and semi-arid countries.
Additionally, water regulations and appropriate management should address en-
vironmental protection while promoting the redistribution of water in favor of less
affluent population groups who often face water access challenges. The principles
of sustainable development are based on a number of societal habits and behav-
iors, which are linked to household consumption patterns. In order to induce ef-
ficient consumption patterns by end users, ultimately the state must play the active
role in decision making for effective water management to ensure sustainable
development at a macro-level and to improve sustainable water service.
In addition, sustainable development consists of balancing the objectives and
trade-offs between promotion of the economy, society, and the environment. First
is to move from short-term economic profitability to long-term efficiency. Sec-
ondly is the move from uniform equality to territorial and geographic equity. And
third is from strict ecological conservation to intra- and inter-generational envi-
ronmental balance. Furthermore, to achieve a regional development program,
these principles must be implemented across the board. It should be noted that
sustainable and equitable development must meet the basic needs of the pop-
ulation and reduce inequalities among households. Indeed, local authorities are
attempting to respond to the increasing complexity and interdependence of the
problems generated in the quest for sustainable development by promoting greater
institutional alignment and organizational capabilities that will foster resiliency.
124 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
Table 1
TUNISIA: ESTIMATION OF THE SECTORIAL CONSUMPTION FUNCTION, 1971–2016
around 0.54 percent. This result shows that the mass effect risks depleting re-
sources in the medium and long term given the limited capacity of production. In
addition, the relationship between consumption and total production is unverified.
Thus, an increase of 1 percent in production leads to an increase of 0.16 percent in
consumption.
In the industrial sector the variables of price, number of subscribers, and
production significantly and positively affect the level of consumption at the
99-percent threshold. Indeed, a price increase of 1 percent leads to an increase in
consumption of 0.2 percent. This positive relationship shows that the price cannot
be considered as an incentive to lower consumption. Thus, industrial users, who
are for the most part considered as large consumers, are generally located in the
consumption band 151 m3 and greater where the price is the highest.
Regarding the number of industrial subscribers, a 1-percent variation in this
variable has the effect of increasing consumption by 0.34 percent. Indeed, the
variable number of subscribers does not have a significant effect on consumption.
This phenomenon is explained by the partial or total use of industries of supply
sources other than those provided by SONEDE. In the industrial sectors, changes
in production do not have a significant effect on consumption. Indeed, if pro-
duction increases by 1 percent, consumption increases by 1.1 percent. This is
explained by the effect that in this sector the large industrial consumption is met by
supply sources outside of SONEDE’s water supply.
In the tourism sector, the coefficients of the variables of number of subscribers
and production are significant at the 99-percent threshold. Similar to what we
uncovered in the other sectors, we find that for the tourism sector, price cannot
incentivize users to reduce their water consumption. The variable of the number of
subscribers does not seem to have a large effect on consumption, which is
explained by the fact that several hoteliers have resorted to the use of water from
their own wells, in particular for different uses. In addition, the relationship be-
tween consumption and production in the tourism sector is consistent with the
phenomenon observed in the industrial sector.
Assessing the Long-Run Drinking Water Equilibrium: To analyze the long-
term situation of drinking water management in Tunisia, we will study the sus-
tainability measures in each sector. Our analysis evaluates the efficiency of pricing
policy, the number of subscribers, and production on the consumption structure for
drinking water over the long run. To do this, we studied stationarity and the
cointegration between consumption and its components in order to assess the
sectoral strategy for the management of drinking water in Tunisia.
In the domestic sector, the two consumption and price series are stationary at
the first difference with the estimated statistics of the augmented Dickey-Fuller
(ADF) tests -4.21 and -4.62, respectively, which are below the critical value
(-2.96) at the 5-percent threshold. In addition, the results conclude that the residual
TUNISIA: DRINKING WATER MANAGEMENT 129
series of the statistical relationship between household consumption and the price
is not stationary (-3.21 > -3.67) and the two series are not cointegrated; therefore,
there is no long-term equilibrium relationship between these two variables.
For the industrial sector, the results show that the consumption, price, and
number of subscriber series are stationary in primary difference at the 5-percent
threshold. The estimated values of the ADF statistic are -4.35, -4.53, and -3.21,
respectively, and below the critical value of -2.96. In addition, the cointegration
tests between the pairs of consumption and price, on the one hand, and con-
sumption and number of subscribers, on the other hand, are subject to spurious
regressions (-3.14 > -3.67; -3.51 > -3.67). However, the non-cointegration of these
two pairs shows that the long-term equilibrium cannot be achieved. This explains
why the current management policy and strategy can only be effective for short-
term projections.
Regarding the tourism sector, the application of the ADF test shows the
stationarity of the three series—consumption, price, and number of subscribers—
expressed as the primary difference at the 5-percent threshold. Estimated ADFs are
-4.08, -5.37, and -3.52, respectively, which are less than the critical value of -2.96.
The results also show the non-stationarity of the series of residuals calculated from
the statistical relationship between consumption and the price in the tourism sector,
(- 3.42 > -3.67), on the other hand, and the stationarity of the series of residuals
calculated from the statistical relationship between consumption and the number of
subscribers in the tourism section (-3.72 < -3.67). Consequently, in the tourism
sector there is no cointegration relationship between the two consumption and price
variables, which leads to a long-term imbalance in the evolution of these two
variables. On the other hand, the balance between the two consumption variables
and number of subscribers seems to be reached and, thereafter, we find a stable
relationship between these two variables for a future projection. This is verified by
the cointegration relationship between the two variables. However, this latter result
is very critical of the fact that the decrease in consumption in this sector is mainly
due to the search for other sources of supply.
In our evaluation of the two consumption variables and the total production
variable, the results show that the null hypothesis test of the unit root on the series
in first difference provides the stationarity of the two consumption and production
series, given the estimated and critical values. (-4.25 < -3.53; -5.29 < -3.53) at the
statistical threshold of 5 percent.
In addition, the estimation of the statistical relationship between consumption
and production aims to deduce the series of residuals. The results from the
application of the ADF test on the series of residuals show the non-stationarity
of the series at the 5-percent threshold. Indeed, the estimated ADF statistic
(-3.04) is greater than the critical value (-3.67), so the estimated relationship
between consumption and production is a fallacious regression. Consequently,
the consumption and production series are not cointegrated, i.e., there is not a
130 THE JOURNAL OF ENERGY AND DEVELOPMENT
long-term equilibrium between these two variables, and this poses a problem
for drinking water management in Tunisia with significant implications for
policy makers.
Conclusion
This analysis highlights the essential challenges for the current policy of
drinking water management in Tunisia, which shows the unsatisfactory results in
affecting the consumption structure according to the price variables, the number of
subscribers, and production. Indeed, this complicates the objectives of sustainable
management of drinking water in the Tunisian case. On the other hand, we note
that household consumption is still following an exponential rate of growth despite
the scarcity of this vital good.
Thus, the tariff pricing approach that is being applied cannot encourage the user
to conserve drinking water. Furthermore, the pricing structure does not make
distinctions between the socio-economic classes of consumers or between the
level of quality of service offered by the public authority. In this context, drinking
water is considered by sector decision makers as a homogeneous good despite the
enormous variations in the physical characteristics at the regional and national
level. Consequently, whatever the nature of the drinking water supplied, SONEDE
has the same price, which results in placing a premium on quantity relative to
quality. This may present a major obstacle in the current strategy of managing
drinking water in Tunisia in the future.
In addition, the other factor that complicates effective drinking water man-
agement is that the quality of service provided to the user depends on the level of
coverage of the costs of drinking water by the tariffs applied. Indeed, if a public
drinking water supply service fails to recover most of the real costs of water, it will
not be possible to ensure an acceptable quality water supply.
However, in Tunisia, the water price does not cover the cost, which obviously
leads to a negative impact on the level of the quality of the service provided. It
should be noted that the long-run marginal cost is systematically higher than the
average price charged. Indeed, this price currently can only reach, on average, 75
percent of the long-run marginal cost. Consequently, this represents a major ob-
stacle to obtaining a better quality of service, especially for low-income users who
cannot bear the real cost of water. Thus, the Tunisian government must work on
developing additional tools to support its drinking water management policies that
can address these gaps and ensure equitable access to an adequate supply of
quality drinking water for its citizens. It is essential to balance regional and socio-
economic inequalities for a long-term solution that supports current and future
generations.
TUNISIA: DRINKING WATER MANAGEMENT 131
NOTES
1
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), Examen des performances
environnementales études par pays (Paris: OECD, 2014).
2
V. Foster, “Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors,” Inter-American Development
Bank, Sustainable Development Department Publication IFM, 96-101, Washington D.C., August
1996.
3
P T. Spiller and W. D. Savedoff, Spilled Water Institutional Commitment in the Provision of
Water Services (Washington, D.C.: Inter-American Development Bank, 1999).
4
OECD, op. cit.
5
M. S. Matoussi and A. Branzini, “Environmental and Water Resources,” Working paper,
Academy International of the Environment, Geneva, Switzerland, 1998.
6
J. J. Opaluch, “Urban Residential Demand for Water in the United States: Further Discussion,”
Land Economics, vol. 58, no. 2 (1982), pp. 225–27; J. Shin, “Perception of Price When Price
Information is Costly: Evidence from Residential Electricity Demand,” The Review of Economics
and Statistics, vol. 67, no. 4 (1985), pp. 591–98; and C. Nauges and A. Thomas, “Privately-
Operated Water Utilities, Municipal Price Negotiation, and Estimation of Residential Water De-
mand: The Case of France,” Land Economics, vol. 76, no. 1 (2000), pp. 68–85.
7
L. D. Taylor, “The Demand for Electricity: A Survey,” The Bell Journal of Economics, vol. 6
(1975), pp. 74–110.
8
J. A. Nordin, “A Proposed Modification of Taylor’s Demand Analysis: Comment,” The Bell
Journal of Economics, vol. 7, no. 2 (1976), pp. 179–21.
9
J. J. Opaluch, op. cit.
10
D. L. Chicoine and G. Ramanurthy, “Evidence on the Specification of Price in the Study of
Domestic Water Demand,” Land Economics, vol. 62, no. 1 (1986), pp. 26–32 and J. Shin, op. cit.
11
M. L. Nieswiadomy and D. J. Molina, “A Note on Price Perception in Water Demand
Models,” Land Economics, vol. 67 (1991), pp. 352–59.
12
P. Point, “Partage de la Ressource en Eau et Demande d’alimentation en Eau Potable,” Revue
Économique, vol. 4 (1993), pp. 849–62.
13
C. W. Howe, “Impact of Price Residential Water Demand: New Insights,” Water Resources
Research, vol. 18 (1982), pp. 713–16.
14
D. E. Agthe and R. V. Billings, “Water-Price Effect on Residential and Apartment Low-Flow
Fixtures,” Journal of Water Resources Planning and Management, (1997), pp. 20–3.