Grossman 1972 Health Capital
Grossman 1972 Health Capital
Grossman 1972 Health Capital
Michael Grossman
National Bureau of Economic Research
The aim of this study is to construct a model of the demand for the
commodity "good health." The central proposition of the model is that
health can be viewed as a durable capital stock that produces an output
of healthy time. It is assumed that individuals inherit an initial stock
of health that depreciates with age and can be increased by investment.
In this framework, the "shadow price" of health depends on many other
variables besides the price of medical care. It is shown that the shadow
price rises with age if the rate of depreciation on the stock of health
rises over the life cycle and falls with education if more educated people
are more efficient producers of health. Of particular importance is the
conclusion that, under certain conditions, an increase in the shadow
price may simultaneously reduce the quantity of health demanded and
increase the quantity of medical care demanded.
I. Introduction
During the past two decades, the notion that individuals invest in them-
selves has become widely accepted in economics. At a conceptual level,
increases in a person's stock of knowledge or human capital are assumed
to raise his productivity in the market sector of the economy, where he
produces money earnings, and in the nonmarket or household sector,
where he produces commodities that enter his utility function. To realize
223
224 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
over time-at an increasing rate, at least after some stage in the life
cycle-and can be increased by investment. Death occurs when the stock
falls below a certain level, and one of the novel features of the model
is that individuals "choose" their length of life. Gross investments in
health capital are produced by household production functions whose
direct inputs include the own time of the consumer and market goods
such as medical care, diet, exercise, recreation, and housing. The produc-
tion function also depends on certain "environmental variables," the
most important of which is the level of education of the producer, that
influence the efficiency of the production process.
It should be realized that in this model the level of health of an indi-
vidual is not exogenous but depends, at least in part, on the resources
allocated to its production. Health is demanded by consumers for two
reasons. As a consumption commodity, it directly enters their preference
functions, or, put differently, sick days are a source of disutility. As an
investment commodity, it determines the total amount of time available
for market and nonmarket activities. In other words, an increase in the
stock of health reduces the time lost from these activities, and the mone-
tary value of this reduction is an index of the return to an investment
in health.
Since the most fundamental law in economics is the law of the down-
ward-sloping demand curve, the quantity of health demanded should be
negatively correlated with its shadow price. The analysis in this paper
stresses that the shadow price of health depends on many other variables
besides the price of medical care. Shifts in these variables alter the
optimal amount of health and also alter the derived demand for gross
investment, measured, say, by medical expenditures. It is shown that the
shadow price rises with age if the rate of depreciation on the stock of
health rises over the life cycle and falls with education if more educated
people are more efficient producers of health. Of particular importance is
the conclusion that, under certain conditions, an increase in the shadow
price may simultaneously reduce the quantity of health demanded and
increase the quantity of medical care demanded.
A. The Model
Let the intertemporal utility function of a typical consumer be
U =: U(fOH02 . .. i Z4 * * *
<OnHni Zn) 2 (1)
commodity in the ith period.1 Note that, whereas in the usual inter-
temporal utility function n, the length of life as of the planning date, is
fixed, here it is an endogenous variable. In particular, death takes place
when Hi = Hmin.Therefore, length of life depends on the quantities of
Hi that maximize utility subject to certain production and resource con-
straints that are now outlined.
By definition, net investment in the stock of health equals gross invest-
ment minus depreciation:
Hi+, - Hi = It - biHiy (2)
where Ii is gross investment and hi is the rate of depreciation during the
ith period. The rates of depreciation are assumed to be exogenous, but
they may vary with the age of the individual. Consumers produce gross
investments in health and the other commodities in the utility function
according to a set of household production functions:
Ii = Ii(Mil THi; Ei), (3 )
Zi - Zi(Xi, Ti; Ei).
In these equations, Mi is medical care, Xi is the goods input in the pro-
duction of the commodity Zi, THi and Ti are time inputs, and Ei is the
stock of human capital.3 It is assumed that a shift in human capital
changes the efficiency of the production process in the nonmarket sector
of the economy, just as a shift in technology changes the efficiency of the
production process in the market sector. The implications of this treat-
ment of human capital are explored in Section IV.
It is also assumed that all production functions are homogeneous of
degree 1 in the goods and time inputs. Therefore, the gross investment
production function can be written as
Ii =Mig(ti; Ei), (4)
where ti -
THilMi. It follows that the marginal products of time and
medical care in the production of gross investment in health are
1 The commodity
Zi may be viewed as an aggregate of all commodities besides health
that enter the utility function in period i. For the convenience of the reader, a glossary
of symbols may be found in Appendix B.
2 In a more complicated version of the model, the rate of depreciation
might be a
negative function of the stock of health. The analysis is considerably simplified by
treating this rate as exogenous, and the conclusions reached would tend to hold even
if it were endogenous.
3 In general, medical care is not the only market good in the gross investment func-
tion, for inputs such as housing, diet, recreation, cigarette smoking, and alcohol con-
sumption influence one's level of health. Since these inputs also produce other
commodities in the utility function, joint production occurs in the household. For an
analysis of this phenomenon, see Grossman (1970, chap. 6). To emphasize the key
aspects of my health model, I treat medical care as the most important market good
in the gross investment function in the present paper.
CONCEPT OF HEALTH CAPITAL 227
dI, ag
aTH1 At '
-
aMi =g i(5)
From the point of view of the individual, both market goods and own
time are scarce resources.The goods budget constraint equates the present
value of outlays on goods to the present value of earnings income over
the life cycle plus initial assets (discounted property income) :4
zP*M- + Vixi E WiT>
+ Ao. (6)
Here Pi and Vi are the prices of Mi and Xi, Wi is the wage rate, TWi is
hours of work, AOis discounted property income, and r is the interest rate.
The time constraint requires that Q, the total amount of time available
in any period, must be exhausted by all possible uses:
TWi+TLI+TH,+T= Q. (7)
where TLI is time lost from market and nonmarket activities due to illness
or injury.
Equation (7) modifies the time budget constraint in Becker's time
model (Becker 1965). If sick time were not added to market and non-
market time, total time would not be exhausted by all possible uses. My
model assumes that TLj is inversely related to the stock of health; that is,
DTLilaHl < 0. If Q were measured in days (Q 365 days if the year
-
is the relevant period) and if pi were defined as the flow of healthy days
per unit of Hi, hi would equal the total number of healthy days in a
given year.5 Then one could write
TL= Q- hi. (8)
It is important to draw a sharp distinction between sick time and the
time input in the gross investment function. As an illustration of this
difference,the time a consumer allocates to visiting his doctor for periodic
checkups is obviously not sick time. More formally, if the rate of de-
preciation were held constant, an increase in THi would increase Ii and
Xi+1 and would reduce TLi+1. Thus, TJJi and TL1+1would be negatively
correlated
By substituting for TWi from equation (7) into equation (6), one
obtains the single "full wealth" constraint:
PiM1+ ViX1+ Wi(TLi + THi + T1) WiQ
(1+r)i (1+r)i
(9)
According to equation (9), full wealth equals initial assets plus the present
value of the earnings an individual would obtain if he spent all of his time
at work. Part of this wealth is spent on market goods, part of it is spent
on nonmarket production time, and part of it is lost due to illness. The
equilibrium quantities of Hi and Za can now be found by maximizing the
utility function given by equation (1) subject to the constraints given by
equations (2), (3), and (9).7 Since the inherited stock of health and the
rates of depreciation are given, the optimal quantities of gross investment
determine the optimal quantities of health capital.
B. Equilibrium Conditions
First-order optimality conditions for gross investment in period i - 1
are:8
(1 bi) *. (1 - n-)WnGn
+(1+r)n
Uk. Ukn
+ xtGo i + (1 - 8) . .. (1 bail-) G.; (10)
Pi- i Wi- 1I
g t4_1 g gI
The new symbols in these equations are: Uhi -D U/ki - the marginal
utility of healthy days; X = the marginal utility of wealth; Gi Dhi/
DHi - (DTLi/DHi) the marginal product of the stock of health in
the production of healthy days; and zi3t the marginal cost of gross
investment in health in period i - 1.
Equation (10) simply states that the present value of the marginal
cost of gross investment in period i - 1 must equal the present value of
marginal benefits. Discounted marginal benefits at age i equal
r Wi Uh* l
2
L(I+r)i+ X
[ (U)(l(r)riGI
-1 ~~~_j
is the psychic rate of return. In equilibrium, the total rate of return on
an investment in health must equal the user cost of health capital in terms
of the price of gross investment. The latter variable is defined as the sum
of the real-own rate of interest and the rate of depreciation.
Wi--+1 y= r- (14)
stantaneous percentage rate of change of marginal cost at age i. For a proof, see Part
B of the Mathematical Appendix.
12 To avoid confusion, a note on terminology is in order. If health were entirely an
investment commodity, it would yield monetary, but not utility, returns. Regardless of
whether health is investment, consumption, or a mixture of the two, one can speak of
a gross investment function since the commodity in question is a durable.
13 Elsewhere, I have used a pure consumption model to interpret the set of phenom-
ena that are analyzed in Sections III and IV. In the pure consumption model, the
marginal monetary rate of return on an investment in health is set equal to zero (see
Grossman 1970, chap. 3).
232 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
IALEC
'..*
rr* -,il + o* \ S
5is
FIG. 1
14 Since the gross investment production function is homogeneous of the first degree,
PMj + WiTHj = Jr1Ij.
CONCEPT OF HEALTH CAPITAL 233
hli
365_ - -
FIG. 2
the equilibrium stock is given by Hi*, where the supply and demand
curves intersect.
In the model, the wage rate and the marginal cost of gross investment
do not depend on the stock of health. Therefore, the MEC schedule would
be negatively inclined if and only if Gi, the marginal product of health
capital, were diminishing. Since the output produced by health capital has
a finite upper limit of 365 healthy days, it seems reasonable to assume
diminishing marginal productivity. Figure 2 shows a plausible relation-
ship between the stock of health and the number of healthy days. This
relationship may be called the "productionfunction of healthy days." The
slope of the curve in the figure at any point gives the marginal product
of health capital. The number of healthy days equals zero at the death
stock Hmin, so that Q - TLi 365 is an alternative definition of death.
Beyond Hmin,healthy time increases at a decreasing rate and eventually
approaches its upper asymptote of 365 days as the stock becomes large.
In Sections III and IV, equation (14) and figure 1 are used to trace out
the lifetime path of health capital and gross investment, to explore the
effects of variations in depreciation rates, and to examine the impact of
changes in the marginal cost of gross investment. Before I turn to these
matters, some comments on the general properties of the model are in
order. It should be realized that equation (14) breaks down whenever
desired gross investment equals zero. In this situation, the present value
of the marginal cost of gross investment would exceed the present value
of marginal benefits for all positive quantities of gross investment, and
equations (16) and (17) would be replaced by inequalities.15 The re-
mainder of the discussion rules out zero gross investment by assumption,
but the conclusions reached would have to be modified if this were not
the case. One justification for this assumption is that it is observed em-
pirically that most individuals make positive outlays on medical care
throughout their life cycles.
Some persons have argued that, since gross investment in health cannot
be nonnegative, equilibriumcondition (14) should be derived by using the
optimal control techniques developed by Pontryagin and others. Arrow
(1968) employs these techniques to analyze a firm's demand for non-
salable physical capital. Since, however, gross investment in health is
rarely equal to zero in the real world, the methods I use-discrete time
maximization in the text and the calculus of variations in the Mathe-
matical Appendix-are quite adequate. Some advantages of my methods
are that they are simple, easy to interpret, and familiar to most econo-
mists. In addition, they generate essentially the same equilibriumcondition
as the Pontryagin method. Both Arrow and I conclude that, if desired
gross investment were positive, then the marginal efficiency of nonsalable
capital would equal the cost of capital. On the other hand, given zero
gross investment, the cost of capital would exceed its marginal efficiency.
The monetary returns to an investment in health differ from the returns
to investments in education, on-the-job training, and other forms of human
capital, since the latter investments raise wage rates.'6 Of course, the
amount of health capital might influence the wage rate, but it necessarily
influences the time lost from all activities due to illness or injury. To
emphasize the novelty of my approach, I assume that health is not a
determinant of the wage rate. Put differently, a person's stock of knowl-
edge affects his market and nonmarket productivity, while his stock of
health determines the total amount of time he can spend producing
money earnings and commodities. Since both market time and nonmarket
time are relevant, even individuals who are not in the labor force have an
incentive to invest in their health. For such individuals, the marginal
product of health capital would be converted into a dollar equivalent by
multiplying by the monetary value of the marginal utility of time.
Since there are constant returns to scale in the production of gross
investment and since input prices are given, the marginal cost of gross
investment and its percentage rate of change over the life cycle are
exogenous variables. In other words, these two variables are independent
of the rate of investment and the stock of health. This implies that con-
sumers reach their desired stock of capital immediately. It also implies
that the stock rather than gross investment is the basic decision variable
in the model. By this I mean that consumers respond to changes in the
cost of capital by altering the marginal product of health capital and not
the marginal cost of gross investment. Therefore, even though equation
(14) is not independent of equations (16) and (17), it can be used to
determine the optimal path of health capital and, by implication, the
optimal path of gross investment.'7
16This difference is emphasized by Mushkin (1962, pp. 132-33).
17This statement is subject to the modification that the optimal path of capital must
always imply nonnegative gross investment.
CONCEPT OF HEALTH CAPITAL 235
18 For a complete discussion of these points, see Becker (1967, pp. 5-12) and Ben-
Porath (1967, pp. 353-61). For models of the demand for physical capital by firms in
which the marginal cost of investment and the amount of investment are positively
correlated, see, for example, Eisner and Strotz (1963) and Gould (1968).
19 Section III demonstrates that an increase in the rate of depreciation on health
capital might cause gross investment to increase.
236 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
Since marginal cost does not depend on age, a,-, - 0 and equation
(14) reduces to
Ryj- r + 8j. ( 18)
20 The possibility that death can occur in period 1 is ruled out from now on.
CONCEPT OF HEALTH CAPITAL 237
r + 6,
r+6i~lX
r s I I
I I
II
11,r IIl in 1 I.
FIG. 3
the elasticity of the MEC schedule (In stands for natural logarithm).21
Equation (19) indicates that the absolute value of the percentage de-
crease in H is positively related to the elasticity of the MEC schedule,
the share of depreciation in the cost of health capital, and the percentage
rate of increase in the rate of depreciation. If -i and bi were constant, the
curve relating In Hi to age would be concave unless r - 0, since22
d~ _ 6
20)
= Hi sil 1si)- ?(
d,
The absolute value of Hi increases over the life cycle because depre-
ciation's share in the cost of capital rises with age.
=-
'Hi
Si 8i
El
Hii- i2
(r +
238 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
If hi grows continuously with age after some point in the life cycle,
persons would choose to live a finite life. Since H declines over the life
cycle, it would eventually fall to Hmin, the death stock. When the cost of
health capital is r + n,,in figure 3, H,, Hmi,,, and death occurs. At
death, no time is available for market and nonmarket activities, since
healthy time equals zero. Therefore, the monetary equivalent of sick time
in period n would completely exhaust potential full earnings, W,,Q. More-
over, consumption of the commodity Z,, would equal zero, since no time
would be available for its production if total time equals sick time.23 Be-
cause individuals could not produce commodities, total utility would be
driven to zero at death.24
Having characterized the optimal path of Hi, one can proceed to ex-
amine the behavior of gross investment. Gross investment's life cycle
profile would not, in general, simply mirror that of health capital. In
other words, even though health capital falls over the life cycle, gross
investment might increase, remain constant, or decrease. This follows
because a rise in the rate of depreciation not only reduces the amount of
health capital demanded by consumers but also reduces the amount of
capital supplied to them by a given amount of gross investment. If the
change in supply exceeded the change in demand, individuals would have
an incentive to close this gap by increasing gross investment. On the
other hand, if the change in supply were less than the change in demand,
gross investment would tend to fall over the life cycle.
To predict the effect of an increase in bi with age on gross investment,
note that the net investment can be approximatedby HjHj.25Since gross
investment equals net investment plus depreciation,
In It In Hi + In (Hi + 8j). (21)
Differentiation of equation (21) with respect to age yields
dHi 1 H
Hi+j Hi -Hi .HiHi.
di Hi
The use of this approximation essentially allows one to ignore the one-period lag be-
tween a change in gross investment and a change in the stock of health.
CONCEPT OF HEALTH CAPITAL 239
since C > 0.
Observe that with the depreciation rate held constant, increases in
gross investment would increase the stock of health and the number of
healthy days. But the preceding discussion indicates that, because the
depreciation rate rises with age, it is not unlikely that unhealthy (old)
people will make larger gross investments than healthy (young) people.
This means that sick time, TLi, will be positively correlated with Mi and
THi, the medical care and own time inputs in the gross investment func-
tion, over the life cycle.28 In this sense, at least part of TL, or TH, may
be termed "recuperationtime."
Unlike other models of the demand for medical care, my model does
not assert that "need" or illness, measured by the level of the rate of
depreciation, will definitely be positively correlated with utilization of
medical services. Instead, it derives this correlation from the magnitude
of the elasticity of the MEC schedule and indicates that the relationship
between the stock of health and the number of healthy days will tend
to create a positive correlation. If E is less than 1, medical care and
"need" will definitely be positively correlated. Moreover, the smaller the
value of A, the greater the explanatory power of "need" relative to that
of the other variables in the demand curve for medical care.
It should be realized that the power of this model of life cycle behav-
ior is that it can treat the biological process of aging in terms of con-
ventional economic analysis. Biological factors associated with aging raise
the price of health capital and cause individuals to substitute away from
future health until death is "chosen." It can be concluded that here, as
elsewhere in economics, people reject a prospect-the prospect of longer
life in this case-because it is too costly to achieve. In particular, only if
the elasticity of the MEC schedule were zero would individuals fully
compensate for the increase in hi and, therefore, maintain a constant
stock of health.
28 Note that the time path of Hi or hi would be nonmonotonic if the time path of
8i were characterized by the occurrence of peaks and troughs. In particular, hi would
be relatively low and THi and M, would be relatively high (if E < 1) when 8, was
relatively high; these periods would be associated with relatively severe illness.
CONCEPT OF HEALTH CAPITAL 24I
A. Wage Effects
Since the value of the marginal product of health capital equals WG, an
increase in the wage rate, W, raises the monetary equivalent of the mar-
ginal product of a given stock. Put differently, the higher a person's wage
rate, the greater the value to him of an increase in healthy time. A con-
sumer's wage rate measures his market efficiency or the rate at which he
can convert hours of work into money earnings. Hence, it is obviously
positively correlated with the benefits of a reduction in the time he loses
from the production of money earnings due to illness. Moreover, a high
wage rate induces an individual to substitute market goods for his own
time in the production of commodities. This substitution continues until
in equilibrium the monetary value of the marginal product of consump-
tion time equals the wage rate. So the benefits from a reduction in time
lost from nonmarket production are also positively correlated with the
wage.
29 Strictly speaking, shifts in Xi would definitely have no effects on Hi if and only
if X. -0. Even though a uniform shift in X. implies that there is no correlation be-
tween its level and rate of change, Hi might be altered if Xi #&0. For a complete dis-
cussion of this point, see Grossman (1970, p. 49).
30 Since the analysis in this section deals with variations in X among individuals of
the same age, time subscripts are omitted from now on. Note also that (25), like the
expression for Ii, ignores the one-period lag between an increase in gross investment
and an increase in the stock of health.
242 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
C la,
(',IW=1 J1EC2: W=W2>Wl
_ _ _I \___ _ I \_ _ _ _
FIG. 4
If an upward shift in the wage rate had no effect on the marginal cost
of gross investment, a 1 percent increase in it would increase the rate of
return, y, associated with a fixed stock of capital by 1 percent. In fact,
this is not the case because own time is an input in the gross investment
function. If K is the fraction of the total cost of gross investment ac-
counted for by time, then a 1 percent rise in W would increase marginal
cost, aT,by K percent. After one nets out the correlation between W and
AT,the percentage growth in y would equal 1 - K, which exceeds zero as
long as gross investment is not produced entirely by time.
Since the wage rate and the level of the MEC schedule are positively
correlated, the demand for health would be positively related to W.
Graphically, an upward shift in W from W1 to W2 in figure 4 shifts the
MEC schedule from MEC1 to MEC2 and, with no change in the cost of
health capital, increases the optimal stock from H1 to H2. A formula for
the wage elasticity of health capital is31
eH,W (1 - K)E. (26)
This elasticity is larger the larger the elasticity of the MEC schedule and
the larger the share of medical care in total gross investment cost
Although the wage rate and the demand for health or gross invest-
ment are positively related, W has no effect on the amount of gross in-
vestment supplied by a given input of medical care. Therefore, the demand
for medical care would rise with the wage. If medical care and own time
were employed in fixed proportions in the gross investment production
function, the wage elasticity of M would equal the wage elasticity of H.
On the other hand, given a positive elasticity of substitution, M would
increase more rapidly than H. This follows because consumers would
have an incentive to substitute medical care for their relatively more ex-
pensive own time. A formula for the wage elasticity of medical care is
emJ-W= Ka,, + (1 - K)8, (27)
where ap is the elasticity of substitution between M and Th in the pro-
duction of gross investment.32 The greater the value of op, the greater
the difference between the wage elasticities of M and H.
Note that an increase in the price of either medical care or own time
raises the marginal or average cost of gross investment. But the effects
of changes in these two input prices are not symmetrical. In particular,
an upward shift in the price of medical care lowers the MEC schedule
and causes the demand for health to decline. This difference arises be-
cause the price of time influences the value of the marginal product of
health capital while the price of medical care does not.
32 For a proof, see Part C of the Mathematical Appendix. The corresponding equa-
tion for the wage elasticity of the own time input is
eTHW (1 - K) (e - (p) .
This elasticity is positive only if ? > a.
244 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
the household as well as in the market, and the analysis focuses on this
environmental variable.
The specific proposition to be examined is that education improves
nonmarket productivity. If this were true, then one would have a con-
venient way to analyze and quantify what have been termed the non-
monetary benefits to an investment in education. The model can, however,
treat adverse as well as beneficial effects and suggests empirical tests to
discriminate between the two.33
To determine the effects of education on production, marginal cost,
and the demand for health and medical care, recall that the gross invest-
ment production function is homogeneous of degree 1 in its two direct
inputs-medical care and own time. It follows that the marginal product
of E, the index of human capital, would be
I a (g tg') ~-1-TH Og'
=M +
where g - tg' is the marginal product of medical care and g' is the mar-
ginal product. of time.34 If a circumflex over a variable denotes a per-
centage change per unit change in E, the last equation can be rewritten as
01 1 _ [M(g-tg') ] ( _gg_tg_ T A( )
rH- F7 L i g -tg' )+ jg)
(28)
Equation (28) indicates that the percentage change in gross investment
supplied to a consumer by a one-unit change in E is a weighted average
of the percentage changes in the marginal products of M and TH.35
If E increases productivity, then rH > 0. Provided E raises both mar-
ginal products by the same percentage, equation (28) would simplify to
rH g-g'A (29)
33 The model developed here is somewhat similar to the one used by Michael (1969).
34 If I is homogeneous of degree 1 in M and TH, then from Euler's theorem
36 For a proof, see Part D of the Mathematical Appendix, where the human capital
formulas are developed in more detail.
37 It should be stressed that the model of nonmarket productivity variations pre-
sented here examines the partial effect of an increase in education with the wage rate
held constant. Although these two variables are surely positively correlated, this corre-
lation does not appear to be large enough to prevent one from isolating pure changes
in nonmarket productivity at the empirical level. For some evidence on this point, see
Grossman (1970, chap. 5) and Michael (1969, chaps. 4 and 5).
:38If W and r + b are fixed and if G depends only on H, then
d In(r + 8) dnmG d nH d In t
dE a lnH dE dE
or
A
H
o- - + rH.
E
246 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
FIG. 5
schooling might supply him with 3 percent more health. Given this con-
dition, both persons would demand the same amounts of M and TH. As
this example illustrates, any effect of a change in E on the demand for
medical care or time reflects a positive or negative difference between
H and rH:39
M TH -rH(e - 1)* (32)
The main purpose of this paper has been to construct a model of the
demand for the commodity "good health." The central proposition of the
model is that health can be viewed as a durable capital stock that pro-
duces an output of healthy time. A person determines his optimal stock
of health capital at any age by equating the marginal efficiency of this
capital to its user cost in terms of the price of gross investment. Graphi-
cally, each person has a negatively inclined demand curve for health
3!) The terms M and TH are equal because, by the definition of factor neutrality, E
has no effect on the ratio of the marginal product of M to the marginal product of TH.
CONCEPT OF HEALTH CAPITAL 247
capital, which relates the marginal efficiency of capital to the stock, and
an infinitely elastic supply curve. The equilibrium stock is determined by
the intersection of these two functions. The demand curve slopes down-
ward due to diminishing marginal productivity of health capital.
Although in recent years there have been a number of extremely in-
teresting explorations of the forces associated with health differentials
(Adelman 1963; Fuchs 1965; Larmore 1967; Newhouse 1968; Auster,
Leveson, and Sarachek 1969), these studies have not developed behav-
ioral models that can predict the effects that are in fact observed. Con-
sequently, the framework I have developed is important because of its
ability to bridge the existing gap between theory and empiricism in the
analysis of health differentials. My model explains variations in both
health and medical care among persons in terms of variations in supply
and demand curves for health capital. This paper has traced upward
shifts in the supply curve to increases in the rate of depreciation on the
stock of health with age, and it has traced upward shifts in the demand
curve to increases in the wage rate and education.
One prediction of the model is that if the rate of depreciation increases
with age, at least after some point in the life cycle, then the quantity of
health capital demanded would decline over the life cycle. At the same
time, provided the elasticity of the marginal efficiency of capital schedule
were less than unity, expenditures on medical care would rise with age.
A second prediction is that a consumer's demand for health and medical
care should be positively correlated with his wage rate. A third prediction
is that if education increases the efficiency with which gross investments
in health are produced, then the more educated would demand a larger
optimal stock of health. On the other hand, given a relatively inelastic
demand curve, the correlation between medical outlays and education
would be negative. It should be noted that one of the advantages of the
model is that it enables one to study the effects of demographicvariables
like age and education without assuming that these variables are posi-
tively or negatively correlated with consumers' "tastes" for health. In-
stead, these variables enter the analysis through their impact on either
the cost of health capital or its marginal efficiency, and one can make
strong predictions concerning their effects on health levels or medical
care.
It must be admitted that this paper has made a number of simplifying
assumptions, all of which should be relaxed in future work. A more gen-
eral model would treat the depreciation rate as an endogenous variable
and would not rule out periods in which the optimal amount of gross
investment is zero. Most important of all, it would modify the assump-
tion that consumers fully anticipate intertemporal variations in depre-
ciation rates and, therefore, know their age of death with certainty. Since
in the real world length of life is surely not known with perfect foresight,
248 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
Appendix A
Mathematical Appendix
A. Utility Maximization-Discrete Time
To maximize utility subject to the full wealth and production function con-
straints, form the Lagrangian expression
L= U(fOHoI ... ., <nHn2Zo, .. Zn)
Ci + Clt. + WiTLiX
+ROR (1 + r)i J.()
t
where Ci = PiMi + WiTHi and Cli - ViXi + WiTi. Differentiating L with re-
spect to gross investment in period i - 1 and setting the partial derivative
equal to zero, one obtains
&hIz 3H4 Ohi+1 3IJj~i
Uhi as dt + Uhi+l -H a
But
ahi
a__i aH1 - (1 - al
a
=( t ..1td - i-, and = G.
G
(1O- (1.. 6'1Idj OHj
Therefore,
________ WiGi (1 - i)Wi++Gi+l
(1+ r) i- 1 (1 + r)i -+- (1+ r)i+ 1
(1 - 60 ... (1
O - ..n.-.... Uhk
++ Gi
(++r)} r)
Uk~~1 U1+
+ (1 - hi) Ak+l Gi+i + (1 -hi) ... . (1 an-l) n Gn
(A3)
41 Strotz (1955-56) has shown, however, that certain restrictions must be placed on
the m,. In particular, the initial consumption plan will be fulfilled if and only if mi =
(mO)i.
42 The variable
qj equals the marginal cost of Zi.
250 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY
aQ d aQ (A11)
aH di a(Al
In the present context,
aQ = e-ri, (A12)
aHi
d aQ + Xe-rira,
di aHe +
Consequently,
-
Gi Wi + ( eri] jr(r Ii + bi) (A13)
which is the continuous time analogue of equation (13).
C. Wage Effects
To obtain the wage elasticities of medical care and the time spent producing
health, three equations must be partially differentiated with respect to the wage.
These equations are the gross investment production function and the two first-
order conditions for cost minimization:
I(M, TH; E) = Mg(t; E) - (H + 8)H,
W - g'
P - JT(g - tg').
I t
IF, + W + -
W
MoP- ()P +I GW p
lop + W -0
dM
dW
k,+ W + P
I(; - I_ p + P
P t -t
I(;p + W tW
emw (1 - Kop.
K)c + (A16)
Along similar lines, one easily shows that
eTHW = (1 -K) (- -p). (A17)
&E g
If a shift in human capital were "factor neutral," the percentage changes in
these two marginal products would be equal:
gg -
^- g tg '
or
Al =
g g rH. (A18)
The average cost of gross investment in health is defined as
a (PM + WTH)IF - (P + Wt)g'1.
Given factor neutrality,
and
A A
d~~t
1 gg -tg g A
H -M + rH.
Appendix B
References