The - Industrial - Revolution by Jeff Horn
The - Industrial - Revolution by Jeff Horn
Jeff Horn
Agricultural Revolution
American System of Manufactures
Arkwright, Richard
Armory Practice
Bridgewater, Duke of
Brunel, Isambard Kingdom
Cartwright, Edmund
Chaptal, Jean-Antoine
Coal
Cockerill, William
Colonialism
Consumer Revolution
Cotton
Credit
Crystal Palace
Discipline
Division of Labor
Domestic Industry
Education
Enlightenment
Factory Acts
Factory System
Fitch, John
Hargreaves, James
“Industrious Revolution”
Interchangeable Parts
viii Alphabetical List of Entries
KEY PEOPLE
Arkwright, Richard
Bridgewater, Duke of
Brunel, Isambard Kingdom
Cartwright, Edmund
Chaptal, Jean-Antoine
Cockerill, William
Fitch, John
Hargreaves, James
Jacquard, Joseph-Marie
Liebig, Justus von
Owen, Robert
Slater, Samuel
Watt, James
Wedgwood, Josiah
Whitney, Eli
EVENTS
Agricultural Revolution
Consumer Revolution
Crystal Palace
Enlightenment
Factory Acts
Luddites
Second Industrial Revolution
x Topical List of Entries
INSTITUTIONS
Colonialism
Credit
Mercantilism
Patent(s)
Royal Society of Arts
Tariffs and Excise Taxes
Transportation by Water
Workforce
PROCESSES
American System of Manufactures
Armory Practice
Discipline
Division of Labor
Domestic Industry
Education
Factory System
“Industrious Revolution”
Interchangeable Parts
Pollution, Health, and Environment
Productivity
Role of the State
Socialism
Standard of Living
Waltham System
Throughout the course of history various events have forever changed the
world. Some, like the assassination of Julius Caesar, happened centuries ago
and took place quickly. Others, such as the rise of Christianity or the Enlight-
enment, occurred over an extended period of time and reshaped worldviews.
These pivotal events, or crossroads, were departures from the established so-
cial order and pointed to new directions and opportunities. The paths leading
to these crossroads in world history were often circuitous, and the routes
branching off from them led to developments both anticipated and unex-
pected. This series helps students understand the causes and consequences of
these historical turning points.
Each book in this series explores a particular crossroad in world history.
Some of these events are from the ancient world and continue to reverberate
today through our various political, cultural, and social institutions; others
are from the modern era and have markedly changed society through their
immediacy and the force of technology. While the books help students dis-
cover what happened, they also help readers understand the causes and effects
linked to each event.
Each volume in the series begins with a timeline charting the essential ele-
ments of the event in capsule form. An overview essay comes next, providing
a narrative history of what happened. This is followed by approximately 50
alphabetically arranged reference entries on people, places, themes, move-
ments, and other topics central to an understanding of the historical cross-
road. These entries provide essential information about their topics and close
with cross-references and suggestions for further reading. A selection of 10 to
15 primary source documents follows the reference entries. Each document is
accompanied by an introductory paragraph discussing the background and
xii How to Use This Book
significance of the text. Because of their critical nature, the events covered in
these volumes have generated a wide range of opinions and arguments. A sec-
tion of original essays presents responses to key questions concerning the
events, with each essay writer offering a different perspective on a particular
topic. An annotated bibliography of print and electronic resources concludes
the volume. Users can locate specific information through an alphabetical list
of entries and a list of entries grouped in topical categories, as well as through
a detailed index.
The various elements of each book are designed to work together to pro-
mote greater understanding of a crossroad in world history. The timeline
and introductory essay overview the event, the reference entries offer easy ac-
cess to essential information about key topics, the primary source documents
give students first-hand accounts of the historical event, and the original argu-
mentative essays encourage students to consider different views related to the
events and to appreciate the complex nature of world history. Through its
combination of background material, primary source documents, and argu-
mentative essays, the series helps students gain insight into historical causa-
tion as they learn about the pivotal events that changed the course of history.
Preface
The Industrial Revolution changed the world. In economic terms, it gave rise
to the modern era. It took centuries to develop the institutional structures,
technological capacity, and global markets while accumulating enough capital
to enable industrialization to occur. Centered in Great Britain in the century
between 1750 and 1850, but with competition initially from France and
the Austrian Netherlands (later Belgium) and then the United States and the
German lands, the Industrial Revolution took advantage of European coloni-
alism in the Atlantic world and trade ties with Asia. The Industrial Revolution
also facilitated the later spurt of 19th- and 20th-century imperialism. The gap
between the industrial “haves” and “have nots” widened dramatically. Unprec-
edented growth in manufacturing output resulting from the Industrial Revo-
lution accelerated the elaboration of European global hegemony, forcing states
that hoped to compete to seek to jumpstart their own industrial revolutions.
Those that did not, or could not, found themselves relegated to providing
resources and markets for increasingly dominant industrialized or industrial-
izing powers.
This extraordinary economic transition did not come cheap. A significant
proportion of the wealth, resources, and markets that underlay the Industrial
Revolution were generated by the Atlantic slave trade and slavery. But the
emerging working classes put in tremendously long hours laboring on danger-
ous machines in terrible conditions as more productive means of manufactur-
ing goods were developed. Given this situation, it is not surprising that a huge
percentage of the laborers in the first factories were there because they had no
choice. Evidence for the declining standard of living for the first generations
of industrial workers is overwhelming and incontrovertible. The Industrial
Revolution was simply not beneficial to those who provided the raw materials
xiv Preface
or made the goods that streamed in increasing numbers from Britain’s, then
the West’s factories, mills, and workshops. Only after 1830 did improvements
in living standards trickle down to England’s workers and slowly reach the
working classes in other industrialized countries.
How did—how could—such a system emerge? Socioeconomic elites devel-
oped progressively more powerful state structures capable of enforcing their
control over recalcitrant populations that did not want to work such long
hours, in dangerous and polluted places tied to machines, especially for so
little money. With the population growing and opportunities for emigration
to the colonies as an outlet, beginning in the 17th century, the rulers of
Britain identified the interests of the state with those of entrepreneurs ever
more tightly. The British state implemented a legal framework conducive to
protecting property owners, supported financial institutions like the Bank of
England to provide cheap and plentiful credit, and fought wars both to defend
and to acquire economic assets. Acts of Parliament to aid certain industries
and particular entrepreneurs with money or monopolistic control were sup-
plemented by the deployment of troops, police spies, and the entire military
apparatus of the British state to prevent the working classes from effectively
resisting their domination with force. Despite the prevalence of the myth that
laissez-faire underlay its economic policies, government action was essential to
British leadership of the Industrial Revolution. States that sought to follow
in Britain’s footsteps had to be even more active in fostering and protecting
industrial society.
The key to the economic breakthrough known as the Industrial Revolution
was making labor more productive through investments of capital. Human
ingenuity responded to the challenge with mechanization; the replacement of
human and animal power by wind, water, and coal; building factories, canals,
steamships, and railroads; all while increasing the division of labor and man-
agement’s oversight of the production process. This was no supply-side pro-
cess; entrepreneurs and states invested their time and energy in response to
clear signs of rapidly accelerating demand for a myriad of goods. One of the
chief reasons for the success of industrialization was the seemingly unquench-
able desire of people up and down the social scale and throughout the western
world for ever more material possessions that first manifested itself in the late
17th century and shows no sign of coming to a halt.
The Industrial Revolution is studied most effectively using an inter- and
cross-disciplinary perspective. History establishes the narrative and provides
the evidence. An historical understanding, however, should be enriched by
insights from business, political science, gender studies, sociology, and espe-
cially economics. At the same time, this book seeks to correct assumptions or
misinterpretations about the Industrial Revolution that are based too much
Preface xv
the new forms of production that made the Industrial Revolution must be
understood as a means of coping with growing demand. This demand
stemmed from rapid population growth and an influx of wealth siphoned off
from other parts of the world. Taken together, these two massive sources of
increased demand for various sorts of industrial products pushed innovators to
find novel ways of giving the people what they needed, wanted, and desired.
The Industrial Revolution gave rise to a new organization of society—the
emergence of new classes, urbanization, and a vastly more powerful state.
Industrialization made possible rates of economic growth that overcame de-
mographic pressures for the foreseeable future. This achievement was and is
enormously important in its own right, but the Industrial Revolution also led
eventually to dramatic and long-lasting improvements in the standard of liv-
ing that underpin the affluence of the contemporary industrialized world.
These two achievements explain why the process of industrialization in the
late 18th and 19th centuries was so “revolutionary.”
The Industrial Revolution was fostered effectively first by the British gov-
ernment and then by those states that followed in England’s wake. During the
early-modern era, official direction of the economy is generally associated
with a group of policies collectively known as mercantilism. From 1651, Brit-
ain closely oversaw trade through a series of Navigation Acts and tight control
over tariff policies to create and then maintain maritime supremacy by ena-
bling British merchants and landowners to earn large profits. The British also
gave certain mercantile associations charters to explore, colonize, and trade
with specific areas. Several companies became “states within states” ruling vast
territories and generating enormous profits for investors. These companies
tied the global economy together, expanding world trade for the benefit of
Europe. By developing institutions like the Bank of England to allow it to
borrow money at low rates, the British state obtained what proved to be a
decisive military advantage in the series of eight wars fought against France
between 1688 and 1815. The British state used its legal system and violence
to protect property and the authority of elites to encourage investment and
guarantee the domination of employers over workers. Law and order enforced
by the state were essential components of the British industrial advantage.
The government also provided monetary incentives, tax breaks, and monop-
olies to entrepreneurs. Parliament passed laws to create patents to support
invention while also investing in improvements to ships, docks, harbors, and
weapons. Without the thoroughgoing intervention of the state, Britain would
not have pioneered the Industrial Revolution.
Although the Industrial Revolution in Great Britain has been studied thor-
oughly, the partial nature of available statistics make it difficult for scholars
to agree on the pace, scope, or timing of the emergence of high levels of
Historical Overview xxiii
heavy emigration to the colonies and the United States as well as long years of
war punctuated this era. Declining mortality played an important role, par-
ticularly among infants and young children, but increasing fertility was a
greater factor. Rising fertility resulted from falling mean age of marriage and
the space between births, while the proportion of women who married grew
and married women became more likely to have children. These factors over-
came the harsh living and working conditions, health hazards, and poor nu-
trition that characterized the period. These factors combined with skyrocketing
urbanization to lower average life expectancy in Britain from 41.3 years in
1826 to 39.5 years in 1850. The simultaneous drop in infant and child death
rates and the absence of major wars suggests both how sharp the decline
in adult mortality was during the Industrial Revolution and the dramatic in-
creases in British fertility that surmounted it.
The British Industrial Revolution was based on a number of economic,
social, and political developments that began in the late 15th century and ac-
celerated during the 17th century. These developments provided the capital
and infrastructure that made industrialization feasible and profitable. In-
creased crop yields significant enough to be described as an “Agricultural
Revolution” complemented dramatic expansion of commercial interaction
both within Europe and between Europe and the rest of the world, especially
the Americas. Goods from Europe’s colonies in the western hemisphere were
exchanged for luxury goods from Asia and human beings from Africa who
were brought to the Americas to work as slaves in farms, mines, and homes.
It was only once the Industrial Revolution was well underway that European
manufactures could compete in many key markets around the world. The
emergence of a true world economic system in the 18th century was vital to
Europe’s ability to industrialize. New goods, new experiences, and increased
interaction with other peoples and places supported fresh ways of thinking
associated with the Scientific Revolution and the Enlightenment. In their
quest to understand the natural world, these movements encouraged tinker-
ing and experimentation, which sometimes led (usually indirectly) to im-
provements in production.
The critical technological developments that permitted a transformation
of the manufacturing process took place in England during the second half
of the 18th century, but were continually refined and improved on until su-
perseded after 1850. In almost every case, new machines and/or production
processes responded to specific problems that slowed down manufacturing.
In this sense, innovation was driven by economic “demand” rather than sci-
entific or technological “supply.” The decisive industry was textiles, particu-
larly cotton, which was both stronger and easier to work than wool, linen, or
silk, facilitating the switch to machine production. Cotton was also lighter,
Historical Overview xxv
washable, and could be grown in many places around the world. Therefore,
cotton textiles had an enormous potential market, greater than any other
textile.
The first “blockage” to expanding production was to manufacture enough
thread. This problem was resolved by Richard Arkwright’s water frame
(1769), James Hargreaves’s spinning jenny (1770), and Samuel Crompton’s
spinning mule (1779). Arkwright and Hargreaves applied principles devel-
oped in woolens to the new fiber, using water and hand power respectively.
Crompton’s machine combined both power sources in impressive fashion; a
spinning mule did 200–300 times the work of a spinning wheel. This mecha-
nization put pressure on weavers to make use of the increased amount of
available thread. Edmund Cartwright developed the power-loom (1785–
1788) in response. Although for several decades the power-loom did not
work any faster than a weaver, one worker could run first two, and then many
looms, increasing output exponentially. American Eli Whitney patented the
cotton gin in 1793 to get the seeds and dirt out of raw cotton. Finished yarn
could be bleached with chlorine using a process invented by French chemist
Claude-Louis Berthollet in 1784. Fifteen years later, Englishman Charles
Tennant greatly improved on Berthollet’s discovery by combining chlorine
with lime to make bleaching powder, which was easier, more effective, and
cheaper to use.
These advances permitted the British cotton industry to grow rapidly. Al-
though wool remained the largest textile sector throughout the 18th century,
the cotton industry expanded much more quickly. British cotton production
increased approximately tenfold between 1760 and 1800, and accelerated even
more rapidly in the 19th century. By 1830, cotton goods constituted half of all
British exports.
Improvements in iron production made the rapid mechanization of indus-
try feasible. The key to British predominance in iron making stemmed from
the use of coal in smelting rather than charcoal. Iron makers preferred char-
coal because, as a vegetable fuel, it did not pass on impurities to the smelted
iron. However, in 18th-century England, wood shortages made charcoal ex-
pensive, encouraging the English to use coal as a replacement fuel. A great
deal of British iron production shifted to the 13 North American colonies
where wood was plentiful. The loss of these colonies in the War of American
Independence accelerated the cost incentive to replace charcoal. Iron masters
experimented until they discovered how to apply heat indirectly using a
reverberatory furnace that kept coal from direct contact with iron. English-
man Henry Cort (1740–1800) developed this process, known as “puddling,”
in 1783–1784 and improved it in the 1790s. Rapid expansion of iron pro-
duction began in the late 1790s and skyrocketed in the first decades of the
xxvi Historical Overview
19th century as machines made from metal became ever more crucial to eco-
nomic development.
The experience of artisans and iron makers with using coal as fuel and
experimenting with machines stimulated British technological creativity. The
most important example was the steam engine. First developed in the late
17th century and improved frequently over the course of the 18th century,
the steam engine, powered by coal, put almost unlimited power at humanity’s
disposal, superseding the limitations of human or animal power. Early steam
engines were highly inefficient at turning steam pressure into motive power.
Some of Britain’s best engineers, led by James Watt (1736–1819), an instru-
ment maker from Glasgow, sought to increase its efficiency. Watt solved several
technical problems, which saved a huge amount of coal and permitted the en-
gine to be moved, making a vast array of industrial machinery possible. Watt’s
patented steam engine was essential to mechanization and the emergence of the
factory system, but it was too large and did not produce enough pressure to run
a steam-powered vehicle. Only after another Englishman, Richard Trevithick,
developed such an engine in 1800 did it become possible to build steamboats
and railroads, the era’s most vital advances in transportation.
The question of why Great Britain was able to undertake an industrial
revolution has been hotly debated since the first signs of industrialization
became visible in the late 18th century. Other countries—notably France, the
Netherlands, and what became Belgium—had many of the same social, eco-
nomic, and technological preconditions for industrialization, so what made
Britain unique? The issue remains important today because it affects national
economic policies in the nonwestern world.
Britain enjoyed a number of important advantages for industrialization.
Rapid population growth provided a surplus of workers forced to labor for
low wages while generating a burgeoning demand for manufactured goods.
In terms of natural resources, Britain had a productive agricultural sector, and
large, high-quality deposits of iron and coal. Britain had myriad rivers and
streams to power machines and to provide cheaper transportation. No place
in Britain is more than 70 miles from the sea or more than 30 miles from a
navigable waterway. The surrounding seas protected the British Isles from
invasion and the damage associated with events like the Revolutionary and
Napoleonic wars (1792–1815) that devastated the continent. Colonies and
overseas commerce furnished needed raw materials and lucrative markets.
Centuries as a leading mercantile nation had generated significant capital and
fostered institutions capable of managing the national economy, like the
Bank of England, that facilitated industrialization. However, by themselves,
these advantages do not explain the process of industrialization or how Brit-
ain was able to lead the way to a new economy.
Historical Overview xxvii
The labor force explains why Britain was able to lead an industrial revolu-
tion more effectively than any other factor. As a group, British workers were
relatively well educated and possessed many craft skills. Perhaps more impor-
tantly, British laborers were thoroughly disciplined. They adopted innova-
tions in technology and in the organization of production far more
systematically than their brethren on the other side of the Channel. The Brit-
ish also adapted to the time-clock and the demands of the machine while
their counterparts were distracted by political and military diversions during
the upheavals of the French Revolution and Napoleon. These characteristics
resulted from a combination of greater control by British elites and by height-
ened desperation on the part of laborers on the margins. The willingness of
entrepreneurs to invest in machines and the financial need of enough laborers
to accept mechanized work, which they despised, were the twin bases of Brit-
ain’s major advantage in the process of early industrialization: labor produc-
tivity. This “domestication” of labor permitted the successful implementation
of the factory system.
The term domestication has a double meaning because the rudimentary
machines found in early factories required the entire family to enter the fac-
tory together, recreating the division of labor found on many farms. In gen-
eral, fathers did the heavy manual labor, women undertook tasks requiring
greater dexterity, and children cleaned, fetched raw materials, or tended
difficult-to-reach parts of the machine. Despite the dangers to life and limb
from unsafe machinery; rickety, crowded factories; and toxic materials essen-
tial to production, children and their parents worked 12- to 17-hour days, six
days a week in order to earn a living wage. Only the continual improvement
of machines in the 19th century made it possible for the family unit to be
replaced by individuals and, later, for men to be supplanted by women or
children. The ease of finding families, and subsequently children, to perform
these onerous tasks reminds us of how difficult economic conditions were,
and why socialist doctrines highlighting the inequality of profits created by
industrialization coming at the expense of enormous human suffering by the
working classes ultimately found such a large audience.
Factories concentrated workers at one site rather than in the home
while mechanized production increased the division of labor and enforced
hierarchical management. The use of machinery imposed geographical
constraints—factories required a nearby power source, either water or coal.
Thus, industrialization was regional more than national, clustering around
rivers and coal deposits. This new form of production lowered costs, not only
permitting greater profits but also allowing prices to be reduced, bringing
manufacturing goods within the purchasing reach of more people, dramati-
cally increasing potential demand. The creation and spread of the modern
xxviii Historical Overview
factory system within the confines of the British textile industry during the
late 18th century was essential to the Industrial Revolution.
The British pioneered the factory system, and it spread most rapidly there.
As a result, manufactured goods produced in the British Isles tended to be
cheaper and in many cases better (thanks to the mechanization of many op-
erations) than the same products made in other countries. British industrial
dominance was founded on relatively inexpensive goods made with machin-
ery and a high level of division of labor by workers with unique craft skills in
economic sectors with highly elastic demand. Changes in the production
process, the development of other countries’ industrial sectors, and the evolu-
tion of consumer demand eventually sounded the death knell for Britain’s
advantages, but not until after 1870.
The Industrial Revolution: A to Z
See also: Standard of Living; Workforce; Document: “The State of the Poor”
Further Reading
Broadberry, Stephen, and Kevin O’Rourke, eds. The Cambridge Economic History of
Modern Europe, vol. 1, 1700–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010.
Clark, Gregory. “The Agricultural Revolution and the Industrial Revolution: Eng-
land, 1500–1912.” 2002. Available online at http://faculty.econ.ucdavis.edu
/faculty/gclark/papers/prod2002.pdf.
King, Steven, and Geoffrey Timmins. Making Sense of the Industrial Revolution: Eng-
lish Economy and Society 1700–1850. Manchester: Manchester University Press,
2001.
Overton, Mark. Agricultural Revolution in England: The Transformation of the Agrar-
ian Economy 1500–1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996.
make guns with reliably interchangeable parts. Nor did that interchangeabil-
ity survive a change in design. When a new weapon was introduced in 1842,
it took seven years to develop the precision machine tools to mimic the same
results. The hand-filing of parts was succeeded by the invention of machines
that automatically made identical parts to a specified pattern. Weapons with
interchangeable parts were considerably more expensive than handmade
weapons, but they were easier to repair. It was at the 1851 Crystal Palace Ex-
hibition in London that the “American System of Manufactures” received its
name from impressed observers.
Once developed, the American System was used to manufacture sewing
machines and then bicycles in addition to ever-more-lethal weapons. From
bicycles, the American System diffused to the automobile industry. The suc-
cess of this system came from the design and use of machine tools, which could
fashion exactly alike metal parts for products ranging from clocks, to cash
registers, to typewriters, to reapers, to locomotives, and finally to automobiles.
Many of these products were not internationally competitive on price or qual-
ity, but U.S. manufacturers were able to survive by selling to the vast and grow-
ing American market while high tariffs kept out foreign rivals. Only after a
long period of constant improvement did U.S. manufacturers become truly
competitive in the world market in the last decades of the 19th century. Simul-
taneous improvements in steel making along with U.S. expertise in machine
building permitted the factory assembly line to be created. The assembly line
must be seen as the culmination of a century-long process through which gen-
uine mass production emerged out of the American System of Manufactures.
See also: Armory Practice; Crystal Palace; Interchangeable Parts; Iron and
Steel; Role of the State; Second Industrial Revolution; Tariffs and Excise
Taxes; Whitney, Eli
Further Reading
Hoke, Donald R. Ingenious Yankees: The Rise of the American System of Manufactures
in the Private Sector. New York: Columbia University Press, 1990.
Hounshell, David A. From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932: The
Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1984.
Mayr, Otto, and Robert C. Post, eds. Yankee Enterprise: The Rise of the American Sys-
tem of Manufactures. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Press, 1981.
Meyer, David R. “The Roots of American Industrialization, 1790–1860.” Available
online at https://eh.net/encyclopedia/the-roots-of-american-industrialization
-1790–1860/.
Smith, Merritt Roe. Harpers Ferry Armory and the New Technology: The Challenge of
Change. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1977.
Arkwright, Richard 5
preferred because they did not have to unlearn other techniques, they did not
mind the closer supervision demanded by factory labor, and they were willing
to be trained to work the machines.) Arkwright solved the labor problem by
accepting a huge number of youthful apprentices from Poor Houses all over
Britain. Apprentices who were children or teenagers lived at the mill and were
bound legally to work for Arkwright either until they were 18 or for seven
years, whichever was longer!
To address an ongoing shortage of labor, Arkwright set up several mills in
Lancashire in association with different groups of limited partners, becoming
Europe’s first cotton baron. The mills got bigger and bigger. The factory at
Chorley was the biggest in Great Britain with 500 workers. In Manchester,
Arkwright engaged 600 workers and built a multistory mill with weavers
established on the premises instead of in a separate building. In the 1780s,
Arkwright greatly upgraded earlier carding machines that combed and
straightened the raw cotton. It hardly mattered that Arkwright’s patent to this
machine was revoked in 1785. The British government ruled that he had
stolen the idea that made his fortune. Stolen or not, Arkwright’s water frame
was the foundation of the factory system inaugurated in Britain’s cotton tex-
tile industry.
Further Reading
“The Arkwright Family in Cromford.” Available online at http://www.cromfordvil
lage.co.uk/arkwrights.html.
Hills, Richard L. “Sir Richard Arkwright and His Patent Granted in 1769.” Notes and
Records of the Royal Society of London 24, no. 2 (1970): 254–60.
MacLeod, Christine. Heroes of Invention: Technology, Liberalism and British Identity
1750–1914. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007.
Mokyr, Joel. The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain 1700–1850.
New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2009.
Further Reading
Hounshell, David A. From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932: The
Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1984.
“The Industrialization of the Springfield Armory, 1812–1865.” Available online at
http://www.forgeofinnovation.org/Springfield_Armory_1812-1865/index.html.
Shackel, Paul. Culture Change and the New Technology: An Archaeology of the Early
American Industrial Era. New York: Plenum, 1996.
Smith, Merritt Roe. Harpers Ferry Armory and the New Technology: The Challenge of
Change. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1977.
Thompson, Ross. Structures of Change in the Mechanical Age: Technological Innovation
in the United States 1790–1865. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press,
2009.
noted engineers—James Gilbert, who drew up the plans, and James Brindley,
who oversaw construction—Bridgewater also decided to improve the drainage
in his mines, which would increase production. That growth in output would
be sold in Manchester via the canal he envisioned.
The technical difficulties involved were enormous. The directors of an
existing canal, the Mersey & Irwell, made them worse by obstructing the
project. A significant portion of the canal had to be constructed underground.
The canal also had to cross the Mersey & Irwell which they addressed by
building an aqueduct 38 feet above the existing canal. Needless to say, this
proposal was widely ridiculed by contemporaries. Despite the staggering cost
of about “10,000 guineas [each worth 21 shillings or 1.05 pounds] a mile,”
the section of the canal running from Worsley to Castlefield in Manchester
was completed in 1761. Canal boats drawn by horses operated until the late
19th century. Once Worsley coal began to reach Manchester by water, the
price of coal in the city fell by half.
In 1762, Egerton embarked on a major expansion of the canal to link Man-
chester and Liverpool. It took more than a decade to complete this section
because the marshy ground was hard to stabilize. Ultimately about 47 miles of
underground canal were constructed at four different levels as links between
the various segments of Egerton’s canal. Other waterways were constructed to
form a more effective and efficient transportation network throughout the
rapidly growing region. Building these additions nearly bankrupted Egerton,
but, by the end of the century, he had recouped his investment and begun to
make substantial profits. Known as the “Canal Duke,” Egerton remained an
enthusiastic supporter of canals and canal building throughout his life. His
heirs sold the canal network in the 1870s for a huge profit and the canals
remained in commercial operation until 1974.
The Duke of Bridgewater inspired two vitally important groups of people.
The duke’s determination to profit from his landholdings by selling coal
attracted the attention of nobles and other large landowners who had largely
been aloof from the industrial economy. His audacious and ultimately profit-
able canal-building schemes motivated others to seek similar opportunities by
developing improved communications. British elites modeled their actions
after successful pioneers like the Duke of Bridgewater to lead the Industrial
Revolution.
Further Reading
“The Bridgewater Canal.” Available online at http://www.bridgewatercanal.co.uk
/history/.
10 Brunel, Isambard Kingdom
See also: Crystal Palace; Education; Iron and Steel; Railroads; Role of the
State; Transportation by Water
12 Cartwright, Edmund
Further Reading
“Brunel 200.” Available online at http://www.brunel200.com/.
“Isambard Kingdom Brunel: Design Engineer (1806–1859).” Available online at
http://design.designmuseum.org/design/isambard-kingdom-brunel.html.
Landes, David. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Devel-
opment in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
versity Press, 1969.
MacLeod, Christine. Heroes of Invention: Technology, Liberalism and British Identity
1750–1914. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007.
Pugsley, Alfred, ed., The Works of Isambard Kingdom Brunel. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1980.
livelihoods, burned the factory to the ground in 1792. Cartwright lost his
entire investment and, because no other manufacturer thought that the re-
wards were worth the risks, was unable to find other partners. Cartwright was
forced to turn his patent over to trustees while he dealt with his debts. While
the invention languished, the number of home-based handloom weavers ex-
panded greatly from 75,000 in 1795 to 225,000 in 1811.
Cartwright did not stop inventing. He made a wool-combing machine in
1790 and took out several other patents related to textile manufacture. Diffu-
sion of the wool-combing machine was also slowed dramatically by opposi-
tion from wool-combers who recognized the threat to their high wages based
on a unique skill. Although a few entrepreneurs were able to make the invest-
ment in power-looms profitable, especially after a number of Stockport man-
ufacturers made major improvements in the device, widespread implementation
of Cartwright’s invention did not come until the mid-1820s. The wool-
combing machine came into wide usage in the same era.
By 1825, a power-loom could weave 7.5 times as much as a cottage artisan
in domestic manufacture, and a boy could supervise two looms. From 2,400
looms in 1813 and 14,150 in 1820, the number of looms expanded to
100,000 in 1833 and 250,000 by midcentury. Cartwright did not live to
see the success of his inventions; he needed a grant of £10,000 from the Par-
liament of the United Kingdom in 1809 to get rid of his last creditors from
his entrepreneurial endeavors. In 1821, he was elected a fellow of the Royal
Society. Cartwright’s inventions solved two major industrial blockages, yet
he was unable to profit from them in large measure because of the organized
opposition of workers, which highlights the gap between invention and
implementation.
Further Reading
“Edmund Cartwright.” Available online at http://lemelson.mit.edu/resources/edmund
-cartwright.
MacLeod, Christine. Heroes of Invention: Technology, Liberalism and British Identity
1750–1914. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007.
Mantoux, Paul The Industrial Revolution in the Eighteenth Century: An Outline of the
Beginnings of the Modern Factory System in England, rev. ed. New York: Harper &
Row, 1961.
Mokyr, Joel. The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1991.
14 Chaptal, Jean-Antoine
Britain, where “private interest directs all actions.” To Chaptal, the public
good required state mediation of the myriad of private interests.
Chaptal founded, revived, or sponsored a host of institutions such as
Chambers of Commerce, Consultative Chambers of Manufacturing, Arts,
and Crafts, industrial expositions, Councils of Agriculture, Arts, and Com-
merce as well as Schools of Arts and Crafts, the Society for the Encourage-
ment of the National Industry, Museums of Arts and Crafts, and free spinning
schools for women. This list is not exclusive and demonstrates both Chaptal’s
commitment to state intervention in the economy and how wide open the
field was for institutional innovation.
Chaptal was not just a bureaucrat or a theoretical chemist. He was also an
entrepreneur. He created three large-scale chemical workshops around Paris.
On his vast estate, he became vitally concerned—both scientifically and
commercially—with improving the process of distilling sugar from grapes
and naturalizing the sugar beet and merino sheep in France. In 1819, Louis
XVIII named Chaptal a peer of the realm. That same year, Chaptal published
one of the first accounts of the nascent industrial revolution in France. For
the rest of his life, Chaptal actively promoted educational reform to improve
interaction between theoretical and applied science while employing his pre-
cepts to increase his personal fortune. Chaptal’s career shows that with the
support of the state, economic rationality and market orientation often led in
different directions on the continent than in Britain.
Further Reading
Bolado, Elsa, and Lluis Argemí. “Jean Antoine Chaptal: From Chemistry to Political
Economy.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 12, no. 2 (2005):
15–39.
Horn, Jeff. The Path Not Taken: French Industrialization in the Age of Revolution,
1750–1830. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2006.
Jacob, Margaret C. Scientific Culture and the Making of the Industrial West. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1997.
Paul, Harry W. Science, Vine and Wine in Modern France. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2002.
Smith, John G. The Origins and Early Development of the Heavy Chemical Industry in
France. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1979.
COAL Coal, more than any other source of fuel, powered the Industrial
Revolution. Water, wind, and animals all contributed mightily to the energy
used in industrialization, but without question, coal took pride of place,
16 Coal
hand with pickaxes. As the demand for coal grew and pits grew deeper, steam
engines were used to pump water out of the mines, but the tunnels that
reached the coal faces were rarely very large, forcing miners to contort them-
selves into uncomfortable positions to get at the coal. Women and girls were
usually responsible for pushing tubs of ore often weighing more than they did
to a collection point. Children as young as five were employed to get into
tight places. Flooding and fire-damp (the combustion of explosive gases in
enclosed spaces with a spark) were daily dangers as were the collapse of mine
shafts or accidents with explosives used to blast tunnels in hard rock. In the
19th century, these threats killed hundreds of British miners annually. Long
hours inhaling coal dust while getting alternately soaked with cold water or
baked by humid heat led many miners to develop respiratory and joint prob-
lems, most notably coal workers’ pneumoconiosis, also known as black lung
disease or black lung; bronchitis; and rheumatism.
The reforms that improved working conditions in factories took longer to
apply to mines. As in the case of textiles, British elites claimed that they could
not take better care of miners or improve safety without undermining profits
or losing jobs to overseas competition. These unfounded claims—as the mas-
sive increases in production during the 19th century demonstrated—were
allowed to stand unchallenged for most of the era of the Industrial Revolu-
tion. Only after the same reformers who tackled child labor in the factories led
by Lord Anthony Ashley-Cooper, the seventh Earl of Shaftesbury, turned
their attention to the mines did the British state take action. The publication
of the shocking Children’s Employment Commission (Mines) Report in 1842
detailing the horrible working conditions in the mines led directly to the par-
liamentary passage of a Mines and Collieries Act, which outlawed women and
children under age 10 from working underground. Because no means of en-
forcing the bill’s provisions were included, several pieces of follow-up legisla-
tion in the 1850s and 1860s were needed to keep women and children out
of the mines. In Britain, government-mandated improvements to safety and
working conditions took place only in subsequent decades, long after the end
of the first Industrial Revolution.
Outside Britain, coal also played a transformative role in industrial devel-
opment. France’s coal reserves were hard to get to and not as high quality as
Britain’s. As a result, France used coal only when necessary and focused more
on water power. This was a rational, though not quite as profitable, strategy
given that nation’s natural resource endowment. The United States’ almost
inexhaustible supplies of wood along with easy access to water power retarded
development of the coal industry until the needs of iron makers amplified
demand after 1840. In succeeding decades, the United States’ rapidly expand-
ing population required steamboats, railroads, and many other machines and
18 Coal
See also: Factory Acts; Factory System; Iron and Steel; Pollution, Health, and
Environment; Productivity; Railroads; Role of the State; Steam Engine;
Transportation by Water; Workforce; Document: “Conditions in the Mines”;
Document: “Living and Working in Manchester”
Further Reading
Adams, Sean Patrick. “The US Coal Industry in the Nineteenth Century.” Available
online at http://eh.net/encyclopedia/the-us-coal-industry-in-the-nineteenth
-century/.
Burt, Roger. “The Extractive Industries.” In The Cambridge Economic History of
Modern Britain, ed. Roderick Floud and Paul Johnson. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2004.
Cockerill, William 19
Landes, David. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Devel-
opment in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
versity Press, 1969.
Testimony Gathered by Ashley’s Mines Commission. Available online at http://www
.victorianweb.org/history/ashley.html.
Wrigley, E. A. Energy and the English Industrial Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2010.
See also: Coal; Iron and Steel; Role of the State; Transportation by Water
Further Reading
Heckscher, Eli. The Continental System: An Economic Interpretation. Oxford: Claren-
don Press, 1922.
Henderson, William O. The Industrial Revolution in Europe, 1815–1914. Chicago:
Quadrangle Books, 1968.
“Industrial History: Belgium.” Available online at http://www.erih.net/industrial
-history/belgium.html.
Teich, Mikuláš, and Roy Porter, eds. The Industrial Revolution in National Context:
Europe and the USA. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996.
In the 16th century, Spain and Portugal developed and maintained vast
empires. Spain dominated the coastline of the western hemisphere from Flor-
ida to the straits of Magellan with the exception of Portuguese Brazil. Portugal
set up trading stations and forts to protect the route to the East Indies. Only
in the 17th century did the Dutch wrest control of much of Portugal’s Asian
empire while also acquiring South Africa and a handful of territories in and
around the Caribbean. The French managed to establish footholds in Canada,
throughout the Caribbean, and in strategic spots in western Africa and India
while the British acquired most of the eastern half of the continent of North
America, a host of possessions in the Caribbean led by Jamaica, trading stations
on the coast of Africa, and scattered outposts on the subcontinent of India,
especially Bengal, among other territories and spheres of interest spread out
across the globe. These colonies provided markets and raw materials that gen-
erated truly enormous wealth essential to industrialization.
For Europeans, the twin poles of economic attraction were the Americas
and Asia. Although they eventually established political and economic
control of vast swaths of territory in Asia, European settlement was always
limited, especially during the age of the Industrial Revolution. European set-
tlement and political control in Africa was even more restrained. Both areas
were able to defend themselves relatively effectively, and disease constrained
the ability of Europeans to settle in many tropical areas of India and west
and central Africa. In the western hemisphere, the introduction of European
diseases like measles so drastically decimated the native population—from
about 54 million in 1492 to approximately 13.5 million in 1570, a decline of
75 percent—that Europeans were able to seize the best land and resources
much more easily and cheaply than they could anywhere else on the globe. To
take advantage of this temporary relative strength, 17th and 18th century
European colonialism focused on the western hemisphere.
Atlantic trade made outsize contributions to European profits, especially for
Great Britain and France. The average annual value of Britain’s Atlantic com-
merce (exports, re-exports, imports, and services) increased from £20,084,000
in 1651–1670 to £105,546,000 in 1781–1800 to an amazing £231,046,000 in
1848–1850. African labor, both in Africa and in the Americas, generated most
of the wealth that financed this burgeoning trade. European exports made up a
little less than 40 percent of these totals. Historian Joseph Inikori estimated that
Africans produced no less than 69 percent (in 1651–1670 and in 1848–1850)
and up to 83 percent (in 1761–1780) of the value of British Atlantic com-
merce. For Britain, whose economy made up about one-third of the Atlantic
total, the rate of increase in Atlantic trade was far superior to that for other re-
gions. Whereas total British foreign trade doubled over the course of the 18th
century, British Atlantic trade increased by a factor of 12 in that same period!
22 Colonialism
developed the legal, financial, and commercial institutions and expertise that
supported the Industrial Revolution.
Although Atlantic trade dwarfed commercial interaction with Asia until
the late 19th century, it was desire for “oriental” (Asian) goods—spices, espe-
cially pepper; cotton and silk textiles; tea and coffee—that encouraged the
“take off ” of European long-distance trade. European demand for these goods
was exceptionally strong, but was not matched by an equivalent Asian desire
for European products. Europeans had to pay for pepper, cottons, and silks
with hard currency—gold and silver—that they did not have, thus constrain-
ing trade. What enabled Europeans to increase their consumption of Asian
goods was the exploitation of the Americas. The specie Europeans spent in
Asia came overwhelmingly from the Americas. In the 16th century, Spain and
Portugal initiated huge transfers of bullion, first by expropriation and then
from mining, that were then succeeded by the plantation economies devel-
oped in and around the Caribbean Sea.
The exploitation of Africans, both in Africa or in the western hemisphere,
enabled Europe to industrialize. Inikori’s important findings are comple-
mented by Kenneth Pomeranz’s provocative comparison of China and
Europe. Pomeranz contends that what enabled Europe to industrialize before
China was privileged access to the resources and markets of the Americas.
Thus, colonialism centered on the western hemisphere was of world historical
significance because of its essential role in permitting the industrialization of
Europe.
More effectively than its rivals, Britain developed a colonial empire popu-
lated by Europeans centered on the Atlantic world that contributed enor-
mously to the Industrial Revolution. Thanks to the effectiveness of mercantilist
trade policies like the Acts of Trade and the Navigation Acts, Britain also
profited more thoroughly from its expanding empire than rival European
powers. An estimate of the scale of annual profit for the era leading up to the
American Declaration of Independence in 1776 was £2.64 million out of an
official total of British imports and exports from the 13 North American
colonies valued at £9.5 million (28 percent). Although significant, this trade
was dwarfed by the annual profits on the trade in human beings, which
constituted almost 40 percent of the sum total of all British commercial and
industrial investment. Colonial trade comprised 15 percent of British com-
merce in the 1698 and one-third by 1774. The protected colonial market for
staple manufactured goods like woolens and for “new” products like cottons
eased the rivalry between the two industries and facilitated a rapid and con-
tinued growth of exports. The new industrial goods went overwhelmingly
to the colonies, thereby increasing demand and permitting continuous im-
provements in economies of scale. State regulation also suppressed potential
24 Colonialism
Further Reading
Broadberry, Stephen, and Kevin H. O’Rourke. The Cambridge Economic History
of Modern Europe, vol. 1, 1700–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010.
“Colonialism.” Available online at http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/colonialism/.
Inikori, Joseph E. Africans and the Industrial Revolution in England: A Study in Inter-
national Trade and Economic Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2002.
Landes, David. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some So
Poor. New York: W. W. Norton, 1998.
Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the
Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2000.
Stuchtey, Benedikt. “Colonialism and Imperialism, 1450–1950.” Available online at
http://ieg-ego.eu/en/threads/backgrounds/colonialism-and-imperialism/benedikt
-stuchtey-colonialism-and-imperialism-1450–1950.
Consumer Revolution 25
in the style of luxury goods imported from France, India, or China. A major
aim of 18th-century technological innovators and merchants was to render
goods that had been luxuries into products that could be marketed to much
wider audiences. This shift toward a wider market even within the luxury
trade was a key link in the chain connecting demand and supply, but it de-
serves reiteration that most members of the popular classes, even in the rich-
est countries and regions, could not afford such goods: their purchasing
power focused on subsistence. For some people outside the elite, the desire to
emulate, to consume was so great that they were willing to work longer hours
or to send their wives or children to work for wages in what has been termed
the “Industrious Revolution.”
To encourage these trends and to allow people to distinguish or differenti-
ate themselves from others through their taste or style, entrepreneurs engaged
in constant product innovation to attract the wandering eyes of fickle con-
sumers. The ability to implement these innovations marked a major diver-
gence from the market environment of earlier eras where reliably made
versions of standardized products, either by region or by a known manufac-
turer, were sold all over the globe. Speedier and more reliable modes of trans-
portation, the reduction of transfer costs, and improved credit facilities
enabled the spread of “fashionable” goods. So too did innovative means of
reaching the public. From traveling salesmen to showrooms in the capitals to
printed catalogues and advertising in the growing number of “fashion” maga-
zines that appeared in the 1770s throughout western Europe, merchants and
manufacturers attempted to influence public taste. Entrepreneurs also devel-
oped goods like medallions and plates that combined fashion (although not
always good taste!) with trendiness. A growing vogue for shopping developed:
to be seen looking at what was for sale was part of the experience. The role of
women in the desire for distinction and in the rise of shopping as a social
activity has been hotly debated. Women certainly were thoroughly engaged
in the process of social differentiation, but men were also deeply involved in
shopping. Women were a fundamental part of the development of taste, fash-
ion, style, and luxury, but both genders were responsible for the emergence of
consumer capitalism.
An important division emerged between the upper and middle classes
whose interest in the new, the fashionable, and in taste extended to all catego-
ries of available goods, and the lower classes who focused more (though far
from exclusively) on commodities they could consume. These goods included
tea, coffee, chocolate, tobacco, and sugar, but beer and spirits also were con-
sumed in increasing quantities. The addictive properties of these commodities
made many laboring families willing to work longer and harder to get their
cup of tea, chocolate fix, or tobacco product of choice. As Scottish economist
Cotton 27
James Steuart put it in 1767, “Men are forced to labour now because they are
slaves to their own wants.” Thus, as with the Agricultural Revolution, both
the “Industrious Revolution” and the Consumer Revolution predated the on-
set of revolutionary industrial transformation. The similarity of these precon-
ditions once again demonstrates the central importance of demand in calling
forth innovative organizational and technological means of meeting potent
consumer demand.
Further Reading
Benson, John. “Consumption and the Consumer Revolution.” Available online at
http://www.ehs.org.uk/dotAsset/b75cb989-ca95–4860-bb14–846183dec190
.pdf.
Berg, Maxine. Luxury & Pleasure in Eighteenth-Century Britain. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
versity Press, 2005.
Breen, T. H. The Marketplace of Revolution: How Consumer Politics Shaped American
Independence. New York: Oxford University Press, 2004.
Brewer, John, and Roy Porter, eds. Consumption and the World of Goods. London:
Routledge, 1994.
“The Consumer Revolution.” Available online at http://www.history.org/history
/teaching/enewsletter/volume5/december06/consumer_rev.cfm.
McKendrick, Neil, John Brewer, and J. H. Plumb. The Birth of a Consumer Society:
The Commercialization of Eighteenth-Century England. Bloomington: Indiana
University Press, 1982.
COTTON The Industrial Revolution began in one key sector: cotton tex-
tiles. New machines and new processes were developed to cope with specific
problems that had previously slowed down production. To compete with,
much less displace, Indian cottons from European, American, and African
markets, the manufacture of cotton textiles in Europe required massive im-
provement in industrial methods. Innovation in technologies, organization of
production, labor oversight, management, and marketing in the manufacture
of cotton textiles provided a model for a transformation that led the way to
an industrial revolution.
As a new sector engaged in import substitution, this industry was inde-
pendent of guild controls; such independence was vital to the ability of this
sector to innovate. Until the 18th century, cotton goods were available from
India and were generally brought in by monopolistic chartered companies.
Early European attempts to surpass or even successfully imitate Indian cotton
goods were thoroughly unsuccessful. Many European governments supported
28 Cotton
and in 1767, Richard Arkwright developed the water frame. Both began to be
used in 1768. Arkwright’s patent dates from the following year, Hargreaves’s
from the year after. Hargreaves’s invention saved considerable labor, but
did not fundamentally alter the production process. Arkwright’s machine
did. With his spinning or jenny-mule (1779), Samuel Crompton, also from
Lancashire, vastly increased the utility of both Arkwright’s and Hargreaves’s
machines. As the name suggests, this is a hybrid machine that was soon able
to do 200–300 times the work of a spinning wheel.
Crompton’s jenny-mule permitted an enormous increase in the quality
and quantity of cotton goods produced. For the first time, a European pro-
ducer could match the quality and undercut the cost of Indian cotton textiles.
A measure of how efficient a labor-saving device the jenny-mule was can be
seen in a comparison of the hours needed to process 100 pounds of cotton.
At the end of the 18th century, it took Indian hand spinners more than
50,000 hours, but with Crompton’s machine, it took only 2,000 hours. Me-
chanics, tinkerers, and workers who actually used the machines continuously
made further small refinements that, taken together, rapidly improved the
initial machines dramatically, thereby increasing their productivity.
Additional breakthrough machines followed, including the power-loom
developed by Reverend Edmund Cartwright in 1786. Although a power-loom
was no faster than a hand-weaver for several decades, a single worker could
run first two and then several looms, which sped up production considerably.
Frenchman Joseph-Marie Jacquard invented a draw loom capable of imprint-
ing designs and figures on the fabric through the use of punch cards. Devel-
oped for use with silk in 1801, the Jacquard loom was applied to all fabrics in
the second quarter of the 19th century. Richard Roberts applied power to re-
versing and turning the spindles at varying speeds to create a mule that did not
have to be “run” by a human being. He patented the “self-acting” mule in
1825 and improved it greatly five years later. Thanks to these innovative ma-
chines, what had taken 2,000 hours in the late 18th century dwindled to only
135 hours in 1825. This first major bottleneck to expanding production—
spinning—was swept aside. These machines saved such prodigious quantities
of labor that prices could fall, profits could rise, and demand could be satisfied
simultaneously.
Other technological developments that eliminated bottlenecks facilitated
the skyrocketing growth of the cotton industry. American mechanic Eli Whit-
ney developed the cotton gin in 1793 to remove the seeds and dirt from raw
cotton. In the 1780s, Arkwright greatly upgraded earlier carding machines
that combed and straightened the raw cotton. Finished yarn could be bleached
a brilliant white with chlorine using a process developed by French chemist
Claude Berthollet in 1784. However, in what would become a frequent
30 Credit
Further Reading
Beckert, Sven. Empire of Cotton: A Global History. New York: Vintage, 2014.
“Brief History of the Cotton Industry.” Available online at http://www.saburchill
.com/history/chapters/IR/014.html.
Landes, David. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Devel-
opment in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
versity Press, 1969.
Riello, Giorgio. Cotton: The Fabric That Made the Modern World. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press, 2013.
“Spinning the Web: The Story of the Cotton Industry.” Available online at http://
www.spinningtheweb.org.uk/.
During the early stages of the Industrial Revolution, a typical firm had
less than one-quarter of its assets in fixed goods like buildings, machines, and
tools. About 20 percent was in raw materials and stock while the remaining
capital—the bulk of the company’s assets—was in trade debt: goods that had
been shipped, but not yet paid for. These percentages take on even greater
weight when the sums involved are considered. Jedediah Strutt established a
cotton-spinning factory at Belper in 1793: it cost £5,000 to erect the build-
ing, another £5,000 for various machines (including but not restricted to
Arkwright water frames), and another £5,000 for stocks of raw materials. In
total, Strutt needed about £60,000 in working capital to get his business off
the ground, demonstrating the high financial barrier to industrial entrepre-
neurship. As machines got bigger and more expensive, the start-up costs and
capital requirements increased proportionately.
Credit was available from a variety of sources. Once established, many
firms made use of bills of exchange from other businesses, which specified
that a certain sum would be paid at a later date, often two or three months in
the future. The same mechanism was also utilized to allow storekeepers to
stock a manufacturer’s goods. A select few entrepreneurs, often inventors or
those seeking to achieve import substitution, received funding or loans di-
rectly from the state. Banks, however, were the most common source of credit
for industry, especially in Great Britain. They provided capital in exchange
for mortgages on buildings and machinery. It deserves emphasis that banks
and capital markets were regulated (more or less successfully) by the state,
usually to ensure its own access to credit.
Banks run by individuals or families and usually licensed by the govern-
ment had provided credit to industrial enterprises for centuries. In the 17th
century, as the financial center of Europe shifted from Amsterdam to Lon-
don, English banks benefited from the emergence of a sophisticated mortgage
market for land that contributed to the availability of capital for productive
purposes. The stability of the mercantilist English government, the profits of
the empire, and the continuing growth of trade combined with institutional
development of the nascent banking system to lower interest rates dramati-
cally. In 1700, annual interest rates were about 6 percent, but this already low
figure fell to 3.5 percent a year around midcentury. Between 1714 and 1832,
the English government prohibited commercial interest rates above 5 percent
a year. In France, Britain’s chief industrial competitor, interest rates never
dipped below 5 percent and even relatively safe investments in certain regions
were required to pay a great deal more than that. Thus, Britons enjoyed the
cheapest and most plentiful credit in the world.
The chief means by which Britain became the financial capital of Europe
was the Bank of England. Founded in 1694 to assist the government to
32 Credit
manage and consolidate its debt while lowering the rate of interest, the Bank
was focused on commerce and state finance. The emergence of private or
country banks in the early 18th century filled some of the void. These banks
were founded by those who were involved in a variety of endeavors (gold-
smiths, merchants, manufacturers) and provided much-needed credit due to
investments from those wishing to take advantage of the booming industrial
economy. When the Bank of England intermittently tightened credit because
of government demands between 1772 and 1825, many of these banks failed.
Thus, even in the country with the lowest borrowing rates and greatest avail-
ability of credit, industry was squeezed for capital and could not expand as
fast as it might have. Only after 1825 was the British and then the European
banking system organized more effectively, first by the Bank of England and
then by other state-run banks, to distribute capital to areas where it was
needed and drawing it from areas with a surplus.
The emergence of a more coherent, government-supervised banking sys-
tem after 1825 helped protect the British industrial achievement while gener-
ating profits that would sustain the island economy long after its manufacturers
were no longer as competitive. At the same time, government-sponsored banks
played major roles in helping continental nations catch up to the British. In
France, Belgium, and the German lands, banks furnished credit for strategic
purposes to build up the industrial economy rather than strictly from a short-
term profit and loss cost accounting. Credit was the grease that made the
Industrial Revolution run.
Further Reading
Hudson, Pat. The Genesis of Industrial Capital: A Study of the West Riding Wool Textile
Industry, c. 1750–1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.
Kindleberger, Charles P. A Financial History of Western Europe, 2nd ed. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1993.
King, Steven, and Geoffrey Timmins. Making Sense of the Industrial Revolution: Eng-
lish Economy and Society 1700–1850. Manchester: Manchester University Press,
2001.
Mokyr, Joel. “The Institutional Origins of the Industrial Revolution.” Available online
at http://faculty.wcas.northwestern.edu/~jmokyr/Institutional-Origins-4.pdf.
Quinn, Stephen. “Money, Finance and Capital Markets.” In The Cambridge Eco-
nomic History of Modern Britain, ed. Roderick Floud and Paul Johnson. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004.
Crystal Palace 33
Potato Famine of the 1840s, the population of the British Isles grew from
9 million in 1780 to 21 million in 1851. The Crystal Palace was the symbol
of that extraordinary growth in national and individual wealth.
Yet, by 1851, change was already in the air. Many British visitors at the
Crystal Palace were startled by the high quality and reasonable prices of man-
ufactured goods and luxury items from the continent and even from the
United States. Other countries began to industrialize, some on the British
model, but all recognized the importance of advanced scientific knowledge
and technological ability to economic development.
The United States’ industrial “coming of age” took place at the Crystal
Palace Exhibition. Although the American exhibit was quite small, the qual-
ity was impressive. Cyrus Hall McCormick’s mechanical reaper, Charles
Goodyear’s India rubber life-raft, and Samuel Colt’s six-shot pistol all won
prestigious medals, and Europeans publicly took notice of American technol-
ogy and metal-working skills. Success in the world of sport even played a role
in winning favorable publicity: the yacht America defeated the pride of Great
Britain, the S.S. Titania, in a race that has been perpetuated as the America’s
Cup. The Liverpool Times fretted, “The Yankees are no longer to be ridiculed,
much less despised. The new world is bursting into greatness—walking past
the old world, as the Americans did to the yachts . . . America, in her own
phrase, is ‘going ahead’ and will assuredly pass us unless we accelerate our
speed.” From humble beginnings, it was clear that by 1850 the Industrial
Revolution in North America had reached a point that some U.S. manufac-
tured goods could compete on the world market. The Crystal Palace marked
both the zenith of British industrial might and possibilities of new industrial
rivalries on the horizon.
Further Reading
Auerbach, Jeffrey A. The Great Exhibition of 1851: A Nation on Display. New Haven,
CT: Yale University Press, 1999.
“Crystal Palace: A History.” Available online at http://www.bbc.co.uk/london/con
tent/articles/2004/07/27/history_feature.shtml.
Hobhouse, Hermione. The Crystal Palace and the Great Exhibition: Science, Art and
Productive Industry: The History of the Royal Commission for the Exhibition of
1851. London: Bloomsbury Academic Press, 2002.
Johnson, Ben. “The Great Exhibition of 1851.” Available online at http://www
.historic-uk.com/HistoryUK/HistoryofEngland/Great-Exhibition-of-1851/.
Discipline 35
general than is necessary just to live and support their weekly debauches.” To
the greatest degree possible, managers wanted laborers to match the regularity
and stamina of the machines they tended. Managers resorted to a variety of
disciplinary measures that ranged from docking the pay of workers who did
not give their best effort to heavy doses of corporal punishment, applied
mostly to women and children.
British owners, managers, and foremen attempted to train children to act
the way they wanted. Their methods were not gentle. In a study of 609 exam-
ples of enforcing discipline or modifying the behavior of factory children
undertaken in 1833, nearly 95 percent of all the tactics used were negative,
with dismissal being the norm (58 percent), and fines (17 percent), corporal
punishment (9 percent), and threats (8 percent) also being common. A re-
ward was given only 23 times (4 percent), a promotion or raise 9 times
(1 percent), and kindness twice. Corporal punishment was considered neces-
sary to make “lazy” children work a 12- or 14-hour day, six days a week. In
1832, a slave owner testified before the House of Commons: “I have always
thought myself disgraced by being the owner of slaves, but we never in the
West Indies thought it possible for any human being to be so cruel as to re-
quire a child of nine years to work twelve and a half hours a day, and that, you
acknowledge, is your regular practice.”
Another aspect of the mounting effort to discipline the workforce focused
on getting workers to show up on time, every day, and to remain at their sta-
tions the entire day. This was not as easy as it sounded as customary practice
ran contrary. Another problem was that when workers labored six days a
week, their day of “rest”—Sunday—was often punctuated by blowing off a
little steam, often by drinking to excess. “Saint Monday” was the term used
when workers failed to come to work after a binge. Even Tuesday was a slow
day for those recovering from a particularly intense drunk. Managers also
wanted to cut down drastically on the number of holidays, religious or other-
wise, both paid and unpaid, to keep the machines humming. When the non-
factory workday usually ran from dawn to dusk and clocks and watches were
not yet common possessions, it was difficult to ensure punctuality, especially
for early morning shifts.
From the perspective of a manager or entrepreneur, discipline also implied
an individual relationship between master and man. In other words, manag-
ers did not want any kind of union, coalition, or association to unite workers
to contest or resist their demands. As individuals, unskilled workers had little
bargaining power; their strength rested solely in numbers. So managers at-
tacked workers’ organizations, breaking them whenever and however possi-
ble. They also took aim at customary work practices that, to their way of
thinking, prevented innovation and reduced efficiency. Managers resented
Discipline 37
Further Reading
Archer, John E. Social Unrest and Popular Protest in England 1780–1840. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2000.
Hobsbawm, Eric. Industry and Empire: The Birth of the Industrial Revolution. Lon-
don: Penguin, 1969.
Horn, Jeff, Leonard N. Rosenband, and Merritt Roe Smith, eds. Reconceptualizing
the Industrial Revolution. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2010.
“Labor History Links.” Available online at http://www.laborhistorylinks.org/index
.html.
Thompson, E. P. The Making of the English Working Class. New York: Vintage Press,
1966 (1963).
Further Reading
Burnette, Joyce. Gender, Work and Wages in Industrial Revolution Britain. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2008.
Daunton, Martin J. Progress and Poverty: An Economic and Social History of Britain
1700–1850. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995.
Hendrickson Kenneth E. III, ed. The Encyclopedia of the Industrial Revolution in
World History, vol. 3. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books, 2014.
Munger, Michael, “Division of Labor.” Available online at http://www.econlib.org
/library/Enc/DivisionofLabor.html.
The putting out system had tremendous productive potential and played
a major role in accelerating the interaction of the rural populace with local,
national, and international markets. A prosperous shopkeeper or affluent
farmer required only a limited amount of capital to begin finding client fami-
lies. The profitability of the system was based on the low wages given to rural
workers, who accepted a pittance because they needed only to augment their
agricultural income. Rural wages were at least 20 percent and up to 50 per-
cent lower than their urban equivalents. Yet careful and thrifty workers could
and did better themselves. Especially on the continent, domestic industry al-
lowed significant numbers of poor or marginal agricultural laborers or small-
holders to remain on the land far longer than would otherwise have been
possible.
Eventually, putting out came to dominate whole regions of Europe and
contributed substantially to total industrial output. From Ireland to Prussia,
dense networks of rural outworkers numbering in the hundreds of thousands
and stretching up to 80 kilometers in a given direction surrounded many
large mercantile cities that shipped goods abroad. This phenomenon has
sometimes been termed “proto-industrialization.” In the Austrian Nether-
lands (modern-day Belgium), a quarter of the working population toiled in
domestic industry in the middle of the 18th century. In addition to textiles,
goods that were put out included gloves, lace, ribbons, stockings, hats, boots,
shoes, pins, nails, and cutlery, as well as other hardware. At the end of the
18th century, the putting out system accounted for 43 percent of all manu-
factured goods in the German-speaking lands. By increasing textile produc-
tion, spreading spinning and weaving skills to the rural population and
introducing a market mentality into the day-to-day lives of many Europeans,
the putting out system paved the way for industrialization based on the fac-
tory system. As a form of production, rural industry lasted alongside newer
means of production until the 1930s.
Domestic industry and especially the putting out system also responded to
the limitations and lack of flexibility inherent in the output of urban guilds
with monopolies on the manufacture and often sale of certain types of goods.
With demand outstripping supply, mercantilist governments dedicated to
self-sufficiency and import substitution wanted to provide work and domi-
nate the domestic market. Because communities of guilds were unwilling or
unable to produce the kinds, qualities, and quantities of goods demanded by
other continents as well as by the burgeoning European population, different
methods of satisfying these markets had to be developed. To sidestep guild
restrictions on urban production, entrepreneurs, including merchants, no-
bles, and even state officials either funded or allowed the massive expansion of
domestic industry into northwestern Europe’s large-scale putting out system.
42 Education
Domestic industry and the putting out system responded to growing con-
sumer demand and the restrictions of the existing productive environment.
Rural labor engaged in this poorly paid work in order to remain on the land
or, far more rarely, to afford to buy luxuries like coffee, chocolate, or even
a fashionable shirt. Although production could be increased relatively easily
through this system and the low wages paid to laborers made this approach
competitive in some ways, machine-based production was of finer quality
and could take advantage of greater economies of scale. Domestic industry
lasted into the 20th century in several regions, but its heyday was 1680–1830.
It enabled and led to industrialization.
Further Reading
Daunton, Martin J. Progress and Poverty: An Economic and Social History of Britain
1700–1850. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995.
Hudson, Pat. “Proto-Industrialisation.” Available online at http://www.ehs.org.uk
/dotAsset/1d40418e-b981–4076–8974-b81686a9d042.pdf.
Kisch, Herbert. From Domestic Manufacture to Industrial Revolution: The Case of the
Rhineland Textile Districts. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1989.
Ogilvie, Sheilagh C., and Markus Cerman, eds. European Proto-industrialization.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996 [1994].
Although financial incentives for innovation and the enticement of skilled work-
ers from abroad played important roles in this process, education was at the
heart of the long-term French approach to becoming competitive.
Educational institutions were to facilitate the application of French pre-
dominance in basic science, especially in chemistry, mathematics, and medi-
cine to the problems of production. French education also aimed to spread
mechanical knowledge more widely and deeply among the laboring classes.
These educational efforts began during the Revolution with the creation of
the National Institute and the Polytechnic in 1794, which were staffed by
some of the best scientific minds alive. These elite institutions were supposed
to provide expert training and to reorient theoretically minded French elites
toward practical problems of industry and engineering. It was hoped that
their effects would trickle down the French educational system. Thanks to
Jean-Antoine Chaptal, students at specialized training schools for mining and
civil engineers also began to spend part of each year in the field learning about
the practical problems they would someday face. The thorough reform of the
university system undertaken by Emperor Napoleon I in 1808 supported
these goals. To bridge the gap between the elite and the rest of the population,
the French opened two Schools of Arts and Crafts (1803, 1811) where skilled
workers, foremen, engineers, and scientists melded scientific theory and
hands-on practice with machines. According to their founding statutes, these
schools were to “train petty officers for industry.”
Chaptal and his collaborators also sought to institutionalize the type of
interaction of scientists, innovators, entrepreneurs, and bureaucrats that took
place in the London Society of Arts and the Lunar Society of Birmingham.
These educational efforts helped France develop expertise in areas where they
could compete successfully with the British, strongly supporting French in-
dustrialization throughout the 19th century.
Further Reading
Horn, Jeff. The Path Not Taken: French Industrialization in the Age of Enlightenment,
1750–1830. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2006.
Jacob, Margaret C. Scientific Culture and the Making of the Industrial West. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1997.
Mitch, David. “Education and Economic Growth in Historical Perspective.” Availa-
ble online at https://eh.net/encyclopedia/education-and-economic-growth-in
-historical-perspective/.
Enlightenment 45
Mokyr, Joel. The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Prince-
ton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2004.
led to new theories concerning the properties of light and colors, which cul-
minated in the invention of the reflecting telescope. Despite the efforts of
gifted writers such as John Locke and Voltaire, who published popular and
popularized explanations of Newton’s ideas in 1704 and 1733 respectively, it
took decades for Newton’s ideas to percolate through the educated strata of
western society. Such fundamental conceptual reordering of people’s under-
standing of the universe demonstrated the possibilities of human endeavor
and took the prestige of English science and technology to new heights, jus-
tifying the broad and deep transformation envisioned by the philosophes.
The Enlightenment emphasized the diffusion of ideas. Frenchmen Denis
Diderot (1713–1784) and Jean le Rond d’Alembert (1717–1783) led a great
collaborative enterprise to rationalize and categorize existing knowledge.
They published a 24-volume compendium of existing knowledge, the Ency-
clopédie, between 1751 and 1772. Diderot and d’Alembert had to overcome
the opposition of powerful individuals in the Church hierarchy and state
administration. Other 18th-century projects of diffusion and rationalization
included the creation of the periodic table of elements and Swede Carl von
Linné’s (or Linnaeus, 1707–1778) development of a means of classifying
plants and animals into categories. The organization and publication of cur-
rent scientific knowledge set the stage for later accomplishments.
Although science made few direct contributions to manufacturing tech-
nology during the first few decades of the Industrial Revolution, it did
accomplish something vital. The Scientific Revolution bequeathed a new in-
ductive method of testing ideas that focused on experimentation. The wave
of scientific discoveries, clever experiments, and geographical explorations
that followed helped to convince the average person that an improvement of
the human condition was not only possible but underway. As a result of the
Enlightenment, the prospect of “progress,” both in understanding and mate-
rially, gradually overcame the pessimistic views of people like Thomas Malthus
that had dominated European society for a millennium. In the 19th century,
this faith in progress became firmly entrenched as technological change and
industrialization first transformed the day-to-day life of western Europeans,
and ultimately, much of the world.
The Enlightenment also shaped agricultural improvement. Arthur Young
(1741–1820), a leading English agricultural writer, emphasized the impor-
tance of education, the development of new knowledge, and the utility of help-
ing agricultural entrepreneurs to escape the binding restrictions of customary
practice through innovation, all hallmarks of the Enlightenment. Young’s fer-
vor for agricultural improvement was shared by an impressive number of other
people in Great Britain and throughout western Europe, bringing the benefits
of the new ways of thinking to ever wider audiences.
Factory Acts 47
Further Reading
Day, C. R. Education for the Industrial World: The Ècole d’Arts et Métiers and the Rise
of French Industrial Engineering. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987.
Jacob, Margaret C. The First Knowledge Economy: Human Capital and the European
Economy, 1750–1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2014.
Jones, Peter M. Industrial Enlightenment: Science, Technology and Culture in Birming-
ham and the West Midlands 1760–1820. Manchester: Manchester University
Press, 2008.
Mokyr, Joel. The Gifts of Athena. Available online at http://www.nes.ru/NES10/cd
/materials/Mokyr-2chapters.pdf.
taxes, which the justices usually wanted to keep as low as possible, the law was
generally ignored. Mill owners increasingly turned to unregulated “free” labor
instead of relying on parish apprentices.
In the aftermath of the Napoleonic Wars, the British Parliament again
took up factory regulation on the instigation of Robert Owen. Peel agreed to
sponsor the project, but it took three years of parliamentary investigations
and numerous concessions that gutted the bill before the passage of the Cot-
ton Mills and Factories Act in 1819. This measure forbade the employment
of children under the age of 9 and restricted children aged 9–16 to 12 hours’
work per day between the hours of 5 a.m. and 9 p.m. (six days a week), but
only in cotton factories. Again, justices of the peace were supposed to enforce
the act, but no funds for inspection were allocated, rendering this bill, like its
predecessor, almost completely without practical effect.
The tide of reform that followed widespread popular unrest in 1830–1831
included important limitations on child factory labor. A narrow Labour in
Cotton Mills Act passed in 1831 excluded night work for anyone under the
age of 21 working in a factory, but was clearly understood as a stopgap meas-
ure. The creation of a parliamentary commission spearheaded by Anthony
Ashley-Cooper, later Earl of Shaftesbury, and Michael Sadler led to a scathing
report that prompted the establishment of more extensive restrictions on
child labor and created more effective means of enforcement, though large
loopholes continued to exist.
The Factory Act of 1833 forbade children under the age of nine from
working in textiles (except silk mills). Children between 9 and 13 could not
work more than eight hours without getting an hour-long lunch break. They
were also to receive two hours of education per day (in addition to going
to work) and could be employed no more than 48 hours a week. For children
aged 14 to 18, the length of the day’s labor that required a formal meal break
was 12 hours. Nobody under 18 years old could work between 8:30 p.m. and
5:30 a.m. Factories were to be regularly inspected and a dedicated professional
corps of inspectors was established that was independent of local authorities
and did not require ministerial authorization to act.
The humanitarian impulses that led to the enfranchisement of Catholics
in 1831, the parliamentary Reform Act of 1832, and the abolition of slavery
in the United Kingdom and its colonies in 1833 did not stop mill owners
from objecting strenuously to the passage of the Factory Act. They com-
plained to the House of Commons that such limitations were “prejudicial to
the Cotton Trade” and “impracticable” because “Free labourers cannot be
obtained to perform the night work, but upon very disadvantageous terms to
the manufacturers.” The continued success of Britain’s textile industry em-
powered the next generation of reformers to push for new restrictions on the
Factory Acts 49
work day in all factories without exception and to apply the same constraints
established in 1833 to young people and to women.
An 1844 Factory Act affected all textile mills (except lace and silk) and
banned women and youths between 13 and 17 from working more than
12 hours a day. Children under the age of 13 could work no more than
6.5 hours a day and children under the age of 8 could not be employed. Three
years later, a Ten Hour Act was applied to women and youths with total hours
reduced to 63 and then 58 hours by May 1848. In 1850, the workday was set
to either 6 a.m. to 6 p.m. or 7 a.m. to 7 p.m. and women and youths could
work a maximum of 10.5 hours a day (with 1.5 hours of breaks). Six more
Factory Acts were passed between 1853 and 1878 that extended the rules on
children, youths, and females established for textiles to all other factories.
The factory acts were a series of small steps in the direction of reform. It
took more than 30 years to pass effective limitations on child labor in the
cotton industry and another 45 years for those restrictions to be applied to all
factory work. There was widespread pressure to improve the conditions of
labor from elites, the middle classes, and workers themselves. The continued
vigor of British industry and the tremendous wealth gained from the Indus-
trial Revolution allowed these halting reforms from above to be implemented
before the eruption of major violence. The factory acts showed that an indus-
trial economy can allow the working classes to gain a share of the benefits
without destroying profitability. This model was widely copied and even sur-
passed by Britain’s industrial rivals in the second half of the 19th century.
Further Reading
Burnette, Joyce. “Women Workers in the British Industrial Revolution.” Available
online at https://eh.net/encyclopedia/women-workers-in-the-british-industrial
-revolution-2/.
“1833 Factory Act.” Available online at http://www.nationalarchives.gov.uk/education
/resources/1833-factory-act/.
Harris, Ron. “Government and the Economy, 1688–1850.” In The Cambridge Eco-
nomic History of Modern Britain, vol. 1, Industrialisation, 1700–1860, ed. Roder-
ick Floud and Paul Johnson. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004.
Quinault, Roland. “The Industrial Revolution and Parliamentary Reform.” In The
Industrial Revolution and British Society, edited by Patrick O’Brien and Roland
Quinault. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993.
50 Factory System
Tuttle, Carolyn. “Child Labor during the British Industrial Revolution.” Available online
at https://eh.net/encyclopedia/child-labor-during-the-british-industrial-revolution/.
by factory labor, and they were willing to be trained to work the machines.)
In the short run, Arkwright solved the labor problem by accepting a huge
number of youthful apprentices from poor houses all over Britain. The child
and teenage apprentices lived at the mill and were bound (i.e., they could not
leave) to work for Arkwright either until they reached the age of 18 or for
seven years, whichever was longer!
Arkwright’s long-term answer to his labor problem was to return to the
region of his birth. He set up his factories in the relatively poor region of
Lancashire where domestic industry was well established. Lancashire also had
a large number of small streams and shallow rivers that were perfect for turn-
ing waterwheels. The region enjoyed excellent access to the sea through the
port of Liverpool. Other entrepreneurs followed him both in moving to the
province to benefit from the same cost advantages and by taking thorough
going advantage of child, female, convict, and apprentice labor.
The British pioneered the factory system, and it spread most rapidly there.
As a result, the manufactured goods produced in the British Isles tended to be
cheaper and in many cases better (thanks to the mechanization of many op-
erations) than those made in other countries, allowing ever-increasing econo-
mies of scale. British industrial dominance in the first half of the 19th century
was founded on relatively inexpensive goods made with machinery and a high
level of division of labor by workers with unique craft skills in economic sec-
tors with highly elastic demand. Yet these advantages did not survive changes
in the production process, the development of other countries’ industrial sec-
tors, and in consumer demand that ultimately sounded the death knell for
British dominance, but not until after 1870.
Factories pre-dated the Industrial Revolution in the sense that large build-
ings that housed many workers collaborating in the manufacture of some
product had existed for centuries. Silks, tapestries, porcelain, weapons, and
some ships were made at sites that qualified as factories. But in the 18th cen-
tury, in order to satisfy the burgeoning market for cotton textiles, a hierarchi-
cal management emerged that was interested in implementing mechanization,
substituting water or coal for human energy, and instituting a greater division
of labor. Such means of maximizing production necessitated a much more
thorough control over labor and the work process. These characteristics were
the difference between a factory derived from the term “manufacture” and a
factory system. This shift, along with reliance on water and coal power, trans-
formed the means of production by lowering costs. Because of competition
both from India and from other European countries, such saving went into
reducing prices to increase demand rather than increasing profits. Lower
profit per unit was acceptable when volume was skyrocketing. The creation
and spread of the modern factory system within the confines of the British
52 Fitch, John
textile sector during the late 18th century represented the true beginnings of
the Industrial Revolution.
Further Reading
Hackett, Lewis. “Industrial Revolution.” Available online at http://history-world
.org/Industrial%20Intro.htm.
Hounshell, David A. From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932: The
Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1984.
Hudson, Pat. “Industrial Organization and Structure.” In The Cambridge Economic
History of Modern Britain, vol. 1, Industrialisation, 1700–1860, ed. Roderick
Floud and Paul Johnson. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004.
Mantoux, Paul. The Industrial Revolution in the Eighteenth Century: An Outline of the
Beginnings of the Modern Factory System in England, rev. ed. New York: Harper &
Row, 1961.
Mokyr, Joel. “The Rise and Fall of the Factory System: Technology, Firms, and
Households since the Industrial Revolution.” Available online at http://faculty
.wcas.northwestern.edu/~jmokyr/pittsburgh.PDF.
territories in the Ohio River valley, where he was captured by Native Ameri-
cans. He survived captivity and settled north of Philadelphia where he began
to experiment with steamboats in 1785 at the same time as several competi-
tors, most notably engineer James Rumsey.
Racing to stay ahead of his rivals and to find financial sponsors, Fitch
staged a spectacle in front of delegates to the Constitutional Convention in
August 1787. This steamboat featured two horizontal racks of oars on either
side of the vessel rather than a paddle wheel. It ran successfully in the Dela-
ware and Schuylkill Rivers. Several delegates even took a ride on the new
invention. Fitch’s hopes for federal financial support were disappointed, but
he took on Henry Voigt as a partner and built an improved 60-foot steamboat
with stern-mounted oars. In the summer of 1790, this steamboat, able to
carry up to 30 passengers, made many round-trips between Philadelphia and
Burlington. The business failed: customers were few and far between.
Despite the bankruptcy of his business, Fitch received the first U.S. patent
for steamboats in August 1791; his French patent was awarded later the same
year. However, the newly established Patent Commission only awarded Fitch
a monopoly on his most recent design rather than the monopoly on steam-
boats that he sought. Other inventors received related patents on the same
day, which undermined Fitch’s efforts to find financial supporters or partners.
Fitch went to France hoping to capitalize on his French patent, but failed to
find backers amid the turmoil of the French Revolution.
Fitch returned to the United States in 1793 and attempted to claim land
around Bardstown, Kentucky, that he had surveyed in the 1780s, but squat-
ters had already taken up residence. A lengthy court battle followed—as he
continued to experiment with steam engines—during which Fitch despaired
and committed suicide in 1798. Fitch’s career shows how difficult it was for
inventors, even those with patent protection, to profit from their inventions
without powerful patrons or partners. His experiences also show that inven-
tors can take various routes to solving the same technical difficulties and dem-
onstrates that the design that becomes popular is not always selected due to
superior technology.
Further Reading
“John Fitch: First Steamboat.” Available online at http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/they
madeamerica/whomade/fitch_hi.html.
“The John Fitch Steamboat Museum.” Available online at http://www.craven-hall
.org/fitch-steamboat-museum/.
54 Hargreaves, James
Prager, Frank, ed. The Autobiography of John Fitch. Philadelphia: Memoirs of the
American Philosophical Society, 1976.
Sutcliffe, Andrea. Steam: The Untold Story of America’s First Great Invention. New
York: St. Martin’s Press, 2004.
wealthy was based on selling his machines. They were cheap to make; they
required only a skilled craftsman to make precision parts that moved seam-
lessly. His problem was that other manufacturers copied his design with ease
and then refused to pay the patent fees. He sued, but the court found that
since his machines had been used before he patented them, his patent was
meaningless. Hargreaves did not die penniless, as another legend has it; he left
an estate worth £4,000, but this was a pittance compared to the economic
value of his invention. A decade after his death, at least 20,000 spinning jen-
nies were at work in Great Britain with thousands more to be found on the
continent. The device was also swiftly adapted to wool and later linen and
silk. Each machine did the work of at least eight people. The spinning jenny
completely altered the production of cotton textiles and played a major role
in sparking the Industrial Revolution.
Further Reading
“James Hargreaves.” Available online at http://www.famousinventors.org/james
-hargreaves.
MacLeod, Christine. Inventing the Industrial Revolution: The English Patent System,
1660–1800. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002.
Mantoux, Paul. The Industrial Revolution in the Eighteenth Century: An Outline of the
Beginnings of the Modern Factory System in England, rev. ed. New York: Harper &
Row, 1961.
Timmins, Geoffrey. Four Centuries of Lancashire Cotton. Preston: Lancashire County
Books, 1996.
counterweigh the generally falling wages of the period up to 1830. The term is
currently at the center of a major academic debate on the Industrial Revolution:
accepting the idea has important implications for explanations of economic
behavior.
According to its proponents, the “Industrious Revolution” responded to
both demand- and supply-side factors and places the Industrial Revolution in
a broader context. By getting families to decide to work longer hours, “indus-
triousness” increased production by expanding the supply of labor. At the same
time, the elasticity of household labor supply meant that demand for con-
sumer goods could be satisfied, thereby allowing demand to grow even more
rapidly. Such a conception of the origins of the British Industrial Revolution
understands this transformation as essentially a supply-side phenomenon.
Households became more industrious in two main ways. First, labor was
reallocated through the reduction of leisure time. Men, women, and children
performed not just more labor, but, more importantly, worked increasingly
for wages. Instead of making what the household needed, families that worked
for wages progressively purchased not only what they needed, but what they
wanted. This shift in the nature of production and consumption permitted
greater specialization and helped to increase the productivity of labor. This
process preceded and was independent of the organizational and technologi-
cal developments associated with the first Industrial Revolution.
The “Industrious Revolution” is a complex notion that may explain certain
aspects of popular behavior in the 17th and 18th centuries, but it is less clear
whether this concept explains the onset of modern economic growth through
industrial transformation, as its adherents claim. Was demand for consumer
goods the cause or the effect of the pressure of declining wages on the family
economy? Within those increasingly industrious families, was the “Industrious
Revolution” a means by which male heads of household appropriated the ben-
efits of the wage labor of women and children? Was there a compelling linkage
between industriousness and industrial transformation? The answers to these
questions and others like them are hotly debated. Beyond the simple yet im-
portant fact that in the 17th and 18th centuries consumption of consumer
goods increased and went further down the social scale than ever before, pro-
ponents of the idea have struggled to marshal convincing evidence to tie it
to broader economic trends and transformations. In its contemporary usage,
focus on the “Industrious Revolution” privileges a supply-side explanation of
the origins of the Industrial Revolution by ignoring or at least undervaluing
issues of class, the standard of living, and changes in the nature of production.
The existence and role of an “Industrious Revolution” and its relationship to
the Consumer Revolution will continue to motivate research into the origins
of the Industrial Revolution for the foreseeable future.
Interchangeable Parts 57
Further Reading
Allen, Robert C., and Jacob Louis Weisdorf. “Was There an ‘Industrious Revolution’
before the Industrial Revolution? An Empirical Exercise for England, c. 1300–
1830.” Available online at http://www.economics.ku.dk/research/publications
/wp/dp_2010/1014.pdf/.
Burnette, Joyce. “Women Workers in the British Industrial Revolution.” Available
online at https://eh.net/encyclopedia/women-workers-in-the-british-industrial
-revolution/.
De Vries, Jan. The Industrious Revolution: Consumer Behavior and the Household Econ-
omy, 1650 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008.
Ogilvie, Sheilagh. “Consumption, Social Capital, and the ‘Industrious Revolution’ in
Early Modern Germany.” Journal of Economic History 70, no. 2 (2010): 287–
325. Available online at http://www.econ.cam.ac.uk/Ogilvie_ESRC/publica
tions/Ogilvie-2010-JEH.pdf.
promising, the opposition of skilled gunsmiths who did not want to be told
how to do their jobs was considered too implacable to ramp up to full-scale
production.
Honoré Blanc (1736–1801), an experienced mechanic and gunsmith, re-
vived the idea. He set up a workshop to make gunlocks, the critical piece. In
1785, Blanc staged a public experiment in which he had another gunsmith
assemble a gunlock, choosing randomly from a bin with the parts to make
50 muskets. The demonstration succeeded brilliantly, but workers’ opposition
again postponed setting up production. When France went to war in 1792,
however, Blanc broke down the process of manufacturing muskets into as
many simple tasks as possible with the goal of using this division of labor to
undermine opposition to interchangeable parts. The government supported
Blanc’s efforts, but artisanal resistance slowed down the process. Production
at Blanc’s workshop at Roanne using a number of purpose-built gauges, tools,
and machines began in 1797. After his death, this enterprise produced
about 10,000 fully interchangeable gunlocks annually in the first years of the
19th century, constituting about 5 percent of the needs of Napoleonic France
at a price 20 percent higher than those made using traditional methods. But
when state subsidies ended, so did production.
American mechanic Eli Whitney attempted to replicate Blanc’s process. He
won a contract with the U.S. War Department to make 10,000 muskets by
September 1800. Whitney built or invented a set of purpose-built machines
capable of manufacturing many of the key parts with precision. It took Whit-
ney until January 1809 to fulfill his contract; he used the goal of interchange-
able parts as an excuse to justify the delays. Although Whitney never developed
a set of machines capable of manufacturing interchangeable parts, he did
propagate the idea, setting the stage for John Hancock Hall (1781–1841) to
achieve interchangeability in 1824 at the Harpers Ferry armory. Based on that
tardy beginning, the manufacturing techniques spread to other armories and
workshops and from there to other industries. After 1850, interchangeable
parts became an integral part of U.S. manufacturing.
Further Reading
Alder, Kenneth. Engineering the Revolution: Arms and Enlightenment in France, 1763–
1815. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997.
Lienhard, John H. “Interchangeable Parts.” Available online at http://www.uh.edu
/engines/epi1252.htm.
Iron and Steel 59
IRON AND STEEL Iron was essential to building the machines and infra-
structure that made the Industrial Revolution. Although steel, an alloy of iron
and carbon, had been made beginning many centuries before the Common
Era, it was not cost effective for widespread employment except for certain
specialized uses such as swords. Experimentation across the 18th century im-
proved iron production, which facilitated mechanization in a wide variety of
industries, making an industrial revolution possible.
Across the early modern era, the British iron industry was the largest, most
innovative and internationally competitive in the world. Britain had large de-
posits of iron ore, but when greater strength or higher quality was needed,
it imported ore from countries on the Baltic Sea, particularly Sweden and
Russia. Wrought (malleable) iron was generally smelted by combining pig
iron (crude cast into ingots known as “pigs”) with charcoal, a vegetable fuel
that did not transmit impurities to the finished product. In 18th-century Eng-
land, however, charcoal was in short supply because of a general shortage of
wood, which led Abraham Darby to experiment with coke beginning in 1709.
As a result of ongoing scarcity, roughly one-third of British iron production
relocated to the 13 North American colonies, especially to Pennsylvania,
where wood was plentiful as well as easy and cheap to move on the many rivers
of the region. The definitive loss of these colonies in 1783 provided a signifi-
cant cost incentive to the British to further their use of coal as a replacement
fuel. Thus, the development of the iron and coal industries was inextricably
linked in the 18th and 19th centuries.
As in textiles, experimentation by those Britons directly involved in the
production process was the key to improving technique. Iron-masters discov-
ered how to apply heat indirectly. A reverberatory furnace stirred molten pig
over a bed of coal until it became wrought iron, preventing direct contact
between the coal and the iron. This process, known as “puddling,” was devel-
oped by Englishman Henry Cort (1740–1800) in 1783–1784 and perfected
in the 1790s. Further improvements made iron produced with coal as fuel of
equal or higher quality to traditional production using charcoal while main-
taining puddling’s huge cost advantage. Cort’s methods also permitted 15 tons
of iron to be processed in 12 hours. A forge-hammer could usually but not
60 Iron and Steel
always produce a single ton in the same time. These innovations enabled a
rapid expansion of iron production in the late 1790s, and even faster growth
in the first decades of the 19th century as machines made from metal became
ever-more crucial to economic development. From 23,000 tons produced an-
nually around 1720, Britain’s annual output attained 3.5 million tons by the
end of the 1850s.
Although iron was the indispensable component of machines and infra-
structure in the age of the Industrial Revolution, steel too played a role. Steel
is an iron alloy that contains 1–2 percent carbon: it is stronger than low-
carbon (less than 1 percent) wrought iron, and more malleable than high-
carbon (cast or) pig iron. The major improvement that took place during the
18th century was the development of the technique to make crucible or cast
steel by English instrument maker Benjamin Huntsman around 1742. His
breakthrough was to mix bars of steel with an alkali in a clay crucible and
then heat them with coke. Cast steel had many uses, but it was still quite
expensive and rather brittle. Only precision instruments, certain tools like
files, and some bladed weapons were worth the expense. Although most
of the machines that “made” the Industrial Revolution would have benefitted
from higher-quality steel construction, iron or even wooden construction
was much more economical and easier to make. Many 18th- and early 19th-
century manufacturing processes were not optimal, but they worked well
enough to begin a revolutionary transformation. Improved iron production
made the Industrial Revolution while the emergence of economical means of
producing steel in the 1860s was the basis of the Second Industrial Revolu-
tion and the eventual eclipse of Britain in metalworking.
Further Reading
Carr, James C., and Walter Taplin. A History of the British Steel Industry. Cambridge,
MA: Basil Blackwell, 1962.
Casson, Herbert Newton. “The Romance of Steel: A History of the United States
Steel Industry.” Available online at http://www.rodneyohebsion.com/steel.htm.
Landes, David. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Devel-
opment in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
versity Press, 1969.
Misa, Thomas J. A Nation of Steel: The Making of Modern America, 1865–1925. Bal-
timore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995.
Spoerl, Joseph S. “A Brief History of Iron and Steel Production.” Available online at
http://www.anselm.edu/homepage/dbanach/h-carnegie-steel.htm.
Jacquard, Joseph-Marie 61
and technology believe that Babbage’s devices were the forerunner of contem-
porary methods of computer programming. Today, Jacquard-style weaving is
still widespread, but now a computer scans the design and operates the loom.
Further Reading
Essinger, James. Jacquard’s Web: How a Hand-Loom Led to the Birth of the Information
Age. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2004.
“The Jacquard Loom.” Available online at http://www.gadagne.musees.lyon.fr
/index.php/history_en/content/download/2939/27413/file/zoom_jacquard
_eng.pdf.
Jenkins, D. T. The Cambridge History of Western Textiles, vol. 1. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press, 1994.
“Joseph-Marie Jacquard.” Available online at http://history-computer.com/Dream
ers/Jacquard.html.
tinker with new machines and ways of organizing production. The combina-
tion of factors that led to rapid industrial growth attracted more entrepre-
neurs to a 30-mile-wide circle around Manchester. New-built canals like the
Duke of Bridgewater’s delivered coal, and foundries provided the iron used to
make machines and factories and later steam engines and railroad tracks.
Seemingly infinite demand for cotton textiles and the county’s growing abil-
ity to supply good-quality textiles at rock bottom prices drove the British
Industrial Revolution and carried the rest of Lancashire and indeed all of
England along with it.
The county’s population doubled to more than 700,000 between 1761
and 1801, making it the fastest growing area in England during an era of
rapid overall population growth. By the latter date, nearly a quarter million
men, women, and children labored in Lancashire’s cotton industry. In 1851,
the county’s population surpassed 2 million with nearly 375,000 people
working in the cotton trades. At its height around 1861, almost 450,000 men
and women made cotton goods in Lancashire. During the Industrial Revolu-
tion, Lancashire produced between 55 percent and 70 percent of Britain’s
total output of cottons, which grew to become the largest industry in the
country. In 1831, the two counties of Lancashire and its neighbor, the West
Riding, housed approximately 55 percent of the manufacturing jobs in the
entire United Kingdom. The radical transformation of economy and society
associated with the first Industrial Revolution occurred first and most thor-
oughly in Lancashire. For most of the period, industrialization was a regional,
not a national, phenomenon: it was centered on the county of Lancashire.
Further Reading
Mantoux, Paul. The Industrial Revolution in the Eighteenth Century: An Outline of the
Beginnings of the Modern Factory System in England, rev. ed. New York: Harper &
Row, 1961.
Marshall, Dorothy. Industrial England 1776–1851. New York: Routledge, 1973.
Timmins, Geoffrey. Made in Lancashire: A History of Regional Industrialisation. Man-
chester: Manchester University Press, 1998.
64 Liebig, Justus von
Further Reading
Brock, William H. Justus von Liebig: The Chemical Gatekeeper. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press, 1997.
“Justus von Liebig and Friedrich Wöhler.” Available online at http://www.chemherit
age.org/discover/online-resources/chemistry-in-history/themes/molecular
-synthesis-structure-and-bonding/liebig-and-wohler.aspx.
Rossiter, Margaret W. The Emergence of Agricultural Science: Justus Liebig and the
Americans, 1840–1880. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1975.
Wilson, Kelpie. “Justus von Liebig and the Birth of Modern Biochar.” Available on-
line at http://www.ithaka-journal.net/english-justus-von-liebig-and-the-birth-of
-modern-biochar?lang=en.
Further Reading
Binfield, Kevin, ed. Writings of the Luddites. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University
Press, 2004.
Horn, Jeff. The Path Not Taken: French Industrialization in the Age of Revolution,
1750–1830. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2006.
“The Luddite Link.” Available online at http://ludditelink.org.uk/.
“The Luddites at 200.” Available online at http://www.luddites200.org.uk/the
Luddites.html.
Randall, Adrian. Before the Luddites: Custom, Community and Machinery in the English
Woollen Industry, 1776–1809. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.
chartered by the state, which provided some support but usually left the vast
majority of the activities of these associations unregulated. Chartered compa-
nies could institute laws, fight wars, make treaties (subject to state approval),
and enjoyed a monopoly of trade and/or colonization in their area of opera-
tion. The English established chartered companies to trade with Muscovy
(1555), the Levant (1581), East Indies (1600), and Hudson’s Bay (1670).
Other charters entrusted colonization to the Virginia Company (1606) and
the Massachusetts Bay Company (1629). The Netherlands established East
India (1602) and West India (1621) companies, while the French established
a number of such companies to trade with the Caribbean, West Africa, the
Levant, and the Indian Ocean. Many other states including Denmark, Swe-
den, Austria, and several German lands also created chartered companies.
Several of these companies, most notably the Dutch East India, the English
East India, and Hudson’s Bay became virtual states within states ruling vast
territories with minimal government supervision (or expense!), earning enor-
mous profits for investors. These state-sponsored companies extended the
European presence to new areas, tied the global economy together, and vastly
expanded world trade.
The British state also regulated the import and export of food. From 1689
to 1846, the notorious English Corn Laws forbade the export of grain unless
prices were extremely cheap, thanks to a bumper crop. The intent was to en-
courage domestic grain production by guaranteeing that a relative scarcity
would keep prices high. Until 1772, additional legislation mandated state
oversight of internal trade in grain, meal, flour, bread, and meat. Although
the government sometimes enforced lower prices in times of dearth, in gen-
eral, these regulations kept food prices above the norm for northwestern
Europe and limited food consumption for the average Briton. Mercantilism,
especially in Britain, benefited economic and political elites at the expense of
the standard of living of the vast majority of the population.
The fundamental dependence of 18th-century economic growth on mer-
cantilism by the European powers especially Great Britain in the 17th and
18th centuries has been obscured by the gigantic shadow cast by the im-
mensely influential work of Adam Smith. For far too many economists, eco-
nomic historians, and politicians, Smith’s well-known attack on mercantilism
and state action more generally in favor of a more individualistic focus on
industry and free trade has assumed the status of dogma. That Smith was
criticizing rather than describing contemporary practice appears to have been
either forgotten or deliberately overlooked. No matter how Smith has been
read by his successors, it must not be forgotten that the economic precondi-
tions for industrialization were fostered in a thoroughly exploitative, mercan-
tilist economic system.
70 Owen, Robert
Further Reading
Hont, Istvan. Jealousy of Trade: International Competition and the Nation-State in His-
torical Perspective. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, 2005.
Horn, Jeff. Economic Development in Early Modern France: The Privilege of Liberty,
1650–1820. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2015.
LaHaye, Laura. “Mercantilism.” Available online at http://www.econlib.org/library
/Enc/Mercantilism.html.
“Mercantilism.” Available online at http://www.landofthebrave.info/mercantilism
.htm.
Stern, Philip J., and Carl Wennerlind, eds. Mercantilism Reimagined: Political Econ-
omy in Early Modern Britain and Its Empire. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
2013.
Further Reading
Claeys, Gregory. Machinery, Money and the Millennium: From Moral Economy to So-
cialism 1815–1860. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1987.
Donnachie, Ian. “Education in Robert Owen’s New Society: The New Lanark Insti-
tute and Schools.” Available online at http://infed.org/mobi/education-in-robert
-owens-new-society-the-new-lanark-institute-and-schools/.
“Robert Owen.” Available online at http://www.newlanark.org/world-heritage-site
/robertowen.shtml.
“Robert Owen (1771–1858).” Available online at http://robert-owen-museum.org
.uk/Robert_Owen_1771_1858.
Royle, Edward. Robert Owen and the Commencement of the Millennium. Manchester:
Manchester University Press, 1998.
72 Patent(s)
Further Reading
Griffin, Emma. A Short History of the British Industrial Revolution. Houndsmills, UK:
Palgrave, 2010.
Henderson, David R. “Patents.” Available online at http://www.econlib.org/library
/Enc1/Patents.html.
Khan, B. Zorina. “An Economic History of Patent Institutions.” Available online at
https://eh.net/encyclopedia/an-economic-history-of-patent-institutions/.
MacLeod, Christine. Inventing the Industrial Revolution: The English Patent System,
1660–1800. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002.
Pursell, Carroll W., ed. Technology in America: A History of Individuals and Ideas, 2nd
ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2010.
See also: Coal; Factory Acts; Factory System; Iron and Steel; Lancashire;
Owen, Robert; Productivity; Railroads; Role of the State; Second Industrial
Revolution; Socialism; Standard of Living; Document: “The State of the
Poor”; Document: “Conditions in the Mines”; Document: “Living and Work-
ing in Manchester”
Further Reading
“Effects of the Industrial Revolution.” Available online at http://webs.bcp.org/sites
/vcleary/ModernWorldHistoryTextbook/IndustrialRevolution/IREffects
.html#publichealth.
“The Environmental Impact of the Industrial Revolution.” Available online at
https://taapworld.wikispaces.com/The+Environmental+Impact+of+the+Indust
rial+Revolution.
Mathias, Peter. The First Industrial Nation: An Economic History of Britain, 1700–
1914, 3rd ed. London: Routledge, 2001.
McLamb, Eric. “The Ecological Impact of the Industrial Revolution.” Available
online at http://www.ecology.com/2011/09/18/ecological-impact-industrial
-revolution/.
Porter, Roy. The Greatest Benefit to Mankind: A Medical History of Humanity from
Antiquity to the Present. New York: W. W. Norton, 1999.
Further Reading
Field, Alexander J. “Productivity.” Available online at http://www.econlib.org
/library/Enc/Productivity.html.
Griffin, Emma. A Short History of the British Industrial Revolution. Houndsmills, UK,
Palgrave, 2010.
O’Brien, Patrick, and Roland Quinault, eds. The Industrial Revolution and British
Society. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993.
Shackleton, Robert. “Total Factor Productivity Growth in Historical Perspective.”
Available online at https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/113th-congress-2013
-2014/workingpaper/44002_TFP_Growth_03–18–2013_1.pdf.
Wrigley, E. A. Energy and the English Industrial Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2010.
78 Railroads
and social effects. By lowering the cost of transporting heavy goods, railroads
provided remote areas with cheap access to distant markets. Before the rail-
road, the paper industry of western Massachusetts paid 8–24 cents per ton-
mile to get their goods to market. By 1865, their freight charges had dropped
to 4.5 cents per ton-mile.
Railroads also required strong government support. Completed in 1833,
the Camden and Amboy railroad linked New York and Philadelphia to be-
come the first working line in North America. Given a monopoly by the state
of New Jersey, this railroad company became one of the largest corporations
in the United States. The cost of building the United States’ lines was signifi-
cantly cheaper than in England or in Europe. By 1865, thanks to the support
of various states and the federal government as well as the initiative of private
citizens, the United States had 35,000 miles of railroad track, 3.5 times that
of the United Kingdom. Yet the 10,000 miles of British track constituted a
dense web; this was not the case in the United States. For Americans, because
of the regional concentration of industry and the reliance on water power, the
railroad was often the first tangible sign of the Industrial Revolution. Rail-
roads, together with steamboats, perpetuated the factory system and brought
the necessities of industrialization to new areas, thereby playing a major role
in creating a truly global economy.
Further Reading
Jensen, Richard. “Railroad History.” Available online at http://www.americanhistory
projects.com/downloads/railroad.htm.
Miner, Craig H. A Most Magnificent Machine: America Adopts the Railroad, 1825–
1862. Lawrence: University of Kansas Press, 2010.
O’Brien, Patrick. The New Economic History of the Railways. London: Routledge,
2014.
“Railroad History, An Overview of the Past.” Available online at http://www.american
-rails.com/railroad-history.html.
Savage, Christopher, and T. C. Barker. Economic History of Transport in Britain. Lon-
don: Routledge, 2012.
borrowing huge sums through the London capital market. The Bank of Eng-
land was created in 1694 to help the government manage and consolidate its
debt and to lower the rate of interest paid by the state. After the defeat of
Napoleon, interest payments on government debt amounted to 56 percent
of the state’s income. A further 31 percent was spent on defense. There can
be no doubt that, like its chief European competitors, Great Britain was a
military regime. The state’s development of efficient and effective means of
borrowing money and limiting interest charges helped Britain win wars, slow
the economic gains of its rivals, gain colonies, and allow investments in in-
dustrialization and transportation to be made.
The British state was also increasingly willing to deploy first law and then
force to support the interests of entrepreneurs. Local justices of the peace
controlled wages and prices: they generally rejected salary demands not linked
to rising prices. The enclosure of fields was mandated by Act of Parliament,
and resistance to the division of common land was overcome by force. The
same process accompanied the creation of the turnpike trusts when they in-
fringed on or replaced local interests. Labor was also controlled more thor-
oughly than in the past. The system of lengthy apprenticeships was maintained
and strengthened and the traditional rights of skilled workers to resist the
demands of their employers were steadily eroded until they were finally elimi-
nated in 1809–1814. Combinations of workers were outlawed while combi-
nations of entrepreneurs were encouraged. Strikes by miners and industrial
workers were broken up by force whenever property was threatened. The
English legal system also enforced social control in dealing with vagrancy and
unemployment. Since many jobs were seasonal, a very high proportion of
workers were unemployed at some point in an annual cycle. Those who did
not have a current means of support could be sent back to the parish of their
birth where they were put into a workhouse, imprisoned in a house of correc-
tion, or even transported to Georgia or later Australia. This Poor Law, like
most of the actions of the British state in the 18th century, maintained or
even increased the servility and dependence of the lower socioeconomic ranks
of English society. This dependence probably made labor more productive,
thereby contributing to economic growth, but it did little to achieve social
peace.
Government resources were also used to improve transportation. Britain
invested directly to develop ships, docks, harbors, and weapons. Turnpikes and
canals were created or upgraded thanks to government-granted monopolies.
The state also spent heavily to attract skilled workers and inventors from abroad
with monetary incentives and tax breaks. For technologies or craft practices
that could not be so acquired, the state resorted to commissioning and/or
rewarding industrial spies. From the 17th century, a patent law protected the
82 Role of The State
Further Reading
Harris, Ron. “Government and the Economy, 1688–1850.” In The Cambridge
Economic History of Modern Britain, vol. 1, Industrialisation, 1700–1860, ed.
Roderick Floud and Paul Johnson. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2004.
“The Industrial Revolution-Role of the State.” Available online at http://www
.intriguing-history.com/industrial-revolution-role-of-state/.
Magnusson, Lars. Nation, State and the Industrial Revolution. New York: Routledge,
2009.
Mathias, Peter. The First Industrial Nation: An Economic History of Britain, 1700–
1914, 3rd ed. London: Routledge, 2001.
Royal Society of Arts 83
Further Reading
Baird, Ileana, ed. Social Networks in the Long Eighteenth Century: Clubs, Literary
Salons, Textual Coteries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2014.
“History.” Available online at https://www.thersa.org/about-us/archive-and-history/.
Jacob, Margaret C. Scientific Culture and the Making of the Industrial West. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1997.
Mokyr, Joel. The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Prince-
ton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2004.
Further Reading
Basalla, George. The Evolution of Technology. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1988.
86 Slater, Samuel
Hounshell, David A. From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932: The
Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1984.
Mokyr, Joel. “The Second Industrial Revolution.” Available online at http://faculty
.wcas.northwestern.edu/~jmokyr/castronovo.pdf.
Pollard, Sidney. Peaceful Conquest: The Industrialization of Europe 1760–1970.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1982.
“Second Industrial Revolution.” Available online at http://ushistoryscene.com/article
/second-industrial-revolution/.
formed another firm that built a separate mill in Pawtucket. Both mills made
yarn that was sold to independent weavers. These enterprises were kept going
by the embargo on British goods imposed in 1807. The ban enabled Ameri-
cans to replace temporarily the British in many domestic markets. Later,
Slater founded a number of other mills for both cotton and wool scattered
around New England, including one at the modestly named Slatersville (now
part of North Smithfield), Rhode Island. These water-powered mills con-
tained both spinning and weaving operations within the same factory build-
ing and became quite widespread after 1815.
Slater elaborated a deeply paternalistic approach to finding and disciplin-
ing labor. He recruited young, unmarried women and recent immigrants. At
Slatersville, families lived and worked in the community surrounding the
mill. Tenement houses, a store, and even a Sunday school (the first one in a
factory in the United States) were provided for the workforce by the com-
pany. In the aftermath of the 1829 downturn, however, Slater lost control
of several of his mills. To restore his business prospects, Slater increasingly
focused on finding (often short-term) competitive advantages and then maxi-
mizing profit before moving on. To achieve greater efficiency on the model of
Robert Owen, Slater and his sons loosened their paternalist control over the
labor force.
Slater took advantage of government incentives and tariff protection, the
financial resources of Quaker merchants, and the machine-making skills of
Yankee artisans along with the strong work habits of their laborers to become
one of the most successful men in New England. When the business environ-
ment became rockier, his managerial practice evolved to become more effi-
cient. Slater, like his models Arkwright and Strutt, was not a technical
innovator; rather, he was an economic opportunist whose most important
expertise was in management where he became the prototype for a new, more
capitalistic businessman.
Further Reading
Hindle, Brooke, and Steven Lubar. Engines of Change: The American Industrial Revo-
lution 1790–1860. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Press, 1986.
Prude, Jonathan. The Coming of Industrial Order: Town and Factory Life in Rural Mas-
sachusetts, 1810–1860. Amherst: University of Massachusetts Press, 1983.
“Samuel Slater: American Factory System.” Available online at http://www.pbs.org
/wgbh/theymadeamerica/whomade/slater_hi.html.
88 Socialism
economic relations differentiated the various forms of societies and that history
demonstrated an enduring cyclical pattern of construction and deconstruc-
tion. Fourier was born into the French middle class: he rejected industrializa-
tion as harmful both to individuals and to communities. He preferred
agricultural societies in which most goods were made in the home for domestic
use because they were more likely to enable humans to master their passions
and attain what he referred to as a natural state of harmony. Owen had several
advantages over his French colleagues. He was a self-made man who amassed a
considerable fortune as a textile entrepreneur, most notably at New Lanark,
Scotland, where he treated workers with respect. Owen put a number of his
ideas into practice before nearly driving himself into bankruptcy with the es-
tablishment of what was intended to be a self-sustaining, cooperative commu-
nity at New Harmony, Indiana. In the aftermath of this community’s failure in
1827, Owen devoted the rest of his life to spreading socialist ideas and lobby-
ing for government-sponsored reforms on behalf of the working classes.
Few factory workers endorsed the ideas of these early socialists. Artisans
whose livelihoods were under assault by mechanization were, by far, the most
likely supporters of socialist ideas until the 1870s. Perhaps factory workers
found the ideas too optimistic, too abstract, expressed in ways that their lim-
ited educations made difficult to grasp, or the plans were too far removed
from their own realities, but for whatever reason(s), early socialism attracted
few workers. This remained the case even after Marx and his collaborator,
Prussian-born English industrialist Friedrich Engels (1820–1895) introduced
an explicitly political element into the movement with The Communist Mani-
festo (1848), calling for an immediate social revolution that would turn soci-
ety upside down. Despite this clarion call, throughout the 19th century, many
and probably most socialists limited themselves to advocating for industrial
reform to curb the excesses of the capitalist system. Only after European gov-
ernments inaugurated their own reforms at the height of British dominance,
limited as they were, did significant numbers of factory workers espouse
socialism.
Socialism emerged as a bogeyman for elites and the middle classes who
sought ways to prevent calls for change in defense of the status quo. Although
Owen and Fourier explicitly disavowed political action on behalf of their
ideas, and the Saint-Simonians did not go beyond lobbying, the fundamental
challenge of socialism—its focus on equality, collective ownership, and
cooperation—threatened the position of economic elites dependent on the
exploitation of workers and their inherited positions in society that provided
them ownership of the means of production. By thoroughly scapegoating
socialist ideas and practices, elites and their agents sought to avoid change
and protect their positions. In the aftermath of the revolutions of 1848,
90 Standard of Living
workers increasingly recognized that the middle classes would not act consist-
ently in their interest, which eventually led many to adopt more radical, even
revolutionary, means of achieving change. However, the adoption of Marxist
ideas on the need for a revolution to remake society belongs to the era of the
Second Industrial Revolution, not the first. The emergence of socialism in the
early 19th century was a harbinger that the working classes would not accept
the growing inequality of industrial society forever.
Further Reading
“History of Socialism.” Available online at http://www.philosophybasics.com/branch
_socialism.html.
Laidler, Harry W. History of Socialism: An Historical Comparative Study of Socialism.
New York: Routledge, 1969.
Lindemann, Albert S. A History of European Socialism. New Haven, CT: Yale Univer-
sity Press, 1984.
“Marxists Internet Archive.” Available online at https://www.marxists.org/.
“Responses to the Industrial Revolution.” Available online at http://webs.bcp.org
/sites/vcleary/ModernWorldHistoryTextbook/IndustrialRevolution/responsesto
IR.html.
was particularly impressive given the heavy emigration from Britain to the
colonies and to the United States as well as the long years of war that punctu-
ated this era. Declining mortality played an important role, especially for
infants and young children, but increasing fertility was a greater factor in the
impressive increase in British population. People had more children for
several reasons. The mean age of marriage fell from 28 for males and 26 for
females in the decade 1680–1689 to 25 for men and 23 for women in 1830–
1837. Women increasingly expected to marry. Married women were also
slightly more likely to have children and to minimize the spacing between
births. These shifts in nuptiality were an essential component of the increased
fertility of the period. Greater willingness to have children and the likelihood
of those children surviving are a vital measure of the positive evolution of the
standard of living during the age of the Industrial Revolution.
Not only was the population growing, but people also moved to urban
areas. The proportion of urban dwellers more than doubled from 21 percent
in 1750 to 45 percent a century later. Cities offered jobs, access to educa-
tional opportunities, and entertainment among many other familiar benefits,
but at the same time they were centers of disease, lawlessness, and poverty
where life expectancy was quite low and falling during most of the first Indus-
trial Revolution. Only after 1850 did governments begin to deal with these
difficult problems with manifest advantages for the standard of living of the
British people.
In short, the British Industrial Revolution relied on exploiting the working
classes, lowering real wages, forcing men to work far longer hours, and requir-
ing women and children to work outside the home to support the family.
Although fertility improved, child mortality declined, and consumption in-
creased, the falling height of army recruits and sinking overall mortality sug-
gests that the effects of industrialization had a generally negative effect on the
British people’s, much less the working classes’, standard of living. Only once
Britain had enjoyed at least two generations as the “workshop of the world”
and defeated rival France in the Revolutionary and Napoleonic wars did the
benefits of the Industrial Revolution “trickle down” to the population at large.
It is the period after the first Industrial Revolution when most of the gains in
the standard of living stemming from the Industrial Revolution were enjoyed,
by the great-grandchildren (or even great-great grandchildren) of those work-
ers who toiled in the first factories that touched off this revolutionary
transformation.
Further Reading
Daunton, Martin J. Progress and Poverty: An Economic and Social History of Britain
1700–1850. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995.
Griffin, Emma. A Short History of the British Industrial Revolution. Houndsmills, UK:
Palgrave, 2010.
King, Steven, and Geoffrey Timmins. Making Sense of the Industrial Revolution: Eng-
lish Economy and Society, 1700–1850. Manchester: Manchester University Press,
2001.
Nye, John V. C. “Standards of Living and Modern Economic Growth.” Available
online at http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/StandardsofLivingandModern
EconomicGrowth.html.
Steckel, Richard H. “A History of the Standard of Living in the United States.” Avail-
able online at https://eh.net/encyclopedia/a-history-of-the-standard-of-living-in
-the-united-states/.
In addition to its traditional spheres of agriculture and mining and its vital
places in textile mills and iron foundries, steam power was applied to run a
host of other machines. Matthew Boulton set up six presses to make coins for
Britain’s Mint. Brewers and canal masters used steam engines primarily as
pumps. Others were interested in transportation. William Murdock, a Boul-
ton and Watt employee, devised a steam-driven wheeled carriage. In 1801,
Henry Bell began to experiment with a steamboat [based on successful French
experiments undertaken in 1783], and a decade later, he established steamer
service on Scotland’s Clyde River. Steamships required ever-improving pres-
sure to supply the motive power. These lessons were applied later to the steam
locomotive, which was the key to building a network of railroads and com-
menced a revolution in land transport.
The constant improvement to the steam engine that took place in the 18th
and 19th centuries relied on the experience of artisans and iron makers with
using coal as fuel and their willingness to experiment with new machines.
The result of this technological creativity was the coal-driven steam engine,
which ultimately placed almost unlimited and reliable power at humanity’s
disposal, replacing the dependence on human or animal power. The steam
engine was the characteristic machine of the Industrial Revolution.
Further Reading
“A Brief History of Steam Power.” Available online at http://johno.myiglou.com
/SteamHistory.htm.
Hunter, Louis C. A History of Industrial Power in the United States, 1730–1930,
vol. 2, Steam Power. Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press, 1985.
“Industrial History: The History of the Steam Engine.” Available online at http://
www.thomasnet.com/articles/custom-manufacturing-fabricating/steam-engine
-history.
Jacob, Margaret C. Scientific Culture and the Making of the Industrial West. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1997.
Musson, A. E., and Eric Robinson. Science and Technology in the Industrial Revolution.
Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1969.
made and sold within a country’s borders. They are usually assessed either at
the point of production or at the point of sale. Taken together, tariffs and
excise taxes were major sources of revenue for all European states. As part of
the approach to economic policymaking usually referred to as mercantilism,
governments used these fiscal instruments to favor some industries and pro-
tect certain producers. The prevalence of these levies demonstrates the limita-
tions in practice of the economic principles articulated by Adam Smith that
free trade accelerated industrial growth and economic realities. Tax policy was
one of the most important ways that the state influenced economy and soci-
ety during the age of the Industrial Revolution.
In the 17th century, high tariffs encouraged European states to develop
their colonial empires and trading relations outside Europe to guarantee ac-
cess to raw materials, luxury goods, and markets. Tariffs also enabled manu-
facturers to make goods to substitute for imports like Indian calico cotton
cloth. European equivalents did not have to be internationally competitive;
they just had to be able to compete behind the government’s tariff walls. In
some places like Great Britain, imported grain was also highly taxed to pro-
tect the incomes of landowners who benefited from higher food prices. These
Corn Laws were first instituted in 1670 and amended frequently in the 18th
century, then reinstated fully in 1815, and remained in force until 1846. At
the same time, mercantilist governments realized that excise taxes stifled ini-
tiative and encouraged smuggling. They therefore moved to reduce or elimi-
nate these duties whenever possible. During the 18th century, state officials
lowered both tariff and excise rates to encourage trade and industry. The chief
exception was Britain where the excise emerged as the government’s chief
means of paying off its enormous wartime debts.
The ebb and flow of customs and excise rates can best be explained through
the lens of political economy. Governments maintained, increased, or re-
duced rates for fundamentally political reasons rather than strictly economic
motives. For most of the 18th century, the British excise on goods like beer,
malt, hops, soap, salt, candles, and leather brought in at least 40 percent of
the state’s total revenue and, in some years, as much as 55 percent. Although
tariff rates were generally on the wane, improved collection and the broadly
based expansion of trade volumes meant that receipts doubled over the course
of the century to about one-third of revenue. British tariff rates on most
goods were exceptionally low before the series of wars with France forced the
government to raise vast sums to support its military adventures. In 1689,
tariff rates were 5 percent on most goods, rising to 15 percent in 1704 and
25 percent in 1759. Further increases stalled in 1786–1792 before continu-
ing their ascent. By 1820, tariff rates reached 60 percent before falling gradu-
ally to about 20 percent in 1850. Given the dependence of the British
Tariffs and Excise Taxes 97
the United States to shelter infant industries and encourage import substitu-
tion. After 1815, the German lands of Prussia, Bavaria, Württemberg, and
Hesse-Darmstadt suffered from the breakup of the French low-tax trading
zone developed by Emperor Napoleon I. They recognized that lowered barri-
ers could encourage commerce and industry. From a hesitant beginning
in 1818, Prussia sponsored a customs union, the Zollverein, that by 1834
encompassed German-speaking Europe (other than Austria). The Zollverein’s
moderate tariff rates, about half of the United Kingdom’s, recognized that
retaliation for high rates was a major threat for economies dependent on both
exports and imports that were not in the dominant financial and military
position enjoyed by the British in the first half of the 19th century.
It is highly significant that concrete movement toward genuine free trade
on the part of the first industrial nation occurred only at the very end of the
era. The abolition of the Corn Laws in 1846 and a general lowering of tariff
rates led eventually to a free trade treaty between the United Kingdom and
France in 1860, which encouraged the elimination of trade barriers around
the world. The effects of free trade on industrialization, however, are part of
the story of the Second Industrial Revolution, not the first, which was strongly
affected by the persistence of excise taxes and high tariffs resulting from the
political economy of the various states undergoing industrialization.
Further Reading
Asakura, Hironori. World History of the Customs and Tariffs. Brussels: World Customs
Association, 2003.
Ashworth, William. Customs and Excise: Trade, Production, and Consumption in Eng-
land, 1640–1845. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2003.
Brewer, John. The Sinews of Power: War, Money and the English State, 1688–1783.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1989.
Nye, John V. “The Myth of Free-Trade Britain.” Available online at http://www
.econlib.org/library/Columns/y2003/Nyefreetrade.html.
“The Second American Party System and the Tariff.” Available online at http://www
.taxhistory.org/www/website.nsf/Web/THM1816?OpenDocument.
roads, building turnpikes and bridges, as well as other means of speeding and
easing transport by land, water transportation remained far easier and less ex-
pensive. Thus, access to navigable rivers or the seacoast was a major geographi-
cal advantage to trade and industry. The development of steamboats as well as
a network of canals along with improvements to ports and docks lowered costs
further and gave new areas access to the global economy. Improved water
transport enabled and supported the Industrial Revolution.
At the dawn of the 18th century, British road transport costs averaged
about 1 shilling per ton-mile, while shipping via inland waterways cost about
2.5 pence per ton-mile and coastal shipping even less. This difference of at
least 480 percent in shipping costs demonstrates the extreme expense of
transporting heavy or bulky goods by land and the benefits of extending and
improving transportation by water.
The island nature of the British state was a tremendous material resource.
It was also a key to building an effective transportation network. Even with-
out man-made improvements, nowhere in Britain is more than 70 miles from
the sea, and very few places are more than 30 miles from navigable water. The
Severn and the Trent river systems provide water carriage to the industrial
Midlands, and the Thames and the Wash Rivers allow easy transport to major
agricultural regions. In the 17th, 18th, and 19th centuries, the British state
seconded by numerous entrepreneurs expended considerable capital on im-
proving waterways, building canals, and ensuring access to the rivers and
streams as sources of industrial power. These efforts were not unique; in fact,
Britain was following in the wake of various continental countries in water
transport. But because of the compactness of the island, the reach of the navi-
gable rivers, and the plentiful ports, the improvements made to the British
water system were more effective in creating a national transportation net-
work and thus a national market than was possible on continental Europe.
The differential in shipping costs encouraged greater investment and
innovation in canal building. Cheap coal was so critical to the British econ-
omy that canals were constructed solely to transport it to market. Beginning
around 1750, canals were constructed along the Severn, Trent, and Mersey
Rivers and their tributaries. Later canals linked the river systems or facilitated
access to inland areas like southern Wales that had vital resources but no
outlet to the sea. With a few notable exceptions like the canal constructed
by the Duke of Bridgewater to link his estates to Manchester and Liverpool,
the construction of most canals was financed through joint-stock companies
to mobilize the enormous sums needed. By 1830, England and Wales
had 3,876 miles of inland canals, up from 1,399 in 1760. From 1780 to
1830, Britain’s canals contributed a 0.8 percent annual increase in transport
productivity.
100 Transportation by Water
In the United States, canals tied the interior of the continent to the Atlan-
tic Ocean and thus to the global economy. The most notable of the large
number of canals built during this era was the Erie Canal financed by the
state of New York. Stretching 363 miles, the canal was completed in 1825. By
joining the Hudson River and Lake Erie, the so-called Eighth Wonder of the
World crossed the Appalachian Mountains to link the port of New York with
markets hundreds of miles in the interior and vice versa. Because of the ex-
pense of building and maintaining canals, the vast distances to be traversed,
the limited tax revenues of local and state governments in the United States,
and the emergence of the railroad as a transportation rival, less than 3,400
miles of canals were built during the Industrial Revolution. Canals linked
several key hubs like the Great Lakes and the river systems of the Midwest,
but the exorbitant cost of building—an average of $37,580 per mile—
ensured the dominance of the railroad after 1830.
Harbors and rivers were dredged and deepened to permit additional or
further access. Even before the use of steam revolutionized ocean transport,
sailing ships were modified through different rigging and hull design to in-
crease carrying capacity while lessening the number of men needed to sail
the vessel. On ships entering London from Spain and Portugal, the tonnage
grew rapidly: the number of tons per man swelled from 7.9 in 1686 to 9.1 in
1726 and 12.6 in 1766. Shipping contributed a 1.4 percent annual increase
in transport productivity between 1780 and 1860. Gradual improvements
took England’s transportation network to a level beyond their European com-
petitors and set the stage for further advances once steam power was added to
the mix.
Steamboats were a major innovation in water transportation because they
could travel more easily upstream on rivers and were not dependent on the
weather or the tide. The possibility of using a steam engine to turn a wheel
outfitted with paddles to propel a boat or ship was tried in a number of places
in the 1780s concurrent with James Watt’s improvements to the machine.
Marquis Claude de Jouffroy first achieved the feat in 1783 on the Saône River
in France, building on an abortive attempt in 1776 by his mentor. Four years
later, American John Fitch made a more successful trial in the Delaware River
in a small boat using a rack of oars instead of a paddle wheel. In 1790, Fitch
and a partner Henry Voigt began service across the Delaware in an improved
craft. Although the business soon failed, Fitch got both U.S. and French pat-
ents for steamboats in 1791.
Robert Fulton is often credited with developing the steamboat, which is
clearly incorrect. Rather Fulton’s accomplishment was to make the steamboat
a commercial success. He received a monopoly from the state of New
York thanks to the support of powerful investor, banker, and diplomat Robert
Transportation by Water 101
See also: Bridgewater, Duke of; Brunel, Isambard Kingdom; Coal; Credit;
Fitch, John; Iron and Steel; Mercantilism; Productivity; Railroads; Role of
the State; Steam Engine; Document: “The State of the Poor”
Further Reading
Daunton, Martin J. Progress and Poverty: An Economic and Social History of Britain
1700–1850. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995.
Rodrigue, Jean-Paul. “The Industrial Revolution and Transportation (1800–1870).”
Available online at https://people.hofstra.edu/geotrans/eng/ch2en/conc2en
/ch2c1en.html.
Szostak, Rick. The Role of Transportation in the Industrial Revolution: A Comparison of
England and France. Montreal: McGill University Press, 1991.
Ville, Simon. “Transport.” In The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain,
vol. 1, 1700–1860, ed. Roderick Floud and Paul Johnson. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press, 2004.
“Waterways of England and Wales: Their History in Maps.” Available online at
http://www.canalmuseum.org.uk/history/maps.htm.
Lowell was productive until the Civil War and beyond. It set the stage for
what became known as the American System of Manufactures at the dawn of
the Second Industrial Revolution.
Lowell began the process of creating the Waltham system with a bit of
industrial espionage. During a two-year trip to England, he, like Samuel
Slater before him, attempted to memorize the design of an important textile
machine in the factories he visited, in this case, the power-loom. When he
returned to the United States, he and mechanic Paul Moody reconstructed
the machines, adapting them to the materials available. With a new textile
machine ready to put to use, Lowell and a group of partners founded the
Boston Manufacturing Company in 1813 to supply the demand that had
accumulated because of the British blockade during the War of 1812. As with
many European enterprises, they raised capital by selling shares mostly to
their friends, relations, and business acquaintances; the firm was ultimately
capitalized at an impressive $600,000. The model of a joint-stock or share-
holder corporation rapidly became widespread in American business.
Along the Charles River in Waltham, Massachusetts, Lowell constructed a
brand-new brick building. Water power was used to mechanize the conver-
sion of raw cotton into cloth. Although frequently given credit in the United
States for being the first to integrate the entire production process in a single
structure, the British, French, Belgians, and Prussians had established such
mills a generation before. As an integrated factory, Waltham was significant,
however, because it abandoned New England’s long-standing reliance on do-
mestic manufacture. Its corporate structure and management practices be-
came the model for other American factories, especially when the coarse
cotton cloth it produced sold well.
Nearly the mill’s entire labor force of 300 was composed of girls fresh from
the farm. The girls, some as young as 15, received much lower wages than
men, but they could live in company boardinghouses that were clean and
respectable—they even had official chaperones. For these girls, the factory
was an escape from the farm and a means of engaging in religious and educa-
tional activities, all while earning cash wages. The boardinghouses enabled
these girls to abandon part-time agricultural work: they were now industrial
workers. Enough Waltham-type mills were constructed that finding sufficient
girls to staff the factories became difficult. The original Waltham mill, how-
ever, had no problem attracting and keeping a loyal workforce.
Although Lowell himself died young, the system he created yielded ex-
tremely high profits. When the Boston Manufacturing Company expanded
and created its own mill town in 1822 along the Merrimack River, the direc-
tors named it after him. The company chose a site with a 30-foot waterfall
that could accommodate the largest waterwheels in North America; they were
104 Watt, James
capable of running in any season and in any weather. Ultimately, the indus-
trial city of Lowell housed 20 mills and 6,000 workers (5,100 of whom were
women aged 15–29). By the end of the 1820s, 10 of the largest corporations
in the United States made use of the hydraulic system established in Lowell.
In 1850, Lowell produced 20 percent of all U.S.-made cotton cloth.
When not at work (13 hours a day), the young women of Lowell, like their
Waltham progenitors, lived in dormitories, separated from their families,
where they were subject to disciplinary “moral instruction,” including the
requirement to “attend public worship . . . and to conform strictly to the rules
of the Sabbath.” They were also to keep clean, while avoiding both “ardent
spirits” and “frivolous and useless conversation.” This heavy-handed manage-
rial paternalism was a way of combating social opposition to women working
outside the home and of attracting laborers, but the positive aspects and rela-
tively high pay lasted only as long as the good times. When a sharp downturn
hit in the mid-1830s, Lowell’s vaunted mills also experienced labor problems
when management tried to cut wages by a quarter. Despite the ambivalent
elements of managerial practice of Lowell and the mills in Lowell, the
Waltham system’s innovations in management and factory organization be-
came the seed of what became known as the American system of production
and the foundation of U.S. industrial competiveness.
Further Reading
Dublin, Thomas. “Women and the Early Industrial Revolution in the United States.”
Available online at https://www.gilderlehrman.org/history-by-era/jackson-lincoln
/essays/women-and-early-industrial-revolution-united-states.
Malone, Patrick M. Waterpower in Lowell: Engineering and Industry in Nineteenth-
Century America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2009.
Temin, Peter, ed. Engines of Enterprise: An Economic History of New England. Cam-
bridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2002.
“The Waltham-Lowell System.” Available online at http://www.nps.gov/lowe/learn
/photosmultimedia/waltham_lowell.htm.
of their engines both at home and abroad, while also ensuring their value to
the state that enforced their patent rights.
In 1800, Boulton and Watt’s patent rights expired and Watt retired from
business, ostensibly to devote himself solely to science. At this point, Britain
had more than 500 operational Boulton and Watt engines. Several dozen
more had been sold on the continent and a significant number of copies of
their design had been made in places where English patent rights could not
be enforced. As a sign of his importance to the study of efficiency and power,
an electrical unit of measurement, the watt, was named after him, which also
recognized that it had been Watt who coined the term “horsepower” to de-
scribe the energy output of an engine.
Watt’s designs and willingness to oversee the quality of the machines he
and Boulton built made his reputation as a scientist and inventor, which
helped him become known to subsequent generations as the inventor of the
steam engine, even though such engines had been in existence for generations
before Watt took out his first patent. Watt did, however, vastly increase the
efficiency of the steam engine, paving the way for further improvements and
facilitating the mechanization so fundamental to the Industrial Revolution.
See also: Coal; Credit; Division of Labor; Iron and Steel; Patent(s); Produc-
tivity; Role of the State; Royal Society of Arts; Transportation by Water;
Workforce
Further Reading
“James Watt.” Available online at http://www.famousscientists.org/james-watt/.
Lira, Cara. “Biography of James Watt.” Available online at http://www.egr.msu.edu
/~lira/supp/steam/wattbio.html.
Musson, A. E., and Eric Robinson. Science and Technology in the Industrial Revolution.
Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1969.
Tann, Jennifer, ed. The Selected Papers of Boulton and Watt. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 1981.
Tann, Jennifer, and M. J. Breckin. “The International Diffusion of the Watt Engine,
1775–1825.” Economic History Review 31 (1978): 541–64.
Further Reading
Dolan, Brian. Wedgwood: The First Tycoon. New York: Viking, 2004.
“Josiah Wedgwood.” Available online at http://www.thepotteries.org/potters/wedg
wood.htm.
“Josiah Wedgwood (1730–1795): The Industrialist.” Available online at http://aboli
tion.e2bn.org/people_33.html.
“Lives of the Wedgwoods: Josiah Wedgwood I.” Available online at http://www
.wedgwoodmuseum.org.uk/learning/discovery_packs/pack/lives-of-the-wedg
woods/chapter/josiah-wedgwood-i-1730–95.
McKendrick, Neil, John Brewer, and J. H. Plumb. The Birth of a Consumer Society:
The Commercialization of Eighteenth-Century England. Bloomington: Indiana
University Press, 1982.
19th century, other gunsmiths achieved Whitney’s goal and the principle of
uniformity with interchangeability as a target was implemented in the manu-
facture of clocks, locks, furniture, and hardware. This advance helped to
transform the economy of the Northeast as much as the cotton gin changed
the South.
Further Reading
“Eli Whitney: The Inventor.” Available online at http://www.eliwhitney.org/7
/museum/about-eli-whitney/inventor.
Hounshell, David A. From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932: The
Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1984.
Phillips, William H. “Cotton Gin.” Available online at https://eh.net/encyclopedia
/cotton-gin/.
Thomson, Ross. Structures of Change in the Mechanical Age: Technological Innovation
in the United States, 1790–1865. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press,
2009.
WORKFORCE The men, women, and children who “made” the Indus-
trial Revolution, particularly during the first decades of industrialization,
rarely had much choice in the matter. Factory and mine labor was backbreak-
ing, exhausting, unhealthy, and required a type of work discipline that did
not come easy to those accustomed to agricultural labor. Owners, managers,
and foremen deployed a variety of methods to “break” the workforce. Getting
people to work as long, as hard, when, and where they wished were the keys
to efficiency. Labor productivity—achieved in part through mechanization
and the substitution of water and steam for human and animal power, but
also by imposing discipline on the workforce—was the key to earning the
profits that drove entrepreneurs to initiate an industrial revolution. As their
standard of living demonstrated concretely, the workforce enjoyed few if any
benefits during the first several generations of industrialization.
A vital part of the process of industrialization was the substitution of
women and children for more expensive (and more truculent) male labor.
Women and children were always paid less to perform the same tasks. The use
of machines was generally reserved for a small cadre of skilled male laborers
because it was claimed that the devices required greater physical strength
to use—this assertion was only partly true—while the bulk of other tasks
Workforce 111
benefitted from the more dexterous fingers of women and children. In eco-
nomic terms, this exchange deskilled the labor force and permitted a thor-
oughgoing substitution of capital for labor.
Women and children were the bulk of the labor force in the cotton textile
sector during the first century of industrialization. A British survey under-
taken in 1818 found that adult women comprised a little over half the work-
ers in cotton textiles with children representing another third. In Scotland,
the reliance on women and girls was even greater. Female labor, overwhelm-
ingly women under 30, especially teenagers, made up over 60 percent of the
cotton workers in Glasgow and approached 70 percent in work sites situated
outside urban areas. The labor of women made the cotton textile industry
productive and profitable.
Children labored at least as much as women. In 1851, a British commis-
sion found that one-third of children over 10 and under the age of 15 worked
outside the home. This figure drastically underrepresented the number of
children in the work force because it did not count those employed in domes-
tic industry or agriculture. At least half and usually a far higher percentage of
nominally school-age children worked full time during the age of the Indus-
trial Revolution.
Nor was the labor of children voluntary. Parents could legally commit their
children to work. This was not just the standard use of juveniles to perform
domestic chores or to help their parents. Destitute English parents sent their
children up to the age of 21 out to work for the parish in exchange for finan-
cial support. A parent could also apprentice their child for seven years to a
master or entrepreneur. In neither case could the child leave or do anything
about their working conditions. From the age of four or five, children worked
the same 12–14 hour shifts as adults; they suffered disproportionately from
frequently unhealthy and dangerous working conditions.
The conditions for many children indentured to the parish who were in-
volved in industry and mining strongly resembled the indentured adult labor-
ers sent out to the colonies to labor for a fixed number of years in exchange
for their passage. Children could be dispatched more than 200 miles away
from their families, isolating them completely. Only in 1816 did Parliament
impose a 40-mile limit. Other attempts were made to improve the lives of
children, but the first measure to have any real effect was the Factory Act of
1833 (passed, not coincidently, the same year that Britain prohibited slavery).
This measure outlawed work for children under the age of 9 and limited it for
children aged 9–13 to 8 hours per day. Night work was forbidden. The meas-
ure also restricted children aged 14–18 to working a mere 12 hours a day.
Thus, until the closing decades of the Industrial Revolution, children could
be and were exploited in huge numbers.
112 Workforce
The deliberate and systematic substitution of the labor of women and chil-
dren represented a considerable savings. In the mid-19th century, in the capi-
tal of the British cotton industry—the city of Manchester—the highest paid
female factory worker made a quarter of what the highest paid male laborer
earned. The lowest paid male worker made 13–15 shillings a week while the
highest paid female workers earned 7–11 shillings. These wages were perhaps
20 percent higher than nonfactory wages; they had to be significantly higher
to convince skilled or free labor to accept the harsh discipline and unpleasant
working conditions of the factories.
Children earned far less. Apprentices and parish appointees worked mostly
for room, board, and a mostly hypothetical training in the techniques appro-
priate to the industry. At best, they made one-sixth to one-eighth the wages
of an adult worker and suffered not just “the slings and arrows of outrageous
fortune,” but from the straps, whips, and fists of their overseers.
Managers sought to make their workers as reliable as the machines they
tended. The reaction of workers to industrial discipline varied widely. A large
number of laborers accepted their new situations and made the best of it.
Workers tried to innovate or get ahead in some way and to use the system to
their advantage. Others went along grudgingly, often because they had no
other alternative, but they tolerated their situation. A significant proportion,
however, felt they were being taken advantage of and resisted the labor de-
mands of the Industrial Revolution, at least to some degree. For many British
workers, resistance took the form of emigration, often to the United States or
the empire. For others, the traditional labor tactics of coalition and combina-
tion, slowdown, and strike were used to oppose workplace innovation or to
preserve customary practices. In some trades, in some times, and in some
places, these tactics had considerable success, at least in the short term. Other
laborers turned to more “modern” forms of resistance and complaint such as
politics and/or unions.
Workers justifiably resented many aspects of the process of industrializa-
tion. Entrepreneurs and labor forces always have certain areas of conflict, but
the emergence of a hierarchical and centralized system of management re-
sponsible for the production, distribution, and sale of manufactured goods
was especially frustrating for the workforce. The increasing complexity of
the economic system, the growing division of labor, and the spread of the
tentacles of the new economy around the world all combined to alienate
the people who actually made the goods from economic decision making.
The working classes lost any true control over or even influence within the
production process.
Management’s habit of firing recalcitrant workers and the enormous num-
bers of jobs made redundant by mechanization also angered the laboring
Workforce 113
classes. The argument that the total number of industrial jobs was increasing
was accurate, but as the shifting sex and age breakdown of factory workers
demonstrates, those who got the new jobs were not the same people who were
being laid off. Technological and managerial obsolescence combined to
render whole segments of the working class without a means of earning a liv-
ing and enabled elites to lower wages with relative impunity.
The imposition of industrial discipline was also a major bone of conten-
tion between masters and men. The elimination of holidays, the increasing
length of the work day and work week, and following the dictates of the clock
were innovations that impinged on the free time, independence, and habits of
a huge proportion of the population. In some sectors, the institution of pay-
ment by output but with regularly increased quotas, rather than payment by
the hour, was also detested. Workers believed that this form of remuneration
destroyed their control over workplace rhythms and ignored the differences in
energy and outlook that stem from the passage of the seasons. Nor did work-
ers like the recourse to corporal punishment, especially against women and
children. The fact that employers also attempted to destroy or prevent any
attempt at labor organization to redress grievances also irked workers, who
believed rightly that their customary rights and traditional protections were
being trampled on.
In England, traditional safeguards against lowering wages too far had
existed for hundreds of years before the onset of industrialization. At the
bidding of manufacturers, Parliament steadily abrogated such protections
over the course of the 18th century. There was considerable discussion about
whether to institute a minimum wage to guarantee the well-being of the
workforce. But establishing a legal minimum wage or fixing some relation-
ship between wage levels and the price of food were both rejected out of hand
by the government as being too binding on manufacturers and potentially
injurious to the national economy: the struggle against Revolutionary and
then Napoleonic France was used to justify continued sacrifices by the work-
ing classes.
The workforce suffered dramatic declines in certain aspects of their stand-
ard of living during the Industrial Revolution that they attempted to make up
for in other ways. As British workers adapted to the time-clock, new produc-
tion methods, and the needs of the machine, entrepreneurs forged a greatly
enhanced productivity to achieve an industrial revolution. The exploitation
of the workforce generated tremendous profits, but had drastic long-term
consequences. Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels based their analysis of the
flaws of capitalism, in particular their argument that the profits of the current
economic system came at the expense of enormous human suffering by the
working classes, on first-hand observation of British conditions. All European
114 Workforce
societies in the 18th and 19th centuries faced the same social, political, and
religious pressures for reform, but British entrepreneurs could rely on the
state to support their efforts to convince and/or force the working classes to
contribute their labor. The workforce did not benefit from the Industrial
Revolution at all before 1830, and the bulk of improvements to their lives
and lifestyles did not begin until 1850.
Further Reading
Burnette, Joyce. “Women Workers in the British Industrial Revolution.” Available
online at https://eh.net/encyclopedia/women-workers-in-the-british-industrial
-revolution-2/.
Griffin, Emma. A Short History of the British Industrial Revolution. Houndsmills, UK:
Palgrave, 2010.
Rule, John. The Labouring Classes in Early Industrial England, 1750–1850. London:
Routledge, 1986.
Thompson, E. P. The Making of the English Working Class. London: Vintage, 1966
1963).
Tuttle, Carolyn. “Child Labor during the British Industrial Revolution.” Available
online at https://eh.net/encyclopedia/child-labor-during-the-british-industrial
-revolution/.
Primary Documents
. . . The Profit That People [the Dutch] have received, and any other may
receive, by reducing the Interest of Money to a very Low Rate.
This in my poor opinion, is the CAUSA CAUSANS of all the other causes
of the Riches of that people; and that if Interest of Money were with us re-
duced to the same rate it is with them, it would in a short time render us as
Rich and Considerable in Trade as they are now, and consequently be of
greater dammage to them, and advantage to us, then can happen by the Issue
of this present War, though the success of it should be as good as we can wish,
except it end in their Total Ruine and Extripation.
To illustrate this, let us impartially search our Books, and enquire what the
State and condition of this Kingdom was, as to Trade and Riches, before any
Law concerning Interest of Money was made. The first whereof that I can
find, was Ann 1545, and we shall be Informed that the Trade of England then
was Inconsiderable, and the Merchants very mean and few: And that after-
wards, viz, Anno. 1635 with ten Years after Interest was brought down to
eight per cent there was more Merchants to be found upon the Exchange
116 The Industrial Revolution
worth each One thousand Pounds and upwards, then were in the former
dayes, viz. before the year 1600 to be found worth One hundred Pounds each.
And since Interest hath been for about twenty Years at six per cent not-
withstanding our long civil Wars, and the great complaints of the deadness of
Trade, there are more men to be found upon the Exchange now worth Ten
thousand pounds Estates, then were then of One thousand pounds. . . .
If we look into the Countrey, we shall find Lands as much Improved since
the abatement of Interest, as Trade, etc. in Cities; that now yeelding twenty
Years purchase, which then would not have sold for above eight or ten at
most. . . .
More might be said, but the Premises being considered, I judge will suffi-
ciently demonstrate how greatly this Kingdom of England hath been advanc’t
in all respects for these last fifty years: And that the abatement of Interest hath
been the cause thereof, to me seems most probable; because as it appears it
hath been in England, so I find it is at this day in all Europe, and other parts
of the World: Insomuch that to know whether any Country be rich or poor,
or in what proportion it is so, no other question needs to be resolved, but this,
viz. What Interest do they pay for Money? Neer home we see it evidently, in
Scotland and Ireland, where ten and twelve per cent is paid for Interest, the
people are poor and despicable, their Persons ill cloathed, their Houses worse
provided, and Money intollerably scarce, notwithstanding they have great
plenty of all provisions, nor will their Land yield above eight or ten years
purchase at most.
In France where Money is at seven per cent, their Lands will yield about
eighteen years purchase; and the Gentry who may possess Lands, live in good
condition, though the Peazants are little better then Slaves, because they can
possess nothing but at the will of others.
In Italy Money will not yield above three per cent to be let out upon real
security; there the people are rich, full of Trade, well attired, and their Lands
will sell at thirty five to fourty years purchase, and that it is so, or better, with
them in Holland, is too manifest. . . .
Now if upon what hath been said, it be granted that de facto, this King-
dom be richer at least four-fold (I might say eight fold) then it was before any
Law for Interest was made, and that all Countries are at this day richer or
poorer in an exact proportion to what they pay, and have usually paid for the
Interest of Money; it remains that we enquire carefully, whither the abate-
ment of Interest be in truth the Cause of the Riches of any Country, or only
the Concomitant or Effect of the Riches of a Country; in which seems to lie
the Intricacy of this Question.
To satisfie myself wherein, I have taken all opportunities to discourse this
point, with the most Ingenious men I had the Honour to be known to, and
Primary Documents 117
have search’t for, and read all the Books that I could ever hear were printed
against the Abatement of Interest, and seriously considered all the Arguments
and Objections used by them against it: All which offer to the consideration
of wiser Heads, viz. THAT THE ABATEMENT OF INTEREST IS THE
CAUSE OF THE PROSPERITY AND RICHES OF ANY NATION, and
that the bringing down of Interest in this Kingdome, from six to four, or
three per cent will necessarily, in less than twenty Years time, double the Capi-
tal Stock of the Nation. . . .
Source: Josiah Child, Brief Observations Concerning Trade and Interest of Money. London: Eliza-
beth Calvert, 1668. Modeled on http://avalon.law.yale.edu/17th_century/trade.asp.
I most sincerely agree with those who regret that the labourer does not get
more for his shilling than is usually the case; the misfortune, however, does
not arise from (what is so often most unjustly reprobated) his being obliged
to purchase the few articles he has occasion for, from petty retail shops, but
because either through ignorance, custom or prejudice, he adheres to ancient
improvident systems in dress, diet, and in other branches of private expendi-
ture. . . . Instead of the ill-grounded complaints, which have so often been
reiterated by writers on the Poor, that the wages of industry are in general too
inadequate to provide the labourers with those comforts and conveniences
which are befitting his station in the community, they would better serve the
cause of the industrious peasant and manufacturer by pointing out the best
means of reducing their expenses, without diminishing their comforts.
There seems to be just reason to conclude that the miseries of the labour-
ing Poor arose, less from the scantiness of their income (however much the
philanthropist might wish it to be increased) than from their own improvi-
dence and unthriftiness; since it is the fact, and I trust will be demonstrated
in a subsequent part of this work, that in many parts of the kingdom, where
the earnings of industry are moderate, the condition of the labourers is more
comfortable than in other districts where wages are exorbitant. . . .
118 The Industrial Revolution
In 1832, Lowell was little more than a factory village. Five “corporations”
were started, and the cotton mills belonging to them were building. Help was
in great demand and stories were told all over the country of the new factory
place, and the high wages that were offered to all classes of workpeople; sto-
ries that reached the ears of mechanics’ and farmers’ sons and gave new life to
lonely and dependent women in distant towns and farmhouses. . . . Troops of
young girls came from different parts of New England, and from Canada,
and men were employed to collect them at so much a head, and deliver them
at the factories. . . .
At the time the Lowell cotton mills were started the caste of the factory girl
was the lowest among the employments of women. In England and in France,
particularly, great injustice had been done to her real character. She was rep-
resented as subjected to influences that must destroy her purity and self-
respect. In the eyes of her overseer she was but a brute, a slave, to be beaten,
pinched and pushed about. It was to overcome this prejudice that such
high wages had been offered to women that they might be induced to become
mill-girls, in spite of the opprobrium that still clung to this degrading
occupation. . . .
The early mill-girls were of different ages. Some were not over ten years
old; a few were in middle life, but the majority were between the ages of
sixteen and twenty-five. The very young girls were called “doffers.” They
“doffed,” or took off, the full bobbins from the spinning frames, and replaced
them with empty ones. These mites worked about fifteen minutes every hour
and the rest of the time was their own. When the overseer was kind they were
allowed to read, knit, or go outside the mill-yard to play. They were paid two
dollars a week. The working hours of all the girls extended from five o’clock
in the morning until seven in the evening, with one half-hour each, for break-
fast and dinner. Even the doffers were forced to be on duty nearly fourteen
hours a day. This was the greatest hardship in the lives of these children. Sev-
eral years later a ten-hour law was passed, but not until long after some of
these little doffers were old enough to appear before the legislative committee
on the subject, and plead, by their presence, for a reduction of the hours
of labor.
Those of the mill-girls who had homes generally worked from eight to ten
months in the year; the rest of the time was spent with parents or friends. A
few taught school during the summer months. Their life in the factory was
made pleasant to them. In those days there was no need of advocating the
doctrine of the proper relation between employer and employed. Help was too
valuable to be ill-treated. . . .
The most prevailing incentive to labor was to secure the means of educa-
tion for some male member of the family. To make a gentleman of a brother
120 The Industrial Revolution
or a son, to give him a college education, was the dominant thought in the
minds of a great many of the better class of mill-girls. I have known more
than one to give every cent of her wages, month after month, to her brother,
that he might get the education necessary to enter some profession. I have
known a mother to work years in this way for her boy. I have known women
to educate young men by their earnings, who were not sons or relatives. There
are many men now living who were helped to an education by the wages of
the early mill-girls.
It is well to digress here a little, and speak of the influence the possession
of money had on the characters of some of these women. We can hardly real-
ize what a change the cotton factory made in the status of the working
women. Hitherto a woman had always been a money saving rather than a
money earning, member of the community. Her labor could command but
small return. If she worked out as servant, or “help,” her wages were from
50 cents to $1 .00 a week; or, if she went from house to house by the day to
spin and weave, or do tailoress work, she could get but 75 cents a week and
her meals. As teacher, her services were not in demand, and the arts, the pro-
fessions, and even the trades and industries, were nearly all closed to her.
As late as 1840 there were only seven vocations outside the home into
which the women of New England had entered. At this time woman had no
property rights. A widow could be left without her share of her husband’s (or
the family) property, an “ incumbrance” to his estate. A father could make his
will without reference to his daughter’s share of the inheritance. He usually
left her a home on the farm as long as she remained single. A woman was not
supposed to be capable of spending her own, or of using other people’s money.
In Massachusetts, before 1840, a woman could not, legally, be treasurer of her
own sewing society, unless some man were responsible for her. The law took
no cognizance of woman as a money-spender. She was a ward, an appendage,
a relict. Thus it happened that if a woman did not choose to marry, or, when
left a widow, to remarry, she had no choice but to enter one of the few em-
ployments open to her, or to become a burden on the charity of some
relative. . . .
One of the first strikes that ever took place in this country was in Lowell
in 1836. When it was announced that the wages were to be cut down, great
indignation was felt, and it was decided to strike or “turn out” en masse. This
was done. The mills were shut down, and the girls went from their several
corporations in procession to the grove on Chapel Hill, and listened to incen-
diary speeches from some early labor reformers.
One of the girls stood on a pump and gave vent to the feelings of her com-
panions in a neat speech, declaring that it was their duty to resist all attempts
at cutting down the wages. This was the first time a woman had spoken in
Primary Documents 121
public in Lowell, and the event caused surprise and consternation among her
audience.
It is hardly necessary to say that, so far as practical results are concerned,
this strike did no good. The corporation would not come to terms. The girls
were soon tired of holding out, and they went back to their work at the re-
duced rate of wages. The ill-success of this early attempt at resistance on the
part of the wage element seems to have made a precedent for the issue of
many succeeding strikes.
Source: Harriet H. Robinson, “Early Factory Labor in New England.” In Massachusetts
Bureau of Statistics of Labor, Fourteenth Annual Report. Boston: Wright & Potter, 1883,
380–82, 387–88, 391–92.
From the whole of the evidence which has been collected under the present
Commission . . . relative to the EMPLOYMENT and the PHYSICAL CON-
DITION of the Children and Young Persons . . . who are engaged in Trade
and Manufactures, we find:
1. That instances occur in which children begin to work as early as three
and four years of age; not infrequently at five, and between five and six; while,
in general, regular employment commences between seven and eight; the
great majority of the children having begun to work before they are nine years
old . . .
2. That in all cases the persons that employ mere Infants and the very
youngest children are the parents themselves, who put their children to work
at some processes of manufacture under their own eye, in their own houses;
but children begin to work together in numbers, in larger or smaller manu-
factories, at all ages, from five years old and upwards . . .
4. That in a very large proportion of these Trades and Manufactures female
children are employed equally with boys, and at the same tender ages: in some
indeed the number of girls exceeds that of boys. . . .
122 The Industrial Revolution
6. That in the great majority of the Trades and Manufactures the youngest
children as well as the young persons are hired and paid by the workmen, and
are entirely under their control; the employers exercising no sort of superin-
tendence over them, and apparently knowing nothing whatever about them. . . .
9. That in some Trades, those especially requiring skilled workmen, . . .
apprentices are bound by legal indentures, usually at the age of fourteen, and
for a term of seven years, the age being rarely younger . . . but by far the
greater number are bound without any prescribed legal forms, and in almost
all these cases they are required to serve their masters, at whatever age they
may commence their apprenticeship, until they attain the age of twenty-one,
in some instances in employment in which there is nothing deserving the
name of skill to be acquired, and in other instances in employment in which
they are taught to make only one particular part of the article manufactured;
so that at the end of their servitude they are altogether unable to make any
one article of their trade in a complete state.
10. That a large proportion of these apprentices consist of orphans, or are
the children of widows, or belong to the very poorest families, and frequently
are apprenticed by boards of guardians [i.e., officials regulating poor relief ].
11. That the term of servitude of these apprentices may, and sometimes
does commence as early as seven years of age, and is often passed under cir-
cumstances of great hardship and ill-usage, and under the condition that,
during the greater part, if not the whole, of their term, they receive nothing
for their labor beyond food and clothing. . . .
17. That in all the districts the privies are very commonly in a disgusting
state of filth, and in great numbers of instances there is no separate accom-
modation for the males and females; but in almost all the buildings recently
constructed a greater attention has been paid to the health and the decent
comfort of the workpeople than in those of older date. . . .
19. That in some few instances the regular hours of work do not exceed
ten, exclusive of the time allowed for meals; sometimes they are eleven, but
more commonly twelve; and in great numbers of instances the employment
is continued for fifteen, sixteen, and even eighteen hours consecutively.
20. That in almost every instance the children work as long as the adults;
being sometimes kept at work sixteen, and even eighteen hours without any
intermission.
21. That in the case of young women employed in the millinery and dress
making business in the metropolis, and in some of the large provincial cities,
even in what are considered the best regulated establishments, during the
busy season, occupying in London about four months in the year, the regular
hours of work are fifteen; but on emergencies, which frequently recur, these
hours are extended to eighteen; and in many establishments the hours of
Primary Documents 123
work during the season are unlimited, the young women never getting more
than six, often not more than four, sometimes only three, and occasionally
not, more than two hours for rest and sleep out of the twenty-four, and very
frequently they work all night; there being in fact no other limit to the dura-
tion of their labor than their physical inability to work longer. . . .
23. That in some processes of Manufacture, as in winding for lace ma-
chines, the children have no regular and certain time whatever for sleep or
recreation, being liable to be called upon at any period during sixteen, twenty,
or twenty-two hours out of the twenty-four, while they have frequently to go
from one place of work to another, often at considerable distances, at all
hours of the night, and in all seasons. . . .
27. That in the cases in which the children are the servants of the work-
men, and under their sole control, the master apparently knowing nothing
about their treatment, and certainly taking no charge of it, they are almost
always roughly, very often harshly, and sometimes cruelly used; . . . the treat-
ment of them is oppressive and brutal to the last degree. . . .
29. . . . that accidents—such as hands contused, fingers cut off, jammed
between wheel- cogs, or drawn in between rollers, and arms caught in straps—
are, however, in some establishments, by no means uncommon; that some-
times the straps, wheels, etc., are so crowded and exposed that the utmost care
is required on the part of the workpeople to escape injury; and that, in by far
the greater number of instances, accidents might be prevented, if proper at-
tention were paid to the disposition and fencing of the machinery. . . .
31. . . . that, from the early ages at which the great majority [of children]
commence work, from their long hours of work, and from the insufficiency
of their food and clothing, their “bodily health “ is seriously and generally
injured; they are for the most part stunted in growth, their aspect being pale,
delicate, and sickly, and they present altogether the appearance of a race
which has suffered general physical deterioration.
32. That the diseases which are most prevalent amongst them, and to
which they are more subject than children of their age and station unem-
ployed in labor, are disordered states of the nutritive organs, curvature and
distortion of the spine, deformity of the limbs, and diseases of the lungs, end-
ing in atrophy and consumption. . . .
From the whole of the evidence collected under the present Commission
relative to the MORAL CONDITION of the Children and Young Persons
included within its terms, whether employed In COLLIERIES and Mines or
in TRADES and MANUFACTURES, we find:
1. That there are few classes of these children and young persons “working
together in numbers,” of whom a large portion are not in a lamentably low
moral condition.
124 The Industrial Revolution
14. That there is not a single district in which the means of instruction are
adequate to the wants of the people, while in some districts the deficiency is
so great that clergymen, and other witnesses, state that the schools actually in
existence are insufficient for the education of one- third of the population.
15. That, were schools ever so abundant and excellent, they would be
wholly beyond the reach of a large portion of the children employed in labor,
on account of the early ages at which they are put to work.
16. That great numbers of children and young persons attend no day-
school before they commence work; that even those who do go for a brief
period to a day-school are very commonly removed to be put to labor at five,
six, seven, and eight years old; and that the instances are extremely rare
in which they attend an evening-school after regular employment has once
begun. . . .
18. That, in all the districts, many children and young persons, whether
employed in the mines of coal and iron, or in trades and manufactures, never
go to any school, and some never have been at any school. . . .
23. That in all the districts, great numbers of those children who, had been
in regular attendance in Sunday-schools for a period of from five to nine
years, were found, on examination, to be incapable of reading an easy book,
or of spelling the commonest word; and they were not only altogether igno-
rant of Christian principles, doctrines, and precepts, but they knew nothing
whatever of any of the events of Scripture history, nor anything even of the
names most commonly occurring in the Scriptures. . . .
32. That there are parents who not only anxiously endeavor to afford their
children, even at the expense of some personal sacrifice and self-denial, good
and sufficient food and clothing, but also the best education within their
reach, and who themselves superintend, as well as they are able, their chil-
dren’s education and conduct; but this attention to their moral condition is
rare. . . .
35. That from the whole body of evidence it appears, however, that there
are at present in existence no means adequate to effect any material and gen-
eral improvement in the Physical and Moral Condition of the Children and
Young Persons employed in labor.
. . . It was no part of the duty prescribed to us by the terms of Your Maj-
esty’s Commission to suggest remedies for any grievances or evils which we
might find to exist, because it was deemed necessary to obtain the fullest in-
formation as to the real condition of the persons included in the inquiry, be-
fore the consideration of remedies could be entertained with any prospect of
advantage. This information we have now collected; and the picture which,
in the faithful performance of this duty, we have been obliged to present of
the physical and moral condition of a large portion of the working classes
126 The Industrial Revolution
gratitude and self-interest, have rejoiced at the success resulting from their
labours, and by regularity and skill have recommended themselves to monied
men desirous of engaging in a profitable concern, and of procuring qualified
hands to conduct it. Thus good workmen would have advanced their condi-
tion to that of overlookers, managers, and partners in new mills, and have
increased at the same time the demand for their companions’ labour in the
market. It is only by an undisturbed progression of this kind that the rate of
wages can be permanently raised or upheld. Had it not been for the violent
collisions and interruptions resulting from erroneous views among the
operatives, the factory system would have been developed still more rapidly
and beneficially for all concerned than it has been, and would have exhibited
still more frequently gratifying examples of skillful workmen becoming
opulent proprietors. Every misunderstanding either repels capital altogether,
or diverts it from flowing, for a time, in the channels of a trade liable to
strikes. . . .
No master would wish to have any wayward children to work within the
walls of his factory, who do not mind their business without beating, and he
therefore usually fines or turns away any spinners who are known to maltreat
their assistants. Hence, ill usage of any kind is a very rare occurrence. I have
visited many factories, both in Manchester and in the surrounding districts,
during a period of several months, entering the spinning rooms, unexpect-
edly, and often alone, at different times of the day, and I never saw a single
instance of corporal chastisement inflicted on a child, nor indeed did I ever
see children in ill-humour. They seemed to be always cheerful and alert, tak-
ing pleasure in the light play of their muscles,—enjoying the mobility natural
to their age. The scene of industry, so far from exciting sad emotions in my
mind, was always exhilarating. It was delightful to observe the nimbleness
with which they pieced the broken ends, as the mule carriage began to recede
from the fixed roller-beam, and to see them at leisure, after a few seconds’
exercise of their tiny fingers, to amuse themselves in any attitude they chose,
till the stretch and winding-on were once more completed. The work of these
lively elves seemed to resemble a sport, in which habit gave them a pleasing
dexterity. Conscious of their skill, they were delighted to show it off to any
stranger. As to exhaustion by the day’s work, they evinced no trace of it on
emerging from the mill in the evening; for they immediately began to skip
about any neighbouring play-ground, and to commence their little amuse-
ments with the same alacrity as boys issuing from a school. It is moreover my
firm conviction, that if children are not ill-used by bad parents or guardians,
but receive in food and raiment the full benefit of what they earn, they would
thrive better when employed in our modern factories, than if left at home in
apartments too often ill-aired, damp, and cold.
128 The Industrial Revolution
Source: Andrew Ure, The Philosophy of Manufactures or an Exposition of the Scientific, Moral,
and Commercial Economy of the Factory System of Great Britain. London: Charles Knight, 1835,
278–80, 300–301.
wholesome country air, in fine, comfortable homes, passed once every half or
quarter hour by omnibuses going into the city. . . .
Going from the Old Church to Long Millgate . . . are remnants of the old
pre-manufacturing Manchester, whose former inhabitants have removed with
their descendants into better-built districts, and have left the houses, which
were not good enough for them, to a working-class population strongly mixed
with Irish blood. Here one is in an almost undisguised working-men’s quar-
ter, for even the shops and beerhouses hardly take the trouble to exhibit a
trifling degree of cleanliness. . . .
Right and left a multitude of covered passages lead from the main street
into numerous courts, and he who turns in thither gets into a filth and dis-
gusting grime, the equal of which is not to be found—especially in the courts
which lead down to the Irk, and which contain unqualifiedly the most hor-
rible dwellings which I have yet beheld. In one of these courts where stands
directly at the entrance, at the end of the covered passage, a privy without a
door, so dirty that the inhabitants can pass into and out of the court only be
passing through foul pools of stagnant urine and excrement. This is the first
court on the Irk above Ducie Bridge—in case anyone should care to look into
it. Below it on the river there are several tanneries which fill the whole neigh-
borhood with the stench of animal putrefaction. Below Ducie Bridge the
only entrance to most of the houses is by means of narrow, dirty stairs and
over heaps of refuse and filth. The first court below Ducie Bridge, known as
Allen’s Court, was in such a state at the time of the cholera that the sanitary
police ordered it evacuated, swept, and disinfected with chloride of lime. . . .
At the bottom flows, or rather stagnates, the Irk, a narrow, coal-black, foul-
smelling stream, full of debris and refuse, which it deposits on the shallower
right bank. In dry weather, a long string of the most disgusting, blackish-
green, slime pools are left standing on this bank, from the depths of which
bubbles of miasmatic gas constantly arise and give forth a stench unendurable
even on the bridge forty of fifty feet above the surface of the stream. But be-
sides this, the stream itself is checked every few paces by high weirs, behind
which slime and refuse accumulate and rot in thick masses. Above the bridge
are tanneries, bonemills, and gasworks, from which all drains and refuse find
their way into the Irk, which receives further the contents of all the neigh-
bouring sewers and privies. It may be easily imagined, therefore, what sort of
residue the steam deposits. Below the bridge you look upon the piles of debris,
the refuse, filth, and offal from the courts on the steep left bank; here each
house is packed close behind its neighbor and a piece of each is visible, all
black, smoky, crumbling, ancient, with broken panes and window-frames.
Source: Friedrich Engels, The Condition of the Working-Class in England in 1844. London:
Swan Sonnenschein & Co., 1892 [1845], 42, 45–46, 48–50.
130 The Industrial Revolution
peoples who possess them, it will perhaps not be without use to convince
some less enlightened persons of the same thing, to arm them against the
effects which some vile sophists might have on their minds. Let them com-
pare a Canadian savage with any citizen of a civilized country of Europe, and
all the advantage will be with the latter. How can one prefer crude nature
to nature perfected, lack of means of subsistence to a life of ease, rudeness to
politeness, the security of politeness enjoyed under the protection of the laws
to the law of the jungle and to anarchy, which destroys the fortunes and con-
ditions of families?
Society, a community of men, could not do without either the arts of the
sciences. Thanks to surveying and hydraulics, riparian regions are protected
from flooding; without these arts, fertile lands would become unhealthy
marshes, and would deprive numerous families of their livelihood. The higher
land could do without surveyors to measure out and divide the fields. The
physical sciences, firmly established by experiment, help to perfect agriculture
and, in particular, horticulture. Botany, applied to the study of medicinal
herbs, and chemistry, which can extract their essences, serve at least to fortify
our hope during our illnesses, even if their property cannot cure us. Anatomy
guides and directs the surgeon’s hand in those painful but necessary opera-
tions that save our life at the expense of an amputated limb.
The mechanical sciences are useful in every field: if a load is to be raised or
transported, they will move it. If we are to dig into the bowels of the earth to
extract metals, the science of mechanics, with ingenious machines, pumps
out the quarries and frees the miner from the super-abundance of water
which would cost him his life or his work. If we need mills to grind the most
familiar and most basic form of food, the science of mechanics perfects them.
It is the science of mechanics that helps craftsmen by improving the various
types of craft at which they work. Every kind of machine lies within its prov-
ince. And how many machines are needed in all the various fields! The craft
of shipbuilding constitutes perhaps one of the greatest efforts of imagination;
but how much knowledge the pilot must possess to steer his ship and brave
wind and wave! He needs to have studied astronomy, to have good charts, an
exact knowledge of geography and arithmetical skill, in order to ascertain the
distance he has travelled and the point at which he is, and in this respect he
will be helped in future by the chronometers which have just been perfected
in England. The arts and sciences go hand in hand: we owe them everything,
they are the benefactors of mankind.
Source: Frederick II, “Discourse on the Usefulness of the Arts and Sciences in a State” (1772).
In S. Eliot and K. Whitlock, eds., The Enlightenment, Texts I. Milton Keynes: Open University
Press, 1992, 66–67. © The Open University; used by permission.
132 The Industrial Revolution
consume. . . . The average earnings of plain silk hands are indeed too well
known to you, to be a very small pittance for the maintenance of a wife and
two or three children; they do not exceed 10s. 6d. per week: if some average
13s. per week, this will do very little for a family. Three shillings at least must
go for house-rent and taxes—one shilling for coal—one shilling and sixpence
for soap and candles, for himself and family; and if he has a wife and three
children he must have one stone and a half of flour, which is at least six shil-
lings more; here we see the poor fellow has left three shillings and sixpence to
provide all other necessaries of life.
. . . The imperious dictates of human nature impel us to raise up a manly
voice in our own behalf: governed by every principle of right towards you,
acknowledging that due deference to your superior station, yet loudly calling
your attention to our present case. . . . Hedged in by a combination act, we
cannot say to you as a public body, that we demand an advance of wages, but
we can say that JUSTICE DEMANDS that we should receive remuneration
for extra labour: this is all we want. . . .
Gentlemen, there is every reason in the world to prove that a remuneration
ought and must take place. Several Hosiers in this town have openly avowed
its necessity. The high price of provision is on our side, reason, honer, moral-
ity, philanthropy, necessity, justice, your own interest, as being accountable to
the Almighty, the practicality of the case, the combination act, and the gen-
eral sufferage of mankind; all declare that we ought to be remunerated for
extra labour.
Gentlemen, being invited by some of you to state our grievances, we have
used great plainness on the subject; well knowing that this will prvail, when
acts of violence would render us detestable to mankind. . . .
Source: Kevin Binfield, ed., Writings of the Luddites. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University
Press, 2004, 80–84.
labor when he was put in charge of his father-in-law’s mill at New Lanark, Scot-
land. The large profits earned under his management helped demonstrate that the
thoroughgoing exploitation of workers, especially of children, was not necessary to
the success of the factory system. At the same time, Owen’s concern with education
and the welfare of society in general were important counterpoints to greedy, abu-
sive mill owners. This passage is from A New View of Society, or Essays on the
Principle of the Formation of Human Character and the Application of the
Principle to Practice written in 1813.
According to the last returns under the Population Act, the poor and working
classes of Great Britain and Ireland have been found to exceed twelve millions
of persons, or nearly three-fourths of the population of the British Islands.
The characters of these persons are now permitted to be very generally
formed without proper guidance or direction, and, in many cases, under cir-
cumstances which must train them to the extreme of vice and misery; and of
course render them the worst and most dangerous subjects in the empire;
while the far greater part of the remainder of the community are educated
upon the most mistaken principles of human nature, such, indeed, as cannot
fail to produce a general conduct throughout society, totally unworthy of the
character of rational beings. . . .
In the year 1784, the late Mr. Dale of Glasgow [Owen’s father-in-law]
founded a spinning and weaving manufactory near the falls of the Clyde, in
the county of Lanark in Scotland; and about that period cotton mills were
first introduced into the northern part of the kingdom.
It was the power which could be obtained from the falls of water which
induced Mr. Dale to erect his mills in this situation, for in other respects it
was not well chosen: the country around was uncultivated; the inhabitants
were poor, and few in number; and the roads in the neighborhood were
so bad that the falls of Clyde now so celebrated were then unknown to
strangers.
It was therefore necessary to collect a new population to supply the infant
establishment with laborers. This however was no light task; for all the regu-
larly trained Scotch peasantry disdained the idea of working from early till
late, day after day, within cotton mills. Two modes only to obtain these labor-
ers occurred: the one, to procure children from the various public charities in
the country; and the other to induce families to settle around the works.
To accommodate the first, a large house was erected, which ultimately
contained about five hundred children, who were procured chiefly from
workhouses and charities in Edinburgh.
These children were to be fed, clothed, and educated; and these duties
Mr. Dale performed with the benevolence which he was known to possess.
136 The Industrial Revolution
To obtain the second, a village was built, and the houses were let at a low
rent to such families as could be induced to accept employment in the mills:
but such was the general dislike to that to that occupation at the time, that,
with a few exceptions, the persons must destitute of friends, employment,
and character, were alone found willing to try the experiment; and of these a
sufficient number to supply a constant increase of the manufactory could not
be obtained. . . .
The benevolent proprietor spared no expense which could give comfort to
the poor children which it contained. The rooms provided for them were spa-
cious, always clean, and well ventilated; the food was of the best quality, and
most abundant; the clothes were neat and useful; a surgeon was kept in con-
stant pay to direct how to prevent as well as cure disease; and the best instruc-
tors which the country afforded were appointed to teach such branches of
education as were deemed likely to be useful to children in their situation;
and kind, well disposed persons were appointed to superintend all the pro-
ceedings. Nothing, in short, at first sight seemed wanting to render it a most
complete charity.
But to defray the expense of these well devised arrangements, and support
the establishment generally, it was absolutely necessary that the children
should be employed within the mills from six o’clock in the morning to
seven in the evening summer and winter; and after these hours their educa-
tion commenced. The directors of the public charities from mistaken
economy, would not consent to send the children under their care to the
cotton mills, unless the children were received by the proprietors at the
ages of six, seven, and eight. And Mr. Dale was under the necessity of
accepting them at those ages, or stopping the manufactory which he had
commenced.
It is not to be supposed that children so young could remain, with the in-
terval of meals only, from six in the morning until seven in the evening, in
constant employment on their feet within cotton mills, and afterwards ac-
quire much proficiency in education. And so it proved; for the greater part of
them became dwarfs in body and mind, and many of them deformed. Their
labor through the day, and their education at night, became so irksome, that
numbers of them continually ran away, and almost all looked forward with
impatience and anxiety to the expiration of their apprenticeship of seven,
eight, and nine years, which generally expired when they were from thirteen
to fifteen years old. At this period of life, unaccustomed to provide for them-
selves, and unacquainted with the world, they usually went to Edinburgh or
Glasgow, where boys and girls were soon assailed by the innumerable tempta-
tions which all large towns present; and many of them fell sacrifices to those
temptations.
Primary Documents 137
Thus were Mr. Dale’s arrangements and kind solicitude for the comfort
and happiness of these children rendered in their ultimate effect almost nuga-
tory. They were sent to be employed, and without their labor he could not
support them; but, while under his care, he did all that any individual cir-
cumstanced as he was could do for his fellow-creatures.
The error proceeded from the children being sent from the workhouses at
an age far too young for employment; they ought to have been detained four
years longer, and education; and then all the evils which followed would have
been prevented. . . .
[After Owen took over] the system of receiving apprentices from public
charities was abolished; permanent settlers with large families were encour-
aged, and comfortable houses were built for their accommodation.
The practice of employing children in the mills, of six, seven, and eight
years of age, was discontinued, and their parents advised to allow them to
acquire health and education until they were ten years old. (It may be re-
marked, that even this age is too early to keep them at constant employment
in manufactories, from six in the morning to seven in the evening. Far better
would it be for the children, their parents, and for society, that the first should
not commence employment until they attain the age of twelve, when their
education might be finished, and their bodies would be more competent to
undergo the fatigue and exertions required of them. When parents can be
trained to afford this additional time to their children without inconvenience,
they will, of course adopt the practice now recommended.)
The children were taught reading, writing, and arithmetic, during five
years, that is, from five to ten, in the village school, without expense to their
parents; and all the modern improvements in education have been adopted,
or are in process of adoption: some facilities in teaching arithmetic have been
also introduced, which were peculiar to this school, and found very advanta-
geous. They may therefore be taught and well trained before they engage in
any regular employment. Another important consideration is, that all their
instruction is rendered a pleasure and delight to them; they are much more
anxious for the hour of school time to arrive, than end: they therefore make a
rapid progress; and it may be safely asserted, that if they shall not be trained
for form such characters as may be the most wished and desired, not one
particle of the fault will proceed from the children; but the cause will rest in
the want of a true knowledge of human nature, in those who have the man-
agement of them and their parents.
Source: Robert Owen, A New View of Society: or Essays on the Principle of the Formation of Hu-
man Character and the Application of the Principle to Practice. London: Richard Taylor and Co.,
1813, 5, 35–36, 38–40, 49–51.
138 The Industrial Revolution
The greatest improvement in the productive powers of labour, and the greater
part of the skill, dexterity, and judgment with which it is anywhere directed,
or applied, seem to have been the effects of the division of labour.
The effects of the division of labour, in the general business of society, will
be more easily understood, by considering in what manner it operates in some
particular manufactures. It is commonly supposed to be carried furthest in
some very trifling ones; not perhaps that it really is carried further in them
than in others of more importance: but in those trifling manufactures which
are destined to supply the small wants of but a small number of people, the
whole number of workmen must necessarily be small; and those employed
in every different branch of the work can often be collected into the same
workhouse, and placed at once under the view of the spectator. In those great
manufactures, on the contrary, which are destined to supply the great wants
of the great body of the people, every different branch of the work employs so
great a number of workmen, that it is impossible to collect them all into the
same workhouse. We can seldom see more, at one time, than those employed
in one single branch. Though in such manufactures, therefore, the work may
really be divided into a much greater number of parts, than in those of a more
trifling nature, the division is not near so obvious, and has accordingly been
much less observed.
To take an example, therefore, from a very trifling manufacture; but one in
which the division of labour has been very often taken notice of, the trade of
the pin-maker; a workman not educated to this business (which the division
of labour has rendered a distinct trade), nor acquainted with the use of the
machinery employed in it (to the invention of which the same division of
labour has probably given occasion), could scarce, perhaps, with his utmost
industry, make one pin in a day, and certainly could not make twenty. But in
the way in which this business is now carried on, not only the whole work is
a peculiar trade, but it is divided into a number of branches, of which the
greater part are likewise peculiar trades. One man draws out the wire, another
Primary Documents 139
straights it, a third cuts it, a fourth points it, a fifth grinds it at the top for
receiving the head; to make the head requires two or three distinct operations;
to put it on, is a peculiar business, to whiten the pins is another; it is even a
trade by itself to put them into the paper; and the important business of mak-
ing a pin is, in this manner, divided into about eighteen distinct operations,
which, in some manufactories, are all performed by distinct hands, though in
others the same man will sometimes perform two or three of them. I have
seen a small manufactory of this kind where ten men only were employed,
and where some of them consequently performed two or three distinct
operations. But though they were very poor, and therefore but indifferently
accommodated with the necessary machinery, they could, when they exerted
themselves, make among them about twelve pounds of pins in a day. There
are in a pound upwards of four thousand pins of a middling size. Those ten
persons, therefore, could make among them upwards of forty-eight thousand
pins in a day. Each person, therefore, making a tenth part of forty-eight thou-
sand pins, might be considered as making four thousand eight hundred pins
in a day. But if they had all wrought separately and independently, and with-
out any of them having been educated to this peculiar business, they certainly
could not each of them have made twenty, perhaps not one pin in a day;
that is, certainly, not the two hundred and fortieth, perhaps not the four
thousand eight hundredth part of what they are at present capable of per-
forming, in consequence of a proper division and combination of their differ-
ent operations.
In every other art and manufacture, the effects of the division of labour are
similar to what they are in this very trifling one; though, in many of them, the
labour can neither be so much subdivided, nor reduced to so great a simplicity
of operation. The division of labour, however, so far as it can be introduced,
occasions, in every art, a proportionable increase of the productive powers of
labour. The separation of different trades and employments from one another,
seems to have taken place, in consequence of this advantage. This separation
too is generally carried furthest in those countries which enjoy the highest
degree of industry and improvement; what is the work of one man in a rude
state of society, being generally that of several in an improved one. In every
improved society, the farmer is generally nothing but a farmer; the manufac-
turer, nothing but a manufacturer. The labour too which is necessary to pro-
duce any one complete manufacture, is almost always divided among a great
number of hands. . . .
This great increase of the quantity of work which, in consequence of the
division of labour, the same number of people are capable of performing, is
owing to three different circumstances; first to the increase of dexterity in every
particular workman; secondly, to the saving of the time which is commonly
140 The Industrial Revolution
lost in passing from one species of work to another; and lastly, to the invention
of a great number of machines which facilitate and abridge labour, and enable
one man to do the work of many. . . . (Book I, Chapter 1).
In the progress of the division of labour, the employment of the far greater
part of those who live by labour, that is, of the great body of the people,
comes to be confined to a few very simple operations, frequently to one or
two. But the understandings of the greater part of men are necessarily formed
by their ordinary employments. The man whose whole life is spent in per-
forming a few simple operations, of which the effects are perhaps always the
same, or very nearly the same, has no occasion to exert his understanding or
to exercise his invention in finding out expedients for removing difficulties
which never occur. He naturally loses, therefore, the habit of such exertion,
and generally becomes as stupid and ignorant as it is possible for a human
creature to become. The torpor of his mind renders him not only incapable
of relishing or bearing a part in any rational conversation, but of conceiving
any generous, noble, or tender sentiment, and consequently of forming any
just judgment concerning many even of the ordinary duties of private life. Of
the great and extensive interests of his country he is altogether incapable of
judging, and unless very particular pains have been taken to render him oth-
erwise, he is equally incapable of defending his country in war. The uniform-
ity of his stationary life naturally corrupts the courage of his mind, and makes
him regard with abhorrence the irregular, uncertain, and adventurous life of
a soldier. It corrupts even the activity of his body, and renders him incapable
of exerting his strength with vigour and perseverance in any other employ-
ment than that to which he has been bred. His dexterity at his own particular
trade seems, in this manner, to be acquired at the expence of his intellectual,
social, and martial virtues. But in every improved and civilized society this
is the state into which the labouring poor, that is, the great body of the peo-
ple, must necessarily fall, unless government takes some pains to prevent it.
(Book V, Chapter 1).
Source: Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, ed. Edwin
Canaan, 5th ed. London: Meuthen, 1904 [1776].
Key Questions
Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present
(1969). Landes’s account has dominated understandings of this question ever
since.
A great deal of attention has been focused on how those gadgets were in-
vented and made. Studies of innovators and manufacturing pioneers have
been complemented by examination of the role of workers and the working
classes in facilitating or inhibiting industrialization. At the same time, schol-
ars have explored the impact of key institutions like the framework of prop-
erty rights, the tax system, and the financial system capped by the Bank of
England. Taken together, these studies pointed to the unique features of Brit-
ish industrialization.
Although Landes’s work compared England to the rest of western Europe,
his focus was clearly on the role of technology in the three key industries of
textiles, coal, and iron. Thanks to a flood of studies exploring developments
in Britain, it became only natural for other scholars to explore the compara-
tive dimensions. Contemporary industrial developments in France, Belgium,
the German lands, and the United States received concerted attention as did
parts of Europe and other areas of the world that only industrialized later.
These studies contextualized British industrialization by highlighting what
was truly unique and what was European or even western about the Industrial
Revolution. These studies found that it was less British scientific prowess than
skill at implementing innovations that marked English technological advance
as different from the continent.
The logical next step for testing arguments about the key factors in the
British Industrial Revolution was to determine their impact. Changes in Eng-
land’s Gross National Product (GNP) had been measured and linked to the
chief industrial districts with changes over time noted in minute detail, but
most assertions about the standard of living for diverse groups or for the
country as a whole were not based on adequate data. C. Knick Harley and
Nicholas Crafts, among a host of others, spent a decade examining the avail-
able quantitative evidence to delineate the effect of transformative industrial
growth on the standard of living in general and of diverse groups. The data
suggested that the British standard of living did not improve during the first
half-century of the Industrial Revolution. What they found ignited a major
controversy. Their findings were challenged and their numbers checked and
rechecked. Problems with the statistics were explored and their limitations
exposed and factored into the analysis. When all was said and done, it was
clear that the British standard of living did not start to improve until the
1820s at the earliest with the 1830s as more likely. For more than two full
generations, the working classes, and even the British people as a whole, did
not benefit from the Industrial Revolution. Who did profit and how that
Key Questions 143
England to become the first industrial nation. Stockland wrote this essay while
conducting research for his doctoral dissertation on the environmental and
economic history of livestock. He focuses on the south of France and on the
18th century. Stockland is an advanced graduate student in the History De-
partment at Columbia University.
The second essay is written by Jeff Horn who is Professor of History at
Manhattan College. He too is a historian of France and the author of five
previous books on the French and Industrial Revolutions that explore tech-
nology, trade, colonialism, politics, and the role of the state. He takes a more
explicitly comparative approach to the question by considering what impeded
Britain’s competitors while emphasizing the role of contingency in England’s
ability to touch off and maintain the Industrial Revolution.
High Wages
British wages in the 18th century were exceptionally high by comparison
with other countries in Europe and Asia. Foreign travelers marveled at the
high living standards of British laborers, who were better nourished and
clothed than their counterparts on the European continent. For British entre-
preneurs, however, the high cost of labor was an impediment that increased
prices and made their goods less competitive in domestic and international
markets. The high costs of labor in Britain acted as a powerful incentive to
Key Questions 145
but also leather and wool. In addition, Britain possessed high-quality supplies
of coal and iron so essential to early industrialization as well as lead, tin, kao-
lin, and other clays. These resources constituted a near optimal basis for an
industrial revolution based on textiles, iron, and coal.
Britain’s low mountains, numerous fast-running streams, pattern of rivers,
jagged coastline, superb harbors, and separation from the continent also pro-
vided unrivaled geographic advantages. England is compact and relatively eas-
ily traversed, encouraging the construction of turnpikes and canals. Streams
provided numerous potential sources of water power and the interlocking
river systems of the Thames, Trent, Severn, and Wash covered most of the
country. In combination with the craggy shoreline, this meant that nowhere
in England is more than 70 miles from the Atlantic or 30 miles from a
navigable river with access to the sea. Abundant harbors and estuaries scat-
tered around the country provided safe havens where ships were protected
from the tempestuous Atlantic as well as jumping off points for sea-borne
commerce.
The ease and extent of transportation by water was perhaps the greatest
geographical advantage enjoyed by Britain. Rivers and canals enabled goods
to be exchanged quickly and relatively cheaply across the length and breadth
of the country. Widespread access to the sea provided an even more inexpen-
sive means of transporting goods. No other nation with the resources to com-
mence industrialization possessed this massive cost advantage to engage in
long-distance trade. Before the onset of industrialization, British road trans-
port costs were about 1 shilling per ton-mile. On inland waterways, transport
cost a little more than 20 percent of that figure with coastal shipping averag-
ing significantly less than that. Transporting goods by land was far slower and
more expensive than by water. A very high percentage of Britain’s cost advan-
tage in long-distance trade stemmed from transportation. Another substan-
tial wedge resulted from superior access to energy sources such as coal whose
rock bottom price derived from low transport costs. Geography was essential
to British industrial leadership.
The English Channel also formed a moat that protected the Hanoverian
state from the vicissitudes of continental warfare. Without this defensive bar-
rier, it is hard to imagine how England could have avoided invasion and de-
feat in 1688, 1715, 1745, 1755–1761, 1778–1781, 1793–1794, 1797–1798,
and 1800–1812. To take one example, even if England could have stopped a
Napoleonic invasion in 1805, the loss of life and property would likely have
been enormous and the war effort and/or recovery would have diverted pre-
cious resources from productive use. Conquest might also have shifted state
policy away from supporting industrialization. Britain used continental wars
and France’s distraction to conquer new territories in India and to acquire
Key Questions 149
Closing
Why was England first? Technology certainly played an important role.
Étienne Stockland makes a convincing case for technology’s significance,
though he also pays close attention to the prior existence of a high-wage econ-
omy and to England’s tremendous endowment of cheap energy resources. For
Stockland, these two factors facilitated the productivity of England’s scientific
culture. Horn also emphasizes England’s wealth of coal and sites appropriate
for waterwheels, but he puts it in more general terms under the heading
of “geography.” He focuses greater attention on how geography protected
the island nation from invasion and allowed it to concentrate on economic
development in ways that its continental competitors could not. As an island,
England could also focus on acquiring and profiting from its empire in ways
that France and other European states could only dream of.
English economic leadership also depended on contingency. Many ac-
counts of the English industrial revolution suggest that with its resource and
capital endowments, institutions, leadership, profitable empire, and techno-
logical creativity, the Hanoverian state was destined to be the first industrial
nation. Such quasi-deterministic interpretations are rejected implicitly by
Stockland and explicitly by Horn, in part because they are historians of politi-
cal economy and write primarily about France, England’s chief political,
military, economic, and technological competitor. It is essential to recall the
multiple pathways and accidents of history that enabled some individuals,
groups, societies, and states to take advantage of their economic opportuni-
ties while preventing others from doing the same. There is a difference be-
tween being able to commence an industrial revolution and being the first to
do so. The gap that developed in the 19th century between England and its
competitors stemmed, in large measure, from the Hanoverian state’s position
as industrial pioneer. That is one of the most important reasons why it mat-
ters why England was the first.
Key Questions 151
Doing More
Online
“The Industrial Revolution Begins in England (1760–1850).” Available online at
http://webs.bcp.org/sites/vcleary/ModernWorldHistoryTextbook/Industrial
Revolution/IRbegins.html.
Temin, Peter. “Two Views of the British Industrial Revolution.” 1995. Available on-
line at https://dspace.mit.edu/bitstream/handle/1721.1/64205/twoviewsofbritis
00temi.pdf?sequence=1.
Voigtländer, Nico, and Hans-Joachim Voth. “Why England? Demographic Factors,
Structural Change and Physical Capital Accumulation during the Industrial
Revolution.” Journal of Economic Growth. 2006. DOI 10.1007/s10887–006–
9007–6. Available online at http://www.anderson.ucla.edu/faculty/nico.v/Research
/WhyEngland_JEG.pdf.
Print
Ashton, Thomas S. The Industrial Revolution, 1760–1830. London: Oxford Univer-
sity Press, 1948.
Broadberry, Stephen, and Kevin H. O’Rourke, eds. The Cambridge Economic History
of Modern Europe, vol. 1, 1700–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010.
Crafts, N. F. R. British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution. Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1985.
Crafts, N. F. R., and C. Knick Harley. “Output Growth and the British Industrial
Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View.” Economic History Review
45 (1992): 703–30.
Horn, Jeff, Leonard N. Rosenband, and Merritt Roe Smith, eds. Reconceptualizing
the Industrial Revolution. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2010.
Landes, David S. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial De-
velopment in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1969.
Landes, David S. “The Fable of the Dead Horse; or, The Industrial Revolution
Revisited.” In The British Industrial Revolution: An Economic Perspective, 2nd ed.,
edited by Joel Mokyr. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1999.
safety until England had become the “workshop of the world” and the un-
questioned industrial powerhouse. When workers attempted to use their
superior numbers to get more money, better conditions, or fewer hours,
the state made sure that their efforts were stillborn, intervening with force
when necessary. Only after 1830 and then in a limited way did the state
intervene to stop the worst of what the working classes experienced as exploi-
tation. In the 20th century, the degree of state intervention on behalf of
either workers or entrepreneurs depended mostly on the politics of the party
in power.
The debate about the necessity of poor working conditions and paying
the lowest possible wages to those who labored in the factories and mines of
the Industrial Revolution raged across the 19th and into the 20th century.
This was no simple scholarly debate; rather, the answer to this question has
tremendous political and policy implications not only for industrialized
countries but also for the developing world. What constitutes exploitation
and how it was or can be established and maintained remains a fundamen-
tally political question.
Historians and economists have approached the issue of exploitation of the
working classes and its necessity to rapid industrialization in a variety of—
often highly politicized—ways. In approaches to the Industrial Revolution,
E. P. Thompson and an outstanding cohort of other labor historians like Eric
Hobsbawm who were influenced greatly by Marxism delineated the condi-
tions that workers endured and demonstrated that the working classes had
not simply accepted their treatment. Following in these footsteps but also
taking advantage of developments in the interlinked but separate histories of
women and of children, the position of these groups has received a great deal
of recent attention that demonstrates how bad their working conditions and
pay scales were. The downward revisions to understandings of the standard of
living for the working classes during the first two generations of industrializa-
tion have also bolstered the case that the working classes were exploited dur-
ing the Industrial Revolution.
Others scholars have argued—more or less explicitly—that if workers did
not emigrate and if they were able to purchase increasing amounts of con-
sumer goods, then they could not really have been exploited. Jan de Vries’s
evocation of an “Industrious Revolution” in which the laboring classes worked
harder (and longer) in order to be able to purchase manufactured trinkets or
foodstuffs like coffee, chocolate, sugar, and tea can be understood as rejecting
the notion of working-class experience as inherently exploitative. Compari-
son of the standard of living of workers to those in England’s closest competi-
tors shows that wages were often higher and consumption beyond the barest
necessities greater there than elsewhere.
154 The Industrial Revolution
productivity during this period was the main driver of this growth. Therefore,
if neoclassical economics is correct, we should expect wages to increase in a
similar fashion. In particular, we would expect real wages to increase, showing
an improvement in the working classes’ purchasing power. Moreover, empiri-
cal evidence should exist that living standards were better for the new work-
ing classes than before the Industrial Revolution, justifying an increase in the
hours worked.
Recent estimations of the evolution of wages for artisans and laborers
in the building trades in England show an increase in real wages of about
60 percent between 1760 and 1860, with most of the increase happening
after 1820. Other estimates put the increase at around 30 percent in the same
period. These lower estimates mean that wages increased less than the im-
provement in output per worker, which demonstrates that some of the profits
derived from that increase in labor productivity did not go to the workers.
Proponents of an “Industrious Revolution” find that real wages for England
and other countries show little evidence of an increase in purchasing power
for workers’ wages, and note that there was actually some deterioration before
1820. They focus, however, on evidence of growing consumer demand for a
broader range of products among the working classes.
Marx’s collaborator Friedrich Engels argued in 1844 that preindustrial
workers were far better off than their successors who toiled in the factories
because they achieved better living standards with fewer hours worked. Clark
recognizes that during its first decades, the Industrial Revolution was not ac-
companied by a noticeable improvement of living conditions for the working
classes, but emphasizes that this trend changed around the same time that real
wages increased, i.e., after 1820 at the earliest and more likely around 1850.
From that date to the beginning of the 20th century, conditions for workers
improved and they started to earn salaries well above the subsistence level,
opening the path for the emergence of a new middle class.
There seems to be mixed evidence of the evolution of the number of hours
worked. In Birmingham and the Black Country, there is no evidence of a
drastic change in the hours worked or the working conditions during the first
half of the 19th century. However, more generally, there appears to have been
a significant increase in the hours worked. This situation suggests a number
of possibilities as to why workers might increase their supply of labor. For
example, was there an “Industrious Revolution” that led them to exchange
leisure for labor in order to earn the money to purchase a broader range of
new consumer products? To answer that question is beyond the scope of this
essay, but even if an “Industrious Revolution” occurred that led workers to
labor longer hours, there does not seem to be evidence that the change in the
working conditions should be labeled as labor exploitation.
Key Questions 157
Conclusion
The Industrial Revolution is a very powerful example that our understand-
ing of the past is not absolute and can still be improved in different ways.
Making use of new historical sources that shed new light is one way to do so.
Another means of bettering historical understandings is to implement more
sophisticated methodologies to assess more accurately previous theories.
The question of whether exploitation of the working classes was neces-
sary to have an Industrial Revolution is very challenging. First of all, we
must define what we mean by labor exploitation. Second, we have to ana-
lyze critically the information available regarding real wages, labor produc-
tivity, and living standards as well as qualitative data related to working
conditions in factories, workshops, and mines. Finally, we have to find an
appropriate measure to determine fair remuneration per time unit of labor
for the working classes. Because of these complicated factors, the debate is
still a vivid one.
There is evidence that the increase in economic efficiency and therefore
economic growth was driven by an increase in labor productivity. Real wages
seem to have increased steadily, but only after the end of the Napoleonic wars
in 1815. The issue that remains controversial relates to the working classes’
living standards across the whole period. Although people had access to a
broader range of consumer products, considerable data suggests that they had
to increase the hours they worked to acquire them, therefore reducing leisure
time and very likely their living standards, at least during the first half of the
19th century.
To consider labor exploitation’s potential link to the outbreak of an indus-
trial revolution, we have to dig further into the qualitative data regarding the
actual conditions under which workers were hired. In Britain, the relation-
ship between employers and employees seems to have changed after the con-
clusion of the first Industrial Revolution around 1850 in favor of workers,
with a reduced working day and more holidays. Nonetheless, although evi-
dence for the exploitation of the working classes is not strong, some of the
harsh working conditions imposed on the labor force did not seem to be a
necessary condition for the Industrial Revolution to happen.
rather than in 1760 or 1780 when the Industrial Revolution began. They
ignore how difficult it was to find people willing to work in the first factories
and they ignore the extraordinary lengths that industrial entrepreneurs went
to in order to ensure a supply of docile labor. Without the exploitation of the
working classes in the first generations of the Industrial Revolution, the Brit-
ish tinkerers who solved the practical problems involved in industrialization
would not have had the time or profit cushion to work out their ideas. Nor
would they have had the incentive to persevere through the inevitable hard
times if they could not skim profits from the wages and working conditions
of their laborers. To execute a relatively rapid transformation that yielded
British industrial domination, the exploitation of the working classes to max-
imize entrepreneurial profits was absolutely necessary.
Until the Industrial Revolution had been underway for about 50 years, the
lives of those who labored in factories suffered from their participation in
the industrialization process. Research has demonstrated conclusively that
the working classes’ standard of living, their measure of well-being, began to
improve only after 1830, a trend that accelerated after 1850. Living standards
fell in the generation from 1760 to 1780, rose marginally until the early
1790s, and then declined once again until around 1820. The standard of
living only began to improve in the 1820s, with most of the improvement
coming after 1830. From 1760 to 1820, the standard of living fell about
16 percent before increasing by over 40 percent between 1820 and 1850. For
the British economy as a whole, real family income, which measures the
amount of goods and services that can be purchased, increased about 30 per-
cent in the entire period, but the first three generations of factory workers
experienced a declining standard of living.
How that increase in income was achieved also matters enormously. Higher
family income stemmed from a surge in the number of hours worked on the
part of men, women, and children alike. In 1760, the average employed Brit-
ish adult worked nearly 50 hours a week. In 1850, British adults labored
more than 61 hours a week with many factory workers and miners putting in
up to 84 hours a week. Despite legislation limiting their hours and potential
places in employment, by that same date, 36 percent of children aged 10–14
worked full time for wages outside the home.
Factories and mines were also deeply unpleasant places to labor—an im-
portant feature of the exploitation of the British working classes. Early indus-
trial machinery was dangerous, cutting off fingers, toes, and limbs: steam
engines were prone to explode, scattering shrapnel. Mine shafts collapsed or
asphyxiated miners. Pollution, extremes of heat and cold, lack of ventilation,
and many other unhealthy factors had a strong impact on the life span and
health of workers. Manchester, in the county of Lancashire, the industrial
Key Questions 159
of the factory system. The heavy reliance on underpaid, underage, and unfree
workers demonstrates the exploitative nature of the labor system in the first
generations of the British Industrial Revolution.
The necessity of exploitation to the British Industrial Revolution was also
demonstrated by the actions of the Hanoverian state. Legal repression in myr-
iad forms was complemented by military repression whenever workers re-
sisted their exploitation. Workers were legally prohibited from combining or
joining forces in any way, while entrepreneurs were encouraged to form trusts
to set wages and prices. Particularly during the age of the French Revolution
and Napoleon (1789–1815), the average British person lost many of their
customary rights and protections while new repressive laws restricted indi-
vidual liberties. The ability of British entrepreneurs to get the state to make
machine-breaking into a crime carrying the death penalty in 1812 during the
Luddite movement is representative of how the legal system protected the
economic interests of factory owners by disciplining the working classes.
The factual evidence that the English working classes were exploited is
overwhelming. Although some entrepreneurs or apologists like Andrew Ure
attempted to defend the treatment of the working classes, their efforts should
be seen as justifications for a system that earned huge profits for elites at the
expense of the health and welfare of the working classes. The emigration of
significant numbers of people from the British Isles in search of opportunity
demonstrates how dire the situation was and the lengths that people would go
to in order to avoid factory work. As attitudes shifted in the 1820s and 1830s,
the British state eventually began to investigate the treatment of workers. The
testimony of workers, entrepreneurs, and state employees charged with over-
sight and inspection is incontrovertible in demonstrating the abuses of the
system and the reliance on exploitation to maximize profits. That initial at-
tempts at government regulation of the worst of industrial abuses took decades
to become effective as entrepreneurs thwarted both the spirit and the letter of
the new laws in the name of keeping their profits as high as possible reveals the
ongoing exploitation of the British working classes.
Closing
Whether the exploitation of the working classes was necessary to the Indus-
trial Revolution looks very different depending on which period is given prior-
ity. If the emphasis is 1760–1800 or even 1820, then it is much harder to make
the case that the working classes were not exploited, though the issue of neces-
sity remains an open question. For the period after 1820 or 1830, whether the
working classes experienced exploitation is more debatable. However, the ne-
cessity of poor treatment of the working classes is undermined by the example
Key Questions 161
of entrepreneurs like Robert Owen and the ongoing profitability after legisla-
tive protections were finally passed and made effective in the 1830s and 1840s.
Sergio Castellanos-Gamboa takes a more business-friendly, quantitative
approach to determining whether exploitation took place. He points to the
economic relationship between productivity and wages as the best means of
investigating the issue of exploitation and whether it was needed to generate
an industrial revolution. Jeff Horn also deploys statistics, but his approach
centers on how working people actually lived. Given the well-known short-
comings of the data collected in this era, all statistics should be taken with a
rather large grain of salt. The necessity of exploitation is a sensitive subject
that requires further analysis using both quantitative and qualitative data.
Readers are encouraged to consider this question equally from the perspective
of entrepreneurs and managers and from that of the working classes, as well
as considering what might have been best in the short and in the long run for
society as a whole.
Doing More
Online
Burnette, Joyce. “Women Workers in the British Industrial Revolution.” Available
online at https://eh.net/encyclopedia/women-workers-in-the-british-industrial
-revolution/.
Nye, John V. C. “Standards of Living and Modern Economic Growth.” Available
online at http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/StandardsofLivingandModern
EconomicGrowth.html.
Tuttle, Carolyn. “Child Labor during the British Industrial Revolution.” Available
online at https://eh.net/encyclopedia/child-labor-during-the-british-industrial
-revolution/.
Print
Clark, Gregory. “The Condition of the Working-Class in England, 1209–2004.”
Journal of Political Economy 113, no. 6 (2005): 1307–40.
De Vries, Jan. The Industrious Revolution: Consumer Behavior and the Household Econ-
omy, 1650 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008.
Floud, Roderick, and Paul Johnson, eds. The Cambridge Economic History of Modern
Britain, vol. 1, Industrialisation, 1700–1860. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2004.
Hobsbawm, Eric. Industry and Empire: The Birth of the Industrial Revolution. Lon-
don: Penguin, 1969.
Horn, Jeff. The Path Not Taken: French Industrialization in the Age of Revolution,
1750–1830. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2006.
162 The Industrial Revolution
Humphries, Jane. Childhood and Child Labour in the British Industrial Revolution.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2011.
Thompson, E. P. The Making of the English Working Class. New York: Vintage Books,
1966 [1963].
This question also underscores the need to consider the role of stocks of
capital in industrialization both more critically and more creatively. How
much was needed to enable an industrial revolution? Could it have been ac-
quired elsewhere? Could England, in particular, with its relatively small size
and population, have found an alternative? How long might it have taken?
Would the delay have permitted England’s competitors to steal a march? Put
another way, the essential question is: What was the tipping point in terms of
capital stocks in allowing or even encouraging industrialization? An essen-
tially technical economic analysis ought to be complemented by an answer
that takes cultural attitudes into account. What level of reserves was necessary
to permit investors to support new ways of manufacturing? Did the benefits
of colonialism and imperialism provide governing elites with the experience
and confidence to encourage entrepreneurs and control the working classes?
Such questions are becoming much more prominent in financial considera-
tions of the Industrial Revolution.
Colonialism and imperialism obviously played a major role in the British
Industrial Revolution. The exact nature of that role and whether the contri-
butions of colonialism and empire were necessary to the transformation of
manufacturing that occurred between 1750 and 1850 are much more uncer-
tain. The greatly enhanced attention given to the inputs of Africans in the
Atlantic world has shifted the terms of this question so that scholarly consen-
sus is in flux. What is absolutely clear is that the foundations of European
industrial revolutions must take global trade and colonies into account.
Europe did not industrialize by itself. Manufacturing relied on markets,
resources, and profits from around the globe in order to transform society. In
the 18th and early 19th centuries, Europeans depended on the Atlantic world
for these inputs more than any other global region. In that era and in that
place, European colonialism was inextricably linked to slavery and the slave
trade, which recalls forcibly the issue of exploitation. This question also calls
for analysis of exactly how much capital—either per capita or in total—is
necessary to begin and sustain an industrial revolution.
Sophie Muller’s essay is focused squarely on the Atlantic world. Based on a
variety of factors including mercantilism, she concludes that colonialism in
the so-called New World was necessary to the British Industrial Revolution.
Muller is completing her doctorate in history at the Graduate Center of the
City University of New York. Her dissertation is entitled “Poster Boys: Pater-
nalism, Working-Class Boyhood, and Masculinity in Victorian and Edward-
ian London.” She teaches part-time at John Jay College of Criminal Justice
and the Cooper Union.
The second essay is by Jeff Horn, who recognizes the importance of coloni-
alism and imperialism to the Industrial Revolution but argues comparatively
Key Questions 165
that the profits, markets, and resources garnered through colonialism were
necessary but not sufficient to explain Britain’s industrial transformation.
Horn is professor of history at Manhattan College and the author of five
previous books. His most recent monograph, Economic Development in Early
Modern France: The Privilege of Liberty, 1650–1820 (Cambridge University
Press, 2015) explores these same issues of trade and empire.
lasting at least partly through the mid-19th century, reflected the mercantilist
desire to keep imperial resources within the empire and out of the hands of
foreigners, especially European competitors. While not benefitting from the
lower market price advantage of “free trade,” the requirement that all New
World resources pass through British ports entrenched a trade monopoly
across the Atlantic. North American colonies consumed British manufactured
goods and in return supplied food and resources to Britain’s sugar-producing
colonies, whose resources then flowed back to Britain for trade or production.
Britain gained considerable financial advantages from this controlled trade.
These entrenched networks survived the end of the Navigation Acts and the
independence of the 13 colonies. The continuation of this connection over the
long term had something to do with continued high demand for British con-
sumer goods in the newly independent American states. However, markets do
not tell the whole story.
British investors had long-standing financial relationships with Chesa-
peake tobacco plantation owners. Even after the American Revolution, these
plantation owners remained conduits through which American tobacco made
its way into continental European markets. These British merchants also ben-
efited from the distraction of European military conflicts after 1792. While
no longer obligated to trade, Britain remained America’s primary trading
partner continuing the exchange of New World resources for British manu-
factured goods. At the beginning of the 19th century, Britain continued to be
the conduit through which America conducted most of its overseas trade.
The importance of Britain’s unequal trade relationship with newly independ-
ent and increasingly wealthy America during the early stages of the Industrial
Revolution should not be understated. This network yielded not only in-
creasing export/import income, but also allowed for an increasing flow of
American cotton in the 19th century, enhancing and continuing Britain’s
industrial supremacy in textiles.
Overseas colonial conquests and resource advantages also supported Brit-
ain’s domestic production. Growing resource extraction from the Americas
increased the population of port cities, resulting in the rise in demand for coal
as an urban fuel source. The conquest and protection of colonies, as well as
internal European conflicts, were costly, but increased demand for coal and
iron to manufacture arms thus supported industrial development. Invest-
ment in joint-stock companies and career opportunities from overseas trade
amplified the flow of capital to the British aristocracy and provided new op-
portunities for manufacturing and factory investment, which would be the
foundation of the emerging middle class.
While there was a confluence of factors resulting in Britain being the first
nation to industrialize, at the core of economic advantage and opportunity
168 The Industrial Revolution
powerhouses like the Dutch forced the English state to develop greater au-
thority and to implement monopolistic trade policies that would later become
associated with mercantilism. State action could have focused on defense,
trade, and supporting the development of those English industries, crafts, and
productions that were or could become internationally competitive.
When England began to industrialize in the third quarter of the 18th cen-
tury, its empire consisted primarily of Bengal in India and scattered outposts
along the western coastline of Africa, various Caribbean islands of which
Jamaica was the largest and most important, and a large number of colonies
on the mainland of North America like Canada, Florida, and what came
to be known as the 13 colonies. Although Bengal generated considerable
profits for the British East India Company and the 13 colonies yielded quan-
tities of tobacco, indigo, and rice that did not duplicate what Great Britain
itself produced, the vast bulk of British trade was in tropical and semitropical
commodities such as sugar, cotton, chocolate, coffee, and rice from the Car-
ibbean basin. These commodities were re-exported to Europe or exchanged
for luxury goods from Asia. Millions of Africans were traded for European
manufactures and then brought as slaves to the western hemisphere to grow
these commodities. This global trading network was essential to British
industrialization.
Atlantic trade spawned huge profits for Europeans. Britain’s exports, re-
exports, imports, and service grew from an average annual value of £20,084,000
in 1651–1670 to £105,546,000 in 1781–1800 reaching an amazing
£231,046,000 in 1848–1850. About 40 percent of this total was produced by
Britain. According to historian Joseph Inikori, African labor generated more
than half of this wealth, reaching a high point of 83 percent of British Atlantic
commerce in 1761–1780. Not only was Atlantic trade growing rapidly, but
the exchange also intensely favored Europe. Annual profit from British trade
with the 13 North American colonies was £2.64 million out of an already
depressed official total of £9.5 million. Thus, 28 percent of the volume of
trade was European profit.
The effects of this rapid expansion of highly profitable trade were pro-
found. Growing trade encouraged technological innovation. Integrating dif-
ferent territories into a global trading system brought new opportunities that
fostered commercial and industrial diversification. Perhaps more importantly,
demand for manufactured goods was no longer limited to the size of the do-
mestic or even regional market. Commercial profits were often invested in
industrial concerns, and improved forms of business practice including joint-
stock companies and the London stock market were developed to cope with
the tremendous profits. Within Britain itself, entrepreneurs found numerous
ways and means of exercising their skills, and access to addictive commodities
170 The Industrial Revolution
and fashionable luxury goods led some workers to labor more hours in order
to afford coffee, chocolate, or a silk scarf. To carry this expanded trade, Brit-
ain’s merchant fleet emerged as the largest in the world, more than tripling in
tonnage over the course of the 18th century.
The mercantilist policies developed to manage this trade were based on
colonialism, but they did not have to be. Managing foreign trade to keep a
positive balance led the British government to favor producers at both the top
and bottom of the market who could acquire and maintain markets abroad.
The British government successfully favored domestic producers at the ex-
pense of consumers. As a policy approach, free trade was barely considered,
much less implemented before the middle of the 19th century.
The possibility that Britain could have garnered the profits and products
it needed to industrialize without colonialism is provided by trade with the
newly independent United States after 1783. Despite losing political control
of these former colonies, trade burgeoned, reaching almost £30 million in
1800, more than 300 percent higher than when the Declaration of Inde-
pendence was promulgated. Profitable though it was, the benefit from U.S.
trade was small potatoes compared to that from the slave trade. It is impor-
tant to note that British colonists purchased only a small percent of the
human beings that the British brought to the western hemisphere. The colo-
nies of other European powers absorbed the vast bulk of them. Also, while
the East India Company acquired vast swaths of land, not all of Britain’s
chartered companies were colonialist. Indeed, the Muscovy and Levant
companies were highly profitable despite not governing any territory. Mer-
cantilist trade policies supported and encouraged colonialism, but territorial
expansion was not always necessary to their success. The probability of
slower growth because of fewer protected markets, greater competition, and
lowered margins did not preclude British industrialization, but making the
breakthrough to an industrial revolution would have been far more difficult
and, at the earliest, it would have come a generation or two later. The huge
profits generated by the empire, as opposed to colonial trade, came only in
the 19th century, when the British Industrial Revolution was already well
underway.
The great exception to this counterfactual hypothesis is Ireland. Until
1801, Ireland was a colony of first England and then Great Britain. The needs
of the Irish economy were thoroughly subordinated to Britain’s to avoid or
minimize competition. This protected market and source of raw materials
was essential to British economic competitiveness and showed English and
Scottish elites the profit possibilities of colonialism. It is hard to imagine how
Britain could have had an industrial revolution in the 18th and 19th centu-
ries without firm control of Ireland.
Key Questions 171
Closing
In the 18th and early 19th centuries European colonialism and imperial-
ism centered on the Atlantic world. Following in the footsteps of Portugal
and Spain, England, France, and the Netherlands established outposts and
trade ties in and to various places in Africa and the Americas during the 17th
century. Slavery and the slave trade enabled the development of these links
and colonies. This trade provided products, especially tropical commodities;
consumed a high proportion of Europe’s export of manufactured goods; and
spawned a high percentage of these nations’ commercial profits. It cannot be
doubted that various national industrial revolutions, especially Britain’s, ben-
efited greatly from European domination of these trade relationships.
Both authors agree that colonialism and imperialism were essential con-
tributors to the British Industrial Revolution and that the Atlantic world was
the key to growing European domination of global trade. Where they differ
is on the meaning of those contributions. Muller argues that the economic
advantages provided by the “New World” to Britain were necessary to the
Industrial Revolution by exploring the growth of markets and the provision of
resources including with the independent United States. By deploying coun-
terfactuals as well as thinking comparatively about the emergence of trade rela-
tions in the Atlantic world, Horn believes that through trade Britain could
have accrued the same or similar benefits that it received through colonialism
and imperialism. Without colonies, Britain could still have industrialized,
though the process might have taken longer to get underway. The essays of
Muller and Horn indirectly support the thesis of Kenneth Pomeranz that
domination of the Americas was the key advantage that Europe had in the race
with China to industrialize. Colonialism and imperialism were state policies
that spurred European competitiveness and enabled an industrial revolution.
172 The Industrial Revolution
Doing More
Online
Harley, C. Knick. “Slavery, the British Atlantic Economy and the Industrial Revolu-
tion.” University of Oxford Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History
113, April 2013. Available online at https://www.nuff.ox.ac.uk/economics/history
/paper113/harley113.pdf.
Stuchtey, Benedikt. “Colonialism and Imperialism, 1450–1950.” Available online at
http://ieg-ego.eu/en/threads/backgrounds/colonialism-and-imperialism/benedikt
-stuchtey-colonialism-and-imperialism-1450–1950.
The Transatlantic Slave Trade Database. Available online at http://www.slavevoyages
.org/.
Print
Davis, David Brion. Inhuman Bondage: The Rise and Fall of Slavery in the New World.
New York: Oxford University Press, 2008.
Hont, Istvan. Jealousy of Trade: International Competition and the Nation-State in His-
torical Perspective. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, 2005.
Inikori, Joseph E. Africans and the Industrial Revolution in England: A Study in Inter-
national Trade and Economic Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2002.
Morgan, Kenneth. Slavery, Atlantic Trade and the British Economy, 1660–1800. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000.
Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the
Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2000.
Voth, Hans-Joachim, and Peter Temin. Prometheus Shackled: Goldsmith Banks and
England’s Financial Revolution after 1700. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
2013.
Wallerstein, Immanuel. The Modern World-System III: The Second Era of Great Expan-
sion of the Capitalist World-Economy, 1730s–1840s. Berkeley: University of Cali-
fornia Press, 2011.
Selected Annotated
Bibliography
ONLINE SOURCES
Simply typing a term into a search engine on the Internet is likely to get you
sponsored links, Wikipedia, or unreliable material. It is a far better research
strategy to start with a recognized portal or a known scholar with a recog-
nizable, appropriate institutional affiliation and use them to find material
that is reliable, accurate, and appropriately cited. If you must use Wikipe-
dia, follow the links to sites that have experts making sure that the informa-
tion is accurate. Google Books has a vast collection of materials related to
the Industrial Revolution, but separating the wheat from the chaff is diffi-
cult. It is better to find references beforehand to something that might be
available on Google Books than to start searching there. Although there is a
great deal of excellent material available on the Web—and more every
day—much of it, even on sites that purport to be for educators or students,
is rife with errors and amounts to little more than a brief introduction. Re-
garding the Industrial Revolution, as with any other topic, Internet re-
sources must be used with great care and should start with the sites listed
below.
http://echo.gmu.edu/
The Roy Rosenzweig Center for History and New Media (http://chnm.gmu.edu/) is
an excellent starting point for most historical research. Its links are checked regularly
to make sure that they are working. This institution also works with experts in many
fields related to the study of the past to make sure controversial subjects are linked
appropriately. The digital address above is to ECHO (Exploring and Collecting
174 Selected Annotated Bibliography
History Online), a directory of 5,000 plus Web sites dedicated to science, technology,
and industry. Start here for general sites on the Industrial Revolution.
http://www.econlib.org/index.html
The Library of Economics and Liberty has an encyclopedia that is interesting and
provocative as well as some primary sources, a few books, and several guides to help
find materials. Much of the material and information found on or through this site
has a particular political viewpoint: it can still be valuable, but it should be used with
caution and never uncritically.
http://eh.net/
EH-Net is maintained by a number of highly respected scholarly organizations re-
lated to economic history, broadly speaking. It has several useful resources. The En-
cyclopedia is reputable and useful, though it is hardly comprehensive. The Databases
and How Much Is That? section provide useful information about economic history,
especially related to questions of change or exchanges over time.
http://legacy.fordham.edu/Halsall/mod/modsbook14.asp
Fordham University’s Internet Modern History Sourcebook’s collection of primary
sources on the Industrial Revolution is an excellent place for students and scholars to
find accessible, well-edited, and reliable documents. It is quite stable, which means you
can link to it, though things have shifted on occasion. Other subjects like 18th-century
Britain will also have relevant documents, so browsing often repays your effort.
http://invention.si.edu/
The Lemelson Center for the Study of Invention and Innovation at the Smithsonian
Institution is a good place to consider issues related to invention in U.S. history. It
provides more technical material on science and technology than almost any other
site.
http://ebooks.library.cornell.edu/m/moa/
The Making of America collection at the Cornell University Library is a well-curated
means of accessing primary sources about early industrialization in the United States,
with particular emphasis on science and technology.
https://memory.loc.gov/ammem/index.html
The American Memory project at the Library of Congress is a superb place to look
for primary sources including images on subjects related to U.S. industrialization.
The general collection contains much of interest for those exploring industrialization
in other places.
http://www.nationalarchives.gov.uk/
The British National Archives provides access to a considerable collection of primary
sources and images. The Find Guides can help you navigate its enormous holdings.
Selected Annotated Bibliography 175
Although focused on the United Kingdom, this repository has documents related to
industrialization around the globe, especially in former and current British colonies.
http://www.lib.utexas.edu/maps/
The Perry-Castañeda Library Map Collection at the University of Texas Library is a
phenomenal collection of historical maps covering the entire world. The maps are
available in a variety of formats and include many maps specific to resources, trans-
portation, and demography that are directly relevant to the Industrial Revolution.
http://www.spinningtheweb.org.uk/
This is a rich collection of materials related to textile history in Northwest England
where the Industrial Revolution began. As with all good local history sites, there is
material here found nowhere else.
http://www.victorianweb.org/
The Victorian Web has an eclectic collection of primary and secondary source mate-
rials. Many topics cannot be explored here, but those that are present are usually
useful and reliable. It is not always updated and there are some dead links. Not the
best place to start, but a reasonable repository of documents, interpretations, and
links.
PRINT SOURCES
Economic History
Daunton, Martin J. Progress and Poverty: An Economic and Social History of Britain
1700–1850. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995.
This book is the most insightful socioeconomic account of this critical century and a
half. Well written, it presents a convincing version of why and how the Industrial
Revolution occurred when and where it did. For a general text, it is highly
recommended.
De Vries, Jan. The Industrious Revolution: Consumer Behavior and the Household Econ-
omy, 1650 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008.
This highly controversial book has received a great deal of attention for its provoca-
tive yet problematic linked arguments about the willingness of laborers to work
longer and harder in order to consume more as well as for its emphasis on the role of
this aspect of demand in enabling the occurrence of the Industrial Revolution.
Floud, Roderick, and Paul Johnson, eds. The Cambridge Economic History of Modern
Britain, vol. 1, Industrialisation, 1700–1860. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2004.
This book is one of the key interpretations of the British Industrial Revolution.
For economic history, this work by acknowledged experts in the field ought to be
176 Selected Annotated Bibliography
consulted. Although a little less wide ranging than previous versions, in the subjects
it does treat, Floud and Johnson set the standard.
Pollard, Sidney. The Genesis of Modern Management: A Study of the Industrial Revolu-
tion in Great Britain. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1965.
This path-breaking book links contemporary business practice to the age of the
Industrial Revolution. There is still no better place to learn about the role of manage-
ment in fostering the British Industrial Revolution.
King, Steven, and Geoffrey Timmins. Making Sense of the Industrial Revolution: English
Economy and Society 1700–1850. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2001.
Organized thematically, King and Timmins take on certain issues of daily life that are
rarely found in other volumes. This book is a useful complement to more economi-
cally oriented approaches.
Mantoux, Paul. The Industrial Revolution in the Eighteenth Century: An Outline of the
Beginnings of the Modern Factory System in England, rev. ed. New York: Harper &
Row, 1961.
This classic still provides the best glimpse of the dirt and grit of the early textile mills
and how difficult it was to establish the factory system. The people who made the
Industrial Revolution—entrepreneurs, inventors, managers, foremen, and workers—
mattered enormously to Mantoux. This account is still unmatched for what it does.
Selected Annotated Bibliography 177
Inikori, Joseph E. Africans and the Industrial Revolution in England: A Study in Inter-
national Trade and Economic Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2002.
Without question, Inikori’s challenge to scholars of the Industrial Revolution has
been one of the most profound of the last generation. His powerful argument about
the exploitative nature of the British Industrial Revolution and its reliance on slavery
has not been adequately dealt with by the scholarship.
Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the
Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2000.
Pomeranz’s provocative assertion that the origins of economic “divergence” between
China and Europe were based on the West’s exploitation of other parts of the world
undermines the complacency of insular scholars of Europe and the United States.
Horn, Jeff, Leonard N. Rosenband, and Merritt Roe Smith, eds. Reconceptualizing
the Industrial Revolution. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2010.
This book contains 15 clearly written chapters that explore the Industrial Revolution
in national context. Multiple chapters consider the British experience and two ex-
plore the United States, while others examine various European countries along with
Japan, India, China, and Brazil. The bibliography also provides useful references.
Hounshell, David A. From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932: The
Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1984.
This ground-breaking examination of the process of technological change spawned a
host of imitators and competitors and is still one of the most highly readable accounts
of U.S. industrialization.
178 Selected Annotated Bibliography
Smith, Merritt Roe. Harpers Ferry Armory and the New Technology: The Challenge of
Change. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1977.
This classic examination of the workings of the Harpers Ferry armory and its place in
the story of American industrialization is still rewarding.
Labor
Burnette, Joyce. Gender, Work and Wages in Industrial Revolution Britain. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2008.
This powerfully argued book is controversial, but has stimulated important debate.
Burnette asserts that differences in jobs and pay resulted from genuine disparities in
productivity and were therefore a response to market forces.
Humphries, Jane. Childhood and Child Labour in the British Industrial Revolution.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2011.
The best of a large number of similar books, Humphries compiled an unmatched set
of autobiographies of young workers, which underlay an account of the Industrial
Revolution that brings together economic statistics and intimate detail in a unique
way.
Thompson, E. P. The Making of the English Working Class. New York: Vintage Books,
1966 [1963].
This magisterial account set the agenda for studies of the people who made Industrial
Revolution for a generation. Reading this book will give a real sense of the problems
and challenges faced by the working classes during the later stages of the British In-
dustrial Revolution as well as their relationships with management and the state.
Primary Sources
Cole, G. D. H., and A. W. Filson, eds. British Working Class Movements: Select Docu-
ments 1789–1875. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1967.
This is an older collection, but it brings together a wonderful set of documents about
how workers attempted to deal with mechanization, new technologies, growing man-
agerial control, and the oppression of the state.
Pollard, Sidney, and Colin Holmes, eds. Documents in European Economic History: Indus-
trial Power and National Rivalry, 1870–1914. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1968.
This venerable collection is particularly strong in demonstrating the role of manage-
ment in the Industrial Revolution, both in Britain and elsewhere.
This concise account investigates the role of culture in yielding scientific and techno-
logical advances in a comparative fashion.
Landes, David S. The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial De-
velopment in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1969.
Landes’s interpretation, with its emphasis on the role of technology, is at the heart of
most modern studies of the Industrial Revolution. Although the analysis also covers
the continent, the British paradigm is at the basis of Landes’s influential account of
economic development.
Mokyr, Joel. The Level of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. Ox-
ford: Oxford University Press, 1991.
This short volume is full of insight into the relationship of technological improve-
ment and economic development. It is clear and is still one of the best books on why
some inventions matter more than others and that how people use an invention
sometimes matters as much or more than its technical superiority.
Index
40, 42, 51, 55–56, 68–69, 85, 88, Energy, 15–18, 62, 76, 106, 145–146,
91–92, 132, 149, 153, 156–157, 148, 150
159, 162, 165–167, 170–171; Engels, Friedrich, 89, 113, 128–129,
demand and, xxviii, 18, 22–23, 42, 156
51, 91, 156–157, 159, 162, 165, England. See Great Britain
170–171; Industrious Revolution, Enlightenment, xxiv, 8, 42, 45–47,
and, 55–56, 91, 153, 159, supply 70–71, 83, 88, 130–131, 147;
and, xxi, 22–23, 33, 68–69, 85, 132, education and, 42, 45, 84, 130–131;
149, 165–167, 170–171 influenced by, 8, 46, 70–71, 83, 88,
Cort, Henry, xxv, 59 130–131, 147
Cotton, xxiii, xxiv–xxv, 5, 12, 27–30, Entrepreneur(s), 7, 13, 15, 19–20, 26,
51, 54, 55–57, 63, 66–67, 70, 35, 37, 51, 52–53, 54–55, 62–63,
86–87, 94, 102–104, 108–109, 64–65, 99, 101, 106–108, 108–110,
112, 128–129, 135, 148, 167; 110–114, 143–144, 146, 152–153,
demand for, 28–30, 63, 86, 102, 158, 160, 164, 169; difficulties
148; novelty of, xxiv, 28–29, for, 19–20, 51, 52–53, 54, 107,
55–57; production of, 5, 12, 108–109, 111–112, 144, 158,
27–30, 51, 54, 66–67, 70, 86–87, 160; innovation by, 7, 15, 26, 37,
94, 102–103, 108–109, 112, 51, 52, 54, 62–63, 64–65, 99, 101,
128–129, 135 106–108, 109, 110–113, 146, 152,
Crafts, Nicolas, 142 158, 160, 169; state and, 35, 53,
Credit, 30–32, 101, 115–117, 147 55, 62–63, 64–65, 107–108, 109,
Crompton, Samuel, xxv, 12, 29, 145 111, 113–114, 152–153, 158, 160
Crystal Palace Exhibition, 4, 10, Environment, 45, 73–75, 152
33–35, 83
Factory, factory system, xxvii–xxviii,
D’Alembert, Jean le Rond, 46 5–6, 12, 35–36, 38, 50–52, 66–67,
Darby, Abraham, 59 70–71, 86–87, 93–94, 103–104,
De Vries, Jan, 55, 153 107, 119–121, 126–127, 145–146,
Diderot, Denis, 46 156, 158–160; discipline and,
Discipline, xxvii, 6–7, 35–38, 107, 35–36, 38, 51, 66–67, 71, 103–104,
110–113, 122–125, 152–161 107, 119–121, 126–127, 158–160;
Disease, 17, 21, 73–75, 123, 136 establishment of, xxvii–xxviii, 5–6,
Division of labor, 3, 6, 7, 38–40, 51, 38, 50–51, 86–87, 93–94, 107, 145;
112, 129, 138–140 regional, xxvii, 50, 66–67, 103, 107,
Domestic industry/manufacture, 13, 119, 146, 158
28, 40–42, 51 Factory Acts, 47–50, 71, 158
Fertility, xxiv, 92
Eden, Frederick Morton, 117–118 Fitch, John, 52–54, 100
Education, 14–15, 42–45, 46, 48, Fourier, Charles, 88
64–65, 70–71, 83, 87, 119, 124, France, 14–15, 17, 25–26, 43–44,
130–131, 137, 146 52–53, 57–58, 61–62, 69, 84–85,
Emigration, xiv, 19, 33, 35, 84, 86, 92, 97, 100, 147–149, 166, 168;
112, 152–153, 159–160 competition and, 14–15, 43–44,
Index 183
Machine-breaking, 12, 37, 54, 61, Owen, Robert, 48, 70–71, 88–89,
132–134, 152 134–137, 160
Manchester, 8–9, 63, 70, 73, 79, 94,
99, 127, 128–130, 158–159 Patent, xxii, xxv–xxvi, 5–6, 12–13,
Market(s), 1, 4, 21–24, 25–26, 29, 52–53, 54–55, 61, 72–73, 81,
27–28, 40–41, 69, 139, 147, 149, 93–94, 100, 104–106, 109–110
164–165 Peel, Robert, 47, 54
Marx, Karl, 39, 88–89, 113, 153, 155 Pollution, 17, 73–75, 129, 158
McCormick, Cyrus Hall, 34 Pomeranz, Kenneth, 23, 163, 171
Mechanization, xxv, xxviii, 3–4, 6, 7, Population, xxii, xxiii, xxvi, 1, 21, 34,
38, 50–51, 66–67, 86–87, 94, 40, 63, 90–91, 135; demand and,
103–104, 110, 112, 132–134; xxii, xxvi, 91; economic growth,
factory system and, xxviii, 38, and, xxii, 34, 63, 90; pressure, 1,
50–51, 86–87, 94, 103, 112; 40, 135
invention and, xxv, 3–4, 6–7, 51, Portugal, 20–21, 165, 168
Index 185
Poverty, 5–6, 37, 40–41, 51, 62, 71, 147; Education and, 15, 43–44, 45,
74, 81, 92, 116–118, 122, 124, 139; 64–65, 82, 83, 130–131, 146;
work, and, 5–6, 37, 51, 81, 118, Enlightenment and, 45–46, 83,
122, 124, 139; domestic industry 130–131, 146, 147; industry and,
and, 40–41, 62, 118 15, 25, 43–44, 46, 64–65, 84,
Productivity, xxiii, 2, 35, 38, 56, 71, 142–143, 146, 147
75–77, 81, 138–140, 145, 150, Scotland, xxiii, 2, 37–38, 152, 159
155–157; growth in, xxiii, 76, 156; Second Industrial Revolution, 39, 42,
labor, 2, 35, 38, 56, 71, 76–77, 81, 60, 78, 80, 84–86, 90, 97–98, 103
138–140, 145, 155–157 Shipley, William, 83
Profit(s), 1, 2, 8, 23, 35, 51, 71, 78, Shipping, 22, 68–69, 100–101, 170
103, 113, 127, 143, 145, 152, 154, Skill, xxvii–xviii, 3, 12, 16, 19, 35, 39,
156, 158, 160, 165–166, 169–170; 51, 109, 122, 127
agricultural, 1–2, 143, 166, Slave(s), slavery, xxiv, 21–23, 25, 143,
169–170; commercial, 23, 143, 163–164, 168–171
166, 169–170; industrial, 35, 51, Slater, Samuel, 86–88
71, 103, 113, 127, 145, 152, 154, Smeaton, John, 94
156, 158, 160; mining, 20–21, Smith, Adam, 14, 39, 69, 138–140,
165, 168; transport, 78 145
Socialism, socialist, xxvii, 70–71,
Quesnay, François, 2 88–90, 155
Spain, 20–21, 165, 168
Railroad, xxvi, 10–11, 63, 78–79, 84, Standard of living, xxi, xxii, xxiv, xxvii,
94, 100 1, 17, 33, 36, 47–49, 56, 73–75,
Raw materials, xxvi–xxvii, 8, 14, 90–93, 113, 117–118, 119–121,
21–22, 30–31, 62–63, 74, 78, 121–125, 128–129, 132–134,
84, 96–97, 118, 143, 147–148, 135–137, 142–144, 153, 155–158;
162–163, 166–167, 170; British children, and, 17, 36, 47–49, 56,
advantage, xxvi, 14, 21–22, 31, 62, 73–75, 91–92, 119–120, 121–125,
96–97, 143, 147–148, 162–163, 135–137, 153, 158; factory system
166–167, 170; colonies and, xxi, and, xxvii, 33, 36, 47–49, 73–75,
21–22, 30, 78, 97, 143, 147, 162– 90–92, 117–118, 119–120,
163, 166–167, 170; transportation 121–125, 132–134, 135–137;
and, 8, 63, 78, 84, 148 profit and, xxii, 36, 91, 113, 117,
Roberts, Richard, 29 119, 144; urbanization and, xxiv,
Royal Society of Arts, 13, 33, 43, 33, 73–75, 92, 125, 128–129, 137
83–84, 105 State (or government) action, xxii,
2, 3, 5, 6–7, 14–15, 17, 22–24, 27,
Sadler, Michael, 48 30–32, 36–38, 43–44, 47–49,
Saint-Simon, count de (Claude-Henri 57–58, 59–60, 61–62, 66–67,
de Rouvray), 88–89 68–69, 72, 73–75, 79, 79–82, 83,
Savery, Thomas, 93 84–85, 86–87, 91–92, 94–95,
Science, 15, 25, 43–46, 64–65, 82–84, 95–98, 105–106, 106–108, 109,
105–106, 130–131, 142–143, 146, 111–114, 121–126, 130–131,
186 Index
THE AUTHOR
JEFF HORN is Professor of History at Manhattan College. He is the author
or editor of five previous books including Economic Development in Early
Modern France: The Privilege of Liberty, 1650–1850 (Cambridge University
Press, 2015). He is working on the biography of a terrorist in the age of
the French Revolution and will soon embark on writing a global history text-
book A People’s History of the World to be published by Oxford University
Press.
THE CONTRIBUTORS
SERGIO CASTELLANOS-GAMBOA is a third-year PhD candidate at
Bangor University, UK. His main areas of research interests include consumer
finance, economic history, and financial macroeconomics. His current re-
search aims at analyzing the evolution of consumer credit in Britain after
World War II.