Critical Solving
Critical Solving
Critical Solving
Learning Objectives
After completing this chapter, students will be able to:
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($)
Construct a large plant 200,000 –180,000
Do nothing 0 0
Table 3.1
Types of Decision-Making
Environments
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE MAXIMUM IN
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) A ROW ($)
Construct a large
200,000 –180,000 200,000
plant
Maximax
Construct a small
100,000 –20,000 100,000
plant
Do nothing 0 0 0
Table 3.2
Maximin
Used to find the alternative that maximizes
the minimum payoff.
Locate the minimum payoff for each alternative.
Select the alternative with the maximum
number.
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE MINIMUM IN
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) A ROW ($)
Construct a large
200,000 –180,000 –180,000
plant
Construct a small
100,000 –20,000 –20,000
plant
Do nothing 0 0 0
Table 3.3 Maximin
Criterion of Realism (Hurwicz)
This is a weighted average compromise
between optimism and pessimism.
Select a coefficient of realism , with 0≤α≤1.
A value of 1 is perfectly optimistic, while a
value of 0 is perfectly pessimistic.
Compute the weighted averages for each
alternative.
Select the alternative with the highest value.
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE ROW
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) AVERAGE ($)
Construct a large
200,000 –180,000 10,000
plant
Construct a small
100,000 –20,000 40,000
plant
Equally likely
Do nothing 0 0 0
Table 3.5
Minimax Regret
Based on opportunity loss or regret, this is
the difference between the optimal profit and
actual payoff for a decision.
Create an opportunity loss table by determining
the opportunity loss from not choosing the best
alternative.
Opportunity loss is calculated by subtracting
each payoff in the column from the best payoff
in the column.
Find the maximum opportunity loss for each
alternative and pick the alternative with the
minimum number.
Minimax Regret
Determining Opportunity Losses for Thompson Lumber
STATE OF NATURE
200,000 – 0 0–0
Table 3.6
Minimax Regret
Opportunity Loss Table for Thompson Lumber
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($)
Construct a large plant 0 180,000
Do nothing 200,000 0
Table 3.7
Minimax Regret
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE MAXIMUM IN
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) A ROW ($)
Construct a large
0 180,000 180,000
plant
Construct a small
100,000 20,000 100,000
plant
Minimax
Do nothing 200,000 0 200,000
Table 3.8
Decision Making Under Risk
This is decision making when there are several
possible states of nature, and the probabilities
associated with each possible state are known.
The most popular method is to choose the
alternative with the highest expected monetary
value (EMV).
This is very similar to the expected value calculated in
the last chapter.
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) EMV ($)
Construct a large
200,000 –180,000 10,000
plant
Construct a small
100,000 –20,000 40,000
plant
Do nothing 0 0 0
Probabilities 0.50 0.50
STATE OF NATURE
FAVORABLE UNFAVORABLE
ALTERNATIVE MARKET ($) MARKET ($) EMV ($)
Construct a large
200,000 -180,000 10,000
plant
Construct a small
100,000 -20,000 40,000
plant
Do nothing 0 0 0
With perfect
200,000 0 100,000
information
EVwPI
Probabilities 0.5 0.5
Table 3.10
Expected Value of Perfect
Information (EVPI)
The maximum EMV without additional information is
$40,000.
EVPI = EVwPI – Maximum EMV
= $100,000 - $40,000
= $60,000
$300,000
–$200,000
Figure 3.1
Sensitivity Analysis
Point 1:
EMV(do nothing) = EMV(small plant)
20,000
0 $120,000 P $20,000 P 0.167
120 ,000
Point 2:
EMV(small plant) = EMV(large plant)
$120,000 P $20,000 $380,000 P $180,000
160 ,000
P 0.615
260 ,000
Sensitivity Analysis
BEST RANGE OF P
ALTERNATIVE VALUES
Do nothing Less than 0.167
EMV Values Construct a small plant 0.167 – 0.615
$300,000 Construct a large plant Greater than 0.615
–$200,000
Figure 3.1
Using Excel
Input Data for the Thompson Lumber Problem
Using Excel QM
Program 3.1A
Using Excel
Program 3.1B
Decision Trees
Any problem that can be presented in a
decision table can also be graphically
represented in a decision tree.
Decision trees are most beneficial when a
sequence of decisions must be made.
All decision trees contain decision points
or nodes, from which one of several alternatives
may be chosen.
All decision trees contain state-of-nature
points or nodes, out of which one state of
nature will occur.
Five Steps of
Decision Tree Analysis
Favorable Market
A Decision Node
1
Unfavorable Market
Favorable Market
Construct
Small Plant
2
Unfavorable Market
Figure 3.2
Thompson’s Decision Tree
EMV for Node = (0.5)($200,000) + (0.5)(–$180,000)
1 = $10,000
Payoffs
Favorable Market (0.5)
$200,000
Alternative with best
EMV is selected 1
Unfavorable Market (0.5)
–$180,000
$106,400
$63,600 Favorable Market (0.78)
Small $90,000
Unfavorable Market (0.22)
Plant –$30,000
No Plant
–$10,000
–$87,400 Favorable Market (0.27)
$190,000
Unfavorable Market (0.73)
$2,400 –$190,000
$2,400 Favorable Market (0.27)
Small $90,000
Unfavorable Market (0.73)
Plant –$30,000
No Plant
–$10,000
$49,200
P (FM) = 0.50
P (UM) = 0.50
Calculating Revised Probabilities
Through discussions with experts Thompson has
learned the information in the table below.
He can use this information and Bayes’ theorem
to calculate posterior probabilities.
STATE OF NATURE
RESULT OF FAVORABLE MARKET UNFAVORABLE MARKET
SURVEY (FM) (UM)
Negative (predicts
unfavorable P (survey negative | FM) P (survey negative | UM)
market for = 0.30 = 0.80
product)
Table 3.12
Calculating Revised Probabilities
Recall Bayes’ theorem:
P ( B | A) P ( A)
P( A | B)
P ( B | A) P ( A) P ( B | A ) P ( A )
where
A, B any two events
A complement of A
(0.70)(0.50) 0.35
0.78
(0.70)(0.50) (0.20)(0.50) 0.45
(0.20)(0.50) 0.10
0.22
(0.20)(0.50) (0.70)(0.50) 0.45
Calculating Revised Probabilities
Table 3.13
Calculating Revised Probabilities
P (FM | survey negative)
P ( survey negative | FM ) P ( FM )
P(survey negative |FM) P(FM) P(survey negative |UM) P(UM)
(0.30)(0.50) 0.15
0.27
(0.30)(0.50) (0.80)(0.50) 0.55
(0.80)(0.50) 0.40
0.73
(0.80)(0.50) (0.30)(0.50) 0.55
Calculating Revised Probabilities
CONDITIONAL
PROBABILITY P(STATE OF
P(SURVEY NATURE |
STATE OF NEGATIVE | STATE PRIOR JOINT SURVEY
NATURE OF NATURE) PROBABILITY PROBABILITY NEGATIVE)
FM 0.30 X 0.50 = 0.15 0.15/0.55 = 0.27
Table 3.14
Using Excel
Formulas Used for Bayes’ Calculations in Excel
Program 3.2A
Using Excel
Results of Bayes’ Calculations in Excel
Program 3.2B
Potential Problems Using
Survey Results
Tails
(0.5)
Other Outcome
Utility = ?
Figure 3.7
Investment Example
Jane Dickson wants to construct a utility curve
revealing her preference for money between $0
and $10,000.
A utility curve plots the utility value versus the
monetary value.
An investment in a bank will result in $5,000.
An investment in real estate will result in $0 or
$10,000.
Unless there is an 80% chance of getting $10,000
from the real estate deal, Jane would prefer to
have her money in the bank.
So if p = 0.80, Jane is indifferent between the bank
or the real estate investment.
Investment Example
p = 0.80 $10,000
U($10,000) = 1.0
(1 – p) = 0.20 $0
U($0.00) = 0.0
$5,000
U($5,000) = p = 0.80
0.9 –
U ($7,000) = 0.90
0.8 –
U ($5,000) = 0.80
0.7 –
0.6 –
Utility
0.5 –
U ($3,000) = 0.50
0.4 –
0.3 –
0.2 –
0.1 –
U ($0) = 0
| | | | | | | | | | |
$0 $1,000 $3,000 $5,000 $7,000 $10,000
Monetary Value
Figure 3.9
Utility Curve
Jane’s utility curve is typical of a risk avoider.
She gets less utility from greater risk.
She avoids situations where high losses might occur.
As monetary value increases, her utility curve increases
at a slower rate.
Risk
Avoider
Utility
Risk
Seeker
Figure 3.10
Monetary Outcome
Utility as a
Decision-Making Criteria
Tack Lands
Point Down (0.55)
–$10,000
1.00 –
0.75 –
Utility
0.50 –
0.30 –
0.25 –
0.15 –
0.05 –
Figure 3.12 0 |– | | | |
–$20,000 –$10,000 $0 $10,000 $20,000
Monetary Outcome
Utility as a
Decision-Making Criteria
Tack Lands
Point Down (0.55)
0.05