A Dynamic AD-AS Analysis of The UK Economy, 2002-2010
A Dynamic AD-AS Analysis of The UK Economy, 2002-2010
A Dynamic AD-AS Analysis of The UK Economy, 2002-2010
Anthony J. Evans*
ESCP Europe Business School
__________________________________________________________
Abstract
This educational note helps instructors to utilize the Cowen/Tabarrok
dynamic AD–AS model. I use it to interpret some major shocks and policy
responses that hit the UK economy from 2002 through 2010 and I describe
how to incorporate the model into a classroom setting.
__________________________________________________________
Introduction
In their Modern Principles of Macroeconomics textbook, Tyler Cowen and
Alex Tabarrok introduce a dynamic version of the aggregate
demand–aggregate supply (AD–AS) model.1 It is a simple framework
to make sense of economic shocks and policy responses. Its main
difference from the traditional AD–AS model is that instead of
showing the price level and real GDP on the two axes, the dynamic
version shows inflation (on the Y axis) and real GDP growth (on the
X axis), making the analysis much more accessible to students for
two reasons. First, in a world of sustained inflation, it can be
confusing to model declines in aggregate demand as leading to a fall
in the price level. Second, inflation and growth are the main
economic indicators discussed in the news—after all, inflation targets
tend to be 2 percent, and recessions are defined as two quarters of
negative GDP growth. Therefore, the dynamic model allows students
to instantly draw upon their existing knowledge of the main
2 Wren-Lewis (2013) has argued that since the Phillips curve shows inflation, we
should use that and simply ignore the AD–AS model. However, as Sumner (2009)
has argued, using the Phillips curve would place too much emphasis on demand
shocks and would neglect supply shocks. Mueller (2014) attempts to inject some
Austrian consideration to macroeconomic configurations by presenting a “goods
side” and “money side” model. Like the dynamic AD–AS model, it draws upon the
Solow model and is also based on the equation of exchange. However, it explains
things in terms of levels rather than growth rates. A dynamic version of the AD–
AS model may be the best of all worlds.
3 The figures are taken from “Second Estimate of GDP: Quarter 4 (Oct to Dec)
2015,” Office for National Statistics, February 25, 2016. The appendix shows NGDP
data for the United Kingdom from Q1 2002 through Q4 2010. The GDP deflator
is being used as the measure of inflation so that it is compatible with the real GDP
growth measure, and thus sums to our measure of NGDP. Unfortunately, using
the GDP deflator means that we lose the ability to talk in terms of changes to CPI.
For the periods chosen, there is not a dramatic difference between the two
measures of inflation, and the CPI figure is included in the appendix. Also,
Christensen (2012) has pointed out that the European Central Bank often conflates
the GDP deflator and CPI.
4 Indeed, the long-term average real GDP growth rate, calculated from Q1 1957 to
Q4 2001, is 2.345 percent. We can treat this rate as being approximately equal to
the Solow rate.
5 This seems like a dramatic over simplification, but two-year-ahead inflation
expectations remained reasonably close to 2 percent from 2006 through 2010 (see
“Do Inflation Expectations Currently Pose a Risk to Inflation?” Bank of England
Quarterly Bulletin 2015 Q2). There are no real estimates of GDP deflator
expectations, so we assume that they remain constant at 2.4 percent.
A. Evans / The Journal of Private Enterprise 31(4), 2016, 97–105 99
Draw the dynamic AD–AS model, identify the inflation rate, and
label the starting position point A. (Figure 1 shows what the graph
should look like.)
Figure 1. Q1 2002
6 Congdon et al. (2006) argued that “although the current welcome decline in oil
and gas prices may depress headline inflation in the next few months, this should
not disguise underlying concerns about domestic inflation.” A similar story
occurred in Europe. Eurozone M3 was growing at around 6.5 percent from 2000
until 2006. It then began to escalate quickly, rising to almost 10 percent in 2008 (see
Christensen 2012).
7 This increase in G could suggest that AD was too high, and as Cowen and
Tabarrok (2009) point out, this is a temporary phenomenon and therefore at some
future point we should expect negative shifts in AD. Note that excessive growth in
government spending also implies negative shifts in the Solow curve, because
100 A. Evans / The Journal of Private Enterprise 31(4), 2016, 97–105
Q4 2007, the economy was growing at 3.1 percent and inflation had
risen to 2.8 percent.8 Draw an updated graph and label the new
situation point B. (Figure 2 shows what the graph should look like.)
Figure 2. Q4 2007
government spending can crowd out private expenditure and private sector
investment, which will reduce total factor productivity.
8 The rise in inflation immediately prior to a crash is evidence of the Ricardo effect
Figure 3. Q1 2009
that we would expect such a large decline in real GDP growth but such a moderate
fall in inflation. During 2008, the MPC were reluctant to cut interest rates because
CPI was high. The diagram above demonstrates the problem with inflation
targeting. Because of a negative Solow shock, the concurrent AD shock wasn’t
deflationary. But it was highly damaging to the real economy.
10 Despite the rhetoric, the evidence suggests that little austerity actually took place
(see Evans 2012). Also, the UK policy uncertainty index fell during this period,
suggesting a rise in confidence.
102 A. Evans / The Journal of Private Enterprise 31(4), 2016, 97–105
Figure 4. Q4 2010
II. Conclusion
Instructors can debrief by providing a critique of various policy
decisions. Indeed, we identify three claims about the point at which
monetary policy errors were made. The first is 2002, by orchestrating
an NGDP growth rate that was suboptimally high. The second is
August 2005, with the decision to cut interest rates. The third is
September 2008, with the decision to allow NGDP growth
11 It’s debatable whether it’s best to show this as a future shock to Solow or as an
immediate one.
A. Evans / The Journal of Private Enterprise 31(4), 2016, 97–105 103
Appendix: NGDP
GDP
CPI RGDP NGDP
Deflator
D7G7 IHYU IHYR IHYO
2002 Q1 1.5 2.4 2.2 4.6
2002 Q2 0.9 1.8 2.2 4.0
2002 Q3 1.0 2.9 2.5 5.5
2002 Q4 1.5 3.0 3.1 6.2
2003 Q1 1.5 2.8 3.4 6.3
2003 Q2 1.3 2.7 3.5 6.3
2003 Q3 1.4 2.5 3.3 5.9
2003 Q4 1.3 2.9 3.2 6.2
2004 Q1 1.3 2.3 3.1 5.5
2004 Q2 1.4 3.1 2.7 5.9
2004 Q3 1.3 3.2 2.2 5.4
2004 Q4 1.4 3.1 1.9 5.1
2005 Q1 1.7 3.1 1.9 5.1
2005 Q2 2.0 3.3 2.5 5.9
2005 Q3 2.4 2.5 3.3 5.9
2005 Q4 2.1 2.7 4.3 7.1
2006 Q1 1.9 3.2 4.0 7.3
2006 Q2 2.3 2.4 3.1 5.6
2006 Q3 2.4 3.3 2.2 5.7
2006 Q4 2.7 3.1 1.4 4.5
2007 Q1 2.9 3.0 2.0 5.1
2007 Q2 2.6 2.8 2.3 5.1
2007 Q3 1.8 2.9 2.9 5.9
2007 Q4 2.1 2.8 3.1 6.0
2008 Q1 2.4 3.0 2.4 5.5
2008 Q2 3.4 2.9 1.2 4.2
2008 Q3 4.8 2.8 –1.2 1.5
2008 Q4 3.9 2.8 –4.2 –1.5
2009 Q1 3.0 2.1 –5.9 –4.0
2009 Q2 2.1 1.8 –5.6 –3.9
2009 Q3 1.5 2.0 –3.8 –1.9
2009 Q4 2.1 2.2 –1.3 0.9
2010 Q1 3.3 3.4 0.7 4.1
2010 Q2 3.5 3.8 1.7 5.6
2010 Q3 3.1 2.5 2.0 4.6
2010 Q4 3.4 2.7 1.8 4.5
2011 Q1 4.1 3.0 2.1 5.2
2011 Q2 4.4 1.5 1.7 3.2
2011 Q3 4.7 2.1 2.0 4.1
2011 Q4 4.6 1.9 2.1 4.0
A. Evans / The Journal of Private Enterprise 31(4), 2016, 97–105 105
GDP
CPI RGDP NGDP
Deflator
D7G7 IHYU IHYR IHYO
2012 Q1 3.5 0.8 1.5 2.3
2012 Q2 2.8 1.6 1.0 2.6
2012 Q3 2.4 2.1 1.2 3.4
2012 Q4 2.7 2.0 1.0 3.0
2013 Q1 2.8 1.6 1.4 3.1
2013 Q2 2.7 2.2 2.2 4.5
2013 Q3 2.7 2.3 2.1 4.5
2013 Q4 2.1 1.8 2.8 4.7
2014 Q1 1.7 2.1 2.8 4.9
2014 Q2 1.7 2.3 3.0 5.4
2014 Q3 1.5 1.8 2.8 4.6
2014 Q4 0.9 1.2 2.8 4.1
2015 Q1 0.1 0.8 2.6 3.4
2015 Q2 0.0 0.5 2.4 2.8
2015 Q3 0.0 0.0 2.1 2.1
2015 Q4 0.1 0.0 1.9 1.9
Source: “Second Estimate of GDP: Quarter 4 (Oct. to Dec.) 2015,” Office for
National Statistics, February 25, 2016. Figures subject to revision.